198
Politics of Income Inequality and Government Redistributive Policies By Dong-wook Lee A dissertation submitted to the faculty of Claremont Graduate University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Political Science Claremont, California 2016 © Copyright by Dong-wook Lee, 2016 All rights reserved.

Politics of Income Inequality and Government … · Politics of Income Inequality and Government Redistributive Policies by Dong-wook Lee Claremont Graduate University: 2016 ... Second,

  • Upload
    trandat

  • View
    217

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Politics of Income Inequality and Government Redistributive Policies

By

Dong-wook Lee

A dissertation submitted to the faculty of Claremont Graduate

University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree

of Doctor of Philosophy in Political Science

Claremont, California

2016

© Copyright by Dong-wook Lee, 2016

All rights reserved.

APPROVAL OF THE DISSERTATION COMMITTEE

This dissertation has been duly read, reviewed, and critiqued by the Committee listed below,

which hereby approves the manuscript of Dong-wook Lee as fulfilling the scope and quality

requirements for meriting the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Political Science.

Dr. Eunyoung Ha, Chair

Claremont Graduate University

Assistant Professor of Political Science

Dr. Melissa Rogers

Claremont Graduate University

Assistant Professor of Political Science

Dr. Jennifer Merolla

University of California, Riverside

Professor of Political Science

Dr. Luciana Dar

University of California, Riverside

Assistant Professor of Higher Education

Abstract

Politics of Income Inequality and Government Redistributive Policies

by

Dong-wook Lee

Claremont Graduate University: 2016

This study examines why redistributive conflicts are high among countries with

economically diverse regions, and how these conflicts shape the way tax-funded public money is

spent on different public programs. I answer these questions in three steps: 1) civic preferences

for redistribution are formed locally, depending on the geographic regions where people live; 2)

in a decentralized nation with economically disparate regions, this geographic pattern escalates

regional conflicts over redistributive policies broadly consumed by the entire society, such as

public education spending; 3) policy compromises under conditions of inter-regional

redistributive conflicts may result in redistributive policies that are more targeted towards

benefits for specific individuals across the country, such as social welfare.

On each of these steps, I provide supporting empirical evidence. First, drawing the most

recent public opinion data from the Korean General Social Survey on the citizen’s support for

the increased centralized redistribution of public education spending, I find evidence that

residents in poorer regions are more supportive of increased public education spending whereas

residents in richer regions are less favorable. Second, to test cross-national variations in

redistributive conflicts among economically disparate regions with policy autonomy, I use a new

measure of economic disparities among regions that capture a cross-nationally comparable intra-

country income variance. When testing the joint effect of severity of economic disparities among

regions and strength of regional autonomy on volatility in public education spending across

OECD countries from 1980 to 2010, I find that this combined condition reduces the volatility. It

is suggested that the joint condition makes it harder to deviate from the status quo spending,

leading to policy gridlock. Third, when looking at the OECD data on social welfare spending

(excluding education spending) which is directed to individualistic benefits, economic disparities

among regions interacts with regional autonomy to affect more positive changes in social

spending. This result is robust when applying an alternative measure of policy commitment to

targeted spending that considers the government’s policy priorities over competing for budget

allocation categories.

Overall, this research suggests that the joint condition of severity in economic disparities

among regions and strength in regional autonomy exacerbates inter-regional conflicts over the

centralized redistribution of public spending where benefits are broadly consumed but remain

geographically isolated. However, through the targeted spending programs where profits are

directed to specific individuals regardless of their residential regions, autonomous regions with a

different distribution of income improve on coordination to facilitate the centralized

redistribution of public spending.

v

TABLE OF CONTENTS

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION ………………………………………………..…………

A Puzzle on the Inter-personal Income Inequality-Public Spending Nexus …….…..

Research Extension: The Uneven Economic Geography of Income Distribution …..

Redistributive Conflicts: Why Regional Disparity and Regional Autonomy

Jointly Matters ..........................................……………………………………………

Redistributive Conflicts and Strategic Policy Choices ...…………………………….

The Organization of Arguments and Evidence …….………………………...………

1

2

8

8

11

12

CHAPTER 2: THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK (POLITICS OF INCOME

INEQUALITY AND REDISTRIBUTIVE ONFLICTS) ...………………………….……..

Regional Disparities and Individual Redistributive Motives ………………………..

Inter-regional Disparity, Regional Autonomy, and Broad Redistributive Spending ...

Inter-personal Income Disparity with a Unitary System of Government ……

Inter-personal Income Disparity with Federalism ……………………………….

Inter-regional Income Disparity with a Unitary System of Government ………..

Inter-regional Income Disparity with Federalism ……………………………….

Policy Targeting: Preference Convergence among Disparate Regions with Policy

Autonomy ……………………….…………………………………………………...

18

18

22

26

27

30

31

34

CHAPTER 3: SPATIAL PATTERNS OF INDIVIDUAL SUPPORT FOR PUBLIC

EDUCATION FINANCING (EVIDENCE FROM SOUTH KOREA) …………….………..

Case Selection: The Structure of Public Education Financing in South Korea ……...

39

40

vi

Theoretical Frame: Individual Income Positions and Preferences for Public

Education Subsidies …………………………………………………………………..

Survey Data for Empirical Validation ………………………………………………..

Dependent Variable …………………………………………………………………..

Independent Variables ………………………………………………………………..

Distribution of National Wealth across Regions ………………………………....

Distribution of Individual Incomes ……………………………………………....

Controls ………………………………………………………………………………

Model Specification and Estimation Strategy ………………………………………..

Empirical Results …………………..………………………………………………...

Model Fit ……………………………………………………………………………...

Robustness Tests …………………………………………………………………...…

Conclusions and Policy Implications ………………………………………………....

43

45

50

51

51

53

60

63

65

71

72

76

CHAPTER 4: COUNTRY-LEVEL APPLICATION TO COMPARATIVE PUBLIC

POLICIES (FEDERLISM, REGIONAL INEQUALITY, AND EDUCATION

SPENDING) ……………………………………………………………….............................

Governing Structure Matters: Politics of Income Inequality on the

Redistribution of Public Education Spending ………………………………………...

Data …………………………………………………………………………………...

Dependent Variable …………………………………………………………………..

Measures of Inter-personal Inequality ………………………………………………..

Measures of Inter-regional Inequality………………………………………………...

80

82

84

85

85

87

vii

Two Uncorrelated Measures of Inequality …………………………………………...

Measures of Federalism ………………………………………………………………

Controls …………………………………………………………………..…………..

Models, Methods, & Empirical Findings ……………………………………………..

Conclusions and Policy Implications …………………………………….…………...

89

92

94

95

106

CHAPTER 5: EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF POLICY BARGAINING (TESTING

THE CONDITIONAL THEORY OF REGIONAL INEQUALITY AND

ECENTRALIZATION) ………………………………………………………………………

Bargaining for a Centralized Provision of Public Policies …………………………...

Data and Methodology ……………………………………………………………….

Statistical Model Specifications ..…………………………………………………….

Dependent Variables …………………………………………..……………………...

Independent Variables ………………………………………………………………..

Controls ……………………………………………………………………………….

Empirical Results …………………..………………………………………………...

Robustness Checks …………………………………………………………………...

Conclusions and Policy Implications …………………………………………………

110

111

115

116

117

126

128

130

138

140

CHAPTER 6: CONCLUDING COMMENTS AND THE CONTRIBUTION OF

RESEARCH TO POLICY GOALS …………………………………………..……………..

REFERENCES ……………………………………………………………………………..

APPENDICES ………………………………………………………………………………

143

147

164

viii

LIST OF TABLES

Table 1.

Patterns of Individuals’ Policy Preferences for Broad Redistribution Explained by the

Uneven Economic Geography of Income Inequality ……………………………………

19

Table 2.

Joint Effects of Economic Disparity and Federalism on Broad

Redistributive Spending ………………………………………………………………...

26

Table 3.

Summary of Household Income Distribution by Regions.…………………..................

54

Table 4.

Summary of Expectations on Support for Increased Education Spending …...................

57

Table 5.

Impact of Household Income Distribution on Public Support for Education

Financing in Korea ……………………………………………………………….…….

66

Table 6.

Marginal Effects of Income Distribution on Public Support for Education Financing …

69

Table 7.

Education Spending and Structure of Inequality in 18 OECD Countries ……………….

86

Table 8.

Inter-regional Inequality and Inter-personal Inequality Compared ….………………….

90

Table 9.

Measures of Federalism …….………………………………………………....................

93

Table 10.

Impacts of Inequality on the Size of Public Education Spending ….……………………

97

Table 11.

Effects of Inter-personal Inequality & Federalism on Public Education Spending ……...

100

Table 12.

Effects of Economic Inequality & Federalism on Volatility of Public Education

Spending ………………………………………………………….……………………...

104

Table 13.

Determinants of Change in Social Expenditure from 1980 to 2010 ..................................

131

Table 14.

Determinants of Change in Policy Priority from 1990 to 2010 ……….…………………

135

ix

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure 1.

Income Inequality and Public Education Spending Compared ………….……………..

7

Figure 2.

U.S. States by Gini Coefficients of Individual Income Inequality ………..……............

30

Figure 3.

Policy Effects of Rising Economic Disparities among Autonomous Regions ………...

37

Figure 4.

Centralized Structure of Education Financing in Korea ………………………………..

41

Figure 5.

Variations in Public Support for Education Financing……………….....………………

47

Figure 6.

Geographic Distribution of Public Support for Education Financing ….....…...………..

49

Figure 7.

The Correlation of Inter-personal Inequality and Inter-regional Inequality ……………

91

Figure 8.

Marginal Effect of Inter-personal Inequality on Public Education Spending,

Conditional on Electoral Federalism ……………………………..…………………….

101

Figure 9.

Marginal Effect of Inter-regional Inequality on Volatility of Public Education

Spending, Conditional on Electoral Federalism ……...………………………………...

105

Figure 10.

Volatility of Social Expenditure across OECD Countries ………………………...……

118

Figure 11.

An OECD Spending Data Replication for Unfolding Analysis ………………….…….

125

Figure 12.

Marginal Effects of Interaction Terms on Changes in Social Expenditure ……………..

133

Figure 13.

Marginal Effects of Interaction Terms on Change in Policy Priority ..………………….

136

1

CHAPTER 1

Introduction

Why do economic disparities among geographic regions within a decentralized country

exacerbate inter-regional conflicts over the centralized redistribution of public spending? More

specifically, how can the severity of regional inequality and the strength of regional policy

autonomy jointly determine a pattern of inter-regional redistributive conflicts? Most

importantly, to what extent does this conditional effect vary by type of redistributive spending

which ranges from the policy benefits broadly consumed by the entire society to the policy

benefits targeted at specific individuals?

To answer these questions, this research first distinguishes inter-regional income

disparity from inter-personal income disparity. Inter-regional income disparity is defined as

inter-regional inequality in regional wealth determined by the income distribution of residents,

while inter-personal income inequality is defined as inter-personal inequality in the nationally

aggregated individual income distribution. This distinction is useful because inter-regional

income disparity better captures redistributive conflicts at the national legislature of regional

representatives. While this is often neglected from a policy perspective, inter-personal income

disparity overly addresses the policy directorship of the poor majority. Furthermore, this

distinction is even more useful when thinking regarding how regional autonomy as an

institutional rule intervenes to mediate redistributive conflicts.

The crux of my argument is that regions diverge in their policy interests against the

centralized redistribution of public spending as inter-regional income disparity becomes severe

and regional autonomy grows stronger while those regional interests collectively shape the

2

residents’ preferences for redistributive policies which are centrally administrated. The likely

policy outcome on broad redistribution is the perpetuation of redistributive conflicts, leading to

the potential for policy gridlock. I also argue for targeted spending where benefits are directed

to individuals across regions as constituting a policy compromise among economically disparate

regions with policy autonomy.

This research contributes to the inequality government spending literature by identifying

an institutional condition under which regional disparity leads to either the perpetuation of a

redistributive conflict or the promotion of a policy compromise, contingent upon how the tax-

funded money is spent.

A Puzzle on the Inter-personal Income Inequality-Public Spending Nexus

Inter-personal income inequality, also known as disparities in the distribution of income

amongst individuals, is an important policy concern in a redistributive government. It matters for

government spending. The literature has determined that inter-personal income inequality harms

economic growth (Easterly, 2007; Berg & Ostry, 2011). Empirical studies demonstrate that inter-

personal income inequality affects economic growth negatively through constraints on human

capital accumulation (Alesina & Rodrik, 1991) or occupational choices (Persson & Tabellini,

1994). Inter-personal income inequality, as noted by Berg and Ostry (2011), may reflect “poor

people’s lack of access to financial services, which gives them fewer opportunities to invest in

education and entrepreneurial activity” (p.34). Governments care about the rise of inter-personal

income inequality because inequality makes it harder for them to make necessary, decisions

during economic hardship such as raising taxes and cutting public spending to avoid a debt crisis.

Moreover, there may be a social backlash against government policies negligent of interpersonal

3

income inequality. Public dissatisfaction can lead to political instability, similar to what was seen

in Greece due to the policy choices of the Greek government in 2011. Unfortunately, political

instability discourages economic investment because a higher likelihood of government collapse

increases economic actors’ uncertainties associated with the return on investment (Alesina &

Perotti, 1996; Goodrich, 1992; De Mesquita & Root, 2000).

The standard theory of redistributive politics proposed by Romer (1975) and expanded by

Meltzer and Richard (1981) is an ideal initial reference point. According to their observations,

the average income of most societies lies above the median income. In a more (right) skewed

distribution of income, median income is lower than median income. Thus, median income

voters are expected to exert political pressures for redistributive government intervention.1 The

benefit that median income voters receive from redistributive interpersonal transfers will be

greater than the costs they pay in taxes needed to finance redistribution.2 The essence of their

model suggests that more redistributive governments are anticipated when the income of the

median (decisive) voters decreases, compared to the average income.

The Romer-Meltzer-Richard (RMR) model, in its application for public spending,

predicts more redistributive spending likely to be found in a society with higher income

inequality. However, how to apply this simple theoretical prediction in an empirical analysis is

1 Based on their numerical advantage in the voting booth, the poor are assumed the winners in this distributional

struggle as increasing inequality pushes the median voter toward the lower end of the income spectrum (Romer,

1975; Meltzer & Richard 1981). Poor individuals may capture legislative majorities to proactively advance

redistribution as interpersonal inequality grows.

2 Two assumptions need to be held: 1) median voters are accounted for political process under majority voting, 2)

taxations should be progressive.

4

less clear. For example, public education spending is one form of government transfer of funds

which helps human capital accumulation. It is often considered more of a “collective good” in

comparison with other government spending categories which are considered more

“individualistic benefits” such as healthcare and social welfare (Jacoby & Schneider, 2009;

Volden & Wiseman, 2007).

One possible explanation why this may be that public education is a policy area in which

benefits are more broadly consumed by the general population rather than being directed to more

specific (especially poor) segments of the population. Indeed, education policy appears to be

more like “collective goods” policies than “particularized goods” often associated with

redistribution. This comparison is empirically demonstrated by Jacoby and Schneider (2009),

who developed a measure of relative policy priorities using yearly data of US state government

finances (1982-2005) in nine policy areas including education, health, and welfare. They found

that education spending was statistically grouped with other collective goods, such as defense

and infrastructure spending and not strongly associated with health and social welfare spending.

General public education (especially non-tertiary) spending is considered a redistributive

policy. The poor individual income earners can benefit more from public education spending

compared to the rich, when sharing (progressive) income tax costs to fund this public provision.

As predicted by the RMR model, an income distribution that is skewed to the right will create

demands for more redistribution of public education spending. In general, the government will

comply to win the median voter’s vote.3 Thus, the impact of individual income inequality on

public education spending is expected to be positive. Using the U.S. government spending data

from 1936 to 1972, Meltzer and Richard (1983) find that the level of government spending,

3 Note that it really depends on the electoral system.

5

including public education, rises with the ratio of mean to median income. Their findings also

suggest that the relative position of the decisive (median) voters in the income distribution is a

more important determinant for redistribution than the level of the individual income. Corcoran

and Evans (2010) present a similar result using the panel data for the U.S. which is constructed

from state and school district spending from 1970 to 2000. They show that growth in inter-

personal income inequality reduces a median voter’s tax share as the burden of progressive tax

rates is imposed on wealthy voters. This reduction induces higher local education spending

because it is more demanded by the median voters.

Although the RMR model has been popularly cited in the government spending literature,

its empirical findings are rather ambiguous. The recent empirical literature indicates that inter-

personal income inequality is negatively associated with a level of redistribution and support for

public services across countries or within the subnational jurisdiction (Glodin & Katz, 1997;

Lindert 1996; Perotti, 1996). The most criticism raised by these empirical works is the difficulty

in applying the RMR model’s assumption about the median income voters. The median income

voters are the crucial voters in a majority rule voting system where a progressive income tax

finances the public provision. However, the decisive voters may be different from the median

voters (Epple & Romano, 1996; Benabou, 2000).

For example, the crucial voters can be determined by a majority voting status defined as

the coalitions of the lower income voters and the upper-income voters against the middle-income

voters (Epple & Romano, 1996; Ansell, 2008a/b). In the domain of public education where

funding requires tax increases and where private options exist, the lower and upper-income

voters might prefer a lower level of public education spending, compared with the middle-

income voters’ preference. The reasons are as follows: 1) the lower income voters favor lower

6

taxes and a greater level of consumption, 2) the higher income voters can opt out for private

education. As income inequality rises, these two opposing groups are more likely to form a

coalition to vote against the middle-income voters. This “ends against the middle” hypothesis

expects a majority voting equilibrium in a lower level of public education expenditures (Ansell

2010). Through a somewhat different mechanism, Goldin and Katz (1997) show supporting

evidence from US data that heterogeneous communities in income distribution were more likely

to lag behind in funding secondary public education, compared to homogenous communities.

Other empirical studies find no statistically significant relationship between inter-

personal income inequality and public education spending. As put forth by Perotti (1992), no

statistically significant association is found because growth-oriented public policy incentives

create more demands for increased public education spending whereas tax burden pressures

dampen those public policy incentives. Moreover, Basset et al. (1999) find that the impact of

inter-personal income inequality on redistributive policies depends on how accurately the

unequal distribution of individual income represent the position of median income voters. Also,

aggregated public education expenditures are often considered too broad to be used as outcomes

to be explained by individual income inequality. As indicated by Zhang (2002), the sectoral

education expenditure may differ by how socio-economic classes interact with the policy process

to affect the allocation of public spending across education levels.

Figure 1 presents time series observations of public education spending for 18 OECD

countries with regards to their Gini index level, a scale of inequality in the nationally aggregated

individual income distribution. A higher level of Gini (as expressed on a scale of 0-100)

indicates more unequal income distributions. The different country plots are shown in Figure 1.

They include overall public education spending as a share of GDP. As illustrated in Figure 1,

7

Figure 1. Income Inequality and Public Education Spending Compared

Data sources: GINI index is based on market (pre-transfer & pre-tax) income. The index value can go from 0 to 100,

where zero is perfect equality. This GINI index is available from the Standardized World Income Inequality

Database (http://myweb.uiowa.edu/fsolt/swiid/swiid.html); Public education spending data is measured as % of

GDP. The dataset is available from World Development Indicators, World Bank.

variations in public education spending across countries over time do not necessarily correspond

with the RMR model prediction: in other words, a higher level of Gini will coincide with the

expansion of public education spending. In contrast with this theoretical expectation, we find that

countries’ education spending patterns vary considerably. For example, Denmark and Finland

roughly match with the RMR prediction, but Canada and Ireland clearly do not. The RMR model

prediction applied to public education spending is unclear empirically. Why would a country

reduce education spending while its inequality continues to rise? This empirical puzzle is not

8

addressed by the RMR model assumption. In the following section, I will discuss how the study

of inequality types helps improve our understanding of variations in public education spending.

Research Extension: The Uneven Economic Geography of Income Distribution

The RMR model of public expenditures assumes that the national median voters decide

the redistributive policy during a national referendum process. However, this assumption

overlooks the fact that individual citizens and policymaking power are geographically spread

across subnational regions, and peoples’ votes are usually represented based on a geographical

unit (i.e. political jurisdictions such as states in the U.S., cantons in Switzerland, or provinces in

Canada) even at the national level. Each region has different income characteristics, reflecting

both the income level and the income distribution. The national median income is not necessarily

identical to the median income of a region. These regional differences may result in different

preferences for national policy. Accordingly, the heterogeneity of median voters’ policy interests

should increase with the rise of inter-regional inequality, defined as differences in regional

incomes within the nation.4

Redistributive Conflicts: Why Regional Disparity and Regional Autonomy Jointly Matters

The concept of inter-regional income disparities is a useful one. It helps us better

understand individual redistributive interests subject to the uneven economic geography of the

4 Many works, among the RMR modelers, rely on an implicit assumption that inter-personal income disparity

captures inter-regional inequality, and typically ignore inter-regional inequality altogether. A growing number of

studies on inter-regional inequality has recognized conceptual differences in inequality of both types (Beramendi,

2012; Giuranno, 2009a/b).

9

income distribution. Similar to the logic of redistributive policies at the individual level,

wealthier regions have the larger fiscal burdens to finance the centralized redistribution in a

progressive tax system. Where regional policy autonomy is possible, it may be in the best

interest of citizens of affluent regions to seek redistribution within their jurisdictions rather than

centralized redistribution. Isolating public financing and redistribution within a region allow for

reducing the relative cost incurred by wealthy citizens in rich regions. For poor citizens in rich

regions, keeping the local revenue and expenditure inside their regional territory serves to secure

more redistributive benefits available to them. Conversely, wealthy citizens and poor citizens are

similar in less affluent regions. They prefer the centralized redistribution of public spending to

less, and more so as regional disparity increases. The reason for this public choice is that the

centralized redistribution brings more benefits to poor citizens and wealthy citizens in the poor

regions which are subsidized by their counterparts in affluent regions.

Because geographical interests shape individual redistributive interests, inter-regional

inequality creates tensions between equity and efficiency regarding the redistribution of public

goods, including education spending. A government may introduce a redistributive mechanism

to financing public goods to reach the targeted equity. A government function lies in transferring

income from richer regions to less affluent regions, through broad uniform provisions of public

goods and services (Tanzi, 2000). Although the vast redistribution helps gains in equity, it can

also come with a loss of efficiency. It is less efficient for the regions with higher GDP per capita

income to share public resources with their poor regional counterparts, despite the fact that

sharing improves equity for poorer regions. Thus, inter-regional asymmetry in wealth can create

losers (the richer regions) and winners (the poorer regions) regarding government interventions

10

(Decressin, 2002). Therefore, the more affluent regions are less incentivized than their poorer

regional counterparts to support the centralized system of uniform redistribution.

A few empirical studies have indeed confirmed the dampening effects of inter-regional

inequality on the size of public education spending (Decressin, 2002; Sibiano & Agasisti, 2012).

The Italian case is noteworthy. Italy has a centralized system of uniform redistribution regarding

public education spending. The country targets equity across its subnational regions with very

high economic gaps (Barro & Sala-I-Martin, 2004). Regions in Italy have some ability to set the

tax rates for local revenues. Using public spending outcomes (the students’ performance in

national test scores by 18 Italian regions), Sibiano and Agasisti (2012) conclude that rich regions

tend to find the uniform redistribution of education spending across the whole nation less

efficient and poor regions find it more efficient regarding the students’ academic performance.

The rise of inter-regional disparity allows losers and winners of redistribution to be more easily

identified. This disparity can undermine support for redistributive policies. In a cross-national

comparison, this reduction is illustrated by Decressin’s (2002) empirical findings: Italy is less

redistributive in public education spending than other European countries such as France and the

United Kingdom, where a lower level of inter-regional inequality is reported. The reason for

drastically less redistribution in Italy is that rich regions have become less supportive of

redistribution due to their low elasticity of education outcomes on taxes paid (Giorno et al.,

1995).

While there is a redistributive policy tension between rich regions and poor regions, a

system that grants regions policy autonomy and thus increases the bargaining power of regions,

intervenes to aggravate (or perpetuate) the redistributive conflicts between rich regions and poor

regions. Several studies on redistributive politics emphasize the causal role of regional

11

autonomy (e.g., Cameron, 1978; Weingast et al., 1981; Cox, 2001; Besley & Coate, 2003;

Lessmann, 2009). However, their focus only hints at the importance of an institutional context

in which inequality plays a role in shaping the redistribution of public education spending.

The problem is that neglecting regional inequality can lead to very different policy

predictions about the conditional effects of regional autonomy on public spending outcomes.

For instance, regional autonomy (whether it is political or fiscal) is based upon the

constitutional rule of sharing national policymaking power by subnational regions. Regional

autonomy allows for multiple institutional channels for public policy access. Among

economically homogenous regions (as small replicas of the RMR polity with a high inter-

personal income disparity), regional autonomy becomes an institutional vehicle of deficit

spending on public education. While the attached cost is equally shared by autonomous regions,

the cost becomes relatively smaller than the policy benefit to each region as regional autonomy

increases (see, the fractionalization of national decision making explained by Franzese 2005).

On the other hand, when regional inequality accounts for the conditional effect of

regional autonomy, one should be concerned about polarization in policy preferences of unequal

regions, especially as inter-regional disparity increases. In this case, regional autonomy

becomes a system of regional representation which exacerbates the redistributive conflicts

among economically uneven regions, leading to the perpetuation of the status quo spending.

This comparative example suggests that neglecting regional inequality leads to an incomplete

picture of policy outputs across nations.

Redistributive Conflicts and Strategic Policy Choices

12

The regional autonomy mechanism that makes it difficult to draw a policy compromise

among disparate regions may work in the opposite way, depending on how public money is

spent. While regions may not be able to agree on policies that are explicitly redistributive to poor

regions, they may be able to compromise on policies that benefit large segments of all regions.

There are three noteworthy conditions in which individually-targeted policies such as social

welfare may benefit rich regions: 1) if they reduce the possibility of large population migrations

away from the poor regions; 2) if they compensate for job market risks which are present in the

rich regions; and 3) if rich regions have high levels of inequality.

California, for example, has strong interests in centralized redistribution, despite being a

rich region, for all three reasons just described. California’s welfare policies and job market

opportunities may bring too many immigrants to the state if central welfare systems are not

generous for people to remain in poorer regions. Job market risks are acute in California,

including high-income professions like the technology sector, which increases demand for

unemployment insurance and stable healthcare access. Moreover, California is one of the most

unequal states regarding income strata, meaning that they have a lot of needy individuals who

would benefit from central redistributive policies.

Likewise, poor citizens in rich regions find this individually targeted spending to their

advantage while it also spillovers policy benefits to qualified individuals in poor regions.

Targeted spending is this region’s strategic choice subject to bargaining over competitive policy

programs. It attenuates redistributive conflicts among disparate regions.

The Organization of Arguments and Evidence

13

The road map of overall theoretical exposition and empirical falsification is organized as

follows. Chapter 2 theorizes how individuals’ policy preferences are collectively shaped,

depending on whether they live in rich or poor regions and the targeting of the policy area. I

show a simple utility model to demonstrate benefits and costs of supporting cross-regional

redistribution by individual citizens who are geographically spread in economically disparate

regions. My assumption is that all citizens seek to maximize their benefits from distributive

policies by sharing the associated costs. I apply this assumption to policy motivations of both

poor and rich individuals in affluent regions, predicting that higher regional disparity in wealth

incurs more costs than benefits from the centralized redistribution of public goods and services.

Thus, I anticipate that those residents of affluent regions are less likely to support increases in

centralized redistribution with the rise of regional disparity. I also elaborate the opposite policy

expectation for redistributive motives of both poor and rich individuals in less affluent regions. I

explain that their relative gains from supporting centralized redistribution increase with the rise

of regional inequality.

Extending from the micro-foundations of redistributive motives among individuals

within a country, I explore macro-level variations in policy outcomes across countries. I analyze

whether decentralization (regional autonomy) may interact with rising regional inequality to

affect policy outcomes. I argue that the wealthy regions with more policy-making autonomy will

be more capable of constraining government distributive policies despite most less affluent

citizens with an interest in redistributing wealth. On the other hand, these less affluent regions

are likely to try to block the rich regions’ efforts to reduce redistributive spending. Thus, my

expectation is that countries with more decentralized systems of governance and higher levels of

14

regional inequality are likely to show policy gridlock, leading to less change in centralized

redistributive spending for the broader benefits of the entire society.

Due to this policy gridlock, however, I also anticipate more compromise between the

rich and the poor regions for centralized legislation over policies that target direct benefits

towards segments of the population across all jurisdictions. This targeted policy spending in the

poor regions will be beneficial because it meets large demands from local constituencies. This

benefits the rich regions also because targeted spending helps their local constituencies who rely

on welfare provision. This common interest will make policy bargaining easier, leading to

increases in redistributive spending on targeted policies for individualistic goods.

In Chapter 3, I test the empirical merits of my argument that regional interests trump (or

interact with) individual redistributive motives. I use the individual-level data from the Korean

General Social Survey (2006) on citizen support for increases in public education spending.

The Korean case is interesting because regional political autonomy has grown stronger in

recent years while income tax systems for financing public education have long been centrally

administrated. To explain variations in citizen support for Korean education spending, I probe

models of cross-level interactions between income attributes of individuals and economic

disparities in regions where those individuals are geographically dispersed. My empirical

analyses yield a finding that both rich and poor residents of rich regions in general have a weak

incentive to support more tax-funded spending on public education, whereas those of poor

regions have a strong incentive to support increases in funding for public education spending.

This finding implies that in centralized broad redistributive programs such as public education,

regional disparity makes the difference in the policy incentive between net benefactors from

poor regions and net contributors from rich regions more visible. Thus, the redistributive

15

policies preferred by economically disparate regions are difficult to coordinate at the national

level.

Moving from a single survey data analysis to cross-national statistics mainly focused on

advanced economies, Chapter 4 tests cross-national differences in policy rigidity explained by a

country’s degree of economic disparity among autonomous subnational regions. In a policy

bargaining, collective regional interests exacerbate redistributive conflicts as regional income

grows more disparate and regions have more power to influence national policy making. I

predict that disparity in regional income increases heterogeneous preferences, thus creating

barriers to national policy reform. For data analyses, I use a new dataset for inter-regional

inequality measured by regional GDP per capita. The database measures inter-regional inequality

in two ways: 1) the dispersion of regional wealth, weighted by each region’s relative size to the

population; 2) the structure of regional wealth distribution, weighted by the relatively deprivation

of each region. Both inter-regional inequality measures are cross-nationally comparable variables

of intra-country variance. Then I test how inter-regional inequality interacts with regional

autonomy (measured in degree of electoral or fiscal federalism) to affect redistributive spending.

Using panel data covering 18 OECD countries from 1980-2010, I confirm that inter-regional

inequality interacts with federalism to exacerbate policy impasses, driving down changes in

public education spending.

In contrast to rigidity in education financing, broadly consumed by general population

across disparate regions in regionally autonomous nations, Chapter 5 provides an empirical

assessment of flexibility in financing public programs that are directed to specific individuals

regardless of region. I predict that if policy benefits are more targeted to demographic segments

of the population (e.g., welfare spending and Medicare), policy concessions on national

16

legislation will be easier because this targeted policy provision brings particularized benefits to

constituency needs for public goods and services -- common demands from every local region.

In this regard, my empirical test focuses on the join impacts of economic disparities and

decentralized authority structures among subnational regions on changes in targeted public

spending. Using the cross-national data on social spending in 24 OECD countries from 1980-

2010, I find evidence that higher inter-regional inequality in a more decentralized polity leads to

more growth on social expenditure. More importantly, considering trade-offs between spending

allocation across policy areas, I examine the relative importance of social spending to other

policy goods broadly consumed by nontargeted general population (e.g., national defense, public

order and security). The associated finding also reveals that countries with more disparate

regions and decentralized authority structures tend to prioritize social spending over other

nontargeted spending policies. This suggests that not all types of public programs preferred by

the disparate regions with strong local autonomies necessarily lead to a policy impasse. Instead,

depending on where and for whom to target, conflicts of the redistributive interests can lead to

more compromise on certain programs than others.

Chapter 6 presents a conclusion with policy implications. In short, the understanding of

geographic-based inequality that I employ provides a more detailed explanation of policy

behavior of individuals than the national-level income strata modeling extensively used in the

existing literature. My research further distinguishes itself by identifying political

decentralization as a relevant institutional factor in an overall explanatory framework because

it amplifies the effect of inter-regional inequality on preferences for government redistribution.

This analytic frame can be applied to a wide range of topics from government finances and

public choices in general to legislative conflicts. It can be also used as a reference to integrated

17

research between individuals within regions within countries. Moreover, my findings strongly

suggest that countries may be able to achieve redistributive spending in some policy areas

more effectively than in others, given the nature of their region-specific income inequality and

institution structures.

18

CHAPTER 2

Theoretical Framework: Politics of Income Inequality and Redistributive Conflicts

The primary goal of this theoretical chapter is to identify how inter-regional income

disparity and regional autonomy jointly constrain the centralized redistribution of public

spending whose policy benefits are broadly consumed by the society but often geographically

isolated (e.g., public education spending). A negative social outcome is anticipated as a result of

policy conflicts among disparate regions over the centralized redistribution of nontargeted

spending. This expectation needs to be separated from a potential for the policy coordination

incentives shared among regions toward targetted spending that directs policy benefits to be

directed to specific (qualified) individuals regardless of their geographic regions (e.g., social

welfare spending). I predict that the former case makes it harder to change the broad

redistributive spending, whereas the latter one induces more positive changes in targeted

redistributive spending. Thus, policy targeting would be an important matter, particularly when

regional disparity grows and regional policy autonomy is stronger.

Regional Disparities and Individual Redistributive Motives

Beramendi (2012) provides a very useful theoretical frame that draws patterns of inter-

personal redistribution based on economic geography. This frame predicts a wider gap in

preferences for inter-personal redistribution across economically disparate regions. A predictable

policy outcome, according to Beramendi (2012), is regional governments’ design of policies for

redistribution among citizens within their territorial units, without extensively resorting to either

interregional transfers or central government coordination.

19

Table 1. Patterns of Individuals’ Policy Preferences for Broad Redistribution

Explained by the Uneven Economic Geography of Income Inequality

Poorer Regions Richer Regions

Poorer Residents More Support Less Support*

Richer Residents More Support* Less Support

Note * Individual residents experience a policy preference dilemma where the political geography trumps class-

interests. This theoretical framework is first introduced by Beramendi (2012). In this civic preference model, I

simplify the analytical frame by assuming regions have a certain degree of regional autonomy and the progressive

tax rate on income is uniformly imposed across disparate regions.

I develop a modified version of Beramendi’s (2012) original setup using two-axis of

redistribution: inter-personal redistribution (from rich to poor citizens) vs. inter-regional

redistribution (from rich to poor regions). Importantly, Beramendi (2012) stresses that the fiscal

structure of redistribution (e.g., full centralization, full decentralization, or hybrid) can be an

outcome of elite choice to overcome the uneven economic geography of income inequality.5 My

research differs from Beramendi’s (2012) by focusing on the role of regional autonomy together

with inter-regional income disparity as a process which determines redistributive spending. I

examine how the uneven economic geography of income distribution in autonomous regions

(wherein the regional government can limit inter-regional redistribution) affects individual

preferences for policy goods broadly redistributed.

The distribution of individual income falls into four groups whose preferences reflect the

underlying geography of inequality. As shown in Table 1, there are four distinctive individual

groups: poorer residents in poorer regions, richer residents in poorer regions, poorer residents in

richer regions, and richer residents in richer regions. First, richer residents in richer regions have

5 Beramendi also looks at other conditions such as regional economic specialization, cross-regional labor mobility,

and the configuration of (centripetal and centrifugal) political representation.

20

no incentive to agree to any transfer of their tax bases towards redistributive spending which

goes disproportionately to the country’s poorer regions. Therefore, richer residents in richer

regions are less likely to be for the increased centralized redistribution of public spending funded

disproportionally by rich regions.

Second, poorer residents in poorer regions receive the most benefits from centralized

spending distributed inter-regionally and will support its expansion (as disproportionally funded

by rich regions). A full redistribution of public spending will be the best policy option for poorer

residents in poorer regions. Their expectation of the redistribution will be large, seeking to

extract resources from inter-regional transfers out of the base of richer regions.

Third, as with poorer residents in poorer regions, similar logic applies for richer residents

in poorer regions: they are more likely to support the broad redistribution of public spending.

These richer individuals want to pay as few taxes as possible, but at the same time, they want to

extract as many resources from other wealthier regions as possible. This situation creates a

dilemma for richer residents in poorer regions. For the broad redistribution of public spending

within a poorer region, richer residents will pay more taxes than poorer residents. Those richer

residents may not prefer this option. However, when this non-targeted public spending is inter-

regionally redistributed, it could lessen the fiscal burden on richer residents in poorer regions and

improve the economic condition of their poor residents. Thus, richer residents in poorer regions

are more likely to support the broad national redistribution of public spending.

Fourth, poorer residents in richer regions will not agree with inter-regional transfers of

public spending because they lose more than what they would gain through intra-regional

transfers. They also experience a policy preference dilemma although this experience differs in

nature from what richer residents in poorer regions would experience. One the one hand, poorer

21

residents in richer regions can extract additional resources from the wealthier individuals (in

poorer regions) by supporting the broad redistribution of public spending. On the other hand, this

inter-regional redistribution will require residents in richer regions to share their tax bases with

residents in poorer regions. To poorer residents in richer regions, this means that the costs of

sharing can exceed benefits from it, especially as regions increasingly vary by levels of income.

Since the governing system of regional autonomy allows for the regional government to enact

autonomous policies, poorer residents in richer regions will pursue a decentralized system of

inter-personal redistribution in which they benefit the most from fiscal transfers occurring only

within their region. Therefore, the redistributive motives of poorer residents in richer regions are

less supportive of broad centralized redistribution of public spending.

In short, Table 1 summarizes how the uneven economic geography of the income

distribution would matter and becomes a political problem (Weingast et al., 1981; Rodden, 2000;

Giuranno, 2009a/b). Citizens’ redistributive interests can be collectively formed depending on

the level of regional wealth rather than the level of individual income, especially in a system of

government that grants regional policy autonomy. As pointed by Beramendi (2012), we may not

see the effects of political geography on the redistribution of public education spending when the

relative level of individual income overlaps strongly with the relative level of regional wealth

(poorer residents in poorer regions or richer residents in richer regions). In such places,

redistributive policies follow individual redistributive motives. More redistribution is preferred

by poor citizens to less (vice versa for rich citizens). However, when individual income and

regional wealth are mismatched, political geography matters more (Beramendi 2012). This

relationship occurs because regional incentives can alter individual redistributive motives

(denoted as * in Table 1).

22

This theoretical framework assumes that poorer residents in richer regions and richer

residents in poorer regions do not necessarily follow class-based interest. Rather, the economic

geography trumps their redistributive motives in the case of policy preferences for the

centralized redistribution of public goods broadly redistributed across disparate regions. This

relationship leads to a testable hypothesis as follows.

Hypothesis 1: Poor citizens in rich regions are less likely to favor of the centrally-

managed broad redistributive spending, whereas rich citizens in poor regions tend to be

more in favor.

A broader implication of this individual-level analysis is that regional disparity increases

redistributive policy tension among disparate regions. The structure of political representation

will further mediate this redistributive conflict. The following section applies this for a cross-

national dimension. I expect more severe conflicts among disparate regions where regional

policy autonomy is possible, compared to a unitary system of government.6

Inter-regional Disparity, Regional Autonomy, and Broad Redistributive Spending

6 It is possible that the rich in poor regions might be even richer than the rich in rich regions. Similarly, the poor in

rich regions might be poorer than the poor in poor regions. However, on average, I assume that the poor in poor

regions is a group of the poorest individuals whereas the rich in rich regions is a group of the richest individuals in

their income status nationwide. See Footnote 36 in Chapter 3 with tangible evidence from the Korean General Social

Survey data in 2006.

23

The policy effect of regional autonomy has long been debated in the field. For example,

federalism (as an institutional form of regional autonomy) is a system of government with semi-

autonomous subnational regions in a regime with the common central government (Riker, 1964).

This system allows for local politicians representing subnational governments to cater to local

demands (Bednar, 2011). Policy administration under a federal system can be more efficient to

cope with local demands, compared to a unitary system of government which seeks “one size fits

all policies” for varied regional interests (Tiebout, 1956; Oates, 1972). While federalism

promotes diversity in the ways that local supplies meet local demands, it creates two competing

forces. First, federalism allows local constituencies to have more access to policy processes

through multiple governments; this highlights the fractionalization effects of national policy

making. The second, the competing force arises when the heterogeneity of administrative regions

under federalism also increase constraints on policy agreement among regions at the national

level (Aysan, 2005a/b). As their policy interests diverge, regions can be highly polarized in their

policy ideals regarding national policy-making.7

Not surprisingly, empirical studies of federalism reveal mixed findings of the policy

effects of federalism. Comparative cross-national studies present no clear relationship in policy

outcomes. Some scholars find that federalism leads to more redistribution among developed

countries due to their high fiscal decentralization capacity to either compensate inequality or

deliver public services (Rodríguez-Pose & Ezcurra, 2010; Lessmann, 2009). However, empirical

work of other scholars provides a counterexample where federalism reduces redistribution

because it undermines the power of the central government to play an equalizing role

(Prud’homme, 1995: Rodríguez-Pose & Ezcurra, 2004). Evidence from policies pursued in a

7 I borrowed the following terms “fractionalization effects” and “polarization effects” from Franzese (2005).

24

sample of European regions suggests that federalism disproportionately benefits a few specific

geographic locations (Cheshire & Gordon, 1998).

The existing research, however, fails to explain the separate conditions which distinguish

the effect of federalism engendering the exploitation of the common pool, from that of

federalism increasing policy veto constraints.8 Common pool issues arise when multiple regions

share fiscal policy authority. Local politicians try to please their constituents and attract

taxpayers and, thus, they seek to provide high-quality public services. In policy practice, a

region’s parochial interests will push for more resources while competing with other localities

(Tiebout, 1956; Weingast, 1995). One of the related consequences is that when regions make

decisions in the national legislature together, they often pass oversized budgets (Weingast et al.,

1981). They are likely to remain cooperative in national policy making, benefiting from

logrolling, or “pork-barrel spending proportional to the number of districts,” as put by Franzese

(2005). The problem is then that their benefits from expansionary policies would exceed their

share of the fiscal burden in public financing; especially when the cost accrues more uniformly

across subnational regions (according to the law of 1/n, see Franzese, 2005). Therefore, the more

the political power shared by regional governments, the greater the potential that will be invested

in regional governments to push for the central government to provide what the regional

governments want (Barro & Gordon, 1983; Kydland & Prescott, 1977). This local incentive will

result in the overuse of the common pool of public funds in distributing benefits specific to local

demands (Franzese, 2005). As predicted by Weingast et al. (1981), the division of labor in policy

making by subnational actors will lead to deficit spending on national policies as it makes

8 Franzese (2005) is a complement. At a slightly different angle, my argument focuses on the question of how

inequality measures highlight such distinction in a different way.

25

logrolling more attractive and ensures more uniform sharing of the cost attached to redistributive

spending.

While the common pool effects are derived from the fractionalization of federalism, the

increased veto constraints under federalism can lead to policy impasse (Franzese, 2005). The

number of veto points is created using institutional separation. These veto points become

competitive when separate institutions vary in their policy preference. Federalism is a system

which divides power between many sub-national decision makers rather than focusing on one

single national authority. It diffuses policy decision power through institutional separation where

different political actors compete through those separate institutions with mutual veto powers

(Triesman, 2000; Tsebelis, 2002; Crepaz & Mozar, 2004). As pointed out by Cox (2001),

because more actors are becoming involved in policy decision making under federalism, they are

more capable of blocking decisions.9 Therefore, any dispersion of political authority is expected

to increase the number of veto players, which would perpetuate the status quo (Treisman, 2006).

Moreover, the number of veto points may remain more competitive when regional governments

are polarized in their policy preference. Competitive veto points reduce the bargaining space for

inter-regional policy agreement and incur high transaction costs to policy making (Cameron,

1978; Tsebelis, 1995, 2002; Persson & Tabellini, 2006). For example, Treisman (2000) finds that

federalism blocks policy changes to the money supply. Federalist countries with a high level of

money supplies have kept the supply high, while those with a low level of money supplies have

remained low. Similarly, the competitive veto player constraints can lock in a country’s existing

degree of public spending.

9 The U.S. Senate filibuster would be a good example of delaying the entire legislative process and forcing a

supermajority coalition to override it.

26

Table 2. Joint Effects of Economic Disparity and Federalism

on Broad Redistributive Spending

Inter-personal Disparity Inter-regional Disparity

Unitary Increase or Decrease (A) Change (C)

Federalism Greater Increase (B) Less Change (D)

The conflicting expectations of overdrawing from the common pool and policy

stalemates between competitive vetoes created under federalism can help us identify how these

policy problems have become more severe when thinking regarding inter-personal income

disparity and inter-regional income disparity, more than what we might see in a unitary system of

government. Common pool effects causing the over provision of public spending will rise further

when the interplay between a higher level of inter-personal disparity (translated into smaller

replicas of the nation) and a greater extent of policy access granted by regional autonomy (i.e.,

the fractionalization effects). The delays on policy adjustment incurred by competitive veto

player constraints will become even more intransigent at the interplay between higher levels of

inter-regional inequality and more different policy interests which results from regional

autonomy (i.e. the polarization effects). Details of these interaction effects are organized in

Table 2.

(A) Inter-personal Income Disparity with a Unitary System of Government

In a unitary system of government, all governing authority is vested in a central

government. Although it is possible to have regional autonomy to some extent, sovereign power

rests with the central administration; it will stay supreme. France is an example of a nation

27

having a strong unitary system of government. Although the country has 90 departments and 36

provinces, these provinces do not have the power commonly exercised by states in the U.S.

Inter-personal income disparity of a centralized polity, holding the level of inter-regional

disparity constant, could have more redistribution of public spending. As the median income

decreases relative to the average income, the median income voters will demand increased broad

redistribution in public expenditure. The government will supply more to improve equity in the

entire country. The increase in broad public spending will be reasonable to win the support of the

median income voter. In an ideal RMR world (with progressive taxation and majority voting),

high inter-personal inequality will increase the amount of public spending broadly consumed.

On the other hand, the size of broad public spending could decrease at high levels of

inter-personal income disparity. A higher level of inter-personal disparity will result in the

polarization of individual voters’ (and their representatives’) policy preferences. Political parties

may not be directly responsive to the national median voters (Iversen & Soskie, 2006a/b;

Stratmann, 1995; Gerber & Lewis, 2004). Also, the decisive voters do not necessarily have to be

the poorer majority, such as described by the “ends against the middle” hypothesis in the

literature review section. The government, therefore, could also decrease the size of broadly

redistributive public spending, depending on who the decisive voters are and what policy

preferences they have.

(B) Inter-personal Income Disparity with Federalism

A federal system of government with high inter-personal inequality, holding inter-

regional income disparity constant, will increase the median income voters’ power to drive pro-

poor policy for redistribution. When putting the nationally aggregated individual income

28

distribution into a regional perspective, there will also be these cases of regional politics in which

the poor individuals are likely to be the decisive voters in subnational governments (more so if

the national distribution of individual income is more skewed to the right). 10 The poorer

individuals from each federal district will demand greater redistribution. Since federalism helps

local voters hold their local politician accountable for the policies which are made, the low-

income earners will have their voices heard by local politicians who seek to enact policies to win

their votes (Tiebout, 1956; Weingast, 1995). From a region’s parochial interest, it is not rational

to draw less from the common pool while others do more (e.g., Treisman, 1999a/b). This

condition will spur the common pool effects (because of collective action): the poorer

individuals will overbid prices for public education spending as the size of this group increases

across federal districts (see. Olson, 1982). Therefore, further resources in broad public spending

will be committed as the general government’s function under federalism will be to meet this

policy demand from a large group of the poorer individuals across federal districts.

Subsequently, the size of broad public spending, at the general government level, will grow.

10 Although federalism, by its institutional design, increases the number of veto-points in political jurisdictions, if

the poorer individuals are the decisive voters in each jurisdiction, the ideological difference between theses veto-

points will be small (Tsebelis, 2002). No policy gridlock is expected. For example, in a strict application of the

RMR model into each sub-national region, the nationwide aggregated individual income distribution will be divided

in each region with the same income distribution. In a high-level of inter-personal inequality situation, the poor

individuals are likely to be decisive voters in each region. As regions all want to have more redistribution of public

education spending, they will overuse the resources in distributing benefits specific to local demands. The critical

problem with the RMR model application is that it does not consider inter-regional inequality at all. It is more

realistic to assume that individual income distributions are different from region to region. Inter-regional inequality

will increase redistributive policy conflicts among regions with mutual veto powers.

29

Given regional replicas of the nationally aggregated individual income distribution, the

number of equally represented regions (and their role in the national policy making) is

proportional to the intensity of the common pool effects. The cost of financing oversized public

spending will be equally shared by these identical subnational segments (Franzese, 2005). As the

number of equal representative actors increases (i.e., the more dispersion of national policy

decision-making power), log rolling will further prevail since benefits from side-payments can

offset the cost that each region should bear to pass excessive public spending bills. As argued by

Crepaz and Mozer (2004), logrolling among potential veto players in the national legislature can

strengthen a policy coalition among those “collective vetoes.” This practice of logrolling also

weakens a region’s ability to exercise restraints to control each other’s public spending budgets.

The policy outcome will then be redistributive spending in an expansionary direction.

Compared to the inter-personal inequality which is explained by a relative poverty gap

between the median income and the average income, inter-regional inequality describes a

relative poverty gap in more complex ways. It captures not only relative poverty between

individual residents within a region but also relative poverty between regions. There will be

poorer individuals and richer individuals in each region. Because of relative homogeneity within

a region compared to across regions, the level of income inequality within a region is lower than

the level of income inequality in the entire country. This simplified assumption makes poorer

individuals in richer regions relatively wealthier than poorer individuals in poorer regions. For

example, Figure 2 compares the Gini score for the United States with Gini scores by the U.S.

state-level in 2010. On the horizontal axis, we see the level of inequality within a state. In most

cases, Gini scores by state-level are lower than the Gini score for the entire United States (0.47).

30

Figure 2. U.S. States by Gini Coefficients of Individual Income Inequality (2010)

Data source: the American Community Survey conducted by the U.S. Census Bureau, 2010

(C) Inter-regional Income Disparity with a Unitary System of Government

High inter-regional income disparity under a unitary government, holding the level of

inter- personal income inequality constant, can lead to either increases or decreases in the

centralized redistribution of broad public spending. Combined with a unitary government, high

inter- regional income inequality works in the way that the RMR model predicts. The unitary

government will supply public spending more broadly to reduce inequality across the regions.

On the other hand, inter-regional income disparity increases bargaining among national

political parties that delegate regional constituencies. The growing divergence between richer

regions and poorer regions gives rise to conflicts in policy negotiation among national political

parties. As the unitary government transfers tax-based money from the richer regions to the

poorer counterparts, national parties that represent the richer regions will block decisions for

31

more broad redistribution of public spending (Aysan, 2005a/b).11 In achieving policy

coordination more effectively, the unitary government mitigates this tension by reducing the size

of broad redistributive public spending (Giuranno, 2009a/b).

(D) Inter-regional Income Disparity with Federalism

Under federalism, national decisions on the broad redistribution of public spending will

be made by politicians that represent geographic jurisdictions. At a higher level of inter-regional

income disparity, policy preferences will vary. A federal system with high inter-regional

disparity, when holding inter-personal income disparity constant, will make regional conflicts

more severe. Thus, policy gridlock is expected.

Given that regions trump individual redistributive motives under federalism, a higher

level of inter-regional income disparity will increase conflicts between poorer regions and richer

regions. Under strong federalism, political decision-making power will be dispersed in both

poorer regions and richer regions with mutual veto power. A high level of inter-regional

inequality in federalism will increase policy divergence across disparate regions. Thus, there will

be competitive veto points. In a situation of competitive veto player constraints, richer regions

will veto more public spending for broader redistribution. The policy supply of the national

government under federalism seeks to meet this demand from richer regions by attempting to cut

broad public spending, but this will be difficult when poorer regions also veto spending cuts as

11 In a relative poverty concept, poorer individuals in richer regions will pay more tax than poorer individuals in

poorer regions based on progressive taxation uniformly imposed by the unitary government. This implies that richer

regions pay relatively more than poorer regions as costs of broad redistribution in public education spending

increase.

32

they want more redistribution. The expected result is a policy impasse. More competitive veto

points at divergent inter-regional disparities will erect barriers to a policy change (either increase

or decrease) for the broad redistribution of public spending. Whether the level of broad public

spending is high or low, it will be locked in where it is (Treisman, 2000).

To summarize, the redistributive policy effects of inter-regional income disparity are

distinctive from those of inter-personal income disparity under federalism although we may not

see this difference in a unitary system of government. I emphasize that the policy effects of

inequality with federalism differ by the two types of inequality. High inter-personal income

disparity and federalism have a synergic effect to create more redistributive demands from

poorer individuals through multiple subnational governments. There will be greater policy

provisions for broad public spending than when there is only a unitary government. High inter-

regional inequality interacts with federalism to erect competitive veto player constraints. It will

then be harder to bring a change in the amount spent on public policies in which benefits are

broadly consumed inter-regionally.

This theoretical overview made several assumptions. First, richer individuals do not want

to subsidize poorer individuals in the broad redistribution of public spending, as poorer

individuals benefit more from the broad provision of public spending (Stasavage, 2005). Second,

a national government is expected to redistribute resources inter-personally (from richer

individuals to poorer individuals) and inter-regionally (from richer regions to poorer regions)

through the broad provision of public goods including public education spending (Tanzi, 2000).

Given this set of assumptions, I expect that high inter-personal inequality across federal

regions would create pro-poor redistributive policy pressure because the regions are the smaller

replicas (microcosms) of the nation with the highly-skewed income distribution of individual

33

citizens. The local constituency demand will push their representatives to exploit a national

common pool of public education spending in distributing benefits specific to their localities.

Therefore, the overuse effect of common property can be an increasing linear function of the

number of regional delegates in the national legislation. These regional delegates engage in pork-

barrel politics making their benefits outweigh their equal share of the costs attached to

maintaining the national pool. The subsequent effect will lead to more public education

spending.

Hypothesis 2: Inter-personal income disparity in federalism, holding inter-regional

income disparity constant, further increases the level of broadly redistributive public

spending, more so than in a unitary system of government.

On the other hand, federalism for inter-regional inequality results in a third assumption:

redistributive motives among individuals are clustered upon their geographic locations.

Federalism fosters the dispersion of national policy decision making in political jurisdictions

with mutual veto power. Power dispersion shapes policies as a manifestation of inter-regional

inequality. Locally elected politicians will seek to enact national educational policy reflective of

a region’s specific demands. More competitive veto points with divergent regional interests will

create smaller bargaining space over the redistributive policies. Richer regions will veto more

spending, whereas poorer regions will veto spending cuts. High inter-regional inequality will

make veto player constraints worse. Changes in public education spending will be difficult. I

expect that the magnitude of policy change is smaller under federalism than in a unitary system

of government.

34

Hypothesis 3: Inter-regional income disparity in federalism, holding inter-personal

income disparity constant, leads to less change in public spending for broad redistribution

than in a unitary system of government.

This logic of redistributive conflicts expressed in a joint effect of inter-regional income

disparity and federalism on public spending for broad redistribution is limited in its policy scope.

Redistributive public programs are not monolithic but rather multidimensional. Indeed, they vary

from redistributive goods that are more directed to individuals (e.g., social security transfers and

healthcare) to redistributed goods that are more broadly consumed for the entire society (e.g.,

public safety and national security). In the following section, I further elaborate how the disparity

in regional economies and regional autonomy (defined as the authority of regional government

more broadly to capture the various policy dimensions of targeted spending) jointly shape

patterns of national policy outcomes over a range of choices on redistributive policy programs.

Policy Targeting: Preference Convergence among Disparate Regions with Policy Autonomy

Out of competing public budget categories, rich regions and poor regions are likely to

find it easier to coordinate their preferences for a social allocation in which benefits are directed

to specific individuals within every territorial region. Rich regions seek an increase in the

centralized redistribution of social spending, only as preferable to other types of redistributive

spending that go disproportionally to poor regions, especially when interregional inequality is

very high.12 For example, in the U.S., rich and unequal states such as California and New York

12 Similarly, rich regions seek the centralized redistribution of goods targeting specific individuals regardless of

geographic locations preferable to policy goods that are disproportionally geographical based.

35

are for increased social welfare spending nationwide although this policy choice creates a

spillover effect across other poor states. Regional transfers (benefits that are more broadly

redistributed for the entire society) redistribute taxpayer money away from a state like California

towards a relatively poor state such as Mississippi. Social transfers such as Medicaid (benefits

that are more directed to specific individuals) also benefit California. For poor regions, on the

other hand, interregional transfers are preferred to social transfers. As inter-regional income

disparity increases, individual beneficiaries of social transfers are larger in number and thus the

benefit of the policy program outweigh the costs of national policy coordination with their rich

regional counterparts. Thus, poor regions have an incentive to support more social transfers.

The authority exercised by regional governments over their territory and people intervene

to solidify their policy coordination on the central government’s budget allocation toward social

categories. This regional authority encompasses not only political representation and tax rate

control, but also it accounts for borrowing autonomy from the centrally imposed restrictions

(Hooghe et al., 2015).13 Regional authority is granted through constitutional rules of

policymaking. It facilitates a reactive power which blocks or delays a policy change away for the

status quo (Triesman, 2006). National representatives of regions endowed with this reactive

power can affect less-preferred expenditures by acting as veto gates for budget policies (e.g.,

upper house veto or amendment of lower house budgets and supermajority rules).

Rising inter-regional income disparity in a polity where regional authority is

institutionalized at a greater degree creates an increasingly cooperative policy incentive among

13 I assume federalism to be a subset of regional authority in a broader scope. I use two terms interchangeably. They

create institutional power that provides opportunities for regional representatives to influence national policy

making.

36

those unequal regions on greater budget allocation toward targeted spending. Given trade-offs

among competing budget categories, the policy pressures escalated by severe inter-regional

income disparity interacting with strong regional authority makes budget allocation towards

targeted spending more appealing to national representatives of regions and thus increases the

likelihood of a policy compromise among them.

Redistributive tensions between the rich and poor Länder in Germany provides an

illustrative case. Germany has high inter-regional income disparity linked to the German

reunification. For example, “in 1991, the GNP per capital in the new Eastern Länder was 30% of

that of the Western Länder” (Renzsch, 1998: 127). Through the German Unity Fund, allocation

of reunified Germany was heavily favored social spending involving for social assistance

(Sozialhife)14 as the form of redistribution which benefited the poor in the affluent Western

regions while also subsidizing the poor in the Eastern regions (Flockton, 1999). In fact, in the

period 1990-1994, Germany’s growth in social security transfer measured as a share of GDP

shows a much faster pace than the OECD’s with an average difference of 15 percent (Beramendi,

2012). Rich regions in Germany benefited somewhat from redistributive social spending but not

from redistributive public work projects. On the other hand, a political consequence brought

about by reunification was a stronger coalition in the upper chamber (Bundesrat) between the

Eastern Länder and poor Western Länder. During a policy negotiation over interregional

transfers primarily to the East (e.g., the Solidarity Pact starting in 1995), reunified Germany

facilitated a stronger institutional position for those contributing to Western Länder (Beramendi,

2012; Gunlicks, 2002). Given this constraint, targeted spending towards policies like social

14 Programs and services provided by local authorities directly to individuals who have exhausted their rights to

receive the unemployment compensation and need basic care in their daily lives (Beramendi, 2012).

37

Figure 3. Policy Effects of Rising Economic Disparities among Autonomous Regions

assistance is an opportunity for rich Western regions to shift allocation to their advantage while it

serves the policy interests of the poor Länder in the union. This interest convergence in policy

preference is predicted in hypothesis testing:

Hypothesis 4: Increased inter-regional inequality and regional authority prompt relative

allocation towards targeted spending in which benefits are directed to individuals.15

15 Inter-personal income disparity’s combined effect with regional authority does not matter to more targeted

spending because the majority poor from economically homogenous regions (by the assumption of inter-personal

income disparity are the beneficiaries from both targeted spending and broad non-targeted spending.

38

Figure 3 illustrates the expected joint effects of severity in regional inequality and

strength in regional autonomy on the relative amount of targeted spending in which benefits

more are directed to individuals across all territorial units. With a rise in the severity of regional

inequality, the strength of regional autonomy should be positively correlated with the size of

relative budget allocation towards targeted spending.16

To summarize, this chapter theorizes inter-regional inequality as conceptually distinct

from inter-personal income disparity. I describe individual redistributive motives by economic

geography and then apply this theory to the political logic of redistributive conflicts. A

discussion on the intervening role of regional autonomy also helps to identify a condition under

which disparate regions’ redistributive conflicts among disparate regions lead to policy gridlock

or a policy compromise. The next three empirical chapters present supporting evidence and

policy implications.

16 Although not shown here, I assume a symmetry of interaction that as the strength of regional authority grow,

severity in regional inequality is also increasingly correlated with relative targeted spending.

39

CHAPTER 3

Spatial Patterns of Individual Support for Public Education Financing:

Evidence from South Korea

Regions differ by their level of income as well as their internal distribution of income.

These differences affect the redistributive interests of their residents. In the previous theory

chapter, I explained how an economic disparity in regional income could shape a policy alliance

between individuals with preferences for redistributive spending. The crux of my argument here

is that both poor and rich residents in the poor areas prefer higher levels of public spending.

These geographically clustered people demand higher central government expenditures, which

are financed by centralized taxes and redistributed across economically disparate regions of a

country. The poor in the poor regions want it because they are likely to be net beneficiaries of

this centralized redistribution, and the rich in the poor regions want it because it offsets the tax

burden to support their poor neighbors which they would otherwise fund by themselves at the

local level. In comparison, residents in affluent regions are likely to prefer having their tax

revenues spent within their regions. More central redistribution requires higher central taxes,

which becomes burdensome for the rich taxpayers from the affluent regions. The marginal gains

of the poor in affluent regions decrease with broader centralized redistribution because they

share the benefits with the poor in the other regions.

To test these regional characteristics influencing the redistributive interests of

individuals, I performed a series of regression analyses. The associated sample data was drawn

from a recent Korean General Social Survey (KGSS) regarding citizen preferences for increases

in public education spending, a policy that is highly centralized in administrative proceedings.

40

To explain the variance of individual preferences across regions, I use the survey respondent’s

residential information. The analysis presented below offers strong evidence that both rich and

poor residents in poor regions support higher public education spending, whereas those in

affluent regions tend to oppose expansionary spending. This empirical result suggests that

regional wealth disparity trumps the redistributive motives of individuals.

The remainder of this survey data analysis is organized as follows. First, I begin with a

case that describes a top-down administrative structure of resource allocation deeply rooted in

Korean public education financing. Second, I offer a brief literature review on the relationship

between income inequality and public spending. This following section details my hypotheses

and their theoretical foundations. Third, in the data section, I describe details of the KGSS data’s

variables and measures. Then, the following section presents the results from my regression

analyses. Lastly, I discuss policy implications of the findings.

Case Selection: The Structure of Public Education Financing in South Korea

The finance of Korean public education is highly centralized.17 Most funding for local

school management costs comes from the central government’s grants and subsidies, equivalent

to roughly 20 percent of the country’s total internal revenue. Additional funding is also available

on the revenue of the education tax, which is levied as surtax on many other types of national

17 In this chapter, I set the analytic scope of public education restricted to public and non-tertiary sectors only, given

that private sources play a much bigger role in financing tertiary education in Korea. For instance, in 2001, 73

percent of tertiary education funds came from private sources. This number is considerably larger than the OECD

average of 31 percent (see OECD Education at a Glance 2014).

41

Figure 4. Centralized Structure of Education Financing in Korea (2006)

taxes including, for example, the gasoline tax and the transportation tax.18 This fund is managed

by the Ministry of Education (MOE). Additionally, there is a small portion of revenue coming

from fees and tuition paid by the students and their parents.

As illustrated in Figure 4, the educational administration of Korea has the three-tier

structure comprised of the central management (i.e., MOE), the macro-local administrative

divisions (i.e.,16 metropolitan and provincial offices of education), and the local subdivisions

(i.e., 180 regional offices of education). The autonomy of local education services is

18 Some education revenue is collected at the local level, although it is much smaller in scale. However, this

localized function is operationalized in a centralized manner. For example, the revenue of Local Education Tax

collected by local governments goes to the Local Education Special Account, a revenue source of Offices of

Education at 16 prefectures over which the central Ministry of Education takes full control.

180 Regional Offices of Education: Funding Mostly Tranferred to Teachers' Salaries in Local Schools.

16 Metropolitan and Provincial Offices of Education (as Administrative Arms of

MOE)

The Ministry of Education (MOE) Budget at the Central Goverment.

20% of internal tax revenue allocated for local governments' education budgets.

Education Tax Revenue (as Surtax)

Budget Planning and Administrative Decisions

80% of thier revenue transferred from the MOE

Other revenue (small degree) transfered from local governing bodies, internal assets, locally issued bonds, school admission fees and tuition.

42

institutionally promoted by electing the head of the local office of education directly in the local

election. However, the authority and responsibility are still financially centralized between these

offices of education. For instance, regional offices of education receive roughly 80 percent of

their revenue (primarily going to the payment of teachers’ salaries) from the grants and subsidies

of the MOE. Also, 16 prefectural educational offices, under which regional offices are

administered, act as administrative arms of the MOE regarding budget planning and decisions.

The continuity of centralized public education finance is mainly attributed to the “blurred

nature” of expenditure responsibilities between the central and local governments (Kim, 2004).

Although Korea has a full-fledged local autonomy system (started in 1995) for balanced regional

development, the fiscal decentralization has been unclear in policy implementation. There are

two reasons for this lingering policy problem, particularly in the domain of public education

finance. First, the Korean government has long pursued public education as an egalitarian tool

for the public regardless of geographic location or socio-economic status.19 The second reason

concerns the coordination issue of strategic interest. For the central government, practicing a

system of centralized redistribution creates opportunities to exert its fiscal power over local

governments. By coalescing to this policy intervention from the center, local governments

19 See an introductory note by Byun (2010) for two long-run policy examples: 1) Education Tax Act (in 1958) for

free compulsory primary education; 2) high school equalization policy (HSEP in 1974) with the introduction of

random school assignment. In the region adopting the HSEP, the middle school graduates are assigned to a high

school within their residential areas based on a random computerized lottery. In case of the regions not adopting the

HSEP, public high schools generally select their students through region-wide high school entrance exams or middle

school transcripts.

43

reserve an institutional channel to ask for more intergovernmental transfers whenever needs for

local expenditure are greater than supplies of locally raised funds.20

Theoretical Frame: Individual Income Positions and Preferences for Public Education

Subsidies

Starting from the seminal contribution of Meltzer and Richard (1981), scholarship in

political economy has shown that individual preferences for redistribution may be inferred from

an individual’s position in the distribution of income. The relevant works by Boix (1997, 1998)

and Ansell (2008a/b, 2010) apply this frame to the study of education. The poor like to support

funding for education because the tax-funded money goes to those who are at the lower end of

the income distribution. On the contrary, the more well-off individuals, who have a greater

ability to opt out for private education, tend to oppose increases in public education subsidies

that are funded by tax hikes.21

20 These cases are quite common, especially among the poor regions having fiscal difficulties to meet increasing

demands, given that local taxation is virtually fixed in Korea. See a similar view in McLure (2001) and Bird &

Tarasov (2004).

21 The redistributive policy preference from income position over publicly financed education is not always clear-

cut, however. The lower income class might prefer more spending on other social policies instead of education

spending, depending on the degree of their demands and expectations for immediate redistributive consequences. As

for the wealthy, they might support the expansion of public subsidies to education when they expect more benefits

from it (e.g., increased labor productivity via the promotion of public access to education) than from other social

policies, or when they need to pay for private education at very high costs (Fernandez & Rogerson, 1995; Ansell,

2008a/b). Therefore, as argued by Levy (2005), if the aggregated effects of income position are tested against

44

These micro-foundations of individual policy preferences, however, have largely ignored

interactions with macro-institutional contexts that affect the relative pay-offs of public

investment in different income classes. This macro-micro joint relation has received little

attention among previous studies that have attempted to identify determinants of preferences for

education spending. Exceptions are partially provided by more recent scholarship (e.g., Ansell,

2010; Busemeyer, 2009, 2012; Busemeyer & Iversen, 2014; Kitchelt & Rehm, 2006). These

pertinent works hinted that the impact of the individual income position on education preferences

strongly depends on the interplay between the individual’s position on the income scale and the

types of institutional arrangements (e.g., representation systems, partisan participation in

government, and existing levels of socio-economic /educational stratification).

Although this multilevel research has significantly contributed to a better understanding

of individual- and institutional-level determinants of policy preferences, there has been a lack of

discussion about the impact of spatial (or more precisely, geographic) contexts on the micro-

level dynamics of preference formation. This is an important omission, especially for the

discussion of individual policy attitudes towards the education subsidies redistributed from the

central government. Inequality in the asset distributions across regions sets the price for the

income share contributing to education investment at different marginal costs (Beramendi &

Rehm, 2016), and this relative price is likely to constrain the central government’s provision

(Wibbels, 2005). As argued by Kim (2006), the wealthy regions view redistribution by the

central government as expensive because they pay for the services (or resources) that are

education preference in fiscal terms, an individual’s income position as such may not necessarily serve as a

significant determinant.

45

transferred to their poor counterparts. On the other hand, poor local governments may interpret

this transfer as a process to guarantee them more fiscal resource inflows.

As an extension to this locality-based research, my focus lies on the policy effects of

macro contexts interacting with the micro-level dynamics of preference formation. To be

concrete, my contextual approach examines the role of regional economic disparity (macro-

component) in shaping the way that an individual’s income position (micro-component)

determines preferences on education spending. I place emphasis on the role of disparity in

regional wealth as a key macro-level determinant of individual preference for public education

investment. I argue for more (less) support among residents in poor (rich) regions. The

centralized redistribution of tax-funded money makes these people net beneficiaries

(contributors) at the price they pay for sharing the public provision of education spending.

Survey Data for Empirical Validation

To examine how individual income positions in the context of regional wealth may affect

individual policy preferences for public education spending, I use the Korean General Social

Survey (KGSS) data collected in 2006. The dataset includes the most recent information about

individual attitudes towards increases in education subsidies by the central government.

Respondents’ geographic locations are identified at the municipal level.22 To be specific, the

KGSS includes the following question about preference for more public education spending:

22 Samples were collected for the population over the age 18 across 96 subnational regions at the municipal level. To

do so, the survey used a multi-stage area cluster sampling method for a total of 1605 interviews.

46

Please show whether you would like to see more or less government spending on education.

Remember that if you say “much more,” it might require a tax increase to pay for it.

1. Should spend much less

2. Should spend less

3. Should spend the same as now

4. Should spend more

5. Should spend much more

Figure 5 (below) summarizes the overall distribution of individual preferences for education

subsidies provided by the central government.23 The average preference level is around 3.8 on a

five-ordinal scale moving from “spend much less” to “spending much more.” The response share

of each category amounts to 26.2 percent for “spend much more,” 43.0 percent for “spend

more,” 21.1 percent for “spend the same as now,” 6.4 percent for “spend less,” 0.6 percent for

“spend much less,” and 2.7 percent for “don’t know.”24 From an overall perspective of the KGSS

samples, a majority of the survey respondents show their support for spending increases (rather

than decreases) in general, regardless of policy categories including environment, health, law

23 The survey respondents do not necessarily know at which government level funding for public education is

collected and redistributed. The survey did not specify nor provide information before the query was exposed to the

respondents.

24 “Don’t know” answers are excluded from the analysis. Including them in the same category as “spend the same as

now” did not alter key findings in any meaningful ways.

47

Figure 5. Variations in Public Support for Education Financing

Source: KGSS 2006 (96 Municipal Regions)

Government should spend money: education

enforcement, education, and retirement pension.25 This general pattern for pro-spending attitudes

applies to the survey questions including the area of public education, where support for

increases in education subsidies reached almost 69 percent of the total responses. Education is

25 See for a similar case in Jacoby (1994)’s study of the American public opinions. By and large, the respondents

showed a desire to have a small government but in terms of spending questions pertinent to a specific policy

category, they show strong preference for spending increase rather than decrease.

48

the largest portion of public support for any policy category examined in the survey

questionnaires. One way to interpret this positive number is that people perceive increases in the

public provision of education subsidies as a channel for equal opportunities (note that we saw

this aspect earlier in the Korean government’s key policy agenda). But at the same time, people

may also see such increases as an important economic engine for human capital development

(Park, 2008). Nonetheless, it is plausible that respondents are aware of the increased tax burden

associated with increased spending (as it was mentioned within the survey question). The

“spending much more” category was only about half the percent as those for large spending (26

percent vs. 43 percent), perhaps because respondents are reminded of the tax burden at that

category.

The second reason for my use of the KGSS data is that they provide valuable

demographic information regarding each survey respondent’s geographic location by

administrative districts (the survey assigned each respondent with a block number indicative of a

municipal region). The geographic data are broken down into 96 regional locations at the

municipal level. 26 This information allows me to examine the spatial distribution of individual

preferences for education spending. My expectation is that the people in the rich metropolitan

areas will be relatively unsupportive of the broad redistribution of public education subsidies,

compared to the people in the less developed regions.

Figure 6 presents scatter evidence among subnational regions in their proportional

differences in total respondents who answered, “should spend much more.” For instance,

Pyeongtaek-si (a suburb region) had 63 percent of the respondents for expansionary education

26 I used the municipal level identification for the survey respondents in order to closely match them with their

electoral districts at a local level.

49

Figure 6. Geographic Distribution of Public Support for Education Financing

Source: KGSS 2006 (96 Municipal Regions)

Notes: Administratively, local governments are divided into a total of 16 prefectures and 234 municipalities. Prefectures, upper-

level local governments, are composed of a metropolis (Seoul), six wide-area cities (Busan, Daegu, Incheon, Gwangju, Daejeon,

and Ulsan), and nine provinces (Gangwon, Kyonggi, Chungbuk, Chungnam, Jeonbuk, Jeonnam, Gyeongbuk, Gyeongnam, and

Jeju). Municipalities consist of cities, towns (Gun), and special districts (Gu). Cities have a population of 50,000 or more, and

towns (Gun) have a population of under 50,000. Special districts are autonomous municipalities under seven big cities (Seoul and

Six wide-area cities).

50

spending, while Secho-gu in Seoul (a capital region) showed that the supporters were only about

33 percent of all responses. Please see Appendix 2 for additional contrasts with other regions in

urban Seoul, which ranges from 20 percent (Jungnang-gu) to 50 percent (Gangbuk-gu).

However, as illustrated in Figure 6, this stark contrast is not always the case, as can be seen in

the comparison between rural districts and six additional metropolitan cites other than Seoul.27

For example, the KGSS survey data collected from Yeongdo-gu—a densely populated district of

Busan, which is the largest port city of South Korea—show that roughly 57 percent of the survey

respondents expressed a strong preference for expansionary spending on public education. This

number is only marginally different from the approximation describing Pyeongtaek.28

Dependent Variable

My empirical research is interested in the behavioral patterns of individuals reacting to

tax-funded spending for public education. Given that, I used a binary coding for representing

“spending much more” with a tax burden reminder, instead of keeping the original five-scale

index (spend much more, more, the same as now, less, or much less).29 The methodological base

for such binary coding follows a contingent valuation method (CVM) that can measure demands

for public services by asking the survey respondents about their willingness to pay for the

27 This is also called six “wide-area” cites, listed as Busan, Daegu, Daejeon, Gwangju, Incheon, and Ulsan. Please

see Figure 6 for their geographic reference in Korea.

28 Defined by the intra-regional distribution of public resources, the net benefit to individuals remains

disproportionate with the size of the local population. Intergovernmental transfers may offset some of the negative

impacts of population density. Fortunately, the sample weight was applied to the KGSS data as indicated in the

survey methodology section, although the weight variables are publicly unavailable.

29 A robustness check for the ordinal scales is reported in Appendix 6.

51

services. This CVM-type survey is common in the works that address a type of value placed by

citizens on education (Mitchell & Carson, 1989; Duncome et al., 2003). Nearly 25 percent of the

KGSS’s respondents support expansionary spending on public education, even at a risk of a

higher tax burden. See Appendix 2 for the binary data distribution by municipalities, which

ranges from 0 percent (Gimpo-si, near Seoul) to 63 percent (Pyeongtaek-si) in support of a major

tax-funded increase in education spending.

Independent Variables

The independent variables of interest are four groups of individuals, defined by their

place in the income distribution (both in the national and region distribution), and by the overall

income of their regions.30 First, I grouped residents according to their position in the nationally

aggregated income distribution as poor residents in poor regions (Pp), rich residents in poor

regions (Rp), poor residents in rich regions (Pr), and rich residents in rich regions (Rr). Then I

modified these group identifiers (PP, RP, Pr, Rr) into the categories of individuals’ relative income

positions within their region (P̅P, P̅r, R̅P, R̅r). I provide greater detail about these identifiers in the

following pages (See Table 3 below for a summary).

Distribution of National Wealth across Regions

The relevant macroeconomic context is inequality in the distribution of national wealth

across geographic regions (henceforth called economic geography). To measure economic

30 The interaction between the individual’s income position and the distribution of the regional wealth can be

constructed as a continuous variable, but this does not allow for me to identify four different groups from the

estimation model all together.

52

geography, I use the regional index of financial independence from the central government. I

measure fiscal independence rather than a direct measure of income because the regions’ fiscal

resources (which might not be closely related to wealth) are closer in theory to the analysis at

hand. Regional residents’ view of policy funded at the central level should be compared to the

funding available in their region. The municipal level data were obtained from the Korean

Statistical Information Service (KOSIS) portal. This index is a ratio of the municipal

government’s own-source revenue to its total revenue. The higher ratio the local government has,

the more independently it functions from the central government subsidies.31 A high tax ratio

also suggests that a region is rich. Simply for inferential convenience, this ratio index measure is

converted to a percentage. It covers the total of 96 municipal regions from which the KGSS data

were collected. It shows a range from 10.1 (Yechen-gun, a rural region) to 90.4 (Secho-gu, a

capital region). In Seoul only, Gangnam-gu (one of the richest regions located on the south side

of the Han River) is almost 2.8 times more financially independence than Jungnan-gu (one of the

relatively less affluent regions located on the north side of the Han River). See Appendix 2 for

additional details on regional variation.32

31 Rich regions often receive large fiscal transfers from the central government as part of the initiative to boost local

economic development. Based on the financial independence formula (i.e., given as own-source revenue divided by

total revenue), such transfers are inversely proportional to the rich region’s level of fiscal independence. However,

in many cases, rich regions are also densely populated. In other words, more own-source revenues are anticipated

form their tax bases. The correlation between the size of the regional population and the index of financial

independence is 0.75 (p <0.05).

32 Apparently, it not necessarily the case that the densely populated municipal regions show a high ratio in the

financial independence index. This is because these regional areas are often recipients of the central government

subsidies due to increasing public demands from their large populations.

53

On disparities in regional wealth, each region was assigned to a decile rank by the level

of financial independence. Note that I did not use a direct measure of regional finance here

because the policy effects triggered by the poor and the rich jurisdictions do not necessarily rely

on a linear assumption due to the (typically right) skewed distribution of regional wealth. In

comparison, a decile rank makes it easier to create different profiles for the disparity in regional

wealth. In practice, municipal regions ranked at the top 20 percent in the distribution of the

financial independence data are considered economically well-off (notated as a subscript of r).

Whereas, those ranked at the bottom 20 percent are considered economically destitute (notated as

a subscript of p). Dummy coding was applied to the variables capturing these two regional

groups, with notions of r and p.

Distribution of Individual Incomes

To show individuals’ positions in the nationally aggregated income distribution, I used

the KGSS data on the monthly income (before tax and other deductions) of the respondent’s

household—values weighted for the size of their household. The household income measure is

used to maximize observations and is a better indicator of individuals’ overall economic

conditions than is individual income (see also Busemeyer et al., 2009; Busemeyer & Iversen,

2014). To distinguish rich (henceforth, denoted by a capital letter R) from poor (denoted by a

capital letter P), every survey respondent was assigned to a decile rank by his or her level of

household income. This rank information is coded in two dummy variables (i.e., the rich ranked

at the top 20 percent, and the poor ranked at the bottom 20 percent). 33

33 As a robustness check, I also adopted a different threshold value (e.g., the top 40 percent and the bottom 40

percent in the distribution of household income). See Appendix 4 for consistency.

54

Table 3. Summary of Household Income Distribution by Regions

Distribution of Household Income among Individuals

(Nationwide)

(Region-specific)

Poor (P) Bottom 20%

Rich (R) Top 20%

Poor (P̅) Bottom 20%

Rich (R̅) Top 20%

Distribution of

National Wealth

across Subnational

Regions

(Nationwide)

Poor (p) Bottom 20%

P p R p P̅ P R̅ P

Rich (r) Top 20%

P r R r P̅ r R̅ r

In short, the group identifier box that sits on the left side of Table 3 illustrates four

different income groups. These are solely based on the individual’s position in the nationally

aggregated income distribution. Pp, for instance, may be equivalent to those destitute poor living

in a remote rural area. On the other hand, Rr represents those who have high earning jobs and

live in an affluent region like Gangnam-gu in Seoul (similar to Beverly Hills in Los Angeles,

California).

The group identifier box that sits on the right side of Table 3 differs in nature by relative

income specific to regions. I assigned the decile rank information of household income

distribution among individuals according to their relative positions in the region-specific income

distribution. To avoid confusion with the nationwide income rank, I applied a new notation for

household income rank specified by regional scope: P̅P < R̅P (written as poor and rich residents

within an impoverished region, respectively) versus P̅r < R̅r (written as poor and rich residents

within an affluent region, respectively). This rank order is in part similar to what we saw earlier

from the household income rank, based on the nationally aggregated distribution (Pp = Pr < Rp =

55

Rr).34 However, when considering relative income positions specific to regions, the former

should differ from the latter in various ways: for example,

either P̅P < P̅r < R̅P < R̅r or

P̅P < R̅P < P̅r < R̅r , or

P̅P < (R̅P = P̅r) < R̅r.35

In simple terms, this implies that the poor in rich regions, P̅r, may earn more or less than (or

equal to) the rich in poor regions, R̅p. In contrast, according to an intra-regional perspective, it is

certain that the earnings of P̅r are less than those of R̅r.

The earning of R̅r (region-specific) should also be bigger than that of Rr (nationwide). As

a real data example from the KGSS in 2006, a group of individuals holding income attributes of

R̅r corresponds to Gangnam-gu’s top 20 household income holders. The data show that these

34 According to the nationally aggregated income distribution, individuals holding the same level of household

income are simply geographically dispersed. In other words, some people living in a wealthy region (Pr) are as poor

as those staying in a poor region (Pp). In fact, an urban area typically shows higher interpersonal inequality than a

rural area. For example, this assumes that Pr may earn an equivalent income to Pp.

35 There are other possibilities for the income rank order as described below.

1) P̅P < P̅r < R̅r < R̅P (e.g., the millionaires living in rural areas)

2) P̅r < P̅P < R̅P < R̅r (e.g., the destitute poor living in urban ghetto areas)

3) P̅r < P̅P < R̅r < R̅P (e.g., conditions 1 and 2 combined)

However, for the sake of model simplicity, in this research I treat these additional cases as outliers. This means that

my analysis begins with an assumption: on average, P̅P is a group of the poorest individuals where as R̅r is a group

of the richest individuals in their income status nationwide. Moreover, this assumption matters for my analysis

focusing on the costs and trade-offs associated with P̅r and R̅P, depending on the regional outlook of income

distribution.

56

individuals mostly had high earning jobs varying from administrative associate professionals to

trade brokers. R̅r’s average monthly income amounted to $10,837 (converted from Korean won

in 2006). This amount is roughly 4,000 dollars more than the average household earning of Rr

($6,983). As such, the real data difference between R̅r and Rr reveal that relative income strata

vary, depending on the geographic locations of unequal income holders.

To ensure that the earning of R̅r is greater than that of R̅p, I checked the KGSS data.

Seocho-gu, which makes up the greater Gangnam area along with Gangnam-gu, is on the

southern side of the Han River. The KGSS data identifies R̅r (Secho-gu’s top 20 household

income earners) as having an average monthly holding of $19,530 in 2006. This dollar amount is

almost five times bigger than the average monthly earning of R̅p in Jungnang-gu (a less affluent

region on the northern side of the Han River in Seoul). The average monthly household income

of R̅p in Jungnang-gu was $4,515 in 2006. This relative income level tendency toward R̅r > R̅p

implies that the rich in affluent regions earn more than the rich in less affluent regions.

According to the KGSS’s additional household income reports, the bottom 20 percent of

household income earners (P̅r) in the greater Gangnam area was found to have average monthly

income holdings of $3,440 (Seocho-gu) and $989 (Gangnam-gu). These amounts are much

larger than the average monthly income holding of P̅P from Haenam-gun, which ranks as the in

the distribution of financial independence (See Appendix 2). In 2006, Haenam-gun’s bottom 20

percent household income earners maintained their average holding of $215 per month. This

relative income portion suggests that, in general, the poor in poor regions have fewer earning

opportunities than do the poor in rich regions.

57

Table 4. Summary of Expectations on Support for Increased Education Spending

Household Income

(Nationwide)

Household Income

(Region-specific)

Poor Rich Poor Rich

Regional

Wealth

Poor [Pp] + [Rp] + Poor [P̅P] + [R̅P] +

Rich [Pr] - [Rr] - Rich [P̅r] - [R̅r] -

The cross check (nationwide vs. region-specific) available from Table 4 helps to yield

predictions about policy preferences of two focus groups in particular: Pr and Rp (also with P̅r

and R̅p). First, applied to the nationally aggregated income distribution scheme, Pr could be

identical to Pp regarding their cost sharing at the same rate of taxation that goes to the national

government’s vault.36 However, Pr could benefit greatly from the large tax contribution by Rr

(given an income level where Rr > Rp), which would help to offset a fixed cost (determined by a

progressive tax rate) incurred to them as long as all available funds for public education were

collected and redistributed intra-regionally rather than nationally. This yields the expectation that

Pr dislikes or at least remain unsupportive of increasing funding for public education that is

shared across regions.

36 Note that this scenario excludes a case in which Rr is also simultaneously identical to Rp at the rate of tax pay. In

such a case, it would assume the same income distribution in every region; hence there would be no distinction

between the rich regions and the poor regions, but rather it would assume one single polity (Meltzer & Richard,

1981).

58

The second prediction also rests on the nationwide income distribution base. The cost of

raising funding for public education could be fixed at the same rate of progressive taxation to

both Rp and Rr. Nonetheless, as for Rp even at the fixed cost, having high local demands from

their poor population would make every single penny of spending worthless towards the quality

improvement of public education unless there are additional contributions from Rr. In other

words, national redistribution to the poor region offsets local education spending that would be

borne by the Rp in a decentralized system. Thus, it is likely that Rp supports expansionary

spending when tax-funded money goes to the central government and gets redistributed across

regions broadly.

This method of scope allows for identifying differences in relative marginal return to

income earners, all depending on the economic geography of their residential locations.37 Several

additional predictions can be drawn from variations in income distribution by region. First,

defined by the region-specific income distribution, P̅r may earn more than P̅p, although it is

obvious that P̅r earns less than R̅r. Second, this assumes that P̅r pays more education tax than does

P̅p, according to the system of progressive national taxation in Korea. From this relative

difference in tax-funded cost among groups, one deduces a third prediction that is, to raise

funding for cross-regional public education, P̅r would have to contribute some of its income

distributions to P̅p, which would reduce P̅r’s net benefits after taking into account the tax

37 In Korea, the education tax collected by the central government is uniformly applied to all income earners at a

progressive tax rate. The costs incurred to these individual taxpayers, therefore, differ only by their income level,

and are independent of their geographic locations. However, location also matters when policy interest comes down

to net benefits, calculated on the basis of location (which assumes that income distribution differs by regions) and

the tax costs to be applied to individuals.

59

contribution by their wealthier counterparts. It is suggested therefore that P̅r might not have a

strong incentive to support increased education spending. The fourth prediction, also applying a

region-specific income distribution scheme, is concerned with the policy incentives of R̅p , visa

vie R̅r. Assuming that the income level of R̅p is lower than that of R̅r, R̅p’s share of income

supplemented by funding from R̅r to finance cross-regional public education would offset costs

to providing education for their local P̅p. Individuals in R̅p pay a fixed amount of tax, but their net

benefits differ depending on whether they have a system of redistribution that includes R̅r or not.

Based on this, we expect that R̅p would support more funding for education when the benefits are

redistributed cross-regionally.

To incorporate this set of expectations into the model estimating all types of cross-level

relations between individual income positions and economic geography, I use dummy variables

to code for nationwide factors of Pp, Rp, Pr, and Rr (also similarly for region-specific factors of

P̅p, R̅p, P̅r, and R̅r). For instance, Pp is assigned a value of 1 if the respondent’s income attributes

match the description of poor residents (P = 1) and poor regions (p = 1). Otherwise, a value of

zero is assigned. Following in this way, I constructed 4 dummy variables to be used together in

the regression analysis, with the middle-income earners omitted as the reference category.38

38 I purposefully chose the middle-income earners as the reference category because their preferences for

redistributive policies are rather tricky when thinking in terms of the structure of disparate income positions. As

demonstrated in the social affinity theory adopted by Lupu and Pontusson (2011), the middle class’ relative income

distance to the poor, compared to their distance to the affluent, is likely to determine public support for redistributive

policies. In addition, from a modeling perspective, the use of middle income earners as the base allows the model

incorporating all of the spatial relations discussed here to be used. In this regard, I implicitly consider Pp (P̅p) >

middle income earners > Rr (R̅r) in their preference orders regarding increases in funding for public education.

60

Controls

To isolate the effects of Pp, Rp, Pr, and Rr (and the effects of P̅p, R̅p, P̅r, and R̅r) on public

preferences for education spending increases, I employ several socio-demographic control

variables (all individual-level data) drawn from standard public sector demand models.

I take into account several alternative explanations for variations in individual

preferences for public education spending. Gender is one factor thought to affect an individual’s

support for social spending.39 It is often argued that women are more likely to favor social

spending since such public expenditures may create more opportunities for women to engage in

the active labor force (Park, 2008). Since women tend to earn less than men, we may expect

them to favor more public education spending (Busemeyer & Iversen, 2014). Female

respondents are assigned a value of 1, and zero otherwise.

College graduates are likely to support higher spending for education budgets (see

Duncombe et al., 2003). Moreover, statistics show a significant earning gap between high school

and college graduates, and this gap highlights the importance of public schools’ preparation not

only for employment but for higher education as well (Plutzer & Berkman, 2005). To capture

these individual traits, I assigned a value of 1 to all survey respondents who held a 4 year college

degree or above.

The provision of publicly funded education is an attractive policy option for families with

school age children. Married with kids is a dummy variable used as a correlative of support for

39 The names of all control variables here are italicized for clarity. These variable names were not necessarily given

in exact phrase as part of the query to the survey respondents.

61

education spending.40 As a related control, seniors are more likely to oppose increases in public

education spending because benefits from these services do not go to them directly. For further

explanation, see the intergenerational conflict argument put forth by Preston (1996) and

Duncombe et al. (2003). I created a dummy variable using the respondent’s age information. A

value of 1 is assigned to all respondents over the age of 65 years.

Occupation in education fields is likely to produce positive impacts on preferences for

spending on public education. Research shows a positive correlation between support for school

budgets and being an employee of school districts (Duncombe et al., 2003). To distinguish

respondents who work in the education field, such as teaching professionals and school

inspectors, I use the KGSS’ variable on 4 digit ISCO-88 numbers offered by the International

Standard Classification of Occupation. This code identifies the respondent’s profession. All

professions associated with education fields within the ISCO-88 are assigned a value of 1, and

zero otherwise.

I also include a measure of the respondent’s ideological self-placement on the liberal-

conservative continuum to capture an individual’s political orientation towards the public share

in education funding. According to general explanations from political psychology, a more left-

ward 41 orientation is associated with a more liberal conception of human rights—i.e., a

40 For the sake of simplicity, dummy coding is used for attributes in the joint occurrence of the respondent’s marital

status (0/1) and their staying with children (0/1). To be more precise, I extracted the pertinent information regarding

school age children from the KGSS’s compound factors in demographic variables of family members (e.g., family

members’ ages and relationship to the respondent). I then re-ran the model with this alternative dummy. The result

did not change appreciably with this alternation.

41 Here, I loosely use the conservative-liberal self-placement as interchangeable with the right-left self-placement,

although the meaning of these dimensions may vary across nations (Dalton, 2006; Inglehart, 1990; Huber &

62

preference for respecting the rights of other individuals (Haidt & Graham, 2007). The ideological

self-placement data from the KGSS are scaled into the range from very conservative (1) to very

liberal (5).

Studies show more religious people, irrespective of their denominations, are less likely to

demand social spending because religious involvement can serve as an alternative to social

insurance for individuals (see, for example, Scheve & Stasavage, 2006; Benabou & Tirole,

2006). Individuals often draw communal material support in times of difficulty from their

religious participation. See for the relevant evidence in the case of the U.S. (Hungerman, 2005;

Chen & Lind, 2014; Dehejia et al., 2007). The respondent’s religiosity is measured as the

frequency in attending religious services.

It is also important to add factors regarding the respondent’s subjective evaluation of the

political economy, as it plays a role in shaping preferences for education. To incorporate this, I

draw on a series of attitudinal survey work conducted by Duncombe et al. (2003) and Park

(2007). When taxed at high rates, individuals are less attracted to increases in tax-funded

education spending. Tax burden for high-income will diminish individual preferences for

expansionary public expenditure. Moreover, support for preferential spending on education is

anticipated to rise when the public has a more positive prospect for future economies and when

they view quality public education as an engine for development. Thus, a prospective of better

economic conditions is likely to have a positive sign on preferences for expansionary education

spending. Also, in the sense that the public provision of quality education is often viewed as

Inglehart, 1995). Quite contrary to this, however, Kim and Kang (2013) found from their cross-cultural validity

study of self-rated political orientation that both Korean and American participations have common characteristics

in self-rated political ideology.

63

equal opportunity enhancing, those respondents having a stronger expectation for government

responsiveness are apt to assign a greater degree of preference to increases in public education

funds.

Model Specification and Estimation Strategy

Based on preferential policy data that has binary outcomes, I look into a series of probit

regression estimates of support for tax-funded education spending. I put all dummy variables

together into one estimation model to examine the contextual effects of income positions across

ninety-six Korean municipal regions.42 One could argue that a multilevel model is a better way to

control for factors specific to the regions. Typically, in performing the analysis, this alternative

method suggests that we take into account the estimation uncertainty regarding individual-level

outcomes due to variations between groups—in my case, such variations would be regional

differences in financial independence. However, in this research, I do not necessarily use a

region’s financial independence as a group-level predictor for explaining the averaged preference

among all individuals that may vary across regions. This averaged preference is not my research

interest. I am more interested in examining how a region’s financial condition affects region-

specific preferences of individuals with different income holding statuses. Thus, a probit model

design is more appealing:

42 I use probit estimators instead of logit because I attempt to model high preferences for education spending as a

function of covariates. The survey recorded for preferences themselves are designed to be normally distributed as a

sampling of the population. Yet, I dichotomize it during my empirical application (i.e., high preference in spite of a

potential tax burden or not).

64

Prob [High Preference i = 1] = Φ [β1 + β2 Poor Residents in Poor Regions

+ β3 Rich Residents in Poor Regions

+ β4 Poor Residents in Rich Regions

+ β5 Rich Residents in Rich Regions

+ ∑ βj𝑗 𝑋

+ ∑ βk 𝑅𝑒𝑔𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑘 + εi ]

where the dependent variable, High Preference, takes a value of 1 if an individual respondent (i)

from the KGSS in 2006 was willing to support increases in tax-funded public education spending

even with a potential for a tax increase. Otherwise, a value of zero is assigned to all other valid

individual responses collected across municipal regions in Korea. Φ denotes the standard

cumulative normal distribution.

βs represent a series of probit estimators to be estimated. β1 is the constant term. β2

through β5 are parameters that capture the policy effects of income positions contextually related

with types of economic geography (e.g., Pp, Rp, Pr, Rr or P̅p, R̅p, P̅r, R̅r). I expect the coefficient

estimates of β2 and β3 to show a positive sign on the predicted probability of high preference. By

comparison, the signs of estimates of β4 and β5 are expected to be negative.

Retaining adjustment for the contextual effects, the estimation model also has a collection

of auxiliary variables that provide alternative explanations. The controls X are a set of standard

socio-demographic variables. See Appendix 1 for the complete list of control variables and their

distributional characteristics. The correlation among these covariates is considerably low as

65

shown in the Spearman Rank Order correlation table in Appendix 3.43 Also, I use dummy

variables for regional fixed effects to model unexplained parts of regional characteristics, such as

political culture and civic engagement. Gangnam-gu, known as one of the richest municipal

regions in South Korea, is omitted for the baseline category. Presumably, including an additional

variable in the estimated model could lead to a more heteroskedastic distribution of errors. Thus,

I will report heteroskedastic-consistent robust-standard errors.44

Empirical Results

There is reasonable evidence of spatial effects revealed by the analysis of the KGSS data

on preferences for increases in public education spending. Results from Table 5 are illustrative of

how regional wealth can shape individual redistributive motives. As far as the probit regression

estimates of preferential effects are concerned, I find that civic preferences for education

spending are not solely determined by personal income level. Economic geography also has a

jonint effect on preferences for education spending.

43 The model equation does not mix the spatial interactions constructed from a nationwide perspective with those

from a region specific perspective together. This is because I want to minimize collinearity of variables such as a

high correlation (r=0.81) between R̅r (Region specific) and Rr (Nationwide).

44 To test this assumption, I look at the likelihood ratios obtained from comparing two models: a model with an

additional control variable and a model without any control variables. When adding more variables, I anticipate

detecting a greater likelihood ratio. For the model with a full battery of controls, I expect to find the significant

presence of heteroscedasticity. For example, using the Stata “hetprob” command, I checked for statistically

significant likelihood ratio statistics. In Table 5 for Model [2], I found the likelihood ratio statistics of 20.90 and the

significant p-value of 0.022, whereas Model [4] has the likelihood ratio of 21.37 and the p-value of 0.019.

66

Table 5. Impact of Household Income Distribution on Public Support for Education

Financing in Korea

Dependent Variable:

1 = Government should spend much more on education*

0 = Otherwise

* If agreeing to “spend much more,” it might require a tax

increase to pay for it. (25% of total survey samples)

Household Income Decile

(Nationwide)

Household Income Decile

(Region-specific)

Gro

up

No

tati

on

B

Probit

Basic

[1]

Probit

Full

[2]

Gro

up

Nota

tion

Probit

Basic

[3]

Probit

Full

[4]

Poor Regions (Fiscal Independence Ranking Bottom 20% = 1, 0)

Poor Residents (Household Income Ranking Bottom 20% = 1, 0) [Pp] 0.119 0.081 [P̅p] 0.162 0.183

(0.222) (0.224) (0.256) (0.258)

Rich Residents (Household Income Ranking Top 20% = 1, 0) [Rp] 0.362 0.439† [R̅p] 0.370* 0.433**

(0.292) (0.296) (0.196) (0.198)

Rich Regions (Fiscal Independence Ranking Top 20% = 1, 0)

Poor Residents (Household Income Ranking Bottom 20% =1, 0) [Pr] -0.940** -1.017** [P̅r] 0.105 0.116

(0.469) (0.461) (0.235) (0.244)

Rich Residents (Household Income Ranking Top 20% = 1, 0) [Rr] -0.351* -0.350* [R̅̅̅r] -0.165 -0.177

(0.192) (0.195) (0.200) (0.204)

Controls

Gender (Female=1, Male=0) -0.032 -0.015 -0.037 -0.022

(0.077) (0.079) (0.077) (0.078)

College Degree (Yes = 1, No=0) 0.103 0.138† 0.100 0.138† (0.087) (0.088) (0.086) (0.088)

Married with Kids (Yes = 1, No=0) 0.172** 0.188** 0.172** 0.191**

(0.082) (0.083) (0.081) (0.082) Seniors (Age 65 or above = 1, Otherwise 0) -0.106 -0.053 -0.118 -0.069

(0.141) (0.146) (0.140) (0.144)

Occupation in Education Field (Yes = 1, No =0) 0.071 0.065 0.074 0.068

(0.140) (0.141) (0.140) (0.142)

Ideological Self-placement (Conservative 1 – Liberal 5) 0.076* 0.044 0.077* 0.045

(0.040) (0.041) (0.040) (0.041) Frequency in Attending Religious Services (1-8) -0.001 -0.000 -0.002 -0.001

(0.015) (0.015) (0.015) (0.015)

Tax Burden for High Income (Much too low 1 – Much too high 5) -0.058* -0.053† (0.034) (0.033)

Better Economic Situation (Much Worse 1 – Much Better 5) 0.072* 0.068†

(0.043) (0.043) Government Responsibility to Reduce Income Gap (1-4) 0.100** 0.108**

(0.049) (0.049) Constant (Residents of Gangnam-gu, Seoul Metropolitan Area) -0.424 -0.676 -0.677* -0.964**

(0.413) (0.500) (0.383) (0.472)

Number of observations 1,454 1,414 1,454 1,414 Fixed Effect Dummy (# of Regions) Yes (87) Yes (87) Yes(87) Yes(87)

BIC (Bayesian Information Criterion) 2337.12 2306.558 2340.865 1779.341

McFadden’s Pseudo R-squared 0.056 0.063 0.054 0.062

Hosmer–Lemeshow Chi2 (Goodness-of-fit Test) 2.75 4.73 4.45 4.33

Prob > Hosmer-Lemeshow Chi2, Testing against the null hypothesis

that there is no difference between observed and model-predicted values)

0.949 0.786 0.815 0.827

Note: Two-tailed test significant at p<0.01***, p<0.05**, p<0.1*, p<0.15†. Heteroskedastic-robust standard errors are in parentheses. The probit

model threshold for tax burden imposition is set based on five intervals (i.e., spend much less, spend less, spend the same as now, spend more, and spend much more). The total number of samples from Korean General Social Survey is 1605, but I omitted responses from nine out of

ninety-six regions from analysis due to no variation in binary outcomes. See Appendix 2 for a list of omitted regions. 72% of the data are

correctly predicted across all estimated probit models.

67

There are two empirical regularities drawn from this contextual analysis. The first one is

that both Pp and Rp (also P̅p and R̅p) are more willing to support redistributive funding for

education. The statistical result deduced from Table 5 (Models [3] & [4]) corroborates the idea

that R̅p’s share of income to finance public education spending engenders more net benefits if

this public money is collected at a progressive tax rate by the central government and

redistributed to subnational regions. As this centralized system of redistribution results in more

tax contributions from R̅r, R̅p’s attitudes are consistent with the idea that they are net

beneficiaries of education spending. As shown from estimates in Models [3] & [4], R̅p is

positively and significantly correlated with the probability of supporting centrally administered

redistribution (for the substantive effect of each variable, please refer to Table 6 below).

Where the people share attributes of Pr and Rr (also P̅r and R̅r), on the other hand, the

probability of detecting a strong preference for more education spending tends to decline.45 In

particular, probit estimates of Models [1] & [2] show that Pr is negatively (and significantly)

correlated with the probability of having a high preference for increased spending. This

relationship suggests that even in a case where Pr holds a similar income position to Pp in the

lower quartile of the nationwide distribution, more redistributive spending by the central

government would not be so attractive. This is because the inclusive procedure may lead to a

reduction in the size of regional assets available per individual having attributes of Pr.

45 The estimated effects of r defined by the region-specific income decile are not so clear-cut, however. I found this

anomaly was mainly due to variations in sampling size of middle income earners. For a robustness check, lowering a

threshold value for income disparity (i.e., top/bottom 20 percent to top/bottom 40 percent) resulted in mitigating this

empirical concern. See Appendix 4.

68

Probit estimates of Pp and P̅p (or Rr and R̅r) report anticipated positive (or negative) signs

on the probability of high preference. However, this relationship turns out to be statistically

meaningless or even insignificant. One way to interpret this null finding is that the tax burden

pressure attached to the survey query has little impact on the probability of Pp and P̅p’s

preference, given their income status that makes them the winners of redistributive spending

most of the time. On the other hand, Rr and R̅r’s share of income via tax payment to the national

government is almost always more costly than immediate benefits brought to these better-offs. In

this regard, having an additional reminder of an associated tax increase with dramatically

increased spending does not appear to make a substantial difference to the affluent individuals.

Created from full models [2] & [4] in Table 5, the post-estimation Table 6 reports the

marginal effects for the probit estimates of Pp, Rp, Pr, and Rr (as well as P̅p, R̅p, P̅r, and R̅r). From

this comparative statics, I find that the marginal effect of size varies relative to the respective

comparison group—i.e., the middle-income earners (defined either in the nationally aggregated

distribution or the region-specific distribution). The y-axis shows a list of dummy variables that

capture four types of the spatial relations between income positions and economic geography. On

the x-axis, the number represents changes in the estimated predicted probability induced by

taking the effects of Pp, Rp, Pr, and Rr (as well as P̅p, R̅p, P̅r, and R̅r) into the regression while

holding other factors at their means or 1 (if dummies).46 Also, the point estimates with their

confidence intervals can be found in Table 6. The further the left (right), the lower (higher) the

probability associated with public approval of expansionary spending on public education.

46 Based on the probit estimates, I use the Stata command “dprobit” to calculate marginal effects. This method

reports discrete changes of dummy variables (Pp, Rp, Pr, and Rr (as well as P̅p, R̅p, P̅r, and R̅r)) from 0 to 1.

69

Table 6. Marginal Effects of Income Distribution on Public Support for Education

Financing (with 90% and 95% Confidence Intervals)

For instance, the predicted probability of pro-spending attitudes towards tax-funded education

diminishes significantly among individuals holding attributes of Pr (in comparative statics, they

are approximately 22 percent less likely to support than are the middle-income earners in the

country). On the other hand, increases in effect size are relatively moderate among R̅p (just about

16 percent more likely to support than the middle-income earners in their respective regions).47

47 Unfortunately, my empirical model does not address how closely the earnings of middle income respondents in

the nationwide distribution approximate those of middle income respondents in the region-specific distribution.

70

However, even this moderate marginal effect of R̅p has a significantly bigger effect, relative to

the marginal effect of R̅r. This implies that high income holding residents in poor regions (e.g.,

Jungnang-gu’s top 20 percent income earners) have significantly different policy motivations

from those of high-income earners in rich regions (e.g., Gangnam-gu’s top 20 percent income

earners). What determines their difference is not the merely level of income holding.

Importantly, the difference is determined instead by the individual’s relative position in the

region-specific income redistribution.

As illustrated by the estimated effects of control variables, the probability of high

preference for education spending is also predicted by some other factors, such as marital status,

living with children, ideological self-placement, the respondent’s tax burden pressure, views on

future economic conditions, and support for inequality reduction policies. The model estimates

show that parents (married individuals with kids) are more likely to favor increases in public

finance of education, compared to their nonparent counterparts. However, marginal effects on

the probability of high preference differ only by 5 to 6 percent, depending on the models being

tested. I also find evidence among the KGSS respondents that liberal orientation is strongly

associated with preferences for increased education spending. However, the size of this estimated

impact is not substantial. For example, the propensity to support public finance for education

would be expected to have a positive change from 2.3 percent to 3.3 percent if an individual ever

experienced a dramatic shift in ideological orientation from very conservative to very liberal

(See Table 5, Models [1] & [3]). Besides, the statistical significance of this relationship on

ideological self-placement and the propensity of support for education finance become weakened

However, a country with more economically disparate regions will show a closer distance between nationally

aggregated and region-specific middle income positions.

71

with additional covariates that control for public evaluations of the economy (see Table 5,

Models [2] & [4]). On the other hand, as anticipated, the respondent’s tax burden decreases from

1.7 to 1.9 percent (depending on the models) in the predicted probability of high preference,

whereas a prospect for better economic conditions increases the chance from 2.2 to 2.4 percent.

The degree of holding the government accountable for equity is also significantly and positively

correlated with a considerably high preference for public education spending. This relationship

yields a probability estimate of a pro-spending attitude that increases by 3.2 to 3.5 percent. All

other control variables, however, show insignificant results.

Model Fit

A binary regression does not offer an equivalent statistic to the R-squared value in the

OLS regression because the model estimates are maximum likelihood estimations obtained by an

iterative process. Unlike the OLS estimate that reports this goodness-of-fit measure, a ML

estimate is not calculated to minimize variance. To evaluate the goodness-of-fit of the probit

models, researchers often use measures for “pseudo” R-squared (e.g., McFadden’s). Such

measures also run similarly along a scale ranging from 0 to 1 (with a higher value indicating a

better fit), although these statistics do not mean the same thing as the R-squared value in OLS

regressions (i.e., variations in the dependent variable explained by the model). The values of my

estimated “pseudo” R-squared from the probit analysis range from 0.05 to 0.06. However, it is

common in a binary regression to have a small pseudo R-squared value when resorting to a

maximum likelihood estimate (e.g., pseudo R-squared less than 0.1 is common in the empirical

literature. See Chu & Willet, 2009). Judging from the size of the pseudo R-squared, I find that

the probit estimates of full models show improvement on model fit. Moreover, to have an

72

alternative check on the fit of these probit models, I ran a Homwer-Lemeshow (H-L) Chi-

squared test. The H-L Chi-squared statistic does not show significant evidence against the null

hypothesis that there is no difference between observed and model-predicted values (see Hosmer

et al., 2013). Indeed, the model shows that more than 72% of data are correctly predicted across

all estimated probit models, and this provides evidence that the model has a reasonable fit.

Another concern with model fit is that adding parameters can increase the likelihood but

result in overfitting. Both BIC (Bayesian Information Criterion) and AIC (Akaike Information

Criterion) mitigate this problem by introducing a penalty term for the number of parameters in

the model. I report the BIC in Table 5 because the penalty term is larger for BIC than AIC. The

smaller the BIC, the better the model fit. As seen in Table 5, the full model (Model [4])—

defining income distribution by region—presents the smallest BIC value.

Robustness Tests

To ensure the robustness of the findings from Table 5, I also check the regression results

from an alternative specification based on the ordered probit estimation method. First, each of Pp,

Rp, Pr, and Rr (as well as P̅p, R̅p, P̅r, and R̅r) is defined at an alternative threshold value; the rich

fall into the top 40 percent income bracket and the poor rank at the bottom 40 percent of the

distribution. See Appendix 4 for the proceeding of this revision on contextually determined

income group specifications. Such modification allows for inferential statistics to be drawn with

a smaller size of the middle-income reference group. This alternative model specification does

not show a significant change in the estimated preferences for increased education finance

reported in Table 5. The result from Appendix 4 shows consistency in the gains of positive

73

directional effects of Pp and Rp (also P̅p and R̅p), thus contrasting with the negative directional

effects of Pr, and Rr (also P̅r, and R̅r).

Unlike studies using experimental data, this survey analysis relies on observation data,

where the assignment into a treated group—i.e., individual identification of Pp, Rp, Pr, or Rr (as

well as P̅p, R̅p, P̅r, or R̅r)—and a control group (i.e., middle income earning group) is not random.

This means that some individual characteristics make certain people more prone to being

selected into a treated group. Thus, it may be hard to compare their preferences directly based on

the pertinent group specification. In fact, this concern becomes an important issue as differences

in policy preference are shaped by geographic clusters (as partially shown earlier in Figure 3).

Therefore, before running the regression analysis, we would first need to find a

comparable propensity score that is the unbiased predicted probability of selecting into treated

groups given pre-treated individual characteristics. This technique allows for matching

observations from treated and control groups based on their propensity scores. In practice, I use

the nearest-neighbor matching method as well as a radium matching method for additional

robustness checks.48 The former seeks to select a control observation that has the closest

characteristics related to each treated observation, which, in turn, helps minimize propensity

score differences. The latter seeks to match a treated observation with control observations that

fall within a specific radius (I applied 0.03 by convention). Having these propensity matching

techniques incorporated into education spending preference model estimations, I find the most

48 To minimize data selection bias, I ensure that the data is sorted in random order prior to propensity matching. All

calibration required to find a good matching was executed through the Stata program “psmatch2.” I also cross-

checked this results with other matching methods, such as kernel matching and stratification matching, as well as the

application of bootstrap standard errors. The results remain robust.

74

significant evidence that Pr (defined by nationwide income distribution) ranges from 23 to 30

percent less for supporting increases in public education than their counterparts in the middle

income earning groups; by comparison of relative preferences, R̅p (defined by region-specific

income distribution) is roughly between 15 and 19 percent more for increases in public education

spending than their counterparts in the middle income earning groups (See Appendix 5 for the

supporting evidence regarding the statistical significance of the treatment effect on the treated).

I also check results from an ordered probit estimation in a view to minimizing a bias that

might have been introduced by the implementation of an ad-hoc threshold value for binary

outcomes. In this research, the ordered probit model contains a qualitative dependent variable for

which the multiple categories (e.g., spend much more, spend more, about the same, spend less,

and spend much less) are a ranking that reflects the magnitude of individual preference.

However, I do not resort to the ordered probit analysis for my base model. The ordered probit

limits an analytical ability to distinguish “spend much more” (with the attachment of a tax

burden disclaimer) from all other response categories (without this tax disclaimer), and there is

also not much variation across negative reactions to increased education spending among the

KGSS respondents (as shown in Figure 5). In any event, Appendix 6 presents ordered probit

estimates of Pp, Rp, Pr, and Rr (as well as P̅p, R̅p, P̅r, and R̅r ) on policy preferences in ordinal

values, ranging from 1 (should spend much less) to 5 (should spend much more). The results

from the different sample sizes—whether accounting for 87 regions (the same as in Table 5) or

96 regions (the expanded samples allowed by using more variations in the dependent variable)—

show consistency in the expected direction on the spatial interactions between income positions

and economic geography.

75

To check robustness with an alternative measure of government spending, I employ the

KGSS variable capturing public sentiment towards changes in government spending. This survey

query asks the respondents how strongly they support or oppose a reduction in government

spending, which is broadly applied to different fiscal policy areas such as unemployment

benefits, education, and public health. Historically, the central government in Korea has long

played a key role in administrating redistributive spending (Park, 2008). This alternative

dependent variable takes a value on a five-point scale, ranging from 1, “strongly in favor of

spending cuts,” to 5, “strongly against spending cuts.” The findings from Appendix 7 offer a

good deal of evidence that regional wealth matters to the public’s policy mood (Models [1]-[3],

in particular), as shown by Pr’s (and Rr’s) statistically significant correlative of changes in

overall government spending. Ordered probit estimates show that some people in the affluent

regions (Pr and Rr) tend to be less supportive of excessive spending sought by the central

government. This finding remains robust even when the estimated model accounts for more

controls regarding information about unemployment status, the respondent’s perceived level of

socioeconomic class, and working status in government or public works (see Appendix 1 for the

detail data description).

My findings can be summarized in two succinct ways. First, there is a contextual effect

between income inequality among individuals and economic disparity among regions where

these individuals are geographically dispersed. Such an effect is best described by the features of

economic geography that point to a clustering of interest around individual support for increases

in public education spending. Second, I test this effect from various types of economic

geography that capture income positions constitutive of regional wealth from a national spectrum

(i.e., Pp, Rp, Pr, and Rr ) as well as a region-specific one (i.e., P̅p, R̅p, P̅r, and R̅r ).

76

The empirical results here show that certain spatial configurations, especially among the

focus groups Rp & Pr (or R̅p & P̅r), are more deterministic of civic preferences for increases in

tax-funded education spending. As the tax burden increases with the cost attached to a rise in

funding for education, R̅p is likely to support more redistributive spending through the central

government, a policy practice that has been a long tradition in Korea in the domain of public

education spending. The empirical analysis also uncovers the significant negative relation of Pr

to the preference for public finance on education—there is a diminishing marginal return to

increased funding for education that is redistributed broadly across regions. This scattered

evidence suggests that regional inequality significantly affects citizens’ strategic calculation of

self-interest subject to economic geography. It is also suggested that the public education finance

in Korea is one policy example that is reflective of how spatial relations can explain variations in

public support for government spending.

Conclusions and Policy Implications

This chapter contributes to the public spending literature by examining how individual

redistributive motives are determined by the spatial interactions between individual income and

regional wealth. My focus is on the empirical assessment that regional wealth disparity trumps

individual redistributive motives. This relationship was tested in the policy domain of public

education spending.

The empirical results in this chapter support my argument in the following ways. First of

all, both poor and rich residents in affluent regions are net contributors compared to the poor and

rich residents in less affluent regions. This relationship is incurred because, while their cost of

tax pay may be fixed, their gross benefits decrease due to this central redistribution. Their

77

relative gains diminish (or relative costs increase) as the income share is sought broadly across

regions via central education tax. This relationship is exemplified by the public education

spending in Korea that has a highly centralized system to promote equality opportunities of

education. Regarding pay-offs, both rich and poor residents in poor regions are likely to be net

beneficiaries since their relative gains increase (or relative costs decrease) due to the greater

inflows of resources from central government redistribution.

The empirical results from this chapter demonstrate how individual redistributive motives

shaped by geographic contexts affect citizen support for public education spending. The findings

from this contextual relationship reveal important policy implications on elements of public

consent that will make policy implementation on public finance easier and more efficient. For

example, civic preferences for education spending are not solely explained by an individual-level

analysis of public interest in the question of “who gets what.” This limited scope has been long

studied both theoretically and empirically and produces convincing evidence that the income

position of the poor and rich serves as an important determinant of redistributive policies. See,

for example, the political economy literature that explains the poor’s ability to extract transfers

from the rich under the full-franchised democracy and the right-skewed income distribution

(Meltzer & Richard, 1981; Boix, 2003).

However, this chapter indicates that such redistributive policies are also contextually

determined. In other words, policies are adopted by public interests formed at the micro-

foundation of individual policy interests that are subject to the macro-context of the economic

geography pertinent to the relevant individuals. From this extended scope, we learn that what is

equally important to (if not more than) the question of “who gets what” is the question of “who

gets what at which price” (Beramendi & Rehm, 2016). This new research query permits us to

78

have a better understanding of why some poor (or rich) individuals are less (or more) willing to

support increases in funding for broad redistribution when this proposed policy appears to be (or

not to be) in their best interest.

The presented empirical results are mainly about how individual interest interacts with

economic geography to influence a preferred choice, but this analytical report also reveals

shortcomings of the policy application. For example, individuals can move to another place

(either a rich region or a poor region) if it is deemed to fit with his or her best interest in the

relative size of net benefits that he or she would receive from the expansion of public provision.

Of course, moving is not an option for everyone since it depends on his or her job specificity and

financial means; labor mobility will thus draw much more complex interactions between income

positions and regional wealth. Suppose that poor individuals move from a destitute rural area to

an affluent city area to look for a better economic opportunity. The new residential location will

give a much greater return than the attached cost because it will provide a large pool of resources

from which to extract at the expense of rich people’s tax, as long as this tax-funded money gets

redistributed back to the new residents and their adjacent neighborhood. In such a case, even the

same income group could end up with different policy preferences over nationwide

redistribution, depending on the residential location.

However, moving to a new geographic location also comes with substantial costs and

risks. For example, having a specific skill set may limit one’s labor mobility given the difficulty

in finding a matched job in a new location. In this regard, relocation may cause financial

insecurities. Taking this interregional economic externality that is driven by geography, where

income and risk are heterogeneous, we start to see a complexity of regional governments’

politics. This complexity is especially noticeable when regions devise their policies for

79

redistribution (see, e.g., the design of decentralization politics explained by Beramendi, 2012). A

further discussion of this labor mobility dynamic is interesting but beyond the scope of this

current chapter.

Although the central government plays a dominant role in administrating public

education spending in Korea over the entire proceedings of tax collection and redistribution to

locals, much of non-tertiary public education spending is decentralized in many other countries

(e.g., the U.S.). It would be thus interesting to examine how the regional disparity affects the

preferences of the poor and rich in the decentralized countries. The next two chapters will

discuss these cross-national differences.

80

CHAPTER 4

Country-level Application to Comparative Public Policies:

Federalism, Regional Inequality, and Education Spending

In the previous chapter, I used the Korean General Social Survey data to show micro-

level evidence on how uneven economic geography shapes individuals’ preferences for

centralized redistribution of tax-funded money for public education. This finding has important

policy implications for a country that has disparate regions: they should expect difficulty in

policy coordination on the goods that are broadly redistributed across disparate those regions but

funded disproportionately by rich regions.

This chapter is devoted to testing an extended model that captures cross-national

differences in redistributive conflict. My core argument is that the diffusion of the national

policymaking authority across disparate regions exacerbates redistributive conflicts. The

redistributive policy conflict becomes more severe in a federal system of government than a

unitary because the former creates more veto players in the national legislative process

composed of local representatives. I highlight this conditional relationship by separating from

federalism’s interaction with inter-personal inequality (neglecting inter-regional inequality. On

the one hand, federalism combined with high inter-personal inequality leads to deficit spending

due to the reduced relative shared cost on public financing among economically homogenous

regions to mitigate high inter-personal inequality. However, considering economically diverse

regions, federalism increases regions’ policy ability to block or delay changes in expenditures

towards a less-preferred direction.

81

To show the distinctive policy effects of inequality of two types (inter-personal inequality

vs. inter-regional inequality) and its interaction with federalism on education spending, I first test

the joint effect of federalism and inter-personal inequality on the level of public education

spending. I use the level measure to test the conditional effect on deficit spending. However, to

contrast with this, I use a volatility measure for public education spending to capture the

combined effect of federalism and regional disparity that makes it hard to move away from the

status quo spending (whether increases or decreases). For this regional inequality test, I create

cross-nationally comparable measures of intra-country variances using regional GDP per capita.

These measures for inter-regional inequality are not highly correlated with the previously used

measures for inter-personal inequality.49

I find supporting evidence using panel data for overall public education spending as a

share of GDP for 18 advanced economies from 1980 to 2010. The test results illustrate

distinctive policy outcomes: 1) inter-personal inequality, measured by income distribution

percentile among individuals across the nation, is associated with a high level of public

education spending in a federal system government than a unitary. 2) In contrast, inter-regional

inequality (measured by the variance of income distribution across geographical-based

subnational units) is associated with lower levels of policy volatility in public education

49 I acknowledge that some countries suffer both high inter-personal inequality and inter-regional inequality. Of

course, all government policies deal with both inter-personal and inter-regional distributive implications

(Beramendi, 2007). Given the data availability, however, I cannot directly deal with simultaneous concerns about

inequality within a region and across regions (The Theil T measure could be an ideal one). In that regard, my

analysis is necessarily underspecified. Nonetheless, I see the value in analyzing regional effects on their own in the

same way that many empirical works looking at inter-personal inequality in isolation have contributed to the

discipline.

82

spending in a federal system of government than a unitary. These results also show evidence that

a higher level of inter-regional inequality, compared to interpersonal inequality, within a

federalist country is more vulnerable to policy gridlock.

The rest of this paper is structured as follows. First, I summarize a theory of why and

how educational policy effects of inequality of both types become distinctive under federalism,

followed by testable hypotheses. The second section discusses data and analytical strategies. The

third section reports empirical findings. Lastly, a conclusion follows with policy implications.

Governing Structure Matters: Politics of Income Inequality on the Redistribution of Public

Education Spending.

Economic inequality is a major policy concern of a redistributive government. Public

education spending is a particularly sensitive policy area because it is a primary factor in the

human capital development and future economic outcomes (Barro, 1997). National public

education spending is considered a redistributive policy (i.e., local tax revenues contribute the

national sum which gets redistributed across subnational regions via the central administration).50

Education policy is redistributive across both individuals and regions, subsidizing the relatively

poor individuals and regions. Most research in the field debates the effects of unequal income

distribution on public education spending (Meltzer & Richard, 1983; Corcoran & Evan, 2010).

The literature on public education spending, however, discuss little the policy effect of

interregional inequality jointly with institutional conditions such as the structure of governance.

In the theory chapter, I looked at how different kinds of inequality interact with a

decentralized system of government to affect the level of education spending and (more

50 Nations vary in the degree to which education spending is locally versus centrally funded and redistributed.

83

importantly) the magnitude of policy changes in education expenses. I argued that in a unitary

system, where the central government controls policies, both inter-personal inequality and inter-

regional inequality do not have a distinctive pattern of education spending. The relationship can

be positive or negative, depending on who shapes salient policies and how the central policy

planners would respond to this public demand (Meltzer & Richard, 1981; Epple & Romano,

1996; Ansell, 2008a/b).

However, as we shift our focus from unitary to federalism, the policy effects of inequality

of both types become distinctive. By its institutional design, federalism allows for local

policymakers (e.g., state legislators in the U.S) to enact national education policies that account

for a region’s specific demands (Tiebout, 1956; Oates, 1972). Federal regions with high inter-

personal inequality will demand high levels of public education spending to benefit most poor

individuals in their region (Franzese, 2005). This relationship is anticipated because these

citizens have more policy access to regional governments, compared to citizens under a single

unitary government. This system of government gives rise to a region’s exploitation of the

national revenue because local policymakers will compete to obtain more resources out of the

common pool to win their regional votes. Given their equal share of the fiscal burden to finance

broad redistribution, which makes the benefits of overdrawing outweigh the shared cost, regional

representation influencing national policy-making will increase the probability of deficit

spending. The conditions are more likely to be met when the number of fiscal policy-makers

increases and a universal agreement among them is required to pass a national redistributive

policy. In such case, we would expect more (or deficit) spending on public education than in a

unitary system of government (Weingast et al., 1981; Franzese, 2005).

84

In comparison, federal regions with high inter-regional inequality will find it hard to draw

a policy consensus on reforming redistribution than regions ruled by a unitary government.

Under a federal system, national policy making power is diffused equally to both rich and poor

regions.51 However, this diffusive power would work as a system of policy constraint as regional

disparity grows. For wealthy federal regions compared to the poorer counterparts, broader

redistribution creates a larger fiscal burden. Thus, national delegates from these richer regions

will seek to block fiscal expansion and pass budget cuts to redistributive spending. Poor regions

also have veto power to delay budget cuts while this tool is not useful to expand spending. As

regional inequality increases, the coordination of policy decision making between the rich and

the poor regions will become increasingly difficult, leading to a stalemate in which policy

gridlock is anticipated (Weingast et al., 1981; Giuranno, 2009a/b; Tsebelis, 2002; Triesman,

2000).

In hypothesis testing, I expect two possible outcomes regarding the level and magnitude

of public education spending. A federal system with inter-personal inequality, further increases

the level of public education spending, relative to a unitary system of government. On the other

hand, a federal system with inter-regional inequality engenders less change (irrespective of an

increase or decrease) in reforming public education spending than a unitary system of

government.

Data

To test the policy effects incurred by the joint relationship between income inequality and

51 Recognizing that regions’ powers can differ in federations depending on, among other things, malapportionment,

and population distributions.

85

federalism across countries over time, I use the panel data from 18 OECD countries from 1980 to

2010. My choice of the OECD data is based on the availability of regional inequality measures

as well as refined institutional controls to be used in the estimated models.

Dependent Variable

To gauge the size of overall public education spending weighted by the size of national

economies, I use the general government’s expenditure on public education as a share of GDP.

Public education spending at the general government level includes all levels of human capital

investment (primary, secondary, tertiary, and others). The general government spending measure

is also applied to both a unitary system of government and federalism to capture overall flows of

redistribution better. The intent is partly because the redistribution would not be fully captured

from a scope of the central government finance if regions have strong incentive to isolate their

fiscal sources. This data series is available from the World Development Indicators (WDI)

database provided by the World Bank group. I used public education spending observations for

18 OECD countries from 1980 through 2010.

Measures of Inter-personal Inequality

The distribution of individual income inequality is measured in the ratio of individual

earnings in the upper 90th percentile to earnings in the bottom 10th percentile – I call this

P9010.52 Although Gini coefficients are another popular measure used in the literature, Gini

52 As an alternative measure, I use the decomposition of P9010 - income differentials in the two halves of the

individual income distribution based on the 90th – 50th earnings ratio divided by the 50th – 10th earnings ratio. This

alternative measure is useful to know what extent the P9010 ratio is driven by inequality in the top of distribution

86

Table 7. Education Spending (GDP %) and Structure of Inequality in 18 OECD Countries

Average Values from 1980 to 2010

(Sources: OECD Stat 2007; Lupe and

Pontusson 2011; World Development

Indicators; UNESCO Institute for

Statistics; the author’s calculation)

90-10 Ratio

Gini

COV

GDP (%)

Countries

P9010

Ratio

Gini

(%)

COV

(0-1)

GDP

(%) Min Max Min Max Min Max

Min Max

Austria 3.31 (9) 32.47 0.22 (6) 5.45 3.23 3.38 29.00 34.60 0.19 0.24 5.01 6.25

Belgium 2.36 (16) 27.54 0.38 (1) 5.41 2.25 2.49 22.70 37.47 0.35 0.42 3.03 6.44

Canada 3.96 (3) 34.88 0.28 (3) 6.17 3.52 4.45 30.51 37.20 0.20 0.37 4.77 7.88

Denmark 2.39 (14) 29.70 0.16 (16) 7.56 2.14 2.74 27.26 32.10 0.14 0.18 5.70 8.72

Finland 2.45 (13) 21.97 0.21 (8) 5.93 2.29 2.59 15.05 25.86 0.14 0.26 4.77 7.65

France 3.11 (10) 27.72 0.18 (15) 5.30 2.83 3.28 23.98 29.20 0.16 0.19 4.38 5.90

Germany 3.34 (8) 24.12 0.30 (2) 4.53 2.94 4.28 19.89 26.60 0.25 0.43 4.43 4.61

Greece 3.36 (7) 24.35 0.21 (9) 2.62 3.24 3.44 21.80 27.20 0.16 0.28 1.77 4.09

Ireland 3.77 (4) 27.38 0.20 (10) 5.01 3.26 4.06 24.40 30.26 0.12 0.26 4.22 5.91

Italy 2.37 (15) 32.93 0.25 (4) 4.62 2.22 2.60 31.23 34.90 0.23 0.27 3.95 4.96

Netherlands 2.68 (11) 32.24 0.19 (13) 5.52 2.40 2.92 29.32 33.60 0.12 0.38 4.84 6.37

Norway 2.12 (18) 22.01 0.20 (11) 6.68 1.95 2.29 19.70 25.20 0.14 0.27 5.35 7.99

Portugal 4.36 (2) 23.42 0.24 (5) 4.33 4.25 4.66 22.19 25.60 0.19 0.36 3.09 5.79

Spain 3.70 (5) 22.80 0.19 (14) 4.21 3.29 4.22 20.81 25.54 0.18 0.23 3.22 4.98

Sweden 2.17 (17) 22.96 0.13 (18) 6.79 1.95 2.35 16.82 25.00 0.08 0.17 5.56 7.51

Switzerland 2.58 (12) 29.71 0.16 (17) 5.17 2.42 2.69 26.80 31.26 0.14 0.19 4.62 6.00

UK 3.40 (6) 31.40 0.20 (12) 5.01 2.98 3.64 25.85 35.30 0.16 0.23 4.37 5.63

USA 4.46 (1) 32.61 0.22 (7) 5.27 3.78 5.02 26.88 36.54 0.16 0.46 4.76 5.77

Note: Values in parentheses are country ranking.

vis-à-vis inequality at the bottom. As put forth by Lupe and Pontusson (2011), this method is designed to capture a

type of SKEW in the 90th -50th earnings ratio over the 50th – 10th earnings ratio. The degree of SKEW is important

because when the distance between the middle income and the lower-income is smaller relative to the distance

between the middle income and the upper-middle, the middle-income voters could “empathize” with the poorer and

support redistributive policies (in the absence of cross-cutting ethnic cleavages). Otherwise, such redistributive

motives will be a minor concern under a higher level of SKEW.

87

coefficients take account of the full income distribution identified as the relationship of

cumulative shares of the entire national income received by the population. The income quintile

ratios are preferred in my research because I am interested in the gap between the poor and the

rich. The income quintile ratio is also easy to interpret. Take for an example that the P9010 ratio

is equal to 5 (see Appendix 8 for the data ranges from 1.95 to 5.02 for the OECD samples). It

means that the poorest person in the richest 10 percent of the population in the income

distribution earns five times as much income as the richest person in the poorest 10 percent

would earn. Table 7 (above) shows time-series cross-national comparison for the distribution of

P9010. The United States, compared with Norway (ranked in the lowest in P9010), has a P9010

ratio difference of 4.46 to 2.12. That says, for example, in US dollar terms, the poorest person in

the richest group makes about four dollars more on average, compared to every single dollar that

the richest of the poorest group makes. However, in Norwegian Krone, the poorest of the richest

group makes about two Krones more. The income quintile ratio data are available from the

OECD Statistics database.

Measures of Inter-regional Inequality

Measuring regional disparity is difficult because the subnational unit level data is limited

and internationally comparable measures of geographic distribution of wealth to a country

require the consideration of many contingent factors. Empirical studies of OECD countries have

displayed a relative success in the data collection and use for robust inequality measures (Kessler

& Lessmann, 2010; Lessmann, 2009, 2011). These macro data relates regional GDP per capita,

the country’s average GDP per capita, the share of the country’s total population in a region, and

the number of regions in that country. From research on subnational income level data, regional

88

GDP per capita data is obtainable from the Cambridge Econometrics Database. I adopt a

mathematical formula most popularly used for calculating regional disparity (Lessmann, 2009,

p.2460): the coefficient of variations of regional GDP per capita (COV).53

53 I also calculated for two alternative measures for robustness (Lessmann, 2009): 1) the population-weighted

coefficient of variation (COVW) = 1

�̅�√

1

𝑛∑ 𝑝𝑖(�̅� − 𝑦𝑖)2𝑛

𝑖=1 , 2) the adjusted Gini coefficient (ADGINI)

= 2 ∑ 𝑖𝑦𝑖

𝑛𝑖=1

𝑛 ∑ 𝑖𝑦𝑖𝑛𝑖=1

−𝑛

𝑛−1 . I emphasize that three disparity measures (COV, COVW, ADGINI) are conceptually different

from each other. While both COV and COVW are measures of dispersion, COVW differs slightly by having values

adjusted for the share of the country population in a region. It could be possible for a measure of COV, without

taking different population densities into account, to report a high score, while COV may not actually matter to a lot

of people. For example, one region with 1,000 inhabitants and a regional GDP per capita of $20,000; the second

region has a regional GDP per capita of $10,000 but only 10 inhabitants (Lessmann, 2006).

Compared to COV and COVW, ADGINI focuses more on measuring deprivation. Dispersion and

deprivation are two ways to conceptualize spatial differences in wealth (see Protnove & Felsenten, 2005). The

dispersion measures, COV and COVW, only capture the distribution of income. The ADGINI retains more

meaningful information about the extent of relative poverty, not merely income spread. In ADGINI, additional

weight is given to a region’s wealth as it veers farther away from the mean of the inter-regional regional wealth

distribution. This weight value makes the inequality measure more sensitive to changes in the upper or lower tail of

this distribution.

The United States and Argentina clearly show the differences in these three measures. In the United States

in 2010, per capita income approximated USD $50,000 in Massachusetts and $30,000 in Mississippi. In Argentina

in 2006, gross provincial product per capita in Buenos Aires was USD $25, 000 and $2,500 in Tucuman. COV

would calculate these differences to be similar across jurisdictions – around $20,000. The ADGINI variable,

however, would take into account the meaningful differences in relative wealth in development is relatively even

and social safety nets redistribute wealth to the neediest populations.

89

COV = 1

�̅�√

1

𝑛∑ (�̅� − 𝑦𝑖)2𝑛

𝑖=1

where �̅� denotes the country’s average GDP per capita. 𝑦𝑖 is the GDP per capita of a region i. 𝑝𝑖

indicates the share of the country’s total population in region i. Finally, n is the number of

regions within a country. This measure is cross-nationally comparable (Lessmann, 2009; Portnov

& Felsensten, 2005).

COV is calculated based on the regional level GDP data from 18 OECD countries

covering the years from 1980 to 2010. This cross-national sample is the most available coverage

for regional GDP per capita.54 See Table 7 for the cross-national time series sample data

distribution. COV allows for the “intra-country” variance information to be translated into the

numerically continuous index (0-1) of “inter-country” variance. For inferential purposes, I

rescale these numbers on one to ten scales. The value of zero denotes that a country is perfectly

evenly developed across its regions, but the value of ten represents extreme inequality.

Two Uncorrelated Measures of Inequality

Inter-regional inequality and inter-personal inequality are not only conceptually

independent but also empirically uncorrelated with each other. Table 8 includes a country’s score

of inter-regional inequality (COV as a variation of regional GDP per capita). This chart also

includes a country’s score of inter-personal inequality measured in two folds: 1) Gini (in percent)

detects inequality in the distribution of aggregated individual income, 2) P90/10 (in ratio of the

54 Unfortunately, the micro-level data on economic inequality across sub-national units are not widely available for

most developing countries. They are critical for calibrating cross-nationally comparable measures of regional

disparity.

90

Table 8. Inter-regional Inequality and Inter-personal Inequality Compared

Average value from 2006 to 2010

Ranking

Inter-regional Inequality Inter-personal Inequality

Countries COV

(0-1)

Countries

Gini

(0-100) Countries

P90/10

(ratio)

1 Belgium 0.352 Canada 36.19 USA 4.92

2 Canada 0.318 USA 35.55 Portugal 4.28

3 Germany 0.307 Austria 33.00 Ireland 3.85

4 Norway 0.267 Italy 32.92 Canada 3.73

5 Greece 0.248 UK 31.81 Germany 3.62

6 Ireland 0.234 Denmark 31.75 UK 3.60

7 Italy 0.231 Netherlands 30.17 Spain 3.42

8 UK 0.225 Switzerland 30.06 Austria 3.34

9 Portugal 0.216 Ireland 29.91 Greece 3.33

10 Finland 0.201 France 28.25 Netherlands 2.90

11 France 0.192 Belgium 26.99 France 2.88

12 Austria 0.188 Greece 25.72 Denmark 2.71

13 USA 0.185 Spain 25.43 Switzerland 2.68

14 Spain 0.181 Germany 25.36 Finland 2.55

15 Switzerland 0.177 Sweden 23.49 Belgium 2.34

16 Denmark 0.172 Finland 23.45 Sweden 2.30

17 Sweden 0.156 Portugal 23.11 Italy 2.26

18 Netherlands 0.155 Norway 22.63 Norway 2.25

Note: the pairwise correlation of COV (Coefficient of Variations of regional GDP per capita) and Gini is -0.04 (p-

value = 0.88). The pairwise correlation of COV and P90/10 is 0.023 (p-value = 0.93). 1 for COV means shares of

national income by only one region. 100% for Gini means shares of national income by only one person. P90/10 is

the ratio of the 10% of people with the highest income to the 10% of people with the lowest income. For example,

USA shows 4.9 in P90/10 ratio; this means that the poorest individual of the richest group earns 4.9 times more per

every single dollar than the richest individual of the poorest group.

91

Figure 7. The Correlation of Inter-personal Inequality and Inter-regional Inequality

Average value from 2006 to 2010

Data source: Table 7

10% of people with the highest income to that of the bottom 10%) captures inequality between

the poorer individuals and the richer individuals. The comparative statistics regarding a country’s

ranking find that in a majority of cases, the level of inter-regional inequality does not overlap

with the level of inter-personal inequality. Their correlation is considerably low and statistically

insignificant on a pairwise correlation, COV and Gini show -0.038 with a p-value of 0.88. On the

other hand, COV and P90/10 show 0.023 with a p-value of 0.93.

92

Substantively, Belgium ranks in the middle of inter-personal inequality based on Gini

index and the bottom of inter-personal inequality based on P90/10. However, the level of inter-

regional inequality in Belgium is the highest based on COV.55 The United States is an opposite

case. Its inter-personal inequality level for both Gini and P90/10 is very high in the country

ranking.56 However, the inter-regional inequality in the United States shows a relatively equal

regional income distribution, compared with other the two-thirds of the sample from OECD

countries in the same period.

Figure 7 (above) shows the statistical relationship between inter-regional inequality and

inter-personal inequality. Again, there is no clear evidence that inter-personal inequality is

linearly correlated with inter-regional inequality. A linear prediction line for the bivariate

relationship between inter-regional inequality and inter-personal inequality finds a statistically

insignificant slope.

Measures of Federalism

I measure federalism as a political decentralization for several reasons. Most importantly,

federalism captures the political dynamics, local input in policy-making, that I argue produce

divergence across regions. Thus, measures of political decentralization would be like my

55 Lessmann (2011) reports the same concern for Belgium.

56 This is partly explained by the Congressional Budget Office’s report on income trends from 1979 to 2007. Income

grew by 18 percent of share of income for the bottom 20 percent of households, but 275 percent for the top 1 percent

of households. See http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/10-25-HouseholdIncome.pdf

93

Table 9. Measures of Federalism

Country

Electoral Federalism (1980-2009)

Are state/province governments locally elected? (Beck et al. 2010,

Database of Political Institutions)

0 = No local election

1 = Legislature locally elected

2 = Legislature and executive locally elected

Mean St. Dev Min Max

Austria 2 0 2 2

Belgium 1.53 0.51 1 2

Canada 2 0 2 2

Denmark 2 0 2 2

Finland 0.30 0.46 0 1

France 1 0 1 1

Germany 2 0 2 2

Greece 0.87 0.35 0 1

Ireland 2 0 2 2

Italy 2 0 2 2

Netherlands 1 0 1 1

Norway 1 0 1 1

Portugal 0.15 0.53 0 2

Spain 2 0 2 2

Sweden 1 0 1 1

Switzerland 2 0 2 2

UK 2 0 2 2

USA 2 0 2 2

conceptualization of federalism. I focus on electoral federalism57 because I am interested in

capturing the level of the closeness between local politicians and their local constituencies. This

57 I use fiscal federalism as an alternative measure. Fiscal autonomy is important to the functioning of federalism.

Without money and the ability to spend it, federalism may have little policy effect. I take a veto player approach by

using a discrete index of approximate strength of regional governments’ power over the distribution of tax revenue.

The data and codebook are accessible at http://www.unc.edu/~hooghe/data_ra.php. This measure captures whether

local governments can dictate spending, negotiate spending, or even cast a veto against it. The political reality could

be more complex than mere description (Sorens, 2011). The interactive relationship between fiscal federalism and

electoral federalism also matters, because the state governors appointed by the central government cannot go free of

94

measure is classified in the strength of federalism based on the degree of local autonomy in

electoral and fiscal matters. Electoral federalism measures subnational control over the election

of local legislative and executive office. This measure is coded 0 if unitary (no local election), 1

if the legislature is locally elected, but the executive is appointed and; 2 if both the legislature

and the executive are locally elected – see Table 9 (above) for these identifiers for the sample

countries. I am not aware, at least in my OECD country sample, of cases where the legislature is

appointed while the executive is elected at the provincial or state government level. This

trichotomous measure is collected from the Database of Political Institutions.58

Controls

We need to capture the effects of open markets on human capital investment measured by

the size of public education spending at the aggregated level. To operataionlize this, the analysis

controls for both trade openness (TRADE) and capital mobility (KAOPEN). These two

globalization measures are expected to be positively correlated with the supply of skilled labor

through human capital investment (Ansell, 2008a/b). The size of total government expenditure

(GOVTEXP) can also be positively correlated with the size of public education spending. An

the central government’s redistributive policy decision, even if the local state government may hold strong fiscal

autonomy. However, this is not an issue to my data, where electorally federal countries also tend to be fiscally

federal. The fiscal federalism measure ranges from 0 to 2, where 0 is a unitary system, 1 denotes weak fiscal

federalism, and 2 indicates strong fiscal federalism.

58 I use a measure for federalism (a type of political decentralization) rather than decentralization more broadly

because the definition of decentralization lies in conceptual muddles. It shows a mixture of fiscal, administrative,

and political decentralization. See the conceptual debates in Schneider (2003) who suggests a factor analysis to

capture those three core dimensions.

95

increase in government expenditure raises the products of private capital and increase the rate of

growth (Strauss, 2001). This growth role of government expenditure will increase human capital

investment to maintain the productivity efficiency (Barro, 1990).

On the other hand, controlling for a country’s level of economic development can be

important to relating market potentials to the size of public education spending. To scale market

potentials, the model accounts for the effect of Logged GDP per capita (GPPPC(LOG)) and GDP

per capita growth (GPPC(GROWTH)). These two economic variables are used to capture the

effect of Wagner’s law. Wagner’s law posits that increasing economic development will lead to

an increased preference for public good redistribution due to social, administrative, and welfare

issues which increase in needs and complexity (see Wagner, 1883; Castles, 1989; Busemeyer,

2007). For measuring the leftist parties’ participation in government, I use the leftist party’s

seats as a share of total legislative seats (LEFT) to capture the constituency effect directly. The

government participation by leftist parties is positively correlated with public education

spending, since their core constituencies, unskilled and poor individual voters, support broader

access to public education (Ansell, 2008a/b; Busemeyer, 2009). Lastly, to isolate demographic

pressures on the expansion of public education spending, the size of the population under age 14

(POP14) is included. The young population has a positive impact on public education spending

due to their potential demands (Busemeyer 2007). Data sources and detail descriptions are

available in Appendix 8.

Models, Methods, & Empirical Findings

Model 1 (without an Interaction Variable):

96

Public Education Spendingit = β1 Inter-personal Inequalityit + β2 Inter-regional Inequalityit

+ β3 federalism it + ∑ βjControlsit + ∑ 𝛽𝑘 Country ki + Ԑ it

𝛽𝑠 are parameter estimates. The subscript i and t are the country and year of the observations

respectively. The j and k (18) denotes, respectively, the control variable and country dummies.

The constant term is suppressed to identify the equation.

The data covers a pooled time series from 1980 to 2010. Given the data’s cross-sectional

structures (TSCS), I examine the effects of inequality on education spending across countries

over time. Despite its inferential advantages like so, the TSCS design tends to violate the

assumptions of linear regression models, such as non-constant error variance, contemporaneous

cross-sectional correlation, panel-corrected standard errors (Beck & Katz, 1995).59 My

estimation relies on panel error adjusted with AR(1) to remove serial autocorrelation.60 While

other studies of education spending use a lagged dependent variable (Busemeyer, 2007, 2009),

other authors such as Achen (2000) and Plümper et al. (2005) assess a lagged dependent variable

biases significantly downward other independent variables in the model. Their alternative

suggestion is a use of AR(1) process. Country dummies are included in the model to control

unmeasured country-specific effects such as social spending related political culture.

59 The conventional feasible generalized least squares-based algorithm (FGSL) is not appropriate to the unbalanced

panel data that we have. In our dataset, the cross-national dimensions (N=18) are smaller than the time dimension

(T=30). This condition (T>N) meets a requirement for the finite sample properties of PCSE estimators to produce

the large time asymptotic based standard errors.

60 Robustness testing for the model with the lagged dependent variable did not change main findings. However,

Kittel and Winter (2005) argue that when a lagged dependent variable is correlated with country dummies, its

combination with country fixed effects can increase statistic bias.

97

Table 10. Impacts of Inequality on the Size of Public Education Spending

Variables Estimates

(PCSE adjusted)

COV (Inter-regional Inequality)

-0.171***

(0.070)

P9010 (Inter-personal Inequality)

0.314***

(0.128)

Trade openness (trade % of GDP)

0.009**

(0.004)

Capital Openness (Chin-Ito Index) 0.446***

(0.062)

Government expenditure (as % of GDP) 0.320***

(0.029)

Left party legislative seats (as % total) 0.007**

(0.003)

GDP per capita (Logged) 1.709***

(0.465)

GDP per capita growth (annual %) 0.022

(0.013)

Population ages 0-14 (% of population) 0.352***

(0.053)

Electoral federalism 0 = No local election,

1 = the legislative locally elected but the executive appointed,

2 = both the legislative and the executive locally elected

-0.271

(0.275)

Number of observations 245

Countries 18

Country Fixed Effect Yes

R square 0.994

Note: Two-tailed tests for significant at *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Errors are

corrected for panel specific AR1. The constant is suppressed.

98

Table 10 (above) presents findings of the positive relationship between inter-personal

inequality (P9010) and public education spending. See Appendix 9 for robustness tests. Inter-

regional inequality (COV) is negatively associated with public education spending. When

inter-personal inequality increases by 1 unit on 1-10 scales (this is equivalent to 10 percent of 0-1

index), there will be a cut in overall public education spending by 0.17 % of GDP. On the other

hand, if P9010 increases by a ratio of 2 (the poorest person of the richest 10 percent of the

population in the income distribution earns 2 times as much as the richest person of the poorest

10 percent would earn), this will lead to an increase in overall public education spending by

0.6 % of GDP (0.314*2 = 0.628). Federalism as a control of a degree of political decentralization

does not show a strong and meaningfully significant effect on overall public education spending

as mixed results presented by previous empirical studies on the policy effects of federalism show

(Martinez-Vazquez & McNab, 2003; Prud’homme, 1995; Woller & Phillips, 1998).

The effects of control variables are mostly significant with positive signs. Two economic

openness measures (trade flows and a degree of capital mobility) have positive associations with

human capital investment. The effect size of trade openness is considerably small, but this is due

to a scaling matter, given trade openness ranges from 17% to 183% of GDP. On the other hand, a

unit increase in the index of capital openness (with a sample range from -1.86 to 2.46 (more

open)) shows 0.4% of GDP. The size of government expenditure is positively associated with

public education spending. The leftist partisan power in the national legislature has positive

impact, but the effect size is relatively small compared to other economic variables (I will look

into the measured in log of GDP per capita (thousand US dollars, 2000 constant) shows that a

$100 (1% of $1000) increase in GDP per capita will lead to an increase in overall public

education spending by 1.709/100 = 0.02% of GDP. GDP per capita growth does not have a

99

significant impact on overall public education spending (I will use GDP growth as an alternative

measure). The demographic pressures measured as population age under 14 show the positive

and significant effect by a factor of 0.3% of GDP.

Model 2 (with an Interaction Variable):

Public Education Spendingit = β1 Inter-personal Inequalityit + β2 Inter-regional Inequalityit

+ β3 federalism it + β4 Inter-personal Inequality X federalism it

+ ∑ βjControlsit + ∑ 𝛽𝑘 Country ki + Ԑ it

Note: A list of controls is identical with that of Model 1. Errors are adjusted for panel corrected standard errors.

Model 2 captures the effect of inter-personal inequality on public education spending,

conditional on federalism. I measure a compound effect between inter-personal inequality and

federalism on public education spending. I obtain a marginal effect of inter-personal inequality

conditional on a degree of federalism (testing against Ho = β1 + β4 Inter-personal Inequality

*federalism it = 0). The model estimate also says the independent effect of inter-personal

inequality (β1) while holding no effect of federalism (testing against Ho = β1 = 0).

Table 11 confirms that inter-personal inequality (P9010) interacts with electoral

federalism to further increase the level of overall public education spending than with a unitary

system of government (See also Appendix 10 for robustness tests). Inter-personal inequality is

negatively, but weakly, associated with public education spending (p-value <0.1). As disused in

the theory section of Chapter 2, the effect of inter-personal inequality under a unitary system

100

Table 11. Effects of Inter-personal Inequality & Federalism

on Public Education Spending61

Estimates

Variables (PCSE adjusted)

P9010 (Inter-personal Inequality) -1.009*

(0.609)

Electoral federalism -2.042**

(0.859)

P90/10 * Electoral federalism 0.745**

(0.330)

COV (Inter-regional Inequality) -0.183***

(0.070)

Trade openness (trade % of GDP) 0.008**

(0.004)

Capital Openness (Chin-Ito Index) 0.411***

(0.068)

Government expenditure (as % of GDP) 0.298***

(0.031)

Left party legislative seats (as % total) 0.005

(0.004)

GDP per capita (Logged) 1.847***

(0.428)

GDP per capita growth (annual %) 0.019

(0.016)

Population ages 0-14 (% of population) 0.362***

(0.052)

Number of observations 245

Countries 18

Country Fixed Effect Yes

R-squared 0.994

Note: Two-tailed tests for significant at *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Estimates are panel corrected

error adjusted with panel specific AR(1). Country fixed effects are controlled.

61 A model extension may incorporate the interaction term of federalism and COV into the estimated model.

However, this addition further complicates the role federalism, whether focusing on interpersonal inequality or inter-

regional inequality. This will be contingent upon issue salience and partisan power to the federal government.

101

Figure 8. Marginal Effect of Inter-personal Inequality (P90/10) on Public Education

Spending, Conditional on Electoral Federalism

Note: Values denote % of Public Education Spending

could be either positive or negative. However, when inter-personal inequality interacts with

federalism, there is a synergic effect of these two variables in a positive causal direction for the

size of public education spending. This synergy is anticipated in theory that federalism by nature

of its institutional design reduces a relative constraint of fiscal burdens imposed as economically

homogenous regions.

Figure 8 draws a marginal effect of inter-personal inequality on public education

spending as the strength of electoral federalism increases. As can be seen, if electoral federalism

102

allows for subnational regions to have the legislative locally elected, the marginal effect of inter-

personal inequality (by 1 unit), on average, will lead to an increase in public education spending

by 0.7% of GDP (-0.264 + 1.009 = 0.745). As the strength of federalism increases, the marginal

effect of inter-personal inequality on public education spending becomes statistically significant

inter-personal inequality, shows a significantly negative effect on the redistribution of public (see

vertical bars passing through the horizontal line of zero in Figure 8). To return to Table 11

(above), electoral federalism (in the absence of inter-personal inequality), which assumes no

effect of education spending. The effects of control variables reported from Table 10 remain

intact for their signs and statistical significance.

Model 3 (with an Interaction Variable)

†Public Education Spendingit = β1 Inter-personal Inequalityit + β2 Inter-regional Inequalityit

+ β3 federalism it + β4 Inter-regional Inequality X federalism it

+ ∑ βjControlsit + ∑ 𝛽𝑘 Country ki + Ԑ it

Notes: † Volatility is calculated by the standard deviation for non-overlapping three-year periods. A list of controls is

identical with that of Model 1. Errors are adjusted for panel corrected standard errors.

To test the effects of veto player constraints, I modified the dependent variable by taking the

standard deviation of non-overlapping three-year periods from 1980 to 2010 The standard

deviation serves to measure policy volatility, commonly used in the political economy literature

(Aisen & Veiga, 2005).62 Lower values mean less change (i.e., a higher likelihood of

62 I also used non-overlapping 5 year-periods for alternative standard deviation calculations and found the key

variable effects remain largely intact.

103

perpetuating policy gridlock) while higher values are more change (i.e., a lower likelihood of

policy gridlock). According to veto player constraints, we should expect to see lower values.

Model 3 uses the standard deviation of public education spending on the left-hand side. The

average values of three years for independent variables are used on the right-hand side of Model

3. One exception is made because a degree of federalism is discrete, so I took the maximum level

during three years and coded it as individual observation used in Model 3.

Based on results from Table 12, inter-regional inequality interacts with federalism to

dampen the volatility of public education spending – see Appendix 11 for robustness tests. Note

that the coefficient of the electoral federalism’s independent effect is positive (more changes)

when assuming regions are fairly identical in comparison. However, in conditional hypothesis

testing, inter-regional inequality (in the absence of federalism effects) has a positive effect on the

volatility of public education spending because inter-regional inequality could either increase or

decrease the level of public education spending. However, inter-regional inequality and

federalism produce a synergic effect of reducing the change in public education spending.

Figure 9 presents the marginal effect of inter-regional inequality (COV) on volatility in

the size of public education spending. As a degree of federalism increases, the marginal effect of

inter-personal inequality, on average, dampens significantly: a shift from a unitary system of

government with no local election to weak federalism with the legislative locally elected will

lead to 0.25 standard deviation less change from the three-year average of public education

spending (0.088 – 0.347 = - 0.25). When a country shifts from a unitary system of government

to adopt a system of full-blown federalism (regarding electoral federalism), the marginal effect

of inter-personal inequality, on average, will reduce changes by a 0.518 deviation from the three-

104

Table 12. Effects of Economic Inequality & Federalism

on Volatility of Public Education Spending†

Estimates

Variables (PCSE adjusted)

COV (Inter-regional Inequality) 0.347***

(0.068)

Electoral federalism 0.443**

(0.173)

COV * Electoral federalism -0.259***

(0.052)

P9010 (Inter-personal Inequality) 0.264***

(0.069)

Trade openness (trade % of GDP) -0.002

(0.002)

Capital Openness (Chin-Ito Index) -0.008

(0.029)

Government expenditure (as % of GDP) 0.036**

(0.016)

Left party legislative seats (as % total) 0.005**

(0.002)

GDP per capita (Logged) -0.220

(0.177)

GDP per capita growth (annual %) -0.025**

(0.012)

Population ages 0-14 (% of population) -0.048***

(0.018)

Number of observations 91

Countries 18

Country Fixed Effect Yes

R-squared 0.879

Note: Two-tailed tests for significant at *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Estimates are panel corrected error

adjusted based on lagged dependent variable models. Country fixed effects are controlled. †Volatility is the

standard deviation of government expenditure on public education over three years non-overlapping periods

between 1980 and 2010. †† Values are taken for the maximum score during three years; all other

independent variables take the average value of three years.

105

Figure 9. Marginal Effect of Inter-regional Inequality (COV) on Volatility of Public

Education Spending, Conditional on Electoral Federalism

Note; Values denote the standard deviation from average public education spending

year average of public education spending (-0.171-0347 = - 0.518). This conditional dampening

effect of inter-regional inequality under federalism is statistically significant.

In return to Table 12 (above), the sign of coefficients for each control variable can be

read regarding more change or less change. Inter-personal inequality (P9010) creates more

changes because the effect could be positive or negative on redistribution. The oversized

government expenditure is positively correlated with more volatility since it will create upward

106

pressures on public education spending. The effect of left party power creates upward pressure

for the size of public education spending because the core constituencies of the left prefer the

broad distribution of public education spending (Stasavage, 2005; Ansell, 2008a/b; Boix, 1995;

Buesmeyer, 2007). For GDP per capita growth, I suspect that economic growth is endogenously

related with the volatility of government spending. The growth literature points to negative

effects of government spending volatility on economic growth (Carmiganni et al., 2007, Fatas &

Mihov, 2003; Fuceri, 2007). Increases in the population under age 14 as a proportion of the total

is used as a proxy for demographic pressures for public education (particularly in primary

education). The effect of this variable shows less change because in OECD countries, the effect

of demographic pressures for public finance on education conflicts with the growing aging

population. See for Preston’s (1984) generational competition hypothesis; Richman and

Stagner’s (1986) extension to Preston. For example, Poterba’s (1996) panel data analysis of the

U.S. states over the 1960-1990 periods shows that an increase in the fraction of elderly residents

affects a significant reduction in per child educational spending.

Conclusion and Policy Implications

I began my inequality research by asking what the role of political geography is about the

redistribution of public education spending, focusing on the level and variability of spending

adjustment. This chapter provides evidence that the redistributive policy effect of inter-regional

inequality works differently from that of inter-personal inequality under federalism. My subset

arguments distinguish the fractionalization effects of federalism from the polarization effects of

federalism. I argue for inter-personal inequality as amplifying fractionalization effects of

federalism that exacerbate regions’ overuse of the common pool. The important prediction is

107

high levels of public education spending nationwide. Stemming from this directional

expectation, I argue that higher inter-regional inequality worsens policy conflicts between

regions bearing their unequal share of fiscal burdens to finance broad redistribution. Given this,

inter-regional inequality further amplifies the polarization effects of federalism. Applying this to

the policy effects of federalism for high inter-regional inequality, I expect that the magnitude of

changes in public education spending will be small. Using the panel data for 18 OECD countries

from 1980 to 2010, I find supporting evidence for these two conditional arguments (one for

levels and the other for the volatility).

These theoretical and empirical distinctions regarding inequality of both types (individual

focus versus regional focus), however, will entirely depend on the level of analysis as well as the

institutional structure in a country. The logical outcome of RMR (the greater the inequality, the

greater the government spending) will make sense only if examining redistributive politics

within one undifferentiated jurisdiction that has a majoritarian voting rule and a system of

progressive taxation. When there is more than one jurisdiction, the median voters’ policy

interests (suggested by RMR) will vary across multiple subnational jurisdictions. In this chapter,

I show federalism as a political structure that highlights the importance of the spatial measure of

inequality. I further acknowledge that the political geography of inequality is also important to

other institutional factors such as voting districts and district-oriented voting behavior (the

personal votes). Some institutional context will dampen the policy effects of inter-regional

inequality.

For instance, presidential systems based on a popular vote will encourage cross-regional

coalitions. In this case, nationally aggregated individual income distribution (inter-personal

inequality) will be a more politically relevant inequality measure. Another example of the utility

108

of inter-personal inequality measures can be found in the demographic context that a country is

divided into nearly homogenous regions. Wealth distribution, in this case, is similar in each

region, rendering a similar type of median voter within it.

Applying inter-regional inequality to this demographic context will be misleading in

predicting political behavior, but will also obfuscate the variance of the relevant factors of

inequality in that country. When in fact, the opposite case will be true; aggregated individual

income measures applied to where inter-regional inequality is high but inter-personal inequality

is low. Then this misapplication will lead to perplexing policy results.

When choosing more appropriate indicators of inequality, it is critical to match these

indicators with the relevant political / demographic conditions of a country. In political contexts,

we need to consider both jurisdictional representation and accountability. To address

demographic contexts, we need to look at the divergence between individual and regional

inequality.

One way to assess this divergence can be done in framing four dimensions of inequality

divergence: 1) high inter-personal & high inter-regional, 2) low inter-personal & low inter-

regional, 3) high inter-personal & low inter-regional, 4) low inter-personal & high inter-regional.

In a country that has a match on inequality of two types (as described in cases #1 and #2), the

distinctions between those two inequality indicators are of little importance and empirical

findings based on either measure will be relatively less affected by choice of inequality

measured. However, where countries have a mismatch on inequality of two types (case #3 – the

U.S.A, case #4 – Belgium, c.f. Table 8), the choice of inequality indicators will be integral.

Also, the weak association between these two inequality indicators suggests how much countries

deviate. Therefore, distinguishing the geographic measure of inequality from the aggregated

109

individual measure of inequality is theoretically, as well as empirically important to account for

policy effects.

This chapter attempts to understand policy effects subject to types of inequality under a

federal system of government. Based on the limited quality of data on inter-regional income

disparity (a cross-nationally comparable measure of the intra-country variance), this chapter is a

first step to unfold the complexity of public spending.

110

CHAPTER 5

Empirical Analysis of Policy Bargaining:

Testing the Conditional Theory of Regional Inequality and Decentralization

Previous studies show cross-national evidence that a decentralized country with uneven

regional economies tends to experience difficulties in centrally financing public goods broadly

redistributed across disparate regions. Many of these works share insights from Tsebelis’ (2002)

study of veto gates in institutional politics. This veto player research predicts a general policy

outcome: diversified regional preferences together with the power of regional authority to block

national policies are likely to create policy gridlock at the challenge of national policy

coordination.

I presented cross-national evidence that a federalist country with uneven regional

economies tends to experience greater difficulty in changing public education financing. The

higher likelihood of policy gridlock is anticipated as regional preferences become more divergent

and regional authority to block national policies further increases.

This empirical chapter, however, presents counter evidence that not all types of

redistributive spending are prone to policy gridlock. Even the redistributive spending that goes

disproportionally to poor regions can still benefit rich regions or at least minimize the latter’s

relative loss by targeting policy benefits to specific individuals within every territorial region.

Given this shared interest, poor areas which prefer centralizing more interregional (as well as

interpersonal) redistribution find it easier to achieve policy coordination with their affluent

counterparts.

111

Most importantly, this chapter highlights specific conditions under which redistributive

policy pressures from economic disparities among autonomous regions encourages a strategic

coalition between rich and poor areas to facilitate the centralized redistribution of public

spending. As an example of this condition, I point to targeted spending such as social

expenditure that directs the associated policy benefits primarily to qualified individuals rather

than to the society as a whole. Using a new annual dataset for policy priority measures

comparable across 22 OECD countries over the recent 20 years, I find supporting evidence.

Growing regional income disparity in highly decentralized countries tends to be accompanied by

growing centralized redistribution of public spending towards social policies while shifting away

from policies that can isolate policy benefits solely on a regional base.

The rest of this empirical chapter is organized as follows. First, I briefly review the

literature and theorize my institution-grounded contextual hypothesis to be tested. There, I pace

emphasis on the combined effect of variations in redistributive demands from disparate regions

and the regionalized administrative authority. The second section is dedicated to describing the

attributes of the data for regression analysis. There, I discuss data analytic strategies, followed by

explaining variables and measurement in detail. In the following section, I discuss the data

analytic results. I conclude this empirical chapter with a potential research extension and policy

implications.

Bargaining for a Centralized Provision of Public Policies

Copious studies on redistributive spending offer compelling models for how and when

redistributive pressures from the poor majority shape public policy choices. There is little

112

discussion, however, drawn from these models to help us understand redistributive spending as a

bargaining outcome between the poor majority and the rich minority.

Fortunately, a few exceptional studies are devoting their attentions to the comparative

analyses of redistributive spending elaborated from a regional perspective. For example, the

popular analysis of public spending (e.g., Meltzer-Richard model of public spending) primarily

focuses on a policy dictatorship of the poor majority where the rich are considered as politically

marginal.

Extending from this analytical tradition, Giuranno (2009a, 2009b) highlights a likelihood

of policy vetoes sought by the rich regions in a country with economically highly-disparate

regions. According to him, we should expect more policy vetoes of national legislation from the

rich regions if the central government looks to increase the tax-funded public spending that goes

disproportionately to the poor regions. Giuranno’s study offers an important insight: wealthy

individuals may be less powerful regarding democratic vote counts than their poor majority

counterparts. However, the rich regions can project their parochial interests through formal

powers allotted to territories in the making of national legislation. The rich regions are more

likely to exercise their policy vetoes when it becomes inefficient for their money to go to the

central government to be redistributed disproportionately to the poor regions. With the rise in

regional disparities, it is likely that the rich regions find the centralized format of redistributive

policies less efficient and contradictory to their strategic policy interest. Thus, policy

noncompliance will be affected by a rich region’s preference regarding the trade-offs between

equity enhancement due to broad redistribution (Tanzi, 2000) and the incentives to constrain

large redistribution due to the cost of efficiency losses (Aysen, 2005).

113

Overall, whether explicitly or implicitly, these present studies describe regional disparity

as a major obstacle to centralized policy bargaining by representatives of localities. To be

specific, regional economic disparities deepen the polarization in policy interests between the

rich and the poor jurisdictions. This divergence exacerbates interregional redistributive conflicts,

potentially leading to the under-provision of public goods and services across sub-national

regions.

This conflict model, however, understates that a policy bargain between disparate regions

can be easier under the decentralized system of regions when goods are directed to individuals

regardless of region. Consistent with works of Basley and Coate (2003) and Giuranno (2009b), I

argue for a condition under which autonomous regions with uneven regional economies achieve

policy coordination in the centralized provision of public spending. A good candidate of this

condition is a targeted spending specific to individual benefits (e.g., social security transfers and

health expenditure).

The key implication for the rich regions is that not all types of the centralized provision

of redistributive policy come at a high cost while policy goods are disproportionally redistributed

to poor regions. Implementing some policies is (relatively) less expensive than others when cost

sharing is unavoidable.63 By ensuring the allocation of public money to be directed to individual

beneficiaries who are a segment of their regional population, the rich regions reduce the

efficiency loss associated with the redistributive policy. Targeted spending becomes a significant

63 The main reasons these costs might be unavoidable are due to externalities and migration. If poor regions become

too disparate without resources to aid their impoverished citizens, the poor in the poor regions are likely to move to

the richer regions. Moreover, rich regions may have economic risks against which they would want to share the

burden of social insurance with poorer regions (Beramendi, 2012).

114

policy preference for the representatives of the rich regions as they seek to win an electoral

support from their local voters. Moreover, in the existence of logrolling institutions to facilitate

political exchange, the affluent regions will have a stronger incentive to coordinate this

centralized provision of targeted spending policy with the poor regions.

On the other hand, my argument for the poor regions implies that more targeted spending

is a desirable policy option because it creates positive spillover effects which contribute to the

general welfare of the poor majority within a local district. Since individual beneficiaries in poor

regions outnumber those in rich regions, a centralized policy provision of target spending agreed

by the rich regions should also be in the poor regions’ best interest. This regional interest

becomes stronger the poorer the regions are. It will create an easy bargaining situation. The

compromise between the interests of the rich and the poor regions is likely to engender a

reasonable policy change.64

In short, a high level of legislative conflict among economically disparate regions does

not necessarily escalate all types of tax-funded public spending programs into policy gridlock.

Instead, targeted spending programs may be more conducive to policy agreement than non-

targeted ones; that is, regions are likely to reach a pro-spending agreement on programs specific

to individuals. This policy outcome is probably with countries that have economically highly-

disparate regions and diffuse policy authority across their territorial regions to a greater extent.

Based on this argument, I predict a testable hypothesis for the growth of social spending

in a decentralized country with growing regional inequality. In data analytic section below, I

focus on the combined (interaction) effects of regional disparity and decentralization rather than

64 In this case, it would be an intersubjective understanding that the autonomous rich regions are likely to attempt to

block a radical policy change during negotiating the centralized provision of redistributive policy.

115

these two variables separately. I did this to capture a bargaining condition mutually recognized

by all participants regarding demands for redistributive goods (explained by the rise of regional

disparity) injunction with local capabilities to block policy enactment at the centralized

legislation (explored by the strength of regional authority).

Data and Methodology

To conduct my contextual hypothesis testing against social spending across countries

over a reasonably extended period, I use the cross-national time-series data. This set up allows

me to capture country-level differences in their policy commitment to targeted spending. The

term “policy commitment” is operationalized in two specific ways: 1) how much is spent on

targeted policy programs, 2) how spending itself is divided across competitive policy areas. The

first definition is related to changes in a GDP share. The second definition is directly concerned

with shifts in the government’s relative policy priority from non-targeted spending programs

(geographically isolated) to targeted spending programs (specific to qualified individuals across

regions).

Measuring a country’s policy priority is challenging especially for a cross-national

analysis, partly because it needs to capture the inherent trade-offs in spending choices by nations.

The scope of the associated data is also limited in their public access. The data scope for a policy

priority analysis requires complete information on government policy spending subcategories

that are cross-nationally comparable to each other. This data constraint sets my research scope

116

for 22 OECD nations over 20 years (1990-2010) due to the availability of data across all nine

common policy areas of redistribution.65

Statistical Model Specifications

To address the empirical relationship between economic inequality across autonomous

regions and targeted spending, I use a series of error correction models (ECMs). In each model,

the dependent variable is expressed as the first difference (∆ targeted spending). This change

expression is also applied to the independent variables (except dummies) along with the level

values of these variables. My motivation for an ECM setup lies in capturing transitory policy

adjustment effects primarily. When the independent variables change in the model, the

dependent variables will adjust. The ECM estimation technique can be useful to capture both

transitory adjustment effects and enduring effects of changes in the dependent variable and allow

us to identify these two effects separately. I focus on transitory adjustment effects (noted by the

delta) rather than enduring effects (indicated by the t-1) to capture how policy (or economy)

shock will deliver effects on government spending in the short run while any significant

transitory adjustment may not be identifiable over time. My ECM model, similar to Kwon and

Pontusson (201), setup takes the following baseline form:

∆𝑦𝑖𝑡 = 𝜃𝑦𝑖𝑡 + ∑ 𝛽𝑗𝑋𝑖𝑡−1 + ∑ 𝛾𝑗∆𝑋𝑖𝑡 + 𝜀it

65 For a longer period to establish a reasonable country estimate, I use social expenditure data as an alternative proxy

for targeted spending. The data covers years from 1980 to 2010 across 26 OECD countries.

117

where ∆𝑦it indicates a change from previous year’s targeted spending (i.e., social spending as a

share of GDP or a policy priority score) in country i. X is a list of the independent variables

including income inequality indicators and socio-economic controls. Ԑ is the disturbance term. γ

is an estimated effect of transitory adjustment in the dependent variable (∆𝑦it). The long run

effect caused by one unit increase in the independent variable 𝑋𝑖𝑡−1 can be estimated by dividing

-𝛽𝑗 by the error correction rate 𝜃 (i.e., the coefficient estimate of the lagged level dependent

variable 𝑦it). My estimates of ECM models are based on the fixed effect model estimation with

the robust standard error adjusted. Fixed effects can greatly reduce omitted variable bias such

unmodeled country-specific factors as political and institutional history. Since I use the panel

data structure, I control for the heteroskedastic errors in the model estimates.

Dependent Variables

A country’s policy commitment to targeted spending can be measured by changes in

social spending or changes in policy priorities on a relative policy focus ranging from

particularized benefits and collective goods (see for a sample summary in Appendix 13 from

1980 to 2010). Public spending is often called “social” when its policy objectives serve “the

provision by public and private institutions of benefits to, and financial contributions targeted at,

households and individuals in order to provide support during circumstances which adversely

affect their welfare” (Adema et al., 2011, p.89). This policy delivery varies across (and within)

countries over time.

Figure 10 (below) plots the volatility of social expenditures across 34 OECD countries

from 1980 to 2014. Each bar graph per country indicates the range between positive and

negative year-to-year changes in social expenditure over time. The graph shows that Slovenia

118

Figure 10. Volatility of Social Expenditure across 34 OECD Countries from 1980 to 2014

Mex

ico

Isra

elK

ore

a* N

ew Z

eala

nd

* A

ust

rali

a* H

ungar

y* S

wit

zerl

and

Chil

e*(€

) It

aly

* U

nit

ed S

tate

sT

urk

ey*(€

) A

ust

ria

*(€

) G

reec

e*(€

) N

ether

lands

OE

CD

- T

ota

l* J

apan

* U

nit

ed K

ingdom

* C

anad

a*(€

) B

elgiu

m* C

zech

Rep

ubli

c*(€

) P

ort

ugal

(€)

Lux

embourg

*(€

) G

erm

any

Icel

and

*(€

) S

lovak

Rep

ubli

c*(€

) F

rance

*' N

orw

ay*(€

) S

pai

n* D

enm

ark

* S

wed

en(€

) E

stonia

*(€

) Ir

elan

d*(€

) F

inla

nd

* P

ola

nd

* S

loven

ia

Yea

r-to

-yea

r C

han

ge

in S

oci

al E

xpen

dit

ure

(%

GD

P)

-5

0

5

10

15

20

Decrease

Increase

Notes: The data is obtained from the OECD Social Expenditure Database (SCOX). Social expenditure is the sum of

government spending covering main policy areas such as old age, survivors, incapacity-related benefits, health,

family, active labor market programs, unemployment, housing, and other social policies. *(€) denotes the Eurozone

sample data used in the analysis, determined by the data availability based on model specifications using 26

countries from 1980 to 2010. The model estimates omitting Slovenia are available in the results from a panel

jackknife test available in Appendix 20.

experienced the most drastic change in the profile of social spending. For instance, between 1995

and 1996 with the inception of the accommodation to the European Monetary Union, social

spending in Slovenia increased by a GDP share of 16.5%. This number is a stark contrast to the

119

Mexican experience. For Mexico, on the other hand, the average change in social spending

between 1985 and 2012 was only about 0.22% in GDP proportion. This variation suggests

different policy efforts sought by countries to move away from the status quo spending. Figure

10 also confers a country’s relative rigidity to change the policy design of social spending. As

shown in this bar chart, the size of a bar above the zero line (welfare expansion) is bigger than

that below the zero line (welfare retrenchment). This result suggests that at the centralized

legislation of local representatives, reductions in welfare policy are harder to negotiate than

welfare increases (Obinger et al., 2005).

I use a GDP share measure of social expenditure at the general government level. The

validity of spending measure at the general government level may be threatened by

heterogeneous policy interests created in the system of multi-tier governance. Nonetheless, the

general government level data captures overall flows of cross-regional redistribution explicitly.

These flows are often intractable from an analysis of redistributive spending solely by the central

government because fiscally autonomous regions have incentives to isolate their tax revenue

from the central government. The panel data are available from the OECD Social Expenditure

Database (SCOX).66

Not only is social spending significant as a single component of the policy process, but its

relationship with other policies is important as a relative component of the resource allocation

process. Typically, the research on inequality measures relevant government expenditure as

social spending – the summation of specific government spending categories thought to be

particularly redistributive, as a percentage of GDP (Lupe & Pontusson, 2011; Beramendi &

66 For a robustness check, I also used the Global Finance Statistics (GFS) data for the central government spending

on social polies, separated from the general government. The result is reported in Appendix 17.

120

Cusack 2009; Bradley et al. 2003a; Iversen & Soskice 2006a/b; Moene & Wallerstein 2001).

These categories normally include disability benefits, survivor pensions, health benefits, family

services & family income support, housing assistance, unemployment benefits, and job market

assistances.67 However, government spending is not only structured as social spending or

otherwise, but can be broadly conceptualized by the relative scope of its reach. Many policies

related to social protection, for example, are more targeted at specific segments of the

population, while other policies, such as public order and safety, by the nature of their services,

are more broadly consumed for the entire society.68

One of the innovations of my empirical research is to analyze a complete picture of

government spending by employing a model capturing relative weights across different policy

areas known as policy priority scores (Jacoby & Schneider, 2009). Policy priorities are defined

as the component of government decision-making in which public officials allocate scarce

67 For types of social spending broken down to explicit categories (in both cash and accrual accounts), see the

aggregated dataset available from OECD Social Expenditure Statistics.

68 Every public policy program is designed for both individualistic benefits and collective benefits for the society.

However, the government’s relative emphasis differs across these policy programs. Roughly speaking, there may be

a country spending large amount on a social policy program. However, this does not necessarily mean that the

government is strongly committed to social spending. It could be that this country has a large public sector.

However, across different public policy programs, this amount of social spending could be relatively smaller than

other areas. For instance, according to the most recent 5 year average GDP share of social expenditure in Greece and

Hungary between 2007 and 2011, the level of social expenditure for these two countries was higher than the OECD

average (23 % vs. 21%). However, when considered in percentage of the total government expenditure, these

countries’ policy commitment to social expenditure was lower than the OECD average (46% vs. 48%). As

illustrated in this example, we will need to consider both the allocation of spending and the level of spending

together if addressing the country’s commitment to social spending.

121

resources, in the form of expenditure, to different program areas. The focal point does not lie just

on the question of how much a country spends on a policy program per se, but also on the

question of how a country divides up its available pool of resources. To implement this

allocation idea, I depart from restricting my analysis to the social spending variable alone.

Instead, I employ the full range of government spending to reveal policy priorities. In doing so, I

can avoid an assumption that large spending on social policies implies a policy commitment to

that area. We cannot, for example, distinguish governments with high levels of spending on all

policy areas including social spending, from those specifically dedicating resources to social

spending.

Measuring policy priorities also helps us evaluate whether countries spend in more

“particularized” (individualistic) ways or more “collective” ways as non-targeted provisions for

everyone within a region (Baron & Ferejohn 1989; Huber & Stephen 2001; Jacoby & Schneider

2001; Kousser 2005; Volden & Wiseman, 2007). The particularized way could be viewed as

targeted provision for qualified individuals across regions while the collective way could be

thought as non-targeted provision for everyone within a region. For example, social expenditures

such as health care and social protection are often categorized as particularized or individualistic

benefits because they are allocated primarily to individuals or households based on need

assessment. On the other hand, examples of collective goods are capital expenditures on

infrastructure, defense, and security that are not easily targetable to individuals but are broadly

consumed by the entire society.69 In many cases, the diffusion of public policy benefits relevant

to this non-targeted provision can be geographically isolated.

69 As pointed out by Jacoby & Schneider (2009), differentiating collective goods from particularized

(individualistic) benefits based on their policy objectives is a merely descriptive purpose. In fact, all forms of

122

Measuring of policy outputs that overcome this assessment limitation can be

operationalized by implementing a technique of the “unfolding” analysis (Coombs, 1964; Poole,

1984; Jacoby & Schneider, 2009).70 What this unfolding technique does is, rather than isolating

spending categories, it uses all government spending to “construct a geometric model in which

yearly [country] spending on policies is represented as distances between points within a space”

(Jacoby & Schneider, 2009, p.1). In other words, the unfolding technique separates policy areas

that are least likely to occur together. As a concrete example from the U.S. results (Jacoby &

Schneider, 2009), states that spend a higher percentage of their resources on law enforcement are

likely to spend a low percentage on healthcare. At the very least, this spatial proximity model

provides a yearly score for each sample country, which accurately summarizes that country’s

expenditures across all major program areas and explicitly depicts the tradeoffs that countries

make in allocating resources across program areas. Therefore, it can be interpreted as an

empirical representation of the country’s spending priorities.

Note that these spending categories have not typically been examined in studies of

inequality, apart from their contribution to total expenditures. However, this omission can be

problematic when taking into account a policy trade-off (or relative policy position): for instance,

the country which spends more on particularized benefits invariably spend less on collective

goods and vice versa (Jacoby & Schneider, 2009). The isolation of social expenditure from other

policies share the features of both collective goods and particularized benefits to a certain extent. However, in this

chapter, I use the distinction between collective goods and particularized benefits as a way to identify comparable

subsets of policies revealed in the output of unfolding analysis (see Figure 2).

70 This technique is called “unfolding” because we seek to “unfold” a country’s profiles of spending values in order

to find the relative position of the country as well as its policy point simultaneously across all countries.

123

types of public spending may thus lead to an ad-hoc or inaccurate assessment of redistributive

policies in a particular nation. Thereby, they may result in precluding the examination of the true

effects of inequality on public expenditures.

Fortunately, measuring of policy outputs that overcome this assessment limitation can be

operationalized by implementing a technique of the “unfolding” analysis (Coombs, 1964; Poole,

1984, Jacoby & Schneider, 2009).71 What this unfolding technique does is that rather than

isolating spending categories, it uses all government spending to “construct a geometric model in

which yearly [country] spending on policies is represented as distances between points within a

space” (Jacoby & Schneider, 2009, p.1). In other words, the unfolding technique separates policy

areas that are least likely to occur together.

As a concrete example from the U.S. results (Jacoby & Schneider, 2009), states that

spend a higher percentage of their resources on law enforcement are likely to spend a low

percentage on healthcare. At the very least, this spatial proximity model provides a yearly score

for each sample country, which accurately summarizes that government expenditures across all

the main program areas and explicitly depicts the tradeoffs that countries make in allocating

resources across program areas. Therefore, it can be interpreted as an empirical representation of

the country’s spending priorities.

To provide a cleaner picture of government spending in the countries of interest, I

replicate this unfolding technique using spending data from 24 OECD countries between1990

and 2010.72 To reflect a full range of policy expenditures, I used all of the expense categories

71 This technique is called “unfolding” because we seek to “unfold” a country’s profiles of spending values in order

to find the relative position of the country as well as its policy point simultaneously across all countries.

72 Complete policy spending categories for post-1960s OECD members are not available until 1990.

124

specified by the international standard Classifications of Functions of Government (COFOG).

The COFOG data allows for an unfolding technique to cover the range of ten policy areas

simultaneously: 1) general public services; 2) defense, 3) public order & safety, 4) economic

affairs, 5) environment protection, 6) housing & community amenities, 7) health, 8) recreation,

culture, & religion, 9) education, and 10) social protection. I combined the fifth and the sixth

categories together since both categories take up a very small portion of country spending (less

than 2% of the total government spending), and they are highly correlated with each other

(p<0.05). In general, the data shows the relatively small fraction of total expenditure goes to the

environment protection policy. I also ensured that spending data on those ten policy areas were

collected at the central government level. This is because the central government is the locus of

government decision making for the efficient allocation of scarce resources. Policy priorities are

outputs of a bargaining among local representatives in the national legislature.

Figure 11 below displays two outcomes of the unfolding analysis. Policy priority scores

range from -0.5 to 1.5 for the policy point location and -0.02 to 0.05 for the country locations.

The policy point location shows a coordinate for nine policies. This coordinate indicates the

relative positions of the policy points fall roughly into two comparable subsets (particularistic

benefits vs. collective goods). The policies on the left side of the graph are policies that provide

more specific services to individuals as a segment of the population within a country.

The policies on the right-hand side of the graph place focus more on spending areas for

generic regulatory purposes or the benefits of the entire society. The country mean policy

coordinates, on the other hand, show the country’s relative policy emphasis given a year.

Negative values on country scores suggest relatively more spending on policies identified on the

left side of the policy plot in Figure 11. Positive country scores indicate relatively more

125

Figure 11. An OECD Spending Data Replication for Unfolding Analysis

Notes: The scale of the illustration differs across the two dot plots. Dots on the right panel are obtained from the unfolding analysis of 24 OECD countries over

recent two decades (1990-2010). Dots on the left panel are the mean points of spending policy priorities for each country. Horizontal bars show the minimum-

maximum range of point coordinates of policy priorities for each country during the period.

126

spending identified on the right side. I interpret these scores as follows: for example, the scale

score for Germany is 0.02 unit smaller than the score for Belgium. This number means that

Germany dedicated on average 2% more of its total spending towards particularized

(individualistic) benefits than Belgium did. Importantly, many of the spending categories that are

typically considered redistributive spending are what I identify as socially (individualistically)

targeted spending using this technique. My expectation that unequal countries will spend more

on social allocation is therefore in alignment with much of the literature on the political effects of

inequality that have not examined regional inequality specifically.

Independent Variables

My interest lies in detecting the joint role of diversity in regional demands and strength of

the regional authority to play in changing national spending policy. This combined factor nicely

captures the complexity in regions’ strategic calculation of self-interests subject to their mutual

recognition of each other’s credible ability to cast a policy veto. It aims at capturing disparate

regions’ incentives to achieve a cooperative policymaking. This intent can be constructed by an

interaction term that involves the degree of regional disparity and the strength of regional

authority. Constructing measures of regional disparity is shown explicitly in the data analytic

section in Chapter 4. For a robustness check, I resort to three alternative measures of regional

disparity: in brief, COV (the coefficient of variance in the distribution of regional GDP per

capita), COVW (Population weighted COV), and ADGINI (the relative poverty adjusted Gini

coefficient of regional income). As a reminder, these are the measures of cross-nationally

comparable intra-country variance, which will allow me to examine how regional inequality

affects redistributive spending across countries.

127

To operationalize strength in the authority of regional governments, I use the Regional

Authority Index (RAI) prepared by Hooghe et al. (2015). The RAI is an annually-based measure

across ten dimensions classified into two domains of authority: 1) “self-rule, or the authority a

regional government exerts within its territory” (i.e., institutional depth, policy scope, fiscal

autonomy, borrowing autonomy, and representation), 2) “shared-rule, or the authority a regional

government or its representatives exerts in the country as a whole” (i.e., lawmaking, executive

control, fiscal control, borrowing control, constitutional reform). Please see Appendix 12 for

additional information on each dimension. The RAI is a single, continuous measure ranging from

centralization (0) in which the central government monopolizes decision-making authority to

decentralization (36.99 given my country samples) in which the regional governments have

extensive decision-making authority.

The RAI is a simplification, compared with other authors who differentiate among

vertical versus horizontal decentralization, or types of decentralization in regards to decision-

making, electoral, fiscal, or personnel (Treisman, 2002), or between fiscal, political, and

administrative decentralization (Schneider, 2003). However, these alternative measures are

largely equivalent with the ten dimensions used for calibrating the RAI. The (internal) validity of

the RAI is, therefore, high. Also, because this fine-grained RAI takes a continuous measure, the

RAI can capture a greater variation. More specifically, it tends to avoid or alleviate disagreement

concerns in the treatment of federal versus non-federal countries (Schackel, 2008).

Given the policy outcome variable of interest expressed in change terms, I expect the rise

of changes in regional disparity (∆ COV, ∆ COVW, or ∆ ADGINI) and regional authority (∆

RAI) to have a joint effect. They will lead to more positive changes in social spending and more

negative changes in policy priorities (this means, targeting more on individualistic benefits).

128

Controls

To isolate the combined effects of regional disparity and regional authority on targeted

spending, I use a full battery of controls that are commonly used in modeling of government

spending. First, a country with growing interpersonal income inequality, measured by changes in

the estimated Gini coefficient of household market (pre-tax, pre-transfer) income, is expected to

show more positive changes in social spending (and imply more negative changes in policy

priorities). Second, growing government participation by the leftist parties should be correlated

with more positive changes in social spending as they pursue more generous welfare spending.73

The government of the left is measured in the proportion of social democratic and other parties in

government based on their share in parliament (see the Comparative Political Data Set by

Armingeon et al., 2005). Third, the larger the economic growth, measured by changes in

Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) converted GDP per capita, the more the cut down of social

spending to remain competitive in the global markets. However, even at a tight budget

constraint, the government’s priority of social services may remain strong because of the needs

for protective actions to make sure that the specialized economy functions smoothly (Wagner’s

law of increase state spending).74 Fourth, growing openness to trade, measured by changes in

73 Lower income groups are usually seen as favoring social spending while upper income groups and capital desire

to have a limited role of government in shaping free market economies (Hibbs, 1987; Wittman, 1983; Keech, 1995).

In competing for votes, parties orient their policy programs to represent these different interests of class-defined core

political constituencies (Hibbs, 1987). Incumbent parties continue to do this in order to get reelected (Schmidt,

1996). In such, parties operate as “transmission belts” for social-political demands.

74 According to Wagner’s hypothesis on the upward trend of public funding, known as Wagner’s law of increasing

state spending, public sectors will grow as per capita income rises in the development of industrial economies

because of increasing demands for social services (Wagner, 1958; Peters, 2002).

129

GDP share of exports plus imports, is expected to induce reduced social spending because

greater trade integration elevates tax competition that constrains government resources (Ferris,

2003; Borcherding et al., 2005).75 In this race to the bottom, governments will find it difficult

without a significant tax revenue increase to pursue targeted policy solutions such as public

spending through social protection. That can shape changes in policy priorities of public

spending more towards collective goods. Fifth, dependent populations, measured in this case as

those over the age of 65, rely disproportionately on government services overall and welfare

spending in particular. Based on this, I expect a positive relationship between growth in the aged

population ratio (percentage of population over 65) and change in social spending, whereas a

negative correlation between this aged population ratio growth and policy priority score changes.

Sixth, growth in the organized strength of labor, measured by changes in the relative size of

union members to the total labor force, is expected to create a positive change in social spending.

Similarly, an increasing rate of unemployment (percentage of the total labor force) will lead to

growth in social benefits that are directed to the unemployed (e.g., Garrett & Mitchell, 2001;

Kittel & Winner, 2005; Rodrik, 1996, 1997).

I also use two additional institutional controls that are almost time-invariant. Seventh,

election studies show that to win votes, transfer payments sought by incumbents increase before

elections. In that regard, I control for election year effects. The election year dummy is used (1=

75 However, some scholars posit an alternative “compensatory” hypothesis whereby governments will seek to

mitigate job market risks through spending on social protection with greater openness to trade (Cameron, 1978;

Rodrik, 1996, 1997; Garrett, 1998; Martinez-Mongay, 2002; Shelton, 2007; Gemmell et al., 2008). Other authors

find no significant relationship between trade openness and public expenditures in OECD countries (Iversen &

Cusack, 2000; Kittel & Winner, 2005; Dreher, 2006; Dreher et al., 2008).

130

election year, 0 = non-election year) accordingly. Finally, to get into the EMU (European

Economic and Monetary Union), countries are required to stabilize their financial programs.

Thus, EMU country-years (assigned a value of 1 since the year of accession) are anticipated to

show a reduction in social spending. Both Election year and EMU dummies are omitted from the

policy priority change model due to collinearity.

Empirical Results

ECM estimates of targeted spending models provide evidence of a policy adjustment

engendered by the relationship of rising economic disparities among autonomous regions with a

pro-spending orientation towards social policies. Determined by the country-year data on social

expenditure from 26 OECD countries (1980-2010), Table 13 predicts an expected policy

outcome: growing regional inequality joint with regional autonomy tends to induce more positive

changes in social spending. The spending size with changes in the relative deprivation adjusted

Gini and RAI (∆ ADGINI*∆ RAI) is almost twice as big as the other measures of regional

disparity (∆ COV*∆ RAI or ∆ COVW*∆ RAI). The interaction effects of ∆ COVW and ∆ RAI

become less significant as a full battery of controls was included in the estimated model. It could

be that more densely populated regions are benefitting most from targeted policy spending,

whereas regions with a smaller size of the population benefit less.

To further examine the joint effects of regional disparity and regional authority from a

dynamic perspective, I use a marginal effect graph. Following Brambor et al. (2006), I create

Figure 12 (a)-(c) above that illustrate the marginal effects of ∆ regional disparity on ∆ social

spending, conditional on the range of ∆ RAI. As an illustration, the y-axis shows a range of

averaged marginal effects expected by one standard deviation increase in ∆ COV (or ∆ COVW

131

Table 13. Determinants of ∆ Social Expenditure (% GDP) from 1980 to 2010

Regional Disparity (COV) Regional Disparity (COVW) Regional Disparity (ADGINI)

[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8] [9]

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Robustness

+ Robust

Std.Error

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Robustness

+ Robust

Std.Error

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Robustness

+ Robust

Std.Error

Social Expenditure (t-1) -0.0715*** -0.1136*** -0.1131*** -0.0772*** -0.1104*** -0.1098*** -0.0732*** -0.1149*** -0.1143***

(0.0240) (0.0152) (0.0155) (0.0240) (0.0156) (0.0158) (0.0244) (0.0152) (0.0155)

Regional Disparity and Decentralization

Regional Disparity (t-1) -0.0010 0.0201 0.0207 -0.0201 0.0142 0.0146 -0.0079 0.0398 0.0411

(0.0245) (0.0155) (0.0156) (0.0256) (0.0171) (0.0172) (0.0504) (0.0421) (0.0419)

∆ Regional Disparity 0.0096 -0.0095 -0.0082 -0.0154 -0.0184 -0.0184 0.0166 -0.0274 -0.0257 (0.0199) (0.0089) (0.0086) (0.0331) (0.0188) (0.0183) (0.0539) (0.0288) (0.0281)

RAI: Decentralization (t-1) -0.0230 0.0182 0.0200 -0.0562* 0.0105 0.0115 -0.0421 0.0037 0.0054

(0.0333) (0.0220) (0.0222) (0.0305) (0.0249) (0.0255) (0.0274) (0.0256) (0.0256) ∆ RAI: Decentralization -0.0438* -0.0343* -0.0315 -0.0457** -0.0341* -0.0312 -0.0406 -0.0328 -0.0303

(0.0222) (0.0179) (0.0186) (0.0203) (0.0200) (0.0206) (0.0240) (0.0207) (0.0212)

Regional Disparity × RAI (t-1) 0.0007 -0.0010 -0.0010 0.0023** -0.0007 -0.0007 0.0032 -0.0012 -0.0012 (0.0012) (0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0010) (0.0009) (0.0009) (0.0021) (0.0020) (0.0020)

∆ Regional Disparity × ∆ RAI 0.0362** 0.0298*** 0.0293** 0.0417*** 0.0233† 0.0228† 0.0714*** 0.0647** 0.0660**

(0.0157) (0.0102) (0.0108) (0.0134) (0.0152) (0.0152) (0.0242) (0.0297) (0.0302)

Controls

Interpersonal Inequality – Gini (t-1) -0.0057 -0.0043 -0.0049 -0.0036 -0.0057 -0.0044

(0.0156) (0.0152) (0.0147) (0.0144) (0.0156) (0.0153) ∆ Interpersonal Inequality – Gini 0.0126 0.0147 0.0132 0.0155 0.0158 0.0181

(0.0211) (0.0211) (0.0210) (0.0210) (0.0212) (0.0213)

Leftist Government (t-1) 0.0013* 0.0013* 0.0013* 0.0013* 0.0014** 0.0014** (0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0006) (0.0006)

∆ Leftist Government -0.0021 -0.0020 -0.0021 -0.0020 -0.0020 -0.0019

(0.0019) (0.0020) (0.0020) (0.0020) (0.0019) (0.0019) Real GDP per capita, PPP (t-1) -0.0017 -0.0019 -0.0016 -0.0017 -0.0014 -0.0016

(0.0015) (0.0015) (0.0015) (0.0015) (0.0016) (0.0016)

∆ Real GDP per capita, PPP -0.0699*** -0.0705*** -0.0697*** -0.0703*** -0.0695*** -0.0701***

(0.0044) (0.0044) (0.0045) (0.0044) (0.0045) (0.0045)

Continued

132

Table 13 (Continued).

Regional Disparity (COV) Regional Disparity (COVW) Regional Disparity (ADGINI)

[1] [2] [3]

[4] [5] [6]

[7] [8] [9]

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Robustness

+ Robust

Std.Error

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Robustness

+ Robust

Std.Error

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Robustness

+ Robust

Std.Error

Controls

Trade Openness (t-1) -0.0089* -0.0088* -0.0085* -0.0084* -0.0091* -0.0090*

(0.0044) (0.0044) (0.0045) (0.0044) (0.0045) (0.0044) ∆ Trade Openness -0.0287*** -0.0286*** -0.0284*** -0.0282*** -0.0287*** -0.0286***

(0.0055) (0.0054) (0.0056) (0.0055) (0.0055) (0.0054)

Old Age Population (t-1) 0.1561*** 0.1459*** 0.1492*** 0.1407*** 0.1649*** 0.1564*** (0.0442) (0.0460) (0.0418) (0.0447) (0.0444) (0.0470)

∆ Old Age Population -0.1905 -0.1920 -0.1826 -0.1841 -0.2370 -0.2390 (0.3036) (0.3090) (0.3199) (0.3236) (0.2854) (0.2892)

Labor Union Power (t-1) -0.0229** -0.0226** -0.0220** -0.0216** -0.0216** -0.0212**

(0.0092) (0.0091) (0.0090) (0.0089) (0.0089) (0.0088)

∆ Labor Union Power 0.0034 0.0032 0.0047 0.0047 0.0061 0.0060

(0.0304) (0.0302) (0.0311) (0.0310) (0.0309) (0.0307)

Unemployment Rate (t-1) -0.0211 -0.0210 -0.0213 -0.0214 -0.0186 -0.0187

(0.0174) (0.0176) (0.0178) (0.0179) (0.0171) (0.0172)

∆ Unemployment Rate 0.1152*** 0.1136*** 0.1144*** 0.1128*** 0.1134*** 0.1117***

(0.0321) (0.0324) (0.0321) (0.0323) (0.0322) (0.0326)

EMU (t) 0.0510 0.0408 0.0404

(0.0820) (0.0832) (0.0839)

Election Year (t) 0.0730* 0.0762** 0.0774**

(0.0361) (0.0365) (0.0353)

Constant 1.9281*** 2.7528*** 2.7865*** 2.4522*** 2.7889*** 2.7999*** 1.9803*** 2.6119*** 2.6122*** (0.5062) (0.6749) (0.7158) (0.5994) (0.6711) (0.7196) (0.4745) (0.7354) (0.7713)

Number of observations 635 590 590 635 590 590 635 590 590 Countries 26 26 26 26 26 26 26 26 26

Fixed Effects (by Country) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

R-squared (within) 0.042 0.626 0.627 0.049 0.624 0.626 0.047 0.625 0.627 Prob>Wald Chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: The dependent variable is changes of social expenditure measured as a share of GDP across 26 countries from 1980 to 2010. All model estimates are evaluated with their statistical significance

against the two-side significant at p<0.01***, p<0.05**, p<0.1*, p<0.15†. Entries are GLS fixed effect model estimators with robust standard errors adjusted (xtreg, fe vce (robust)). COV= coefficient of variation, COVW = Population weighted coefficient of variation, ADGINI = Regional Adjusted Gini Coefficient. EMU = the European Monetary Union. Please see Appendix 12 for the detail data

description of each variable. Constrained by the unbalanced panel data structure, the regression analysis uses approximately 78 to 72 percent of the total observations (T: 31 years × N: 26 countries).

133

Figure 12. Marginal (Short-Run) Effects of Interaction Terms on ∆ Social Expenditure (% GDP)

(a) Marginal Effects of ∆COV Interacting

with ∆RAI

(b) Marginal Effects of ∆COVW Interacting

with ∆RAI

(c) Marginal Effects of ∆ADGINI

Interacting with ∆RAI

(d) Marginal Effects of ∆RAI Interacting

with ∆COV

(e) Marginal Effects of ∆RAI Interacting

with ∆COVW

(f) Marginal Effects of ∆RAI Interacting

with ∆ADGINI

Used 90% confidence intervals. The coefficient

estimate on the interaction term is 0.029 (robust

standard errors = 0.010, t-statistics =2.91).

Used 90% confidence intervals. The coefficient

estimate on the interaction term is 0.023 (robust

standard errors = 0.015, t-statistics =1.53)

Used 90% confidence intervals. The coefficient

estimate on the interaction term is 0.064 (robust

standard errors = 0.029, t-statistics =2.18)

Notes: The slope lines connect the estimates of averaged marginal effects generated by the interaction terms tested in full models from Table 13. The vertical axis on the right

indicates the percentage distribution of conditional values included in the sample estimation. All bars of histograms are set by the width of 0.25. All marginal effects (values on the

vertical axis) are calculated with an assumption that leads to increasing by one standard deviation to incorporate variations across measures. ∆RAI=0.984, ∆COV=1.779,

∆COVW=1.335, ∆ADGINI=0.680.

134

or ∆ ADGINI) as ∆ RAI moves from low to high. I find that the marginal effects of ∆COV (or

∆COVW) are statically significant (but not much so in regards to the marginal effect of

∆ADGINI). The marginal effects of ∆COV (or ∆COVW) show a shift in year change in social

spending value from -0.3% of GDP (with a change in a more centralized system: Denmark 2006-

2007) to 0.5% of GDP (with a change for a more decentralized system: France 1981-1982).

It is worth noting that there is no a priory understanding in my theoretical approach to

discerning the marginal effects of regional disparity given regional authority from the marginal

effects of vice versa. According to Berry et al. (2012), it is also valuable information to make

additional predictions about the marginal effect of regional authority conditional on regional

disparity since there is an implicit assumption that I establish interaction effects as symmetric.

The intent for Figure 12 (d)-(e) above follows this recommendation. I find that the marginal

effects of ∆ RAI on ∆ social spending are statistically significant and positive as ∆COV (or ∆

ADGINI) moves from low to high. The magnitude of the marginal effects remains robust,

though.

Overall, Figure 12 above shows insufficient evidence that the interaction effects of

regional disparity and authority on social spending are symmetric. This finding raises an

important concern about the conditional hypotheses being tested.76 To ensure symmetry of this

interaction effect, I additionally checked for social spending’s relative reach in competition with

other policy programs. Using the data on policy priority scores for 22 OECD countries from

76 As pointe out by Berry et al. (2006), if each element of the interaction terms works fundamentally different

theoretical roles by designing one of these variables as the conditioning variable while the other as not, the joint

effect test would make little sense. In this case, rather than describing the effects of these two elements as

interactive, one should depict them as merely additive.

135

Table 14. Determinants of ∆ Policy Priority from 1990 to 2010

Regional Disparity (COV) Regional Disparity (COVW) Regional Disparity (ADGINI)

[10] [11] [12] [13] [14] [15]

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Policy Priority (t-1) -0.2462*** -0.4384*** -0.2519*** -0.4305*** -0.2440*** -0.4388***

(0.0667) (0.1000) (0.0657) (0.0944) (0.0690) (0.1019) Regional Disparity and Decentralization

Regional Disparity (t-1) -0.0025 0.0251 -0.0093 0.0340 0.0077 0.0644

(0.0211) (0.0239) (0.0244) (0.0283) (0.0441) (0.0490) ∆ Regional Disparity 0.0040 0.0090 0.0229 0.0270 -0.0119 -0.0051

(0.0202) (0.0170) (0.0220) (0.0182) (0.0361) (0.0288)

RAI: Decentralization (t-1) 0.0048 0.0575 0.0019 0.0652 0.0077 0.0515* (0.0298) (0.0365) (0.0356) (0.0406) (0.0264) (0.0277)

∆ RAI: Decentralization 0.0415* 0.0299* 0.0457* 0.0376* 0.0482* 0.0434**

(0.0224) (0.0157) (0.0249) (0.0184) (0.0238) (0.0166)

Regional Disparity × RAI (t-1) -0.0002 -0.0016 -0.0000 -0.0019 -0.0010 -0.0032

(0.0008) (0.0011) (0.0011) (0.0014) (0.0017) (0.0021)

∆ Regional Disparity × ∆ RAI -0.0280** -0.0382** -0.0413** -0.0506** -0.0863*** -0.1214***

(0.0109) (0.0154) (0.0152) (0.0183) (0.0238) (0.0247)

Controls

Interpersonal Inequality – Gini (t-1) 0.0209 0.0205 0.0212

(0.0137) (0.0141) (0.0139)

∆ Interpersonal Inequality – Gini 0.0199 0.0228 0.0212

(0.0197) (0.0197) (0.0203)

Leftist Government (t-1) 0.0003 0.0002 0.0003

(0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0006)

∆ Leftist Government 0.0003 0.0002 0.0003

(0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0007)

Real GDP per capita, PPP (t-1) -0.0050*** -0.0050*** -0.0047**

(0.0017) (0.0017) (0.0017)

∆ Real GDP per capita, PPP -0.0054 -0.0056 -0.0055

(0.0037) (0.0037) (0.0038)

Trade Openness (t-1) 0.0081 0.0081 0.0085

(0.0057) (0.0055) (0.0055)

∆ Trade Openness 0.0105 0.0111 0.0113

(0.0076) (0.0074) (0.0076)

Old Age Population (t-1) -0.1432** -0.1344** -0.1309**

(0.0598) (0.0590) (0.0576)

∆ Old Age Population 0.0871 0.0870 0.0558

(0.1922) (0.1970) (0.1781)

Labor Union Power (t-1) 0.0043 0.0073 0.0093

(0.0125) (0.0128) (0.0125)

∆ Labor Union Power -0.0087 -0.0069 -0.0062

(0.0354) (0.0350) (0.0357)

Unemployment Rate (t-1) -0.0111 -0.0138 -0.0099

(0.0110) (0.0100) (0.0105)

∆ Unemployment Rate 0.0022 0.0043 0.0039

(0.0288) (0.0317) (0.0312)

Constant -0.0800 0.7856 0.0509 0.3697 -0.1675 0.2517

(0.5675) (1.3601) (0.6345) (1.4361) (0.5027) (1.4022)

Number of observations 353 344 353 344 353 344

Countries 22 22 22 22 22 22 Fixed Effects (One Way) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

R-squared (Within) 0.154 0.278 0.162 0.279 0.156 0.283

Prob>Wald Chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: The dependent variable is changes of policy priority (rescaled to percentage points). The complete list of spending policy sub-categories (see the data description for Appendix 12) is not available before 1990 in most sample countries. Entries are GLS fixed effect model estimators

with robust standard errors adjusted. The coefficient estimates are expressed at the statistically significant level at *p<0.1, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01,

two-tailed test.

136

Figure 13. Marginal (Short-Run) Effects of Interaction Terms on ∆ Policy Priority

(a) Marginal effect of ∆COV

conditional on ∆RAI

(b) Marginal effect of ∆COVW

conditional on ∆RAI

(c) Marginal effect of ∆ADGINI

conditional on ∆RAI

(d) Marginal effect of ∆RAI conditional

on ∆COV

(e) Marginal effects of ∆RAI

conditional on ∆COVW

(f) Marginal effects of ∆RAI

conditional on ∆ADGINI

Used 90% confidence intervals. The coefficient

estimate on the interaction term is -0.038 (robust

standard errors = 0.015, t-statistics = -2.48).

Used 90% confidence intervals. The coefficient

estimate on the interaction term is -0.051 (robust

standard errors = 0.018, t-statistics = -2.76).

Used 90% confidence intervals. The coefficient

estimate on interaction term is -0.121 (robust

standard errors = 0.025, t-statistics = -4.91).

Notes: The slope lines are a series of point estimates simulated for averaged marginal effects based on the coefficient estimates of the interaction terms using full models from

Table 14. The vertical axis on the right indicates the percentage distribution of conditional values included in the sample estimation. All bars of histograms have width 0.25. The

marginal effects present the expected changes in policy priority due to increases by one standard deviation in ∆RAI (0.844), ∆COV(1.280), ∆COVW(1.062), ∆ADGINI(0.582).

137

1990 to 2010, I find more robust evidence that the interaction effects are indeed symmetric and

engender a policy good that is more directed to individual beneficiaries.

Table 14 provides supporting evidence that growing economic disparities among

autonomous regions are inversely associated with changes in the government’s policy priority

(given a linear assumption on more collective goods). Thinking regarding policy trade-offs

between collective goods and particularized (individualistic) benefits, one could interpret this

negative association as a shift in the government’s policy priority from collective goods to

particularized (individualistic) benefits. As shown in Table 14, the interaction terms of ∆ COV

(or ∆ COVW or ∆ ADGINI) and ∆ RAI show a negative sign on ∆ policy priority consistently.

The directional effect of the interaction variable is also statistically significant regardless of

employing alternative measures of regional disparity. A unit increase in ∆ ADGINI and ∆ RAI is

expected to create a relatively large incentive in prioritizing a policy towards particularized

(individualistic) benefits. For example, Table 14 (full models) shows variations in effect size: 3%

more of the total government spending by ∆ COV*∆ RAI, 5% by ∆ COVW*∆ RAI, and 12% by

∆ ADGINI*∆ RAI to be allocated for a policy good directed to individual benefits.

As a follow-up, Figure 13 also summarizes the marginal effects of interaction variables

on changes in policy priority scores. Not only does every marginal effect graph show a shift in

policy orientation from a positive value (collective goods) to a negative value (individualistic

benefits) on the y-axis, but these relationships are also statistically significant regardless of

applying alternative measures of regional inequality. More importantly, this statistical

significance remains robust when applied to a test for the symmetry of interaction effects (Berry

et al., 2006). In accounting for the conditioning variable based on its range from low to high,

whether I choose to estimate the marginal effect of regional disparity on policy priority or the

138

marginal effect of regional authority on policy priority, I demonstrate a consistent finding

regarding a general pattern in the interaction effects on policy priority. As an additional note, my

finding confirms with Table 14 that the marginal effect size of the interaction variable is bigger

when I employ the joint effect by ∆ ADGINI*∆ RAI. This result shows a policy focus shift from

0.4% more of the total government spending to be allocated for collective goods to 0.3 (or 0.4) %

more for individualistic benefits.

In general, the effects of control variables show expected directional signs as depicted in

Table 13 and Table 14. For the variables measured in change, I find economic growth (and

increase in openness to trade) is negative and significantly associated with changes in social

spending. Whereas, growth in the unemployment rate is positively and significantly correlated

with the growth of social expenditure. Regarding policy priority estimates, I find that the

variables capturing economic growth and old age population ratio are negatively correlated with

the government’s policy priority of collective goods. However, the statistical significance of this

relationship is shown primarily in the long-run effects although the short-run effects predict

anticipated policy directions.

Robustness Checks

I employ alternative measures of social expenditure. First, to capture social spending as a

proportion of the government budget, I use spending as a share of the total government

expenditure.77 My expectation for positive changes in social spending due to the interaction

77 Most studies use social spending as a share of GDP, thus, capturing the overall allocation of societal resources.

However, this measure is strongly affected by the size of government and arguably does not capture governments

allocate the resources directly under their controls. Social spending as a share of the total government spending can

139

variable remains intact (See Appendix 14). Second, I use a disaggregated measure of social

expenditure (e.g., social security transfers, health expenditure). As shown in Appendix 15, the

model estimates anticipate more positive changes in GDP share of social security transfers78 and

health expenditures attributed to growth in economic disparities among autonomous regions.

Third, I use the government expenditure on social protection, which is considered as the most

important government core function to redistribute income and wealth in the EU-28 countries.79

This social protection measure (e.g., aggregated on sickness and disability, old-age, survivors,

family, children, unemployment, housing, R & D, social exclusion, etc.) is available both at the

general government level and the central government level. I cross-check them for robustness in

the interaction effects of regional inequality and authority on social protection. Appendix 16

presents the supporting evidence. The data sources and summary statistics are all available in

Appendix 21.

To check robustness to alternative independent variables, I use disaggregated measures of

the Regional Authority Index: Self-rule vs. Shared-rule. The self-rule measure supposes to

capture a horizontal idea of the authority exercised by the regional government over the people

within its territory, while the shared-rule is a vertical concept of regional authority about the

central government. Appendix 17 confirms that (regardless of how it gets defined regarding the

self-rule versus the shared-rule) the interaction effects of regional disparity and RAI on policy

priorities are consistently negative and statistically significant. The magnitude of this interaction

provide a more direct measure of government preference and has the additional benefit of increasing the variance

across countries (Rudra & Haggar, 2005).

78 This measure is often criticized as it is overly sensitive to fluctuation in the business cycles (Ha 2008).

79 See <http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Government_expenditure_on_social_protection>

140

effect is larger in use of the shared-rule definition than the self-rule one, given the fact that the

national legislation of regional delegates is the locus of nationwide redistributive policymaking.

As an alternative modeling strategy to capture fixed effects in the residuals, I choose to

manually introduce country fixed effects to the model with a concern for the time-invariant or

slow-moving variable effects. In the analysis, I estimate ECM with fixed effects models and

panel-corrected standard errors (Beck & Katz, 1995). This ECM design includes country

dummies in the model to capture the country-level specificity. As shown in Appendix 18, the

interaction variable is positively correlated with social spending whereas negatively associated

with policy priority. I find a consistency that the interplay of ∆ ADGINI and ∆ RAI is

significantly correlated with the alternative measures of change in targeted spending (∆ social

spending or ∆ policy priority). Also, Appendix 19 reports a comparison between the long-run

(level) based estimates of the marginal effects (Beweley, 1979) and the short-run (change) based

estimates of the marginal effects. In the case of the policy priority variable, the general pattern of

a downward slope is common to both the long-run and the short-run based estimates.

To check whether my country-year samples suffer from a country selection bias, I

employ a Panel Jackknife analysis technique. This sensitivity analysis was carried out by

removing one country at a time from the overall sample and then estimating the model. I repeat

this analysis iteratively with the replacement. Appendix 20 presents a coefficient plot for

interaction effects. Except ∆ COVW * ∆ RAI, all other interaction variables (∆ COW * ∆ RAI or

∆ ADGINI * ∆ RAI) show robust findings to a significant test on their directional effects.

Conclusion and Policy Implications

141

The primary goal of this chapter was to contest whether a joint factor (the regions’

heterogeneous policy preferences and their mutual recognitions of each other’s capability to cast

a credible policy veto on national legislation) leads to cooperative policymaking on public

spending programs. This chapter focuses on policy areas in which benefits are directed to the

regional segments of the population. To conduct this empirical test, I use social expenditure data

from 26 OECD countries (1980-2010) and a policy priority measure incorporating government

spending’s relative reach across competing for policy programs in 22 OECD countries (1990-

2010). I find that the interplay of rising regional disparity and regional authority tend to bring

about growth in social spending and a greater tendency towards the government’s policy priority

of individualistic benefits. This finding is robust to alternative (or disaggregated) measures for

government spending types, governmental levels, estimation techniques, along with a check for

sampling bias.

The interaction variable effect is the most critical part of this chapter. However, two

components of the interaction need a further reflection. The degree of regional disparity can be

endogenously correlated with the degree of regional authority. Political or fiscal decentralization

can determine regional differences in economic performance whereas this economic geography

of inequality can affect the willingness of regions to overcome their fragmentation (Beramendi,

2012). However, this chapter uses the sample period (1980-2010) that shows a mix of increases

and decrease in the annual number of reforms for increasing regional authority although there is

an increase in regional reforms starting 1960s. See for Marks et al. (2008) especially the

summary table of trending regional authority reforms (p.170). Nonetheless, this nonlinearity in

the regional authority reform trend, finding an instrumental variable for the regional disparity is

an important task, which will be a useful research extension from this particular one.

142

This empirical research still sheds important light on linking the economic logic of

redistribution with the political logic of redistributive conflicts. Policymakers tie their hands to

their local constituencies for the return of political support from these locals. To this constraint, a

delegate democracy shapes politics into a public competition to make it best suitable for

parochial policy interests.

This myopic interests often create a policy dilemma to politicians at the national level.

With the rise of regional inequality, politicians are obliged to meet stronger demands from their

local constituencies. However, when they engage in a policy bargaining for the national

legislation, especially working under a decentralized system of governance, they may find it

difficult to amend existing policies.

This research offers a potential for finding a common policy ground at the national level.

The redistributive policy bargaining among regions with economically uneven stands but

politically equally powerful does not have to end in policy gridlock. Instead, a cooperative

policymaking is possible even during the escalation of policy conflicts. Possibilities for policy

coordination partly depends on a type of policy programs targeted by these politicians in their

strategic calculation of self-interests subject to the structure of their policy competition.

143

CHAPTER 6

Concluding Comments and the Contribution of Research to Policy Goals

This dissertation begins with the question of why high inter-personal income disparity

within a country does not lead to an increase in broadly redistributive public spending such as

public education. It answers this by introducing the geographic determinant of individual

redistributive motives, which are mostly neglected in the current studies of income inequality

and government redistributive policies. As discussed, studies on income inequality have mainly

focused on the inter-personal income disparity that measures the unequal distribution of the

nationally aggregated individual income such as Gini coefficients. While building on this

conventional approach, my approach assumes that inequality across regions differs from one

region to another. This assumption is rather plausible because individual income earners are

geographically dispersed. From this, I argue that policy preferences are related to this geographic

dispersion.

I theorize that regional wealth largely shapes individual redistributive interests, especially

where the regional disparity is high and regional policy autonomy is possible. Using the Korean

General Social Survey (2009) data, I find supporting evidence that regional interests trump (or

interact with) individual preferences for increased public education spending centrally

administrated. Rich citizens in the poor region are likely to favor increased public education

spending while poor citizens in rich regions are less likely to be in favor. This result is contrary

to a class-based interest that poor citizens (irrespective of their regional locations) prefer more

redistribution to less, whereas rich citizens (irrespective of their residential regions) show the

opposite.

144

This micro-level finding implies that a policy tension between net beneficiaries from poor

regions and net contributors from rich regions arises from conflicts over the centralized

coordination of broad redistribution. Redistributive policies preferred by economically disparate

regions are therefore difficult to coordinate at the national level because rich regions find it

inefficient to support an increase in broadly redistributive spending which goes disproportionally

to poor regions.

However, institutional systems also mediate these regional interests. I argue that an

institutionalized system of regional policy autonomy (e.g. federalism) empowers disparate

regions’ policy veto to block or delay less-preferred expenditures. From this conditional effect, I

draw two policy predictions: 1) exacerbating redistributive conflicts among regional interests on

the broad redistribution of collective public goods, leads to policy gridlock at the nation level, 2)

alternatively prioritizing targeted spending in which benefits are directed to specific individuals

across all jurisdictions, leads to a greater likelihood of policy compromise at the national level.

Empirical results are supportive of those two policy predictions. Using OECD public

spending data over the last 30 years, I confirm that inter-regional income disparity and regional

autonomy jointly constrain changes in public education spending. I also find that not all

redistributive conflicts necessarily create a policy hurdle perpetuating the status quo spending.

Rather, depending on how public budgets are allocated across competitive policy programs,

redistributive conflicts create a policy incentive which makes reaching a policy compromise

relatively easier. To confirm this statement, when testing against social welfare spending as well

as policy priority (to analyze relative position of all policies), I find that the joint effect of inter-

regional income disparity and regional autonomy creates more positive changes in targeted

spending for individualistic benefits across all regions.

145

On the theoretical side, this dissertation extends the question of “who gets what”

prevailing in the existing literature to the question of “who gets what at which price” (e.g.

Beramendi & Rehm, 2016). The latter is more concerned with combing interest between an

economic logic of redistribution and a political logic of redistributive conflicts. This research

does not devalue the importance of inter-personal income inequality as having a significant role

to play in shaping redistributive policies. However, it is suggested that inter-regional income

disparity conditional on an institutionalized system of regional autonomy should also be

considered when trying to resolve the puzzling variances left out of the studies on inter-personal

inequality.

On the empirical side, this study provides two useful measures: the measure of regional

inequality and the measure of policy priority. The regional disparity measure is a cross-nationally

comparable variable of intra-country inequality variance. It can be very useful for a variety of

institutional analyses in a cross-national context over time. It could serve as a conditional

variable or an outcome variable. For example, we could look at the effect of regional inequality

on the electoral performance of a national party organization where the fragmentation of regional

interests challenges to an intra-party coalition at the national legislature. On the other hand,

regional inequality could be viewed as a policy evaluation outcome by electoral designs such as

majoritarian rules compared with proportional representation rules.

This research also introduces a new measure of the government’s policy priority which is

cross-nationally comparable over time. The policy priority measure is especially useful for

capturing the correlated government spending categories (as shown in trade-offs among

competitive public policy programs). This empirical measure is considered more complicit in the

146

reflection of government spending categories as a whole, rather than selecting one area over

another without extensively taking into account their correlation.

My research separating inter-regional income disparity from inter-personal income

disparity is practically useful. In legislative elections at the national level, national parties should

take into consideration the electoral consequences of inter-regional income disparity which can

divide their national votes and thus weaken party strength at the national level. This conjecture is

primarily due to heterogeneous redistributive interests among the national representatives of

disparate regions. In that case, even though the national party desires to implement broad

redistributive policies to attract votes, inter-regional income disparity will become an obstacle to

winning the national election. Therefore, it is an important policy task for the national party to

strategically consider the inter-regional income disparity as a vital issue for their political

survival at the national level.

Our lives are geographically bound and so are our redistributive policy interests. An

approach to inter-regional income disparity is a useful way of thinking about our redistributive

motives and policy debates among our regional representatives in the national legislature.

147

REFERENCES

Achen, C. H. (2000). Why lagged dependent variables can suppress the explanatory power of

other independent variables. Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political

Science Association, Los Angeles, CA.

Adema, W., Fron, P., & Ladaique, M. (2011). Is the European welfare state really more

expensive?: Indicators on social spending, 1980-2012. A Manual to the OECD Social

Expenditure Database (SOCX) (No. 124). OECD Publishing. The dataset is accessible at

http://www.cpds-data.org/.

Alesina, A., & Perotti, R. (1996). Income distribution, political instability, and investment.

European Economic Review, 40(6), 1203-1228.

Alesina, A., & Rodrik, D. (1991). Distributive politics and economic growth (No. w3668).

National Bureau of Economic Research.

Ansell, B. W. (2008a). University challenges: Explaining institutional change in higher

education. World Politics, 60(02), 189-230.

Ansell, B. W. (2008b). Traders, teachers, and tyrants: democracy, globalization, and public

investment in education. International Organization, 62(02), 289-322.

Ansell, B. W. (2010). From the ballot to the blackboard: The redistributive political economy of

education. Cambridge University Press.

Armingeon, K, Isler, C., Knöpfel, L., Weisstanner, D & Engler, S. (2015). Comparative

Political Data Set 1960-2013. Bern: Institute of Political Science, University of Berne.

Aisen, A., & Veiga, F. J. (2005). Does political instability lead to higher inflation? A panel data

analysis (No. 2005-2049). International Monetary Fund.

Aysan, A. F. (2005a). The role of the efficiency of redistributive institutions on redistribution: an

148

empirical assessment. University Library of Munich, Germany.

Aysan, A. F (2005b). Inequality, the efficiency of redistributive institutions, and redistribution: is

government effectiveness the missing link between inequality and redistribution? Mimeo.

Barro, R. J. (1990). Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth, Journal of

Political Economy 98(5), 103–125.

Barro, R. J. (1997). Determinants of economic growth: a cross-country empirical study.

The MIT Press.

Barro, R. J., & Gordon, D. B. (1983). Rules, discretion, and reputation in a model of monetary

policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12(1), 101-121.

Barro, R., Sala-i-Martin, X., (2004). Economic growth. The MIT Press.

Barron, D., & Ferejohn, J. (1989). Bargaining in legislature. American Political Science Review,

83, 1181-1206.

Bassett, W. F., Burkett, J. P., & Putterman, L. (1999). Income distribution, government transfers,

and the problem of unequal influence. European Journal of Political Economy, 15(2),

207-228.

Beck, N., & Katz, J. N. (1995). What to do (and not to do) with time-series cross-section

data. American Political Science Review, 89(3), 634-647.

Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., & Walsh, P. (2010). New tools in comparative

political economy: The Database of Political Institutions. The World Bank Economic

Review, 15(1), 165-176.

Bednar, J. (2011). The political science of federalism. Annual Review of Law and Social

Science, 7, 269-288.

Bénabou, R. (2000). Unequal societies: income distribution and the social contract. American

149

Economic Review, 96-129.

Bénabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2006). Incentives and prosocial behavior. The American Economic

Review, 96(5), 1652-1678.

Beramendi. P. (2007). Inequality and the territorial fragmentation of solidarity. International

Organization, 61(4): 783-820.

Beramendi, P. (2012). The political geography of inequality: regions and redistribution.

Cambridge University Press.

Beramendi, P., & Cusack, T. R. (2009). Diverse disparities the politics and economics of wage,

market, and disposable income inequalities. Political Research Quarterly, 62(2), 257-

275.

Beramendi, P., & Rehm, P. (2016). Who gives, who gains? Progressivity and preference.

Comparative Political Studies, 49(4), 529-563.

Berg, A., & Ostry, J. (2011). Equality and efficiency. Finance & Development, 48(3), 12-15.

Berry, W. D., Golder, M., & Milton, D. (2012). Improving tests of theories positing interaction.

Journal of Politics, 74(03), 653-671.

Besley, T., & Coate, S. (2003). Centralized versus decentralized provision of local public goods:

a political economy approach. Journal of public economics, 87(12), 2611-2637.

Bewley, R. A. (1979). The direct estimation of the equilibrium response in a linear dynamic

model. Economics Letters, 3(4), 357-361.

Bird, R. M., & Tarasov, A. V. (2004). Closing the gap: fiscal imbalances and intergovernmental

transfers in developed federations. Environment and Planning C, 22(1), 77-102.

Boix, C. (1997). Political parties and the supply side of the economy: the provision of physical

150

and human capital in advanced economies, 1960-90. American Journal of Political

Science, 41(3), 814-845.

Boix, C. (1998). Political parties, growth, and equality: conservative and social democratic

economic strategies in the world economy. Cambridge University Press.

Boix, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge University Press.

Borcherding, T. E., Ferris, J. S., & Garzoni, A. (2005). Growth in the real size of government

since 1970. In Handbook of public finance (pp. 77-108). Springer US.

Bradley, D., Huber, E., Moller, S., Nielsen, F., & Stephens, J. D. (2003). Distribution and

redistribution in postindustrial democracies. World Politics, 55(02), 193-228.

Brambor, T., Clark, W. R., & Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: Improving

empirical analyses. Political Analysis, 14(1), 63-82.

Busemeyer, M. R. (2007). Determinants of public education spending in 21 OECD democracies,

1980–2001. Journal of European Public Policy, 14(4), 582-610.

Busemeyer, M. R. (2009). Social democrats and the new partisan politics of public investment in

education. Journal of European Public Policy, 16(1), 107-126.

Busemeyer, M. R. (2012). Inequality and the political economy of education: an analysis of

individual preferences in OECD countries. Journal of European Social Policy, 22(3),

219-240.

Busemeyer, M. R., Goerres, A., & Weschle, S. (2009). Attitudes towards redistributive spending

in an era of demographic aging: the rival pressures from age and income in 14 OECD

countries. Journal of European Social Policy, 19(3), 195-212.

Busemeyer, M. R., & Iversen, T. (2014). The politics of opting out: explaining educational

financing and popular support for public spending. Socio-Economic Review, 12(2), 299-

151

328.

Byun, S. (2010). Does policy matter in shadow education spending? Revisiting the effects of

the high school equalization policy in South Korea. Asia Pacific Education Review 11(1):

83-96.

Cameron, D. R. (1978). The expansion of the public economy: a comparative analysis.

American Political Science Review, 72(04), 1243-1261.

Castles, F. G. (1989). Explaining public education expenditure in OECD nations. European

Journal of Political Research, 17(4), 431-448.

Chen, D. L., & Lind, J. (2014). The political economy of beliefs: Why fiscal and social

conservatives/liberals come hand-in-hand, Mimeo, University of Chicago.

Cheshire, P. C., & Gordon, I. R. (1998). Territorial competition: some lessons for policy. The

Annals of Regional Science, 32(3), 321-346.

Chiu, E. M., & Willett, T. D. (2009). The interactions of the strength of governments and

alternative exchange rate regimes in avoiding currency crises. International Studies

Quarterly, 53(4), 1001-1025.

Coombs, C. H. (1960). A theory of data. Psychological review, 67(3), 143.

Corcoran, S., & Evans, W. N. (2010). Income inequality, the median voter, and the support for

public education (No. w16097). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Cox, G. W. (2001). The institutional determinants of economic policy outcomes. In S. Haggard,

& MD McCubbins (Eds.), Presidents, parliaments and policy, Cambridge University

Press.

Carmignani, F., Colombo, E., & Tirelli, P. (2007). Public expenditure and growth volatility: do"

152

globalisation" and institutions matter? (No. 116). Dipartimento di Economia Politica

Università degli Studi di Milano-Bicocca.

Crepaz, M. M., & Moser, A. W. (2004). The impact of collective and competitive veto points on

public expenditures in the global age. Comparative Political Studies, 37(3), 259-285.

Dalton, R. J. (2006). Social modernization and the end of ideology debate: patterns of

ideological polarization. Japanese Journal of Political Science,7(01), 1-22.

Decressin, J. (2002). Regional income redistribution and risk sharing: how does Italy compare in

Europe?. Journal of Public Economics, 86(2), 287-306.

Dehejia, R., DeLeire, T., & Luttmer, E. F. (2007). Insuring consumption and happiness through

religious organizations. Journal of Public Economics, 91(1), 259-279.

Dreher, A. (2006). The influence of globalization on taxes and social policy: An empirical

analysis for OECD countries. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(1), 179-201.

Dreher, A., Sturm, J. E., & Ursprung, H. W. (2008). The impact of globalization on the

composition of government expenditures: Evidence from panel data. Public Choice,

134(3-4), 263-292.

De Mesquita, B. B., & Root, M. H. L. (Eds.). (2000). Governing for prosperity. Yale University

Press.

Duncombe, W., Robbins, M., & Stonecash, J. (2003). Measuring citizen preferences for public

services using surveys: Does a “gray peril” threaten funding for public education? Public

Budgeting & Finance, 23(1), 45-72.

Education at a Glance 2014 (www.oecd.org/edu/eag.htm)

Easterly, W. (2007). Inequality does cause underdevelopment: Insights from a new

instrument. Journal of Development Economics, 84(2), 755-776.

153

Epple, D., & Romano, R. E. (1996). Ends against the middle: Determining public service

provision when there are private alternatives. Journal of Public Economics, 62(3), 297-

325.

Fatas, A., & Mihov, I. (2003). On constraining fiscal policy discretion in EMU. Oxford Review

of Economic Policy, 19(1), 112-131.

Fernandez, R., & Rogerson, R. (1995). On the political economy of education subsidies. The

Review of Economic Studies, 62(2), 249-262.

Ferris, J. S. (2003). Do alternative measures of government result in alternative explanations for

government size? Economics Bulletin, 8(4), 1-11.

Franzese, R. (2005). Fiscal Policy with Multiple Policymakers: Veto Actors and Deadlock;

Collective Action and Common Pools; Bargaining and Compromise.

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1084095.

Flockton, C. (1999). Employment, welfare support and income distribution in East Germany. In

C. Flockton (ed.) Recasting East Germany: Social Transformation after the GDR.

London, Routledge.

Furceri, D. (2007). Is Government Expenditure Volatility Harmful for Growth? A Cross‐Country

Analysis. Fiscal Studies, 28(1), 103-120.

Garrett, G. (1998). Partisan politics in the global economy. Cambridge University Press.

Garrett, G., & Mitchell, D. (2001). Globalization, government spending and taxation in the

OECD. European Journal of Political Research, 39(2), 145-177.

Gerber, E. R., & Lewis, J. B. (2004). Beyond the median: voter preferences, district

heterogeneity, and political representation. Journal of Political Economy, 112(6), 1364-

1383.

154

Gemmell, N., Kneller, R., & Sanz, I. (2008). Foreign investment, international trade, and the size

and structure of public expenditures. European Journal of Political Economy, 24(1), 151-

171.

Giorno, C. R., Roseveare, P. D., & van den Noord, P., (1995). Estimating potential output, output

gaps, and structural budget balance. Economics Department Working Paper No. 152.

Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.

Giuranno, M. G. (2009a). Regional income disparity and the size of the public sector. Journal of

Public Economic Theory, 11(5), 697-719.

Giuranno, M. G. (2009b). Pooling sovereignty and subsidiarity principle. Discussion

Papers, 9(01).

Goldin, C., & Katz, L. F. (1997). Why the United States led in education: lessons from

secondary school expansion, 1910 to 1940 (No. w6144). National Bureau of Economic

Research.

Goodrich. S. (1992). Political instability as a determinant of U.S. foreign direct investment.

Harvard University Senior Thesis.

Gunlicks, A. B. (2002). The impact of unification on German federalism. German Politics,

11(3): 131-152.

Ha, E. (2008). Globalization, veto players, and welfare spending. Comparative Political Studies

41:783-813.

Haidt, J., & Graham, J. (2007). When morality opposes justice: Conservatives have moral

intuitions that liberals may not recognize. Social Justice Research,20(1), 98-116.

Hibbs, D. A. (1987). The political economy of industrial democracies (p. 58). Harvard

University Press.

155

Hosmer Jr, D. W., Lemeshow, S., & Sturdivant, R. X. (2013). Applied logistic regression (Vol.

398). John Wiley & Sons.

Huber, J., & Inglehart, R. (1995). Expert interpretations of party space and party locations in 42

societies. Party politics, 1(1), 73-111.

Huber, E., & Stephens, J. D. (2001). Development and crisis of the welfare state: parties and

policies in global markets. University of Chicago press.

Hungerman, D. M. (2005). Are church and state substitutes? Evidence from the 1996 welfare

reform. Journal of Public Economics, 89(11), 2245-2267.

Hooghe, L., Marks, G., & Schakel, A. H. (2010). The rise of regional authority: a comparative

study of 42 democracies. Taylor & Francis.

Hooghe, L., Marks, G., Schakel, A. H., Osterkatz, S. C., Niedzwiecki, S., & Shair-Rosenfield, S.

(2015). Measuring Regional Authority: A Postfunctionalist Theory of Governance.

Volume I: Measuring Regional Authority. Oxford University Press. The dataset is

accessible at http://www.unc.edu/~gwmarks/data_ra.php.

Huber, E., & Stephens, J. D. (2001). Development and crisis of the welfare state: parties and

policies in global markets. University of Chicago Press.

Inglehart, R. (1990). Culture shift in advanced industrial society. Princeton University Press.

Iversen, T., & Cusack, T. R. (2000). The causes of welfare state expansion: deindustrialization or

globalization?. World Politics, 52(03), 313-349.

Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2006a). Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: Why some

democracies redistribute more than others. American Political Science Review, 100(2),

165.

Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2006b). The cause of welfare state expansion: deindustrialization or

156

globalization? World Politics, 52(3), 313-349.

Jacoby, W. G. (1994). Public attitudes toward government spending. American Journal of

Political Science, 336-361.

Jacoby, W. G., & Schneider, S. K. (2001). Variability in state policy priorities: an empirical

analysis. Journal of Politics, 63(2), 544-568.

Jacoby, W. G., & Schneider, S. K. (2009). A new measure of policy spending priorities in the

American states. Political Analysis, 17(1), 1-24.

Keech, W. R. (1995). Economic politics: The costs of democracy. Cambridge University Press.

Kessler, A. S., & Lessmann, C. (2010). Interregional redistribution and regional disparities:

How equalization does (not) work. Centre for Economic Policy Research.

Kim, K. R., & Kang, J. S. (2013). Liberal–conservative self-identification in Korea: a cross-

cultural explanation. Korean Social Science Journal, 40(2), 113-120.

Kim, J. (2004). Fiscal decentralization in Korea. International symposium, on

fiscal decentralization in Asia revisited, Hitotsubashi University, November,

September, 5-6.

Kittel, B., & Winner, H. (2005). How reliable is pooled analysis in political economy? The

globalization‐welfare state nexus revisited. European Journal of Political Research,

44(2), 269-293.

Kitschelt, H., & Rehm, P. (2006). New social risk and political preferences. The politics of post-

industrial welfare states: adapting post-war social policies to new social risks, 52-82.

Kousser, T. (2005). Term limits and the dismantling of state legislative professionalism.

Cambridge University Press.

Kwon, H. Y., & Pontusson, J. (2010). Globalization, labour power and partisan politics

157

revisited. Socio-Economic Review, 8(2), 251-281.

Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of

optimal plans. The Journal of Political Economy, 473-491.

Lessmann, C. (2006). Fiscal decentralization and regional disparity: a panel data approach for

OECD countries. Available at SSRN 936874.

Lessmann, C. (2009). Fiscal decentralization and regional disparity: evidence from cross-section

and panel data. Environment and Planning A, 41, 2455-2473.

Lessmann, C. (2011). Regional inequality and decentralization: an empirical analysis.

Levy, G. (2005). The politics of public provision of education. The Quarterly Journal of

Economics, 1507-1534.

Lindert, P. H. (1996). What limits social spending? Explorations in Economic History, 33, 1-34.

Lupu, N., & Pontusson, J. (2011). The structure of inequality and the politics of redistribution.

American Political Science Review, 105(02), 316-336.

Marks, G., Hooghe, L., & Schakel, A. H. (2008). Patterns of regional authority. Regional and

Federal Studies, 18(2-3), 167-181.

Martinez-Mongay, C. (2002). Fiscal policy and the size of governments. The Behavior of Fiscal

Authorities. Stabilization, Growth and Institutions.

Martinez-Vazquez, J., & McNab, R. M. (2003). Fiscal decentralization and economic

growth. World development, 31(9), 1597-1616.

McLure Jr, C. E. (2001). The tax assignment problem: ruminations on how theory and practice

depend on history. National Tax Journal, 339-363.

Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S.F. (1981). A regional theory of the size of government. Journal

of Political Economy 89(5):914-27.

158

Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1983). Tests of a rational theory of the size of government.

Public Choice, 41(3), 403-418.

Mitchell, R. C., & Carson, R. T. (1989). Using surveys to value public goods: the contingent

valuation method. Resources for the Future.

Moene, K., & Wallerstien, M. (2001). Inequality, social insurance, and redistribution. American

Political Science Review, 95(04), 859-874.

Oates, W. A. (1972). Fiscal federalism. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

Obinger, H., Leibfried, S., & Castles, F. G. (2005). Federalism and the welfare state: new world

and European experiences. Cambridge University Press.

Olson, M. (1982). The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social

Rigidities. Yale University Press.

Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (2013), “Social expenditure:

aggregated data”, OECD Social Expenditure Statistics (database). The dataset is

accessible at http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?datasetcode=SOCX_AGG.

Park, C. (2008). Korean attitudes toward the role of government. Korean Political Science

Review. 42(4), 269-288.

Perotti, R. (1992). Fiscal policy, income distribution, and growth. Columbia University.

Department of Economics.

Perotti, R. (1996). Growth, income distribution, and democracy: what the data say. Journal of

Economic growth, 1(2), 149-187.

Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1994). Is inequality harmful for growth? Theory and evidence.

American Economic Review, 84(3), 600-621.

Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2006). Democratic capital: the nexus of political and economic

159

change (No. w12175). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Peters, A. (2002). An application of Wagner’s ‘law’of expanding state activity to totally

diverse countries. Transition, (31): 1-43.

Plümper, T., Troger V., & Manow, P. (2005). Panel data analysis in comparative politics:

linking method to theory. European Journal of Political Research 44(2): 327-54.

Plutzer, E., & Berkman, M. (2005). The graying of America and support for funding the nation’s

schools. Public Opinion Quarterly, 69(1), 66-86.

Portnov, B., & Felsenstein, D. (2005). Regional disparities in small countries. Springer.

Poterba, J. M. (1996). Demographic structure and the political economy of public education (No.

w5677). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Preston, S. H. (1984), Children and the elderly in the United States, Demography 21: 435-457.

Preston, S. H. (1996). Children will pay. New York Times Magazine, 29, 96-97.

Poterba, J. M. (1996). Demographic structure and the political economy of public education (No.

w5677). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Poole, K. T. (1984). Least squares metric, unidimensional unfolding. Psychometrika, 49(3), 311-

323.

Prud’homme, R. (1995). On the dangers of decentralization, World Bank Policy Research

Working Paper 1252.

Renzsch, W. (1998). Financing German unity: fiscal conflict revolution in a complex federation.

Publius: The Journal of Federalism 28(4):127-146.

Richman, H. A., & Stagner, M. W. (1986). Children: treasured resource or forgotten minority.

Our Aging Society: Paradox and Promise, 161-179.

Riker, W. H. (1964). Federalism: Origin, operation, significance. Boston: Little, Brown.

160

Rodden, J. (2000). The dilemma of fiscal federalism: Hard and soft budget constraints around the

world. Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA.

Rodrik, D. (1996). Why do more open economies have bigger governments? (No. w5537).

National Bureau of Economic Research.

Rodrik, D. (1997). International trade and big government. International Trade and Finance:

New Frontiers for Research, 89.

Rodríguez-Pose, A., & Ezcurra, R. (2010). Does decentralization matter for regional disparities?

A cross-country analysis. Journal of Economic Geography, 10(5), 619-644.

Romer, T. (1975). Individual welfare, majority voting, and the properties of a linear income tax.

Journal of Public Economics, 4(2), 163-185.

Rudra, N., & Haggard, S. (2005). Globalization, democracy, and effective welfare spending in

the developing world. Comparative Political Studies, 38(9), 1015-1049.

Schakel, A. H. (2008). Validation of the regional authority index. Regional and Federal Studies,

18(2-3), 143-166.

Scheve, K., & Stasavage, D. (2006). Religion and preferences for social insurance. Quarterly

Journal of Political Science, 1(3), 255-286.

Schmidt, M. G. (1996). When parties matter: a review of the possibilities and limits of partisan

influence on public policy. European Journal of Political Research, 30(2), 155-183.

Schneider, A. (2003). Decentralization: conceptualization and measurement. Studies in

Comparative International Development (SCID),38(3), 32-56.

Shelton, C. A. (2007). The size and composition of government expenditure. Journal of Public

Economics, 91(11), 2230-2260.

Sibiano, P., & Agasisti, T. (2012). Efficiency and heterogeneity of public spending in education

161

among Italian regions. Journal of Public Affairs.

Solt, F. (2009). Standardizing the world income inequality database*. Social Science Quarterly,

90(2), 231-242.

Sorens, J. (2011). The institutions of fiscal federalism. Publius: The Journal of Federalism,

41(2), 207-231.

Stasavage, D. (2005). Democracy and education spending in Africa. American Journal of

Political Science, 49(2), 343-358.

Strauss, T. (2001). Growth and government: is there a difference between developed and

developing countries?. Economics of Governance, 2(2), 135-157.

Stratmann, T. (1995). Campaign contributions and congressional voting: does the timing of

contributions matter?. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 127-136.

Tanzi, V. (2000, November). On fiscal federalism: issues to worry about. In Conference on

Fiscal Decentralization, International Monetary Fund.

Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. The journal of political economy,

416-424.

Treisman, D. (1999a). Political decentralization and economic reform: a game theoretic

analysis. American Journal of Political Science, 43(2): 488-517.

Treisman, D. (1999b). Russia’s tax crisis: explaining falling revenues in a transitional economy.

Economics and Politics. 11(2): 145-169.

Treisman, D. (2000). Decentralization and inflation: commitment, collective action, or

continuity. American Political Science Review, 837-857.

Treisman, D. (2002). Defining and measuring decentralization: a global perspective.

Unpublished manuscript.

162

Treisman, D. (2006). Fiscal decentralization, governance, and economic performance: a

reconsideration. Economics & Politics, 18(2), 219-235.

Tsebelis, G. (1995). Conditional agenda‐setting and decision‐making inside the European

parliament. The Journal of Legislative Studies, 1(1), 65-93.

Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton University Press.

Volden, C., & Wiseman, A. E. (2007). Bargaining in legislatures over particularistic and

collective goods. American Political Science Review, 101(01), 79-92.

Visser, J. (2011). ICTWSS: Database on institutional characteristics of trade unions, wage

setting, state intervention and social pacts in 34 countries between 1960 and

2007. Institute for Advanced Labour Studies, AIAS, University of Amsterdam,

Amsterdam.

Wagner, A. (1958). Three extracts on public finance. Classics in the theory of public finance,

1(7).

Wagner, A. (1883) Three extracts on public finance, in R. A. Musgrave and A. T. Peacock (eds)

(1958), Classics in the theory of public finance. London: Macmillan.

Weingast, B. R. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: market-preserving federalism

and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 1-31.

Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and

costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. The Journal of Political Economy,

642-664.

Wibbels, E. (2005). Decentralized governance, constitution formation, and redistribution.

Constitutional Political Economy, 16(2), 161-188.

Wittman, D. (1983). Candidate motivation: a synthesis of alternative theories. American

163

Political Science Review, 77(01), 142-157.

Woller, G. M., & Phillips, K. (1998). Fiscal decentralization and LDC economic growth: an

empirical investigation. The journal of development studies, 34(4), 139-148.

Zhang, L. (2002). Income distribution and political economy of allocation of public education

spending. Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research, Discussion paper, (02-25).

164

APPENDICES

165

Appendix 1. Variables used to predict public support for education financing in Korea 2006 (Chapter 3).

Categories Variable(s) Description Mean SD Sources

Public support

for education

financing

Support for public education financing Dummy value coded as 1 if the respondent says “spend much more,” 0 for

otherwise (i.e., spending more, spend as the same now, spend less, and spend

much less). Binary codes created by the author.

0.268 0.443 KGSS 2006

Revised by the author

Level of support for education

financing

Five-scaled values for public support for education financing. (1=spend

much less – 5=spend much more).

3.899 0.894

Household

Income Disparity

Nat

ion

wid

e

Inco

me

Dec

ile

Poor residents in poor regions A set of dummy variables is created to identify the geographic distributions

of “before taxes or other reductions” monthly household income on a

nationwide base (or a subnational region base). Individuals at the bottom

20% and top 20% in household income decile are assigned to be in the poor

and the rich people, respectively. Each of these two groups is further divided

into subgroups, depending on the wealth of the region they reside. The

regional wealth is measured in degree of fiscal independence (=locally

collected revenue / total local revenue *100). Regions at the bottom 20% and

the top 20% in their fiscal independence decile are assigned to be in the poor

and the rich, respectively. All of the variables are dummies. The base

categories are the median household income earners residing in neither poor

nor rich regions.

0.062 0.241 KGSS 2006,

KOSIS – Statistical

Database

(Korean language

version)

Revised by the author

Rich residents in poor regions 0.246 0.158

Poor residents in rich regions 0.058 0.234

Rich residents in rich regions 0.012 0.108

Reg

ion

-Sp

ecif

ic

Inco

me

Dec

ile

Poor residents in poor regions 0.058 0.234

Rich residents in poor regions 0.029 0.169

Poor residents in rich regions 0.057 0.232

Rich residents in rich regions 0.047 0.211

Controls Gender The respondent’s gender: Female = 1, male = 0 0.554 0.497 KGSS 2006,

ISCO-88 ,

Revised by the author

College degree The highest level of school the respondent attended: 4 year college (or

above) = 1, junior college (or below) = 0.

0.490 0.500

Married with kids The respondent’s marital status with children: married with kids = 1,

otherwise = 0.

0.621 0.485

Seniors Age over 65 = 1, otherwise = 0 0.124 0.329

Occupation in education field The variable takes a value of one if the respondents work for school districts

or works in the educational field. To identify individuals with their

occupation types, 4 digit ISCO-88 codes are used.

0.068 0.252

Continued

166

Appendix 1 (Continued).

Categories Variable(s) Description Mean SD Sources

Controls Ideological self-placement Self-identification of ideological positioning on a 5 points scale: (1) Very

conservative, (2) somewhat conservative, (3) neither liberal nor

conservative, (4) somewhat liberal (5) very liberal.

2.926 0.938 KGSS 2006

Revised by the author

Attending religious service Frequency in the respondent’s attending religious service: (1) Less than once

a year – (8) A few times a week.

3.483 2.576

Tax burden for high-income Describing the respondent’s feeling about taxes for high income. (1) Much

too low, (2) too low, (3) about right, (4) too high, (5) much too high.

2.319 1.143

Better economic situations How satisfied with the current state of economy: (1) Very dissatisfied, (2)

somewhat dissatisfied, (3) neither satisfied nor dissatisfied, (4) somewhat

satisfied, (5) very satisfied.

3.342 0.918

Government responsibility Responsible for reducing the income gap between the rich and the poor: (1)

Definitely should not be, (2) probably should not be, (3) probably should be,

(4) definitely should be.

3.176 0.815

Unemployed† Whether working for pay: 1=Yes, 0 = No 0.418 0.493

Perceived social-class† Subjective class identification: 1=lower, 2=middle, 3=upper. 1.312 0.517

Government / public workers† Types of an organization working for: 1= government or publicly owned

firms, 0 = private firms or nonprofit organization or others.

0.042 0.203

Regional Dummies Administrative subnational boundaries. 87 for probit model estimates, 95 for

ordered probit model estimates.

Notes: KGSS = Korean General Social Survey, KOSIS = Korean Statistical Information Service. ISCO-88 = International Standard Classification of Occupation †Additional

control variables used in ordered probit model estimate. See Appendix 6.

167

Appendix 2. Regional Support for Education Financing in Korea (2006)

Rank Regions

Metro

Areas

Binary Outcomes Five-scale Outcomes Financial

Independence Index Yes No

Spend

much

less

Spend Less

Spend

as the

same now

Spend more

Spend

much

more

1 Seocho-gu Seoul 33.33 66.67 0.00 0.00 16.67 50.00 33.33 90.40

2 Gangnam-gu Seoul 35.71 64.29 0.00 0.00 7.14 57.14 35.71 87.20

3 Songpa-gu Seoul 32.35 67.65 0.00 5.88 17.65 44.12 32.35 84.20

4 Seongnam-si 20.69 79.31 3.45 0.00 20.69 55.17 20.69 72.40

5 Yeongdeungpo-gu Seoul 20.83 79.17 0.00 0.00 29.17 50.00 20.83 71.20

6 Suwon-si 25.45 74.55 0.00 1.82 20.00 52.73 25.45 65.60

7 Changwon-si 15.00 85.00 2.50 5.00 45.00 32.50 15.00 63.80

8 Hwaseong-gun 44.44 55.56 0.00 11.11 22.22 22.22 44.44 63.60

9 Ansan-si 30.56 69.44 2.78 19.44 16.67 30.56 30.56 62.80

10 Anyang-si 31.25 68.75 0.00 6.25 31.20 31.20 31.25 62.70

11 Bucheon-si 10.00 90.00 0.00 5.00 30.00 55.00 10.00 62.00

12 Goyang-si 44.44 55.56 0.00 0.00 13.89 41.67 44.44 60.60

13 Yangcheon-gu Seoul 31.58 68.42 0.00 5.26 21.05 31.58 31.58 59.70

14 Osan-si 33.33 66.67 6.67 6.67 26.67 26.67 33.33 58.40

15 Siheung-si 26.67 73.33 0.00 6.67 40.00 26.67 26.67 58.10

16 Yongin-si 26.67 73.33 0.00 0.00 6.67 66.67 26.67 56.40

17 Gumi-si 9.09 90.91 0.00 0.00 31.82 59.09 9.09 54.10

18 Ulju-gun 30.00 70.00 0.00 0.00 10.00 60.00 30.00 50.50

19 Gwangyang-si† 0.00 100.00 0.00 20.00 20.00 60.00 0.00 48.70

20 Yangsan-si 33.33 66.67 0.00 0.00 50.00 16.67 33.33 48.30

21 Dongjak-gu 37.14 62.86 0.00 8.57 14.29 40.00 37.14 48.20

22 Uijeongbu-si 33.33 66.67 0.00 0.00 16.67 50.00 33.33 48.20

23 Pohang-si 30.30 69.70 0.00 0.00 18.18 51.52 30.30 47.80

24 Cheonan-si 22.45 77.55 2.04 4.08 28.57 42.86 22.45 47.70

25 Gwangmyeong-si† 0.00 100.00 0.00 0.00 40.00 60.00 0.00 47.50

26 Cheongju-si 34.21 65.79 0.00 10.53 10.53 44.74 34.21 47.40

27 Gwangjin-gu Seoul 40.00 60.00 0.00 0.00 16.00 44.00 40.00 44.90

28 Seongbuk-gu Seoul 31.25 68.75 0.00 6.25 25.00 37.50 31.25 44.50

29 Uiwang-si 50.00 50.00 0.00 0.00 16.67 33.33 50.00 44.10

30 Gangseo-gu Seoul 34.29 65.71 0.00 11.43 20.00 34.29 34.29 43.90

31 Pyeongtaek-si 63.64 36.36 9.09 9.09 9.09 9.09 63.64 43.90

32 Nam-gu Ulsan 11.11 88.89 0.00 22.22 11.11 55.56 11.11 43.10

33 Guri-si 28.57 71.43 0.00 0.00 0.00 71.43 28.57 42.50

34 Namdong-gu Incheon 37.50 62.50 0.00 0.00 12.50 50.00 37.50 41.00

35 Paju-si 19.05 80.95 0.00 14.29 23.81 42.86 19.05 40.80

36 Gimpo-si 0.00 100.00 0.00 33.33 33.33 33.33 0.00 40.70

37 Namyangju-si 29.41 70.59 0.00 17.65 23.53 29.41 29.41 40.40

38 Gimhae-si 15.00 85.00 5.00 0.00 30.00 50.00 15.00 40.40 39 Suseong-gu Daegu 20.83 79.17 0.00 8.33 16.67 54.17 20.83 39.50

40 Yuseong-gu Daejeon 31.25 68.75 0.00 6.25 31.25 31.25 31.25 39.20

41 Dobong-gu Seoul 43.75 56.25 0.00 0.00 18.75 37.50 43.75 39.00

42 Masan-si 21.05 78.95 0.00 5.26 47.37 26.32 21.05 38.90

43 Busanjin-gu Busan 30.77 69.23 0.00 0.00 15.38 53.85 30.77 38.80

44 Buk-gu Ulsan 50.00 50.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 50.00 50.00 38.40

45 Jeonju-si 40.48 59.52 0.00 0.00 21.43 38.10 40.48 37.40

46 Gwanak-gu Seoul 43.75 56.25 6.25 0.00 18.75 31.25 43.75 36.60

47 Geoje-si 33.33 66.67 0.00 0.00 22.22 44.44 33.33 35.60

48 Jeju-si 26.32 73.68 0.00 5.26 5.26 63.16 26.32 33.80

49 Dangjin-gun 11.11 88.89 0.00 11.11 33.33 44.44 11.11 33.30

50 Yeonsu-gu† Incheon 0.00 100.00 0.00 27.27 27.27 45.45 0.00 32.90

51 Dalseo-gu Daegu 15.38 84.62 0.00 0.00 38.46 46.15 15.38 32.50 52 Nam-gu Incheon 33.33 66.67 0.00 0.00 11.11 33.33 33.33 32.10

53 Jung-gu Daegu 18.18 81.82 0.00 0.00 18.18 63.64 18.18 32.10

54 Nowon-gu Seoul 26.83 73.17 0.00 12.20 12.20 48.78 26.83 32.00 55 Dongdaemun-gu† Seoul 40.00 60.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 60.00 40.00 32.00

Continued

168

Appendix 2 (Continued).

Rank Regions

Binary Outcome Five-scale Outcome Financial

Independence

Index

Metro

Areas Yes No

Spend

much

less

Spend less

Spend

as the

same now

Spend more

Spend

much

more

56 Anseong-si 37.50 62.50 0.00 12.50 25.00 25.00 37.50 31.90

57 Gangbuk-gu Seoul 50.00 50.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 50.00 50.00 31.10

58 Haeundae-gu Busan 33.33 66.67 0.00 5.56 27.78 33.33 33.33 31.00

59 Wonju-si 14.29 85.71 7.14 7.14 28.57 42.86 14.29 30.90

60 Seo-gu Gwangju 22.22 77.78 0.00 0.00 25.93 51.85 22.22 30.70

61 Yeosu-si 33.33 66.67 0.00 0.00 11.11 55.56 33.33 30.60

62 Bupyeong-gu Incheon 26.92 73.08 0.00 0.00 23.08 50.00 26.92 30.50

63 Eunpyeong-gu Seoul 34.62 65.38 0.00 0.00 23.08 42.31 34.62 30.40

64 Jungnang-gu Seoul 20.00 80.00 0.00 0.00 20.00 60.00 20.00 30.40

65 Dalseong-gun 11.11 88.89 0.00 11.11 55.56 22.22 11.11 30.20

66 Yeonje-gu Busan 50.00 50.00 0.00 0.00 33.33 16.67 50.00 30.00

67 Dongnae-gu Busan 37.50 62.50 0.00 25.00 25.00 12.50 37.50 29.70

68 Gyeyang-gu Incheon 23.08 76.92 3.85 11.54 7.69 53.85 23.08 29.00

69 Suncheon-si 18.18 81.82 0.00 4.55 13.64 63.64 18.18 28.80

70 Gyeongsan-si 11.11 88.89 0.00 33.33 22.22 33.33 11.11 28.70

71 Jincheon-gun 36.36 63.64 0.00 27.27 9.09 27.27 36.36 27.00

72 Sasang-gu Busan 22.22 77.78 0.00 0.00 11.11 66.67 22.22 26.90

73 Nam-gu Busan 12.50 87.50 0.00 12.50 12.50 62.50 12.50 26.70

74 Gyeongju-si 20.00 80.00 0.00 0.00 40.00 40.00 20.00 26.60

75 Gangneung-si 25.00 75.00 8.33 8.33 33.33 33.33 25.00 26.50

76 Sokcho-si 14.29 85.71 0.00 14.29 0.00 71.43 14.20 26.50

77 Gwangsan-gu Gwangju 28.57 71.43 0.00 11.43 31.43 28.57 28.57 26.00

78 Saha-gu Busan 36.36 63.64 0.00 9.09 18.18 36.36 36.36 25.80

79 Seo-gu Daegu 55.56 44.44 0.00 0.00 11.11 33.33 55.56 25.40

80 Buk-gu Daegu 16.67 83.33 0.00 12.50 16.67 54.17 16.67 25.20

81 Daedeok-gu Daejeon 25.00 75.00 0.00 12.50 37.50 25.00 25.00 24.40

82 Jung-gu Ulsan 33.33 66.67 0.00 16.67 33.33 16.67 33.33 23.10

83 Buk-gu Gwangju 14.29 85.71 0.00 14.29 14.29 57.14 14.29 22.10

84 Dong-gu Dae-gu 33.33 66.67 0.00 11.11 11.11 44.44 33.33 21.60

85 Donghae-si† 0.00 100.00 0.00 25.00 25.00 25.00 0.00 21.20

86 Yeongdo-gu Busan 57.14 42.86 0.00 0.00 14.29 28.57 57.14 18.80

87 Buk-gu Busan 13.04 86.96 0.00 8.70 8.70 69.57 13.04 18.20

88 Hwasun-gun 28.57 71.43 0.00 14.29 42.86 14.29 28.57 17.20

89 Geochang-gun 20.00 80.00 0.00 10.00 50.00 20.00 20.00 14.50

90 Jeongeup-si 11.11 88.89 0.00 0.00 55.56 33.33 11.11 14.00

91 Hongseong-gun 25.00 75.00 0.00 25.00 12.50 37.50 25.00 12.40

92 Yeongwol-gun 28.57 71.43 0.00 14.29 14.29 42.86 28.57 12.10

93 Buan-gun† 0.00 100.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 100.00 0.00 12.00

94 Gochang-gun† 0.00 100.00 0.00 0.00 55.56 44.44 0.00 10.70

95 Haenam-gun† 0.00 100.00 0.00 0.00 14.29 85.71 0.00 10.40

96 Yecheon-gun† 0.00 100.00 0.00 11.11 22.22 66.67 0.00 10.10

Note: Empty spaces denote zero percent of the response categories. All numbers drawn in the table are expressed in percentage.

† 9 municipalities dropped from the probit analysis due to no variations on the binary dependent variable.

169

Appendix 3. Spearman Rank Order Correlation (N=1414)

Measure [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8] [9] [10] [11] [12] [13] [14] [15] [16] [17] [18] [19]

[1]. Support for Education (0/1) -----

[2]. Pp (0/1) -0.02 -----

[3]. Rp (0/1) 0.01 -0.03 -----

[4]. Pr (0/1) -0.05 -0.02 -0.02 ----- [5]. Rr (0/1) -0.03 -0.05* -0.04 -0.03 -----

[6]. P̅P (0/1) -0.02 0.64* -0.03 -0.02 -0.04 -----

[7]. R̅P (0/1) 0.01 -0.05 0.61* -0.03 -0.06* -0.04 -----

[8]. P̅r (0/1) 0.00 -0.04 -0.03 0.63* -0.04 -0.03 -0.04 -----

[9]. R̅r (0/1) -0.03 -0.05 -0.04 -0.02 0.82* -0.04 -0.05* -0.04 -----

[10]. Female (1/0) -0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 -0.02 0.02 0.01 0.02 -0.02 -----

[11]. College Degree (1/0) 0.04 -0.18* 0.09* -0.09* 0.12* -0.11* 0.07* -0.07* 0.13* -0.16* -----

[12]. Married with Kids (1/0) 0.06* -0.05* -0.05 -0.04 0.03 -0.02 -0.00 -0.02 0.03 0.05 -0.23* -----

[13]. Seniors (1/0) -0.02 0.22 -0.01 0.06 -0.06* 0.17* -0.04 0.04 -0.06* -0.02 -0.26* 0.02 ----- [14]. Occupation in Education (1/0) 0.02 -0.05 0.06* -0.03 0.02 -0.03 0.03 -0.05 0.01 0.14* 0.22* 0.02 -0.06* -----

[15]. Ideological Self-placement (1-5) 0.05 0.02 0.07* -0.04 0.04 -0.02 0.05 -0.04 0.02 -0.03 0.11* -0.05 -0.06* 0.04 -----

[16]. Attending Religious Services (1-8) 0.01 0.06* 0.02 -0.01 0.03 0.04 0.01 -0.01 0.01 0.20* -0.02 0.11* 0.04 0.03 0.02 -----

[17]. Tax burden for High Income (1-5) -0.06* 0.03 0.05 -0.05 0.05* 0.01 -0.02 -0.01 0.03 0.02 0.02 -0.00 0.03 -0.05 -0.07* 0.05 -----

[18]. Better economic situation (1-5) 0.04 0.04 -0.01 0.05 0.06* 0.03 -0.02 0.04 0.03 -0.04 0.02 -0.03 0.04 -0.01 0.09* 0.04 -0.03 -----

[19]. Government responsibility (1-4) 0.08* 0.03 -0.00 -0.04 -0.08 -0.00 -0.01 -0.10* -0.07* 0.03 -0.01 -0.08* 0.05 0.02 0.10* -0.03 -0.14* -0.02 -----

Note: The reported correlation is based on Table 5. To avoid violations of normality given a non-linear relationship being tested, Spearman rank-order coefficients are tested as an alternative to Pearson’s

correlation. Spearman’s correlations significant at p<0.05*. For the nationwide income disparity specification, Pp = Poor residents in poor regions, Rp = Rich residents in poor regions, Pr = Poor residents in rich

regions, Rr = Rich residents in rich regions. For the region-specific income disparity specification, P̅P = Poor residents in poor regions, R̅P = Rich residents in poor regions, P̅r = Poor residents in rich regions,

R̅r = Rich residents in rich regions.

170

Appendix 4. Robust to Alternative Income Distribution Specifications

Dependent Variable:

(1) Government should spend more on education* (0) Otherwise

* If agreeing to “spend much more,” it might require a tax increase to pay

for it. (25% of total survey samples)

Household Income

Deciles (Nationwide)

Household Income

Deciles (Region-specific)

Probit Basic

[1]

Probit Full

[2]

Probit Basic

[3]

Probit Full

[4]

Poor Regions (Fiscal Independence Ranking Bottom 40% = 1, 0)

Poor Residents (Household Income Ranking Bottom 40% = 1, 0) 0.294 0.227 0.108 0.092

(0.215) (0.214) (0.178) (0.181)

Rich Residents (Household Income Ranking Top 40% = 1, 0) 0.486** 0.472** 0.119 0.128 (0.220) (0.219) (0.167) (0.169)

Rich Regions (Fiscal Independence Ranking Top 40% = 1, 0)

Poor Residents (Household Income Ranking Bottom 40% =1, 0) -0.046 -0.066 -0.234 -0.249†

(0.196) (0.202) (0.164) (0.168) Rich Residents (Household Income Ranking Top 40% = 1, 0) -0.032 -0.013 -0.281* -0.258†

(0.169) (0.172) (0.158) (0.162)

Controls

Gender (Female=1, Male=0) -0.044 -0.030 -0.034 -0.020 (0.077) (0.079) (0.077) (0.079)

College Degree (Yes = 1, No=0) 0.084 0.115 0.113 0.146

(0.087) (0.089) (0.088) (0.090) Married with Kids (Yes = 1, No=0) 0.164** 0.178** 0.168** 0.183**

(0.082) (0.083) (0.082) (0.084)

Seniors (Age 65 or above = 1, Otherwise 0) -0.111 -0.053 -0.103 -0.048 (0.141) (0.145) (0.141) (0.145)

Occupation in Education Field (Yes = 1, No =0) 0.076 0.068 0.075 0.070

(0.140) (0.141) (0.141) (0.142) Ideological Self-placement (Conservative 1 – Liberal 5) 0.076* 0.045 0.079* 0.047

(0.040) (0.042) (0.040) (0.042)

Frequency in Attending Religious Services (1-8) -0.002 -0.002 -0.001 -0.000 (0.015) (0.015) (0.015) (0.015)

Tax Burden for High Income (Much too low 1 – Much too high 5) -0.053† -0.052

(0.033) (0.033) Better Economic Situation (Much Worse 1 – Much Better 5) 0.064† 0.064

(0.043) (0.043)

Government Responsibility to Reduce Income Gap (1-4) 0.106** 0.106** (0.049) (0.049)

Constant (Residents of Gangnam-gu, Seoul Metropolitan Area) -0.653 -0.929* -0.470 -0.754

(0.401) (0.487) (0.410) (0.491)

Number of observations 1,454 1,414 1,454 1,414 Fixed Effect Dummy (# of Regions) Yes (87) Yes (87) Yes(87) Yes(87)

BIC 2340.242 2310.354 2341.878 2312.616

McFadden’s Pseudo R-squared 0.054 0.061 0.054 0.060

Hosmer–Lemeshow Chi2 (Test for Goodness-of-fit) 3.12 2.75 6.34 9.22

Prob > Hosmer-Lemeshow Chi2, Testing against the null hypothesis that there is no difference between observed and model-predicted values)

0.927 0.949 0.609 0.324

Note: Two-tailed test significant at the two-tailed test at p<0.01***, p<0.05**, p<0.1*, p<0.15†. Heteroskedastic-robust standard errors are in parentheses. 72% of data are correctly predicted across all estimated probit models. The average sample sizes of household income groups are 16

percent and 17 percent of the total survey responses.

171

Appendix 5. Propensity Score Matching Estimates of Geographic-based Household Income

Distribution Groups on Support for Increases in Education Financing

Household Income

(Nationwide)

Household Income

(Region-specific)

Nearest

Neighbor

Matching

Poor Rich Poor Rich

Regional

Wealth

Poor 0.12

[t= 1.41]

0.07

[t=0.39] Poor

0.00

[t=0.00] 0.19

[t= 2.19]

Rich -0.30

[t= -1.96]

-1.44

[t= -1.55] Rich

0.09

[t= 0.84]

-0.07

[t= -0.98]

Radius

Matching

Poor Rich Poor Rich

Regional

Wealth

Poor 0.16

[t=1.11]

0.14

[t=0.88] Poor

0.03

[t=0.29] 0.15

[t = 1.92]

Rich -0.23

[t= -2.55]

-0.11

[t= -1.62] Rich

0.07

[t= 0.75]

-0.08

[t=-1.16]

Notes: The numbers inside the boxes indicate sensitivity analysis for average treatment effects. The emboldened

output shows a statistically significant treatment effect on the treated.

172

Appendix 6. Robust to Ordered Probit Estimators

Query: Government Should Spend Money on Education.

1. Spend much less 2. Spend less 3. Spend the same as now 4. Spend more 5. Spend much more* (*25% of total survey samples)

87 Regions (Samples from Probit Estimates) 96 Regions (All Samples)

Household Income Deciles (Nationwide)

Household Income Deciles (Region-specific)

Household Income Deciles (Nationwide)

Household Income Deciles (Region-specific)

Basic

[1]

Full

[2]

Basic

[3]

Full

[4]

Basic

[5]

Full

[6]

Basic

[7]

Basic

[8]

Poor Regions (Fiscal Independence Ranking Bottom 20% = 1, 0)

Poor Residents (Household Income Ranking Bottom 20% = 1, 0) 0.149 0.126 0.175 0.170 0.126 0.098 0.200 0.194 (0.176) (0.176) (0.185) (0.187) (0.159) (0.158) (0.181) (0.183)

Rich Residents (Household Income Ranking Top 20% = 1, 0) 0.075 0.118 0.258† 0.277* 0.089 0.121† 0.257* 0.278*

(0.251) (0.260) (0.165) (0.167) (0.247) (0.255) (0.154) (0.155)

Rich Regions (Fiscal Independence Ranking Top 20% = 1, 0)

Poor Residents (Household Income Ranking Bottom 20% =1, 0) -0.255 -0.318† 0.244 0.251 -0.253 -0.313 0.252 0.262 (0.182) (0.203) (0.177) (0.188) (0.184) (0.204) (0.179) (0.190)

Rich Residents (Household Income Ranking Top 20% = 1, 0) -0.248* -0.251* -0.105 -0.099 -0.251* -0.252* -0.107 -0.100

(0.137) (0.144) (0.143) (0.149) (0.138) (0.145) (0.145) (0.151) Controls

Gender (Female=1, Male=0) -0.027 -0.020 -0.035 -0.030 -0.025 -0.020 -0.034 -0.032

(0.062) (0.063) (0.062) (0.063) (0.061) (0.062) (0.061) (0.062) College Degree (Yes = 1, No=0) 0.153** 0.180** 0.141** 0.171** 0.154** 0.181** 0.144** 0.175**

(0.071) (0.072) (0.070) (0.071) (0.070) (0.071) (0.070) (0.070)

Married with Kids (Yes = 1, No=0) 0.191*** .215*** 0.191*** 0.218*** 0.190*** 0.218*** 0.191*** 0.221***

(0.066) (0.067) (0.065) (0.066) (0.065) (0.066) (0.064) (0.065)

Seniors (Age 65 or above = 1, Otherwise 0) -0.093 -0.069 -0.100 -0.079 -0.126 -0.093 -0.131 -0.102

(0.105) (0.108) (0.104) (0.108) (0.099) (0.103) (0.098) (0.103) Occupation in Education Field (Yes = 1, No =0) 0.185* 0.189* 0.188* 0.192* 0.192* 0.194* 0.196* 0.198*

(0.104) (0.106) (0.104) (0.106) (0.103) (0.105) (0.103) (0.105)

Ideological Self-placement (Conservative 1 – Liberal 5) 0.076** 0.049 0.077** 0.050 0.073** 0.048 0.074** 0.049 (0.033) (0.034) (0.033) (0.034) (0.032) (0.034) (0.032) (0.034)

Frequency in Attending Religious Services (1-8) 0.017† 0.016 0.017† 0.015† 0.016† 0.015 0.016 0.014

(0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.011) (0.012) (0.011) (0.012) Tax Burden for High Income (Much too low 1 – Much too high 5) -0.043† -0.039 -0.040 -0.036

(0.029) (0.029) (0.029) (0.029)

Better Economic Situation (Much Worse 1 – Much Better 5) .095*** 0.092** 0.093*** 0.091** (0.036) (0.036) (0.035) (0.035)

Government Responsibility to Reduce Income Gap (1-4) 0.067† 0.076* 0.078* 0.085** (0.041) (0.041) (0.040) (0.040)

Number of observations 1,454 1,414 1,454 1,414 1,513 1,470 1,513 1,470

Fixed Effect Dummy (# of Regions) Yes (87) Yes (87) Yes (87) Yes (87) Yes (96) Yes(96) Yes (96) Yes(96) BIC 4246.42 4150.995 4244.71 4149.287 4439.932 4337.181 4437.604 4334.703

Pseudo (McFadden’s) R2 0.036 0.041 0.037 0.042 0.041 0.045 0.041 0.046

Note: Two-tailed tests significant at two-tailed test at p<0.01***, p<0.05**, p<0.1*, p<0.15†. Heteroskedastic-robust standard errors are in parentheses. The cut point values (4) are not reported here due to a space limit.

173

Appendix 7. Robust to Overall Government Spending

Query: Cut in government spending.

1.Strongly in favor of

2.In favor of 3. Neither in favor of nor against

4. Against

5. Strongly against

Household income decile (Nationwide) Household income decile (Region-specific)

Ordered Probit

Basic

[1]

Ordered Probit

Full

[2]

Ordered Probit

Full + Additional controls

[3]

Ordered Probit

Basic

[4]

Ordered Probit

Full

[5]

Ordered Probit

Full + Additional controls

[6]

Poor Regions (Fiscal Independence Ranking Bottom 40% = 1, 0)

Poor Residents (Household Income Ranking Bottom 40% = 1, 0) 0.140 (0.143) 0.097 (0.146) 0.080 (0.148) 0.076 (0.134) 0.092 (0.138) 0.089 (0.139) Rich Residents (Household Income Ranking Top 40% = 1, 0) 0.145 (0.144) 0.083 (0.145) 0.072 (0.146) 0.084 (0.125) 0.128 (0.125) 0.128 (0.126)

Rich Regions (Fiscal Independence Ranking Top 40% = 1, 0)

Poor Residents (Household Income Ranking Bottom 40% =1, 0) -0.441 (0.146)*** -0.435 (0.148)*** -0.438 (0.149)*** -0.055 (0.132) -0.066 (0.134) -0.084 (0.136)

Rich Residents (Household Income Ranking Top 40% = 1, 0) -0.262 (0.123)** -0.264 (0.125)** -0.234 (0.127)* 0.010 (0.130) -0.015 (0.132) 0.010 (0.134)

Controls

Gender (Female=1, Male=0) -0.065 (0.060) -0.060 (0.061) -0.117 (0.064)* -0.064 (0.060) -0.060 (0.061) -0.120 (0.064)*

College Degree (Yes = 1, No=0) -0.094 (0.071) -0.103 (0.072) † -0.112 (0.074) † -0.096 (0.071) -0.110 (0.072) † -0.120 (0.074) † Married with Kids (Yes = 1, No=0) -0.220 (0.062)*** -0.215 (0.063)*** -0.193 (0.064)*** -0.212 (0.062)*** -0.208 (0.063)*** -0.186 (0.064)***

Seniors (Age 65 or above = 1, Otherwise 0) 0.133 (0.108) 0.082 (0.114) 0.013 (0.115) 0.120 (0.109) 0.070 (0.114) -0.001 (0.115)

Occupation in Education Field (Yes = 1, No =0) 0.091 (0.105) 0.095 (0.107) 0.150 (0.109) 0.093 (0.105) 0.095 (0.108) 0.150 (0.110) Ideological Self-placement (Conservative 1 – Liberal 5) 0.021 (0.033) 0.029 (0.034) 0.025 (0.034) 0.023 (0.033) 0.031 (0.034) 0.026 (0.034)

Frequency in Attending Religious Services (1-8) -0.028 (0.011)** -0.028 (0.012)** -0.029 (0.012)** -0.029 (0.011)** -0.029 (0.012)** -0.030 (0.012)** Tax Burden for High Income (Much too low 1 – Much too high 5) 0.027 (0.027) 0.027 (0.028) 0.025 (0.028) 0.024 (0.028)

Better Economic Situation (Much Worse 1 – Much Better 5) 0.054 (0.035) † 0.053 (0.035) † 0.058 (0.035)* 0.057 (0.035)*

Government Responsibility to Reduce Income Gap (1-4) 0.017 (0.038) 0.014 (0.038) 0.017 (0.038) 0.013 (0.038) Unemployed (1=Working for pay, 0 = No) 0.201 (0.065)*** 0.206 (0.066)***

Perceived Level of Socioeconomic-class (Low=1, Middle=2, High=3)√ -0.072 (0.062) -0.072 (0.062)

Government or Public Workers: (1=government, publicly owned firm,

0=private firm, nonprofit organization, others)

0.479 (0.146)*** 0.486 (0.146)***

Number of observations 1,498 1,456 1,452 1,498 1,456 1,452 Fixed Effect Dummy (# of Regions – “Gangnam-gu” as the base) Yes (96) Yes(96) Yes(96) Yes(96) Yes(96) Yes(96)

BIC 4863.629 4759.483 4750.719 4871.940 4766.288 4757.025 Pseudo (McFadden’s) R2 0.048 0.050 0.055 0.046 0.048 0.053

Note: Two-tailed tests significant at the two-tailed test at p<0.01***, p<0.05**, p<0.1*, p<0.15†. Heteroskedastic-robust standard errors are in parentheses. The cut point values (4) are not reported here due to a space limit.

√Designed for capturing a subjective measure (while household income variables are used as objective measures).

174

Appendix 8. Variables, Definitions, and Sources (Chapter 4)

Variables Description Min Max Data Source

Education Spending

General Public

Education Spending

Public expenditure on education, total (% of

GDP): Government spending on educational

institutions, education administration, as well as

subsidies

1.77 8,72 World Development

Indicators (WDI),

UNESCO Institute for

Statistics (UNESCO)

Education Spending

Policy Priority across

Sectors (Tertiary over

Primary)

Using % of the distribution of public current

expenditure on education by tertiary (or

primary), the variable is created regarding ratio

values.

0.19 1.97 UNESCO; Ratio (Tertiary

/ Primary) is the author’s

calculation.

Economic Inequality

P9010 Earnings of a worker in the 90th percentile of the

earnings distribution as a share of the earnings of

a worker in the 10th percentile of the earning

distribution.

1.95 5.02 Lupu and Pontusson

(2011), OECD (2007)

SKEW The 90th-50th earning ratio divided by the 50th –

10th earning ratio.

0.75 1.77

COV† The Coefficient of Variation. 0.08 0.46 Author’s calculation from

data of national statistics

and the Cambridge

Econometrics (NUT2

Level).

COVW† Weighted Coefficient of Variation. 0.08 0.43

ADGINI† Adjusted Gini Coefficient 0.04 0.25

Federalism

FISCAL

FEDERALISM

The extent which regional representatives

codetermine the distribution of the national tax

revenue. 0, 1, 2

0 2 Regional Authority Index

(Hooghe et al. 2010)

ELECTORAL

FEDERALISM

Extent which state / Province governments are

locally elected: 0, 1, 2.

0 2 Database of Political

Institutions (DPI, Beck et

al. 2010)

Controls

LEFT Leftist party legislative seats as % of total seats 0 65.0 Comparative Parties

Dataset I

KAOPEN Capital openness Index -1.86 2.46 Chin-Ito Index (2010)

GOVTEXP Total government expenditure as % of GDP 9.7 29.8 WDI

TRADE Imports + Exports / GDP 17.19 183.07

GDPPC (LOG) Log of GDP per capita, constant 2000 US$ 1.86 3.74

GDPPC_GROWTH GDP per capita growth (annual %) -8.79 7.6

POP14 Age under 14 (% of Population) 13.48 30.36

Note: †Values (with a possible range from 0 to 1) are rescaled to a possible range from 0 to10 for analysis purpose. †† In the

modeling analysis, values are adjusted for counting every 10 scale move to see the effects more clearly. * Total enrollment,

regardless of age, to the population of the age group that officially corresponds to the level of education.

175

Appendix 9. Robustness Tests: Impacts of Inequality on Public Education Spending

[1] [2] [3]

Variables coef/pcse coef/pcse coef/pcse

Inter-regional Inequality

COV

-0.1910***

(0.0717)

COVW -0.2417**

(0.1032)

ADGINI -0.4748***

(0.1796)

Inter-personal Inequality

P9010

0.5567***

0.5105***

0.5876***

(0.1817) (0.1840) (0.1791)

SKEW 1.5970** 1.5912** 1.6710**

(0.7703) (0.7700) (0.7794)

Controls

TRADE

0.0091**

0.0092**

0.0085*

(0.0043) (0.0043) (0.0044)

KAOPEN 0.4702*** 0.4796*** 0.4706***

(0.0698) (0.0700) (0.0700)

GOVTEXP 0.3182*** 0.3120*** 0.3180***

(0.0302) (0.0301) (0.0301)

LEFT 0.0077** 0.0076** 0.0079**

(0.0038) (0.0038) (0.0039)

GDPPC (LOG) 1.4688*** 1.5517*** 1.4846***

(0.5077) (0.5093) (0.5067)

GDPPC (GROWTH) 0.0256 0.0271 0.0262

(0.0168) (0.0168) (0.0167)

POP14 0.3647*** 0.3675*** 0.3734***

(0.0537) (0.0532) (0.0545)

FISCAL FEDERALISM -9.1473*** -9.1608*** -8.0811***

(1.1985) (1.1717) (1.0296)

ELECTORAL FEDERALISM -0.3188 -0.3471 -0.2766

(0.2766) (0.2673) (0.2739)

Number of observations 245 245 245

Countries 18 18 18

R square 0.9943 0.9944 0.9944

Note: Two-tailed tests for significant at *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. All models account for

country fixed effects. Errors are corrected for panel specific AR1. The constant is suppressed.

176

Appendix 10: Effects of Inter-personal Inequality & Federalism on Public Education Spending

[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]

Variables coef/pcse coef/pcse coef/pcse coef/pcse coef/pcse coef/pcse

Inter-personal Inequality

P9010 0.8586*** 0.8474*** 0.8667*** -0.9256 -0.8423 -0.9562

(0.2372) (0.2366) (0.2367) (0.5906) (0.5769) (0.5872)

SKEW 1.5611* 1.5828* 1.5370* 0.8046 0.5259 1.0401

(0.8256) (0.8296) (0.8235) (1.9598) (1.9032) (2.0153)

Testing Collective Action

Problem Constraints

P9010 * Fiscal Federalism -0.3967 -0.4438 -0.3563

(0.3499) (0.3545) (0.3525)

SKEW * Fiscal Federalism -0.2386 -0.2927 -0.0689

(1.6675) (1.6911) (1.6649)

P9010 * Electoral Federalism 0.8593*** 0.7942*** 0.8943***

(0.3061) (0.2997) (0.3041)

SKEW * Electoral Federalism 0.6448 0.7802 0.5658

(1.0611) (1.0382) (1.0894)

Inter-regional Inequality

COV -0.1777** -0.1903***

(0.0711) (0.0716)

COVW -0.2235** -0.2278**

(0.0994) (0.1028)

ADGINI -0.4318** -0.4872***

(0.1758) (0.1808)

Controls

TRADE 0.0109*** 0.0113*** 0.0101** 0.0086** 0.0087** 0.0078*

(0.0041) (0.0041) (0.0042) (0.0044) (0.0044) (0.0044)

KAOPEN 0.4609*** 0.4706*** 0.4593*** 0.4285*** 0.4391*** 0.4269***

(0.0618) (0.0630) (0.0609) (0.0750) (0.0754) (0.0751)

GOVTEXP 0.3315*** 0.3280*** 0.3293*** 0.2992*** 0.2955*** 0.2965***

(0.0300) (0.0300) (0.0300) (0.0341) (0.0341) (0.0341)

LEFT 0.0072** 0.0071** 0.0073** 0.0052 0.0053 0.0051

(0.0032) (0.0032) (0.0032) (0.0041) (0.0041) (0.0041)

GDPPC (LOG) 1.1847** 1.2398** 1.2291** 1.4971*** 1.5692*** 1.5134***

(0.5018) (0.5000) (0.5023) (0.4706) (0.4714) (0.4678)

GDPPC (GROWTH) 0.0290* 0.0311* 0.0288* 0.0236 0.0253 0.0238

(0.0162) (0.0162) (0.0163) (0.0162) (0.0162) (0.0161)

POP14 0.3386*** 0.3400*** 0.3478*** 0.3653*** 0.3655*** 0.3735***

(0.0545) (0.0535) (0.0555) (0.0521) (0.0516) (0.0525)

FISCAL FEDERALISM -6.5107** -7.0712** -6.8371** -6.5497*** -5.9886*** -5.6495***

(2.7181) (2.8542) (2.7234) (1.6212) (1.5753) (1.5405)

ELECTORAL FEDERALISM -0.3045 -0.3327 -0.2686 -3.0879** -3.1126** -3.0353*

(0.2752) (0.2638) (0.2758) (1.5688) (1.5364) (1.5883)

Number of observations 245 245 245 245 245 245

Countries 18 18 18 18 18 18

R square 0.995 0.995 0.995 0.994 0.994 0.994

Note: Two-tailed tests for significant at *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Estimates are panel corrected error

adjusted with AR(1). Country fixed effects are controlled. The constants are suppressed.

177

Appendix 11: Effects of Economic Inequality & Federalism on Volatility of Public Education Spending†

[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]

Variables coef/pcse coef/pcse coef/pcse coef/pcse coef/pcse coef/pcse

Inter-regional Inequality

COV 0.0790 0.3094***

(0.0603) (0.0707)

COVW 0.0365 0.3874***

(0.0811) (0.0664)

ADGINI 0.1749 0.6878***

(0.1369) (0.1771)

Testing Veto Player Constraints

COV * Fiscal Federalism -0.0178

(0.0411)

COVW * Fiscal Federalism 0.0111

(0.0645)

ADGINI * Fiscal Federalism -0.1110

(0.1245)

COV * Electoral Federalism -0.2366***

(0.0566)

COVW * Electoral Federalism -0.2788***

(0.0448)

ADGINI * Electoral Federalism -0.5064***

(0.1212)

Inter-personal Inequality

P9010 0.3050*** 0.3027*** 0.3009*** 0.3535*** 0.3017*** 0.3656***

(0.1007) (0.1005) (0.0993) (0.0931) (0.0754) (0.0965)

SKEW 1.0357*** 1.0511*** 1.0490*** 1.0269*** 1.0513*** 1.1220***

(0.3205) (0.3428) (0.3187) (0.3309) (0.2700) (0.3178)

Controls

TRADE -0.0029 -0.0035 -0.0025 -0.0029 -0.0027 -0.0031

(0.0025) (0.0026) (0.0026) (0.0021) (0.0021) (0.0022)

KAOPEN -0.0222 -0.0191 -0.0113 0.0003 -0.0134 0.0048

(0.0276) (0.0263) (0.0263) (0.0273) (0.0271) (0.0254)

GOVTEXP 0.0350* 0.0377** 0.0338* 0.0319** 0.0366** 0.0317**

(0.0199) (0.0188) (0.0197) (0.0157) (0.0157) (0.0162)

LEFT 0.0010 0.0013 0.0009 0.0042* 0.0037* 0.0041*

(0.0021) (0.0021) (0.0020) (0.0024) (0.0022) (0.0025)

GDPPC (LOG) -0.2345 -0.2080 -0.2568 -0.3528** -0.2839* -0.3657**

(0.1884) (0.2192) (0.1903) (0.1671) (0.1634) (0.1649)

GDPPC (GROWTH) -0.0206 -0.0202 -0.0227* -0.0252** -0.0301** -0.0246**

(0.0133) (0.0138) (0.0126) (0.0110) (0.0125) (0.0103)

POP14 -0.0323 -0.0287 -0.0254 -0.0325* -0.0304* -0.0276

(0.0197) (0.0206) (0.0200) (0.0178) (0.0181) (0.0177)

FISCAL FEDERALISM†† -0.4793 -0.5674 -0.4648 -0.4823 -0.5840 -0.8037*

(0.4307) (0.4436) (0.4494) (0.4021) (0.3848) (0.4384)

ELECTORAL FEDERALISM†† -0.0494 -0.0504 -0.0511 0.4482** 0.4117*** 0.4898**

(0.1115) (0.1135) (0.1132) (0.1793) (0.1493) (0.2005)

Number of observations 91 91 91 91 91 91

Countries 18 18 18 18 18 18

R square 0.861 0.857 0.859 0.887 0.891 0.881

Note: Two-tailed tests for significant at *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Estimates are panel corrected error adjusted

based on lagged dependent variable models. Country fixed effects are controlled. †Volatility is the standard deviation of

government expenditure on public education over three-year non-overlapping periods between 1980 and 2010. †† Values

are taken for the maximum score during three years; all other independent variables take the average value of three years.

178

Appendix 12. Variables and Data Description across 26 Countries from 1980 to 2010 (Chapter 5).

Variables Descriptions Mean Std.Dev. Min Max Sources

Dependent Variables

Social expenditure Social expenditure which is measured as a percentage of GDP is

amount to the total of public expenditure with financial flows

controlled by general government and mandatory “private” (all social

benefits not provided by the general government) expenditure. Social

expenditure account for gross expenditure along nine social policy

areas: “[1] old age – pensions, early retirement , home-help and

residential services for the elderly, [2] survivors – pensions and

funeral payments, [3] incapacity-related benefits – care services,

disability benefits, benefits accruing from occupational injury and

accident legislation, employee sickness payments, [4] health –

spending on in-and out-patient care, medical goods, prevention, [5]

family – child allowances and credits, childcare support, income

support during leave, sole parent payments, [6] active labor market

policies – employment services, training, employment incentives,

integration of the disabled, direct job creation, and start-up incentives,

[7] unemployment – unemployment compensation, early retirement

for labor market reasons; [8] housing – housing allowances and rend

subsidies, [9] other social policy areas – non-categorical cash benefits

to low-income households, other social services; i.e., support

programs such as food subsidies, which are prevalent in some non-

OECD countries.” (Adema et al. 2011, p.90).

21.20 5.04 9.9 36 The OECD Social

Expenditure Database

(SOCX). Adema et al.

2011.

Policy Priorities Sources of relative spending priority over the functional categories of

central government expenditures. Sources are set to a mean of zero.

Units are proportions (rescaled to percentage points). Positive scores

indicate the degree of which country’s policy spending is devoted to

collective goods, rather than particularized (individually-targeted)

policies (Jacoby & Schneider, 2009). Expenditure by ten functional

categories based on data recorded for the Classification of Function of

Government (COFOG) – General public services, national defense,

public order & safety, economic affairs, environmental protection &

housing & community amenities, health, recreation & culture &

religion, education, and social protection. Measured as a percentage of

GDP.

-0.22 1.39 -2.95 3.65 Calculated by the

Author using OECD

Statistics based on

Jacoby & Schneider’s

(2001, 2009)

unfolding analysis.

Continued

179

Appendix 12 (Continued).

Variables Descriptions Mean Std.Dev. Min Max Sources

Independent Variables

COV A measure of the coefficient of variation, using the country’s average

GDP per capita and the GDP per capita of subnational regions.

Regional levels specified by the standard subdivisions of countries

(i.e., state, province, NUTS2 classification). Calculation based on the

formulae provided by Lessmann (2009).

22.93 9.96 7.51 76.99 Calculated by the

Author using:

Cambridge

Econometrics,

National Accounts,

EUROSTAT. COVW The population-weighted coefficient of variation of regional GDP

per capita. Units are proportions (rescaled to percentage points).

21.68 8.60 6.10 54.64

ADGINI The region-adjusted Gini coefficient of regional GDP per capita.

Units are proportions (rescaled to percentage points).

11.36 4.07 3.71 29.12

RAI An index measure of the regional government authority that

combines ten institutional dimensions grouped into two larger

categories:

1) Self-rule: measuring levels of the authority exerted by a regional

government within its territory. Dimensions across institutional

depth, policy scope, fiscal autonomy, borrowing autonomy,

representation

2) (Multilateral) Shared-rule: measuring levels of the authority

exerted by a regional government or its representatives in the

country as a whole. Dimensions across law-making, executive

control, fiscal controls, borrowing control, constitutional reform.

RAI (regional authority index) is the sum calculated from the index

of self-rule (0-18) and index of shared rule (0-12). Theoretically, it

has a range of 0-30, but empirically the number goes over 30 due to

the number of tiers each country. The sample data at this research

ranges from 0 to 36.99 across 26 countries from 1980 to 2010. The

larger the number, the greater degree of the regional authority.

Unlike the decentralization/ centralization measures (or the federal /

nonfederal distinctions) which compress regional and local level

architectures into a dichotomous value, thus ignoring the importance

of temporal and spatial variations among them, RAI better capture

the scale and structure of these subnational governments aggregated

by country.

15.89 10.46 0 36.99 Regional Authority

Index; Hooghe et al.

(2005)

Continued

180

Appendix 12 (Continued).

Variables Descriptions Mean Std.Dev. Min Max Sources

Controls

Gini Coefficient Interpersonal inequality. Estimates of the Gini index of the household

market (pre-tax, pre-transfer) income inequality, using Luxembourg

Income Study data. Units are scales of 0 to 100.

31.62 5.60 22.83 54.79 SWIID, Ver. 5.0., Solt

(2009).

Leftist Government Relative power measured by the proportion of social democratic and

other parties in government based on their seat share in parliament.

This measure is expressed in percentage of the total parliamentary seat

share of all governing parties. Weighted by the number of days in

office given a year.

37.72 39.81 0 100 CPDS (updated August

4, 2015); See notes from

Armingeon et al. (2015).

Real GDP per capita, PPP PPP-converted GDP per capita (chain series) at 2005 constant price.

Rescaled to a unit of 100.

254.55 517.98 72.29 517.98 Penn World 7.1.

Trade Openness The sum of exports and imports as a share of GDP. 73.17 35.56 15.92 183.62 WDI

Old age population Population age at 65 or above (% total) 14.08 2.46 9.05 22.96 WDI

Labor Union Power Net union membership (% of wage and salary earners in employment.

This is also called labor union density

37.46 20.01 7.6 87.4 Visser (2013) Version

4.0.

Unemployment Rates Unemployment (% of total labor force), national estimates 7.80 3.93 1.6 23.90 WDI

EMU Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if a country (since the year

of accession) has become a member of European Monetary Union.

For Germany, the data up to the end of 1990 are for the West

Germany before reunification unless otherwise mentioned. Data for

1991 onwards covers all of Germany.

0.18 0.38 0 1 CPDS

Election Year Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if there was a legislative

election or an executive election given a year.

0.32 0.47 0 1 DPI

Notes: OECD = Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, EUROSTAT = European Statistics, DPI = Database of Political Institutions, CPDS = Comparative

Political Data Set, WDI = World Development Indicators, SWIID = Standardized World Income Inequality Database. All data summary is calculated based at time t.

181

Appendix 13. Changes in Social Expenditure and Policy Priority from 1980 to 2010.

Country

Ranking

Social Expenditure (% GDP) Policy Priority

Countries Average

1980-1989

Average

2001-2010 ∆ Countries

Average

1990-1994

Average

2006-2010 ∆

1 Portugal 10.14 25.50 15.36 Ireland 0.90 2.31 1.41

2 Japan 10.98 22.70 11.72 Poland*** -0.80 -0.24 0.56

3 Greece 13.60 24.20 10.60 United Kingdom** -1.08 -0.94 0.14

4 Spain 16.58 26.70 10.12 Slovenia** -0.79 -1.23 -0.44

5 France 21.98 31.70 9.72 Austria** -1.42 -1.97 -0.55

6 Switzerland 15.86 25.40 9.54 Sweden** -0.83 -1.54 -0.71

7 Finland 19.24 28.70 9.46 Finland -1.32 -2.10 -0.78

8 Italy 20.64 29.20 8.56 Netherlands** 0.21 -0.80 -1.01

9 Norway 16.50 23.60 7.10 Germany -1.18 -2.20 -1.02

10 Ireland 16.50 23.30 6.80 France** -1.06 -2.09 -1.03

11 Australia 11.00 17.60 6.60 Greece*** 0.71 -0.42 -1.12

12 United States 13.58 19.60 6.02 Hungary** 1.30 0.03 -1.27

13 Austria 23.50 29.40 5.90 Spain** 0.19 -1.10 -1.29

14 Denmark 24.30 30.10 5.80 Denmark -1.16 -2.52 -1.35

15 United Kingdom 18.26 23.80 5.54 Slovak Republic** 1.58 0.10 -1.48

16 Czech Republic* 15.78 20.40 4.62 Canada 2.77 1.26 -1.50

17 Germany 23.74 28.00 4.26 Czech Republic** 1.06 -0.45 -1.51

18 New Zealand 17.32 21.00 3.68 Belgium 0.71 -0.82 -1.53

19 Belgium 25.18 28.80 3.62 United States 3.01 1.45 -1.56

20 Canada 15.00 17.90 2.90 Portugal* 1.04 -0.55 -1.59

21 Hungary** 21.20 23.50 2.30 Norway 0.31 -1.98 -2.29

22 Sweden 26.52 28.20 1.68 Italy 1.29 -1.61 -2.90

23 Slovenia** 22.60 23.90 1.30

24 Slovak Republic** 18.52 18.50 -0.02

25 Netherlands 26.52 24.30 -2.22

26 Poland* 23.18 20.70 -2.48

*Average (1990-1994) ** average (1995-1999), *** average (2000-2004) due to the data availability.

182

Appendix 14. Robustness to Social Expenditure (% Total General Government Expenditure) from 1980 to 2010

Regional Disparity (COV) Regional Disparity (COVW) Regional Disparity (ADGINI)

[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8] [9]

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Robustness

+ Robust

Std.Error

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Robustness

+ Robust

Std.Error

Baseline

+ Robust

Std.Error

Full

+ Robust

Std.Error

Robustness

+ Robust

Std.Error

Regional Disparity and Decentralization

Regional Disparity (t-1) 0.0427 0.0446 0.0440 0.0419 -0.0063 -0.0072 -0.0634 -0.0531 -0.0506

(0.0989) (0.0911) (0.0909) (0.1336) (0.1080) (0.1079) (0.2303) (0.2143) (0.2140) ∆ Regional Disparity -0.0108 -0.0105 -0.0065 -0.0700 -0.0765 -0.0752 -0.1039 -0.0834 -0.0770

(0.0436) (0.0476) (0.0473) (0.0727) (0.0746) (0.0730) (0.1246) (0.1422) (0.1383)

RAI: Decentralization (t-1) 0.3242 0.0919 0.0935 0.2972 -0.0149 -0.0141 0.2570 0.0052 0.0080 (0.2424) (0.1494) (0.1503) (0.2634) (0.1682) (0.1660) (0.2438) (0.1559) (0.1564)

∆ RAI: Decentralization -0.0252 -0.0729 -0.0647 -0.0500 -0.0671 -0.0571 -0.0287 -0.0961 -0.0899

(0.0969) (0.0906) (0.0954) (0.1005) (0.0973) (0.1032) (0.1008) (0.0928) (0.0962) Regional Disparity × RAI (t-1) -0.0040 -0.0019 -0.0019 -0.0033 0.0018 0.0019 -0.0025 0.0028 0.0028

(0.0047) (0.0041) (0.0041) (0.0066) (0.0054) (0.0055) (0.0113) (0.0099) (0.0099)

∆ Regional Disparity × RAI 0.0756 0.0819 0.0790 0.0839* 0.0534 0.0494 0.2676*** 0.3474** 0.3494** (0.0500) (0.0734) (0.0758) (0.0451) (0.0662) (0.0676) (0.0885) (0.1310) (0.1299)

Social Expenditure (t-1) -0.3830* -0.5332** -0.5321** -0.3734* -0.5323** -0.5313** -0.3754* -0.5334** -0.5326** (0.1892) (0.2028) (0.2012) (0.1896) (0.2020) (0.2005) (0.1890) (0.2018) (0.2002)

Constant 13.9498** 13.6423** 13.3693** 13.6502** 14.5377** 14.2935** 15.3831** 15.3904*** 15.0061**

(5.5918) (5.1938) (5.4152) (5.2809) (5.2324) (5.4497) (5.8288) (5.3098) (5.5977)

Number of Observations 494 485 485 494 485 485 494 485 485

Countries 26 26 26 26 26 26 26 26 26 Fixed Effects (by Country) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

R-squared 0.305 0.403 0.405 0.299 0.404 0.406 0.302 0.406 0.408 Prob > Wald Chi2 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

Notes: The dependent variable is measured in percentage of total general government expenditure. Control variables are not shown here due to the space limit

(see Table 13 and Appendix 12). Statistical significance is based on the two-sided test, ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.1.

183

Appendix 15. Robustness to Alternative Measures of Social Spending

∆ Social Security Transfer (% GDP) ∆ Health Expenditure (% GDP)

[1]

COV

[2]

COVW

[3]

ADGINI

[4]

COV

[5]

COVW

[6]

ADGINI

Regional Disparity and Decentralization

Regional Disparity (t-1) 0.0403** 0.0292* 0.0803** -0.0023 0.0001 -0.0091

(0.0149) (0.0169) (0.0385) (0.0050) (0.0070) (0.0144) ∆ Regional Disparity 0.0011 0.0002 -0.0001 -0.0053 -0.0088 -0.0143

(0.0088) (0.0069) (0.0265) (0.0048) (0.0072) (0.0120)

RAI: Decentralization (t-1) 0.0232* 0.0113 0.0144 0.0015 -0.0009 -0.0061

(0.0128) (0.0181) (0.0179) (0.0081) (0.0102) (0.0112)

∆ RAI: Decentralization 0.0122 0.0224 0.0116 -0.0068 -0.0120 -0.0049

(0.0186) (0.0214) (0.0176) (0.0169) (0.0175) (0.0157)

Regional Disparity × RAI (t-1) -0.0017** -0.0013 -0.0030 -0.0000 0.0000 0.0006

(0.0006) (0.0008) (0.0018) (0.0002) (0.0003) (0.0008)

∆ (Regional Disparity × RAI) 0.0247* 0.0030 0.0711** 0.0092* 0.0179** 0.0146

(0.0142) (0.0130) (0.0345) (0.0047) (0.0079) (0.0127)

Controls

Social Security Transfer (t-1) -0.1023*** -0.0962*** -0.1007***

(0.0219) (0.0239) (0.0230)

Health Expenditure (t-1) -0.1273*** -0.1226*** -0.1246***

(0.0265) (0.0261) (0.0266)

Interpersonal Inequality – Gini (t-1) -0.0193** -0.0186** -0.0204** 0.0082 0.0090 0.0085

(0.0079) (0.0089) (0.0083) (0.0079) (0.0082) (0.0078)

∆ Interpersonal Inequality – Gini -0.0187 -0.0170 -0.0166 -0.0097 -0.0081 -0.0080

(0.0196) (0.0191) (0.0191) (0.0094) (0.0091) (0.0093)

Leftist Government (t-1) 0.0005 0.0004 0.0005 0.0001 0.0002 0.0001

(0.0007) (0.0008) (0.0007) (0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0003)

∆ Leftist Government -0.0009 -0.0010 -0.0009 -0.0003 -0.0003 -0.0003

(0.0017) (0.0017) (0.0017) (0.0005) (0.0006) (0.0005)

Real GDP per capita, PPP (t-1) -0.0025** -0.0022* -0.0021* 0.0011** 0.0010** 0.0011**

(0.0010) (0.0013) (0.0011) (0.0004) (0.0005) (0.0004)

∆ Real GDP per capita, PPP -0.0452*** -0.0450*** -0.0450*** -0.0134*** -0.0134*** -0.0133***

(0.0027) (0.0027) (0.0028) (0.0017) (0.0017) (0.0017)

Trade Openness (t-1) -0.0083** -0.0073* -0.0084** -0.0011 -0.0010 -0.0009

(0.0036) (0.0036) (0.0035) (0.0020) (0.0018) (0.0019)

∆ Trade Openness -0.0184*** -0.0177*** -0.0186*** -0.0097*** -0.0096*** -0.0095***

(0.0054) (0.0054) (0.0054) (0.0025) (0.0026) (0.0025)

Old Age Population (t-1) 0.0997*** 0.0927*** 0.1072*** 0.0152 0.0170 0.0171

(0.0328) (0.0314) (0.0334) (0.0223) (0.0222) (0.0216)

∆ Old Age Population -0.1237 -0.1274 -0.1799 0.0978 0.1045 0.0970

(0.2518) (0.2647) (0.2449) (0.1533) (0.1576) (0.1494)

Labor Union Power (t-1) -0.0196** -0.0178** -0.0176** -0.0058* -0.0053* -0.0053*

(0.0071) (0.0068) (0.0065) (0.0029) (0.0028) (0.0029)

∆ Labor Union Power 0.0294 0.0313 0.0313* -0.0027 -0.0030 -0.0020

(0.0173) (0.0197) (0.0172) (0.0050) (0.0051) (0.0051)

Unemployment Rate (t-1) -0.0230 -0.0254 -0.0207 -0.0119 -0.0128 -0.0127*

(0.0165) (0.0166) (0.0158) (0.0071) (0.0075) (0.0068)

∆ Unemployment Rate 0.1393*** 0.1403*** 0.1380*** -0.0049 -0.0064 -0.0066

(0.0334) (0.0336) (0.0328) (0.0109) (0.0108) (0.0113)

EMU (t) 0.0400 0.0250 0.0331 0.0026 0.0039 -0.0017

(0.0541) (0.0566) (0.0567) (0.0543) (0.0541) (0.0525)

Election Year (t) 0.0801* 0.0825* 0.0845* 0.0167 0.0173 0.0180

(0.0443) (0.0442) (0.0441) (0.0167) (0.0163) (0.0165)

Constant 2.5828*** 2.6482*** 2.3963** 0.4148 0.3108 0.3957

(0.8390) (0.8600) (0.9036) (0.3835) (0.3932) (0.3902)

Number of observations 605 605 605 573 573 573

Countries 26 26 26 26 26 26

Fixed Effects (by Country) Yes Yes Yes Yes

R-squared (Within) 0.546 0.541 0.545 0.368 0.3700000 0.368 Prob>Wald Chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: See Appendix 21 for the data source and description of the dependent variables. Statistical significance at

two-tailed test, ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.1. Errors are adjusted for the robust standard errors.

184

Appendix 16. Robustness to ∆ Social Protection at Different Government Levels

Central Government General Government

[1] COV [2] COVW [3] ADGINI [4] COV [5] COVW [6] ADGINI

Regional Disparity and Decentralization

Regional Disparity (t-1) 0.0091 0.0038 0.0381 0.0535 0.0369 0.0907 (0.0298) (0.0335) (0.0662) (0.0617) (0.0687) (0.1379)

∆ Regional Disparity -0.0208 0.0233 -0.0026 -0.0008 -0.0072 -0.0040 (0.0369) (0.0489) (0.0033) (0.0340) (0.0434) (0.0056)

RAI:- Decentralization (t-1) -0.1052* -0.0724 -0.0728 -0.0132 -0.0368 0.0051 (0.0565) (0.0532) (0.0676) (0.0532) (0.0696) (0.0608)

∆ RAI: Decentralization 0.0346 0.0379 0.0332 0.0328 0.0223 0.0254 (0.0433) (0.0655) (0.0525) (0.0591) (0.0813) (0.0724)

Regional Disparity × RAI (t-1) -0.0011 -0.0011 -0.0153 -0.0022 -0.0018 0.0560 (0.0011) (0.0020) (0.0859) (0.0022) (0.0032) (0.0756)

∆ (Regional Disparity × RAI) 0.0905** 0.0653* 0.1318 0.0910*** 0.1289*** 0.2341***

(0.0368) (0.0374) (0.0840) (0.0149) (0.0387) (0.0589) Controls

Social Protection (t-1) -0.3377*** -0.3432*** -0.3387*** -0.1881*** -0.1917*** -0.1923*** (0.0329) (0.0337) (0.0322) (0.0445) (0.0444) (0.0438)

Interpersonal Inequality – Gini (t-1) -0.0675*** -0.0717*** -0.0686*** -0.0176 -0.0191 -0.0222*

(0.0222) (0.0232) (0.0214) (0.0120) (0.0128) (0.0119)

∆ Interpersonal Inequality – Gini -0.0008 0.0025 0.0031 0.0073 0.0093 0.0079

(0.0374) (0.0374) (0.0377) (0.0443) (0.0440) (0.0447)

Leftist Government (t-1) 0.0004 0.0002 0.0003 0.0002 0.0001 0.0000

(0.0008) (0.0009) (0.0007) (0.0010) (0.0010) (0.0011)

∆ Leftist Government 0.0012 0.0012 0.0013 -0.0009 -0.0008 -0.0009

(0.0021) (0.0020) (0.0021) (0.0013) (0.0013) (0.0013)

Real GDP per capita, PPP (t-1) -0.0006 -0.0003 -0.0006 -0.0008 -0.0007 -0.0004

(0.0019) (0.0021) (0.0018) (0.0024) (0.0025) (0.0024)

∆ Real GDP per capita, PPP -0.0481*** -0.0487*** -0.0487*** -0.0560*** -0.0557*** -0.0558***

(0.0061) (0.0062) (0.0062) (0.0057) (0.0057) (0.0060)

Trade Openness (t-1) -0.0194*** -0.0180*** -0.0194*** -0.0096** -0.0094** -0.0095**

(0.0059) (0.0063) (0.0059) (0.0044) (0.0041) (0.0043)

∆ Trade Openness -0.0115 -0.0095 -0.0116 -0.0172** -0.0171** -0.0169**

(0.0084) (0.0092) (0.0085) (0.0064) (0.0065) (0.0067)

Old Age Population (t-1) 0.2239*** 0.2185*** 0.2344*** 0.1137 0.1144 0.1238

(0.0791) (0.0771) (0.0799) (0.1016) (0.1022) (0.1079) ∆ Old Age Population -0.4889 -0.6334 -0.5257 -0.4923 -0.5177 -0.5422 (0.5466) (0.5345) (0.5065) (0.4243) (0.4369) (0.4256)

Labor Union Power (t-1) -0.0153 -0.0138 -0.0130 -0.0320 -0.0317 -0.0307

(0.0142) (0.0152) (0.0153) (0.0209) (0.0211) (0.0229) ∆ Labor Union Power 0.1169*** 0.1202*** 0.1156*** 0.0689* 0.0701* 0.0706*

(0.0352) (0.0356) (0.0340) (0.0345) (0.0352) (0.0342) Unemployment Rate (t-1) 0.0763** 0.0823** 0.0805** 0.0134 0.0155 0.0176 (0.0334) (0.0324) (0.0296) (0.0251) (0.0264) (0.0248) ∆ Unemployment Rate 0.0974 0.1016 0.0917 0.0919** 0.0960** 0.0940**

(0.0602) (0.0601) (0.0608) (0.0412) (0.0428) (0.0424) EMU (t) 0.1454 0.1342 0.1557 0.0231 0.0245 0.0249 (0.2126) (0.2082) (0.2154) (0.1257) (0.1233) (0.1255) Election Year (t) -0.0463 -0.0408 -0.0369 0.0885 0.0889 0.0978 (0.0949) (0.0970) (0.0958) (0.0601) (0.0615) (0.0589) Constant 6.0619** 6.1438** 5.7024** 3.7391 4.1779 3.9254

(2.3339) (2.6884) (2.5447) (2.9728) (2.8423) (3.2688)

Number of observations 357 357 357 287 287 287 Countries 25 25 25 24 24 24 Fixed Effects (by Country) Yes Yes Yes Yes R-squared (Within) 0.491 0.488 0.486 0.713 0.709 0.708 Prob>Wald Chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: See Appendix 21 for the data source and description of the dependent variables. Statistical significance at

two-tailed test, ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.1. Errors are adjusted for the robust standard errors.

185

Appendix 17. Robustness to Variations in Regional Authority (Self-rule vs. Shared-rule)

∆ Social Expenditure (% GDP) ∆ Policy Priority

[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8] [9] [10] [11] [12]

COV COVW ADGINI COV COVW ADGINI COV COVW ADGINI COV COVW ADGINI

By Self Rule By Shared Rule By Self Rule By Shared Rule

Regional Disparity and Decentralization

Regional Disparity (t-1) 0.012 0.013 0.031 0.010 0.001 0.023 0.039* 0.062** 0.093* -0.015 -0.004 -0.004

(0.013) (0.015) (0.038) (0.016) (0.015) (0.039) (0.022) (0.027) (0.048) (0.016) (0.017) (0.034)

∆ Regional Disparity -0.010 -0.019 -0.027 -0.008 -0.017 -0.022 0.014 0.030 -0.000 -0.003 0.017 -0.011

(0.009) (0.019) (0.029) (0.008) (0.019) (0.027) (0.018) (0.018) (0.032) (0.015) (0.018) (0.028)

Self-rule (t-1) 0.026 0.026 0.012 0.092** 0.126** 0.086**

(0.023) (0.026) (0.027) (0.041) (0.047) (0.033)

∆ Self-rule -0.032 -0.034 -0.028 0.038 0.053** 0.056* (0.022) (0.026) (0.023) (0.025) (0.024) (0.028)

Regional Disparity × Self-rule (t-1) -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.003** -0.004** -0.006**

(0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002)

∆ (Regional Disparity × Self-rule) 0.032** 0.026 0.069** -0.048** -0.071*** -0.144***

(0.012) (0.019) (0.031) (0.018) (0.021) (0.032)

Shared-rule (t-1) -0.001 -0.095 -0.037 -0.093 -0.059 -0.018

(0.095) (0.107) (0.106) (0.072) (0.090) (0.066)

∆ Shared-rule -0.055 -0.089 -0.085* -0.230* 0.013 -0.151*** (0.059) (0.069) (0.049) (0.124) (0.135) (0.040)

Regional Disparity × Shared-rule (t-1) -0.002 0.001 -0.002 0.003 0.002 0.002

(0.002) (0.003) (0.006) (0.002) (0.002) (0.004)

∆ (Regional Disparity × Shared rule) 0.046 -0.006 -0.067 -0.389** -0.026 -1.225***

(0.094) (0.085) (0.407) (0.170) (0.211) (0.222)

Social Expenditure (t-1) -0.114*** -0.111*** -0.115*** -0.108*** -0.109*** -0.108*** (0.015) (0.016) (0.015) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016)

Policy Priority (t-1) -0.455*** -0.452*** -0.452*** -0.456*** -0.436*** -0.438***

(0.107) (0.099) (0.107) (0.090) (0.088) (0.094)

Constant 2.861*** 2.741*** 2.659*** 3.024*** 3.261*** 2.887*** 0.600 -0.151 0.002 2.248 1.609 1.465

(0.614) (0.630) (0.679) (0.793) (0.732) (0.844) (1.399) (1.364) (1.410) (1.401) (1.409) (1.534)

Number of Observations 26 26 26 26 26 26 22 22 22 22 22 22

Countries 0.625 0.624 0.625 0.625 0.625 0.625 0.290 0.296 0.294 0.264 0.260 0.267

Fixed Effect (by Country) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

R-squared 26 26 26 26 26 26 22 22 22 22 22 22

Prob > Wald Chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: All estimates are obtained from the fixed effect model with robust standard errors adjusted. The control variables are not shown here due to the space limit. Statistical

significant test at the two-sided test, ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.1.

186

Appendix 18. Robustness to Panel Corrected Standard Errors

∆ Social Expenditure

(% Total Govt Expenditure) ∆ Policy Priority

[1] COV [2] COVW [3] ADGINI [4] COV [5] COVW [6] ADGINI

Regional Disparity and Decentralization

Regional Disparity (t-1) 0.0440 -0.0072 -0.0506 0.0252 0.0344 0.0653 (0.0577) (0.0788) (0.1359) (0.0256) (0.0248) (0.0550)

∆ Regional Disparity -0.0065 -0.0752 -0.0770 0.0096 0.0274 -0.0044

(0.0429) (0.0660) (0.1292) (0.0195) (0.0226) (0.0435)

RAI: Decentralization (t-1) 0.0935 -0.0141 0.0080 0.0578* 0.0658* 0.0519*

(0.0726) (0.1081) (0.0836) (0.0318) (0.0358) (0.0309)

∆ RAI: Decentralization -0.0647 -0.0571 -0.0899 0.0313 0.0393 0.0444*

(0.0808) (0.0870) (0.0819) (0.0257) (0.0250) (0.0265)

Regional Disparity × RAI (t-1) -0.0019 0.0019 0.0028 -0.0016 -0.0019 -0.0032 (0.0023) (0.0038) (0.0061) (0.0010) (0.0012) (0.0022)

∆ (Regional Disparity × RAI) 0.0790 0.0494 0.3494** -0.0389* -0.0516* -0.1220**

(0.0801) (0.0695) (0.1502) (0.0236) (0.0285) (0.0604)

Controls

Social Protection (t-1) -0.5321*** -0.5313*** -0.5326***

(0.0851) (0.0843) (0.0841) Policy Priority (t-1) -0.4385*** -0.4307*** -0.4389***

(0.0764) (0.0761) (0.0747)

Interpersonal Inequality – Gini (t-1) 0.0097 0.0186 -0.0001 0.0209** 0.0205** 0.0213**

(0.0335) (0.0339) (0.0335) (0.0095) (0.0095) (0.0095)

∆ Interpersonal Inequality – Gini 0.0541 0.0613 0.0597 0.0208 0.0239 0.0221

(0.0587) (0.0592) (0.0593) (0.0159) (0.0158) (0.0159)

Leftist Government (t-1) -0.0055** -0.0051* -0.0052* 0.0003 0.0002 0.0003

(0.0028) (0.0028) (0.0028) (0.0006) (0.0006) (0.0006)

∆ Leftist Government -0.0048 -0.0048 -0.0048 0.0003 0.0002 0.0003

(0.0034) (0.0034) (0.0034) (0.0009) (0.0009) (0.0009)

Real GDP per capita, PPP (t-1) 0.0107** 0.0118*** 0.0121*** -0.0050*** -0.0050*** -0.0047***

(0.0045) (0.0043) (0.0042) (0.0012) (0.0013) (0.0012)

∆ Real GDP per capita, PPP 0.0258 0.0281 0.0276 -0.0057 -0.0059 -0.0057

(0.0199) (0.0201) (0.0199) (0.0039) (0.0040) (0.0039)

Trade Openness (t-1) -0.0078 -0.0069 -0.0069 0.0082** 0.0082** 0.0086**

(0.0132) (0.0131) (0.0131) (0.0038) (0.0039) (0.0038)

∆ Trade Openness -0.0206 -0.0189 -0.0209 0.0106** 0.0113*** 0.0115***

(0.0215) (0.0212) (0.0215) (0.0042) (0.0043) (0.0043)

Old Age Population (t-1) 0.6140*** 0.6015*** 0.6209*** -0.1420*** -0.1333** -0.1294**

(0.1844) (0.1851) (0.1889) (0.0518) (0.0521) (0.0520)

∆ Old Age Population 0.2948 0.1113 0.0822 0.0812 0.0810 0.0512

(0.9676) (0.9572) (0.9536) (0.2509) (0.2499) (0.2482)

Labor Union Power (t-1) -0.0328 -0.0344 -0.0352 0.0044 0.0075 0.0095

(0.0445) (0.0446) (0.0449) (0.0101) (0.0099) (0.0106)

∆ Labor Union Power -0.0234 -0.0254 -0.0229 -0.0090 -0.0072 -0.0065

(0.1468) (0.1480) (0.1476) (0.0166) (0.0167) (0.0168)

Unemployment Rate (t-1) 0.0330 0.0451 0.0438 -0.0113 -0.0140 -0.0102

(0.0470) (0.0486) (0.0470) (0.0109) (0.0112) (0.0110)

∆ Unemployment Rate 0.2116** 0.2195** 0.2174** 0.0019 0.0039 0.0036

(0.0974) (0.0984) (0.0979) (0.0233) (0.0236) (0.0234)

EMU (t) -0.0713 -0.0661 -0.0981 -0.0059 -0.0057 -0.0061

(0.3166) (0.3146) (0.3169) (0.0826) (0.0844) (0.0792)

Election Year (t) 0.1976 0.2027 0.2042 0.0192 0.0224 0.0176 (0.1628) (0.1639) (0.1610) (0.0354) (0.0351) (0.0351)

Number of observations 485 485 485 344 344 344

Countries 26 26 26 22 22 22

Fixed Effects (by Country) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

R-squared (Within) 0.462 0.463 0.465 0.332 0.333 0.337

Prob>Wald Chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: Standard errors are adjusted for panel corrected standard errors. The control variables are not shown here due to the space limit. Statistical

significance is shown at the two-sided test, ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.1, †p<0.15. The constant is suppressed, given that country dummies are manually introduced to the model estimation.

187

Appendix 19. Marginal Effects of Interaction Terms from the PCSE Estimates

1. Short-Run Effect (∆ Term) 2. Long-Run Effect (t-1 term)

Soci

al E

xpen

dit

ure

Poli

cy P

riori

ty

Notes: the vertical axis is the marginal effect of regional disparity (level or change) shifted by one standard deviation. Social expenditure is measured as a percentage of total government spending to

capture budget allocation incentives. The GDP share measure also shows a similar pattern. The standard errors and confidence intervals of the long run effects are estimated through the Bewley

transformation regression (Bewley 1979).

188

Appendix 20. Robustness to Panel Jackknife Analysis of Interaction Effects

(a) ∆ Social Expenditure (% GDP) (b) ∆ Policy Priority

Notes: The panel Jackknife estimates are presented on the full models from Table 13 and Table 14. Each country enlisted on the vertical axis represents 25 countries that

omit this country from the analysis iteratively with replacement. Confidence intervals are reported at the 90%. For the policy priority, the analysis is conducted across 21

countries due to the data availability from 1990 to 2010.

189

Appendix 21: Descriptive Statistics for Additional Variables

Variables Descriptions Mean Std.Dev. Min Max Sources

Alternative Dependent Variables

Social Expenditure Social expenditure (% Total general government expenditure). See

detail categories same as the above indicated in Appendix 12.

47.89 7.01 11.07 76.01 The OECD Social

Expenditure Database

(SOCX)

Social Security Transfer Social security transfer (% of GDP) accounts for social assistance

grants and welfare benefits paid by the general government (e.g.,

benefit for sickness, old-age, family allowances, etc.).

13.82 3.35 6.17 23.40 Comparative Political

Dataset; OECD

National Account

Statistics

Health Expenditure Current expenditure on healthcare (% of GDP). Provided by the

general government.

5.66 1.19 2.41 9.08 OECD Health

Expenditure and

Financing

Social Protection Social protection expenditure by the central government (% of GDP)

on sickness and disability, old-age, survivors, family children,

unemployment, housing, R& D, social exclusion, etc.

16.98 4.17 8.31 25.58 Government Finance

Statistics Online

Database.

Social protection expenditure by the general government (% of GDP) 14.04 3.66 5.17 22.56

Alternative Independent Variables

Self-rule This is an index measure to score the authority exercised by a

regional government over the people living within its territory.

Country scores are aggregated measures from each regional their and

individual regional government in that country. They account for a

regional government’s institutional autonomy (1-4), authoritative

competence in policy making (0-4), ability to control over local

taxation (0-4), borrowing without centrally imposing restrictions (0-

3), and having an independent legislature or executive (0-4).

Empirical ranges may go beyond the dimensional sum (18) due to

additive values by the multiple existences of regional tiers within a

country.

12.52 6.98 6.10 29.95 Regional Authority

Index (RAI)

Database; Hoogle et al

(2015).

Shared-rule The shared rule also a variable to capture the degree of the authority

exercised by a regional government particularly in the country as a

whole. Scores are the sum of policy indices across five dimensions:

Law making (0-2), executive control (0-2), fiscal control (0-2),

borrowing control (0-2), and constitutional reform (0-4).

3.37 4.39 0 15.01