37
February 17, 1999 Business Systems and Corporate Governance Torben Pedersen, Associate Professor, Department of International Economics and Manage- ment, Copenhagen Business School, Nansensgade 19.7, 1366 Copenhagen K. Denmark. E- mail [email protected]. Steen Thomsen, Professor, Department of International Business, The Aarhus School of Business, Fuglesangs Alle´ 4, 8210 Aarhus V. Denmark. E-mail [email protected]. Aarhus School of Business Abstract: The paper tests the applicability of Whitley’ s business systems framework to the study of international differences in corporate ownership structure. In support of Whitley’ s framework we document the existence of large differences among the largest companies in 12 European nations. Furthermore we find that these differences can be partly attributed to the institutional determinants stressed by Whitley: structure of the financial system, government regulation and labour relations. However, we also find evidence of microeconomic effects attributable to firm size and industry structure which cut across national borders and which influence cross country variations in ownership structure. We conclude that ownership structures are influenced by both economic and system effects.

Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

February 17, 1999

Business Systems and Corporate Governance

Torben Pedersen, Associate Professor, Department of International Economics and Manage-ment, Copenhagen Business School, Nansensgade 19.7, 1366 Copenhagen K. Denmark. E-mail [email protected].

Steen Thomsen, Professor, Department of International Business, The Aarhus School ofBusiness, Fuglesangs Alle´ 4, 8210 Aarhus V. Denmark. E-mail [email protected] School of Business

Abstract: The paper tests the applicability of Whitley’ s business systems framework to thestudy of international differences in corporate ownership structure. In support of Whitley’ sframework we document the existence of large differences among the largest companies in 12European nations. Furthermore we find that these differences can be partly attributed to theinstitutional determinants stressed by Whitley: structure of the financial system, governmentregulation and labour relations. However, we also find evidence of microeconomic effectsattributable to firm size and industry structure which cut across national borders and whichinfluence cross country variations in ownership structure. We conclude that ownershipstructures are influenced by both economic and system effects.

Page 2: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

2

1. Introduction

Since the beginning of the 1990s a large number of economic and legal studies have docu-

mented the existence of significant international variations in corporate governance (Franks

and Mayer 1990, 1995, Roe 1991 and 1994a, Prowse 1995, Moerland 1995, Shleifer and

Vishny 1997, Pedersen and Thomsen 1997, Laporta et al. 1997, 1998a, 1998b, as well as more

descriptive work by Buxbaum and Hopt 1994, Charkham 1994, Porter 1992, Prentice and

Holland 1993 and others). But apart from the investor protection explanation launched by

Laporta, Silvanes, Shleifer and Vishny (1998) - which regards ownership diversification as a

function of legal protection of small investors - little systematic research has been done on the

determinants of international differences in corporate governance. Instead the existence of

international differences as such has been advanced as an argument against economic

ownership theory, c.f. Roe (1994a): "..... the differences suggest that differing histories,

cultures and paths of economic development better explain the differing structures than

economic theory alone." (p. 28)

This paper turns to sociology - to the business systems analysis of Richard Whitley (1994,a,

1994b, Whitley and Kristensen 1996) - for a deeper understanding of the origins of corporate

governance systems. By testing the business systems framework the paper aims to contribute

to the ongoing dialogue between economics and sociology (in the spirit of Foss 1997).

The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 discusses Whitley’ s framework and its applicati-

on to the study of international corporate governance compared to other contributions.

Section 3 presents the data. Section 4 provides an overall empirical test of the model which

Page 3: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

3

regards corporate ownership structure as determined by system effects (nationality) and

economics (size and industry effects). Section 5 provides a closer examination of the nation

effect and its institutional origins. Section 6 concludes.

2. Business systems and corporate governance

This section discusses Whitley’ s business system concept and its application to international

corporate governance. The reference text is Whitley (1992).

According to Whitley (1992 p. 4) business systems .. “ are particular ways of organizing,

controlling and directing enterprises” (p. 7) or “particular arrangements of hierarchy-market

relations which become institutionalized and relatively successful in particular contexts”,

which is almost exactly equivalent to some of the broader definitions of corporate governance

(Charkham 1994, Williamson 1996) . These “distinctive ways of organising economic

activities become established and effective because of major differences in key social

institutions, such as the state, the financial system and the education and training system” (p.

13) including labour market organization (p. 16).. as well as the indirect influence of “more

general and diffuse attitudes and beliefs about work, material values and authority relations”

(p. 16), “family and kinship relations, identities and authority structures”. Business systems

consist of differences in “ First, the nature of the firm. Second, the connections that firms

develop with each other .. Third, how activities and skills are coordinated within firms..” (p.

18). While business systems often coincide with national economies, it is recognized that “As

well as distinct systems within nation states, there are of course substantial differences

Page 4: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

4

between firm structures and connections across industries” . Furthermore, nation states need

not have equally homogeneous business systems. It is stressed that “ in societies where major

social institutions are highly differentiated and have been established for some time since

industrialization took place - such as Britain and the USA - business systems are not as

internally homogenous and mutually distinct as those in recently industrialised societies

which are less institutionally pluralistic” (p. 17) . The more homogeneous, less pluralistic

systems develop particularly “distinctive managerial rationalities and practices”. The social

institutions which emerge from this do not obstruct the market mechanism, but provide

institutional foundations for efficiency. They “are key phenomena in the constitution of

different competitive orders and should not be counterposed to market efficiency”.

The key elements in this framework seem to be as follows. 1) National business systems differ -

in particular with respect to corporate governance. 2) The differences stem from differences in

key social institutions (government regulation, the financial system, labour market institutions,

culture). 3) In contrast, business systems and governance are presumably less influenced by

microeconomic factors like transaction costs. 4) The more differentiated the key social

institutions are, the more differentiated the nature of the business system, and differentiation

may be expected to increase over time as a function of economic development. In particular

greater differentiation is expected in the Anglo-American business system. 5) Individual

business systems develop distinctive, viable business philosophies and ways of doing business.

In principle the elements in this framework are all testable In this paper we test the business

system concept by applying it to explain variations in corporate ownership (a key determinant

of corporate governance) among the 100 largest companies in each of 12 European nations.

Page 5: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

5

Specifically, we test the 4 hypotheses listed below.

Hypothesis 1. Large international/system variations in corporate governance are to beexpected.

Hypothesis 2. In contrast, economic efficiency as expressed in general (cross-country)economic factors, is expected to have little impact on corporate governance becauseeconomic efficiency is socially constructed and the economic rules of the game willdiffer from system to system.

Hypothesis 3. The nation/system differences will be a function of differences in keyinstitutions: government regulation, the nature of the financial system and labourrelations.

Hypothesis 4. Highly developed systems (wealthy, early industrializers) - like the US/UK- will have less uniform corporate governance modes than less developed systems (lateindustrializers).

Page 6: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

6

These hypotheses are explained in the rest of this section and tested in the rest of the paper.

Out viewpoint is that an assessment of the business systems framework requires the discipline

of comparison with alternative theories and hypotheses.

Hypothesis 1. Large international variations in corporate governance are to be expected. The

existence of such differences is a precondition for the relevance of Whitley’ s argument. A

lack of significant international differences would refute the core of the business system

framework. Although Whitley (1994b) has constructed system categories we have chosen to

focus on the national level because of the subjectivity bias inherent in classifying nations by

system.

A theoretical alternative to the business systems view is referred to by Whitley as “economic

rationalism”, under which heading he subsumes both neoclassical and transaction cost

economics and other approaches. An extensive economic literature now exists on corporate

ownership and governance including important contributions by Coase (1937), Demsetz

(1983), Jensen and Meckling (1976), Williamson (1975, 1985, 1996), Hart (1995), Hansmann

(1988, 1996), Fama and Jensen (1983), Putterman (1993), Laffont and Tirole (1993), Shleifer

and Vishny (1997). In economic ownership theory, corporate governance is seen as a cost

efficient response to coordination and incentive problems. For example, ownership

concentration is predicted to decrease with firm size, vertical integration is seen as a solution

to hold up problems under conditions of asset specificity, and government ownership is

Page 7: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

7

regarded as a more or less efficient response to externalities. Often, the theory has abstracted

from system effects except for assuming that transactions take place in a in a free enterprise

economy (“In the beginning there were markets”, Williamson 1975). But this restriction is

arguably a consequence of a parsimonious the analytical approach rather than a result of

inherent inability to deal with such effects, which have in fact been analysed by Williamson

(1993, 1996) and North (1990) among others. And large sub fields within economics do

analyse the causes and effects of various kinds of intervention in the market place (for example

the effect of taxation, market size, dual class shares, etc.), comparative economic systems and

the like. Therefore, the existence of nation effects does not in itself demonstrate the irrelevance

of economic factors such as differences in market size, industry structure etc..

Hypothesis 2. In contrast, economic efficiency as expressed in general (cross-country)

economic factors are expected to have little impact on corporate governance because eco-

nomic efficiency is socially constructed and the economic rules of the game will differ from

system to system. Whitley explicitly recognizes that business systems can be shaped by

industry effects (Whitley 1992 p. 15), i.e. that individual industries can develop their distinct

“business recipes”, but maintains that economic factors “will not generate highly dissimilar

business systems”. In this paper we borrow an analytical approach from industrial economics

(Scherer and Ross 1989) to test this hypothesis: to the extent that corporate governance

structure in given industries tend to be similar across national borders, this can in fact be

regarded as evidence of underlying economic effects which are robust enough to cut across

systems. In other words we test whether there are differences in ownership structure by

Page 8: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

8

industry when controlling for nation effects. While the business system framework is broad

enough to encompass significant industry variation within any single system it cannot explain

why this variation should be correlated across national boundaries.

Hypothesis 3. The nation/system differences will be a function of differences in key institutions:

government regulation, the nature of the financial system and labour relations.. System

differences caused by regulation and alternative financial institutions also figure prominently in

the economic literature. As mentioned, empirical evidence that ownership structures are

influenced by the legal system forms the basis for Roe’ s “political theory” of ownership (Roe

1991, 1994). Specifically, Roe (1991, 1994) argues that the regulation of financial institutions

determines whether countries adopt (US-style) market-based systems with highly dispersed

ownership or (German-style) bank based systems with more concentrated ownership. But

although he hints at a political / public choice explanation Roe does not explicitly address the

question of why politicians in different nations regulate their financial systems the way they do.

We have previously argued (Pedersen and Thomsen 1997) that further progress is possible by

drawing on the new institutional economics, especially North's work on institutions and

efficiency (North 1990) and Williamson´s integration of system parameters into transaction

cost analysis (Williamson 1991, 1993) . Douglas North (1990) highlights the importance of

lock-in effects occurring when regulation allows particular organizational structures to develop

which then reinforce the pattern of regulation. This leads to path dependency because once a

given ownership structure is in existence it will tend to reinforce itself by developing a network

of complementary institutions. For example the Anglo-American market-based model has

Page 9: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

9

created a finely tuned network of investment analysts, stockbrokers and institutional investors

which at the same time improve the efficiency of the system and lobby for its continued

existence and expansion. No comparable network is developed in markets with a high degree

of financial intermediation but here banks or other organizations may assume new functions

and a more powerful political role. The implication is that corporate governance systems are

essentially historically determined, for example (as argued by Whitley) by the historical pattern

of industrialization.

The historical view is essentially a theory of lock-in and path dependency but is less helpful in

analysing (or guiding) institutional change. In caricature, it simply implies that “everything is

the way it is because it was the way it was”. To move beyond this half-tautological level it is

necessary to analyse the effects of particular institutions, changes in which can modify the

workings of the corporate governance system. Although Whitley (1994) emphasizes continuity

and argues that large scale systems change is improbable, substantial changes have taken place

in American corporate governance since the days of J. P. Morgan, in Japanese corporate

governance following the dismantling of the family based Zaibatsus for more loosely knit

Keiretsus, or in German corporate governance since the days of Walter Rathenau and the

dissolution of I.G. Farben. Here, Whitley’ s references to the role of the state, the financial

system and labour organization provide a more specific, although still quite broad, analytical

focus.

One way to make this framework operational is to focus on government regulation which

interferes directly in corporate governance (e.g. legal rules restricting the ownership rights of

financial institutions or foreign ownership, taxation of personal/family ownership vs.

Page 10: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

10

Institutional investors, regulation of board size, composition and responsibility etc.). Another

way is to focus directly on complementary financial institutions, e.g. the size and liquidity of

the national stock market vis-a-vis the banking system. These measures are shown to have

some explanatory power in Pedersen and Thomsen (1997). A third more specific causal

mechanism from institutions to corporate governance is proposed by La Porta et al. (1998a)

who argue that legal systems differ in terms of investor protection and that low rates of

investor protection lead to high rates of ownership concentration as an alternative means to

discipline managers.

The observation that large changes as mentioned above have taken place historically also tend

to discredit casual references to the cultural origins of corporate governance as in the above

quotation by Roe (1994a). The same objections apply to the argument proposed by La Porta

et al. (1997) with a reference to Fukuyama (1995) that low-trust cultures tend to promote

family ownership whereas high-trust cultures can sustain large public corporations with highly

dispersed ownership because they enable a certain level of trust even among anonymous

individuals and trading partners. While culture is difficult to define, there is virtual agreement

in the literature (e.g. Hofstede 1980) that cultures change very slowly, if at all, which seems

inconsistent with the magnitude of these changes. Obviously, this does not preclude that

culture plays an important role as a background for changes in formal institutions as empha-

sized by Whitley, but it means that cultural variables must be supplemented by reference to

other causal mechanisms, for example by reference to changes in the above mentioned formal

institutions: "Because business systems are interdependent with dominant institutions, major

changes in their characteristics depend on related changes in associated institutions"

(Whitley 1994).

Page 11: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

11

Hypothesis 4. Highly developed systems (wealthy, early industrializers) - like the US/UK - will

have less uniform corporate governance modes than less developed systems (late

industrializers). The hypothesis of greater differentiation in more “advanced” economies (like

the US/UK) than in newly industrialized or continental nations can be tested by examining to

what extent the corporate governance structures of UK firms are more or less similar than the

governance structures of firms in the “less advanced” continental nations.

3. The data

Corporate governance - the mechanisms by which companies are controlled and directed - is a

complex subject which is influenced by owner-manager relations, stakeholder relations, board

structures and practices, management compensation, capital structure, company law and other

variables. In this as well as in previous papers (Pedersen and Thomsen 1995, 1997, 1998), we

have chosen to focus on ownership structure, not because other factors are unimportant, but

because corporate ownership is a measurable variable which plays an important role in

economics as well as in management studies. We regard corporate ownership as a structural

determinant of corporate governance. and explore a structure-conduct-performance paradigm

according to which a set of basic conditions (system, industry etc.) determine ownership

structure which then jointly influence company behaviour and ultimately performance.

Page 12: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

12

Although many aspects of corporate governance are directly determined by nation/system

effects we need an independent measure of corporate governance in order to assess the

magnitude and significance of the system effects. And our emphasis on the importance of

ownership structure appears to be compatible with Whitley´s thinking : "Since market

economies are defined largely in terms of private ownership and control of economic

resources and activities, the organization of property rights and the relations between owners

and controllers of resources are key differentiating features of these economies" (1992, p.

157).

We focus on the largest corporations in individual countries, partly because we expect to find

more varied governance structures among these companies. To some extent this may tend to

overstate the impact of nation and systems effects since private ownership (personal/ family

majority ownership) is characteristic for smaller companies in all market economies.

Research in European ownership structures has previously been inhibited by a lack of

publicly available information. Moreover, ownership arrangements are often complex and so is

the legal/institutional environments in which they are embedded. However, the situation has

improved in recent years, and a number of databases (Amadeus, World Scope, Who own

Whom, Directory of Multinationals) now contain ownership information on European

companies. Although the information available is still not comparable to what is obtainable on

US companies, the coverage of large ownership stakes has improved in recent years, and since

ownership structures tend to be more concentrated in Europe, large share holdings are a better

discriminant there than in the US. We use this fact to construct a set of ownership categories

based on the identity and ownership share of the largest owner and the legal form of owner-

Page 13: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

13

ship.

Our viewpoint is that ownership matters for three reasons in particular. First, potential owners

differ (with respect to goals, economic competence, information access, risk preference etc).

Second, legal ownership modes differ (with respect to the bundle of rights allocated to the

owner). Third, the level of ownership concentration determines the trade off between

monitoring efficiency (high concentration) and diversification of risk. Ownership, therefore, has

at least three dimensions: 1) identity (of the largest owner, 2) ownership concentration (share

owned by the largest owner) and 3) the legal form of the company (e.g. proprietorship vs.

cooperative vs. joint stock company).

The ownership categories were constructed in the following way. Information about the

largest owner was found for each of the 100 largest companies in 12 European nations. On

this basis a distinction was made between minority and majority ownership. Thus, minority

ownership implies that the largest owner holds less than 50% of the votes. If the company

turned out to be a cooperative, it was categorized as such. If the largest owner holds less

than 20% of the company's votes, its ownership form was classified as dispersed -

regardless of the owner's identity. If the largest owner holds between 20 and 50% of the

votes, its ownership was categorized as dominant, again regardless of the owner’ s identity.

In case of Majority ownership (defined by the largest owner holding more than 50% of the

votes) the company was classified according to the identity of the majority owner, that is

owned by a single person/family, by the government or by a foreign multinational. An

exact definition of the ownership categories as well as the other variables employed is given

in table 1.

Page 14: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

14

// Insert table 1 around here //

The ownership information was collected for the 100 largest non-financial companies in each

of the following 12 European nations in 1990: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France,

Germany, Great Britain, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Spain and Sweden.

We also collected information about a number of standard variables: industry (63 4-digit ISIC

codes), firm size and a number of nation variables.

4. Nation effects

Table 2 (extracted from Pedersen and Thomsen 1997) documents ownership differences

among 12 European nations using the typology explained in the previous section.

// Insert Table 2 around here//

There appear to be clear differences between European nations. A chi-square test for equal

distribution of ownership categories in all countries confirms the initial impression of

significant differences (Pedersen and Thomsen 1997). In other words, hypothesis 1 is

supported by the data. For example, dispersed ownership is common in Great Britain and

Page 15: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

15

(to a lesser extent) in the Netherlands, but rare or non-existent in the rest of Europe.

Foreign ownership is predominant in Belgium and Spain, but is much less frequent in the

rest of Europe. Government ownership is common in France and Italy, but uncommon in

the Netherlands, Great Britain and Belgium. Cooperatives play a significant role in the

Scandinavian economies and in the Netherlands. Dominant minority ownership (a

characteristic of bank participation) is common in Germany.

But the table fails to support hypothesis 4. The ownership structures in the largest UK

companies are much more similar than in most continental nations where a greater

plurality of ownership structures is generally observed. It may be that greater differentiation

is observed in other sectors of the British economy.

Why do ownership structures differ so much between nations? Informal scrutiny of the table

appears to support some of Whitley’ s basic ideas.

The role of government regulation is evident the extent of government ownership (a radical

form of government intervention) in Europe in general and in particular in France, Italy and

Austria. Apart from the nationalization/privatization waves in France, post world war II

nationalization played a role in Italy and Austria. Along the same lines, openness to foreign

direct investment has been a deliberate Belgian policy which may (along with geographic

location advantages) have assisted the exceptional number of foreign subsidiaries in that

country.

Page 16: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

16

The financial system also appears to play a role. For example, ownership structures are

more dispersed in the UK and in the Netherlands which have well-developed stock markets

than in (bank-based) Germany or the Scandinavian countries, where cooperatives have been

an important source of finance for farm-related products. These patterns may well be

related to

industrialization history as hypothesized by Whitley. A familiar observation in economic

history is that early industrializers like Britain and the Netherlands attracted funds from the

share markets (with highly dispersed ownership), second movers like Germany relied more

on bank finance and the government was seen as having a role in catching up among late

industrializers like Italy and Spain.

However, non-institutional factors may also be important, for example geography may play

a role in terms of country size as well as availability of natural resources (agriculture,

natural resources). For instance, that the high frequency of cooperatives in Denmark and

the Netherlands is associated with a relative specialization in agricultural industries (in

which the frequency of cooperatives is generally high). Country size may also be important

both in terms of market size and via an indirect effect on the size of the largest firms (which

tend to be larger in large countries). However, there are marked differences even among

large countries (Germany, France, UK) and the nation effect remains significant after

controlling for country size (Pedersen and Thomsen 1997).

One final observation to be made in table 2 is the striking dissimilarity of the individual

countries which seems to indicate that classification by broad categories may conceal

Page 17: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

17

important differences between national systems. We experimented with a classification of

the 12 nation into some of the system categories proposed by Whitley (1994):

Partioned (group1): UK, NL

Collaborative (group2): Germany, Denmark, Sweden, Norway and Finland

Co-ordinated (group3): Austria, France, Belgium, Italy, Spain

and found a significant association with the data in table 2. However, the categorization is

subject to some subjectivity bias. And our data also demonstrates major differences within

these system categories which can be meaningfully related to the corporate governance

literature. For example there are major differences between the markets for corporate

control in the UK and the Netherlands, the banking systems in Germany and

Denmark/Norway, the extent of foreign direct investment in Belgium/Spain and France.

We therefore maintaine our focus on national systems of corporate governance.

5. Testing system and economic effects

To test the influence of system vs economic effects on European ownership structures, we

would like a test of the relative importance of general economic factors (firm size, industry)

and nation effects. This is clearly a multi-dimensional problem since we have 6 ownership

categories (into one of which any of our 1200 companies falls) and we seek to explain the

distribution over these 6 categories by firm size (one degree of freedom), industry (62 degrees

of freedom, since we have 63 industries) and nation (11 degrees of freedom since we have 12

Page 18: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

18

nations in the sample). Conventional (parametric) tests of association quickly exhaust the 1200

observations available. However, if we assume a general association in the data (so that a

company located in specific industry has a higher probability of belonging to a particular

ownership category regardless of its nationality), we can use a Cochran-Mantel-Haenszel test

of general association to detect whether significant industry effects remain after controlling for

nation and size effects (table 3).

// Insert table 3 around here //

It turns out that both industry and nation effects have a significant association with

ownership structure. The tests indicate that after controlling for size and industry there are

still distinctly different patterns of ownership structures between the 12 European nations.

The nation effect is significant with a probability of independence (no nation effect) of less

than 0.001, even after controlling for industry and company size.

The results also indicate that industry has a significant influence on corporate ownership

(even after controlling for nation and company size). The distribution of ownership

structures over industries appears to follow a non-random pattern which is generally consistent

with the predictions of general ownership theory (Pedersen and Thomsen 1998). Thus,

cooperatives tend to exist in farm-related businesses. Multinational companies and their

subsidiaries are predominant in scale and scope intensive industries like cars, chemicals or oil,

government ownership is particularly common in classical public utilities (water, electricity,

telecommunication, railroads, postal services). This indicates the existence of general economic

forces which are strong enough to cut across nation/system effects.

Page 19: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

19

Obviously, the existence of significant industry effects does not in itself prove the significance

of economic forces. For example the apparently viable privatization of public utilities in the

UK indicates that government ownership is not given by “laws of nature”. And political

motives appear to have been important for the creation of cooperatives in the Scandinavian

countries. In an assessment of the potential impact of economic forces, we have previously

examined to what extent the observed industry effect could be attributed to classical industry

variables like average firm size, industry growth rates, capital intensity, risk, research intensity

and profit margins (Pedersen and Thomsen 1998). All of these effects were found to be

significant at the 1% level and to explain 58% of the industry effect on ownership structure.

Given industry and national origin, company size (grouped in 10 size categories) does not

seem to have any direct influence on corporate ownership structures (rejecting the null

hypothesis of independence runs a 10.1% risk of error). One reason is no doubt that some

size effects are captured by the nation and industry effects. It is clear that the largest firms in

large nations tend to be relatively large (see Scherer and Ross 1989 p. 63 for some simple

calculations) and it is also clear that firm size tends to vary by industry even comparing

different nations (e.g. Scherer and Ross p. 86). However, since size is a continuous measure

(dollar sales) we can apply standard analysis of variance for a precise, controlled estimation of

the size effect. Table 4 reports ANOVA estimates of the association between firm size

(measured by turnover in US$) and ownership structure.

// Insert table 4 around here //

Page 20: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

20

The findings are very much in accordance with expectations. Statistically speaking, there are 3

distinct size groups at the 5% level of significance (the Duncan groups). These are A)

Companies with dispersed ownership are larger than companies from other ownership

categories. B) Companies with dominant minority and government ownership are smaller than

companies with dispersed ownership, but larger than C) Cooperatives and companies owned

either foreign multinationals, families or single individuals. Naturally, the limited size of the

multinational companies is attributable to the fact that they are national subsidiaries which are

compared to domestic parent companies.

Controlling for nation and industry (main) effects, the size effect remains significant even

though roughly half of the observed effects may be attributable to differences among industries

and nations. There is a tendency, for example, for companies with dispersed ownership to be

larger than companies with dominant minority ownership, on average 2 billion US$ larger, half

of which is potentially attributable to the fact that companies with dispersed ownership tend to

be more frequent in countries and industries that have many large companies. But even within

the same industry and nation companies with dispersed ownership tend to be larger.

Estimating the size-effect relative to dispersed ownership one finds the same size rank order

except that multinational subsidiaries now appear to be smaller than family-owned companies

and cooperatives. This rank change is attributable to the fact that the frequency of multina-

tional subsidiaries is high in nations (like Britain and Germany) and industries (like chemicals)

which have quite large domestic companies.

Page 21: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

21

In conclusion hypothesis 2 (on the relative insignificance of industry effects) is rejected by the

data.

6. The origins of national corporate governance systems

In the following we further examine to what extent the nation effect can be attributed to the

institutional factors which are highlighted in Whitley’ s work. The importance of complemen-

tary institutions is explored in Pedersen and Thomsen (1997), where we find that a large

part of the international variance in ownership structures is potentially attributable to stock

market size, the size of the banking sector, the use of dual class shares and openness with

regard to foreign direct investment. These findings indicate that a substantial share of the

international variation in European ownership structures is attributable to government

regulation and the structure of the national financial systems. In other words, they support

hypothesis 3. The work of Laporta et al. (1998) also tends to support the importance of

government regulation of the financial system for corporate ownership structures.

At first glance Whitley’ s insistence of the importance of labour market organization is

more difficult to apply to the explanation of corporate ownership structures. However, in

some countries (Germany, Scandinavia) strong labour unions have been conceded seats on

the boards of the largest companies which could affect the impact of ownership structure on

Page 22: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

22

company behaviour and performance (and thereby ownership structure, Furubotn and

Pejovich 1974 ).We therefore tested the impact of employee board representation on owner-

ship structure. One hypothesis is that employee representation will limit the control benefits

of large owners, which should reduce ownership concentration. An alternative hypothesis

is that employee representation will stimulate the creation of countervailing power (i.e.

concentration of ownership rights) to ensure that owner interests are represented by the

board.

Table 5 provides a test of the explanatory power of some institutional variables in explaining

the differences in international ownership structure observed in table 2 (stock market size

relative to GDP, mandatory employee representation on boards, regulation of foreign direct

investment).

// Table 5 //

The results confirm that these variables have a statistically significant effect. A large stock

market tends to increase the frequency of dispersed ownership. This may be argued to be

partly a tautology, but substituting the investor protection measure constructed by Laporta et

al (1998) yields similar significant results. We have reported the stock market measure because

it also captures other effects of stock market size than those attributed to the investor

protection measure. Employee representation tends to work in the opposite direction (in

support of the countervailing power hypothesis). Regulation (authorization requirements for

FDI) tends to reduce the frequency of foreign subsidiaries.

Page 23: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

23

However, institutional variables should be tested against an alternative hypothesis. Presumably

both institutional and non-institutional fores may be at work (Demsetz 1998). Table 6

therefore tests the impact of some traditional economic variables: average firm size, the size

and international openness of the economy. As in previous work (Pedersen and Thomsen

1997), we hypothesize that differences in company size are likely to lower the level of

ownership concentration, increase the frequency of government ownership and lower the

frequency of cooperatives. The size of the economy should tend to increase the size of the

stock market and thereby make it more attractive to diversity ownership. The openness of the

economy should increase foreign direct investment and the frequency of foreign ownership.

// Table 6 //

To some extent, these expectations are supported by the data. As documented at the micro-

level in table 4, differences in the size of the largest companies are indeed one cause of the

large international variations in ownership structure. Furthermore, openness of the national

economy tends to increase the frequency of foreign subsidiaries. The size the of the economy

also appears to have a significant effect, but in the opposite direction of what was expected.

Given that both standard economic and institutional variables appear to have a significant

impact, we also test to what extent these effects are compatible by including them in the same

model (table 7).

// Table 7 //

Table 7 demonstrates that both types of explanations remain significant when examined jointly.

Page 24: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

24

The effects of the institutional variables are generally weaker and the effects of regulation on

the frequency of foreign subsidiaries becomes insignificant. However, a large share market is

again found to increase ownership diversification (reduce family and state ownership). And the

level of ownership concentration is again found to be higher in countries with employee

representation on (supervisory) company boards.

Obviously these findings are subject to reverse causality problems. From one perspective a high

trade intensity (a standard economic measure) represents the impact of low trade barriers (an

institutional factors). However, institutions may also be endogenous, for example if small

economies liberalize their trade because they have to rely trade for a substantial part of their

consumption and production. Following North (1990) we believe that causality problems of

this kind are to be expected given the existence of positive feedback and lock-in effects.

In conclusion, the results indicate that both economic and institutional variables influence

ownership structures. In particular, hypothesis 3 is still supported after controlling for standard

economic variables.

7. Discussion

This paper has applied ideas from Richard Whitley’s analysis of business systems to study

ownership structures among the largest 100 companies in 12 European countries. The results

indicate that there are significant nation/system effects which can be attributed at least partly to

the institutional factors highlighted in Whitley’ s framework. On the other hand, we have

documented the existence of significant industry effects, which indicates that general economic

Page 25: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

25

factors as well as system effects shape the governance structures of the largest European

companies. Finally, we have been unable to confirm the existence of larger variation in British

ownership structure than is found on the continent. Our findings therefore support the general

direction of Whitley’ s business systems analysis along with other contributions (La Porta et

al. 1996, 1997, Roe 1991, 1994, Prowse 1995). But our findings are also a tribute to the new

institutional economics, since general ownership theories (hitherto based mainly on US data

seem to apply to other countries as well.

As for policy conclusions, these findings indicate that governments and other actors have

significant discretion in shaping the character of their corporate governance systems, but their

freedom is not infinite. There are general economic forces which need to be taken into

consideration and which can only be ignored at some, potentially high costs. Whitley’ s

assertion of distinct managerial rationalities is only true with some qualifications. We believe

that the recent crisis in East Asian business systems is a case in point. Writing in 1992, Whitley

began his influential book with the following sentence:

“The relative decline of the United States in the wold economy since 1970 and the concomi-

tant rise of Japanese firms in many sectors, have encouraged growing interest in the compar-

ative analysis of business organization, as well as reinforcing doubts about the general

applicability of US management theories and practices” (Whitley 1992).

Now, 6 years later, we are more reluctant to conclude that Japan and other Far Eastern

countries would not have benefited from greater attention to US practices in capital budgeting,

information disclosure, accountability, shareholder value and respect for basic market

Page 26: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

26

mechanisms. Nevertheless, we maintain that Whitley’ s insights regarding the viability of non

US forms of ownership remain true regardless of the present crisis: There is generally more

than one solution to the coordination of economic activity. But neither are there likely to

infinitely many solutions, and to be viable institutions and systems have to pass the joint tests

of technical and institutional efficiency.

As to implications for further research, Whitley and others have made important contributions

by pointing to the importance of system effects on corporate governance (as well as on many

other phenomena) and by highlighting the critical role of government regulation and financial

systems in shaping these systems. These insights deserve to be incorporated into the economic

theory of the firm. But the theory could also be refined considerably by analysing the causes of

institutional differences as well as the mechanism by which they affect the economy. Why, for

example, is the financial system so critical ? Why do governments tend to follow distinct paths

of intervention and regulation? What are the critical policy areas which discriminate between

different systems? And to what extent is company behaviour influenced by the formal

institutions of governance?

References

Agresti, Alan. Categorical Data Analysis. New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1990.Baums, Theodor, Hopt, K. J. and Buxbaum, R. (eds.). Institutional Investors and Cor-

porate Governance. Berlin: de Gruyter, 1994.Charkham, Jonathan P. Keeping Good Company - A Study of Corporate Governance in

Five Countries. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1994.Coase, Ronald H. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica (New series), 4 (1937), pp. 386-405Demsetz. Harold. “The Structure of Ownership and The Theory of the Firm.” Journal of Law

and Economics, 26 (1983), pp. 375-390.Demsetz, Harold. “On the Contrast Between Institutional and Non-Institutional Sources of

Economic Growth.” Paper presented to the second annual meeting of the international

Page 27: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

27

society for the new institutional economics, Paris, September 1998.Demsetz, Harold and Lehn, Kenneth . “The Structure of Corporate Ownership: Causes and

Consequences.” Journal of Political Economy, 93(1985), pp. 1155-1177.Debreu, Gerard. The Theory of Value. An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium. John

Wiley. New York, 1959.Fama, Eugene F. and Michael C. Jensen. “Agency Problems and Residual Claims.” Journal of

Law and Economics, 26(1983), pp. 327-49.Foss, Nicolai J. “Understanding Business Systems: An Essay on the Economics and

Sociology of Organization.” International Studies in Management and Organization,this issue.

Franks, Julian and Mayer, Colin. “Takeovers: Capital Markets and Corporate Control: AStudy of France, Germany and the UK.” Economic Policy, 14(1990),. pp. 189-231.

Franks, Julian and Mayer, Colin. “Ownership and Control.” In Horst Siebert (ed.). Trends inBusiness Organization: Do Participation and Cooperation Increase Competitive-ness? Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr. 1995.

Fukuyama, Francis. Trust. New York: Free Press, 1995.Furubotn, Erik And Pejovich, S. The Economics of Property Rights. Cambridge, Mass.:

Ballinger, 1974.Hansmann, Henry. 1988. “Ownership of the Firm.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organi-

zation, 4(1988), pp. 267-305.Hansmann, Henry. The Ownership of Enterprise. Cambridge Mass.: The Belknap Press of

Harvard University Press. 1996.Hart, O. 1995. Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structures. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Hofstede, Geert. “Culture and Organizations.” International Studies of Management and

Organization 10(1980) pp.15-27.Hoshi, Takao. “Understanding Japanese Corporate Governance”. Paper presented at the

Asia Research Centre, Department of International Economics and Management,Copenhagen Business School, September 1997.

Jensen, M. and Meckling, W. “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behaviour, Agency Costs, andOwnership Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics, 3 (1976), pp. 305-360

Laffont J.-J. and Tirole, J. . A Theory of Incentives in Regulation and Procurement. Cam-bridge, MA: MIT Press, 1993.

Laporta, Rafael; Lopez-de-Silanes; Shleifer, A; Vishny; R. W. 1997. “Trust in Large Organiza-tions”. American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings, American Eco-nomic Review, 87(1997) , p. 333-339.,

Laporta, Rafael; de-Silanes Lopez; Shleifer, Andrei; Vishny, Robert W. 1998a. “Law andFinance”. Discussion Paper Number 1768. Harvard Institute of Economic Research.Harvard University. Cambridge, AM,. 02138. June. 1996. Journal of PoliticalEconomy, Forthcoming.

Laporta, Rafael; de-Silanes Lopez; Shleifer, Andrei. “Corporate Ownership Around theWorld”, unpublished working paper, Second Draft, 1998b.

Moerland, Peter W. “Corporate Ownership and Control Structures: An International Compari-son.” Review of Industrial Organization, 10(1995), pp. 443-464

North, Douglas C. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance.Cam-bridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.

Pedersen, Torben and Thomsen, Steen.”European Models of Corporate Governance.” Papersand proceedings. European International Business Academy Annual Meeting,

Page 28: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

28

Urbino, December 1995, pp. 315-333.Pedersen, Torben and Thomsen, Steen. “European Patterns of Corporate Ownership: A

Twelve Country Study”. Journal of International Business Studies, 28 (1997), pp.759-778.

Pedersen, T. and Thomsen, S. “Industry and Ownership Structure”. Working Paper,Copenhagen Business School, WP-6-1997. International Review of Law andEconomics, Forthcoming, 1998.

Porter, Michael E. Capital Disadvantage: America's Failing Capital Investment System.Harvard Business Review, 70(1992), pp. 65-82.

Prentice, D. D. & P. R. J. Holland, editors. Contemporary Issues in CorporateGovernance. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1993.

Prowse, Stephen. 1995. Corporate Governance in an International Perspective: A Survey ofCorporate Control Mechanisms AmongLarge Firms in the U.S., U.K., Japan and Germany. Financial Markets,Institutions and Instruments, 4 (1995), pp.

Putterman, Louis. “Ownership and the Nature of the Firm.” Journal of ComparativeEconomics, 17(1993), pp. 243-63

Roe, Mark J. A Political Theory of Corporate Finance. Columbia Law Review, 1(1991), pp.10-67.

Roe, Mark J. “Some Differences in Corporate Governance in Germany, Japan and America.”In Baums, T., T. Buxbaum & K. J. Hopt, editors. Institutional Investors and Cor-porate Governance. Berlin: de Gruyter, 1994a..

Roe, Mark J. Strong Managers, Weak Owners - the Political Roots of American CorporateFinance. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994b.

Scherer, Frederich. M. & Ross, David. Industrial Market Structure and Economic Perfor-mance. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1989.

Shepherd, William. G. Public Enterprise: Criteria and Cases. In H. W. de Jong, editor,The Structure of European Industry. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers,1989.

Shleifer, Andrei. “Government in Transition.” European Economic Review, 41(1997), pp.385-410.

Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert. W. ”Large Shareholders and Corporate Control.” Journal of Political Economy, 95 (1986), pp. 461-488.

Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert. W. “A Survey of Corporate Governance.” Journal ofFinance, 52(1997), pp. 737-783.

Whitley, Richard. Business Systems in Asia: Firms, Markets and Societies. London: Sage,1992.

Whitley, Richard. “Dominant Forms of Organization in Market Economies”. OrganizationStudies 15(1994), pp. 153-182.

Whitley, Richard. And Kristensen, P. The Changing European Firm. London.: Routledge,1996.

Williamson, Oliver E. Markets and Hierarchies. Free Press.1975.Williamson, Oliver E. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Free Press.1985.Williamson, Oliver E. “Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete

Structural Alternatives.” Administrative Science Quarterly, 36 (1991), pp. 269-296.

Williamson, Oliver E. “Transaction Cost Economics and Organization Theory”, Industrial

Page 29: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

29

and Corporate Change, 2(1993), pp. 107-156.Williamson, Oliver E. The Mechanisms of Governance. N.Y, Oxford University Press. 1996.

Page 30: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

OWNERSHIP CATEGORY (as of 1990)1. Dispersed ownership: No single owner owns more than 20% of the company's shares.2. Dominant ownership: one owner (person, family, company) owns a sizeable (voting) share (20% < share < 50%) of the company.3. Personal/family ownership: one person or a family owns a (voting) majority of the company. We include in this category foundation (trust) ownership because it reflects the will of a personal founder and often gives the family (heirs) some degree of control.4. Government ownership: the (local or national) government owns a (voting) majority of the company5. Foreign ownership: a foreign multinational (MNE) owns a (voting) majority of the company.6. Cooperatives: the company is registered as a cooperative or (in a few cases) ma- jority owned by a group of cooperatives.

INDUSTRY (4-digit ISIC code. 63 industries, Europe’ s Largest Companies and othersources).

FIRM SIZE..(turnover bill. US$, average 1990-1993, Europe’ s largest companies andother sources).

COUNTRY VARIABLESStock market relative to GDP (World Competitiveness Report 1991)Are Employees entitled to seats on the board of Large Companies? (Buxbaum1994 and other sources)Authoritization required for Foreign Direct Investment? (Dummy, OECD 1992)Average Company Size by nation (turnover bill. US$, average 1990-1993).Size of the Economy (LOG GDP US$ 1990, World Competitiveness Report 1991) )Trade Intensity (Exports,/GDP, World Competitiveness Report 1991)

Page 31: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

Ownership type Nation Average share oflargestowner(%)

Dispersedownership

Dominantownership

Familyowned

Foreign owned

Coopera-tive

Govern-mentowned

Belgium 76.5 4 20 6 61 3 6

Denmark 67.8 10 9 30 23 17 11

Finland 64.5 12 25 23 11 10 19

France 54.6 16 28 15 16 3 22

Germany 62.8 9 30 26 22 3 10

GreatBritain

30.7 61 11 6 18 1 3

Italy 71.6 0 22 20 29 0 29

Nether-lands

56.2 23 16 7 34 13 7

Norway 75.9 6 14 29 19 19 13

Spain 61.2 6 22 8 45 5 14

Sweden 65.2 4 31 18 14 12 21

* Cooperatives are not included in the calculation of the average ownership share.

Page 32: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

Hypothesis Control variables Probability of independence Ownership _|_ Nation | Size Industry 0.000 Ownership _|_ Industry | Size Nation 0.000 Ownership _|_ Size | Nation Industry 0.101

-------------------------------------------------------------------------Explanation: _|_ = association with |= given the control variables

On average we have 1200/6=200 observations per ownership category which could in principlebe explained by 62*11=682 nation-specific industry effects. To overcome this problem we relyon the the Cohran-Mantel-Haenszel test which calculates a measure of the deviation betweenactual ownership patterns and what these patterns would look like if they were independentof the variables in question (the deviations are weighted by their variance). This is done foreach level of the control variables and the scores are added up. The test value in theCochran-Mantel-Haenszel test is (Agresti 1990):

Value = (n - m)' V-1 (n - m)

where n is the vector of the cell counts in the frequency table for ownership mode andcountry on each level of company size and industry, m is the vector of the expected valuesunder the condition of independence and V-1 (n - m) is the inverse variance of the value (n-m). The test value follows a hyper geometrical distribution which for large n approaches achi-square distribution. Large test values indicate large deviations from what the data wouldhave looked like under the hypothesis of independence and lead to a rejection of thehypothesis.

The test is weak to the extent that there can be different kinds of (possibly contradictory)associations in different strata of the data, so a rejection of a significant association does notmean that no association exists (it may be that belonging to a certain industry in Spain hasthe opposite effect of belonging to the same industry in Britain, but that on aggregate theycancel out so that no general association exists). In contrast, significance of the CMH testis a fairly strong indication that significant correlations exist (which are strong enough to cutacross possible counter-effects in different sub-strata).

Page 33: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

OWNERSHIPCATEGORY

Av. Turnover(billion US$)

DuncanGroup

Effect relativeto dispersedownership

Relative effectcontrolling for

nation andindustry

Dispersed 6.1 A

Dominant 3.9 B -2.2 -1

Government 3.5 B -2.6 -1.4

Foreign Multi-national

1.9 C -4.2 -3.2

Family 1.9 C -4.2 -1.9

Cooperative 1.1 C -5 -2

Page 34: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

Table 5. Effect of institutional variables on ownership modes(Multinomial logistic regression).

OWNERSHIPCATEGORY

Stock market size Employeerepresentation(dummy)

Authorization onFDI (dummy)

Dispersed 0 0 0

Dominant -0.0614*** 0.7137*** 0.1151

Family -799 1.6187*** 0.3501

Foreign -686 0.4832* 0.9700***

State -919 0.9905*** 0.1944

Cooperative -491 1.7013 0.03

Chisquare 146.4*** 35.2*** 73.9***

The effect on dispersed ownership function is used as a baseline*** and ** = significantly different from the effect on dispersed ownership at the 1% and 5%significance levels respectively.

Page 35: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

Table 6. Effect of economic variables variables on ownership modes (Multinominal logistic regression).

OWNERSHIPCATEGORY

Average Companysize

Size of the economy(log GDP)

Trade intensity(Exports % of GDP)

Dispersed 0 0 0

Dominant -0.9829*** 2.4148*** -0.0002

Family -0.9337*** 1.8473*** -0.0165**

Foreign -1.2214*** 2.8896*** 0.0179***

State -1.1089*** 2.4389*** -0.0144

Cooperative -0.7715*** 0.8842* -0.0064*

Chisqaure 161.6457*** 116.0547*** 73.0579***

The effect on dispersed ownership function as a baseline in calculating the interaction effect *** and ** = significantly different from the effect on dispersed ownership at the 1% and 5%significance levels respectively.

Page 36: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

Table 7.Combined effects of institutional and economic variables on ownership modes (Multinomial logistic regression).

OWNERSHIPCATEGORY

Stock market size Employeerepresentation(dummy)

Authorization onFDI (dummy)

Average Com-pany size

Size of the econ-omy(log GDP)

Trade intensity(Exports % ofGDP)

Dispersed 0 0 0 0 0 0

Dominant -0.0208 0.9812*** -0.7714** -0.5512*** 1.6827*** 0.0230**

Family -0.0390*** 1.4226*** -0.0949 -0.3856** 0.7449 -0.0055

Foreign -0.0094 0.8858*** -0.1289 -0.8200*** 2.0494*** 0.0302***

State -0.0382** 1.0425*** -0.2277 -0.5919*** 1.4383*** 0.0055

Cooperative -0.0073 1.1570*** -0.2277 0.4278 0.2462 0.0077

Chisquare 14.0** 13.3** 26.2*** 34.7*** 40.8*** 37.7***

The effect on dispersed ownership function is used as a baseline*** and ** = significantly different from the effect on dispersed ownership at the 1% and 5% significance levels respectively.

Page 37: Pederseon-Business Systems and Corporate Governance

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Poul Andersen and Nicolai Foss for helpful comments.