pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

  • Upload
    hop-luu

  • View
    224

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    1/24

    The underinvestment and overinvestment hypotheses: An

    analysis using panel data

    Artur MORGADO

    Instituto Politcnico de Coimbra (Portugal)

    Julio PINDADO

    Universidad de Salamanca (Spain)

    Address for correspondence:

    Julio Pindado

    Dpto. de Administracin y Economa de la Empresa

    Campus Miguel de Unamuno

    Universidad de Salamanca

    37007 Salamanca

    Telfono: (923) 294400

    294640 Ext. 3506

    Fax: (923) 294715

    E-mail: [email protected]

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    2/24

    2

    The underinvestment and overinvestment hypotheses: An analysis

    using panel data

    ABSTRACT

    In this paper we study the relationship between firm value and investment in order to

    test the underinvestment and overinvestment hypotheses. The results obtained, using

    panel data methodology as the estimation method, indicate that the abovementioned

    relation is quadratic, whichimplies that thereexists an optimal level of investment. As a

    consequence, firms that invest less than the optimal level suffer from an

    underinvestment problem, while those firms that have a level of investment higher than

    the optimum suffer from an overinvestment problem. The aforementioned quadratic

    relation is maintained when firms are classified depending on their investment

    opportunities. Moreover, in accordance with the theory, those firms with valuable

    investment opportunities maintain an optimal level of investment higher than that of

    those whose investment opportunities are of low quality.

    1. INTRODUCTION

    In a world of perfect capital markets, Modigliani and Miller (1958) demonstrated that

    investment, financing and dividend decisions are independent. During the last decades,

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    3/24

    3

    however, the empirical evidence has shown that those decisions are interdependent.

    Accordingly, some theories that explain the previous evidence have been developed.

    These theories are based on capital-market imperfections; in particular, with respect to

    the investment decision, the existence of asymmetric information between the main

    stakeholders is the foremost imperfection.

    The role of the asymmetry of information in investment decisions has as its

    primary basis the theoretical works of Jensen and Meckling (1976), Myers (1977) and

    Myers and Majluf (1984). The first two papers emphasize the consequences of the

    existence of post-contract asymmetric information between shareholders and

    bondholders, while the paper of Myers and Majluf (1984) emphasizes the role of the

    pre-contract asymmetric information between current and prospective shareholders. All

    the abovementioned papers show that informational asymmetries may lead to some

    investment projects with a positive net present value (NPV) not being undertaken. A

    second foundation in the study of inefficient investment decisions is the work of Jensen

    (1986). This paper, starting from the hypothesis of the existence of asymmetric

    information between managers and shareholders, introduces the so-called problem of

    overinvestment, as a basic argument of his free cash flow theory. According to this

    theory there can be negative NPV investment projects that end up being completed. In this way, whenever an underinvestment process or an overinvestment process

    arises the value of the firm will be affected. Thus, it is worthwhile to hypothesize that

    the relationship between investment and firm value is not monotonic but rather

    increases up to one determined optimal level and decreases after this level. Firms will

    first undertake those investment projects with a positive NPV and the firm value will

    grow until the positive NPV projects become exhausted. Those firms that continue

    investing will undertake negative NPV projects and, hence, their market value will

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    4/24

    4

    decrease. In this context, levels lower than the optimum confirm the underinvestment

    hypothesis and levels higher than the optimum, the overinvestment hypothesis.

    To test the main hypothesis put forward in our paper, that is, that the relationship

    between firm value and investment is quadratic rather than linear, we havedeveloped a

    model that relates firm value and investment, incorporating a quadratic term of

    investment in the equation. The results obtained in the estimation of this model allow us

    to conclude that the abovementioned hypothesis is verified. We also study the

    relationship between firm value and investment depending on the quality of investment

    opportunities. In this case, the results also confirm the previous hypothesis and show

    that the optimal level of investment is higher for those firms with valuable investment

    opportunities.

    The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section II describes the

    underinvestment and overinvestment hypotheses in orderto develop a model that relates

    firm value and investment in Section III. In Section IV we present the database, explain

    the estimation method and discuss the results. Finally, our conclusions are presented in

    Section V.

    2. THE UNDERINVESTMENT AND OVERINVESTMENTHYPOTHESES

    In imperfect capital markets, financing and investment decisions are not independent. In

    fact, capital-market imperfections, such as informational asymmetries and agency costs,

    could lead to either underinvestment or overinvestment processes, that is, not all

    positive NPV projects will be undertaken and some negative NPV projects will not be

    rejected. Informational asymmetries contribute to several conflicts between the main

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    5/24

    5

    stakeholders, which give rise to either overinvestment or underinvestment processes.

    Next, we describe these topics and how they are connected, following Figure I.

    Given the limited liability of shareholders, they are encouraged to invest in

    riskier investment projects than those initially defined in the loan conditions. This is due

    to the fact that riskier projects are expected to give larger benefits which will be mainly

    enjoyed by the shareholders; whereas if large losses occur, these will be passed on to

    the bondholders (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). In this case, the well-known problem of

    asset substitution arises. When post-contract asymmetric information exists, and given

    the impossibility of developing full contracts, such asymmetry of information could

    induce costs for shareholders, since bondholders discount the prospective substitution of

    assets. Thus, either the rise in interest rates, credit rationing or the imposition of limiting

    conditions in investment or financing terms, may limit the capacity of the shareholders

    to develop their investment projects. This problem of asset substitution between

    shareholders and bondholders is, therefore, one of the mechanisms that lead to

    underinvestment.

    The conflict between shareholders and bondholders also gives rise to a problem

    of underinvestment by moral hazard. Given the priority of bondholders in case of

    bankruptcy, shareholders may find themselves in a situation where bondholders

    appropriate part of the value created. Therefore, shareholders will have an incentive to

    abandon NPV projects whenever the NPV is lower than the amount of debt issued

    (Myers, 1977). Thus, bondholders will try to prevent those suboptimal investment

    policies being adopted by using several mechanisms, such as debt covenants, the

    reduction of the stated periods of loan, and greater supervision and control. However, all

    these procedures only imply a slight mitigation of the problem and, moreover, their cost

    is ultimately borne by the shareholders.

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    6/24

    6

    Additionally, the conflict between shareholders and bondholders also gives rise

    to a problem of underinvestment by adverse selection. This problem arises from the

    higher premium required by bondholders, since they do not have enough information to

    distinguish the quality of the different investment projects of the firm (Stiglitz and

    Weiss, 1981). Thus, if the investment outlay of all positive NPV projects is higher than

    the internal funds available, the firm might forgo those investment projects rather than

    issue risky debt.

    The conflict between current and prospective shareholders may also lead to

    underinvestment caused by adverse selection. Myers and Majluf (1984) proved that, due

    to pre-contract asymmetric information between prospective and current shareholders in

    relation to the investment projects and the assets in place, the firm might forgo positive

    NPV projects. Owing to informational asymmetries the prospective shareholders are

    unaware of the firm value and raise the price at which they offer funds. With this price

    the existing shareholders may lose more if the investment projects are undertaken than

    they would if the investment projects are abandoned.

    In summary, the conflicts between bondholders and shareholders and the current

    and prospective shareholders may lead to underinvestment processes.

    Moreover, the overinvestment process arises from the conflict between

    managers and shareholders. When informational asymmetries exist, and taking into

    account that the mechanisms used to align the interests between shareholders and

    managers may not be fully efficient, managers may use the free cash flow to undertake

    negative NPV projects in their own best interest (Jensen, 1986). Note that free cash flow

    is cash flow in excess of that required to fund all positive NPV projects, hence

    managers waste these funds instead of paying them to shareholders. Managers will have

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    7/24

    7

    incentives to overinvest because of the pecuniary and non-pecuniary benefits associated

    with the larger dimension of the firm (Jensen, 1986; Stulz, 1990).

    The empirical evidence on the underinvestment hypothesis was initially

    developed through the successive studies on the sensitivity of investment to cash flow,

    especially after the methodological innovative study by Fazzari et al. (1988).1 Almost

    all these studies 2 find a strong dependence of investment on the availability of internal

    funds, this dependence being interpreted as evidence of the underinvestment problem by

    adverse selection. However, the positive relationship found between investment and

    cash flow may not arise only from the underinvestment problem by adverse selection. It

    may also indicate that high levels of cash flow allow managers to undertake negative

    NPV projects, which would not happen if they had to raise external funds and explain

    the rationality of their investments. The study by Vogt (1994) allows us to distinguish

    both effects and obtain empirical evidence of both problems (underinvestment and

    overinvestment) depending on the different features of the firms. Thus, the

    overinvestment hypothesis is confirmed whenever the positive relationship between

    investment and cash flow is maintained for firms whose investment opportunities are of

    low quality. On the contrary, for firms with valuable investment opportunities, a

    positive relationship indicates an underinvestment problem.

    There are also several papers that obtain empirical evidence on each of the

    hypotheses using the event study methodology. These studies analyse the reaction of the

    market to announcements of investment decisions (see for example Doukas, 1995;

    Vogt, 1997; Chen and Ho, 1997) or to announcements of dividend decisions (see for

    example Lang and Litzenberger, 1989), distinguishing the firms according to their

    investment opportunities and/or free cash flow level. In general, these studies provide

    evidence that abnormal returns are larger for the firms with valuable investment

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    8/24

    8

    opportunities. However, the evidence on the free cash flow effect is not so clear (see

    Chen and Ho, 1997).3

    The underinvestment and overinvestment problems have also been studied

    through other perspectives. For instance, Lang et al. (1996) obtain favourable evidence

    on the overinvestment hypothesis, when finding that high ratios of indebtedness limit

    the development of investment projects only for the firms whose investment

    opportunities are of low quality. Nohel and Tarhan (1998) also find evidence in

    accordance with the free cash flow theory by studying the effect of the reacquisition of

    shares on the operational performance of firms. Adedeji (1998) obtains mixed evidence

    on the underinvestment hypothesis by studying the simultaneous interrelation between

    the investment, financing and dividend decisions. Finally, Miguel and Pindado (2001)

    conclude that, in a context of asymmetric information, firms are worried either by the

    underinvestment problem or by the overinvestment problem depending on their cash

    flow and debt levels, thus corroborating the trade-off between underinvestment and

    overinvestment considered by Stulz (1990).

    As a consequence of the abovementioned empirical evidence, nowadays there is

    a generalized consensus on the distortions that informational asymmetries introduce into

    the investment decision. Thus, contrary to the hypothesis of perfect capital markets

    maintained by Modigliani and Miller (1958), informational asymmetries could lead to

    underinvestment or overinvestment processes. Both problems will affect the firms

    value since, on the one hand, positive NPV projects will not be undertaken and, on the

    other hand, negative NPV projects will not be rejected. Hence, when a firm becomes

    affected by an underinvestment problem, if an additional investment is undertaken the

    market value should increase. If the problem is one of overinvestment, any additional

    investment must negatively affect the wealth of the shareholders. Assuming as a

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    9/24

    9

    reasonable hypothesis that the investment projects of greater NPV will always be

    undertaken in first place, even in the managers own best interest (Stulz, 1990), the

    market value will increase until a certain investment level is reached. After that

    optimum the market value will start to decrease. Therefore, the main hypothesis to

    prove in our paper is: the relationship between market value and investment is

    quadratic, implyingthat there exists an optimal level. Levels below the optimal one will

    confirm the underinvestment hypothesis while higher levels will confirm the

    overinvestment one (see Figure II).

    3. SPECIFICATION OF THE MODEL

    In order to test the hypothesis mentioned in the previous section, we develop a model

    that relates the value of the shares of the firm to its main financial decisions, taking into

    account the behaviour of the investment variable described above:

    (V it /Ki,t-1)=0 + 1(I it /Ki,t-1) + 2(I it /K i,t-1)2 + 3(B it /Ki,t-1)+ 4(D it /Ki,t-1)+ eit

    (1)

    where Vit is the market value of the shares of firm i at the end of period t, Iit is the

    investment undertaken by firm i in period t, Bit is the increment of the market value of

    the long-term debt, Dit are the dividends paid in period t, and finally Ki,t-1 is the

    replacement value of the assets at the end of period t-1.4

    The model defined in equation (1) relates investment and firm value, controlling

    the other two main financial decisions of the firm, that is, financing and dividends

    decisions, which could affect firm value due to the existence of market imperfections.

    The expected relationship between increment of debt and firm value is positive, since,

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    10/24

    10

    whenever the bankruptcy probability is not very high, an increment of debt will have a

    positive effect on the wealth of the shareholders because new debt means obtaining new

    tax-shields. The expected relationship between dividends and firm value is also positive,

    because in addition to the possible effects in relation to the imperfections, dividends are

    a source of value creation for the shareholders of the firm. Note that the well-known

    capital-market arbitrage condition stipulates that the net after-tax return for shareholders

    may be obtained in two ways: from capital appreciation and from current dividends (see

    Whited, 1992; Blundell et al., 1992).

    As we have commented in the previous section, the overinvestment and

    underinvestment processes are not exclusive and must affect the market value of the

    firm. Thus, if a firm is facing by an underinvestment problem, a marginal increase in

    investment must positively affect the market value of the shares, while the effect will be

    negative if the problem is one of overinvestment. Therefore, an optimal level of

    investment will exist, which is reflected in the model since weincorporated in equation

    (1) the investment variable and its square.

    Consequently, if, after estimating the model, we differentiate the firm value

    variable with respect to the investment variable, we would obtain:

    +=

    1

    21

    1

    12

    it

    it

    it

    it

    it

    it

    K

    I

    K

    I

    K

    V

    (2)

    then, making the first derivative equal to 0 and solving for the investment variable, we

    obtain:

    2

    1

    1 2

    =

    it

    it

    K

    I(3)

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    11/24

    11

    Finally, if the second partial derivative of the firm value variable with respect to

    the investment variable is negative, the value obtained from equation (3) will be a

    maximum.

    2

    1

    2

    1

    2

    2=

    it

    it

    it

    it

    K

    I

    K

    V

    (4)

    Accordingly, in order to obtain a maximum from equation (3), 2 should be

    negative. Also, for the optimal level of the investment determined in equation (3) to be

    positive, 1 should be positive. Consequently, if the signs of these coefficients hold

    when equation (1) is estimated our main hypothesis will be proved.

    If the previous hypothesis is verified, we can also, in agreement with the theory,

    put forward an additional hypothesis: that the optimal level of investment will be

    different depending on the quality of investment opportunities. To be exact, the

    abovementioned optimal level will have to be higher for those firms that have valuable

    investment opportunities. In order to test this hypothesis, we define a dummy variable

    for each firm, DQi, which is equal to 1 for those firms that during the period have an

    average Tobins q less than one, and 0 otherwise. Thus, we extended the specification of

    the model in equation (1) by incorporating a dummy variable that interacts with the linear

    and quadratic terms of the investment variable. This dummy variable represents the

    quality of investment opportunities. Therefore, the new model would be as follows:

    (V it /Ki,t-1) = 0 + (1 + 1DQ i) (I it /Ki,t-1) + (2+ 2DQ i) (I it /Ki,t-1)2 + 3(B it /Ki,t-1)+

    4 (Dit/Ki,t-1) + eit (5)

    Thus, we classify the firms in two groups: when Tobins q is less than 1, firms

    are classified as non-valuable project firms (hereafter, NVP firms), otherwise they are

    classified as valuable project firms (hereafter, VP firms). In this new model, 1 and 2

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    12/24

    12

    are the coefficients that define the optimal level of investment for VP firms, since for

    those firms DQi is equal to 0. Hence, the optimal level for VP firms will be obtained

    using equation (3). However, for NVP firms DQi takes the value of 1, therefore the

    optimal level will be obtained through the following equivalent equation:

    ( )22

    11

    1 2

    ++

    =

    it

    it

    K

    I(6)

    Based on this new model, as it appears in Figure III, we therefore put forward

    the following additional hypothesis: the optimal level of investment for VP firms,

    (Iit/Ki,t-1)q>1

    , will be higher than the optimal level of investment for NVP firms, (Iit/Ki,t-

    1)q

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    13/24

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    14/24

    14

    an individual effect, i. Hence, we took first differences of the variables in order to

    eliminate the individual effect. We also included the dummy variables dt to measure the

    time effect, so as to control the effect of macroeconomic variables on firm value.

    Consequently, we split the error term into three components: the individual effect, i,

    the time effect, dt, and, finally, the random disturbance, it. As a result, the final

    specification of the models to estimate is as follows:

    (Vit /Ki,t-1) = 0 + 1(I it /Ki,t-1) + 2(I it /Ki,t-1)2 + 3(B it /Ki,t-1)+ 4(D it /Ki,t-1)+ dt +

    i + it (7)

    (Vit /Ki,t-1)=0 + (1 + 1DQ i) (I it /Ki,t-1) + (2+ 2DQ i) (I it /Ki,t-1)2

    + 3(B it /Ki,t-1)+

    4 (Dit/Ki,t-1) + dt + i + it (8)

    The estimation was carried out using DPD98 for GAUSS written by Arellano

    and Bond (1998). In order to check for potential mis-specification of the models we use

    the Sargan statistic of over-identifying restrictions, which tests for the absence of

    correlation between the instruments and the error term. Another specification test used

    is the m2 statistic, developed by Arellano and Bond (1991), to test for lack of second-

    order serial correlation in the first-difference residuals. Finally, besides the

    aforementioned specification tests, Table 4 provides two Wald tests: the first (z1) is a

    test of the joint significance of the reported coefficients, while the second (z2) is a test of

    the joint significance of the time dummies. As can be seen in Table 4, our models pass

    all the abovementioned tests.

    4.3 RESULTS

    The results obtained verify our main hypothesis. As can be seen in column I of Table 4,

    1 is positive and 2 is negative, both coefficients being significant. These results

    indicate that the relationship between investment and firm value is quadratic rather than

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    15/24

    15

    linear. That is, a marginal increase in investment has a positive effect on the wealth of

    shareholders whenever the optimal investment level has not yet been exceeded. This

    level reflects the beginning of the exhaustion of positive NPV projects.

    According to the results shown in column I of Table 4 and substituting the

    values obtained for the coefficients 1 and 2 into equation (3), we find that the optimal

    level of investment is 0.4558. This implies that, in general terms, firms keep investing

    in positive NPV projects until this level is reached, and hence the value of their shares

    keeps rising. However, once this optimal level has been reached firms undertake

    negative NPV projects and, thus, the value of their shares decreases. In this way, the

    results obtained confirm both the underinvestment and the overinvestment hypotheses.

    The former for those firms whose level of investment is lower than the optimum,

    therefore located in Figure II to the left of (Iit/Ki,t-1)*. The latter for those firms whose

    investment level is located to the right of (Iit/Ki,t-1)*.

    The fact that the investment level is located to the left of the optimumindicates

    that the firms suffer from financial constraints which do not allow them to undertake all

    the positive NPV projects at any time. Therefore, these firms are facing an

    underinvestment process. The financial constraints suffered by those firms are due to

    the higher premium required by bondholders or prospective shareholders. This higher

    premium is due to either the conflict between shareholders and bondholders or the

    conflict between current and prospective shareholders. On the contrary, when the firms

    investment level is located to the right of the optimum, this indicates that the firms are

    undertaking negative NPV projects. These negative NPV investments do not increase

    the wealth of shareholders. Hence, they are only undertaken to maximize the objective

    function of the managers, and so firms are in the face of an overinvestment process. The

    overinvestment process arises when managers waste free cash flow instead of paying

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    16/24

    16

    these funds to shareholders; this behaviour is caused by the conflict between

    shareholders and managers.

    All the other variables in the model also show significant coefficients. The

    increment of debt variable has a positive coefficient, due to the new tax-shields

    obtained. The coefficient for the dividends variable is also positive. This latter result

    indicates that the dividends paid in the period are one of the sources of value creation

    for shareholders, as stipulated in the capital-market arbitrage condition.

    Column II of Table 4 provides the results of the estimation of model II,

    developed to study the relationship between firm value and investment depending on

    the quality of investment opportunities. Before discussing these results let us point out

    that 1 and 2 are, respectively, the coefficients for the investment and the square

    investment variables for VP firms, while in the case of NVP firms the coefficients for

    the abovementioned variables are (1+1) and (2 +2). Therefore, as 1 is positive and

    2 is negative, we can affirm that the relationship between firm value and investment is

    quadratic for VP firms. However, before interpreting the coefficients for NVP firms, we

    must perform two linear restriction tests in order to check whether these coefficients are

    significantly different from zero. As Table 4 shows, the null hypothesis H0: 1+1 = 0 is

    rejected, since the t1 statistic takes the value of 32.3175, and the null hypothesis H0: 2

    +2= 0 can also be rejected, since the t2 statistic takes the value of 35.4839. Therefore,

    both (1+1)=0.3869 and (2 +2)=0.6867 are significantly different from zero, and their

    signs allow us to confirm the previous quadratic relationship also for NVP firms.

    Furthermore, by substituting the values obtained for 1 and 2 in equation (3), we find

    that the optimal level of investment for VP firms is 0.7774. The optimal level of

    investment for NVP firms is 0.2837, as can be verified by substituting (1+1) and (2

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    17/24

    17

    +2) in equation (6). These results support the relationship between investment and firm

    value posed in model I, where the optimal level of investment obtained for the whole

    sample of firms is 0.4558. Thus, in agreement with our second hypothesis, the following

    is verified: (Iit/Ki,t-1)q1. Finally, in model II, the significance

    and sign of the other variables remain, thus confirming the results obtained in model I.

    5. CONCLUSIONS

    This paper tests the following main hypothesis: the relationship between firm value and

    investment is quadratic, which implies that an optimal level of investment exists; levels

    lower than the optimum confirm the underinvestment hypothesis and higher levels the

    overinvestment one.

    The results obtained allow us to conclude that the abovementioned hypothesis is

    fulfilled. In fact, there exists an optimal level of investment, which is the level where the

    positive NPV projects are exhausted. Therefore, firms that exceed that value find

    themselves in an overinvestment process, created by the divergence of interests between

    shareholders and managers and facilitated by the existence of asymmetric information.

    In contrast, firms that do not reach that value find themselves in an underinvestment

    process, which implies that the existence of asymmetric information increases the price

    of the external financial resources, hence the firms forgo positive NPV projects. In this

    case, the underinvestment process is also facilitated by the existence of asymmetric

    information but it arises from the conflict between shareholders and bondholders and

    the conflict between current and prospective shareholders.

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    18/24

    18

    Finally, our study also allows us to conclude that firms with valuable investment

    opportunities can undertake larger investments until reaching the optimal level, whereas

    firms without valuable investment opportunities have an optimal level of investment far

    below that of the previous ones, which confirms an exhaustion of their positive NPV

    projects.

    .

    REFERENCES

    Adedeji, A. (1998) Does the pecking order hypothesis explain the dividend payout ratios of firms inthe UK?,Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 25, 1127-55.

    Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1991) Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo

    Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations, Review of Economic Studies, 58,

    277-97.

    Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1998) Dynamic Panel Data Estimation Using DPD98 for GAUSS: A

    Guide for Users, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London.

    Blundell, R., Bond, S., Devereux, M. and Schiantarelli, F. (1992) Investment and Tobins Q:

    Evidence from Company Panel Data,Journal of Econometrics, 51, 233-57.

    Chen, S. and Ho, K. (1997) Market Response to Product-Strategy and Capital-Expenditure

    Announcements in Singapore: Investment Opportunities and Free Cash Flow, Financial

    Management, 26, 82-8.

    Cleary, S. (1999) The Relationship Between Firm Investment and Financial Status, The Journal

    of Finance, 54, 673-92.

    Del Brio, E., Perote, J. and Pindado, J. (2000) Measuring the Impact of Corporate Investment

    Announcements on Share Prices, SSRN Working PaperN. 234578.

    Doukas, J. (1995) Overinvestment, Tobins q and Gains from Foreign Acquisitions, Journal of

    Banking and Finance, 19, 1285-303.

    Fazzari, S., Hubbard, R. and Petersen, B. (1988) Financing Constraints and Corporate Investment,

    Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 141-95.

    Hubbard, R. (1998) Capital-Market Imperfections and Investment,Journal of Economic Literature,

    36, 193-225.

    Jensen, M. and Meckling, W. (1976) Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Cost

    and Ownership Structure,Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305-60.

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    19/24

    19

    Jensen, M. (1986) Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow: Corporate Finance and Takeovers,

    American Economic Review, 76, 323-9.

    Kaplan, S. and Zingales, L. (1995) Do Financing Constraints Explain Why Investment Is

    Correlated With Cash Flow?,NBER Working Paper N. 5267.

    Lang, L. and Litzenberger, R. (1989) Dividend Announcements. Cash Flow Signalling vs. Free

    Cash Flow Hypothesis?,Journal of Financial Economics, 24, 181-91.

    Lang, L., Ofek, E. and Stulz, R. (1996) Leverage, Investment and Firm Growth, Journal of

    Financial Economics, 40, 3-29.

    Lewellen, W. and Badrinath, S. (1997) On the measurement of Tobin's q, Journal of Financial

    Economics, 44, 77-122.

    Miguel, A. and Pindado, J. (2001) Determinants of Capital Structure: New Evidence from

    Spanish Panel Data,Journal of Corporate Finance, 7, 77-99.

    Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. (1958) The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory

    of Investment,American Economic Review, 48, 261-97.

    Moulton, B. (1986) Random Group Effects and the Precision of Regression Estimates, Journal

    of Econometrics, 32, 385-97.

    Moulton, B. (1987) Diagnostics for Group Effects in Regression Analysis, Journal of Business

    and Economic Statistics, 5, 275-82.

    Myers, S. (1977) Determinants of Corporate Borrowing, Journal of Financial Economics, 5,

    147-76.

    Myers, S. and Majluf, N. (1984) Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms

    Have Information that Investors Do Not Have, Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 187-

    221.

    Nohel, T. and Tarhan, V. (1998) Shares Repurchases and Firm Performance: New Evidence on

    the Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow,Journal of Financial Economics, 49, 187-222.

    Perfect, S. and Wiles, K. (1994) Alternative Constructions of Tobin's q: An empirical comparison,

    Journal of Empirical Finance, 1, 313-41.

    Stiglitz, J. and Weiss, A. (1981) Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information,American Economic Review, 71, 393-410.

    Stulz, R. (1990) Managerial Discretion and Optimal Financing Policies, Journal of Financial

    Economics, 26, 3-27.

    Vogt, S. (1994) The Cash Flow/Investment Relationship: Evidence from U.S. Manufacturing

    Firms,Financial Management, 23, 3-20.

    Vogt, S. (1997) Cash Flow and Capital Spending: Evidence from Capital Expenditure

    Announcements,Financial Management, 26, 44-57.

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    20/24

    20

    Whited, T. (1992) Debt, Liquidity Constraints and Corporate Investment: Evidence from Panel

    Data, The Journal of Finance, 47, 1425-60.

    FOOTNOTES1

    Hubbard (1998) offers an excellent review of those studies.

    2The exceptions are the studies by Kaplan and Zingales (1997) and Cleary (1999).

    3See Del Brio et al. (2000) for a more complete overview and additional evidence.

    4A more detailed definition of the variables can be found in the appendix.

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    21/24

    21

    TABLE 1

    STRUCTURE OF THE SAMPLE

    Number of annual observationsper company Number ofcompanies Number ofobservations

    10 76 760

    9 22 198

    8 24 192

    7 5 35

    6 8 48

    Total 135 1,233

    TABLE 2SAMPLE DISTRIBUTION BY SUB-SECTOR CLASSIFICATION

    Sub-sectors Number of

    companies

    % of

    companies

    Energy 14 10.37

    Extractive Industry 3 2.22

    Transport Industry 14 10.37

    Textile Industry 3 2.22

    Building 22 16.30

    Trade and Services 35 25.93

    Food Industry 21 15.56Metal Industry 8 5.93

    Chemical Industry 9 6.67

    Paper Industry 6 4.44

    TABLE 3

    SUMMARY STATISTIC

    Mean Standard

    deviation

    Minimum Maximum

    (V it /Ki,t-1) 0.8869 1.2857 0.0061 21.2218

    (I it /Ki,t-1) 0.0609 0.2686 -0.8204 3.8364

    (I it /Ki,t-1)2 0.0758 0.6967 0.0000 14.7181

    (B it /Ki,t-1) 0.0175 0.1977 -1.1657 4.6467

    (D it /Ki,t-1) 0.0184 0.0305 0.0000 0.4075

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    22/24

    22

    TABLE 4

    ESTIMATION

    Model I: (V it /Ki,t-1) =0 + 1(I it /Ki,t-1) + 2(I it /Ki,t-1)2 + 3(B it /Ki,t-1)+ 4(D it /Ki,t-1)+ dt + i + it

    Model II: (V it /Ki,t-1) = 0 + (1 + 1DQ i) (I it /Ki,t-1) + (2+ 2DQ i) (I it /Ki,t-1)2 + 3(B it /Ki,t-1)+

    4(D it /Ki,t-1)+ dt + i + it

    Number of companies = 135; Number of observations = 1.098

    I II

    Constant -0.11082* (0.0141) -0.11617* (0.0098)

    (I it /Ki,t-1) 0.44016* (0.0150) 0.48305* (0.0095)

    (I it /Ki,t-1)2 -0.48281* (0.0066) -0.31069* (0.0036)

    (B it /Ki,t-1) 1.73516* (0.0542) 1.28198* (0.0285)

    (D it /Ki,t-1) 15.56776* (0.2533) 17.06528* (0.1878)

    DQi*(I it /Ki,t-1) -0.09344* (0.0156)

    DQi*(I it /Ki,t-1)2 -0.37605* (0.0189)

    z1 14475 (4) 22787 (6)

    z2 21286 (8) 100034 (8)

    m2 -1.548 -1.580

    Sargan 118.49 (108) 125.80 (132)Notes:i) Heteroskedasticity consistent standard asymptotic error in parentheses.ii) * indicates significance at the 1% level.

    iii) z1 is a Wald test of the joint significance of the reported coefficients, asymptotically distributed as2under the null of no relationship; z2 is a Wald test of the joint significance of the time dummies; degreesof freedom in parentheses.iv) m2 is a serial correlation test of second order using residuals in first differences asymptoticallydistributed as N(0,1) under the null of no serial correlation.

    v) Sargan is a test of over-identifying restrictions, asymptotically distributed as 2 under the null;degrees of freedom in parentheses.

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    23/24

  • 7/28/2019 pindado 2002 The Under Investment and Over Investment Hypotheses.pdf

    24/24

    Figure II

    (Vit/Ki,t-1)

    (Iit/Ki,t-1)

    Figure III

    (Vit/Ki,t-1)

    (Iit/Ki,t-1)

    Underinvestment (Iit/Ki,t-1) Overinvestment

    (Iit/Ki,t-1)q< (Iit/Ki,t-1)

    q>