33
Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly * Anand Krishnamoorthy a , Ashutosh Prasad b , and Suresh P. Sethi b a College of Business Administration, University of Central Florida, Orlando, FL 32816-1400 b School of Management, The University of Texas at Dallas, Richardson, TX 75083-0688 European Journal of Operational Research, forthcoming February 2009 * Corresponding author. Address: College of Business Administration, University of Central Florida, 4000 Central Florida Blvd., Orlando, FL 32816-1400. Telephone: +1 407 823-1330; Fax: +1 407 823-3891; E-mail: [email protected].

Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

  • Upload
    ngocong

  • View
    216

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

Anand Krishnamoorthya, Ashutosh Prasadb, and Suresh P. Sethib a College of Business Administration, University of Central Florida, Orlando, FL 32816-1400

b School of Management, The University of Texas at Dallas, Richardson, TX 75083-0688

European Journal of Operational Research, forthcoming

February 2009

*Corresponding author. Address: College of Business Administration, University of Central Florida, 4000 Central Florida Blvd., Orlando, FL 32816-1400. Telephone: +1 407 823-1330; Fax: +1 407 823-3891; E-mail: [email protected].

Page 2: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

1

Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly

Abstract

This paper analyzes dynamic advertising and pricing policies in a durable-good duopoly. The

proposed infinite-horizon model, while general enough to capture dynamic price and advertising

interactions in a competitive setting, also permits closed-form solutions. We use differential

game theory to analyze two different demand specifications – linear demand and isoelastic

demand – for symmetric and asymmetric competitors. We find that the optimal price is constant

and does not vary with cumulative sales, while the optimal advertising is decreasing with

cumulative sales. Comparative statics for the results are presented.

Keywords: Control; Dynamic programming; Game theory; Marketing; Differential games

Page 3: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

2

1. Introduction

Decisions on advertising and pricing are inherently dynamic. Advertising effects are both

immediate and continue to persist after the advertisement is withdrawn, due to the memory of the

advertisement and the state dependence in buying behavior. Thus, the omission of consideration

of future effects results in under-advertising. Pricing dynamics are also quite common and

include skimming and penetration pricing, which are long-run strategies, and price promotions,

which are temporary changes in price. Furthermore, pricing and advertising can interact in their

dynamic effects. We consider these dynamic aspects in determining optimal pricing and

advertising decisions in this paper.

Well-known models of advertising effects on sales in the economics and management

literature include those by Vidale and Wolfe (1957), Nerlove and Arrow (1962), and Sethi

(1983). Some of these models were descriptive to begin with, but using optimal control theory, it

is possible to derive their profit-maximizing dynamic advertising policies. The models have also

been extended to competitive settings. Some papers that deal with dynamic advertising decisions

are Bass et al. (2005), Deal (1979), Erickson (1985, 2008), He et al. (2007, 2008), Naik et al.

(2008), Nair and Narasimhan (2006), Sethi (1973, 1983), Sorger (1989), and Wang and Wu

(2001). In contrast, far fewer models feature both price and advertising decisions, owing mainly

to the fact that introducing price competition in extant models of advertising competition renders

the analysis intractable. This paper specifically addresses this gap in the literature by presenting

and solving a dynamic duopoly model with inter-related pricing and advertising decisions.

The proposed model is a differential game extension of a recent model by Sethi et al.

(2008; SPH, hereafter) that examined advertising and price decisions by a monopolist firm in a

durable-good market. The SPH model’s dynamics is specified as

0( ) ( ) ( ( )) 1 ( ), (0) [0,1],x t u t D p t x t x xρ= − = ∈ (1)

where x(t) is the cumulative sales (as a fraction of market potential) at time t, D(p(t)), with

'( ( )) 0D p t < , captures the impact of price p(t) on the rate of change of cumulative sales, u(t) is

the advertising effort at time t, and ρ is the effectiveness of advertising. A useful feature of the

SPH model is that it permits closed-form solutions for both price and advertising, a feature that is

otherwise lacking in the literature and that we are able to partially retain in this competitive

extension. The square-root term 1 ( )x t− captures decreasing returns and market saturation

Page 4: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

3

similar to the Vidale-Wolfe (1957) formulation, and it also captures an element of word-of-

mouth interaction as noted by Sethi (1983) and Sorger (1989) in the following expansion for

small values of x:

1 (1 ) (1 )x x x x− ≈ − + − . (2)

The modeling of durable goods dynamics is important in economics and management

(e.g., Mansfield, 1961; Bass, 1969). A durable good is one that once purchased by the customer

does not need to be repurchased for a lengthy period of time. Examples are cars, televisions,

washing machines, and microwave ovens. In contrast, consumables and perishable goods, such

as grocery items, need to be repeatedly repurchased. The nature of durable goods means that the

market potential depletes with sales and therefore over time, and eventually, saturation is

reached. Thus, the dynamic decisions must also take into account that sales obtained in the

present are lost in the future.

Whereas the early durable goods models were descriptive in nature, it did not take long

for modelers to posit the effect of decision variables such as price and advertising on these

models and attempt to find normative guidelines. For example, the Bass (1969) model was

extended to include pricing decisions by Robinson and Lakhani (1975). A review of such models

is provided by Mahajan et al. (1990). A more recent study of optimal pricing policies for a

monopolist is the paper by Krishnan et al. (1999), based on the following proposed extension of

the Bass (1969) model:

( )( ) ( ( ))(1 ( ))(1 )( )

p tx t a bx t x tp t

β= + − − , (3)

where p(t) is the price at time t, ( )p t the change in price at time t, and a, b, and β are model

parameters. They find that either a monotonically-declining or an increasing-decreasing pricing

pattern is optimal.

It should be noted that these pricing prescriptions do not take into account the impact of

competition. With a few exceptions, the durable-goods diffusion models, such as the Bass (1969)

model, apply to category-level sales and do not account for within-category, brand-level

competition. In contrast, there are advertising models for perishable goods that emphasize market

share competition but in which the category sales remains constant over time because the market

does not deplete (e.g., Prasad and Sethi, 2004). In this paper, we make a contribution by

Page 5: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

4

providing optimal pricing and advertising policies in a durable good category in the presence of

competition.

Krishnan et al. (2000) propose a brand-level diffusion model to analyze the impact of a

late entrant on the diffusion of different brands of a new consumer durable and that of the

category as a whole. They argue that in categories where the primary question is “whether or not

to buy the category” rather than “whether or not to buy the brand,” potential adopters of a brand

should come from the remainder of the market (i.e., the unfulfilled market potential). Their

model is given by

( ) ( ( ))(1 ( ))i i ix t a b x t x t= + − , (4)

where ( )ix t is the adoption rate of brand i, ( ) ( )iix t x t=∑ is the cumulative adoption of the

category, and ai and bi are diffusion coefficients. Notice from equation (4) that the market pool

of potential adopters of brand i is 1 ( )x t− , i.e., the proportion of consumers who have not yet

bought any brand in the category, and not 1 ( )ix t− . The adoption rate depends on attracting these

remaining potential customers, similar to the Bass (1969) model and to the model we propose.

However, in our case, price and advertising also influence the adoption rate.

Teng and Thompson (1984) incorporate price and advertising in a new-product oligopoly

model but limit their analysis to the case of price leadership (i.e., there is only one price, that of

the largest firm) and resort to numerical analysis to show that the optimal price and advertising

patterns are high initially and then decrease over time. In contrast, under our specification, we

are able to solve the differential game explicitly and obtain that the price is constant and

advertising should decrease over time.

There also exist other dynamic models of pricing and advertising. In one of the earliest

models of price and advertising in a dynamic duopoly, Thepot (1983) uses Nerlove-Arrow-type

dynamics to obtain the open-loop pricing and advertising decisions under exogenous,

exponential demand growth. Gaugusch (1984) models a duopoly in which one firm chooses its

price and does not advertise, while the other chooses its advertising effort under a fixed price. He

finds that the first firm increases its price while the rival decreases its advertising rate. Dockner

and Feichtinger (1986) derive the optimal price and advertising decisions of firms operating in a

sticky-price oligopoly. For tractability, they analyze a duopoly and find that the optimal price

Page 6: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

5

and advertising should decrease over time if the actual demand is lower than that specified by the

dynamic sales equation.

Chintagunta et al. (1993) analyze a Nerlove-Arrow model of price and advertising in a

duopoly in which the total market expands exogenously over time. Using numerical analysis,

they find that in equilibrium, the advertising and pricing decisions follow the Dorfman-Steiner

rule. Mesak and Clark (1998) derive the optimal pricing and advertising policies for a new-

product monopolist and, as in Chintagunta et al. (1993), find that the advertising-sales and

advertising-price relationships are of Dorfman-Steiner-type.

It is worth noting that the aforementioned dynamic models of price and advertising are

not applicable to durable goods markets (i.e., markets in which the market potential depletes over

time). In this paper, we analyze a model of a durable-good duopoly, and are able to derive

explicit solutions for the optimal pricing and advertising policies.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section presents the model and the

related assumptions. Section 3 presents the analysis and the results for the case of linear demand.

Section 4 presents the analysis and the results for the case of isoelastic demand, and Section 5

presents a discussion of the results and managerial implications. Section 6 concludes with a

summary and directions for future research.

2. Model

We start by listing the notation in Table 1.

<Insert Table 1 about here>

Denote the cumulative sales of firm i, {1,2}i∈ , at time t by si(t). The rate of change of

cumulative units sold, which is the instantaneous sales, is denoted ( )is t , and is given by

( )( ) ( ) ( ( )) ( ) ( ),ii i i i i i j

ds ts t u t D p t T s t s tdt

ρ= = − − , {1,2}, i j i j∈ ≠ , (5)

where ( ) ( )i js t s t+ is the cumulative sales of the category at time t, T is the market potential,

subscript j refers to the rival firm, ui(t) denotes the advertising effort of firm i at time t, ρi is the

effectiveness of firm i’s advertising, and ( ( ))i iD p t is the demand function for firm i, specified as

a function of own price, pi(t), at time t. Thus, this is a competitive extension of the SPH model.

This model has the desirable property that the sales rate goes to zero as the market depletes.

Page 7: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

6

Consistent with the literature on durable-goods diffusion models, the potential adopters of firm i

come from the remainder of the market, i.e., from consumers who have not yet purchased from

the product category. As in the literature, the sales can be divided by the market potential T to

normalize it to 1.

Each firm chooses its advertising and price to maximize its discounted infinite-horizon

profit, given by

( )( ), ( )

0

max ( ) ( ) ( ( )) ,i

i i

r ti i i i iu t p t

J e p m s t C u t dt∞

−= − −∫ (6)

where ir is the discount rate of firm i, im is the marginal cost of production of firm i, and

( ( ))iC u t is the cost of firm i’s advertising.

Firm i’s total advertising expense is specified as

2( ( )) ( )2

ii i

cC u t u t= , (7)

where we refer to / 2ic as the unit cost of advertising, for convenience. This specification is

common in the literature, where the cost of advertising is assumed to be convex and, more

specifically, quadratic (e.g., Sethi, 1983; Sorger, 1989). It captures the diminishing returns to

advertising. Alternatively, one can use linear advertising costs and have advertising appear as a

square-root in the state equations.

The differential game between the two firms can therefore be summarized as follows:

1

1 1

2

2 2

211 1 1 1 1( ), ( )

0

222 2 2 2 2( ), ( )

0

max ( ) ( ) ( ) ,2

max ( ) ( ) ( ) ,2

r t

u t p t

r t

u t p t

cJ e p m s t u t dt

cJ e p m s t u t dt

∞−

∞−

= − −

= − −

∫ (8)

1 1 1 1 2 1 1

2 2 2 1 2 2 2

s.t. ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ( )),

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ( )).

s t u t T s t s t D p t

s t u t T s t s t D p t

ρ

ρ

= − −

= − − (9)

In this paper, we adopt the feedback solution concept for differential games. This better

reflects the competitive dynamics of the two rivals over time since feedback equilibria are

subgame perfect. In addition, several papers provide evidence that a feedback solution fits the

data better than its open-loop counterpart (e.g., Chintagunta and Vilcassim, 1992).

Page 8: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

7

Next, we perform a detailed analysis of the model. To obtain the optimal policies, we

solve the differential game given by (8-9) to obtain the feedback Nash equilibrium strategies. For

expositional convenience, we will suppress the time-dependence of the state and control

variables when no confusion arises.

The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation for firm i is

( ) ( )

( )

2

,

( ) ( ) ( )2

max ( ) ,i i

i ii i i i i j i i i i i i j i i

ii i u p i

j j i j j jj

c Vp m u T s s D p u u T s s D p

srV

Vu T s s D p

s

ρ ρ

ρ

∂ − − − − + − − ∂= ∂ + − − ∂

(10)

where ( , )i i i jV V s s= is the value function of firm i.

Writing the first-order conditions for pi and ui from the HJB equation in (10), we get

( ) ( )' '( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) 0,ii i i j i i i i i i i j i i i i i j i i

i

Vu T s s D p p m u T s s D p u T s s D p

sρ ρ ρ

∂− − + − − − + − − =

∂ (11)

( )( ) ( ) ( ) 0.ii i i i j i i i i i i j i i

i

Vp m T s s D p c u T s s D p

sρ ρ

∂− − − − + − − =

∂ (12)

We presently assume that the solutions are in the interior and later show that this is true.

To determine the optimal pricing and advertising strategies of the two firms, we need to

specify the demand function. We start with the linear demand specification.

3. Linear Demand Specification

We now consider the following linear demand specification:

( ( )) ( )i i i i iD p t p tα β= − , (13)

where αi is the demand intercept and βi represents price sensitivity. The linear demand function is

one of the most commonly used in the literature (e.g., Petruzzi and Dada, 1999).

Substituting (13) and simultaneously solving the two first-order conditions in (11-12)

yields the optimal price and advertising policies, denoted *( , )i i jp s s and *( , )i i ju s s , respectively,

which are given in Proposition 1.

Proposition 1: The optimal feedback pricing and advertising strategies of firm i are given by

* 1( , ) ,2

i ii i j i

i i

Vp s s m

sαβ

∂= + − ∂

(14)

Page 9: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

8

2

* ( , ) .4

i ii i j i i i i j

i i i

Vu s s m T s s

c sρ

α ββ ∂

= + − − − ∂ (15)

The sales trajectories corresponding to the equilibrium in (14-15) can be obtained by

substituting the optimal strategies in (14-15) and solving the two state equations in (9).

Substituting the optimal solutions from (14-15) into the HJB equation in (10) and simplifying

yields

( )34

2 2 22

1( , ) 432

.ji ii i j j j i i i i i i j j j j i j

i j ji j i i j

VV VV s s c m c m T s s

s s sc c rβ ρ α β β ρ α β

β β

∂ ∂ ∂ = + − + + − − − ∂ ∂ ∂

(16)

To prove that the pair of strategies in (14-15) forms a feedback equilibrium, we need to

show that there exist two continuously-differentiable functions ( , )i i jV s s , , {1,2}, i j i j∈ ≠ ,

which satisfy the partial differential equations in (16) and the boundary condition that

lim ( ( ), ( )) 0i i jtV s t s t

→∞= .

We propose the following form for the value function ( , )i i jV s s :

( , ) ( ) .i ii i j i i j i

i j

V VV s s k T s s ks s

∂ ∂= − − ⇒ = = −

∂ ∂ (17)

With this, and Proposition 1, we can conclude that the optimal advertising is decreasing

with cumulative category sales and, therefore, over time. Note that each firm’s advertising is

positive and increasing in the unfulfilled market potential. In other words, firms choose high

advertising levels not only if their cumulative brand sales are low, but also when the rival’s

cumulative brand sales are low. This is because a low cumulative sales level of either firm means

there is more of the unfulfilled market potential to tap into. We can also conclude, given the

linear value function and Proposition 1, that *( , ) 0i i jp s s > if the condition 0ii i

im k

αβ

+ + >

holds, which is clearly true since the value function should be positive. The optimal price is

independent of the cumulative sales level and thus constant over time.

To explore the solution fully, we need further insight into the constant ik , since it directly

affects the optimal decisions and the value function. Equating the coefficients of i jT s s− − in

(16), we have

Page 10: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

9

( ) ( )342 2 2

2

( ) 4 ( ), , {1, 2}, .

32j j i i i i i i i j i j j j j

ii j i i j

c k m c k k mk i j i j

c c r

β ρ α β β ρ α β

β β

− + − − += ∈ ≠ (18)

We first consider the case of symmetric firms.

3.1. Symmetric Firms

Equation (18) represents the system of simultaneous quartic equations that has to be solved to

obtain the Nash equilibrium of the differential game. For the case of symmetric firms, i.e.,

i jc c c= = , i jr r r= = , i jρ ρ ρ= = , i jm m m= = , i jα α α= = , and i jβ β β= = , a symmetric

solution will be obtained with i jk k k= = . Rewriting equation (18), we now have the following

quartic equation to solve for k: 2 3

2

( 5 ( ))( ( ))32

k m k mkcr

ρ α β α ββ

− + − += . (19)

Since the value function is positive, k > 0 on the left-hand side of equation (19). For the right-

hand side to be positive, we require either that k mαβ

> − or 5

k mαβ

< − . The former can be

ruled out because for demand to be non-negative, we require 0ipα β− ≥ , or /ip α β≤ .

Moreover, we know from the solution for price in (14) that * 1 ( )2ip m kα

β= + + .

Therefore, k mαβ

> − is infeasible.

Remark 1: The solution must also satisfy the boundary condition that lim ( ( ), ( )) 0i i jtV s t s t

→∞= . We

find that 5

k mαβ

< − satisfies this, whereas for k mαβ

> − , it is not satisfied.

With the solution for k, the optimal price and advertising solutions, ∀ i, can be rewritten as

* 1( , ) ( ),2i i jp s s m kα

β= + + (20)

( )2* ( , ) ( ) .4i i j i ju s s k m T s s

cρ α ββ

= − + − − (21)

Page 11: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

10

It is evident that the solution for the optimal price in (20) is a constant.

<Insert Table 2 about here>

The comparative statics for the parameters on the variables of interest are given in Table

2. Since we have assumed symmetry, *2u , *

2p , and 2V have the same comparative statics as *1u ,

*1p , and 1V , respectively.

Remark 2: For the comparative statics of k w.r.t. the model parameters, we have 0kc∂

<∂

,

0kr∂

<∂

, 0kρ∂

>∂

, 0km∂

<∂

, 0kα∂

>∂

, and 0kβ∂

<∂

.1

In summary, the comparative statics of k w.r.t. the model parameters are in the expected

directions (i.e., k decreases with the unit cost of advertising, the discount rate, the marginal cost

of production, and the price sensitivity of demand, and increases with the effectiveness of

advertising and the baseline demand). Since the value functions are directly proportional to k, the

comparative statics for k carry through to that for the value functions of the two symmetric firms.

Next, consider the comparative statics of price w.r.t. the model parameters.

Remark 3: For the comparative statics of p w.r.t. the model parameters, we have 0pc∂

<∂

,

0pr∂

<∂

, 0pρ∂

>∂

, 0pm∂

>∂

, 0pα∂

>∂

, and 0pβ∂

<∂

.

We find that, for every parameter except m, the comparative statics of price are the same

as those of k. For the marginal cost m, we find that the optimal price is increasing in m. These

signs are in the expected directions.

Finally, consider the comparative statics of advertising (taking s1 and s2 as given) w.r.t.

the model parameters.

1 All the proofs can be found in the Appendix.

Page 12: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

11

Remark 4: For the comparative statics of u w.r.t. the model parameters, we have 0uc∂

<∂

,

0ur∂

>∂

, 0uρ∂

>∂

, 0um∂

<∂

, 0uα∂

>∂

, and 0uβ∂

<∂

.

In other words, the optimal advertising intensity decreases with the unit cost of

advertising, the marginal cost of production, and the price sensitivity of demand, and increases

with the effectiveness of advertising and the baseline demand. One would expect that due to the

carryover effect of advertising, firms that value the future more would advertise at higher levels,

but, interestingly, we find that lower discount rates lead to lower levels of advertising.

We next turn our attention to the case of asymmetric competitors.

3.2. Asymmetric Firms

We now examine the duopolistic competition between asymmetric firms trying to maximize their

discounted profits in an infinite-horizon setting. To solve the differential game, one has to solve

the following set of simultaneous equations:

( )( ) ( )( )( )4 32 2 21 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 2 2 22

1 2 1 1 2

1 432

k c k m c k k mc c r

β ρ α β β ρ α ββ β

= − + − − + , (22)

( )( ) ( )( )( )4 32 2 22 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 1 12

1 2 2 1 2

1 432

k c k m c k k mc c r

β ρ α β β ρ α ββ β

= − + − − + .

(23)

Given the solutions for k1 and k2, we see that the optimal price and advertising levels are

indeed positive, as assumed previously. The optimal price and advertising policies can now be

rewritten as

* 1( , ) ( ),2

ii i j i i

ip s s m k

αβ

= + + (24)

( )( )2* ( , ) .4

ii i j i i i i i j

i iu s s k m T s s

α ββ

= − + − − (25)

We use Mathematica to numerically solve the system of quartic equations given by (22-

23) for a range of parameter values.

The comparative statics for the parameters on the variables of interest in the asymmetric

case are presented in Table 3.

<Insert Table 3 about here>

Page 13: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

12

From Table 3, one can see that ki is increasing in cj, mj, and βj, and decreasing in rj, ρj,

and αj. The results for the own parameters are similar to those in the symmetric case (i.e., ki is

decreasing in ci, ri, mi, and βi, and increasing in ρi and αi).

<Insert Figure 1 about here>

For the comparative statics of price w.r.t. the model parameters, we find that pi is

decreasing in ci, ri, and βi, and increasing in ρi, mi, and αi. This is consistent with our findings in

the symmetric case. For the cross parameters, we find that pi decreases with rj, ρj, and αj, and

increases with cj, mj, and βj (see Figure 1).

<Insert Figure 2 about here>

For the comparative statics of advertising (taking s1 and s2 as given) w.r.t. the model

parameters, we find that, consistent with our findings in the symmetric case, ui is decreasing in

ci, mi, and βi, and increasing in ri, ρi, and αi. For the cross parameters, we find that ui increases

with rj, ρj, and αj, and decreases with cj, mj, and βj (see Figure 2).

This concludes our study of the linear specification for the demand function ( ( ))i iD p t . In

the next section, we analyze a nonlinear specification.

4. Isoelastic Demand Specification

We now consider the isoelastic demand function:

( ( )) ( ) ii i iD p t p t η−= , (26)

so called because the elasticity of demand is iη , a constant. It is assumed that the demand is

elastic, i.e., 1iη > , so that the optimal price is finite.

Substituting (26) and simultaneously solving the two first-order conditions in (11-12)

yields the optimal price and advertising policies given in Proposition 2. We assume 0i

i

Vs

∂<

∂ so

that *( , ) 0i i jp s s > and later show this is indeed true.

Proposition 2: The optimal feedback pricing and advertising strategies of firm i are given by:

* ( , ) ,1

i ii i j i

i i

Vp s s m

η ∂

= − − ∂ (27)

Page 14: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

13

1

* ( , ) .1

i

i i ii i j i i j

i i i i

Vu s s m T s s

c s

ηρ ηη η

− + ∂

= − − − − ∂ (28)

In Proposition 2, note that, as with linear demand, each firm’s advertising is increasing in

the unfulfilled market potential. In other words, firms choose high advertising levels when there

is more of the unfulfilled market potential to tap into.

The sales trajectories corresponding to the equilibrium in (27-28) can be obtained by

substituting the optimal price and advertising decisions in (27-28) and solving the two state

equations in (9). Substituting the optimal solutions from (27-28) into the HJB equation in (10)

and simplifying, we have

( )( )

2 12222

2

2111( , )

2 1.

jij jii i i

j ji i ij j ji i i

i i j i ji j ji i

VVV V mm ms ss s

V s s T s sr cc

ηη ηη ρρηη

ηη

− +− ∂∂ ∂ ∂ − − − ∂ − ∂∂ − ∂ = + − − −

(29)

We try the following form for the value function ( , )i i jV s s :

( , ) ( ) .i ii i j i i j i

i j

V VV s s k T s s ks s

∂ ∂= − − ⇒ = = −

∂ ∂ (30)

Equating the coefficients of i jT s s− − in (29), we have

( ) ( )

( )

( )2 12

2 22

2

2111 , , {1, 2},

2 1.

jiji

j j j ji i i i iji

ii j ji i

k k mm k k mk i j i j

r cc

ηη ηη ρρηη

ηη

− +− + + + −− = − ∈ ≠ −

(31)

As before, the analysis of this equation is discussed for symmetric and asymmetric firms.

We first consider the case of symmetric firms.

4.1. Symmetric Firms

Equation (31) represents the system of simultaneous equations that need to be solved to obtain

the Nash equilibrium of the differential game. For symmetric firms, i jc c c= = , i jr r r= = ,

i jρ ρ ρ= = , i jm m m= = , i jη η η= = , and i jk k k= = . Equation (31) now becomes

Page 15: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

14

( )

( )

22

2

( )( ) (3 2 )1

2 1

m km k m kk

cr

ηηρ ηη

η

− +

+ + − − =−

. (32)

Given the solution for k, the optimal price and advertising solutions can be rewritten as

* ( )( , ) ,1i i j

m kp s s ηη

+=

− (33)

1* ( )( , ) .

1i i j i jm ku s s T s s

c

ηηρ

η η

− + +

= − − − (34)

We use Mathematica to numerically solve equation (32) for k.

As before, the solution for the optimal advertising is decreasing with cumulative sales

and the optimal price is a constant.

Finally, we consider the case of asymmetric firms.

4.2. Asymmetric Firms

To solve the differential game for asymmetric firms, one needs to solve the following set of

simultaneous equations:

( ) ( )

( )

( )1 22 2 12 1 1 1 2 2 22 2

1 1 1 2 11 2

1 21 2 21 1

21 11 0,

2 1

m k m km k k

kr cc

η ηη η

ρ ρη η

ηη

− − + + + + − − − − =

(35)

( ) ( )

( )

( )2 12 2 12 2 2 2 1 1 12 2

2 2 2 1 22 1

2 22 1 12 2

21 11 0.

2 1

m k m km k k

kr cc

η ηη η

ρ ρη η

ηη

− − + + + + − − − − =

(36)

The solutions are complicated, and numerical analysis is used to obtain the set of

positive-real roots that satisfy the system of equations in (35-36). Given the solutions for k1 and

k2, the optimal price and advertising solutions can be rewritten as

( )* ( , ) ,1

ii i j i i

i

p s s m kη

η

= + − (37)

Page 16: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

15

( )1

* ( , ) .1

i

i ii i j i i i j

i i i

u s s m k T s sc

ηρ ηη η

− +

= + − − − (38)

The comparative statics for the parameters on the variables of interest in the asymmetric

case are presented in Table 4.

<Insert Table 4 about here>

From Table 4, one can see that ki is decreasing in ci, ri, mi, and ηi, and increasing in ρi.

For the cross parameters, we find that ki decreases with rj, ρj, and ηj, and increases with cj and mj.

Since the value function of firm i is directly proportional to ki, the comparative statics for ki carry

through to that for the value functions of the respective firms.

<Insert Figure 3 about here>

The comparative statics of price w.r.t. the model parameters are presented in Figure 3.

We find that pi is decreasing in ci, ri, and ηi, and increasing in ρi and mi. For the cross parameters,

pi decreases with rj, ρj, and ηj, and increases with cj and mj.

<Insert Figure 4 about here>

Figure 4 presents the comparative statics of advertising (taking s1 and s2 as given) w.r.t.

the model parameters. We find that ui is decreasing in ci, mi, and ηi, and increasing in ri and ρi.

For the cross parameters, we find that ui increases with rj, ρj, and ηj, and decreases with cj and mj.

In summary, the comparative statics on the common parameters (i.e., ci, cj, ri, rj, ρi, ρj, mi,

and mj) are in the same direction in both the linear and the isoleastic demand specifications,

suggesting that the results are robust across different demand specifications.

5. Discussion

Proposition 1 deals with the linear demand specification and it provides the expressions for the

optimal price and the optimal advertising. It finds that the optimal price is constant and that the

optimal advertising decreases with cumulative sales. We now discuss the relevance of these

results.

The result that the optimal price is constant may be implied by sales dynamics models,

e.g., Bass (1969), that do not model price as a control variable but still fit sales data well;

possible explanations for this are that price is constant or correlated with time (see Bass et al.,

1994). Bayus (1992) estimates the empirical price trends of three consumer durables – console

Page 17: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

16

TVs, CD players, and telephones – and finds that their prices have declined over time. However,

price time series in durables goods is complicated by technology and cost factors. For example,

Dolan and Simon (1996, p. 293) describe price trends for personal computers from 1987 to 1992,

showing it remained flat in the education segment, declined in the home and business segments,

and increased in the scientific segment. The price declines were attributed to cost decreases and

intense competition and the price increases to added technological value.

Proposition 1 also states that the optimal advertising level decreases with cumulative

category sales. This is because a high cumulative sales level of either firm means there is less of

the unfulfilled market potential to tap into. This result is consistent with the observation that

firms begin to drastically reduce their advertising efforts in the decline stage of the product life

cycle (Ferrell and Hartline, 2008, p. 286).

Comparing the results in the linear-demand case in Tables 2 and 3, one can see that the

comparative statics results for the own-parameters in the asymmetric case are the same as those

in the symmetric case, i.e., (a) the value-function coefficient of a firm is decreasing in its unit

cost of advertising, discount rate, marginal cost of production, and price sensitivity, and

increasing in its advertising effectiveness and demand intercept, (b) the optimal price of a firm is

decreasing in its unit cost of advertising, discount rate, and price sensitivity, and increasing in its

advertising effectiveness, marginal cost of production, and demand intercept, and (c) the optimal

advertising level (taking sales as given) of a firm is decreasing in its unit cost of advertising,

marginal cost of production, and price sensitivity, and increasing in its discount rate, advertising

effectiveness, and demand intercept.

For the cross parameters, we find that (a) the value-function coefficient of a firm is

decreasing in the rival firm’s discount rate, advertising effectiveness, and demand intercept, and

increasing in the rival’s unit cost of advertising, marginal cost of production, and price

sensitivity, (b) the optimal price of a firm is decreasing in the rival firm’s discount rate,

advertising effectiveness, and demand intercept, and increasing in the rival’s unit cost of

advertising, marginal cost of production, and price sensitivity, and (c) the optimal advertising

level (taking sales as given) of a firm is decreasing in the rival firm’s unit cost of advertising,

marginal cost of production, and price sensitivity, and increasing in the rival’s discount rate,

advertising effectiveness, and demand intercept.

Page 18: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

17

Whereas Proposition 1 deals with a linear demand function, Proposition 2 examines an

isoelastic demand function. The optimal price and advertising paths, however, are not

qualitatively affected. Therefore, the empirical support needed for Propositions 1 and 2 is

identical.

Qualitatively, Propositions 1 and 2 state the same thing – that the optimal price is a

constant and that the optimal advertising declines as the market potential depletes. This is a good

thing because it suggests that the results are at least somewhat robust to specification changes. A

remaining practical issue for the firm is how to estimate the parameters of the model and decide

which specification to use. Although we do not examine econometric issues here, a few points

are in order. As Chintagunta and Jain (1995) point out, when firms make their decisions

strategically, the levels of marketing mix variables like price and advertising are endogenously

determined, i.e., the first-order conditions for Nash equilibria in price and advertising are

functions of the state variable (market share or, as in our case, sales). As a result, the estimation

of the model parameters should specify a system of simultaneous equations that consists of both

the response functions and the equilibrium conditions. Ignoring this endogeneity problem will

lead to inconsistent parameter estimates and, therefore, incorrect decision-making by managers.

More recently, researchers have begun using Kalman filter to estimate the parameters of dynamic

response models (e.g., Naik et al., 1998). Since the state equation in our model is nonlinear in

sales, one has to use extended Kalman filter to estimate the model parameters (see Naik et al.,

2008).

Looking at the results in Table 4, one can see the following comparative statics results for

the own-parameters in the isoelastic case: (a) The value-function coefficient of a firm is

decreasing in its unit cost of advertising, discount rate, marginal cost of production, and price

elasticity, and increasing in its advertising effectiveness, (b) the optimal price of a firm is

decreasing in its unit cost of advertising, discount rate, and price elasticity, and increasing in its

advertising effectiveness and marginal cost of production, and (c) the optimal advertising level

(taking sales as given) of a firm is decreasing in its unit cost of advertising, marginal cost of

production, and price elasticity, and increasing in its discount rate and advertising effectiveness.

For the cross parameters, we find that (a) the value-function coefficient of a firm is

decreasing in the rival firm’s discount rate, advertising effectiveness, and price elasticity, and

increasing in the rival’s unit cost of advertising and marginal cost of production, (b) the optimal

Page 19: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

18

price of a firm is decreasing in the rival firm’s discount rate, advertising effectiveness, and price

elasticity, and increasing in the rival’s unit cost of advertising and marginal cost of production,

and (c) the optimal advertising level (taking sales as given) of a firm is decreasing in the rival

firm’s unit cost of advertising and marginal cost of production, and increasing in the rival’s

discount rate, advertising effectiveness, and price elasticity.

Comparing the results in the linear and the isoelastic demand cases, we see that the

comparative statics on the common parameters (unit cost of advertising, discount rate,

advertising effectiveness, and marginal cost of production) are in the same direction in both

demand specifications, suggesting that the results are robust across the two demand

specifications.

In the literature review, we discussed how our results compare with those of extant

dynamic models of price and advertising, with and without competition. Consider, for example,

the monopoly model of Sethi et al. (2008). Consistent with that model, we find that in the case of

linear demand, the value-function coefficient and the optimal price decrease with the discount

rate and the price sensitivity of demand, and increase with the effectiveness of advertising. The

optimal advertising intensity increases with the discount rate and the effectiveness of advertising,

and decreases with the price sensitivity of demand. In addition to the three parameters, we also

derive the comparative statics for two additional parameters (the marginal cost of advertising and

the baseline demand) that are not in the SPH model. While the SPH model considers the case of

a monopolist, our analysis also presents the comparative statics with respect to the competitor’s

parameters.

The comparative statics result that the optimal advertising *( , )i i ju s s is increasing in the

discount rate r is not obvious. In fact, some nondurable-goods models of advertising dynamics

suggest that the optimal advertising should decrease if the discount rate increases (e.g., Bass et

al., 2005). To understand the intuition behind our result, we first note that advertising has two

effects: it increases the current sales and it also affects future sales via the state variable. The

latter is sometimes called the carryover effect of advertising. In a nondurable-goods model, the

carryover effect is positive, i.e., both current and future sales increase with advertising. By

definition, as the discount rate increases, the contribution of future sales to the firm’s objective

decreases. Thus, the effectiveness of advertising is reduced because the carryover effect has

Page 20: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

19

become less important. This leads to the conclusion in the literature that advertising should

decrease when the discount rate increases.

In contrast, in a durable-goods model, the size of the market is fixed. Thus, if the current

sales increases, the future sales must decrease. Another way to state the two effects of

advertising for the durable goods case is that advertising leaves the total sales unaffected but it

increases the allocation of sales to the near term versus the future. When the discount rate

increases, it is profitable to have a greater allocation of sales to the near term. Therefore, the

optimal advertising is increasing in the discount rate. This intuition has not been pointed out in

previous studies.

Next, we discuss the practical meaning of the value-function coefficient ki. The value

function for firm i at time t, denoted ( ( ), ( ))i i jV s t s t , is the value of its total net discounted future

profit stream, assuming that each firm makes optimal decisions starting from the sales

( ( ), ( ))i js t s t at time t . We know from the optimal control theory that ( , )i i j

i

V s ss

∂, evaluated at

the optimal ( ( ), ( ))i js t s t , is called the shadow price at time t, and it is the marginal improvement

of the value function if a small increase is applied to the starting sales for firm i at time t (Sethi

and Thompson, 2000, p. 35). In our case, ii

i

Vk

s∂

= −∂

is the shadow price and it is constant and

negative. It is negative because in a durable goods setting, due to a fixed sales potential, an

increase of the initial sales level reduces the potential for further earnings due to market

saturation.

Since each firm’s profit in the symmetric case (for given si and sj) is directly proportional

to k, the two firms would want k to be as high as possible. The analysis shows that k is increasing

in ρ and α and decreasing in c and r. Therefore, one of the ways for firms to increase their profit

would be to increase the effectiveness of their advertising, i.e., increase ρ. To increase the

effectiveness of advertising, firms could create more alternative advertisements and use pre-

testing to select the best ad copy (Gross, 1972).

In our analysis, we also noted the impact of the value-function coefficient, k, on the

optimal pricing and advertising decisions and profit of the firm. Our analysis can, therefore, help

managers determine the profit-maximizing levels of advertising and price. Once k is determined,

Page 21: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

20

the application of the formulae to practice is straightforward. The approximate value of k can be

obtained offline, and the moment-to-moment decisions can be made using the value of k from the

paper.

We acknowledge that the predictions of the model are subject to the model’s

specification. In particular, we assume that the interaction between price and advertising is

multiplicative. Future research could investigate how our results change when the interaction

between price and advertising is more complicated than that specified in this paper. One could

also formulate a Stackelberg game to examine how the results change when there is sequential

entry instead of simultaneous entry (e.g., see Fruchter and Messinger, 2003). It would also be

interesting to extend the current model to study price and advertising competition in a three-or-

more-firm oligopoly along the lines of Fruchter (1999) and Naik et al. (2008), and the impact of

uncertainty on the optimal price and advertising decisions, as in Prasad and Sethi (2004).

6. Conclusions

This paper analyzes a model of advertising and price competition in a dynamic durable-good

duopoly. The previous literature on optimal price and advertising decisions in this setting is very

limited. Theoretically, we extend a recent monopoly model by Sethi et al. (2008), which

incorporates important elements such as advertising and price interaction, market saturation, and

feedback solutions, by including competition and without losing the advantage of analytical

tractability. Using differential game theory, we obtain the optimal advertising and pricing

decisions for two different demand specifications and present the comparative statics for

symmetric and asymmetric competitors. An important feature of the proposed model is that,

while it is realistic enough to capture price and advertising in a competitive setting, it allows for

explicit feedback solutions.

The analysis reveals that the optimal advertising effort should decrease over time as more

of the market potential is captured, and that the optimal price is stationary. Normative results

based on the analysis of the model for symmetric and asymmetric competitors suggest that when

the demand is linear in price, each firm’s optimal price and profit should increase with its

advertising effectiveness and base demand, and decrease with its unit cost of advertising,

discount rate, and price sensitivity. These should also increase with the rival’s unit cost of

advertising, marginal cost of production, and price sensitivity, and decrease with the rival’s

Page 22: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

21

discount rate, the effectiveness of the competitor’s advertising, and its base demand.

Interestingly, the optimal advertising effort moves in the same direction for both competitors

(i.e., decreases with the unit cost of advertising, marginal cost of production, and price

sensitivity, and increases with the discount rate, advertising effectiveness, and base demand).

For isoelastic demand, we find that each firm’s optimal price and profit should increase

with its advertising effectiveness, and decrease with its unit cost of advertising and discount rate.

These should also decrease with the rival’s discount rate, advertising effectiveness, and price

elasticity, and increase with the rival’s unit cost of advertising and marginal cost of production.

As with linear demand, the optimal advertising effort moves in the same direction for both

competitors (i.e., decreases with the unit cost of advertising and marginal cost of production, and

increases with the discount rate and advertising effectiveness).

The current study leaves open avenues for future research. A promising avenue for future

research would be to study how the results change when there is sequential entry instead of

simultaneous entry. Such models would be formulated as Stackelberg games (e.g., see Fruchter

and Messinger, 2003; He et al., 2007; He et al., 2008; He et al., 2009). Specifically, one could

obtain and analyze feedback Stackelberg equilibria in a vertical supply chain dealing with

durable goods along the lines of He et al. (2009), which considers non-durables. Another fruitful

extension is to study price and advertising competition in an oligopoly along the lines of Fruchter

(1999) and Naik et al. (2008). Although duopoly models are representative of many real-world

markets, modeling markets characterized by three or more firms might yield additional insights.

Page 23: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

22

Appendix

Proof of Remark 2

Denote equation (19) as 2 3

2

( (5 ))( ( ))(., ) 032

k m k mf k kcr

ρ α β α ββ

− + − += − = . The implicit

function theorem yields, for any parameter χ, //

k ff k

χχ∂ ∂ ∂

= −∂ ∂ ∂

. We have

( )2 3

2 2

( (5 ))( ( )) 04 8 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))

k k m k mc c cr k m k m

ρ α β α ββ β ρ α β α β

∂ − + − += − <

∂ + − + − +,

( )2 3

2 2

( (5 ))( ( )) 04 8 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))

k k m k mr r cr k m k m

ρ α β α ββ β ρ α β α β

∂ − + − += − <

∂ + − + − +,

( )3

2 2

( (5 ))( ( )) 02 8 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))

k k m k mcr k m k m

ρ α β α βρ β β ρ α β α β∂ − + − +

= >∂ + − + − +

,

2 2

2 2

( (4 ))( ( )) 08 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))

k k m k mm cr k m k m

ρ α β α ββ ρ α β α β

∂ − + − += − <

∂ + − + − +,

( )2 2

2 2

( (4 ))( ( )) 08 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))

k k m k mcr k m k m

ρ α β α βα β β ρ α β α β∂ − + − +

= >∂ + − + − +

, and

( )( )

2 2 2 2

2 2 2

2 ( )(5 ) ( ( ))

2 8 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))

k k m k m k mkcr k m k m

ρ α αβ β α β

β β β ρ α β α β

− − + + − +∂= −

∂ + − + − +. Note that

2 22 ( )(5 )k k m k mα αβ β− − + + can be written as 2( (5 ))( (3 )) 2 (5 )k m k m k k mα β α β β− + + + + + ,

which is positive since 5

k mαβ

< − . Therefore, 0kβ∂

<∂

.

Proof of Remark 3

For the comparative statics of price, note from (20) that for any parameter χ, except for m, the

sign of /p χ∂ ∂ is the same as that of /k χ∂ ∂ . Therefore, we have 0pc∂

<∂

, 0pr∂

<∂

, 0pρ∂

>∂

,

0pα∂

>∂

, and 0pβ∂

<∂

. For m, we have

Page 24: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

23

2 3

2 2

1 8 ( ( ))(1 ) 02 2(8 (2 (5 2 ))( ( )) )

p k cr k mm m cr k m k m

β ρ α ββ ρ α β α β

∂ ∂ + − += + = >

∂ ∂ + − + − +.

Proof of Remark 4

From (21), we have

( )( )

2 2 21 2

2 2 2

16 (3 (5 3 ))( ( )) ( ( ))0

8 8 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))

cr k m k m k m T s suc c cr k m k m

ρ β ρ α β α β α β

β β ρ α β α β

+ − + − + − + − −∂= − <

∂ + − + − +,

( )3 4

1 22 2

( (5 ))( ( ))0

8 8 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))k m k m T s su

r cr cr k m k mρ α β α ββ β ρ α β α β

− + − + − −∂= >

∂ + − + − +,

( )( )

2 2 21 2

2 2

8 ( )( ( )) ( ( ))0

4 8 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))

cr m k m k m T s suc cr k m k m

β ρ α β α β α β

ρ β β ρ α β α β

+ − − + − + − −∂= >

∂ + − + − +,

( )( )

2 31 2

2 2

( ( )) 8 ( ( ))0

2 8 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))

k m cr k m T s sum c cr k m k m

ρ α β β ρ α β

β ρ α β α β

− + + − + − −∂= − <

∂ + − + − +,

( )( )

2 31 2

2 2

( ( )) 8 ( ( ))0

2 8 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))

k m cr k m T s suc cr k m k m

ρ α β β ρ α β

α β β ρ α β α β

− + + − + − −∂= >

∂ + − + − +, and

( )( )

2 31 2

2 2 2

( ( )) 8 ( ( )) ( )( ( ))0

4 8 (2 (5 2 ))( ( ))

k m cr k m m k m T s suc cr k m k m

ρ α β β α β ρ α β α β

β β β ρ α β α β

− + + + + + − + − −∂= − <

∂ + − + − +.

Page 25: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

24

References

Bass, Frank M., 1969. A new product growth model for consumer durables. Management Science 15 (5), 215-227.

Bass, Frank M., Krishnan, Trichy V., Jain, Dipak C., 1994. Why the Bass model fits without decision variables. Marketing Science 13 (3), 203-223.

Bass, Frank M., Krishnamoorthy, Anand, Prasad, Ashutosh, Sethi, Suresh P., 2005. Generic and brand advertising strategies in a dynamic duopoly. Marketing Science 24 (4), 556-568.

Bayus, Barry L., 1992. The dynamic pricing of next generation consumer durables. Marketing Science 11 (3), 251-265.

Chintagunta, Pradeep K., Vilcassim, Naufel J., 1992. An empirical investigation of advertising strategies in a dynamic duopoly. Management Science 38 (9), 1230-1244.

Chintagunta, Pradeep K., Rao, Vithala R., Vilcassim, Naufel J., 1993. Equilibrium pricing and advertising strategies for nondurable experience products in a dynamic duopoly. Managerial and Decision Economics 14 (3), 221-234.

Chintagunta, Pradeep K., Jain, Dipak C., 1995. Empirical analysis of a dynamic duopoly model of competition. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 4 (1), 109-131.

Deal, Kenneth R., 1979. Optimizing advertising expenditures in a dynamic duopoly. Operations Research 27 (4), 682-692.

Dockner, Engelbert J., Feichtinger, Gustav, 1986. Dynamic advertising and pricing in an oligopoly: A Nash equilibrium approach. In: Başar, Tamer, Editor, 1986. Proceedings of the 7th conference on economic dynamics and control, Springer, Berlin, 238-251.

Dolan, Robert J., Simon, Hermann, 1996. Power Pricing: How Managing Price Transforms the Bottom Line. Free Press, New York.

Erickson, Gary M., 1985. A model of advertising competition. Journal of Marketing Research 22 (3), 297-304.

Erickson, Gary M., 2008. An oligopoly model of dynamic advertising competition. European Journal of Operational Research, doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2008.06.023.

Ferrell, O. C., Hartline, Michael D., 2008. Marketing Strategy. fourth ed. Thomson South-Western, Mason.

Fruchter, Gila E., 1999. Oligopoly advertising strategies with market expansion. Optimal Control Applications and Methods 20 (44), 199-211.

Page 26: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

25

Fruchter, Gila E., Messinger, Paul R., 2003. Optimal management of fringe entry over time. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 28 (3), 445-466.

Gaugusch, Julius, 1984. The non-co-operative solution of a differential game: Advertising versus pricing. Optimal Control Applications and Methods 5 (4), 353-360.

Gross, Irwin, 1972. The creative aspects of advertising. Sloan Management Review 14 (1), 83-109.

He, Xiuli, Prasad, Ashutosh, Sethi, Suresh P., Gutierrez, Genaro, 2007. A survey of Stackelberg differential game models in supply and marketing channels. Journal of Systems Science and Systems Engineering 16 (4), 385-413.

He, Xiuli, Prasad, Ashutosh, Sethi, Suresh P., Gutierrez, Genaro, 2008. A survey of Stackelberg differential game models in supply and marketing channels: An erratum. Journal of Systems Science and Systems Engineering 17 (2), 255.

He, Xiuli, Prasad, Ashutosh, Sethi, Suresh P., 2009. Cooperative advertising and pricing in a stochastic supply chain: Feedback Stackelberg strategies. Production and Operations Management, doi: 10.3401/poms.1080.01006.

Krishnan, Trichy V., Bass, Frank M., Jain, Dipak C., 1999. Optimal pricing strategy for new products. Management Science 45 (12), 1650-1663.

Krishnan, Trichy V., Bass, Frank M., Kumar, V., 2000. Impact of a late entrant on the diffusion of a new product/service. Journal of Marketing Research 37 (2), 269-278.

Mahajan, Vijay, Muller, Eitan, Bass, Frank M., 1990. New product diffusion models in marketing: A review and directions for research. Journal of Marketing 54 (1), 1-26.

Mansfield, Edwin, 1961. Technical change and the rate of imitation. Econometrica 29 (4), 741-766.

Mesak, Hani I., Clark, James, W., 1998. Monopolist optimum pricing and advertising policies for diffusion models of new product innovations. Optimal Control Applications and Methods 19 (2), 111-136.

Naik, Prasad A., Mantrala, Murali K., Sawyer, Alan G., 1998. Planning media schedules in the presence of dynamic advertising quality. Marketing Science 17 (3), 214-235.

Naik, Prasad A., Prasad, Ashutosh, Sethi, Suresh P., 2008. Building brand awareness in dynamic oligopoly markets. Management Science 54 (1), 129-138.

Page 27: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

26

Nair, Anand, Narasimhan, Ram, 2006. Dynamics of competing with quality- and advertising-based goodwill. European Journal of Operational Research 175 (1), 462-474.

Nerlove, Marc, Arrow, Kenneth, 1962. Optimal advertising policy under dynamic conditions. Economica 29 (114), 129-142.

Petruzzi, Nicholas, Dada, Maqbool, 1999. Pricing and the Newsvendor problem: A review with extensions. Operations Research 47 (2), 183-194.

Prasad, Ashutosh, Sethi, Suresh P., 2004. Competitive advertising under uncertainty: A stochastic differential game approach. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 123 (1), 163-185.

Robinson, Bruce, Lakhani, Chet, 1975. Dynamic price models for new-product planning. Management Science 21 (12), 1113-1122.

Sethi, Suresh P., 1973. Optimal control of the Vidale-Wolfe advertising model. Operations Research 21 (4), 998-1013.

Sethi, Suresh P., 1983. Deterministic and stochastic optimization of a dynamic advertising model. Optimal Control Applications and Methods 4 (2), 179-184.

Sethi, Suresh P., Thompson, Gerald L., 2000. Optimal Control Theory: Applications to Management Science and Economics. Springer, New York.

Sethi, Suresh P., Prasad, Ashutosh, He, Xiuli, 2008. Optimal advertising and pricing in a new-product adoption model. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 139 (2), 351-360.

Sorger, Gerhard, 1989. Competitive dynamic advertising: A modification of the Case game. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 13 (1), 55-80.

Teng, Jinn-Tsair, Thompson, Gerald L., 1984. Optimal pricing and advertising policies for new product oligopoly models. Marketing Science 3 (2), 148-168.

Thepot, Jacques, 1983. Marketing and investment policies of duopolists in a growing industry. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 5 (3), 387-404.

Vidale, M. L., Wolfe, H. B., 1957. An operations research study of sales response to advertising. Operations Research 5 (3), 370-381.

Wang, Qinan, Wu, Zhang, 2001. A duopolistic model of dynamic competitive advertising. European Journal of Operational Research 128 (1), 213-226.

Page 28: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

27

Table 1: Notation

( )is t Cumulative sales of firm i at time t

T Market potential

( )iu t Advertising effort of firm i at time t

( )ip t Price of firm i at time t

ic Coefficient associated with the advertising cost of firm i

iρ Effectiveness of advertising of firm i

im Marginal cost of production of firm i

iα Demand intercept of firm i (linear demand)

iβ Price sensitivity of firm i (linear demand)

iη Price elasticity of firm i (isoelastic demand)

ir Discount rate of firm i

( , )i i jV s s Value function of firm i when its cumulative sales is is and its rival’s is js

Table 2: Comparative statics for the symmetric case with linear demand

Variables c r ρ m α β k ↓ ↓ ↑ ↓ ↑ ↓

*ip ↓ ↓ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↓ *iu ↓ ↑ ↑ ↓ ↑ ↓

iV ↓ ↓ ↑ ↓ ↑ ↓

Legend: ↑ increase; ↓ decrease.

Page 29: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

28

Table 3: Comparative statics for the asymmetric case with linear demand

Variables ic jc ir jr iρ jρ im jm iα jα iβ jβ

ik ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ *ip ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ ↓ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ *iu ↓ ↓ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ ↑ ↓ ↓

iV ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑

Legend: ↑ increase; ↓ decrease.

Table 4: Comparative statics for the asymmetric case with isoelastic demand

Variables ic jc ir jr iρ jρ im jm iη jη

ik ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓ *ip ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ ↓ ↑ ↑ ↓ ↓ *iu ↓ ↓ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↓ ↑

iV ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓ ↑ ↓ ↓

Legend: ↑ increase; ↓ decrease.

Page 30: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

29

Figure 1: Comparative statics of p1 and p2 for asymmetric firms with linear demand 2

1 0.2c = , 2 [0,0.4]c ∈

0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40c2

1.25

1.30

1.35

1.40

1.45p1, p2

p2

p1

1 1ρ = , 2 [0,2]ρ ∈

0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0r2

1.15

1.20

1.25

1.30

1.35

1.40

p1, p2

p2

p1

1 0.2m = , 2 [0,0.4]m ∈

0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40m2

1.24

1.26

1.28

1.30

1.32p1, p2

p2

p1

1 0.5β = , 2 [0,1]β ∈

0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0b2

1.5

2.0

p1, p2

p2

p1

2 Unless otherwise stated, the parameter values in Figures 1-2 are: 1 0.2c = , 2 0.2c = , 1 0.1r = , 2 0.1r = , 1 1ρ = ,

2 1ρ = , 1 0.2m = , 2 0.2m = , 1 1α = , 2 1α = , 1 0.5β = , 2 0.5β = , and 1 2 1T s s− − = . Due to space restrictions, the graphs for { 1 0.1r = , 2 [0,0.2]r ∈ } and { 1 1α = , 2 [0,2]α ∈ } are not presented here.

Page 31: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

30

Figure 2: Comparative statics of u1 and u2 (given s1 and s2) for asymmetric firms with linear demand

1 0.2c = , 2 [0,0.4]c ∈

0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40c2

1.5

2.0

2.5

u1, u2

u2

u1

1 1ρ = , 2 [0,2]ρ ∈

1.0 1.5 2.0r2

1.0

1.5

2.0

u1, u2

u2

u1

1 0.2m = , 2 [0,0.4]m ∈

0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40m2

1.3

1.4

1.5

u1, u2

u2

u1

1 0.5β = , 2 [0,1]β ∈

0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0b2

1.5

2.0

2.5

u1, u2

u2

u1

Page 32: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

31

Figure 3: Comparative statics of p1 and p2 for asymmetric firms with isoelastic demand3

1 0.2c = , 2 [0,0.4]c ∈

0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40c2

12

14

16

18

20

22

p1, p2

p2

p1

1 1ρ = , 2 [0,2]ρ ∈

1.0 1.5 2.0r2

5

10

15

20

25

30

p1, p2

p2

p1

1 0.2m = , 2 [0,0.4]m ∈

0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40m2

13.0

13.5

p1, p2

p2

p1

1 1.25η = , 2 [1.01,2]η ∈

1.4 1.6 1.8 2.0h2

10

20

30

40

p1, p2

p2

p1

3 Unless otherwise stated, the parameter values in Figures 3 and 4 are: 1 0.2c = , 2 0.2c = , 1 0.1r = , 2 0.1r = ,

1 1ρ = , 2 1ρ = , 1 0.2m = , 2 0.2m = , 1 1.25η = , 2 1.25η = , and 1 2 1T s s− − = . Due to space restrictions, the graphs for { 1 0.1r = , 2 [0,0.2]r ∈ } are not presented here.

Page 33: Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly*

32

Figure 4: Comparative statics of u1 and u2 (given s1 and s2) for asymmetric firms with isoelastic demand

1 0.2c = , 2 [0,0.4]c ∈

0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40c2

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

u1, u2

u2

u1

1 1ρ = , 2 [0,2]ρ ∈

1.0 1.5 2.0r2

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

u1, u2

u2

u1

1 0.2m = , 2 [0,0.4]m ∈

0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40m2

2.09

2.10

2.11

2.12

2.13

2.14

u1, u2

u2

u1

1 1.25η = , 2 [1.01,2]η ∈

1.4 1.6 1.8 2.0h2

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

4.5

u1, u2

u2

u1