23
Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure of an Integrated Regulatory Model?: The U.K. in a Time of Crisis.” Economic Society of Kansai University Working Paper Series, F57.

Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

Paper should be cited as:

Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure of an Integrated Regulatory Model?: The U.K. in a

Time of Crisis.” Economic Society of Kansai University Working Paper Series, F57.

Page 2: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

Working Paper Series F57

The Failure of an Integrated Regulatory Model?:

The U.K. in a Time of Crisis

Sara Konoe

Faculty of Economics

Kansai University

[email protected]

8th July 2012

Economic Society of Kansai University

Osaka, 564-8680 JAPAN

Page 3: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

2

The Failure of an Integrated Regulatory Model?:

The U.K. in a Time of Crisis

Abstract

The U.K.’s financial regulatory system, which was represented by an independent

supervisor—the Financial Services Authority (FSA)—had once been reviewed

positively. Transformative and speedy institutional changes, such as the establishment

of FSA in 1997 and its strengthened role by the Financial Services and Markets Act

(FSMA) in 2000, were made possible by the political leadership of Prime Minister Blair

and the Chancellor of the Exchequer Brown, as well as the U.K.’s majoritarian political

system. However, when the 2007-09 global financial crisis hit the U.K., its regulatory

framework lost its prestige. After a series of failures of financial institutions including

Northern Rock, the existing regulatory system was much criticized for its ineffective

supervisory practices and the malfunctioning tripartite system in crisis management

between the HM Treasury, the Bank of England (BOE) and the FSA, thus leading to a

symbolic decision: the break-up of the FSA. By analyzing institutional impact on the

development of the crisis and the subsequent reform, as well as political and economic

context where organizational changes occurred, this paper addresses the question about

why a particular regulatory model was chosen at a particular time, and draws

implications for a global regime responsible for financial oversight by pointing out

remaining future agendas.

Keywords: financial supervision, the United Kingdom, Bank of England, Financial

Services Authority, financial crisis, financial reform

JEL classification: F59; G01; G38; K20

Page 4: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

3

1. Introduction

This paper analyzes which factors affected the sequence and direction of the

United Kingdom’s financial regulatory reforms in the 1990s and the early 2000s. By

analyzing the history of regulatory changes, the paper especially examines the role of

the 2007-09 financial crisis that influenced the reform characteristics and what these

changes could mean in a broader context of supervisory reform at regional and global

levels. Based on the case study of the U.K. financial reforms, this paper attempts to

draw implications for larger questions: how contextual (either economic or political)

and institutional (either regulatory or political) factors could impact the development of

crises and financial reform, and why particular regulatory models have been chosen at

given times in a country whose political system has particular characteristics.

This case study focuses on the reforms of supervisory organizational structure in

financial regulation. In particular, prudential regulation is the focus of this study, among

many aspects of financial supervision that could include conduct-of-business and

consumer protection issues. A question about what kinds of regulations are agreed upon

and enforced seems to be more relevant than a question of who regulates the markets.

However, due to a wide scope of interpretation inherent in law and regulations, the

organizational structure of supervision could still matter in the implementation of

regulatory goals. Although this study does not examine the contents of regulations in

detail, the ensuing discussions need to be reassessed in light of the substantive analysis

of regulations.

Barth, Caprio, and Levine (2006) examined the relationship between political

system and banking policies: democratic and open systems foster private market-based

monitoring and less restriction on the markets. Admittedly, there should be some

long-term influence of political institutions on supervisory power. However, contextual

factors need to be taken into account as an intermediate variable to explain a regulatory

model as well as its actual power and functions. Political and economic contexts (such

as a financial crisis) could matter in influencing the directions of supervisory

organizational reforms and the ideas about which structure is better than others. Even a

crisis with a limited scope, such as the run on Northern Rock, may have had a long-term

impact on discussions over which regulatory organizations are better than others, and on

actual functions and power given to a regulatory authority. The 2007-09 global financial

crisis made market failure problems more imminent, thus providing a rationale for the

enhanced consolidation of supervisory power in order to address market failures. The

2007-09 financial crisis most directly and significantly affected the financial sector in

advanced industrial democracies; a perception shift occurred primarily among financial

policy-makers in these countries.

According to MacNeil (2010), it has been difficult to precisely identify the causes

of the 2007-09 financial crisis due to the interplay of many factors at the national,

regional, and international levels. The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in

the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been made to attribute relevant

causal factors to the existing regulatory framework.1 It has to be remembered that the

pre-crisis major regulatory reform in 1997 in the U.K. (i.e., the creation of an integrated

1. MacNeil, 485-87.

Page 5: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

4

regulator, the FSA) intended to achieve economies of scale and scope in regulatory and

supervisory practices across different financial sectors in an increasingly integrating

financial market (Briault 1999). The decision to split up the functions of the FSA may

seem to be contradictory with what was attempted in 1997. Questions need to be asked

about how different contexts behind these reforms—whether pre-crisis or

mid-crisis—can explain how an institutional shift occurred in such a short interval and

what this could imply for actual supervisory practices.

In recent decades before the crisis, the U.K. system had attracted many

international businesses, partly because of the perception that the FSA’s practices were

less intrusive. Cassis (2010) commented:

It was widely acknowledged until the financial crisis of 2008 that, with the

Financial Services Authority, founded in 2000, London had a regulatory

environment that was superior to that of its main competitors, especially New

York, Frankfurt, and Paris. […] It was undoubtedly as much the consequence as

the cause of the City’s international pre-eminence—and the big banks are

unlikely to leave London with the end of “light tough” regulation.2

The economic benefit and political privilege enjoyed by the City of London and

its regulator, the FSA, could not be maintained as the crisis heavily saddled the U.K.

and uncovered the negative aspects of the past regulatory framework. Regulators seem

to have taken blame, at least symbolically, by the break-up of the FSA, while the

influence of the City of London may have been somewhat mitigated through a series of

financial collapse.

2. Driving Force for Regulatory Integration

2-1) Does Democracy Favor a Particular Banking Policy?

A linkage between political institutions, on the one hand, and banking policies

and regulatory and supervisory organizations, on the other hand, has not yet been

thoroughly examined, except for in a few pieces of work including Barth, Caprio, and

Levine (2006). Barth et al. (2006) examined the impact of political systems “along a

spectrum from those geared toward protecting and advancing the interests of small elites

to those based on more open, competitive, democratic institutions.”3 In general terms,

through an illustrative comparison between Mexico and the United States, Barth et al.

(2006) point out that a competitive and open political system helps a country to avoid

channeling funds and directing a banking system in favor of a small, dominant group.

Moreover, they conducted a large-N empirical analysis to systemically examine

the relationship between democracy and banking policies, and between democracy and

supervisory organizational structure. Their results showed 1) a statistically significant

positive relationship between democracy (i.e., an open, competitive, and democratic

political system) and banking policies that foster private market monitoring (e.g.,

information disclosures, etc.), 2) a statistically significant negative relationship between

democracy and regulatory restrictions on bank activities and government ownership of

banks,4 and 3) no significant relationship between democracy and the strength of

2. Cassis, 292. The FSA was proposed in 1997 and given a full power through the FSMA in 2000.

3. Barth, Caprio, and Levine, 286.

4. Bank regulatory policy variables are constructed based on World Bank Survey that reflects

updates for the year-end of 2002 (ibid., 76). Banking policies indexes are constructed based on the 2003

Page 6: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

5

official supervisory power (i.e., the authority to demand information, or intervene in a

problem bank, etc.).5 In a democratic political system, the last point is explained by its

ambiguous attitude toward supervisory power, since:

democratic political systems may be either (1) wary of the potential corrupting

influence of bank supervisory power or (2) keen to overcome market failures

with strong official supervision. […] Democratic political systems might have a

public interest desire to ameliorate market failures, but worry that establishing a

powerful supervisory agency will facilitate private interest activities.6

Thus, “countries may choose to have powerful or weak supervisory agencies for

very different reasons.”7

2-2) Liberalizing Financial Markets and Regulatory Responses

While available research suggests that democracy is likely to reduce regulatory

restrictions, can political institutional indicators really explain the recent-decades

changes in regulatory policies? From the 1980s to the early 2000s, after the collapse of

the Bretton Woods system, financial markets were liberalized to a great extent with

increasing cross-border capital mobility, the removal of capital control, and

technological advancement. For example, cross-sector entry restrictions to financial

businesses and interest rate controls were deregulated in industrial economies where

they were formerly restricted, and various kinds of capital market products and

activities (e.g. mutual funds, derivatives, and securitized products) were permitted to

expand. It would be difficult to attribute the driving force of this trend to the possibility

of industrial economies having become more democratic,8 since from the 1980s to the

early 2000s, no significant democratization trends could be found in these economies,

except for a limited number of transitional economies in Central and Eastern Europe.

To examine the factors that drove the financial liberalization in these countries,

alternative explanations can be found in single-country or comparative case studies. For

example, Johnson and Kwak (2001) note that in the U.S., it was the role of Wall Street’s

increasing influence over Congress and bureaucratic officials through campaign

contributions and personal exchanges that led the country to liberalization.9 In the

analysis of deregulatory politics in the U.S. from the 1980s to the 1990s, Reinicke

(1995) shows how regulatory fragmentation among multiple regulators in that country

led to de facto deregulation and undermined the separation between commercial

banking and investments that had been imposed by the Glass-Steagall Act. Deeg and

Lütz (2000) describe the role of European integration and enhanced competition in

capital markets in helping the formation of liberalization initiatives under a

public-private alliance between Germany’s large private banks and the government, thus

leading to securities market consolidation and integration. These accounts point to the

role of a tie between business and politics, and that of regulatory fragmentation, global

competition, and market integration, in facilitating financial liberalization.

World Bank Survey, and political institution variables are constructed based on Policy IV data from 1998

to 2002 (ibid., 288-91).

5. Ibid., 297-306.

6. Ibid., 305. 7. Ibid., 305. 8. To empirically examine this question, a study on a sample of advanced industrial economies in

their time series data must be conducted.

9. Johnson and Kwak, 90-104.

Page 7: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

6

Financial market integration progressed both across national borders and across

different financial sectors. Cross-border integration led to policy initiatives toward

international regulatory harmonization through the developments of the Basel Accords.

As discussed by Oatley and Nabors (1998), Singer (2004), and Drezner (2007),

politicians’ or regulators’ responsiveness to rising competition from foreign financial

sectors, and the concern over stability issues raised by financial crises in the 1980s,

helped countries to come together and decide on a common framework—the Basel

Accords—to ensure a level playing field.

Cross-sector integration brought about policy initiatives toward regulatory

integration by reducing differences in standards between sector-based regulators (e.g.,

banking, securities, and insurance regulators) or through the organizational

consolidation of their entities. Some countries have sector-based multiple financial

supervisors, whereas others have a single consolidated one. In recent decades, there has

been a shift from a multiple-regulator system to a single-regulator system. The

emergence of a financial conglomerate embracing different financial services made such

a sector-based multiple-regulator system ineffective to monitor an entire entity, thus

provided justification for regulatory integration across sectors by consolidating financial

regulators; the 1997 reform in the U.K. was one of them. The 1997 reform was

undertaken to achieve economies of scale and scope, as well as to avoid confusion over

who regulates what.10

Other research highlighted the positive effect of a

single-regulator system on the soundness of the banking system. Barth, Dopico, Nolle,

and Wilcox (2002) found a statistically significant positive effect of having a single

regulator on equity capital ratio (the ratio of equity capital to assets) and a negative

impact on liquidity risk (the ratio of loans to assets plus the ratio of deposits to assets),

at least for a country sample which excluded transitional economies.11

2-3) Choosing Financial Supervisory Models

Barth et al. (2006) show an undetermined relationship between democracy and

supervisory power. In addition, the actual power and functions of a supervisory system

could be affected by the specific regulatory model to be chosen (Barth et al., 2002).

Financial regulatory and supervisory operation includes diverse tasks that require

different skills and knowledge, and the ways in which responsibilities are allocated have

been a contentious issue. Under a consolidated regulatory model with cross-sector

integration, there are still multiple options to be chosen: the consolidated supervisory

authorities under 1) the central bank, 2) the finance ministry, 3) those that are

independent of both the finance ministry and central bank, or 4) the separation of

supervisory authority over financial stability and solvency matters and

conduct-of-business issues (i.e., the “twin-peaks” model).

The effectiveness of the first model was challenged when rapidly-developed

securities markets raised a series of investor protection claims before the 1997 reform in

the U.K (e.g., mis-selling of pensions; see discussion in Section 2-4). The second model

10. Darling, 19.

11. Barth, Dopico, Nolle, and Wilcox 170, 175, 176-81 and 185. Concerning the impact on liquidity

risk, low values of F statistics and of adjusted R-squared were noted. They consider that more illiquid

loans or more liquid deposits will increase liquidity risk (ibid., 170), but alternative reliance on wholesale

funding as opposed to deposits, may increase liquidity risk even more, given the example of Northern

Rock. Indicator must be improved in light of the 2007-09 financial crisis.

Page 8: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

7

was criticized during the financial crisis in Japan, when financial supervisory practices

were not undertaken independently of other fiscal policy concerns, ultimately leading to

the delay of regulatory intervention and public fund injections. Before the 2007-2009

financial crisis, the third model found favor; some countries with multiple regulators or

supervisory authorities under the central bank moved toward this third model, as

suggested by Masciandaro (2004). For example, Norway (1986), Iceland (1988),

Austria (2002), Denmark (1988), Germany (2002), Sweden (1991), the U.K. (1997),

Estonia (1999), Latvia (1998), Malta (2002), Hungary (2000), Japan (1998), and South

Korea (1998) each introduced a single financial authority to supervise the entire

financial system.12 This was a part of an organizational shift from “function-based” to

“objective-driven supervision,” as defined by Lannoo (1998), and, as discussed above, it

arose from the integration of financial sectors through conglomeration and the

increasing difficulty of maintaining functional divisions within the business.

The fourth model, known as the “twin-peaks” paradigm, has been considered

effective for countries with mature securities markets, although the U.S. version of this

model did not attract much support because of its combination with multiple regulators

whose jurisdictions were divided along the lines of federal or state, or between sectors.

The model distinguishes financial stability and solvency issues from

conduct-of-business issues such as transparency and disclosure. The countries with

significant securities-market funding tend to develop independent and stringent

supervisory authorities over investor protection and conduct of business. The

twin-peaks model has been supported by Michael Taylor and the Wallis Commission in

Australia, among others.13 Netherland and Australia have maintained this model such

that a central bank plays a role as a financial supervisor with its authority being limited

to stability issues.

In most cases of a twin-peaks model, the central bank takes a role in financial

stability, whereas there is a separate agency overseeing investor protection issues.

Regardless of a central bank being an overarching supervisor (the first model) or being a

watchdog limited to stability matters (the fourth model), the involvement of a central

bank in supervision has been debated. Both advantages and disadvantages of locating

financial supervisory functions under the central bank have been made clear. A central

bank could be well-suited for supervising banks, since it has direct access to bank

information through monetary policy operations and it usually plays a role of lender of

last resort. In contrast, a central bank that combines supervisory functions may

encounter the temptation of relaxing monetary policies too much in order to mitigate

financial distress among financial firms. In addition, there may be spillover reputational

damage on a central bank as an independent monetary authority if it fails in effectively

supervising financial institutions.14 Moreover, Barth et al. (2002) found a statistically

positive effect of a central bank being a supervisor on the ratio of non-performing loans

12. Masciandaro, 152, 155-56. However, each country’s model greatly differs in its arrangement

and often comprises the elements of other models. For example, in Germany, the consolidated financial

regulator, the federal financial supervisory authority (BaFin: Bundesanstalt für

Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht) is located under the umbrella of the Federal Ministry of Finance (BMF:

Bundesministerium der Finanzen), although its operation has been made independent from the influence

of the BMF. BaFin and Bundesbank cooperate to conduct financial supervision.

13. For the summary of discussion involving regulatory models, see Davies and Green, Global

Financial Regulation, 189-94, and Hall, 48-50.

14. Garicano and Lastra, 9.

Page 9: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

8

(NPLs) to total assets. This might suggest that a separate single supervisor tightens

supervisory practices, although a low NPL ratio could merely reflect a lack of

transparency and the overvaluation of problematic assets.

When the 2007-09 financial crisis hit the U.K., a single-regulator model (the

third model) where supervisory power is held at the FSA outside of the Bank of England,

was questioned due to its perceived failures to supervise banks and undertake prompt

handling of troubled or problematic banks. As mentioned by Garicano and Lastra (2010),

the 2007-09 financial crisis “decisively shifts the argument” against a

single-financial-regulator model that is separate from a central bank. Garicano and

Lastra (2010) go on to say that “[w]e learnt again, in the Northern Rock debacle which

caught the Bank of England completely unprepared, that the Central banks absence

from supervision or closer involvement in the pursuit of financial stability has enormous

costs.”15 A political decision was made to choose a “twin-peaks” model (the fourth

model) in which the central bank plays a supervisory role over stability issues. In the

sections below, the paper addresses the following questions: How can this swift move

be made possible and how can it be interpreted? Did an integrated regulatory model

actually fail?

2-4) The Politics of Institutional Changes

Tsebelis (2002) explained that the U.K.’s majoritarian Westminster system can

favor dynamic, but unstable, policy changes due to a limited number of veto points,

through which powerful opponents could block government actions despite the support

of a political majority. That is, once the political majority is formed, it can bring about

transformative changes, although such policy changes could be easily negated and

replaced by the next majority after a change in administration. This system is contrasted

with political systems with many informal or formal veto points (typically seen in Japan

or the U.S.), as defined by Cox and McCubbins (2001), in which policy opponents can

find multiple channels to impede rapid policy changes. In the latter system, once

changes are made, their implementation tends to be fairly stable. According to Mahoney

and Thelen (2010), in a system of weak veto players, institutional changes can be

characterized as “displacement (outright changes of existing arrangements)” or

“conversion (substantive changes through interpretation),” rather than “layering (new

rules attached to existing ones)” or “drift (changes due to neglect of an institutions).”

The dynamic but fragile reform paths of the British financial system match this

theoretical expectation. Both pre-crisis and post-crisis financial regulatory reforms were

put through with a change of administration: from the Conservative Party to the Labor

Party and from the Labor Party to the Conservative-Liberal Democrat party coalition.

The first reform in 1997 responded to a series of supervisory failures, and subsequent

criticism against a self-regulatory structure based on the two-tier system of the

Securities and Investments Board (SIB) and Self-Regulation Organizations (SROs) and

against the oversight role of the BOE as a banking supervisor. The fraud or failure in the

banking sector, such as Johnson Matthey Bankers Ltd. in 1984, the Bank of Credit and

Commerce International (BCCI) in 1991, and Barings in 1995, uncovered the limited

capacity of the BOE, whereas the Maxwell affair and the mis-selling of pensions in the

early 1990s called the effectiveness of the self-regulatory system into question. The

15. Garicano and Lastra, 10.

Page 10: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

9

BOE was considered to be poorly suited for monitoring complex multinational banking

groups, and the awareness of close cooperation between banking and securities

regulators was raised, thus leading to a decision to create an integrated financial

regulator, the FSA, in 1997. The FSA gained full force through the enactment of the

Financial Services and Markets Act (FSMA) in 2000.16

The second reform responded to the failures of the financial system revealed in

the midst of the 2007-09 global financial crisis, symbolically represented by the failure

of Northern Rock. While addressing bank failures, the tripartite system of crisis

management between the FSA, the BOE, and the Treasury was deeply criticized for its

ineffectiveness. After complaints were raised against the FSA’s supervisory practices in

the lead-up to the crisis, and with the aid of a change in administration, a new

framework was decided upon to split the FSA and transfer most of its responsibility

concerning financial stability to the BOE, either under its direct oversight or through its

subsidiary. Davies and Green (2010) note that, in a time of crisis, “issues related to bank

rescues and the provision of lender of last resort support once again assumed

prominence, and the links between supervisors and central banks again appeared

crucial.”17

This policy change came through as liquidity issues were perceived to be much

more important than formerly believed, both at national and international levels, during

the crisis.18 As Scott (2010b) explained, the crisis revealed the reality that the “run”

could happen, even with the presence of a deposit insurance system. With the

reoccurrence of significant financial crises that had been absent since the 19th century,

the central bank’s role has become much more pronounced again. Milne and Wood

(2008) emphasized the effective role of central bank as a lender of last resort to ensure

financial stability from the 19th century up to the recent crisis, and asked why this did

not work in Northern Rock’s case. They stated that it became politically difficult for

politicians to let depositors suffer from financial firms’ failures since most depositors

are no longer prosperous citizens like they were in the 19th century, and, despite this

change, a deposit insurance scheme had remained defective and insolvency schemes for

banks did not exist in the U.K. before the run on Northern Rock. In a research interview

led by the author, Prof. Geoffrey Wood also pointed out that the BOE’s lack of access to

information due to the demise of discount markets and the transfer of supervisory

authority to the FSA, led to the BOE’s diluted or ineffective role in ensuring and

16. In September 2005, I highlighted this reform process in my presentation at the American

Political Science Association (APSA). The following literature discusses the regulatory structure and

process related to the 1997 reform: Peter Sinclair, “The Financial Sector,” in Blair Effect: The Blair

Government 1997-2001, ed. Anthony Seldon (London: Little, Brown and Company, 2001); Eilís Ferran,

“Examining the UK’s experience in adopting the single financial regulator model,” Brooklyn Journal of

International Law [online journal]; available from

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=346120, Internet. Accessed on June 30, 2012;

International Monetary Fund, “United Kingdom: Selected Issues.” IMF Staff Country Report no.99/44

(1999) [database online]; available from http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=2994.0,

Internet. Accessed on June 30, 2012.

17. Davies and Green, Banking on the Future, 70.

18. The improved understanding of liquidity is essential. Persaud (2010) points out the negative

side of mark-to-market accounting that forced financiers with long-term funding commitments to sell

assets in the credit crunch, thus worsening the crisis. He notes that “[t]he risk management, valuation and

accounting system that the institutions with overnight funding use should be different than the one that

the long-term investor should use (Persaud, 156).”

Page 11: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

10

managing financial stability.19

Consolidating prudential responsibilities under a central bank may not be

enough, however, to address the problem of too many decision-makers, or too many

heads, in crisis management. As the following section shows, successful crisis

management also depends on the scope and timing of the Treasury’s ability to provide a

government guarantee; thus, a new framework would not be immune to a coordination

problem between multiple authorities.20 The 2007-09 financial crisis spurred

discussions over a governance scheme determining collaborative terms between the

Treasury and central bank in the financial stability matter, not only in the U.K., but

beyond.

3. Northern Rock’s Impact and Proposed Reforms

3-1) “The Run on the Rock”

The run on Northern Rock in September of 2007 struck a blow to the U.K. Such

a significant crisis had not occurred in the U.K. since the 19th century. The crisis

management system did not work properly this time, and the failure led to the overhaul

of its financial regulatory/supervisory architecture afterwards. Northern Rock’s

challenges began with its growing assets and short-term financing. It grew from £15.8

billion at the end of 1997 to £101.0 billion at the end of 2008.21 To finance growing

assets, Northern Rock increasingly relied on more money from the wholesale markets

(such as the interbank market) and the use of securitization by creating a vehicle called

Granite. The portion of retail funds (as opposed to wholesale funds) to the total

liabilities and equity declined from 62.7% at the end of 1997 to 22.4% at the end of

2006. In contrast, as of the end of 2006, the portion of wholesale funds to the total

liabilities was 24.0%, and that of securitization was additional 39.8%.22 Both

securitization and other wholesale funding matured in the short term and required

refinancing on a regular basis. In response to the warnings issued by the BOE and the

FSA, Northern Rock tried to change its strategy, but it did not prevent the subsequent

bank run.23 Rapidly rising assets and plummeting share prices that began in February

2007 signaled the presence of a problem.24

The House of Commons Treasury Committee’s report stated:

insofar as the FSA undertook greater “regulatory engagement” with Northern

Rock, this failed to tackle the fundamental weakness in its funding model and

did nothing to prevent the problems that came to the fore from August 2007

onwards. We regard this as a substantial failure of regulation.”25

In addition, the report highlights the role of an oft overlooked issue in the crisis,

which was the liquidity aspect: “[t]he problems affecting Northern Rock were those of

19. Prof. G. Wood, personal communications, March 14-15, 2012.

20. Scott, Reducing Systemic Risk, 772.

21. Milne and Wood, 3.

22. Ibid., 3-5.

23. House of Commons, 15. In response to the crisis, the House of Commons Treasury Committee

examined the cause of this extraordinary crisis and published its report, “The Run on the Rock,” in

January 2008. Concerning the pre-crisis warning, see also Milne and Wood, 9.

24. House of Commons, 23-24.

25. Ibid., 24.

Page 12: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

11

liquidity and funding, rather than solvency,”26 but liquidity regulation had not yet

drawn significant attention at that time, and, even at an international level, agreement

with respect to liquidity regulations has not occurred.27

Eventually, the BOE’s liquidity support seemed necessary to keep Northern

Rock running. After possible takeovers of Northern Rock by other banks (such as

Lloyds Bank) and the covert operation of the liquidity support from the BOE to

Northern Rock turned out to be (or was judged to be) difficult, the tripartite authorities

of the Treasury, the BOE, and the FSA decided to announce the BOE’s liquidity support

to this troubled institution. Unexpectedly, this plan was leaked at night on September 13,

2007 through BBC before it was initiated. The deposit run on the bank began on the

next day, and continued until the Chancellor of the Exchequer announced a full deposit

guarantee on September 17, 2007.28

The report criticized the tripartite authorities for their failure to make a timely

decision by saying “[i]t is unacceptable, that the terms of the guarantee to depositors

had not been agreed in advance in order to allow a timely announcement in the event of

an adverse reaction to the Bank of England support facility.”29 The functions of

tripartite authorities have also drawn criticism in academics. For example, Hall noted

that “[t]he impression one gets from its operation in the run-up to and during the crisis

is that no one was in overall control with each party possessing an effective power of

veto.”30 In his memoir, then Chancellor Alistair Darling criticized the BOE for its

attitude toward crisis management by saying:

[m]y frustration was that I could not in practice order the Bank to do what I

wanted. Only the Bank of England can put the necessary funds into the banking

system […] The fact that we had given the Bank independence had a downside

as well as an upside.”31

Following extended lending from the BOE, Northern Rock was nationalized in

February 2008. Regulatory failure in the run-up to the crisis became a big issue. In

response, in March 2008, the FSA issued a report entitled, “The Supervision of

Northern Rock: A Lessons Learned Review,” and admitted its supervisory failure for

this incident as well as proposed the plans to overhaul the regulatory structure.32 In the

report, for example, a lack of resources and capacity used for this particular supervision

has been identified, while the emphasis on liquidity regulation was made for the

improvement of future regulation. Then Prime Minister Gordon Brown admitted his

mistake in creating the FSA by saying that, “we set up the FSA believing the problem

would come from the failure of an individual institution. That was the big mistake.”33

26. Ibid., 26.

27. Ibid., 28-29.

28. Ibid., 50-68.

29. Ibid., 71-72.

30. Hall, 52.

31. Darling, 23.

32. BBC News: http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/business/7313896.stm; The FSA report on the case of

Northern Rock is available at: http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/nr_report.pdf; Internet. Accessed on June

30, 2012.

33. BBC News: http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-13032013; Internet. Accessed on June 30,

2012.

Page 13: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

12

3-2) Re-assessment of Existing Framework and a New Proposal

The collapse of Northern Rock was only the beginning of a larger banking crisis.

The failures of other banks and building societies followed, and bank bailout schemes

were implemented in October 2008 and January 2009. In response to the need for

strengthening regulation, the new Banking Act was enacted in February 2009, and a

new FSA chairman issued a “Turner Review” in March 2009 to provide a perspective

on the cause of financial crisis and better regulation (Financial Services Authority

2009).34

The FSA’s role

The role of the FSA and its regulatory practices was re-assessed after the crisis.

MacNeil (2010) noted the FSA’s wide discretion in “the regulatory techniques” and “the

intensity of regulation” outside a formal legal structure, and maintained that “the formal

legal structure of regulation can be of much less significance than the manner in which

regulation is practiced” such as so-called “light touch,” “risk-based,” and

“principles-based” regulation.35 In principle-based regulation, as mentioned by Davies

and Green (2008), the financial regulator does not have to identify “a particular rule

breach” but, rather, “the principles themselves can be used as the basis for enforcement

action.”36 Davies and Green (2008) continue to state, however, that this aspect needs to

be conditioned by the fact that rules written in the FSA Handbook have been extensive

and detailed.

Moreover, Ferran (2011) explained that the FSA concentrated too much on

consumer protection matters, rather than prudential regulation and systemic risk. For

example, he shows how few times the concept of “systemic” was mentioned in the

FSA’s annual reports in the early 2000s before the crisis.37 Darling (2011) also

mentioned that: “[t]he FSA […] had spent a great deal of time since its inception

concentrating on consumer issues, rather than examining the systemic risks […]”38 In

addition, Wood considered that this may be partly explained by the contradiction

between the task of consumer protection (or conduct of business) and that of prudential

regulation. For the purpose of consumer protection, keeping business open would be

preferable to closing down the business. In contrast, from a perspective of prudential

regulation, it may be necessary to close down the business before assets grow and

problems and resolution costs amass.39

In addition, as implied by Garicano and Lastra (2010), this may have something

to do with incentive distortion, depending on whether or not task and performance could

easily be measured.40 Conduct-of-business issues could be more objectively identifiable

in terms of whether certain actions could violate regulations, while risk assessment and

examination of banks could make it more difficult to reach objective judgment about

whether a bank should continue business, or whether it deserves a warning or a

34. Hall, 31-32.

35. MacNeil, 486-87.

36. Davies and Green, Global Financial Regulation, 207.

37. Ferran. 460.

38. Darling, 20.

39. Prof. G. Wood, personal communications, March 14-15, 2012.

40. Garicano and Lastra, 12-13.

Page 14: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

13

regulator’s intervention to limit its business. This ambiguity comes from the nature of

prudential regulation where the valuation of assets could constantly change as economic

conditions and prospect change. If multiple tasks are combined within one entity,

employees’ efforts may be directed toward the former type of regulation.

The BOE’s role and other aspects

Even if the FSA had been eager to investigate systemic risk, things may not have

been so different for Northern Rock, whose asset size was ranked 8th among the U.K.

banks and building societies as of the end of 2006, and 9th for deposits.

41 As stated in

the Report to the G-20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors in October 2009,

which was prepared by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the Bank for

International Settlements (BIS), and Financial Stability Board, Northern Rock was

classified as one of six major British banking groups (MBBGs). However, it was not

thought to represent a systemic institution in the manner of its Big Four counterparts in

terms of its assets, liabilities, and stock market capitalization.42

Moreover, Milne and Wood (2008) emphasized that the BOE’s liquidity support

to Northern Rock was different from a central bank’s traditional role of lender of last

resort.43 They pointed out that “[t]here was a determined attempt to keep the institution

going, and to find a rescuer for it. This can certainly not be justified by the size or

reputation of Northern Rock.”44 If such non-traditional operation has become all the

more important due to the interconnected nature of financial transactions or the political

mandate of protecting small depositors not being solely comprised of the rich, the task

of prudential regulation gets closer to the field of crisis management operations, which

include liquidity provision and potential arrangements of rescue options. This means

that the recent financial market developments may have enhanced a central bank’s

required mandate for financial stability. This account sounds even more convincing in

the context of the increasing importance of “macro-prudential,” which is later discussed.

However, the BOE did not keep up with this expectation at that time. Darling

(2011) wrote:

(t)he Bank had concentrated on its monetary policy duties, primarily the

regulation of interest rate. Although it had had responsibility for financial

stability since becoming independent in 1997, it did not have a sufficiently deep

understanding of what was going on in the individual banks—or, indeed, of the

critical relationships within the banking system.”45

In addition, a problem existed in the terms of cooperation between the BOE and

the FSA, and between the three authorities, including the Treasury. According to

Darling (2011), “[t]he whole system depended on the chairman of the FSA, the

Governor of the Bank and the Chancellor seeing things in exactly the same way. The

problem was that, in September 2007, we simply did not see things in the same way.”46

They differed in opinion about whether the Bank “put money into the banking system,”

41. Milne and Wood, 4.

42. IMF staff et al., 16.

43. Milne and Wood, 27-32.

44. Ibid., 31.

45. Darling, 20.

46. Ibid., 21.

Page 15: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

14

as did the European Central Bank (ECB) and U.S. Federal Reserve.47 Whereas the

FSA’s chairman and Chancellor called for earlier responses, the BOE was hesitant up to

the last minute of the crisis due to its concerns about moral hazard.48

Policy Shift

After blame was placed on the existing framework (especially the role of the

FSA), policy proposals were presented to improve the existing framework. In his

discussion of old and newly proposed frameworks, Hall (2009) noted:

[w]hat is clear […] is that the hoped-for change in supervisory culture—from

one based on trust among like-minded industry colleagues to a more intrusive,

questioning and adversarial approach—failed to materialize following the

handover of the regulatory reins to the FSA in 1997 […] the FSA proved

susceptible to special pleading from Government and industry alike for “light

tough” regulation—a clear case of political and industry capture of the regulator

[…]49

After the investigation by the House of Commons Treasury Committee and the

House of Lords Economic Affairs Committee, the government intended to implement

modifications to the existing system (Davies 2010). In July 2009, HM Treasury (2009)

proposed how a system should be reformed by strengthening financial stability

functions at the BOE and supervisory power at the FSA. However, the Conservative

Party accelerated its criticism against the existing authorities and further “settled on a

pre-election narrative which placed primary responsibility for the financial crisis in the

U.K. on Gordon Brown, and specifically linked that to the regulatory reform he

introduced in 1997.”50 Then Chancellor Darling under the Brown government admits

his responsibility in this matter:

“[t]he responsibility for the architecture was largely mine. When we were in

opposition in the early 1990s, Gordon had asked me to take responsibility for the

City. I realized quickly that getting the right supervision and regulatory regime

was essential and set about planning for the change in regulatory control which

we implemented once we were in power.”51

Reflecting the Conservative Party’s frustration and political strategy, subsequent

to the electoral winning of a coalition of Conservative-Liberal Democrats in May 2010,

a more thorough overhaul of the supervisory structure was announced. In his speech at

Mansion House in June 2010, Chancellor Osborne stated his doubt about the tripartite

system and the existing regulatory authorities’ lack of attention to macro-prudential

issues (e.g., the growth of assets and level of debts) by pointing out the BOE’s narrow

focus on consumer price inflation, the weak presence of a financial policy division of

the Treasury, and the FSA’s narrow focus on rule-based regulation. He further stated:

only independent central banks have the broad macroeconomic understanding,

the authority and the knowledge required to make the kind of macro-prudential

judgments that are required now and in the future. And, because central banks

are the lenders of last resort, the experience of the crisis has also shown that they

47. Ibid., 21.

48. Ibid., 21-24.

49. Hall, 50-51.

50. Davies, 96.

51. Darling, 19-20.

Page 16: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

15

need to be familiar with every aspect of the institutions that they may have to

support. So they must also be responsible for day-to-day micro-prudential

regulation as well. […] In the agreement that forms the basis of this coalition

government, we stated our intention to give the Bank of England control of

macro-prudential regulation and oversight of microprudential regulation.”52

With the support of a new coalition government formed by the Conservative and

Liberal Democratic Parties, the BOE was given macro-prudential authority through the

creation of the Financial Policy Committee (FPC) and incorporated micro-prudential

function through the creation of its subsidiary, the Prudential Regulation Authority

(PRA). The consumer protection and conduct-of-business functions were separated

from these functions outside of the BOE through the creation of the Consumer

Protection and Market Authority (CPMA), along with the Economic Crime Agency

(ECA), an agency in charge of white-collar crime.

4. Perspectives on the New Framework

4-1) Post-Crisis Regulatory Integration

In the U.K., a new supervisory structure was created in 2010-12. Micro- and

macro-prudential functions, on the one hand, are now combined under the BOE into

different organizational entities: the PRA and FPC. Monetary and prudential policies are

combined under the BOE into different entities: Monetary Policy Committee (MPC)

and FPC. On the other hand, prudential regulation is separated from the

conduct-of-business authority, the former being assigned to the PRA and the latter to the

CPMA, so that it follows the “twin-peaks” model. Garicano and Lastra (2010) consider

that this model of splitting between micro- and macro-prudential supervision and

assigning the latter to the central bank provides an important linkage between the role of

lender of last resort and that of watchdog of the soundness of a financial market as a

whole, while avoiding potential reputational damage on a central bank in case of

supervisory failure at a micro-prudential level.53

The post-crisis U.K. reform may seem to be a backlash against the pre-crisis

global trend toward an integrated financial regulator, a trend described in Section 2.

Would this really be the case? In the U.S., sector-based and local-jurisdiction-based

regulatory fragmentation happened to be combined with a twin-peaks model, but a

twin-peaks model does not necessarily imply regulatory fragmentation in prudential

regulation. At least, the U.K. did not return to the pre-1997 regime, in which

sector-based and self-regulatory practices operated in combination with the overarching

banking supervision by the BOE. In addition, the fact that a new framework was

adopted in the moment of crisis and in the midst of regulatory tightening could make

differences in how regulatory organizations would actually function.

Opinions are divided about how a new framework should be interpreted in terms

of regulatory fragmentation or integration. Some criticize regulatory fragmentation

brought about by the split of the FSA into the PRA and CPMA. For example, Rawlings

52. “Speech at the Lord Mayor’s Dinner for Bankers & Merchants of the City of London by the

Chancellor of the Exchequer, the Rt Hon George Osborne MP, at Mansion House.” 16 June 2010, sent.

100-104. Available from http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/press_12_10.htm; Internet. Accessed March 6,

2012.

53. Garicano and Lastra, 10.

Page 17: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

16

(2010) maintains that “firms will be subject to at least two regulators and […] to

different sets of rules […]” and warns of the possibility of “a risk of competition

between the agencies.” He takes a rather critical stance on these issues and notes that

“even if the FSA made mistakes, this does not mean the idea of a unified system was

wrong.”54 In contrast, if one pays more attention to the aspect of combining micro- and

macro-prudential authorities under the BOE, which has an independent authority in

monetary policy, this reform can be seen as a move toward regulatory integration. To

make a comparison with the fragmented regulatory system of the U.S., Scott (2010a)

stresses “the United Kingdom has moved toward even greater consolidation by making

the FSA, in effect, a subsidiary of the Bank of England.”55

4-2) The Role of the Central Bank in Prudential Regulation

By pointing out the problems of regulatory capture, or “groupthink,” in

micro-prudential regulation, John Gieve, the former Deputy Governor of the BOE,

stressed the potential role of the BOE (Bank) in macro-prudential regulation. In his

remarks on June 2009 before an official decision on this new framework, Gieve argued

that:

banks and regulators are in constant discussion and negotiation and tend to

develop shared views and shared misjudgments, as they did on structured credit

and wholesale funding. We need a second opinion and challenge from a body

that is not involved in day-to-day supervision but can take a view of the system

as a whole […] If, as I favour, we introduce a power to vary capital and liquidity

requirements with the economic cycle, the Bank should have the lead

responsibility for making those judgments.56

Briault (2009) emphasized “the collective intellectual failure” of which financial

industries and financial regulators were a part in the lead-up to the crisis.57 If such a

failure in perception is embedded in the existing regulatory structure, modifying

incentives of regulators through regulatory reshuffling may make a sense, as long as the

new framework is better at overcoming knowledge limitation by giving a regulator

some distance from an industry.

The increasing role or involvement of a central bank in macro-prudential

regulation is also supported by views expressed by Davies and Green (2010). They

maintain that:

(c)arrying out the day-to-day tasks of prudential regulation of individual

institutions is neither necessary nor sufficient to create the understanding of

financial stability […] But the central bank does need first-hand knowledge of

systemically important institutions, focusing on their liquidity, funding, and

capital adequacy.58

From this perspective, some distance between the PRA and the FPC can also be

justified, except for some systemically important financial institutions (SIFIs), while

others emphasize the benefit of combining micro- and macro-prudential regulation to a

54. Rawlings, 527.

55. Scott, A General Evaluation of the Dodd-Frank US Financial Reform Legislation, 479.

56. John Gieve. “Regulating banks calls for attack on inertia.” Financial Times, June 28, 2009.

57. Briault, Fixing Regulation, 12.

58. Davies and Green, Banking on the Future, 87.

Page 18: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

17

fuller extent.59

In addition, the concern over potential conflict-of-interest issues between

financial supervision and monetary policy could be in part balanced out by a positive

synergy brought about by the combing two functions. In FSA Occasional Papers,

Briault (1999) stated that “[t]here is no firm empirical evidence of the monetary

authorities [’s…] loosening monetary conditions simply in order to support banks or

other financial institutions.”60 In recognizing the positive synergies that are created

when bank regulation and monetary policy are combined into one institution, Briault

(2001) stated that “the real issue here is […] whether the synergies in doing so are

greater or less than the alternative synergies arising from the creation of a single

financial services regulator.”61

Beneficial synergy between monetary policy and financial stability was also

acknowledged by Davies and Green (2010). They wrote that:

[t]he analysis of financial market developments … has not often influenced

debates in the MPC […] the need is to integrate the core functions of the central

bank, so that the two forms of stability can be seen as interconnected.62

This leads to their conclusion that “stresses in the financial system, ‘excess’

growth of credit, and the inflation of asset price bubbles need to be seen as political

justification for changes in interest rates.”63 Similarly, Allen and Carletti (2010)

emphasize the need for a check-and-balance mechanism of a central bank whose

policies tend to disregard any possible financial stability measures other than

narrowly-defined economic indicators when it makes monetary policy.64 They

considered low interest rates set by the U.S. Federal Reserve in 2003-04 to be a primary

contributor to the bubble in pre-crisis years. Low interest rate policy continued despite

the rapidly rising housing prices.65

The argument for maintaining a close linkage between monetary policy and

financial stability operations, including prudential regulation, can be made through the

understanding the causal relationship between economic bubbles and financial crises, a

topic frequently discussed after the recent crisis. According to Persuad (2010),

“[c]rashes follow booms, and the credit cycle is often an appendage of the economic

cycles. Consequently, any focus on systemic failure has to put the credit and economic

cycles at the heart of financial regulation.”66 Persuad continues by arguing that, in order

to reduce the housing bubble, regulatory intervention to lower the loan-to-value ratio of

mortgage lending would be more effective and less damaging to the economy than

tightening monetary policy.67 Potential interventional tools, ranging from monetary

policy to prudential regulations, need to be discussed and decided upon in terms of

which would be more effective and offer an advantage based on a cost-benefit analysis.

59. Buckingham, 33.

60. Briault, The Rationale for a Single Regulator, 28.

61. Briault, Revisiting the Rationale for a Single Regulator, 27.

62. Davies and Green, Banking on the Future, 88.

63. Ibid., 89.

64. Allen and Carletti, 17-18.

65. Ibid., 5-6.

66. Persaud, 153.

67. Ibid., 154-55.

Page 19: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

18

4-3) Some Parallels to the EU Framework

As stated above, one of the concerns that used to be discussed with regards to

the central bank’s enhanced role in financial supervision was the conflict of interest

between monetary policy and prudential regulation. The central bank that holds

financial supervisory authority may want to avoid the failure of financial institutions

and be willing to provide a larger amount of liquidity to failing banks than the optimal

level justified from a monetary policy point of view. For member states within the

European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU), the creation of the European Central

Bank (ECB) helped them to overcome such concerns, and provided them with more

options in its supervisory models. Monetary policy mandates have been transferred

from national central banks (NCBs) to the ECB, thus making conflict of interest issues

less relevant when national central banks take a role as a supervisor.68 Examples

include a Dutch central bank, De Nederlandsche Bank, which became “an integrated

prudential regulator”69 with its supervisory functions over banking and insurance

sectors. In contrast, since the BOE has kept its monetary policy authority as a

non-member state of the EMU, the concern over conflict of interest issues would not be

resolved at the national level.

At the European level in the EMU, concern over the conflict of interest could

persist, as was the case for the U.K. The central bank model adopted at the EU level

resembles a new U.K. framework (except for the remaining sector-based feature at the

EU level), in terms of combining the monetary and macro-prudential authorities. In the

EU, the ECB enhanced its role in macro-prudential regulation by hosting the secretariat

of the European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) in collaboration with financial

supervisors at European levels, including the European Banking Authority (EBA), the

European Securities and Market Authority (ESMA), and the European Insurance and

Occupational Pensions Authority (EIOPA), which are in charge of micro-prudential

regulation. The Treasury report issued in July 2009 before the decision of breaking up

the FSA expressed its support for the creation of ESRB along with its proposal of

strengthening the functions of prudential regulation in the FSA and BOE.70

As the crisis enhanced the public’s awareness of macro-prudential matters and

its linkage to crisis management processes, a new trend—a consolidated supervisor

under a central bank—gained support, at least in the U.K. At the same time, the crisis

highlighted how relevant technical discussions about prudential regulations and

financial stability operations can be to the public, and how important it could be to

make a financial supervisor more accountable. It became clear that the ultimate burden

would eventually be placed on taxpayers.

If a central bank gains more power over financial supervision, their institutional

status in relation to politics and to fiscal authority needs to be re-examined. Discussions

over how fiscal and financial authority should be linked, and to what degree they keep

some distance from each other, are underdeveloped. Japan’s model, in which the

ministry of finance served as the regulatory, led to disastrous crisis management in the

1990s. Tripartite arrangements between the FSA, BOE, and the Treasury did not work

effectively in addressing the crisis in the U.K. There are still relevant questions to be

68. Davies and Green, Banking on the Future, 206-09.

69. Ibid., 207.

70. HM Treasury, 96-97.

Page 20: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

19

asked about an institutional design over financial stability issues. For example, how

independent should a central bank be in its financial stability operation?

5. Implications in a Global Context

This paper presented the political contexts and institutional structure which

affected the 2007 crisis management and the 1997 and 2010-12 financial supervisory

reform process in the U.K., and analyzed the basic elements of the latter reform.

Regulatory restructuring toward “re-regulation” in normal times, or in the absence of a

serious crisis with a systemic scope, may not be so effective when compared to actions

taken during times of crisis, since a new scheme may not accompany the “political

will”71 to enforce a newly built structure in a stringent way. This is evidenced by the

failure of the newly established FSA in the U.K., in which a new structure seemingly

could not make much difference in terms of the stringency of regulating markets in the

field of prudential regulation.

In the particular context of the post global financial crisis in 2007-09, Helleiner

and Pagliari (2011) argue that the international economic order has become increasingly

diffuse and diverse due to the increasing influence of emerging economies and the loss

of credibility of existing authorities in international financial regulation. In an

increasingly vulnerable financial market, and with enhanced attention to the timely

undertaking of crisis management and its linkage to prudential judgment, a trend toward

the consolidation of regulatory bodies in increasing coordination with a central bank

may attract the interests of other states, while the conglomeration does not seem to

cease to exist and, thus, continues to justify a consolidated regulator model rather than a

sector-based one. Enhanced attention to the macro-prudential could lead to further

integration, as seen in the U.K. reform, where micro- and macro-prudential maintain a

linkage with some distance.

Regulatory integration in a diffused world can be explained by distinguishing

regulatory fragmentation between sovereign entities from that within them. According

to Davies and Green (2008), “statutory-based” regulations that are enforced by each

sovereign entity and recognized in an international society could create tension with

those that are self-regulatory or sub-national. They argue that:

[w]here regulators operate in their jurisdictions on the basis of regulatory

standards imposed or maintained elsewhere, statutory regulation is evidently

preferable and may be required. It is difficult for a regulator in country A to

agree to place legal reliance on a regime of self-regulation in country B.

Thus, they postulate that the “trend towards statute-based regulation” is likely to

continue.72 The post-crisis diffusion of power could result in more regulatory

consolidation at the levels of entities that are given sovereignty over policies, in whole

or in part, which could reduce the scope of different practices at sub-national levels.

Thus, in a world of increasing power diffusion, the enhancement of a

national-level supervisory power may be still appreciated, in order to respond to

democratic states’ increasing concerns over market failures and their interventionist

stance. Apart from institutional options discussed in this paper such as the role of a

central bank in financial supervision and the relationship between micro- and

71. I thank Prof. Pepper Culpepper for his insightful suggestion.

72. Davies and Green, Global Financial Regulation, 213.

Page 21: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

20

macro-prudential authorities, articulating ways to resolve accountability issues of

financial supervision and to build useful linkages between fiscal policy and financial

stability mandates without introducing overwhelming, ad hoc, and interest-group-driven

political influences, remains to be seen.

Author Note

I would like to thank the interviewees and scholars who provided me with relevant

information and advice. My appreciation goes to the interviewees at the FSA, Treasury, and the

BOE during the summer of 2006. I revisited this issue in 2011-12 after the financial crisis.

Special thanks are due to Prof. Geoffrey Wood, Mr. Clive Briault, Dr. Kevin James, and Prof.

Hal Scott for their insightful comments.

This paper is an updated version of a paper presented at the 19th International Conference

of Europeanists organized by the Council for European Studies and held on March 22-24, 2012,

in Boston, Massachusetts, U.S.A.

Work Cited

Allen, Franklin, and Elena Carletti. “An Overview of the Crisis: Causes, Consequences, and

Solutions.” International Review of Finance 10, no. 1 (2010): 1-26.

Barth, James R., Gerard Caprio, Jr., and Ross Levine, Rethinking Bank Regulation: Till Angels

Govern. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006.

Barth, James R., Luis G. Dopico, Daniel E. Nolle, and James A. Wilcox. “Bank Safety

and Soundness and the Structure of Bank Supervision: A Cross-Country Analysis.”

International Review of Finance 3, no. 3-4 (2002): 163-188.

Buckingham, Patrick. “What could go wrong.” International Financial Law Review 29, no. 6

(2010): 33.

Briault, Clive. Fixing Regulation. London: Centre for the Study of Financial Innovation (CSFI),

2009.

Briault, Clive. “The Rationale for a Single National Financial Services Regulator.” FSA

Occasional Paper, 1999. [publication online]. Available from

http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/occpapers/op02.pdf; Internet. Accessed June 30, 2012.

Briault, Clive. “Revisiting the Rationale for a Single National Financial Services Regulator.”

FSA Occasional Paper. 2002. [publication online]. Available from

http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/occpapers/op16.pdf; Internet. Accessed June 30, 2012.

Cassis, Youssef. Capitals of Capital: the Rise and Fall of International Financial Centres

1780-2009. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010.

Cox, Gary W. and Mathew D. McCubbins. “The Institutional Determinants of Economic Policy

Outcomes.” In Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy, eds. Stephan Haggard and Mathew D.

McCubbins, 21-63. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001.

Darling, Alistair. Back from the Brink. London: Atlantic Books, 2011.

Davies, Howard and David Green. Global Financial Regulation: The Essential Guide.

Cambridge: Polity, 2008.

Davies, Howard and David Green. Banking on the Future: The Fall and Rise of Central

Banking. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010.

Davies, Howard. The Financial Crisis: Who is to Blame? Cambridge: Polity, 2010.

Deeg, Richard and Susanne Lütz. “Internationalization and Financial Federalism: the United

States and Germany at the crossroads?” Comparative Political Studies 33, no.3 (2000):

374-405.

Drezner, Daniel W., All Politics Is Global: Explaining International Regulatory Regimes.

Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2007.

Page 22: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

21

Ferran, Eilís. “The Break-up of the Financial Services Authority.” Oxford Journal of Legal

Studies 31 no. 3 (2011): 455-80.

Financial Services Authority. “The Turner Review: A regulatory response to the global banking

crisis.” March 2009. [publication online]. Available from

http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/turner_review.pdf; Internet. Accessed on June 30, 2012.

Garicano, Luis and Rosa Lastra. “Toward a New Architecture for Financial Stability:

Seven Principles.” CEP Discussion Paper no. 990, July 2010: 25 pars. [database

online]. Available from http://cep.lse.ac.uk/pubs/download/dp0990.pdf; Internet.

Accessed June 30, 2012.

Hall, Maximilian J.B., “The reform of UK financial regulation.” Journal of Banking Regulation

11, no. 1 (2009): 31-75.

Helleiner, Eric and Stefano Pagliari. “The End of an Era in International Financial Regulation?

A Postcrisis Research Agenda.” International Organization 65 (2011): 169-200.

HM Treasury. Reforming Financial Markets. London: the Stationery Office. July 2009.

Available from http://www.official-documents.gov.uk/document/cm76/7667/7667.pdf;

Internet. Accessed on June 30, 2012.

House of Commons Treasury Committee. “The run on the Rock: Fifth Report of Session

2007-08.” Volume 1, January 2008. [publication online]. Available from

http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200708/cmselect/cmtreasy/56/56i.pdf;

Internet. Accessed June 30, 2012.

International Monetary Fund and the Bank for International Settlements, and the Secretariat of

the Financial Stability Board staff. “Report to the G-20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank

Governors.” prepared by, October 2009. [publication online]. Available from

http://www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/100109a.pdf; Internet. Accessed on June 30, 2012.

Johnson, Simon and James Kwak. 13 Bankers: The Wall Street Takeover and the Next Financial

Meltdown. New York: Vintage, 2011.

Lannoo, Karel. “From 1992 to EMU: The Implications for Prudential Supervision.” CEPS

(Center for European Policy Studies) Research Report 23 (1998): 1-46.

MacNeil, Iain. “The Trajectory of Regulatory Reform in the UK in the Wake of the Financial

Crisis.” European Business Organization Law Review 11 (2010): 483-526.

Mahoney, James and Kathleen Thelen, eds. Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity,

Agency, and Power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010.

Masciandaro, Donato. “Unification in financial sector supervision: the trade-off between central

bank and single authority.” Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance 12, no. 2

(2004): 151-69.

Milne, Alistair and Geoffrey Wood. “Shattered on the Rock? British Financial Stability from

1866 to 2007.” Paper presented at the conference in honour of Ted Balbach, Federal Reserve

Bank of St Louis, 3 March, 2008.

Oatley, Thomas, and Robert Nabors. “Redistributive Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth

Transfers, and the Basel Accord.” International Organization 52, no. 1 (1998): 35-54.

Persaud, Avinash D., “The Role of Policy and Banking Supervision in the Light of the Credit

Crisis.” In Time for a Visible Hand: Lessons from the 2008 World Financial Crisis, eds.

Stephany Griffith-Jones, José Antonio Ocampo, and Joseph E. Stiglitz, 150-63. Oxford:

Oxford University Press, 2010.

Rawlings, Philip. “Reform of Bank Regulation in the United Kingdom: The Opening Salvo.”

Journal of International Banking Law and Regulation 25, no. 10 (2010): 522-28.

Reinicke, Wolfgang H. Banking, Politics and Global Finance. Washington, D.C.: Edward Elgar,

1995.

Scott, Hal S. “A General Evaluation of the Dodd-Frank US Financial Reform Legislation.”

Journal of International Banking Law and Regulation 25, no. 10 (2010a): 477-80.

Scott, Hal S. “Reducing Systemic Risk through the Reform of Capital Regulation.” Journal of

Page 23: Paper should be cited as: Konoe, Sara (2012). “The Failure ... · The recent undertaking of regulatory restructuring in the U.K., at least, shows that a political judgment has been

22

International Economic Law 13, no. 3 (2010b): 763-78.

Singer. David Andrew. “Capital Rules: The Domestic Politics of International Regulatory

Harmonization.” International Organization 58, no. 3 (2004): 531-65.

Tsebelis, George. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton: Princeton University

Press, 2002.