47
Neo-liberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal. 1993-94 – 2004-05 SUDIPTA BHATTACHARYYA  Based on surveys conducted in 1993-94 and 2004-05 on same set of households, this study shows nature of the differentiated economy of West Bengal (WB) against the backdrop of neoliberal reform in India since 1991. The major findings of this study is that during the decade of neo-liberal reform, the interventionist economy eroded in rural West Bengal and peasant differentiation was going on. The analysis which follows examines the structure of investment and production taking place in West Bengal, the reference point being the debate between Marxism and populism about peasant differentiation. The process of socio-economic differentiation has been intensified during neo-liberal reform, but methodologically farm size alone fails to register its extent. The main claim advanced by populism - Chayanov’s argument concerning demographic differentiation, that rising consumer/worker ratios are accompanied by higher family labour input – was not applicable. The efficiency of small farms in the form of inverse relationship between farm size and productivity suggested by Sen has not been found. Among the effects of state intervention in the agrarian sector have been: a decline in the number of holdings above ten acres, in the extent of sharecropping contracts, and in the incidence of absolute landlessness. Though landlessness increased to limited extent during reform period. The institutional credit provision by the state eroded during neo-liberal reform and  distress sales (in the form of product marketed) by poorer farmers are still evident. BACKGROUND West Bengal is one of the important Indian states that has been ruled by the Left Front Government over three and half decades (1977-2009) and makes a record as the longest staying democratic government in the world. After the Indian independence like other states the agrarian structure was dominated by retrogressive elements like landlords, moneylenders, and traders, all of whom had flourished under colonialism. Radical peasant movements Sudipta Bhattacharyya is the Associate Professor at the Department of Economics and Politics, Visva-Bharati, Santiniketan, West Bengal. 

Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    16

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

Neo­liberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal. 

1993­94 – 2004­05

SUDIPTA BHATTACHARYYA

  Based   on   surveys   conducted   in   1993­94   and   2004­05   on   same   set   of  households,   this  study shows nature of  the  differentiated  economy of  West  Bengal (WB) against the backdrop of neoliberal reform in India since 1991. The  major  findings  of   this   study   is   that   during   the  decade  of  neo­liberal  reform, the interventionist economy eroded in rural West Bengal and peasant  differentiation   was   going   on.   The  analysis   which   follows   examines   the  structure   of   investment   and   production   taking   place   in   West   Bengal,   the  reference   point   being   the   debate   between   Marxism   and   populism   about  peasant   differentiation.   The   process   of   socio­economic   differentiation   has  been   intensified  during  neo­liberal   reform,  but  methodologically   farm size  alone   fails   to   register   its  extent.  The main  claim advanced  by  populism ­  Chayanov’s   argument   concerning   demographic   differentiation,   that   rising  consumer/worker ratios are accompanied by higher family labour input – was  not   applicable.   The   efficiency   of   small   farms   in   the   form   of   inverse  relationship between farm size and productivity suggested by Sen has not been  found.  Among  the effects  of  state   intervention   in   the agrarian sector  have  been: a decline in the number of holdings above ten acres, in the extent of  sharecropping   contracts,   and   in   the   incidence   of   absolute   landlessness.  Though landlessness  increased to limited extent  during reform period.  The  institutional  credit  provision by the state  eroded during neo­liberal  reform  and   distress sales (in the form of product marketed) by poorer farmers are  still evident.

BACKGROUND

West Bengal   is  one of  the important  Indian states   that  has been ruled  by the Left  Front 

Government over  three and half  decades (1977­2009) and makes a  record as  the longest 

staying democratic government in the world. After the Indian independence like other states 

the agrarian structure was dominated by retrogressive elements like landlords, moneylenders, 

and   traders,   all   of  whom had   flourished  under   colonialism.  Radical   peasant  movements 

Sudipta Bhattacharyya is the Associate Professor at the Department of Economics and Politics, Visva­Bharati, Santiniketan, West Bengal. 

Page 2: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

mobilized   by   leftist   organisations   challenged   the   ruling   Congress   Party,   which   in   turn 

compromised with the vested interests in what was a de facto unreformed agriculture. As a 

result,   all   land   reform   legislation   passed   by   the   state   was   shelved,   and   remained 

unimplemented. Consequently the programme of capitalist development remained unfinished. 

This was the background to the peasant movements which emerged in post­independence 

West Bengal, and played a pivotal role behind the formation of a Left­Centrist Coalition in 

1967 and 1969 and ultimately the Left Front government in 1977. In the period since then, 

the   state   in   West   Bengal   has,  within   the   legislative   limits   imposed  by   the   constitution, 

adopted   a   pro­poor   stance   in   terms   of   agricultural   policy.   However,   this   pro­poor 

interventionist legacy started to get disturbed since early nineties, when Government of India 

adopted IMF styled neo­liberalism in 1991 and as a result food, fertilizer and credit subsidies 

were   largely  eliminated   in   agriculture.  Public   investment   in   agriculture  was  also   largely 

reduced   with   the   good   hope   that   the   private   investment   would   crowd   out   the   public 

investment.   There   was   a   deregulation   of   the   market,   the   agricultural   trade   was   also 

liberalized.  Last  but  not   the   least  a   large  area  was converted   from food crops   to  export  

oriented commercial crops. There was a move from untargeted to targeted PDS and rural 

poor  was  largely  eliminated  by type  2 error  as   they could not  prove  themselves  as poor 

overcoming government red tapism. The new market oriented contract farming, corporate 

retail chain, agribusiness and microfinance institution supposed to replace partly or wholly 

the public distribution system, government co­operatives, nationalized rural credit institutions 

and   government   mandis.   But   the   expectation   was   largely   belied.   Because   these   newly 

emerged neo­liberal  institutions  could not spread much. As Barbara Hsarriss­White noted 

down deregulated markets becomes far more imperfect than regulated market (REF). The 

2

Page 3: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

impact of market reform in agriculture was disastrous. Private investment did not crowd out 

public investment rather opposite happened following the fact that both are complementary in 

India.  The spread of  corporate  retail  chain  and agribusiness  was utterly   limited   in  India. 

Where they succeeded e.g. Madhya Pradesh they turned out as extremely anti­poor (Mehta 

2005). In some places there were organized and violent protest against such institutions. On 

the other hand microfinance institution in India has become largely a government body which 

are refinanced and controlled by commercial bank and NABARD. As a result of there is a 

breakdown of old institutions and the new institutions becomes non­functional. On the other 

hand the cost of production enhanced to a large extent but the selling price remains low. As a 

result for the producers investment in agriculture becomes a non­profit phenomenon. On the 

other hand a large proportion of consumers has lost its purchasing power. Most strikingly the 

agricultural  growth rate   (1.66%) had declined  below the  population  growth  rate   (1.85%) 

during liberalization period. The inequality and poverty also significant during this period.    

THE PROBLEM. 

The   analysis   which   follows   examines   the   changing   structure   of   investment   and 

production taking place over a decade of neo­liberal policy regime of the Government of 

India in West Bengal where Left Front Government did not have any choice.  The process of 

socio­economic differentiation has been intensified during one decade of neo­liberal policy 

regime.   The   main   claim   advanced   by   populism   ­   Chayanov’s   argument   concerning 

demographic differentiation, that rising consumer/worker ratios are accompanied by higher 

family labour input – was not applicable. Of particular interest is the role during the last thirty 

two years of the Left Front government in the process of agrarian transformation, and the 

3

Page 4: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

extent   to   which   its   pro­poor   policy   interventions   have   stabilized   smallholding   peasant 

production. Among the effects of state intervention during eighties in the agrarian sector had 

been: a decline in the number of holdings above ten acres, in the extent of sharecropping 

contracts, and in the incidence of absolute landlessness. However, during the nineties this 

process   had   been   halted.   Particularly   landlessness   both   in   absolute   and   relative   terms 

increased. The institutional credit provisions by the state eroded during neo­liberal reform 

and distress sales (in the form of product marketed) by poorer farmers are still evident.

This   analysis   is   carried   out   against   the   backdrop   of   the   debate   between   Marxism   and 

populism.  The principal Marxist contributions to this debate came from Kautsky [1988] and 

­ more importantly ­ from Lenin [1977]. In his seminal text, ‘The Development of Capitalism 

in   Russia’   first   published   in   1899,   Lenin   outlined   his   thesis   about   the   socio­economic 

differentiation of the peasantry, and how an emergent capitalism depended on this process. 

Challenging the Russian populists (or Narodniks), who maintained that the peasantry was an 

homogeneous  entity  not   affected   fundamentally  by  differentiation,  Lenin  maintained   that 

capitalist development required creation of a home market, both for labour­power and the 

product of labour, each of which would be furnished by different components of what had 

hitherto been a self­sufficient (or middle) peasantry.

During the 1960s the populist ideas of the Russian Narodniks re­emerged, mainly as a result 

of the re­engagement by development studies with the economic ideas of A. V. Chayanov 

[1966; 1991]. The latter’s newly­translated work reinstated the concept of an homogenous 

Third World peasantry, whereby economically self­sufficient smallholders were recast as a 

4

Page 5: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

different mode of production; instead of economic differentiation, determined by exogenous 

variables   (rent,   labour   and   land   markets),   peasants   were   subject   to   an   endogenous   and 

distinctly   non­economic   dynamic,   a   process   of   cyclically­determined   demographic 

differentiation. This non­Marxist interpretation was taken up with enthusiasm by many in the 

field  of  development  studies:   for  example,  Lipton [1977],  Georgescu­Roegen [1960] and 

Amartya  Sen  [1966]  all   extended   the   interpretation  of   an  homogenous  peasantry,   in   the 

process giving it a dynamic character by arguing that family labour farms (non­differentiated 

petty producers) were more ‘efficient’ than capitalist farms which hired labour at the going 

wage rate. On the other hand Bhaduri [1993] developed a model of the agrarian economy 

where differentiation was linked to peasant  indebtedness,  with some households escaping 

debt via increased thrift and other falling more deeply into debt and becoming poor. Such an 

approach   to   socio­economic  differentiation  does  not   have   any   immediate   relation   to   the 

development   of   capitalism   in   agriculture;   much   rather,   its   focus   is   on   a   process   of 

differentiation   as   this   occurs   in   an   environment   of   pre­capitalist   relations.   This   was   in 

keeping with his previous work, where Bhaduri [1973] had examined conflict involving a 

typical   landlord and a typical  peasant in a context  structured by economically backwards 

semi­feudal relations. In a similar vein, Easwaran and Kotwal [1989] posited the existence of 

classes  defined  by  unequal   access   to   credit   on   the  part  of  peasant   households,  without, 

however, specifying the basis for this inequality of access. Such an approach is not so very 

different from a typical neo­classical model based on the utility maximizing behaviour of the 

principal  and the agent [Stiglitz,  1987].  Ranajit  Guha [1988] also divided the entire  rural 

population   into   two   communities   ­   elite   and   subaltern.   Since   class   is   replaced   by 

5

Page 6: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

‘community’,  peasant  differentiation  arising from unequal  possession of assets   is   thereby 

overlooked.

The common thread in each of the above texts is that they have all neglected the role of 

ownership of the means of production as the basis on which class differentiation in the rural 

economy takes place. In my opinion the classical Marxist analysis, as embodied in the work 

of Lenin, is much more nuanced than any of these theoretically simplistic positions, since it 

recognises both the existence and at the same time the theoretical complexity of the different 

modes of production which combine in any given transitional social formation.

In   spite   of   having   a   successful   experiment   of   a   limited   land   reform and  pro­poor   state 

intervention, the agrarian economy of West Bengal had been class differentiated even during 

the pick period of state intervention in eighties. The neo­liberal reform in 1990s has made this 

differentiation more intensified. . A consequence has been a greater ownership concentration 

in   the upper  echelons  of   the  rural  class  structure,  combined  with an equally  pronounced 

tendency   towards  proletarianization  and a   loss  of  ownership  of   the  means  of  production 

affecting those at the lower ends of the same hierarchy. It is important to note, however, that 

West Bengal constitutes an unusual case, in that class differentiation has been accompanied 

by pro­poor state intervention particularly during 1980s. By moderating the effects of the 

market,   the   limited   agrarian   reform   in   West   Bengal   has   had   a   positive   impact   on   the 

economic   condition   of   the   rural   poor.   Simply   put,   pro­poor   intervention   has   helped   to 

stabilize petty commodity production by smallholding peasants.1 It has also helped to stop the 

market­led process of immiseration2, and has made differentiation itself more broad based ­ 

giving an upward impetus to more people.3 But even during 1980s these positive changes had 

6

Page 7: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

not been sufficiently strong to stop the process of differentiation altogether, or to alter the 

concentration of means of production in the hands of a few. Since the early 1990s along with 

other  Indian states  West Bengal   too was exposed with market  reform that  dampened the 

positive impact of interventionist regime to a great extent. Since the early 1990s agricultural 

production, yield, consumption of fertilizer, proportion of HYV area, cropping intensity and 

institutional   credit   experienced  a  negative   trend  break   (Bhattacharyya  and  Bhattacharyya 

2007). As the neo­liberal reforms involved withdrawal of state from pro­poor interventionist 

policies   one   can   expect,   therefore,   to   encounter   a   familiar   and   consistent   pattern   of 

maldistribution,  whereby economic indicators  (assets,  irrigation,  output,  marketed surplus, 

etc.) are likely to be biased towards the upper echelons in the agrarian class structure.

Table 1 illustrates the Gini coefficients for the distribution of different variables among size 

classes/asset   groups   that   represent   productive   capacity  or   the  means  of   production.  The 

figures   are  drawn  from  the  various   rounds  of   the  National  Sample  Survey  Organization 

(NSSO), the reference years for which are 1972 (pre Left Front regime), 1982 (beginning 

years of the Left Front rule), 1992 (beginning of market reform) and 2002­03 (after a decade 

of market reform). The major findings are as following: 

First of all, the Gini Coefficient of West Bengal for almost all variables are lower than India 

in  all  reference year.  This   is  because of  the dual facts   that  (a)  West  Bengal experienced 

successful land reform under United Front and Left Front Government vis­à­vis other states 

in  India and (b) West  Bengal  has significantly high population  density  among all   Indian 

states. 

7

Page 8: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

Secondly, owing to the land reform land based variables like owned land, the concentration 

of owned and operated land declined in West Bengal during 1972­92. At the same time non­

land  asset   registered  an   increase.  However,  during   the   first  decade  1972­82 owned  land 

increased from 0.572 to 0.593 and the operated land declined from  0.608 to 0.501 and that of 

irrigated   land   also   increased   from   0.452   to   0.469.   In   the   next   decade   (1982­92)   land 

inequality massively declined in West Bengal from 0.593 to 0.503 for owned land and from 

0.501 to 0.434 for operated land. The concentration in non­land asset however increased from 

0.547 to 0.570. The concentration in irrigated area and borrowing however remained almost 

unchanged in West Bengal during this period. However, during the next decade 1992 ­ 2002­

03,  which  was essentially  neo­liberal  era,  again  land  inequality   increased (from 0.434  to 

0.525 for operated land and 0.503 to 0.517 for operated land) and non­land asset inequality 

declined  (from 0.570  to 0.438).  Also concentration  in  irrigated  area also increased.    The 

increase in inequality is due to the withdrawal of pro­poor intervention during neo­liberal 

reform.

It  should be noted that  increased inequality  in  the non­land asset market  in West Bengal 

during eighties  was  interconnected with declined  inequality   in  the  land market.  The land 

reform during the eighties apart from lowering land inequality acted as an engine of agrarian 

growth and investment. As a result of that an enhanced market for non­land assets, inputs and 

implements were created. A bulk of the erstwhile zamindars invested in the market of non­

land assets. An inequality developed as a result in the non­land asset market. At the India as a 

whole almost similar tendencies were found except the fact that the concentration for owned 

8

Page 9: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

land declined marginally from 1992 to 2002­03. Another scenario at the all India level is the 

growing concentration of the borrowing during the last decade from 0.392 to 0.474 (we don’t 

have data for West Bengal), which may be a reflection of increased unequal access to credit 

during the neo­liberal era.   

T A B L E –1VALUE OF GINI­COEFFICIENTS FOR VARIABLES REPRESENTING 

PRODUCTIVE CAPACITY : WEST BENGAL AND INDIA*

       Variables            1972             1982 1992 2002­03

WestBengal

India WestBengal

India WestBengal

India WestBengal

India

Asset (Non­land)Owned LandOperated LandIrrigationOutstanding Credit Borrowing

0.660**0.5720.6080.452NANA

0.5850.6650.6710.5010.387NA

0.5470.5930.5010.4690.3610.353

0.5850.6650.5880.5080.4060.396

0.5700.5030.4340.4720.4030.352

0.6210.6520.5880.5430.3980.392

0.4380.5170.5250.5400.377NA

0.5610.6360.6940.6590.3810.474

*Cultivator Households where otherwise not mentioned.  **Value for All Rural Households.NA = Not Available.

METHODOLOGY

The   analysis   which   follows   is   based   on   a   field   survey   conducted   among   210   sample 

households in two parts of Bankura district, West Bengal, over 1993/94 and 2004­05. As a 

matter of fact we had initially surveyed these households in 1993­94. In 2004­05 we have re­

9

Page 10: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

surveyed same households once more. In some particular cases where we found an original 

household surveyed in 1993­94 got bifurcated into two or three in 2004­05 as a result of 

inheritance, we selected the dominant household that inherited most of the property belong to 

the  original  household.  Where   the  property  had been equally  distributed  among  multiple 

inheritor, we randomly selected any one of them. 

Bankura   district   was   selected   in   order   to   capture   the   diversity   in   the   topography   and 

population distribution.4  It also possessed a relative advantage over other districts in West 

Bengal, since it is purely agricultural and not close to the state capital or an international  

border.5

Two sample areas in Bankura district were selected, the most advanced and the most 

backward block respectively; various developmental indicators were used in order to identify 

these blocks.6 The eight sample villages, consisting of four from each block, were chosen on 

the basis of the size and ethnic distribution of population, the extent of land reform, and other 

development indicators. The 210 sample households (of which 100 households belong to the 

backward region)  were classified  on  the basis  of   land owned/controlled  and of Patnaik’s 

[1976]   E­criterion   (see   Appendix   1   below).   The   latter   is   particularly   relevant   to   an 

understanding of changes occurring in West Bengal agriculture, where there is a tremendous 

concentration of households below 2.5 acres. If we consider NSSO classification7 we find an 

increase in the concentration of households from 138 to 153 out of 210 total households (66% 

and 73% of total respectively) during 1993­94 to 2004­05 in the ‘marginal holding’ or 0.01 ­ 

2.5 acres. However, as we will see later the households belong to this category are internally 

10

Page 11: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

differentiated among different economic classes. Patnaik’s E­criteria would like to explore 

this dynamics.   

HOUSEHOLD AND CLASS

The distribution of sample households in each region, as well the combined figure for both, is 

presented in Table 2. As expected, while a close link exists between farm size and labour use, 

this is not absolute. The number of landless households is relatively small: only five percent 

of the sample was wholly landless in 1993­94, neither owning nor operating any holdings, 

which   appears   to   reflect   the   low   incidence   of   immizeration   in   the   villages   concerned. 

However   in  2004­05,   the   total  number  of   landless  households   increased   from 10   to  13. 

However, regional distribution of the data reveals that the in the backward region the number 

of  landless households rather declined from 5 to 2. But  in  the advanced region the same 

doubled, from 5 to 11during the same decade. We have to note that the advanced region is 

more exposed to capitalist agriculture, and therefore, by neo­liberal reform. The swelling of 

the number of the landless households are owing to the many factors.  The erstwhile five 

landless households in 1993­94remained landless in 2004­05 as well and six households have 

added as new. Among the six new landless households, three households sold their land in 

distress and shifted to low paid non­farm activities, but they earn a major income from selling 

their   labour  as  agricultural   labour,  particularly   in   the  busy  agricultural   season.  The  non­

agricultural works are not at all remunerative (Ghosh 2006). In fact the wage rate for such 

non­agricultural work is less than the agricultural work in busy season. Such a conversion 

from agriculture to non­agriculture is  primarily  due to non­availability  of agricultural   job 

apart   from busy   season.  The   increase   in  non­agricultural   job   is   therefore  nothing  but   a 

11

Page 12: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

situation   of   disguised   proletarianization   (Murray   2006,   Kay   2008).   Two   households 

mortgaged their land and become landless at least temporarily. One household lost its land in 

family   feud.   In  general   it  might  be presumed that   in   the  post   liberalization  period   these 

households lost their land due to deterioration in the living condition and non­availability of 

the formal credit, for which they are compelled to mortgage or sell their land, which in effect 

reflects the process of the intense differentiation of the peasantry. 

Table­2: Cross Classification of the Number of Households and Average and  Total Area (Acre) by Economic Class and Acreage Groups

LLS PP SP MP RP LLDPd1 Pd2 Pd1  Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1  Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1

All Rgn0.00 10 13 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 00.01­2.5 0 0

71[0.74](51.77)

69[0.65](44.54)

27[1.33](35.81)

27[1.26](34.08)

13[1.69](22)

14[1.46](20.45)

12[1.37](16.44)

16[1.32](21.13)

15[1.45](21.78)

2.5­50 0 1[2.64]

(2.64)1[3.83](3.83)

11[3.96](43.51)

5[3.43](17.18)

6[3.14](18.84)

3[2.89](8.67)

10[3.73](37.26)

12[4.02](48.28)

8[3.38](27.06)

5­10 0 0 1[4.32](4.32)

0 4[7.30] (29.21)

2[7.33](14.66)

5[7.99](39.93)

2[6.67](13.33)

2[7.02](14.03)

5[7.06](35.34)

9[7.11](64.02)

10­150 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

1[13.86](13.86)

02[12.38](24.75)

15&Ab0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

2[29.87](59.73)

0 0

Total 10 13 73[0.80 70[0.69 42[2.58 34[1.94 24[3.37 19[2.23 27[5.23 33[3.17 34[4.05

12

Page 13: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

](58.73)

](48.37)

](108.53)

](65.92)

](80.77)

](42.45)

](141.32)

](104.75)

](137.61)

AdvRegion0.00 5 11 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 00.01­2.5 0 0

44[0.44](19.18)

35[0.29](10.21)

12[0.99](11.84)

8[0.74](5.92)

4[0.89](3.56)

5[1.16](5.78)

10[1.40](13.96)

10[1.12](11.17)

12[1.57](18.81)

2.5­5 0 0 0 0 1[3.96](3.96)

2[3.59](7.17)

1[1.84](1.84)

3[2.89](8.67)

5[3.82](19.10)

4[3.74](14.95)

6[3.03](18.15)

5­10 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 2[7.02](14.03)

4[6.92](27.67)

6[6.93](41.58)

10­150 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

1[13.86](13.86)

01[10.89](10.89)

15&Ab 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0Total

5 1144[0.44](19.18)

35[0.29](10.21)

13[1.22](15.18)

10[1.31](13.09)

5[1.08](5.40)

8[1.81](14.45)

18[3.39](60.96)

18[2.99](53.79)

25[3.58](89.43)

Backward Rgn0.00 5 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 00.01­2.5 0 0

27[1.25](32.59)

34[1.01](34.33)

15[1.60](23.97)

19[1.48](28.16)

9[0.05](18.44)

9[1.63](14.67)

2[1.24](2.47)

6[1.66](9.96)

3[0.99](2.97)

2.5­50 0

1[2.64](2.64)

1[3.83](3.83)

10[3.96](39.55)

3[3.34](10.01)

5[3.40](17.00) 0

5[3.63](18.16)

8[4.17](33.33)

2[4.46](8.91)

5­10 0 0 1[4.32](4.35) 0 4[7.30]

(29.21)2[7.33](14.66)

5[7.99](39.93)

2[6.67](13.33) 0 1[7.67]

(7.67)3[7.48](22.44)

10­150 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

1[13.86](13.86)

15&Abv 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

2[29.87](59.73)

0 0

Total5 2

29[1.36](39.55)

35[1.09](38.16)

29[3.19](92.73)

24[2.20](32.83)

19[3.02](75.37)

11[2.55](28)

9[8.92](80.36)

15[3.98](50.96)

9[5.35](44.18)

Secondly,  Around 73% of   total  households   in  both  advanced  and backward   (and 

therefore in  the combined) region belong to the size group0.01­2.5 acre.  In  the advanced 

region   the  households   in   this   size  group  marginally  declined   from 82   to  80.  Given   the 

13

Page 14: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

increased landlessness in this region a process of depeasantization is very clear in this region. 

However, in the backward region the households belong to this group actually increased from 

56  to 73 and as  a   result   in   the  combined  region  the households   in   the  same size  group 

increased from 138 to 153. The backward region was dominated previously by landlord class 

who occupied a very large size landed property. However, over the decade households belong 

to the landlord class had lost its character and adopted the same pattern of labour process, i.e.  

they cultivate purely on the basis of hired in labour. At the same time their land size declined 

drastically primarily because of govt measure of land reform and natural inheritance rule. 

There are also changing composition of the households belonging to this size group. 

First of all, the proportion of small peasant belonging to this size group declined both in the 

advanced and the backward region. The proportion of the middle peasant either increased 

marginally (from 4 to 5) in the advanced region, or remained stagnant (at 9) in the backward 

region.  The self­employed classes as a  whole witnessed almost a stagnation for  this  size 

group. On the other hand poor peasant within this size group increased from 27 to 34 in the 

backward region and declined from 44 to 35 in the advanced region. The exploiting classes 

(particularly   landlords)   actually   swelled   from 27   to  43.  The   increasing   concentration  of 

landlord households in this size group reveals the fact that the erstwhile owners of big sizes 

of land is losing their land either following the inheritance rule or the legal implementation of 

the land reform, but they maintain the same labour process by alienating themselves from all 

kinds of direct production on tiny plots of land. In other words, they remain the exploiting 

classes – though their ownership of land holding declined. 

In 2004­05 the farms below 2.5 acres in the advanced as well as in the backward 

region is around 73%. However, the households belonging to the exploited classes still higher 

14

Page 15: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

in   the   advanced   region   (41.82%)   as   compared   to   the   backward   one   (36%).   The   most 

significant  aspect   is   that   the   rich peasant  and  the  landlords’  dependence on hired   labour 

increased from 18% to 28% in the backward region during 1993­94 to 2004­05. At the same 

time the proportion of the self employed classes remained unaltered in the advanced region, 

but the same declined from 48% to 35% during the same period. Therefore, the backward 

region is now on the path of transition towards agrarian capitalism.    

On the other hand the numbers of households belong to the higher size categories 

above 2.5 acres declined over the decade 1993­94 and 2004­05. There are a decline for all 

size groups in the combined region and almost in both the regions separately. However with 

regard to the large farms above 10 acres there is a varying picture in the two regions. In 1993­

94 in the backward region a mere 3 households operate 24.5 percent or almost a quarter of the 

total area though constituting only 3 percent of the farms. In the advanced region the 2 farms 

operating  above  10 acres  have  only  10.6  percent  of   the  area.  Over   the  decade   the   land 

concentration reduced significantly, so that we find in 2004­05 only one farm prevails in the 

backward region whose land is above 10 acres (14.99 acres). In the advanced region no farm 

is left with the operated area above 10 acres.  

It is clear, moreover, that the above considerations have had a differential impact in terms of 

the two regions studied. In the more advanced region, therefore, both landholding and class 

structure are more polarized: three quarters of all holdings are less than 2.5 acres in size, and 

44 percent of cultivators are landless, compared with the respective figures of 56 percent of 

holdings and 34 per cent of cultivators in the backward region. The same holds true of the 

relative importance of rich peasants and landlords: the latter account for 39 per cent of all 

15

Page 16: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

land in the advanced region, compared with only 18 per cent in the backward one. Petty 

commodity producers, or middle peasants, are less common in the advanced region than in 

the backward one: in the latter context they account for nearly half of all farms, while in the 

former they constitute only 16 per cent.

One seeming anomaly requires explanation. It concerns the jump from 13 to 30 acres in farm 

size between the highest and second­highest category, which is due to the presence in the 

backward  area  of   two  relatively   large   landholding  groups.  Having  been  members  of   the 

landlord class, the owners of these holdings lost their power when the Left Front assumed 

government, declared a large portion of their land surplus and redistributed it among landless 

households.  Under  the active supervision of  the  Krishak Sabha  and the  Panchayat,   these 

landless   households   then   formed   a   collective   farm   known   as   ‘Bangopalpur  Chatanibad 

Jouthakhamar’.8 For their part, the two households from which the land had been confiscated 

were able to retain a considerable amount of their property by means of  benami  transfers. 

Since  they were households  with  large  families,   the per  capita   land distribution shows a 

decline when the remaining property is adjusted to take account of family size.

16

Page 17: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

TABLE 3: CROSS CLASSIFICATION OF THE NET LABOUR DAYS HI/HO PER HOLDING                   BY ECONOMIC CLASSES AND ACREAGE GROUPS (ACRES)

      Landless    Poor Peasant   Small Peasant Middle Peasant    Rich Peasant         Landlord           Total Acres 1993­04 2004­05 1993­04 2004­05 1993­04 2004­05 1993­04 2004­05 1993­04 2004­05 1993­04 2004­05 1993­04 2004­05

All Region0.00 ­111.63 ­83.69 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 ­111.63 ­83.69

0.01 to 2.5 0.00 0.00 ­240.07 ­157.22 ­17.91 ­25.96 28.80 35.64 159.66 81.75 265.96 127.93 ­81.51 ­41.102.5 to 5 0.00 0.00 0.00 ­180.00 ­7.20 ­35.60 62.02 90.00 327.96 220.58 512.84 366.13 213.20 189.245 to 10 0.00 0.00 ­187.75 0.00 ­41.70 ­7.50 147.64 96.50 662.19 487.20 1198.19 611.40 594.85 405.07

10 to 15 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1200.00 0.00 1495.51 880.00 1397.00 880.0015 & abv. 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1150.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1150.00 0.00

Total ­111.63 ­83.69 ­236.06 ­157.54 ­17.37 ­26.29 61.87 50.63 371.11 193.67 643.14 251.71 68.06 22.20Advanced Region

0.00 ­103.00 ­79.91 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 ­103.00 ­79.910.01 to 2.5 0.00 0.00 ­317.26 ­189.89 ­28.50 ­22.88 42.00 41.20 184.28 96.00 320.89 140.86 ­102.93 ­32.05

2.5 to 5 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 10.00 46.00 135.00 90.00 435.50 310.50 583.17 461.00 447.81 279.215 to 10 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 662.19 551.50 1556.67 1651.00 1333.05 771.40

10 to 15 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1200.00 0.00 1165.38 0.00 1182.69 0.0015 & abv. 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Total ­103.00 ­79.91 ­317.26 ­189.89 ­25.54 ­9.10 60.60 59.50 363.59 244.89 714.20 251.96 89.96 39.30Backward Region

0.00 ­120.25 ­104.50 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 ­120.25 ­104.500.01 to 2.5 0.00 0.00 ­114.26 ­123.59 ­9.45 ­27.26 22.94 32.56 36.57 58.00 46.25 71.00 ­50.15 ­51.01

2.5 to 5 0.00 0.00 0.00 ­180.00 ­8.92 ­90.00 47.43 0.00 220.43 175.63 301.88 208.00 80.60 105.275 to 10 0.00 0.00 ­187.75 0.00 ­41.70 ­7.50 147.64 96.50 0.00 230.00 481.25 351.50 140.57 201.56

10 to 15 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1825.63 880.00 1825.63 880.0015 & abv. 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1150.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1150.00 0.00

Total ­120.25 ­104.50 ­112.86 ­125.20 ­13.71 ­33.46 62.20 44.18 386.14 132.20 445.76 251.15 43.97 3.40

Table  3 on the net labour days hired in or out per holding reveal the variation in the 

economic status of households within each acreage group. It is quite clear from the table that 

the   class   categories   isolate   successfully   holdings   of   different   types   with   respect   to   the 

variables of labour hiring, and therefore show consistently and significantly different mean 

values for holdings in the different economic classes, regardless of the acreage group into 

which they fall. As one would expect, the highest proportion of labour­purchasing holdings 

by acreage group is found in farms above 2.5 acres. Thus in 1993­94 rich peasants purchase 

from 160 to 1150 days of labour annually per holding over the acreage groups across both 

regions, while for the middle peasant class it ranges from 29 to 148 days over the acreage 

groups. By contrast, small­peasants sell between 7 and 48 days per annum, while in the case 

17

Page 18: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

of poor peasants the figure varies from 188 to 240 days per year. The figures of 2004­05 also 

support this trend, however the magnitude of variation had been narrowing. 

HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE AND WORKFORCE 

Chayanov [1966] argued that the ratio of consumers to workers in the farming household is a 

crucial variable, because it is this which determines the amount of labour effort that family 

workers will  put  into production.  Accordingly,   the higher   the  consumer/worker   ratio,   the 

higher will be the number of days of work performed by family workers. Our findings, which 

employ a household­members­to­worker ratio that is the same as Chayanov’s concept of a 

consumer/worker ratio, indicate a broad relation between the latter, farm size and economic 

class. However, the relationship that Chayanov identified ­ namely, rising consumer/worker 

ratios accompanied by a higher family labour input ­ was not found. We have not found 

Chayanov proposed inverse relationship between farm size and economic well being.  

The  distribution  of   the  numbers  of   the  household  members,  and household  workers,  are 

depicted in Tables 4 by size and class groups. As in the Farm Management Studies, a clear 

direct relationship (as opposed to Chayanovian inverse one) connects farm size and family 

size, and ­ more broadly ­ the latter and economic status. The work participation rate (WPR) 

is substantially higher in the backward region when compared to the advanced region, a not 

unexpected   finding since   rural   families   in   the   former  context  are   likely   to  have a   lower 

income  per  worker,   and  more   family  members  must  work   to  obtain  a  minimum  family 

income. 

18

Page 19: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

TABLE 4: Family Members and Workers by Economic Class and Acreage GroupEcClasses Member per worker Worker per Holding Member perHolding  Participation RateAll Region 1993­94 2004­05 1993­94 2004­05 1993­94 2004­05 1993­94 2004­05Landless 2.28 2.04 1.8 2.15 4.1 4.38 43.9 49.12Poor Peasant 1.96 1.95 3.01 2.97 5.92 5.79 50.93 51.36Small Peasant 1.81 2.04 3.4 3.26 6.17 6.65 55.21 49.12Middle Peasant 2.36 2.23 3 3.16 7.08 7.05 42.35 44.78Rich Peasant 3.88 2.51 2.15 2.85 8.33 7.15 25.78 39.83Landlord 4.37 2.63 1.53 2.66 6.68 7.00 22.91 37.98 Total 2.4 2.20 2.68 2.90 6.45 6.40 41.58 45.35Advanced RegionLandless 2 2.27 1.4 2.00 2.8 4.55 50 44.00Poor Peasant 2.41 2.31 2.3 2.43 5.52 5.60 41.56 43.37Small Peasant 2.45 2.37 2.92 3.00 7.15 7.10 40.86 42.25Middle Peasant 3.38 3.00 1.6 2.25 5.4 6.75 29.63 33.33Rich Peasant 4 2.89 1.94 2.56 7.78 7.39 25 34.59Landlord 4.33 2.60 1.6 2.57 6.92 6.68 23.12 38.50 Total 3.01 2.53 2.08 2.48 6.27 6.28 33.19 39.51Backward RegionLandless 2.45 1.17 2.2 3.00 5.4 3.50 40.74 85.71Poor Peasant 1.59 1.70 4.1 3.51 6.52 5.97 62.96 58.85Small Peasant 1.58 1.91 3.62 3.38 5.72 6.46 63.25 52.26Middle Peasant 2.23 1.90 3.37 3.82 7.53 7.27 44.76 52.50Rich Peasant 3.7 2.15 2.56 3.20 9.44 6.87 27.06 46.60Landlord 4.5 2.70 1.33 2.85 6 7.69 22.22 37.00 Total 1.99 1.94 3.34 3.37 6.64 6.54 50.3 51.53Acreage Gp  All Region      '0.00 2.28 2.04 1.8 2.15 4.1 4.38 43.9 49.12 0.01 to 2.5 2.23 2.16 2.51 2.73 5.6 5.90 44.76 46.23 2.5 to 5 2.23 2.31 3.08 3.41 6.89 7.90 44.76 43.23 5 to 10 2.97 2.29 3.43 4.21 10.19 9.64 33.64 43.70 10 to 15 7.4 3.14 1.67 7.00 12.33 22.00 13.51 31.82 15 & Abv 3.73 0.00 5.5 0.00 20.5 0.00 26.83 0.00Total 2.4 2.20 2.68 2.90 6.45 6.40 41.58 45.35Advanced Region      '0.00 2 2.27 1.4 2.00 2.8 4.55 50 44.00 0.01 to 2.5 2.78 2.48 2.05 2.40 5.7 5.96 35.97 40.25 2.5 to 5 3.13 2.97 2.38 2.43 7.46 7.21 31.96 33.66 5 to 10 4.74 2.52 2.38 5.00 11.25 12.60 21.11 39.68 10 to 15 5.5 0.00 2 0.00 11 0.00 18.18 0.00 15 & Abv 0 0.00 0 0.00 0 0.00 0 0.00Total 3.01 2.53 2.08 2.48 6.27 6.28 33.19 39.51Backward Region      '0.00 2.45 1.17 2.2 3.00 5.4 3.50 40.74 85.71 0.01 to 2.5 1.72 1.89 3.18 3.08 5.46 5.82 58.17 52.94 2.5 to 5 1.89 1.97 3.48 4.33 6.57 8.53 52.98 50.78 5 to 10 2.34 2.12 4.08 3.78 9.54 8.00 42.74 47.22 10 to 15 15 3.14 1 7.00 15 22.00 6.67 31.82 15 & Abv 3.73 0.00 5.5 0.00 20.5 0.00 26.83 0.00Total 1.99 1.94 3.34 3.37 6.64 6.54 50.3 51.53Note: Participation rate is calculated as the workers to members ratio, multiplied by 100.

This is confirmed when the members to workers ratio is linked to economic class and 

land size. As the economic position of the household improves, therefore, it becomes possible 

even for adult members of working age to withdraw from work, a factor reflected in lower 

participation  rates.  By farm size,   too,  a  higher   than  average participation  rate  occurs   for 

holdings below 5 acres, and a lower than average rate on holdings above 5 acres. The only 

deviation from this pattern is the case of landless households in the backward region in 1993­

19

Page 20: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

94, which have a below average work­participation ratio,though in 2004­05 it was more than 

doubled; magnitude for which was far above the average.   

Table 5 has summarised the family labour, hired in labour and hired out labour. It is observed 

that landlords hire in all the labour they use per farm, not working a single day in the fields.  

The rich peasant on the other hand rely on hiring in for 77% (1993­94) / 68% (2004­05) of 

their labour input with the remaining share contributed by family labour. The middle peasants 

hire   in   30.25%   (1993­94)   /   38.60%   (2004­05)   and   the   small   peasant   hire   in   a   meagre 

proportion 5% ­ 6% in both years. Poor peasants hire out 84% to 82% of total labour days 

and only 16% to 18% of total labour days they work on their own farm. These households are 

better thought as agricultural labourer with some land. We have seen in Table 2 that these 

households belong largely to the lowest landed size group (0.01­2.5 acres). In Chayanov­Sen 

formulation,  however, these farms are projected as ‘family labour farm’ as if these farms 

survive on ‘self­exploitation’ and devoid from any kind of off farm activities. The acreage 

grouping also shows a broad direct association between the size of farms and percentage of 

total labour hired in and a broad inverse relation between size of farm and the proportion of 

family labour days hired out on wage. 

The impact of liberalization is very clear. Agricultural investment massively declined during 

period of neo­liberal reform. As a result labour absorption in agriculture declined far more 

following the logic of Keynesian investment multiplier. In our survey all the variables related 

to labour absorption largely declined during 1993­94 and 2004­05. These variables include 

family labour days per holding, hired in labour days per holding and hired out labour  days 

per holding. 

20

Page 21: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

Table  5: Distribution of Labour DaysFL per Holding HI per Holding FL+HIper Holding % of HI to Total HO  per  Holding FL+HO  per Holding %of HO to Total

Class/Group Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2ALL REGIO NLandless 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 208.33 83.69 208.33 83.69 100.00 100.00Poor Peasant 57.68 35.67 2.82 1.81 60.50 37.49 4.66 4.84 296.35 159.36 354.04 195.03 83.71 81.71Small Peasant 204.71 112.12 11.39 7.32 216.10 119.44 5.27 6.13 56.97 33.62 261.68 145.74 21.77 23.07Middle  Peasant 147.50 98.37 63.96 61.84 211.46 160.21 30.25 38.60 2.10 11.21 149.60 109.58 1.40 10.23Rich Peasant 110.81 91.30 371.11 194.67 481.92 285.97 77.01 68.07 0.00 1.00 110.81 92.30 0.00 1.08Landlord 0.00 0.49 643.16 254.29 643.16 254.78 100.00 99.81 0.00 2.56 0.00 3.05 0.00 84.00   Total 92.10 53.39 162.41 87.62 254.51 141.01 63.81 62.14 124.57 65.41 216.67 118.80 57.49 55.06ADVANCED REGIO NLandless 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 127.00 79.91 127.00 79.91 100.00 100.00Poor Peasant 44.24 19.14 4.59 2.34 48.84 21.48 9.40 10.89 295.72 192.23 339.96 211.37 86.99 90.94Small Peasant 280.21 102.20 8.77 12.10 288.98 114.30 3.03 10.59 30.08 21.20 310.29 123.40 9.69 17.18Middle  Peasant 113.00 110.50 60.60 62.00 173.60 172.50 34.91 35.94 0.00 2.50 113.00 113.00 0.00 2.21Rich Peasant 73.56 125.38 363.59 244.88 437.15 370.26 83.17 66.14 0.00 0.00 73.56 125.38 0.00 0.00Landlord 0.00 0.72 714.22 255.75 714.22 256.47 100.00 99.72 0.00 3.75 0.00 4.47 0.00 83.89   Total 67.99 44.12 227.45 115.53 295.43 159.65 76.99 72.36 127.61 72.21 195.60 116.33 65.24 62.07BACKWARD REGIO NLandless 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 289.65 104.50 289.65 104.50 100.00 100.00Poor Peasant 78.07 52.20 0.13 1.28 78.20 53.48 0.17 2.39 297.32 126.48 375.39 178.68 79.20 70.79Small Peasant 170.86 116.25 12.56 5.33 183.42 121.58 6.85 4.38 69.03 38.93 239.89 155.04 28.78 25.02Middle  Peasant 156.58 89.54 64.85 61.72 221.42 151.26 29.29 40.80 2.65 17.54 159.23 107.08 1.66 16.38Rich Peasant 185.33 50.40 386.14 134.40 571.47 184.80 67.57 72.73 0.00 2.20 185.33 52.60 0.00 4.18Landlord 0.00 0.00 445.76 251.15 445.76 251.15 100.00 100.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00   Total 118.62 63.58 90.87 61.33 209.49 124.91 43.38 49.10 121.23 57.23 239.85 120.81 50.54 47.37ALL REGIO N   0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 208.33 83.69 208.33 83.69 100.00 100.00 0.01 ­ 2.5 66.91 38.74 48.33 37.54 115.25 76.27 41.94 49.21 161.02 78.63 227.93 117.37 70.64 67.00 2.5 ­ 5 140.01 97.93 223.52 206.10 363.53 304.03 61.49 67.79 32.16 16.83 172.18 114.76 18.68 14.66 5 ­ 10 173.14 174.57 614.21 414.36 787.36 588.93 78.01 70.36 33.27 9.29 206.42 183.86 16.12 5.05 10 ­ 15 43.33 0.00 1397.00 880.00 1440.33 880.00 96.99 100.00 0.00 0.00 43.33 0.00 0.00 0.00 15 & Abv 650.00 0.00 1150.00 0.00 1800.00 0.00 63.89 0.00 0.00 0.00 650.00 0.00 0.00 0.00    Total 92.10 53.39 162.41 87.62 254.51 141.01 63.81 62.14 124.57 65.41 216.67 118.80 57.49 55.06Advanced Region   0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 127.00 79.90 127.00 127.00 100.00 100.00 0.01 ­ 2.5 60.93 24.08 75.21 56.20 136.14 192.34 55.25 70.00 163.45 88.25 224.37 279.62 72.85 78.56 2.5 ­ 5 142.50 120.71 447.85 279.64 590.35 869.99 75.86 69.85 0.00 0.36 142.50 218.36 0.00 0.30 5 ­ 10 62.50 247.20 1333.05 771.40 1395.55 2166.95 95.52 75.73 0.00 0.00 62.50 158.02 0.00 0.00 10 ­ 15 65.00 0.00 1182.69 0.00 1247.69 1247.69 94.79 0.00 0.00 0.00 65.00 159.79 0.00 0.00 15 & Abv 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00    Total 67.99 44.12 227.45 115.53 295.43 410.96 76.99 72.36 127.61 72.21 195.60 272.59 65.24 62.07Backward Region   0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 289.65 104.50 289.65 289.65 100.00 100.00 0.01 ­ 2.5 75.68 54.79 8.98 17.08 84.66 101.74 10.60 23.77 157.46 68.09 233.14 243.74 67.54 55.41 2.5 ­ 5 138.61 16.66 96.73 137.46 235.34 372.80 41.10 89.19 50.35 32.20 188.95 230.06 26.64 65.90 5 ­ 10 241.23 76.66 171.86 216.00 413.09 629.09 41.60 73.81 53.75 14.44 294.98 336.58 18.22 15.85 10 ­ 15 0.00 134.22 1825.63 880.00 1825.63 2705.63 100.00 86.77 0.00 0.00 0.00 100.00 0.00 0.00 15 & Abv 650.00 0.00 1150.00 0.00 1800.00 1800.00 63.89 0.00 0.00 0.00 650.00 713.89 0.00 0.00    Total 118.62 63.58 90.87 61.33 209.49 270.82 43.38 49.10 121.23 57.23 239.85 283.22 50.54 47.37

Note: Pd1 = Period 1, i .e . 1993­94; Pd2 = Period 2, i.e . 2004­05. FL = Family Labour, HI = Hired In, HO  = Hired O ut.

21

Page 22: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

LAND AND OTHER MEANS OF PRODUCTION 

Data on land tenure ­ owned/operated, as well as that leased in and leased out ­ by economic 

class and farm size are presented in Table 6. Nearly three quarters of all rural households in 

the two regions compared own/operate holdings under 2.5 acres, which account for only 28 

per cent of total land; by contrast, only two percent of households own/operate land of ten 

acres and above, holdings which account for some 17 percent of total land. This element of 

inequality is more pronounced in the advanced region, where labour­purchasing households 

comprise 39 per cent of households owning/controlling 82 per cent of the total area.

                      Table 6: Distribution of ownership, operated and irrigated land by Ec. Class & size group   Per holding Per holding  % of Leased  % of Leased  Per holding % of irrigated

Economic Class   owned area operatedin to operated

out to  area  to total ope

& Acreage Group (acre)   area (acre)  area    owned area irrigated  rated area

  93­9404­05

93­94

04­05

93­94

04­05

93­94

04­05

93­94

04­05 93­94

04­05

Economic Class  All Region              Landless 0.02  0.03 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00Poor Peasant 0.93  0.68 0.73  0.63 9.19  8.60 0.00  0.00 0.34 0.12 42.18 17.68Small Peasant 2.75  2.20 2.47  1.78 8.81  8.21 4.00  0.00 0.80 0.34 31.05 17.84Middle Peasant 4.34  2.36 3.22  2.09 4.21  6.27 0.00  0.00 1.53 0.74 45.54 33.05Rich Peasant 5.20  3.32 4.79  3.14 8.92  1.43 0.01  0.95 3.51 1.36 67.15 43.00

Landlord 5.09  3.57 4.72  3.30 2.67  1.8515.25 

21.96 2.38 0.95 58.91 34.17

TOTAL 2.86  2.01 2.50  1.83 6.57  4.23 5.27  6.89 1.29 0.56 51.47 31.53Advanced Region              Landless 0.02  0.03 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.27 0.00 0.00 0.00

Poor Peasant 0.42  0.25 0.36  0.23 1.61 22.8

2 0.00  0.00 1.09 0.19 60.82 64.25

Small Peasant 1.23  1.21 1.16  1.1031.77 

15.90

28.95  0.00 0.66 0.83 89.43 63.69

Middle Peasant 0.77  1.81 0.72  1.5133.70 

16.12 0.00  0.00 1.66 1.40 61.31 77.51

Rich Peasant 2.94  3.04 2.85  2.9217.91  2.79 1.25  0.61 2.60 2.34 48.95 78.16

Landlord 4.63  3.00 4.49  0.37 4.11  3.3022.81 

45.14   1.06 72.76 54.71

TOTAL 1.88  1.57 1.81  1.4512.53  6.90

15.31 

16.86 1.13 0.88 65.01 67.17

Backward Region              Landless 0.02  0.01 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.45 0.00 0.00 0.00Poor Peasant 1.71  1.09 1.28  1.04 5.84  4.80 0.00  0.00 0.67 0.06 33.15 5.21Small Peasant 3.43  2.60 3.04  2.06 4.90  6.30 0.00  0.00 1.76 0.14 21.10 6.38Middle Peasant 5.27  2.75 3.88  2.51 2.10  1.18 0.00  0.00 7.23 0.26 44.40 10.11Rich Peasant 9.72  3.66 8.67  3.40 2.87  0.00 0.00  1.31 1.78 0.20 80.96 5.89Landlord 6.38  4.74 5.35  4.60 0.00  0.56 0.00  1.13   0.72 33.22 15.71TOTAL 3.94  2.48 3.25  2.25 3.19  2.54 0.00  0.58 1.47 0.20 43.79 8.95Acreage Group  All Region              

22

Page 23: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

   0.00 0.02  0.03 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 ­ 2.5 2.21  1.13 1.01  0.96 9.05  4.01 2.76  0.00 0.57 0.33 53.29 33.11

 2.5 – 5 4.31  4.46 3.80  4.3112.11  6.00

14.89 

24.45 1.43 1.23 39.87 34.15

 5 – 10 8.35  7.37 7.21  6.93 2.18  3.32 1.88  0.00 3.10 2.10 42.91 29.39

 10 ­ 15  14.55 15.0

212.98 

14.99 0.01  0.00 1.51  0.00 5.39 1.66 41.88 11.07

 15 & Abv 29.79  0.0028.88  0.00 3.31  0.00 0.00  0.00

29.87 0.00

100.00 0.00

TOTAL 2.86  2.01 2.50  1.83 6.57  4.23 5.27  6.89 1.29 0.56 51.47 31.53Advanced Region                 0.00 0.02  0.03 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

 0.01 ­ 2.5 0.82  0.81 0.76  0.6914.58  7.54 6.89  0.00 0.58 0.54 70.38 72.08

 2.5 – 5 4.36  4.90 4.28  4.7524.27 

11.56

40.74 

51.33 1.98 2.31 59.91 68.65

 5 – 10 7.14  7.85 6.95  7.53 5.93  0.00 5.78  0.00 4.58 4.33 65.87 57.53

 10 ­ 15  12.96  0.0012.54  0.00 1.33  0.00 2.55  0.00 7.10 0.00 57.33 0.00

 15 & Abv 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

TOTAL 1.88  1.57 1.81  1.4512.53  6.90

15.31 

16.86 1.13 0.88 65.01 67.17

Backward Region                 0.00 0.02  0.01 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 ­ 2.5 1.79  1.49 1.37  1.26 4.41  1.77 0.00  0.00 0.56 0.11 38.99 8.34 2.5 – 5 4.28  4.06 3.52  3.89 6.04  1.44 0.00  2.32 1.12 0.22 29.86 5.76 5 – 10 9.10  7.09 7.38  6.59 0.00  5.31 0.00  0.00 2.18 0.85 29.59 12.34

 10 ­ 15  17.75 15.0

213.86 

14.99 0.00  0.00 0.00  0.00 1.98 1.66 14.29 11.07

 15 & Abv 28.79  0.0028.88  0.00 3.31  0.00 0.00  0.00

29.87 0.00

100.00 0.00

TOTAL 3.94  2.48 3.25  2.25 3.19  2.54 0.00  0.58 1.47 0.20 43.79 8.95

There was a decline in per holding owned (from 2.86 acres to 2.01 acres) and operated area 

(from 2.5 acres to 1.83 acres) over decade of neo­liberal reform. The decline was sharp in the 

backward region and also prominent in the advanced region. There was a decline of land 

holding in all classes but the same was sharp for the higher classes as revealed by the lower 

value of Gini Coefficient for ownership and operated area.   

Taking both regions together, the extent of leasing in and leasing out is small: only seven to 

four per cent of operated area is leased in and five to seven per cent of owned area is leased 

out. The single digit low percentage figure for leasing in / out have suggested that share­

tenancy is on the decline following the impementation of  Operation Barga  in West Bengal 

(Dasgupta 1984).9 In the advanced region, however, there was decline in operated area leased 

23

Page 24: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

in from 13% to 7% though there was a marginal increase in owned area is leased out  from 

15% to 17%. The latter was primarily based on seasonal leave for boro cultivation and not 

true sense of the classical tenancy. The backward regionhas low incidence of tenancy than the 

advanced region even where the percentage of leased in land declined from 3.19% to 2.54%. 

The   class­specific   patterns  of   leasing­in   and   leasing­out   reveal   that   the   rural   poor   enter 

sharecropping   arrangements   to   augment   the   meagre   income   from   their   own   holdings. 

Although rich peasants lease in some amount of land, they do so for different reasons: the 

lure of higher profits from extending cultivation. It remains the case, however, that in the 

wake   of  Operation   Barga,   no   new   tenancy   contracts   have   been   signed   and   after   the 

liberalization the incidence of tenancy declined. 

Turning   to  a   consideration  of   productive  assets   other   than   land,   these  consist  of 

machinery, irrigation, livestock, storage and transportation. As a much earlier study by Sen 

and Sengupta [1969] of three villages in Burdwan district carried out over a five year period 

(1957/58 to 61/62) showed, access to irrigation has for a long time been an important factor 

in the productive capacity of holdings in the five acre category. Significantly, that same study 

confirmed that, even at this earlier conjuncture, all farmers of 4­6 acre holdings employed 

hired labour for cultivation. In our study we have seen that both in the advanced and in the 

backward region the irrigated area per holding and percentage of irrigated total area declined 

during the decade of liberalization. 

The data presented in Tables 7 indicate that, across both regions, about two thirds 

(1993­94) and over 60% (2004­05) of  total  non­land assets and owned/controlled by rich 

peasants and landlords. Categorized in terms of farm size, however, no consistent pattern of 

24

Page 25: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

non­land assets emerges. Thus ownership/control of machinery and irrigation is concentrated 

in farms belonging to the 5­10 acre category, which account for 35% (1993­94) and 46% 

(2004­05) of these particular means of production; by contrast, holdings below five acres and 

above ten account for a much smaller amount of such productive assets. Much the same is 

true  of   livestock,  ownership of  which  is  concentrated  both among  the   landless,  marginal 

(0.01­2.5 acres) and also among holdings in excess of fifteen acres. The reason why farm size 

cannot explain the way means of production are distributed is that the majority among the 

total holdings in the 5­10 acre category, of which two (1993­94) and five (2004­05) holdings 

belong to rich peasants and nine (1993­94) and five (2004­05) to landlords, are cultivated 

intensively   (see  Table  2).  No other   farm size  group  contains   such  a  high  proportion  of 

capitalist farms purchasing labour­power.

25

Page 26: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

Table 7: Distribution of Majoar Assets by Economic Classes and Acreage Groups                    Mechanical & Irrigational                        Storage & Transport                                Livestock                   TotalPer Acre (Rs) P.Holding[Rs]\         Percentage  PerAcre(Rs) P.Holding[Rs]          Percentage  Per Acre (Rs) P.Holding[Rs]\         Percentage  Per Acre (Rs)  P. Holding [Rs]          Percentage 

Class/Group Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2ALL REGIO NLandless 0 0 183 60 (0) [0] (0) [4] 0 0 250 692 (0) [16] (2) [45] 0 0 1354 788 (1) [75] (0) [51] 0 0 1787 1540 (0) [100] (1) [100]Poor Peasant 680 472 510 326 (0) [1] (3) [5] 1737 1238 1304 855 (4) [17] (11) [14] 12463 7176 9356 4958 (20) [75] (16) [81] 14879 8886 11170 6139 (9) [100] (12) [100]Small Peasant 2119 410 5354 795 (13) [20] (3) [5] 899 968 2270 1876 (5) [16] (12) [11] 6140 7383 15512 14313 (24) [61] (23) [84] 9158 8762 23136 16985 (14) [100] (16) [100]Middle  Peasant 545 395 1788 881 (5) [8] (2) [5] 789 1546 2589 3453 (3) [12] (12) [18] 7044 6526 23096 14576 (23) [76] (13) [77] 8379 8466 27473 18910 (11) [100] (10) [100]Rich Peasant 2163 6818 11283 21641 (13) [22] (81) [52] 1034 1742 5393 5530 (6) [24] (34) [13] 3996 4677 20846 14846 (16) [49] (23) [35] 7193 13238 37521 42017 (11) [100] (39) [100]Landlord 8176 917 32225 2523 (69) [25] (12) [13] 6422 1320 25312 3632 (82) [64] (28) [19] 4814 4567 18975 12566 (16) [10] (24) [67] 19412 6804 76512 18720 (55) [100] (22) [100]   Total 3318 2365 8129 4214 (100) [20] (100) [25] 2452 1415 6006 2522 (100) [43] (100) [15] 6046 5681 14811 10124 (100) [43] (100) [60] 11816 9460 28947 16860 (100)[100] (100)[100]ADVANCED REGIO NLandless 0 0 95 53 (0) [0] (0) [3] 0 0 500 782 (0) [77] (3) [46] 0 0 848 867 (0) [12] (1) [51] 0 0 1443 1702 (0) [100] (1) [100]Poor Peasant 1227 852 518 248 (1) [3] (1) [5] 3793 3351 1600 977 (3) [38] (14) [18] 16156 13910 6815 4058 (17) [49] (16) [77] 21176 18112 8933 5284 (5) [100] (9) [100]Small Peasant 10996 1193 14335 1561 (12) [44] (2) [14] 3269 1139 4262 1490 (3) [23] (6) [13] 12579 6342 16398 8295 (15) [29] (9) [73] 26844 8674 34995 11346 (7) [100] (6) [100]Middle  Peasant 1109 683 1595 1234 (0) [7] (1) [8] 2852 2332 4100 4213 (1) [37] (13) [28] 10847 5346 15596 9656 (6) [50] (9) [64] 14808 8361 21291 15103 (2) [100] (6) [100]Rich Peasant 4683 13016 15819 38897 (12) [29] (85) [67] 1852 1352 6256 4042 (5) [29] (29) [7] 5980 5138 20201 15355 (27) [36] (31) [26] 12515 19507 42276 58294 (10) [100] (53) [100]Landlord 12149 1715 43638 3271 (75) [26] (11) [19] 9256 1646 33244 3139 (88) [67] (35) [18] 5417 5722 19457 10911 (35) [6] (34) [63] 26822 9084 96339 17321 (76) [100] (25) [100]   Total 8243 5703 14484 7513 (100) [26] (100) [42] 5652 1739 9932 2291 (100) [58] (100) [13] 7477 6167 13139 8124 (100) [14] (100) [45] 21372 13609 37555 17929 (100)[100] (100)[100]BACKWARD REGIO NLandless 0 0 271 100 (0) [0] (0) [15] 0 0 0 200 (0) [0] (0) [31] 0 0 1860 350 (1) [91] (0) [54] 0 0 2131 650 (1) [100] (0) [100]Poor Peasant 399 370 499 404 (0) [0] (24) [6] 683 673 854 733 (10) [6] (9) [10] 10572 5374 13212 5858 (21) [89] (17) [84] 11654 6417 14566 6995 (19) [100] (16) [100]Small Peasant 432 216 1328 477 (26) [6] (20) [2] 448 926 1378 2038 (27) [11] (18) [11] 4916 7641 15115 16821 (27) [79] (33) [87] 5796 8783 17821 19335 (27) [100] (30) [100]Middle  Peasant 489 246 1839 625 (44) [9] (12) [3] 582 1140 2191 2900 (26) [10] (11) [13] 6661 7135 25069 18155 (30) [80] (16) [84] 7732 8520 29099 21680 (30) [100] (15) [100]Rich Peasant 248 275 2209 933 (20) [9] (24) [4] 412 2154 3667 7317 (20) [16] (40) [33] 2489 4191 22136 14235 (12) [71] (17) [63] 3150 6620 28012 22485 (13) [100] (22) [100]Landlord 106 200 523 912 (10) [5] (20) [4] 667 1027 3278 4693 (17) [19] (22) [22] 3590 3529 17638 16130 (9) [73] (17) [74] 4363 4755 21438 21735 (10) [100] (18) [100]   Total 355 255 1139 585 (100) [6] (100) [4] 526 1211 1688 2776 (100) [11] (100) [18] 5185 5373 16651 12323 (100) [80] (100) [79] 6065 6839 19478 15685 (100)[100] (100)[100]ALL REGIO N   0.00 0 0 183 60 (0) [0] (0) [4] 0 0 250 692 (0) [16] (2) [45] 0 0 1354 788 (1) [75] (0) [51] 0 0 1787 1540 (0) [100] (0) [100] 0.01 ­ 2.5 5845 901 6059 904 (53) [16] (16) [9] 6801 1655 7049 1660 (85) [58] (48) [16] 10100 8015 10469 8042 (42) [23] (58) [76] 22747 10571 23576 10607 (63) [100] (46) [100] 2.5 ­ 5 1478 3095 5333 11145 (10) [15] (37) [36] 1054 1439 3806 5183 (7) [22] (28) [17] 5332 4039 19246 14545 (22) [58] (20) [47] 7864 8574 28385 30873 (13) [100] (25) [100] 5 ­ 10 4027 4160 28084 30109 (34) [35] (48) [46] 779 1036 5435 7495 (5) [12] (20) [11] 5075 3913 35389 28319 (28) [51] (19) [43] 9881 9108 68907 65923 (19) [100] (26) [100] 10 ­ 15 2004 75 23590 1120 (1) [11] (0) [1] 581 761 6833 11400 (1) [28] (2) [14] 3184 4470 37480 67000 (3) [53] (3) [84] 5769 5305 67903 79520 (2) [100] (2) [100] 15 & Abv 280 0 8350 0 (2) [18] (0) [0] 243 0 7250 0 (1) [16] (0) [0] 1736 0 51860 0 (4) [62] (0) [0] 2259 0 67460 0 (2) [100] (0) [100]    Total 3318 2365 8129 4214 (100) [20] (100) [25] 2452 1415 6006 2522 (100) [43] (100) [15] 6046 5681 14811 10124 (100) [35] (100) [60] 11816 9460 28947 16860 (100)[100] (100)[100]ADVANCED REGIO N   0.00 0 0 95 53 (0) [0] (0) [3] 0 0 500 782 (0) [77] (3) [46] 0 0 848 867 (0) [12] (1) [51] 0 0 1443 1702 (0) [100] (1) [100] 0.01 ­ 2.5 11297 1712 9735 1277 (56) [19] (12) [13] 13133 2552 11317 1903 (91) [69] (60) [20] 11278 8758 9719 6531 (55) [10] (58) [67] 35708 13022 30771 9711 (76) [100] (39) [100] 2.5 ­ 5 3460 6772 11933 22537 (7) [24] (38) [55] 1773 1135 6115 3779 (5) [34] (21) [9] 6148 4337 21206 14434 (19) [36] (23) [35] 11381 12245 39254 40749 (7) [100] (29) [100] 5 ­ 10 10607 10557 71206 81646 (36) [65] (49) [67] 1294 990 8688 7660 (3) [13] (15) [6] 5433 4126 36475 31910 (20) [19] (18) [26] 17335 15673 116369 121216 (15) [100] (31) [100] 10 ­ 15 2895 0 34875 0 (1) [17] (0) [0] 540 0 6500 0 (1) [34] (0) [0] 3181 0 38320 0 (6) [40] (0) [0] 6616 0 79695 0 (2) [100] (0) [100] 15 & Abv 0 0 0 0 (0) [0] (0) [0] 0 0 0 0 (0) [0] (0) [0] 0 0 0 (0) [0] (0) [0] 0 0 0 0 (0) [100] (0) [100]    Total 8243 5703 14484 7513 (100) [26] (100) [42] 5652 1739 9932 2291 (100) [58] (100) [13] 7477 6167 13139 8124 (100) [14] (100) [45] 21372 13609 37555 17929 (100)[100] (100)[100]BACKWARD REGIO N   0.00 0 0 271 100 (0) [0] (0) [15] 0 0 0 200 (0) [0] (0) [31] 0 0 1860 350 (0) [91] (0) [54] 0 0 2131 650 (1) [100] (0) [100] 0.01 ­ 2.5 522 386 675 496 (21) [3] (62) [4] 618 1084 799 1394 (26) [8] (37) [12] 8951 7543 11566 9699 (38) [84] (57) [84] 10091 9013 13040 11589 (35) [100] (54) [100] 2.5 ­ 5 433 133 1603 512 (44) [10] 13) [2] 676 1684 2500 6494 (33) [14] (35) [30] 4902 3800 18138 14649 (23) [72] (18) [68] 6011 5617 22242 21655 (26) [100] (21) [100] 5 ­ 10 217 212 1547 1477 (14) [3] (23) [4] 481 1063 3433 7404 (28) [10] (24) [21] 4867 3781 34720 26323 (31) [84] (19) [75] 5566 5056 39700 35204 (29) [100] (20) [100] 10 ­ 15 91 75 1020 1120 (0) [0] (2) [1] 668 761 7500 11400 (4) [18] (4) [14] 3191 4470 35800 67000 (2) [79] (5) [84] 3950 5305 44320 79520 (2) [100] (5) [100] 15 & Abv 280 0 8350 0 (21) [18] (0) [0] 243 0 7250 0 (10) [16] (0) [0] 1736 0 51860 0 (5) [62] (0) [0] 2259 0 67460 0 (7) [100] (0) [100]    Total 355 255 1139 585 (100) [6] (100) [4] 526 1211 1688 2776 (100) [11] (100) [18] 5185 5373 16651 12323 (100) [80] (100) [79] 6065 6839 19478 15685 (100)[100] (100)[100]

Note: Note:The percentages of different assets do not add upto total,as we exclude`other'asset here. 

26

Page 27: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

CAPITAL INVESTMENT AND CREDIT

One of the big impacts of neo­liberal reform was to remove fertilizer subsidies and as a result 

we have witnessed unprecedented increase in fertilizer  price.  At the same time there was 

increased prevalence of monetization and market dependence. As a result purchased input as 

a percentage of total cost increased from 26% to 72% for all classesduring the decades of 

neo­liberal  reform (Table 8).  The increase was phenomenal   in   the backward region from 

8.84% to 70% in comparison to the advanced (from 33% to 73%), which marks the increased 

dependence on market in the backward region. The interesting aspect is that in spite of this 

steep increase in the purchased inputs, the total inputs declined drastically both in per holding 

and per acre terms in the backward region. The decline in total cost in the backward region is  

a reflection of decline in total capital investment as a result of growing market dependence 

and enhanced cost of purchased inputs. Particularly, there was a drastic decline of livestock 

maintenance cost from 81% to 30% during the decade of neo­liberal reform in the backward 

region.  During the decade of neo­liberal  reform the backward region witnessed the trend 

towards more capistalist development side by side the advanced region. The most important 

feature was that all classes uniformly performed in the increase in purchased inputs and a 

decline   in   the   livestock  maintenance.  The  farm­size  criterion  again   failed   to   register   the 

unequal extent of inputs purchased by the different categories of peasant. 

27

Page 28: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

Table 8: Distribution of Purchased and Total Cost by Economic Classes and Acreage Groups   Percentage of Total Cost                     Chemical  Livestock  Purchased                     Purchased Inputs                     Total Inputs  Fertilizer  Maintenance Input           Per Hold.         Per Acre         Per Hold.         Per AcreClass/Group Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1ALL REGION                        Landless 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Poor Peasant16.6

126.6

855.1

631.9

4 18.7074.6

9 632.78 1682.75 787.742435.7

4 3384.34 2253.034213.1

2

Small Peasant13.6

932.4

261.9

321.5

5 16.5173.1

0 1502.57 4662.57 581.482405.2

1 9100.40 6378.453521.7

6

Middle Peasant 9.9033.6

270.5

714.9

7 14.7866.5

0 1703.21 7016.37 506.153141.1

6 11521.2710551.6

43423.8

5

Rich Peasant23.0

635.7

049.3

410.0

0 28.3271.3

3 7014.7415094.7

41340.2

14754.9

3 24770.6321161.0

54732.5

7

Landlord28.6

334.6

735.1

214.3

3 36.5674.6

3 8211.9411414.7

92028.9

74149.3

6 22460.8015295.6

05549.5

0

   Total21.1

134.0

249.8

815.0

9 26.4672.3

9 2946.58 6551.251174.4

73675.9

6 11134.57 9049.984438.1

0ADVANCED REGION                        Landless 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Poor Peasant25.4

226.8

233.1

532.8

1 28.7778.4

8 953.82 2369.902188.1

18124.0

6 3315.51 3019.737605.9

7

Small Peasant28.4

939.0

830.6

012.9

2 34.3674.7

4 3976.54 8262.253271.8

46316.7

0 11572.7711055.1

09521.9

0

Middle Peasant23.7

339.2

833.6

5 7.22 27.4564.8

7 2568.0011064.6

32377.7

86125.7

4 9356.0017057.2

88662.9

6

Rich Peasant31.6

937.4

928.9

0 7.63 39.7272.0

0 8646.2824652.5

32553.0

38249.5

9 21770.1734241.8

26428.2

0

Landlord33.1

736.3

925.4

510.7

5 42.5474.7

810852.3

614279.8

83033.7

67488.9

8 25512.4019095.7

77131.9

5

   Total31.0

936.6

328.1

011.0

6 38.8673.0

0 4849.50 9978.802796.2

77574.3

0 12479.8313670.3

17196.0

0BACKWARD REGION                        Landless 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Poor Peasant 3.9026.3

886.9

024.4

0 4.1866.9

8 145.69 995.59 106.83 913.38 3488.78 1486.332558.1

4

Small Peasant 4.0825.4

982.2

630.5

3 4.9271.4

0 393.55 3162.70 123.081436.7

8 7992.10 4429.852499.4

2

Middle Peasant 7.0821.5

778.0

931.5

0 12.2069.9

7 1475.63 4072.18 371.991600.3

6 12091.08 5820.273048.0

4

Rich Peasant10.8

622.1

978.2

527.8

3 12.1966.3

5 3751.67 3625.40 420.171066.9

2 30771.56 5464.133446.2

9

Landlord 5.6724.7

184.1

434.9

9 6.2773.7

5 877.44 5243.85 163.911147.6

4 13984.12 7110.622612.2

3

   Total 6.9324.1

180.8

530.3

6 8.8470.0

9 853.37 2780.95 253.841212.5

9 9654.77 3967.612871.8

2ALL REGION                           0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

 0.01 ­ 2.522.1

631.7

042.6

617.9

5 27.2475.5

9 1698.82 4730.381587.2

54714.3

6 6236.54 6257.705826.9

7

 2.5 ­ 516.7

135.3

355.7

910.9

0 21.7069.2

3 3179.4211881.2

6 885.153268.4

2 14653.9917163.2

14079.6

8

 5 ­ 1023.8

137.4

447.6

212.1

3 30.5168.4

6 8821.9020942.0

71222.7

62922.3

3 28911.7130590.3

24007.3

0

 10 ­ 1532.5

939.5

441.3

334.0

9 40.5583.6

018273.0

014270.0

01419.8

1 951.97 45067.9817070.0

03501.7

9

 15 & Abv12.5

8 0.0076.9

4 0.00 14.35 0.0014903.5

0 0.00 499.03 0.00 103861.13 0.003477.6

9

28

Page 29: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

    Total21.1

134.0

249.8

814.9

3 26.4672.3

9 2946.58 6551.251174.4

73675.9

9 11134.57 9049.984438.1

0ADVANCED REGION                           0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

 0.01 ­ 2.528.3

433.9

628.9

714.0

4 34.5176.7

7 2660.79 7266.913239.0

99744.4

4 7709.81 9465.719385.4

6

 2.5 ­ 527.3

638.2

231.4

3 7.01 34.1669.4

7 7069.2320462.8

62134.7

36019.7

5 20694.9229455.9

06249.3

4

 5 ­ 1035.5

040.7

124.5

8 8.42 46.0168.7

921205.6

345967.0

03050.6

26101.2

7 46091.3866818.9

06630.6

6

 10 ­ 1541.8

5 0.0026.6

3 0.00 52.25 0.0026857.5

0 0.002170.3

0 0.00 51406.00 0.004154.0

2 15 & Abv 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

    Total31.0

936.6

328.1

010.8

6 38.8673.0

0 4849.50 9978.802796.2

77574.3

0 12479.8313670.3

17196.0

0BACKWARD REGION                           0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

 0.01 ­ 2.5 5.0623.1

780.5

432.7

4 7.1171.1

4 290.21 1950.61 202.041517.1

0 4079.26 2742.062839.8

6

 2.5 ­ 5 5.6121.3

781.1

529.6

7 8.7368.0

4 980.83 3871.77 261.521004.2

6 11239.55 5690.032996.8

7

 5 ­ 10 5.7325.8

183.2

425.2

7 6.5567.2

8 1201.15 7039.33 162.831011.1

2 18339.6110463.3

32486.0

8

 10 ­ 15 3.2139.5

488.0

134.0

9 3.4183.6

0 1104.0014270.0

0 79.65 951.97 32391.9317070.0

02337.0

8

 15 & Abv12.5

8 0.0076.9

4 0.00 14.35 0.0014903.5

0 0.00 499.03 0.00 103861.13 0.003477.6

9

    Total 6.9324.1

180.8

530.3

6 8.8470.0

9 853.37 2780.95 253.841212.6

1 9654.77 3967.612871.8

2

Note: Pd1 = 1993­94, Pd2 = 2004­05

Table 9: Distribution of Institutional and Non­institutional Credit by Economic Classes and Acreage Groups              Total Institutional             Total Non­institutional            Total Inst + Non­inst

Classes/Groups PerHolding(Rs)    PerAcre(Rs)

 Percentage PerHolding(Rs)     PerAcre(Rs)

 Percentage PerHolding(Rs)     PerAcre(Rs)

All Region Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1Landless 2030 1246 0 0 78 26 567 3509 0 0 22 74 2597 4755 0Poor Peasant 1390 1515 1731 2192 41 31 2031 3402 2528 4924 59 69 3421 4917 4259 7117Small Peasant 2744 1903 1062 982 60 34 1851 3643 716 1879 40 66 4595 5546 1778 2861Middle Peasant 1313 2263 390 1013 32 30 2764 5291 821 2369 68 70 4077 7554 1212 3382Rich Peasant 2519 6612 481 2083 28 57 6320 4952 1207 1560 72 43 8838 11564 1689 3643Landlord 3224 3717 796 1351 29 23 7928 12362 1959 4494 71 77 11151 16080 2755 5845   Total 2125 2860 847 1605 38 34 3515 5612 1401 3149 62 66 5640 8471 2248 4753Advanced Region                              Landless 3800 1200 0 0 91 23 380 4096 0 0 9 77 4180 5296 0Poor Peasant 1715 1758 3934 6026 40 27 2603 4767 5971 16342 60 73 4318 6525 9905 22368Small Peasant 2149 3600 1768 2752 35 42 3946 5040 3247 3853 65 58 6095 8640 5015 6606Middle Peasant 893 3375 827 1869 13 25 5920 10000 5481 5536 87 75 6813 13375 6309 7405Rich Peasant 3611 10483 1066 3508 30 71 8533 4240 2520 1419 70 29 12144 14724 3586 4927Landlord 4064 4418 1136 2317 30 25 9548 12930 2669 6781 70 75 13612 17348 3805 9098   Total 2668 4092 1538 3106 33 37 5360 7097 3091 5387 67 63 8028 11189 4629 8493Backward Region                              Landless 260 1500 0 0 26 84 754 280 0 0 74 16 1014 1780 0Poor Peasant 898 1271 659 1166 44 38 1163 2037 853 1869 56 62 2061 3308 1512 3035

29

Page 30: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

Small Peasant 3010 1196 941 543 77 28 912 3061 285 1390 23 72 3922 4257 1227 1934Middle Peasant 1424 1455 359 572 42 44 1934 1865 487 733 58 56 3357 3320 846 1305Rich Peasant 333 1967 37 579 15 25 1892 5807 212 1709 85 75 2226 7773 249 2288Landlord 889 2208 166 483 21 17 3427 11139 640 2438 79 83 4316 13347 806 2921   Total 1527 1504 454 656 51 27 1486 3977 442 1734 49 73 3013 5481 896 2390All Region                                 0.00 2030 1246 0 0 78 26 567 3509 0 0 22 74 2597 4755 0 0.01 ­ 2.5 1569 2483 1466 2474 32 36 3387 4442 3164 4427 68 64 4956 6924 4630 6901 2.5 ­ 5 2022 2259 563 621 30 18 4712 10045 1312 2763 70 82 6734 12304 1875 3385 5 ­ 10 5833 9929 809 1385 66 53 3044 8707 422 1215 34 47 8877 18636 1230 2600 10 ­ 15 4667 0 363 0 34 0 9033 40000 702 2668 66 100 13700 40000 1064 2668 15 & Abv 0 0 0 0 0 0 2250 0 75 0 100 0 2250 0 75    Total 2125 2860 847 1605 38 34 3515 5612 1401 3149 62 66 5640 8471 2248 4753Advanced Region                               0.00 3800 1200 0 0 91 23 380 4096 0 0 9 77 4180 5296 0 0.01 ­ 2.5 1986 3524 2418 4726 29 35 4827 6541 5876 8771 71 65 2027 10065 2468 13496 2.5 ­ 5 1315 2786 397 819 10 17 11473 13825 3465 4067 90 83 9115 16611 2753 4887

 5 ­ 101056

3 23200 1520 3079 71 86 4250 3760 611 499 29 14 2350 26960 338 3578 10 ­ 15 5000 0 404 0 53 0 4400 0 356 0 47 0 0 0 0 15 & Abv 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0    Total 2668 4092 1538 3106 33 37 5360 7097 3091 5387 67 63 8028 11189 4629 8493Backward Region       0.00 260 1500 0 0 26 84 754 280 0 0 74 16 1014 1780 0 0.01 ­ 2.5 959 1341 668 1043 43 39 1278 2141 890 1665 57 61 2237 3482 1558 2709 2.5 ­ 5 2422 1767 646 458 73 21 890 6517 237 1690 27 79 3312 8284 883 2149 5 ­ 10 2923 2556 396 367 56 18 2302 11456 312 1645 44 82 5225 14011 708 2013 10 ­ 15 4000 0 289 0 18 0 18300 40000 1320 2668 82 100 22300 40000 1609 2668 15 & Abv 0 0 0 0 0 0 2250 0 75 0 100 0 2250 0 75    Total 1527 1504 454 656 51 27 1486 3977 442 1734 49 73 3013 5481 896 2390

The above data must be linked in turn to the availability and source of agricultural credit as 

shown in Table 9. That non­institutional credit increased from 62% to 66% of borrowing over 

the decade of neo­liberal reform underlines the degree to which moneylenders and traders 

tightened   their   domination   over   agricultural   production   in   West   Bengal.   By   contrast, 

institutional  credit  had been more  and more   insignificant,  owing  to   the  state  withdrawal 

policy of reform. The impact was disastrous for the backward region. Earlier this region was 

the big beneficiary of the IRDP policies that contributed to the ratio of institutional credit was 

30

Page 31: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

as high as 51% in 1993­94. Over the decade the percentage drastically declined to 27. There 

was a  broadly  negative  association  between ascending class   status  and  the  proportion  of 

institutional credit received during 1993­94 which has benn vanished in 2004­05. Rather the 

association became positive after a decade. Accordingly in 1993­94   the landless class had 

the highest access to this source of borrowing (78 per cent), while the rich peasant had the 

lowest   (around 28%).  However,  over   the decade of  neo­liberal   reform the corresponding 

percentages were 26% and 23%. Both the regions also broadly follow this transformation, 

though it was much sharp in the advanced region. The farm size wise distribution showed that 

advanced and combined region strictly follow this trend. 

CROPPING PATTERNS OUTPUT AND MARKETED SURPLUS

In terms of aggregate sown area and yield in the sample villages, paddy grown in different 

seasons (aman and boro) constitutes the main crop in each region, occupying some 73% and 

61%   of   the   gross   output   in   1993­94   and   2004­05   respectively.   Although   a   substantial 

difference exists between the two regions in terms of the overall share of paddy cultivated – it 

accounts  for nearly ninety per cent of  total  output  in  the backward region in both years, 

compared with only 56%(1993­94) and 41% (2004­05) in the advanced one. When output per 

holding and per acre is considered, this difference is not so acute. In this connection is should 

be noted that evidence of increased output in a backward region is not specific to our village 

level findings: other economically backward areas of West Bengal, such as Purulia, registered 

a   very  high   level   growth   rate   during   the  past   [Saha  and  Swaminathan,   1994;  Sen  and 

Sengupta, 1995]. The relatively high level of production in our sample villages in Bankura 

district ­ even by the poorer categories of farmer ­ was due mainly to the expansion both of 

31

Page 32: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

irrigation  facilities  and thus  also of  boro  cultivation,  an effect  again  of   the  land reforms 

carried out in West Bengal. 

In overall terms, average per holding output is positively associated with ascending 

class status up to the rich peasant category, but declines for the landlord group for both in 

1993­94 and  2004­05  (Table  10).  Because  of  higher  cropping   intensity  on   labour  hiring 

farms, however, output per acre sown shows a less positive variation with ascending class 

status than output per acre operated. Accordingly, those units which purchase labour­power 

have a significantly higher yield than holdings belonging to pettycommodity producers or 

sellers of labour­power. Up to the ten acre limit,  farm size is inversely related to yield in 

1993­94 (defined as output per acre operated as well as sown), but units of ten acres and 

above possess a high value output. However, in 2004­05 no such inverse relationship was 

found.   In  fact   there  was no  clear   tendency.  Compared with  holdings  owned/operated  by 

sellers of labour­power and petty commodity producers, therefore, those owned/operated by 

labour­purchasing categories register nearly double the yield level in both the year.

TABLE 11                   DISTRIBUTION OF THE PRODUCT MARKETED:ALL REGION     Food  Potato    Oilseed    Other    %  Mktd  To Total   %  Mktd  To Total   %  Mktd  To Total   %  Mktd Class/Group Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1 Pd2 Pd1Landless 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00Poor Peasant 14.50 3.32 76.34 87.77 9.16 5.89 0.00Small Peasant 45.58 22.75 45.21 75.55 8.95 1.70 0.26Middle Peasant 74.79 23.54 21.57 73.79 3.33 2.67 0.31

32

Page 33: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

Rich Peasant 77.29 35.79 19.35 59.36 2.91 4.78 0.45Landlord 43.51 34.62 49.42 63.73 7.07 1.65 0.00   Total 61.98 31.82 32.82 64.77 4.93 3.26 0.28   0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 ­ 2.5 24.87 12.54 65.45 84.06 9.43 3.04 0.24 2.5 ­ 5 52.53 34.97 42.87 61.43 4.60 3.61 0.00 5 ­ 10 50.02 56.52 42.69 39.98 6.73 3.50 0.55 10 ­ 15 62.65 100.00 29.44 0.00 6.97 0.00 0.94 15 & Abv 100.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00    Total 61.98 31.82 32.82 64.77 4.93 3.26 0.28 ADVANCED REGIONLandless 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00Poor Peasant 10.17 0.00 80.21 90.79 9.62 6.10 0.00Small Peasant 18.41 7.50 69.02 90.70 12.56 1.80 0.00Middle Peasant 5.38 12.19 87.19 84.75 7.42 3.06 0.00Rich Peasant 39.45 32.31 51.84 62.65 7.78 5.04 0.93Landlord 43.02 24.05 49.85 74.03 7.13 1.92 0.00   Total 36.77 24.57 54.92 71.66 8.00 3.62 0.30   0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 ­ 2.5 20.86 10.71 69.43 85.87 9.71 3.12 0.00 2.5 ­ 5 36.48 30.39 57.37 65.75 6.16 3.86 0.00 5 ­ 10 41.16 45.84 50.81 49.79 7.57 4.36 0.45 10 ­ 15 62.65 0.00 29.44 0.00 6.97 0.00 0.94 15 & Abv 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00    Total 36.77 24.57 54.92 71.66 8.00 3.62 0.30 BACKWARD REGIONLandless 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00Poor Peasant 100.00 100.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00Small Peasant 97.16 52.92 0.00 45.58 2.07 1.50 0.76Middle Peasant 97.60 100.00 0.00 0.00 1.98 0.00 0.41Rich Peasant 99.83 98.56 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.17Landlord 100.00 100.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00   Total 99.40 90.61 0.00 8.81 0.37 0.29 0.24   0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 ­ 2.5 90.93 50.12 0.00 46.80 4.81 1.54 4.26 2.5 ­ 5 100.00 100.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 5 ­ 10 96.63 100.00 0.00 0.00 2.30 0.00 1.07 10 ­ 15 0.00 100.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 15 & Abv 100.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00    Total 99.40 90.61 0.00 8.81 0.37 0.29 0.24__________________________________________________________________________________________________________

A crucial indicator of the extent to which agriculture is commercialized, marketed surplus is 

linked to the purchase both of inputs and of manufactured consumption goods. Table 11 show 

marketed product per acre and per holding for different crops, and also the percentage of the 

latter marketed by each class. Up to the rich peasant category, total output sold per holding 

33

Page 34: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

and per  acre for  both period  increases  with economic  class,  after  which  it  declines.  The 

exceptions in 1993­94are the cash crops (potatoes, oilseed), which register a decline from the 

small  to  the middle peasant  categories.  In 1993­94 the percentage of foodcrops marketed 

increase   by   ascending   size   groups,   while   the   main   cash   crop   (potatoes)   declines   ­   the 

exception   being   the   landlordclass.   However,   in   2004­05   potato   also   followed   the   same 

tendency as paddy. Though oilseed maintained some fluctuations. This is explained with the 

fact that over the decade of neoliberal reform the upper classes has been able to take control 

of   product   marketed.   Higher   the   ascending   classes,   greater   is   the   control   over   product 

marketed. 

A regional comparison of marketed surplus confirms that producers in the advanced 

area sell both cash crops and foodcrops, whereas only the latter are sold in the backward area. 

With regard to the respective share of each class/category in the total marketed surplus, there 

is a high degree of concentration among economic classes: for both regions, separately and 

combined, therefore, the top two economic classes account about eighty percent of the total 

product sold for both time periods. This domination is relatively less in the backward region 

(66%) in 2004­05. This element of concentration is not reflected for both periods when farm 

size is considered, the maximum concentration happened for the size group 0.01 – 2.5 acres. 

CONCLUSION

Based on surveys conducted in 1993­94 and 2004­05 on same set of households, this  study 

shows   nature   of   the   differentiated   economy   of   West   Bengal   against   the   backdrop   of 

34

Page 35: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

neoliberal reform in India since 1991.  The major  findings of this study is that during the 

decade of neo­liberal reform, the interventionist economy eroded in rural West Bengal and 

peasant differentiation was going on.

West  Bengal  is  an eastern regional  state  of  India.   It  experienced  land reform under  Left 

centrist government during late sixties and under Left Front govt since 1977. The land reform 

programme   is   famous   as   ‘Operation   Barga’.   Also   West  Bengal  experienced   successful 

implementation of grass root level local self­govenance (Panchayat Raj) during this regime. 

As   a   result   WB   witnessed   highest   agricultural   growth   and   significant   level   of   poverty 

reduction   during   eighties   (Saha­Swaminathan   1994,   Sen­Sengupta   1995).   Since   1991 

agricultural  growth declined  and West  Bengal moved in reverse gear (Bhattacharyya and 

Bhattacharyya 2007).  Since 1991 govt of India implemented IMF directed market economic 

reform reflected in:  reduction of subsidy in food, fertilizer and credit; trade liberalization and 

a move from foodgrain to export oriented agriculture.; promotion of microcredit  institution, 

agribusiness and corporate retail chain. Since early nineties Indian agriculture showed worst 

performance after independence and its growth was below the population growth rate.   The 

inequality and poverty also significant. West Bengal had to accept neoliberal reform as a state 

in India. Land inequality in West Bengal is less than India as a whole because of the radical 

reform in late sixties. Land inequality reduced in WB during eighties due to operation barga, 

while   the  non­land   inequality   increased.  During  nineties   land   inequality   increased   again 

owing to neo­liberal reform though land reform never stopped in WB (Bhattacharyya and 

Bhattacharyya 2007).  

35

Page 36: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

This paper is written in the context of long debate between Marxism and Populism.  Started 

from   19th  Century   Russia   by   Narodniks   that   Russian   peasantry   was   a   homogeneous   / 

unddifferentiated entity.  Any kind of capitalist  development would be self  defeating as it 

would impoverish the peasantry and the home market for capitalism would collapse. Lenin 

(1899): Capitalism had already developed and brought differentiation of peasantry. The latter 

created home market for Capitalism. Kautsky (1899) supported Lenin’s argument.     There 

was a revival of Populism in 1920s Russia in the hands of Chayanov (1966) who proposed 

demographic and cyclic differentiation among peasant community.  This populist view was 

also adopted by   Sen (1966) who showed  family Labour farms are more efficient vis­à­vis 

Capitalist Farm and this efficiency was the major explanation behind the inverse relationship 

between   Farm   Size   and   Productivity.   Geogescu­Rogen   (1960)   &   Lipton   (1977,   2004) 

supported this point. According to the Marxist critiques Sen’s argument is fallacious based on 

identical   production   function   and   co­existence   of   Family   Farms   and   Capitalist   Farms. 

(Patnaik 1979). The socalled family labour farms are in reality the impoverished agricultural 

labourer with tiny land. (Patnaik 1979, Bhattacharyya 2001). The socalled ‘efficiency’ is their 

desperation and vulnerability. Thus ‘efficiency’ measured in output per unit of labour gives 

opposite result.  

The neo­populism,  is  however,   is  a part  of neo­liberalist  views.   World Bank adopts  the 

policy of participation of a homogenous/ undifferentiated group of depoliticized people in an 

inactive state. (WDR 2001, Bhattacharyya 2007). This participation is important to eradicate 

poverty   (WDR 2001).  Following   this  model  nationalized   rural  banking  was   replaced  by 

Microfinance   institutions.   PDS   system   /   Mandis   were   replaced   by   Agribusiness   and 

Corporate Retail Chain.

36

Page 37: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

As mentioned before this study is based on two phases of survey 1993­94 and 2004­05 on 

same set of households.   Two blocks of Bankura district, West Bengal chosen. Kotulpur as 

the advanced and Hirbandh as the backward one.   210 households were surveyed in villages 

purposively selected. 110 households surveyed from the advanced and 100 from backward. 

Households are classified on the basis of usual acreage group and Patnaik’s E­criteria.  The 

question   is   that   why   should   we   adopt   a   second   criteria   when   NSSO   has   prescribed   a 

particular one. NSSO gives classification on the basis of acreage group. These are marginal 

peasant: 0.01­2.5 acres, small peasant: 2.5­5 acres, semi­medium: 5­10 acres, medium: 10­25 

acres,  large: 25 and above.  However,  according to NSSO 48th  round there is no holdings 

above 10 acres   in  West  Bengal  since  1991.  We have  also  seen  a  huge concentration  of 

households in 0.01­2.5 acres.  However, this does not indicate a halt of differentiation. Land 

under ownership or operation is no more an indicator of household’s economic strength in 

West  Bengal. NSSO data showed that inequality in the basic means of production in West 

Bengal shifted from land to non­land asset. We need a second criterion for classification side 

by side acreage groups. Patnaik’s E­criteria is helpful here.  Marxian class criteria defined as 

(a) resource endowment, (b) nature of labour use, (c ) Production of a retained surplus. The 

vector of all three criteria is impossible to measure empirically. We use second one as the 

empirical approximation. 

This study gets important findings regarding household structure and participation. Landness 

increased  and distress  selling  of   land has  happened.  After   losing   job   the  households  are 

compelled   to  move   to  non­remunerative  non   farm  jobs;   the  phenomena  which   is   called 

37

Page 38: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

disguised   proletarianization  (Murray   2006,   Kay   2008).  Though   the   tendency   is   not 

widespread.  Households  belong  to 0­2.5 acres   increased from 138 to 153 during decade. 

Partly due to land reform and partly due to inheritance rule.  This is reflected in swelling of 

landlord households from 15 to 27 and rich peasant from 12 to 16 during the decade. In spite 

of land loss, these labour hiring classes maintained the erstwhile labour process. 

This study made important findings on participation of households. In Chayanov, ascending 

farm size is inversely related to well being. In contradiction to this in our study the ascending 

class / size status is related to lower participation rate, and therefore, greater well being. It is 

interesting   to  note   that    participation   rate   increased   for  upper   classes  during  neo­liberal 

reforms. This means the well being of higher peasant classes have also been curbed during 

neo­liberal   reforms.  The  poor  classes   /   lower  size  groups  are  predominantly  agricultural 

labour reflected in lower hired in and higher hired out  land and vice versa. The socalled 

family labour farms do not belong to self­sufficient ‘peasant economy’. 

Looking into land structure the average  area declined during decade.  Declining area with 

rising cost gives a question on farm viability in India (Naryanmoorthy 2007). Tenancy as an 

institution declined in West  Bengal  following Operation Barga (Bhattacharyya 2007). This 

goes against the hypothesis that through oepration barga Left Front gave tenancy a permanent 

status, which is a pre­capitalist institution. (Khasnabis 1981, Rudra 1981).  A big decline of 

irrigated area particularly in the backward region in WB owing to neoliberal policy of state 

withdrawal may give birth to ‘ultra Left terrorism’.  The households belong to self­employed 

declined, exploited classes remained same and that for exploiter increased.  The control of 

38

Page 39: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

land by exploiter classes increased in liberalization period (from around 50 to 60 %). The 

self­employed   are   major   land   loser.    The   condition   of   exploited   remains   more   or   less 

unchanged  who continue   to  own  around  11­  12%  of   total   land  area.  The  percentage  of 

irrigated   land  increased   for   the  exploiter   increased   from 60  to  70%. The same for  other 

classes declined.   Let us look at the differentiated non­land asset market, market for capital 

investment and credit. The exploiter classes hold 60% of asset while the exploited classes are 

around 12%.  The cost of production increased largely for the exploiter and self­employed 

classes, declined for exploited.  For exploiter classes the access to institutional credit jumped 

to a large extent from 40 to 62 % and the same declined for the rest.   

The  output and product marketed showed extreme kind of differentiation.  Particularly the 

product marketed showed a huge inequality, where the exploiter classes occupy 78% and the 

exploited 4%.  The pattern of inequality remains same between pre and post liberalization 

which reminds us Harriss­White’s note that deregulated markets may become more or less 

imperfect   than   regulated  market   (Harriss­White   1996).  Left  Front   pre­occupied  with   the 

reforms in the structures of production,  and nothing for market (Harriss­White 2008).  No 

inverse   relationship  between   farm size   /   economic  class   and  productivity   is   found.  This 

thoroughly refutes populist proposition of Chayanov and Sen. 

39

Page 40: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

NOTES 

1.  West  Bengal  economy may be characterised  as a  small   farm economy where average operated area is much less than that at the national level. This peasant economy experienced an overall rate of agricultural output growth of 1.74 per cent per annum during the period 1949­1980 that was below the rates of rural (2.31 per cent) and total population (2.42 per cent)   increase in  the same period [Boyce,  1984]. Using an index number series on aggregate agricultural production, Saha and Swaminathan [1994] claimed that ‘the exponential growth rate of all West Bengal for the period 1981­82 to 1990­91 was an impressive 6.4 per cent per annum. Though some doubt has been cast regarding the validity of official data [Dattaray, 1994] from which this conclusion was derived, no effective challenge was made against the findings about the high growth performance of West Bengal. Sen and Sengupta [1995], by contrast, used an alternative source of data (Comprehensive Cost of Production Studies by the Central Government, Ministry of Agriculture), and reaffirmed a significant trend­break in the growth rate during the eighties.

2.  When compared  with  all   the  other   Indian   states,   the  magnitude  of   the  decline   in   the percentage of people living below the poverty line was largest in West Bengal. On the basis of the following indicators, it can be argued that the process of immiserisation has actually been stopped in West  Bengal.   (i)  The percentage  of  male  and female  agricultural   labour population to main workers marked an increase for India, but experienced a decline for West Bengal during 1981­91 (Census of India 1981 and 1991). (ii) casualisation of rural workers, which increased steadily for all India from 1972­73 to 1983, fell in West Bengal during 1987­88 [Chandrasekhar, 1993]. (iii) It is evident from NSSO Surveys that, between 1983 and 1987­88,   unemployment   rates   of   all   kinds   (Usual   Status   Unemployment   Rate,   Current Weekly Status Unemployment Rate and Current Daily Status Unemployment Rate, etc.) for male   workers   declined   in   West   Bengal,   while   they   rose   on   an   All­India   basis [Chandrasekhar,  1993].   (iv)  Agricultural  wages   tripled   in  West  Bengal   from 1977­78  to 1987­88, and the real wage increase in West Bengal was also among the highest in India [Sen and Sengupta,  1995]. (v) The All­India percentage of agricultural labour households with land declined during 1977­78 to 1983, but increased in West Bengal over the same period [Government of India, Ministry of Labour, 1991].

3. It may be noted that a radical redistribution of land did take place immediately after the 1917 October  Revolution.   In  Lenin’s  analysis,  however,   this   simply   laid   the  basis   for  a democratic and wide­based process of peasant class differentiation, rather than the narrowly based process of landlord oppression [Lenin, 1970: 97­98].

4.  Topographically   the  district   forms  an   intermediate   tract   lying  between   rice  producing alluvial plains of Bengal to the east and Chotanagpur plateau on the West. Compared to other districts in West Bengal, it represents a very high degree of regional variation. The entire subdivision  of  Bishnupur  and also  some of   the  eastern  thanas  of  Sadar   subdivision,  are agriculturally productive, and not materially different from the flat plains in the adjoining districts of Burdwan and Hoogly. But the west and north west of the district are part of the agriculturally   non­fertile   Chotanagpur   plateau,   where   the   terrain   consists   of   undulating lateritic  ridges covered with sparse forest.  There is  also a variation  in  the distribution of 

40

Page 41: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

population  between   the  eastern  and   the  western  part  of  Bankura  district:   the  population density   is   much   higher   in   the   eastern   part   than   in   the   west.   While   the   Bengali   Hindu population is predominant in the eastern plain, the western thanas contain a large proportion of tribal (mainly Santal) population. Moreover, the literacy rate is much higher in the former than in the latter.

5. It is a common phenomenon that a district nearer to the state capital (particularly when the state   capital   is   a  metropolitan   city)  will   have   a   higher   level   of   economic  development. Proximity to the state capital also draws the attention of the policy makers, so much so that ­ instead of being located in distant, far­off districts ­ the new branch offices of the  Gramin Bank  and  the   fresh   inflow of  agricultural  credit   therefrom,  are  actually  disbursed   in   the districts closest to the cities. This implies that any survey conducted in districts nearer to a state capital may give a biased and over­optimistic view of the credit distribution in the state. On the other hand, Bankura is not a bordering district of West Bengal, like West Dinajpur, Murshidabad or Nadia. Generally there is alleged to be a continuous and illicit international flow of produce and labour in regions close to the border, as a result of which the survey population may also undergo constant change.

6. Two sample blocks were selected, on the basis of their levels of economic development. One block was Kotulpur, which seemed to be the most advanced and most prosperous in the district; the other was Khatra­2, the most backward. The following developmental variables were used in order to identify blocks with high and low level of development: percentage of irrigated area to total cultivated area; percentage of villages having one or more educational institutions; percentage of rural population served by medical amenities; percentage of rural population served by a pukka road; percentage of rural population served by power supply; percentage of cultivated area to total area; and the percentage of rural population served by a local market or hat.

7. NSSO gives classification on the basis of acreage group. These are marginal peasant: 0.01­2.5 acres, small peasant: 2.5­5 acres, semi­medium: 5­10 acres, medium: 10­25 acres, large 25 acres and above.  8. The Bangopalpur Chatanibad Jouthakhamar is a large co­operative farm formed in 1984 with 84 poor households belonging to a scheduled tribe and/or a scheduled caste. This co­operative was formed after the acquisition by the state of an unfragmented 35 acres of ceiling surplus   land  from erstwhile  zamindars.  The co­operative   farm has   in   its  possession nine wells, one tractor, two pump sets, three oxen, poultry, 4 ponds used for fish production; about 27   acres   of   land   have   been   brought   under   cultivation:   foodcrops   cultivated   in   1993/94 amounted to 600 quintals. One of the main conditions governing co­operative production is that a quarter of all output has to be deposited in the community store on the farm, for use partly as seed and partly for contingencies like drought. A portion of what is produced by the co­operative is sold in order to purchase additional inputs for or enhance the capital base of the unit.

9. Before the Left Front Government came to power, all the tenancy contracts were verbal ones. It was consequently impossible for a poor peasant to establish his identity as a tenant, 

41

Page 42: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

let   alone  claim  other   legal   rights   that  a   tenant   is   supposed   to  have.   In  addition   to   such disadvantages, a poor peasant was unable to meet the legal expenses that would be incurred in the event of a dispute with the landlord. Given this background, the Left Front’s Operation Barga was revolutionary in two respects. First, every tenant now has a barga certificate, as a result   of   which  he   cannot   be   evicted,   or   deprived   of   legal   rights   guaranteed   under   the constitution. Second, in the event of a dispute with the owner, all legal costs of going to court are now borne by the landlord. In this way, Operation Barga has swung the balance of power where  land is  concerned firmly  in the direction  of  tenants.  Under  the existing legislative situation, therefore, a landlord can expect to obtain from leased out land nothing more than a legally stipulated share; the only way to change this is through a lengthy and costly legal confrontation. This is the main reason why the owners of land in rural West Bengal have stopped leasing out land; furthermore, owners of sublet land frequently dispose of this at a nominal amount to the existing tenant. All these factors have led to descriptions of tenancy as a dying institution.

REFERENCES

Bhaduri, A., 1973, ‘A study in Agricultural Backwardness under Semi-feudalism’, The Economic Journal, Vol. 83, No. 329.

Bhaduri, A., 1984, The Economic Structure of Backward Agriculture, London, Academic Press.

Bhaduri, A., 1993a, ‘Class Relations and Patterns of Accumulation in an Agrarian Economy’, in A. Bhaduri (ed.) [1993].

Bhaduri, A., 1993b, ‘The Evoluation of Land Relations in Eastern India Under British Rule’, in A. Bhaduri (ed.) [1993].

Bhaduri, A., 1993c, ‘Mathematical Appendix: A Model of Differentiation among Initially Indebted Peasants’, in A. Bhaduri (ed.) [1993].

Bhaduri, A. (ed.), 1993, Unconventional Economic Essays, Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Bhattacharyya, Sudipta, 1996, ‘Evolution of the Agricultural Credit Market in West Bengal since   1977:   A   Journey   from   Peasant   Class   Differentiation   to   Agriculture­led Development’, in A. Roychoudhury and D. Sarkar (eds.),  Economy of West Bengal:  Problems and Prospects, New Delhi: Allied.

Bhattacharyya,   Sudipta,   1996,  Agricultural   Credit,   Institutional   Reform   and   Economic  Development. A Study of West Bengal: 1977 ­ 1994, Unpublished Ph.D thesis, Centre for Economic Studies and Planning, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi. 

Bhattacharyya,  Sudipta 2007. ‘Class and Politics of Participatory Rural Transformation in West   Bengal:   An   Alternative   to   World   Bank   Orthodoxy’,   Journal   of   Agrarian Change, Vol.7, No.3, July, pp. 348­81.

42

Page 43: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

Bhattacharyya, Maumita and Sudipta Bhattacharyya 2007 ‘Agrarian Impasse in West Bengal in the Liberalisation Era’, Economic and Political Weekly, Dec 29.

Boyce, James K., 1984, Agrarian Impasse in Bengal, Institutional Constraints to Technological Change, Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Chandrasekhar, C. P., 1993, ‘Agrarian Change and Occupational Diversification: Non-Agricultural Employment and Rural Development in West Bengal’, The Journal of Peasant Studies, Vol. 20, No. 2.

Chayanov, A. V., 1966,  Theory of Peasant Economy,  D. Thorner,  R. E. F. Smith and B. Kerblay (eds.), Homewood, IL: The American Economic Association.

Chayanov, A.V., 1991, The Theory of Peasant Cooperatives, London: I.B. Tauris.Das, Maumita, 1998,  Agrarian Change and Economic Development in Rural West Bengal, 

Unpublished M.Sc dissertation, Department of Economics with Rural Development, Vidyasagar University, West Bengal.

Dasgupta,   Biplab,   1995,   ‘Institutional   Reform   and   Poverty   Alleviation   in   West   Bengal’ Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 30, No. 41.

Dattaray, S., 1994a, `Agricultural Growth in West Bengal', Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 29, No. 29.

Dattaray, S., 1994b, `Growth of Agriculture in West Bengal', Economic and Political Weekly, Vol.29, No. 47.

Eswaran M. and A. Kotwal, 1989, ‘Credit and Agrarian Class Structure’, in Pranab Bardhan (ed.), The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions , Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Ghosh, Jayati 2006. ‘Being your own Boss’, www.macroscan.org, 18.12.2006.Government of India, 1993, Report of the Expert Group on the Estimation of Proportion and  

Number of the Poor. 1987­1988, Perspective Planning Division, Ministry of Planning.Guha, Ranajit, 1988, ‘On Some Aspects of the Historiography of Colonial

India’, in Selected Subaltern Studies, Ranajit Guha and Gayatri Chakravorty Spivak (eds.), New York: Oxford University Press.

Harriss-White, Barbara 2008. ‘Commercial Capital in West Bengal Agriculture’, Oxford: Delhi.

Hinton, William, 1968, Fanshen : A Documentary of Revolution in a Chinese Village, New York: Vintage Books.

Kautsky, Karl, 1988, The Agrarian Question, Vol.1, London, Zwan.Kay, C. 2008, ‘Reflectios on Rural Development and Development

Strategies: Exploring Synergies, Eradicating Poverty’, Innaurial Address as Professor in Development Studies and Rural Development delivered on 4 December at the Institute of Social Studies, The Hague, The Netherlands. http://www.iss.nl/layout/set/print/content/download/14008/133876/file/Inaugural%20Address%20Prof%20Kay.pdf

Lenin,  V.   I.,  1970,   ‘Two Tactics  of  Social  Democracy  in   the First  Russian Revolution’, Selected Works, Vol.1, Moscow, Progress Publishers. 

Lenin, V. I., 1977, The Development of Capitalism in Russia, Moscow: Progress Publishers. Lieten, G. K., 1990, ‘Depeasantisation Discontinued: Land Reforms in West

Bengal’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol.25, No. 40.

43

Page 44: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

Lipton, Michael, 1977, Why Poor People Stay Poor: A Study of Urban Bias in World Development, London: Temple Smith.

Mehta, Jaya (2005) ‘Agribusiness in India’, Alternative Economic Survey 2004­05. Murray,  W. E. (2006),  ‘Neo­feudalism in Latin America? Globalisation,  agribusiness and 

land   re­concentration   in   Chile,   Journal   of   Peasant   Studies,   Routledge,   Vol.33:4, pp.646­677.

Mukherjee, Badal and Mukhopadhyay, Swapna, 1995, ‘Impact of Institutional Change on Productivity in a Small-Farm Economy: Case of Rural West Bengal’, Economy and Political Weekly, Vol. 30, No. 34.

Narayanamoorthy,  A 2007.   ‘Deceleration   in  Agricultural  Growth:  Technology Fatigue  or Policy Fatigue?’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol.42, No.25, June 23­29.

Patnaik,  Utsa,  1972,   ‘Economics  of  Farm Size  and Farm Scale:  Some Assumptions  Re­examined’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 7, Nos.31­33.

Patnaik Utsa, 1976, ‘Class Differentiation Within the Peasantry: An Approach to the Analysis of Indian Agriculture’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 11, No. 39.

Patnaik, Utsa, 1979, ‘Neo-populism and Marxism: The Chayanovian View of the Agrarian Question and its Fundamental Fallacy’, Journal of Peasant Studies, Vol. 6, No.4.

Patnaik Utsa, 1987, Peasant Class Differentiation: A Study in Method with Reference to Haryana, Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Patnaik, Utsa, 1988, ‘Ascertaining the Economic Characteristics of Peasant Classes-in-Themselves in Rural India’ Journal of Peasant Studies, Vol. 15, No.3.

Patnaik, Utsa (ed.), 1990, Agrarian Relations and Accumulation –‘Mode of Production Debate’ in India, Bombay: Oxford University Press.

Rao, C. H. Hanumantha and Gulati, Ashok, 1994, ‘Indian Agriculture: Emerging Perspectives and Policy Issues’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 29, No. 53.

Reserve Bank of India, 1989, Report of the Committee on the Financial System (Chairman: M. Narasimham), Bombay: RBI.

Rogaly, Ben, et. al., 1995, ‘“Sonar Bangla?”: Agricultural Growth and the Change in West Bengal Bangladesh’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 30, No. 29.

Saha, Anamitra and Swaminathan, Madhura, 1994a, ‘Agricultural Growth in West Bengal in the 1980s: A Disaggregation by Districts and Groups’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 29, No. 13.

Saha, Anamitra and Swaminathan, Madhura, 1994b, ‘Agricultural Growth in West Bengal’ Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 29, No. 31.

Sen, Abhijit, and Ranja Sengupta, 1995, ‘The Recent Growth in Agricultural Output in Eastern India, with Special Reference to the Case of West Bengal’, Paper Presented at a Workshop on ‘Agricultural Growth and Agrarian Structure in Contemporary West Bengal and Bangladesh’, Calcutta, January.

Sen, Abhijit, 1996, `Economic Reforms, Employment and Poverty: Terms and Options’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol.31, Nos. 35-37.

44

Page 45: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

Sen, Amartya, 1966, ‘Peasants and Dualism with and without Surplus Labour’, Journal of Political Economy, Vol.74, No.???

Sen, P.K., and P.C. Sengupta, 1969, Agro­Economic Studies on Intensive Cultural Practices  in Small Holdings, Calcutta: University of Calcutta Press.

Sengupta, Sunil and Gazdar, Haris, 1997, ‘Agrarian Politics and Rural Development in West Bengal’,   in   Jean   Dreze   and   Amartya   Sen   (eds.),  Indian   Development:   Selected  Regional Perspectives, Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1987, ‘The Principal and Agent (ii)’ in John Eatwell et. al (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Volume 3, London: Macmillan

World Bank 2001, World Development Report 2000/2001, Washington, DC: World Bank.

APPENDIX 1PATNAIK’S E­CRITERION

The Marxist concept of class differentiation is simply stated: under a regime of commodity production,   rich  peasants   increasingly  employ  the  labour  of  others,   thereby appropriating surplus that contributes in turn to the accumulation process. The latter development is itself premised on the sale of labour­power by poor peasants who, required to work for others, are thereby   increasingly   subjected   to   exploitation.   The   self­employed   petty   commodity producers, the middle peasants of Lenin, are in a vulnerable position. While a few of them succeed in transforming themselves  into rich peasants,   the majority  are always under  the constant   threat  of   ‘depeasantization’,  or  being  pushed  down  into   the   ranks  of   the   semi­proletariat.  At the top end of  the rural class structure,  and more or less distinct  from the peasantry, stands the landlord, defined by ‘possession of substantial means of production and non­involvement  in any manual   labour,   living entirely by appropriating surplus labour of others’.   At   the  bottom  end   is   the   landless   labourer  who,   since  he   posses   no   means  of production, is obliged to live entirely by selling his labour­power. 

The   labour­exploitation   index   seeks   to   give   an   empirical   approximation   to   the analytical concept of the class status of the household. The latter is determined by the extent of the use of outside labour, or the degree to which the peasant family works for others, relative to self­employment on its own holdings. Under certain simplifying assumptions, the labour­exploitation index identifies the extent to which surplus labour is appropriated from the workers concerned.               E = X/Y = {(Hi­Ho) + (Lo­Li)}/F   where Hi = Labour­days hired on the operational holding of the household      Ho = Family labour days hired out to others

45

Page 46: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

      Li = Labour days worked on leased in land (whether by family or hired labour)      Lo = Labour days similarly worked on land leased out by the household      F = Labour days worked by household workers on the operational holding.

  In Patnaik’s [1988: 305] words: ‘The index is a ratio, or a pure number, which can have positive or negative values depending on whether the household is a net employer of outside labour or is itself on balance working for others (as labourer or tenant). The range of values of E is from plus infinity to minus infinity, for at the two poles of the rural class structure, there will be diametrically opposite types of households for whom F will be zero or near zero: first, the big landlords have such a large resource endowment that they perform no manual labour themselves, but rely entirely on employing others' labour; and the landless labourers, with zero resource endowment, hence zero self­employment, who are entirely dependent on working for others’.

Within the ranks of the peasantry, class is identified in the following terms: the degree to   which   work   is   done   for   oneself   (self­employment   on   holdings   owned/controlled)   in relation to that undertaken for others (employed on holdings owned/controlled by others) or, conversely, that undertaken by others for oneself (the employment of others on one’s own holdings). For this purpose, certain limits are set upon the values of the E­ratio, which are given in the following Table. All subsequent use of class categories in this paper refer to the definitions given in Table­A1, based on Patnaik [1976, 1987]. 

TABLE – A.1

The following limits are specified to the value of E in order to classify households into a set of mutually exclusive and all­exhaustive categories (sub­categories not specified here are not ruled out).

Class Category Defining Characteristics Value ofE = X/ F

Reason

1. Landless labourers No self­employment; working entirely for others

( E → − ∞ ) F = 0 X < 0 and large 

2. Poor peasants (te  Tenants and labourers 

with smallholdings)

Working for others exceeds self­employment

( E ≤ − 1)        

F > 0 , X < 0, X  ≥ F 

3. Small peasants No employment of or working for others; self­ ( 0 ≥ E > − 1 )

    F > 0 , 

46

Page 47: Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant ... · Neoliberalism, Weakening State and Peasant Differentiation in Indian Agriculture: Survey Findings on Panel Data from West Bengal

employment exceeds working for others 

X ≤ 0 , X  < F  

4. Middle peasants  Self­employment predominates, combined with the employment of a small amount of others’ labour

( 1 > E > 0 )  F > 0 , X > 0 , X < F

5. Rich peasants Self­employment equalled by the amount of labour­power purchased

( E ≥ 1 ) F > 0 , X > 0 , X ≥ F   

6. Landlords No manual labour expended in the form of self­employment; large amounts of outside labour employed

( E → ∞ )  F = 0 , X > 0, and large   

Source: Patnaik [1987].

47