32
NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS Poverty & Inequality Group Development Research Group The World Bank Poverty and Inequality Course Module 1: Multi-Topic Household Surveys 03/08/2013

NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

  • Upload
    justin

  • View
    40

  • Download
    1

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS. Poverty & Inequality Group Development Research Group The World Bank Poverty and Inequality Course Module 1: Multi-Topic Household Surveys 03/08/2013. Consumption/income. Traditional measure for poverty Consumption - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Citation preview

Page 1: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Poverty & Inequality GroupDevelopment Research Group

The World BankPoverty and Inequality Course

Module 1: Multi-Topic Household Surveys 03/08/2013

Page 2: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Consumption/income• Traditional measure for poverty– Consumption

• Detailed list of food and non-food consumption items• Diary or recall method

– Income• Detailed information on all source of income including

wage and non wage work, farm and non-farm work• Also includes remittances, rental income, and pensions

• Consumption is more commonly used to measure poverty headcount than income

• Full/Complete consumption used to measure– Poverty headcount– MDG #1 ($1/day)– Private consumption for National Accounts

Page 3: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

When you can’t or don’t need to collect complete consumption

• Consumption expenditure data is notorious for being difficult to collect in household surveys – often requiring a disproportionate amount of the total interview time

• Shorter consumption modules: cheaper and easier– Reduce time to complete the interview

• length of fieldwork• Respondent and interviewer burden/fatigue• “cost” to interviewers of questionnaires with lots of pages

• Shorter consumption modules can be used to – To rank households: identify poorer from richer

households or– To approximately identify “poor” households

Page 4: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Non-monetary indicators • There are other dimensions of poverty apart from

insufficient income or consumption

• Use of proxy indicators

• Correlates of consumption can be used to evaluate welfare status of households and rank poverty status– Assets– Health status– Education level– Access to public services– Housing conditions– Level of indebtedness– Unemployment

Page 5: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Outline• Partial consumption/Income• Asset Indices• Subjective wellbeing• Multidimensional poverty

Page 6: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

PARTIAL CONSUMPTION/INCOME

Page 7: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Partial Consumption/income• Shorter list of consumption items

Subset list of items from mean of 75 food items in LSMS (mean of 130 total consumption items)

Collapsed list of items into broader categories. Example: Susenas short form collapses over 100 items into 15 items

• Take top 10 food items with respect to share in total food expenditure.– A shorter food module, down to 1 page from several.

• But excluding rare or infrequently consumed items may not reduce interview time by much at the mean.– Tanzania

• 49 minutes for 7-day food recall, 58 food items• 41 minutes for 7-day food recall, 17 food items (subset)

Page 8: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

ASSET INDICES

Page 9: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Asset index• Can be used to characterize household economic

status in the absence of expenditure and income data• An aggregate index is constructed based on consumer

durable assets owned by household members, along with a set of housing characteristics– Note: this is not wealth in the formal sense of the value of household

assets owned minus liabilities. • Data used to construct asset indices are simple to collect and are

frequently available • Stata code

– factor var_1 var_2 var_3 predict new_var• It is better to choose assets with same unit. Be careful when mixing

different unit like counts and binary variables

Page 10: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

10

Asset index• The main proponents of this measure are Filmer and Pritchett

– Filmer and Pritchett overcome the lack of data on income and consumption expenditures in DHS surveys by constructing a proxy for long-run household wealth, using survey information on assets and using the statistical technique of principal components.

• Deon Filmer and Kinnon Scott. 2012.“Assessing Asset Indices” Demography 49 (1):359-92

• Compare these alternative approaches to welfare measurement– Overlap between “consumption” and “index” approaches– Implication for the analysis of welfare gradients– Correlates of the congruence between approaches

Page 11: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Overlap in the classification in the poorest quintilesReasonable, but not “perfect”, match between rankings:

Asset indices highly related to each other, less congruence with PCE

Per Capita HH expend

Predicted per capita HH expend.

PC index, all indicators

PC index, assets only IRT index Share weighted

average Count index PC value of durable goods

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Proportion of the population classified in the poorest 20 percent by per capita expenditure who are in the poorest 20 percent

according to other welfare indices

Albania 1 0.47 0.42 0.41 0.41 0.37 0.38 0.47

Brazil 1 0.68 0.64 0.62 0.63 0.57 0.63

Nicaragua 1 0.56 0.51 0.46 0.5 0.48 0.49 0.52

Uganda 1 0.52 0.48 0.43 0.51 0.47 0.48

Vietnam 1 0.54 0.49 0.5 0.47 0.49 0.48 0.49

Note: Blank entry indicates that data are not available . Cross country averages are weighted

Page 12: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

12

Asset index• Findings

– Reasonable, but not “perfect”, match between rankings– Inferences about inequalities in education, health care use,

fertility, child mortality, labor market outcomes are quite robust– Rankings are most similar in settings with small transitory

shocks to expenditure, or with little random measurement error in expenditure.

– In settings where private goods such as food are the main component of expenditures, asset indices and per capita consumption yield the least similar results.• Asset index may do well when we are not able to measure consumption

very well. For example in urban areas where we can have a lot of underreporting of consumption. In such instances, assets which are more observable could do better.

Page 13: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

SUBJECTIVE WELLBEING

Page 14: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Subjective Wellbeing (SWB)• SWB concerns peoples’ self-reported

assessment of their own well-being. – sometimes questions are asked about the

household from one individual. – Could be historical or refer “current” situation

• Three broad approaches have been identified when measuring subjective well-being;– Evaluative

• Cantril ladder– Experience – Eudemonic

Page 15: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Subjective Wellbeing (SWB)• SWB provides a wider focus than income/consumption

levels alone. • Could be directly related to poverty or less clearly

linked to poverty– Self-reported poverty (Are you poor on scale of 1-6)– Self-reported wellbeing (less clearly linked to the word "poor") for

example subjective reporting of health status, welfare, satisfaction of life, etc

• Subjective poverty line (SPL) (Pradhan and Ravallion 2000) – questions on the perceived adequacy of (food or total)

household consumption – SPL is ‘the level of total spending above which respondents say

(on average) that their expenditures are adequate for their needs’.

Page 16: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Subjective Wellbeing (SWB)• Example of SWB questions

– Overall, how satisfied are you with your life nowadays?– Do you feel poor?– Overall, how happy did you feel yesterday?– Minimum income question (MIQ): is a subjective survey

question designed to directly assess the delicate balance between what people earn and what they spend. The question reads, "Living where you do now, what is the smallest income you and your family would need (before any deductions) to make ends meet each month?“

– Cantril ladder: Rate your current life on a ladder scale for which 0 is ‘the worst possible life for you’ and 10 is ‘the best possible life for you’.

Page 17: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Subjective Wellbeing• SWB does not necessarily correlate with

increased standard of living

• The Easterlin paradox: Average happiness do not increase as countries grow wealthier

• Studies have found that in some rich countries, happiness has not grown along with living standards– Relative nature – Increase living standards temporary happiness

Page 18: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Subjective Wellbeing• How well do subjective wellbeing correlate

with the objective income measure?– Cojocaru and Diagne (2013) find weak

correlation between subjective relative income and household relative welfare position as measured by consumption or assets in Central Asia and Europe.

– Alem et al (2012) also find that while consumption poverty has declined in Ethiopia, subjective poverty remains largely unchanged

Page 19: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Subjective Wellbeing (SWB)• Problem of different scales across people - one

person’s standard of welfare may be different from another person’s standard– Married individuals– Single– Urban

• People may not be consistent overtime. (Kahneman 2010)– not explained by any material change– the response on Friday may be diff from Monday

Page 20: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Subjective Wellbeing• Responses can be affected by

– Wording of question– Context of question

• Some factors can affect perception– Previous poverty status can affect current perception – Relative economic standing – Being engaged in any kind of income-generating job

• Hypothetical vignettes: – Respondents score a set of vignettes describing different

scenarios related to the topic (such as poverty status) for a hypothetical person/household

– Vignettes can help reveal the respondents’ own scale

Page 21: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Subjective Wellbeing: Guatemela

Page 22: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Subjective Wellbeing: References• A. Deaton and A. Stone. 2013. “Two happiness puzzles”

Forthcoming, American Economic Review

• Alexandru Cojocaru , and Mame Fatou Diagne. 2013. “ How Reliable and Consistent Are Subjective Measures of Welfare in Europe and Central Asia? Evidence from the Second Life in Transition Survey” World Bank Working Paper

• Yonas Alem, Gunnar Köhlin and Jesper Stage. 2012. “ The Persistence of Subjective Poverty in Urban Ethiopia” Working paper in economics, University of Gothenburg

Page 23: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Subjective Wellbeing: References

• Beegle, Kathleen, Kristen Himelein and Martin Ravallion. 2012. “Frame-of-Reference Bias in Subjective Welfare Regressions.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 81:556-570.

• Daniel Kahneman1 and Angus Deaton (2010). “High income improves evaluation of life but not emotional well-being”

• King, G., C. J. L. Murray, J. A. Salomon, and A. Tandon. 2004. “Enhancing the Validity and Cross-Cultural Comparability of Measurement in Survey Research.” American Political Science Review, 98.1, pp. 191-207

Page 24: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Subjective Wellbeing: References• Pradhan, M. and Ravallion, M. (2000) “Measuring poverty using

qualitative perceptions of consumption adequacy,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(3), pp. 462–71.

• Daniel Kahneman and Alan B. Krueger (2006) “Developments in the measurement of subjective well-being” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 3-24

• Gero Carletto and Alberto Zezza (2006) “Being Poor, Feeling Poorer: Combining Objective and Subjective Measures of Welfare in Albania”

• King, G. and J. Wand. 2007. “Comparing Incomparable Survey Responses: Evaluating and Selecting Anchoring Vignettes.” Political Analysis, 15, pp. 46-66.

Page 25: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY

Page 26: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Multidimensional Poverty • Poverty is not just about income, it is made up of

several factors– Poor health– Limited access to education– Life expectancy– Lack of income– Inadequate living standard– Limited access to information and knowledge– Lack of empowerment

• A multidimensional measure of poverty can incorporate these different factors/indicators to capture the complexity of poverty and better inform policies to relieve it.

Page 27: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Multidimensional Poverty Index • Developed by James foster and Sabrina Akirie

– Under the Oxford Poverty & Human Development Initiative and the United Nations Development Program

– Newer version of the human development index (HDI)

• They use two forms of cutoffs to identify the poor– First- Traditional dimension-specific deprivation cutoff, which identifies

whether a person is deprived with respect to that dimension. – Second- Poverty cutoff which delineates how widely deprived a person

must be in order to be considered poor.

• The methodology allows for– Decomposability - Poverty identification for subgroups of the population– Allows identification of dimensional deprivations that contributes the most to

poverty for any given group

Page 28: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Multidimensional Poverty • Multidimensional poverty index (MPI)

– Uses 3 dimensions• Health: Nutrition and Child mortality• Education: Years of schooling and Schooling attendance• Living standards: Cooking fuel, Sanitation, Water, Electricity, Floor, Assets

• MPI reveals not only how many people are poor but also the composition of their individual poverty

• A person is multidimensionally poor if he or she is deprived in at least one third of weighted indicators

• Provides one number by which countries can be ranked using a simple tool– MPI = H * A– H: Percentage of people who are “multidimensionally” poor – A: Average intensity of MPI poverty across the poor (%)

Page 29: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Multidimensional Poverty • Limitation of multidimensional indices• Uses relative weights for each dimension, which are

generally chosen somewhat arbitrarily by the analyst.

• Ravallion (2011) suggests a “dashboard approach” with a set of “multiple indices” that measure various dimensions of poverty rather than a single ‘multidimensional index’”

• Ferreira and Lugo (2012) look at the pros and cons of the single index versus “dashboard approach”

Page 30: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

Multidimensional Poverty: References

• Sabina Alkire and James Foster (2011) “Counting and multidimensional poverty measurement”, Journal of Public Economics 95: 476–487)

• Francisco Ferreira and Maria Ana Lugo (2012) “Multidimensional poverty analysis: Looking for a middle ground” ECINEQ working papers

• Ravallion, Martin (2011): “On multidimensional indices of poverty”, Journal of Economic Inequality, 9 (2): 235-248.

Page 31: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

A few final thoughts• Other options for measuring poverty• When conducting smaller surveys: – It is good to have a handful of

comparable questions to a larger/national survey.

– It helps with external validity. – Allows survey to survey imputation

Page 32: NON-INCOME POVERTY IN HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS

THANK YOU