224
i POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS STATUS FOR PAKISTAN: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS BY MUHAMMAD SHAHZAD IQBAL Registration No: 2012-GCUF-09408 Thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTORATE OF PHILOSOPHY IN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS GOVERNMENT COLLEGE UNIVERSITY FAISALABAD FAISALABAD (PAKISTAN) August 2016

POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

i

POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS STATUS

FOR PAKISTAN: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

BY

MUHAMMAD SHAHZAD IQBAL

Registration No: 2012-GCUF-09408

Thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of

the requirements for the degree of

DOCTORATE OF PHILOSOPHY

IN

ECONOMICS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

GOVERNMENT COLLEGE UNIVERSITY FAISALABAD

FAISALABAD (PAKISTAN)

August 2016

Page 2: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

ii

DEDICATED TO MY PARENTS WHO SACRIFICED THEIR

GOLDEN AGE TO EDUCATE ME

Page 3: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

iii

AUTHOR’S DECLARATION

I Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal hereby state that my PhD thesis titled “Potential Economic

Gains From GSP Plus Status For Pakistan: An Empirical Analysis” is my own work and has

not been submitted previously by me for taking any degree from this University

(Government College University Faisalabad) or anywhere else in the country/world.

At any time if my statement is found to be incorrect even after my Graduate the university

has the right to withdraw my PhD degree.

Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal

October 31, 2017

Page 4: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

iv

PLAGIARISM UNDERTAKING

I solemnly declare that research work presented in the thesis titled “Potential Economic

Gains From GSP Plus Status For Pakistan: An Empirical Analysis” is solely my research

work with no significant contribution from any other person. Small contribution/help

wherever taken has been duly acknowledged and that complete thesis has been written by

me.

I understand the zero tolerance policy of the HEC and University (Government College

University Faisalabad) towards plagiarism. Therefore I as an Author of the above titled thesis

declare that no portion of my thesis has been plagiarized and any material used as reference

is properly referred/cited.

I undertake that if I am found guilty of any formal plagiarism in the above titled thesis even

after award of PhD degree, the University reserves the rights to withdraw/revoke my PhD

degree and that HEC and the University has the right to publish my name on the

HEC/University Website on which names of students are placed who submitted plagiarized

thesis.

Student /Author Signature:___________________________

Name:. Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal .

Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 .

Page 5: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

v

CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY COMMITTEE

We certify that the contents and form of thesis submitted by Mr. Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal,

Registration No. 2012-GCUF-09408 has been found satisfactory and in accordance with the

prescribed format. We recommend it to be processed for the evaluation by the External

Examiner for the award of degree.

Signature of Supervisor ……………………….

Name: ……………………Dr. Sofia Anwar………

Designation with Stamp…professor/Chairman….

Co-Supervisor

Signature ……………………….……………….

Name: …….. Dr. Muhammad Aamir Khan….

Designation with Stamp Assistant Professor,

COMSATS Institute of Information Technology,

Islamabad ………….

Member of Supervisory Committee

Signature ………………….…………..………….

Name: ……Dr. Muhammad Rizwan Yaseen…….

Designation with Stamp.Assistant Professor……..

Chairperson

Signature with Stamp……………………………

Dean / Academic Coordinator

Signature with Stamp……………………………

Page 6: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

vi

TABLE OF CONTENTS

AUTHOR’S DECLARATION ................................................................................................ iii

PLAGIARISM UNDERTAKING ........................................................................................... iv

LIST OF FIGURES ................................................................................................................. xi

LIST OF TABLES .................................................................................................................. xii

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT ..................................................................................................... xiv

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS ................................................................................................. xv

ABSTRACT ........................................................................................................................... xix

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION ............................................................................................. 1

1.1 An Outline of Pakistan Economy ................................................................................. 2

1.1.1 Agriculture Sector ......................................................................................................... 3

1.1.2 Industrial Sector ............................................................................................................ 5

1.1.3 Services Sector .............................................................................................................. 7

1.1.4 Pakistan’s Trade Statistics ............................................................................................ 9

1.2 European Union (EU28) and Position of Pakistan ..................................................... 12

1.2.1 Principles and Objectives ............................................................................................ 13

1.2.2 EU’s Trade Policy: Fan of Instruments ...................................................................... 13

1.2.3 EU’s Trade Policy: Differentiation by Area ............................................................... 16

1.3 GSP plus Status and Pakistan ..................................................................................... 20

1.4 Motivation of the Study .............................................................................................. 20

1.5 Research Problem ....................................................................................................... 23

1.5.1 Objectives of the Study ............................................................................................... 24

1.6 Research Questions ..................................................................................................... 24

1.6.1 The General Questions ................................................................................................ 25

1.6.2 Specific Research Questions ....................................................................................... 25

CHAPTER 2: THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK ................................................................... 26

2.1 International Trade and Growth Theories ................................................................... 27

2.2 Brief History of Modern Trade Agreements ............................................................... 28

2.3 Preferential and Free Trade Agreements of Pakistan ................................................. 31

2.3.1 External Trade Regime of EU and Pakistan ............................................................... 33

2.3.2 The Evolution of the GSP plus Arrangements ............................................................ 35

Page 7: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

vii

2.4 Justification for Using CGE Modeling ....................................................................... 35

2.4.1 Econometric Models vs. CGE Models........................................................................ 36

CHAPTER 3: REVIEW OF LITERATURE .......................................................................... 39

3.1 Introduction ................................................................................................................. 39

3.2 International Trade and Economic Growth................................................................. 40

3.3 Exports and Economic Growth Nexus ........................................................................ 42

3.4 Computable General Equilibrium Models and the Economy ..................................... 45

3.5 Computable General Equilibrium Models and Trade Liberalization ......................... 51

3.6 European Union (EU) and Trade Liberalization ......................................................... 56

3.7 Trade Liberalization in the GTAP Framework ........................................................... 59

3.8 History of CGE Models Applied in Pakistan .............................................................. 65

3.9 Drawbacks in Previous Studies ................................................................................... 72

3.9.1 Limited Focus on Trading Blocks and Especially the European Union ..................... 72

3.9.2 Usage of Inadequate Databases .................................................................................. 72

3.9.3 Poor Quality of Limited Number of Studies on Regional Issues................................ 73

3.9.4 Single Model Repetition to Analyze Trade Liberalization ......................................... 74

3.9.5 Contradictory Results of Some Studies on Trade liberalization ................................. 74

3.10 Proposed CGE Study in Light of Past Literature Review ........................................... 74

3.11 Summary of Literature Employed CGE Models in Pakistan ...................................... 75

CHAPTER 4: METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK ......................................................... 79

4.1 Historical Background of the CGE Modelling ........................................................... 80

4.2 Defining the CGE Model ............................................................................................ 84

4.3 Multi-Country Models (GTAP Model) ....................................................................... 88

4.4 Working of GTAP 9 Database .................................................................................... 90

4.5 GTAP Standard Model: Income Expenditure Global Accounts ................................. 90

4.5.5 The Standard GTAP Model and the Accounting Relationships ................................. 91

4.5.6 Distribution of Sales to the Regional Markets ............................................................ 91

4.5.7 Source of Household Purchases in the GTAP Model ................................................. 93

4.5.8 Firm’s Purchase Sources ............................................................................................. 93

4.5.9 Sources of Household (HH) Factors Service Income ................................................. 94

4.5.10 Regional Income and Border Involvement in the GTAP Framework ........................ 94

Page 8: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

viii

4.5.11 The GTAP Model and the Global Sectors .................................................................. 95

4.5.12 Equilibrium Condition in the GTAP Model ............................................................... 96

4.5.13 Linearized Representation of Accounting Equations ................................................. 96

4.5.14 Macroeconomic Closures............................................................................................ 97

4.5.15 Data Sources Used in Creating the GTAP Database .................................................. 98

4.6 MyGTAP Database ..................................................................................................... 99

4.6.5 Relationships in MyGTAP Model ............................................................................ 100

4.6.6 Inter-regional Transfers ............................................................................................ 102

4.6.7 Multiple Households and Endowments .................................................................... 103

4.6.8 Expenditures of Private Household .......................................................................... 105

4.6.9 Constant Difference of Elasticity (CDE) .................................................................. 107

4.6.10 LES ........................................................................................................................... 107

4.6.11 Armington Elasticity ................................................................................................. 109

4.6.12 Population ................................................................................................................. 110

4.6.13 Welfare ...................................................................................................................... 110

4.7 MyGTAP Model Closure .......................................................................................... 110

4.8 Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for MyGTAP ...................................................... 111

4.8.5 Framework of Macroeconomic Accounting ............................................................. 112

4.8.6 The Macro Aggregates .............................................................................................. 118

4.9 Data Sources for SAM 2007-08 ................................................................................ 119

CHAPTER 5: RESULTS & DISCUSSION ......................................................................... 120

5.1 Pakistan-EU Trade Relationships at a Glance .......................................................... 120

5.2 Does GSP Plus is different from Normal GSP? ....................................................... 121

5.3 Opportunities for Pakistan under GSP plus Arrangements ....................................... 122

5.4 Pakistan’s Major Competitors: Challenges vs. Opportunities .................................. 123

5.5 Potential for Pakistani Imports after GSP plus Status .............................................. 126

5.6 Research Simulations Used in this Study ................................................................. 128

5.7 Results of the Simulations with GTAP 09 ................................................................ 129

5.7.1 Changes in GDP and Production of Pakistan ........................................................... 129

5.7.2 Changes in Exports and Imports of Pakistan ............................................................ 133

5.7.3 Impact on Real Investment ....................................................................................... 142

Page 9: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

ix

5.7.4 Change in Prices of Goods for Domestic Household ............................................... 143

5.7.5 Changes in the Prices of Commodities Supplied ...................................................... 145

5.7.6 Changes in Prices of Imported Commodities ........................................................... 147

5.7.7 Impact on Pakistan’s Terms of Trade ....................................................................... 150

5.8 Results of the Simulations with MyGTAP ............................................................... 151

5.8.1 Changes in GDP and Production of Pakistan ........................................................... 152

5.8.2 Changes in Exports and Imports of Pakistan ............................................................ 155

5.8.3 Impact on Real Investment ....................................................................................... 161

5.8.4 Impact on Pakistan’s Terms of Trade ....................................................................... 162

5.8.5 Changes in Household Income in Pakistan ............................................................... 163

5.8.6 Household Income of Large and Medium Farm ....................................................... 164

5.8.7 Income of Small Farm Household ............................................................................ 165

5.8.8 Income of Landless Farmer Household .................................................................... 166

5.9 Effects on Real Returns to Factors in Pakistan ......................................................... 168

5.9.1 Wages of Large Agriculture Land Owned Labor ..................................................... 169

5.9.2 Wages of Medium Agriculture Land Owned Labor ................................................. 170

5.9.3 Wages of Small Agriculture Land Owned Labor ..................................................... 170

5.9.4 Wages of Skilled and Unskilled Labor ..................................................................... 171

5.9.5 Real Return to Land of Large Agriculture Farms ..................................................... 172

5.9.6 Real Return to Land of Medium Agriculture Farms ................................................. 173

5.9.7 Real Return to the Land of Small Agriculture Farms ............................................... 173

5.9.8 Real Return to the Land of Non-irrigated Agriculture Farms................................... 174

5.9.9 Real Return to the Capital ......................................................................................... 175

CHAPTER 6: SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION .............................................................. 176

6.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................... 176

6.2 Summary of Research Findings and Policy Implications ......................................... 176

6.3 Limitations of the Study............................................................................................ 184

6.4 Recommendations for Further Research ................................................................... 185

6.5 Concluding Observations .......................................................................................... 186

Bibliography ......................................................................................................................... 188

APPENDIX 1 ........................................................................... Error! Bookmark not defined.

Page 10: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

x

APPENDIX 2 ........................................................................... Error! Bookmark not defined.

APPENDIX 3 ........................................................................... Error! Bookmark not defined.

APPENDIX 4 ........................................................................... Error! Bookmark not defined.

APPENDIX 5 ........................................................................... Error! Bookmark not defined.

Page 11: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

xi

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure 1.1: Sectoral Share of GDP in Pakistan ......................................................................... 3

Figure 1.2: History of Industrial Sector Growth ....................................................................... 7

Figure 1.3: Components of Services Sector .............................................................................. 8

Figure 1.4: Growth Rate of Services Sector of Pakistan .......................................................... 9

Figure 4.1: The Standard GTAP Model .................................................................................. 91

Figure 4.2: Flows of Income and Expenditures in MyGTAP Model ..................................... 99

Figure 5.1: Merchandise Exports and Imports of Pakistan¸ (Percent) .................................. 134

Figure 5.2: Term of Trade (TOT) of Pakistan, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent) ................... 151

Figure 5.3: Merchandise Exports and Imports of Pakistan (Percent) ................................... 156

Figure 5.4: Changes in Real Investment, Constant 2007 Prices (Million US$) ................... 161

Figure 5.5: Changes in Term of Trade (TOT) of Pakistan, Constant 2007 Prices, (Percent) 162

Figure 5.6: Changes in Households Income in Pakistan, Constant 2007 Prices (Percent) ... 164

Page 12: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

xii

LIST OF TABLES

Table 1.1: History of Growth rates of Pakistan Economy (Average Growth) .......................... 2

Table 1.2: Performance of Agriculture Sector of Pakistan ....................................................... 4

Table 1.3: Trade Performance of Pakistan (US$ Million) ...................................................... 10

Table 1.4: Pakistan Top 10 Importing countries (US $ Million) ............................................ 10

Table 1.5: Pakistan’s Top Ten Exports to the World (US $ Millions) ................................... 11

Table 1.6: The Pyramid of the EU Trade Relations................................................................ 17

Table 2.1: Comparison between CGE Models and Econometric Models .............................. 36

Table 3.1: Summary of CGE Models History in Pakistan ...................................................... 75

Table 5.1:Comparison of Imports by the EU (28) with GSP Plus Beneficiaries (US $ Million)

.............................................................................................................................. 125

Table 5.2: Imports from Pakistan into the EU 28 (category wise) (US$ million) ................ 126

Table 5.3: Top 10 Exporters of EU28 ................................................................................... 127

Table 5.4: GDP Quantity Index, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent and Millions US$) ........... 129

Table 5.5: Changes in Pakistan’s Real Out Put, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent and Millions

US$) ..................................................................................................................... 130

Table 5.6: Aggregate Exports of Pakistan, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent and Millions US$)

.............................................................................................................................. 136

Table 5.7: Aggregate Imports of Pakistan, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent and Millions US$)

.............................................................................................................................. 139

Table 5.8: Real Investment, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent and Millions US$) .................. 142

Table 5.9: Changes in Prices of Goods in Domestic Market, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent)

.............................................................................................................................. 144

Table 5.10: Change in the Supply Price of Input, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent) .............. 146

Table 5.11: Changes in Prices of Imported Commodities, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent) 148

Table 5.12: GDP Quantity Index, Constant 2007 Prices (Percent and Millions US$) ......... 152

Table 5.13: Changes in Pakistan’s Real Output, Constant 2007 Prices (Percent and Millions

US$) ..................................................................................................................... 153

Table 5.14: Aggregate Exports of Pakistan, Constant 2007 Prices (Percent and Millions US$)

.............................................................................................................................. 157

Page 13: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

xiii

Table 5.15: Aggregate Imports of Pakistan, Constant 2007 Prices (Percent and Millions US$)

.............................................................................................................................. 159

Table 5.16: Changes in Household Income of Large and Medium Farm, Constant 2007 Prices

(Percent) ............................................................................................................... 165

Table 5.17: Changes in Household Income of Small Farmers, Constant 2007 Prices (Percent)

.............................................................................................................................. 165

Table 5.18: Changes in Household Income of Landless Farmers, Constant 2007 Prices

(Percent) ............................................................................................................... 166

Table 5.19: Changes in Household Income of Rural Agricultural Labor, Constant 2007 Prices

(Percent) ............................................................................................................... 167

Table 5.20: Changes in Household Income of Rural Non-farm Household, Constant 2007

Prices (Percent) .................................................................................................... 167

Table 5.21: Changes in Household income of Urban Household, Constant 2007 Prices

(Percent) ............................................................................................................... 168

Table 5.22: Change in Real Wages of Large Agriculture Land Owned Labor (Percent) ..... 169

Table 5.23: Change in Real Wages of Medium Agriculture Land Owned Labor (Percent) 170

Table 5.24: Change in Real Wages of Small Agriculture Land Owned Labor (Percent) ..... 171

Table 5.25: Change in Real Wages of Skilled and Unskilled Labor (Percent) ..................... 171

Table 5.26: Change in Real Return to Land of Large Farms (Percent) ................................ 172

Table 5.27: Change in Real Return to Land of Medium Farms (Percent) ............................ 173

Table 5.28: Change in Real Return to Land of Small Farms (Percent) ................................ 173

Table 5.29: Change in Real Return to Land of Non-irrigated Farms (Percent) .................... 174

Table 5.30: Change in Real Return to Capital (Percent) ...................................................... 175

Page 14: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

xiv

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

I am thankful to Almighty Allah Who granted me the health, energy and courage to

undertake this research and without His countless blessings it was not possible to complete. It

is utmost pleasure for me to extend my sincere gratitude and give due credit to my supervisor

Dr. Sofia Anwar for sparing her precious time in spite of her extremely busy schedule. Her

human-friendly attitude and timely comments enabled me to complete this research work. I

owe special thanks to my Co-supervisor Dr. Muhammad Aamir Khan, for his guidance and

highly valued comments at each stage. His expertise, critical comments and suggestions

made it possible to improve significantly.

I formally acknowledge and thank a number of people and especially Mr. Muhammad

Tayyeb Riaz for his support and company at every challenging time. I am also grateful to Dr.

Hasnain Abbas Naqvi and Dr. Vaqar Ahmed for being a source of inspiration and guidance at

each stage of my research career.

I am indebted to say thanks to my Parents for their moral support and encouragement

rendered during this research work. My wife and children suffered a lot during my Ph.D.,

special thanks for them, for listening to my complaints and frustrations, and for believing in

me.

Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal

Page 15: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

xv

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS

ACP African, Caribbean and Pacific

ACCU African Continental Custom Union

ADB Asian Development Bank

ADF Augmented Dickey and Fuller

AEG Augmented Engle-Granger

AGE Applied General Equilibrium

ASEAN Association of Southeast Asian Nations

ADRL Autoregressive-Distributed Lag

CAP Common Agriculture Policy

CCP Common Commercial Policy

CDE Constant Difference of Elasticity

CER Closer Economic Relation

CET Common External Tariff

CGE Computable General Equilibrium

COMESA Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa

CPEC China-Pak Economic Corridor

DDA Doha Development Agenda

EAC East African Community

EBS Export Bonus Scheme

EBA Everything But Arms

EBS Export Bonus Scheme

ECOWAS Economic Community of West African States

EEC European Economic Community

EPA Economic Partnerships Agreement

ERP Economic Revival Program

EU European Union

FBS Federal Bureau of Statistics

FDI Foreign Direct Investment

FTA Free Trade Agreement

Page 16: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

xvi

FTAA Free Trade Area of the Americas

GAMS General Algebraic Modeling System

GATT General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade

GDP Gross Domestic Product

GEMPACK General Equilibrium Modelling Package

GSP Generalized System of Preferences

GTAP Global Trade Analysis Project

GMP Global Mediterranean Policy

GOP Government of Pakistan

HH Household

HMF Household with Large and Medium Farm

HSF Household with Small Farm

HS Harmonized System

HO Heckscher-Ohlin

IEA International Energy Agency

IFPRI International Food Policy Research Institute

IPTS Institute for Prospective Technological Studies

KPK Khyber Pakhtunkhwa

PSSP Pakistan Strategy Support Program

PTCA Preferential Trading and Cooperation Agreements

PTA Preferential Trade Agreement

IMF International Monetary Fund

IO Input-Out out

ITC International Trade Centre

JMC Joint Ministerial Commission

LDC Least Developed Economies

MATLAB Matrix Laboratory

MINAP Micro Impacts of Macro- economic Adjustment Policies

MFA Multi-Fiber Arrangement

MFN Most Favored Nation

MS Micro-simulation Approach

Page 17: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

xvii

NAFTA North American Free Trade Area

NEC Not Elsewhere Classified

NEC National Economic Council

NTB Non-Tariff Barrier

NWFP North West Frontier Province

OCT Overseas Countries and Territories

OECD Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development

OGL Open General License

OIC Organization of Islamic Cooperation

OLS Ordinary Least Square

OMA Orderly Marketing Arrangement

PBS Pakistan Business Council

PIDE Pakistan Institute of Development Economics

PTA Preferential Trade Agreement

PSDP Public Sector Development Programme

R & D Research and Development

RH Representative Households

RHS Right Hand Side

RWSM Regional Water System Model

SAARK South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation

SAM Social Accounting Matrix

SAP Structural Adjustment Programs

SADC South African Development Community

SAFTA South Asian Free Trade Agreement

SAPTA South Asian Preferential Trade Agreement

SBP State Bank of Pakistan

SITC Standard International Trade Classification

SME Small and Medium Enterprises

SPS Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary

SRO Special Regulatory Orders

STPF Strategic Trade Policy Framework

Page 18: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

xviii

TOT Terms Of Trade

TQ Tariff Quota

TC Tariff Ceilings

USA United States of America

VER Voluntary Export Restraint

VAR Vector Autoregressive

WIOD World Input-Output Database

WTO World Trade Organization

Page 19: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

xix

ABSTRACT

The importance of trade has been recognized as a vital component of sustainable

development for an economy. To achieve the goal of sustained economic growth, economies

always try to maximize the benefits of trade and especially exports.

The purpose of the study is to investigate the impact of Generalized System of Preferences

(GSP) plus on the economic growth of Pakistan. The European Union, the largest trading

partner of Pakistan granted this status to Pakistan in December 2013. The study attempted to

employ the Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model in its global version called

Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) to measure the economic gains for Pakistan at macro

level under the GSP plus status. The study also used MyGTAP, developed by Minor &

Walmsley (2013) to calculate the impact at the household level. This MyGTAP model uses

the data of the latest available Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) to makes changes in the

standard GTAP by including multiple types of household and labor.

The results of different simulations run by standard GTAP and MyGTAP reveal that there is

an overall increase in the GDP of Pakistan. The results of all simulations by using standard

GTAP 09 suggest a positive change in the real GDP, real investment, merchandise imports

and terms of trade of Pakistan while the merchandise exports of Pakistan show decline in

case of the second simulation. The main findings of the simulations, run under MyGTAP

model also show a positive change in real GDP, merchandise imports, real investment and

terms of trade while the first simulation shows a negative change in merchandise exports.

Similarly, – EBA status of Pakistan in the EU28 show an increase in the household income

with maximum gain by the household of rural Sindh with no agriculture land and a positive

change in real wages of most of the factors. However, the large and medium agricultural

household types show a negative change in household income in case of the first simulation.

Comparatively low improvement over the urban and non-farm household of rural areas of

Pakistan.

Keywords: Economic growth, trade, GSP Plus, European Union, CGE model, real GDP,

terms of trade, real investment, household income etc.

Page 20: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

1

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION

International trade theories concern with the gains accruing to trading partners on their

mutual trade if tradable goods are produced according to the principle of comparative

advantage based on their factor endowments. Economies at national or international level pay

special attention towards the production structures while considering the trade policy

instruments. Tariffs and quotas are the instruments of trade policy that affect the relative

prices of the goods in any given economy. The demand for inputs changes when the

economy changes the mix of produced goods and services. Hence, it is difficult to predict

that any given change in trade policy will affect only one sector of the economy. The

backward and forward linkages in the economy bring a change in the sectoral output mix

according to the strength of the linkages. (Karingi, et al., 2005).

In the desire of economic growth expansion, many developing economies have espoused

external economic liberalization policies. It is based on a common fabrication that countries

with less trade restrictions have fast-paced economies and vice-versa. Trade liberalization has

an inherent tendency to raise employment elasticity of economic growth thereby creating a

better impact. However, critics of globalization find a chance to emphasis that growth

benefits might possibly be unevenly spread; as a result, the impingements of distributions

could also affect the poor adversely (Krueger, 1998).

Trade liberalization can effectively be the reason of better economic growth. Benefits of total

factor productivity gained by the economies of scale alongside enhanced efficiency; have a

powerful potential to be transformed in to an immense raise in potential output. The studies

conducted by Freund & Bolaky (2008) and Changa, Kaltanic, & Loayza, (2009) show that

the growth effect of trade openness is significantly positive provided that partner countries

successful in achieving regulatory reforms like business rules, financial developments,

expansion in better education or rule of law, increase in employment opportunities labor

market flexibility, etc. Otherwise, trade is not associated with long-run growth in such

economies. In addition, due to the tendency of attracting Foreign Direct Investment (FDI)

and larger access to regional markets, liberalized trade regime becomes a place of interest for

Page 21: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

2

foreign investment prospects. A higher value of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI)

consequently, may also pave the way for a larger-scale technology transfer (Chanda , 1997 )

and inter-industry linkages (Wang, 2011) as well as total factor productivity.

1.1 An Outline of Pakistan Economy

Pakistan came into being existence as a result of the division of the sub-continent on August

14, 1947. It was an agrarian economy at the time of independence with agriculture sector

playing a vital role. The service sector scarcely existed at that time and industrial sector was

at its beginning. Currently, the industrial sector is well established along with moderately

developed services sector in the country and the role of agriculture sector is supportive in the

structure of GDP. Since last decade, the economy of Pakistan has shown a good progress in

all essential sectors.

Pakistan is a developing country and is still struggling to enhance the economic growth. The

progress of the economy for the last sixty-eight years is poor as well as inspiring. It is

inspiring because despite of great population growth rate it has reached fast development rate

resulting a decrease in poverty levels and an increase in per capita income. Due to structural

changes, the economy has changed from an agrarian economy to a more expanded

production structure economy. From country’s total exports, production contributes 80

percent of it. Although country is growing in long run but inconsistant economic growth is

still a problem. The history of economic growth in different decades can be seen from the

table 1.1.

Table 0.1: History of Growth rates of Pakistan Economy (Average Growth)

Time

Period

1950-

1960

1960-

1970

1970-

1980

1980-

1990

1990-

2000

2000-

2007

2007-

2014 Average

Growth

Rates 3.50 6.10 4.20 6.60 4.40 6.10 4.53 5.06

Source:- Pakistan Bureau of Statistics

Economic growth is a generic term, it means progress in all segments of the country’s

economy (Barro & Martin, 2004). Commodity sector and services sectors are major sectors

Page 22: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

3

of the economy. The industrial sector, agriculture sector, construction, and power sectors,

quarrying and mining, are the elements of the commodity sector while communication,

transport and storage segments, retail and wholesale trade, public administration, possession

of dwellings and defense are the elements of the service sector.

The backbone of Pakistan economy is agriculture. The contribution of the agriculture sector

to GDP was greater in early years of independence, but now the trend has changed and the

industrial, as well as services sectors, have a major share in overall GDP. If we take a look at

current situation of Pakistan, we can observe a remarkable increase in services sector GDP of

Pakistan. In 2014-15 share of the agriculture sector to GDP was 25% whereas the share of

the industrial sector to GDP was 19% and services sector’s share to GDP was 56 %.

(Pakistan economic survey 2014-15).

Figure 0.1: Sectoral Share of GDP in Pakistan

Source: Pakistan Economic Survey 2014-15

To demonstrate the sectoral importance in the economy of Pakistan a complete overview of

three sectors of the economy is given separately.

1.1.1 Agriculture Sector

This sector is a major contributor to the Pakistan economy since 1947. Its contribution to

GDP in 2015 remained 20.9%. It provides employment chances for 43.5% of total country’s

Agri Sector

25%

Ind. Sector

19%

Services

Sector56%

Agri Sector Ind. Sector Services Sector

Page 23: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

4

labor force. Also, 60% of the population in rural areas extracts their livelihood directly or

indirectly from agriculture sector (Government of Pakistan, 2014-15). The agriculture sector

provides raw material to the textile sector. It has been playing an important role in decreasing

the poverty, changing the direction of industrialization, enabling overall economic growth

and ensuring food security. Being a dominant sector of the economy, every government tried

to make the agriculture sector fruitful, gainful, and effective to increase the quality of life and

to expel hunger and malnutrition from the country (Iqbal, 2008).

Table 0.2: Performance of Agriculture Sector of Pakistan

Time Period Growth Rate

(Percentage) Share in GDP

1950-1960 1.8% 47.7%

1960-1970 5.1% 45.8%

1970-180 2.4% 38.9%

1980-1990 5.4% 30.6%

1990-2000 4.4% 25.8%

2000-2010 3.2% 22.1%

2010-2015 2.73% 21%

2015-16 2.76% 20.9%

Source: Federal Bureau of Statistics, Government of Pakistan (2015).

Major crops of the country comprise wheat, cotton, sugarcane, maize, rice and minor crops

comprise mash, mung, onion, masoor, chilies, and potatoes. Fishery, livestock, forestry are

the sub-sectors of agriculture sector of Pakistan. Kharif and Rabi are two main crop seasons

in Pakistan (Sethi, 2007). If we take an expression at the past of Pakistan, it is clear that the

country’s agriculture sector contributed a healthy share in GDP growth. The growth from the

previous sixty-sevenyears can be seen from the table 1.2.

The above table shows that the growth rate of agriculture over the years was volatile. It was

1.8% in 1950-1960; the lowest-most in the history. During the decade of 1960-1970, the

highest growth rate i.e. 5.2% was recorded; credit goes to green revolution (Khan J. , 2012).

The growth rate declined to 2.4% during 1970-1980 again due to lack of implementation of

Page 24: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

5

the policy recommendations by five-year plan (Chaudhry & Chaudhry, 1997). Agriculture

sector saw growth of 5.4% in 1980-1990. But, starting from 1990 to 2010, the growth rate

was constantly decreasing from 4.4% in 1990-2000 to 3.2% in 2000-2010 respectively.

While it remained 2.73% on average during the era of 2000-2010. From 2011-2015 it has

been growing at the rate of 2.76%. The declining trend in growth rate is due to physical

changes in the economy, as now a days more and more devotion is given to the services

sector and industrial sector (Khan J. , 2012).

As far as the percentage share of the agriculture sector to GDP is concerned, there is also a

declining trend. It was at its peak in 1950’s and 1960’s, but it started slowing down in

1970’s. Due to structural changes in the economy, industrial sector and services sector shares

increased resulting a decline in the share of the agriculture sector.

1.1.2 Industrial Sector

This sector further can be divided into manufacturing, mining, electricity generation and

construction sub-sectors. In 1947 at the time of independence, out of entire 955 industries

only 34 industries belonged to Pakistan. These industries were not sufficient for a new born

economy to face the industrialized world. By accepting this challenge, Pakistan employed all

of its available resources in the production sector (Hussain, 2005).

The industries operating in Pakistan at the time of independence were cotton ginning

factories, rice husking mills, small sugar mills, canning factories and flour mills. In 1947 it

was suggested in an industrial conference of Pakistan to inaugurate those industries which

employed the locally produced raw materials. In order to strengthen the industrial sector of

the country industrial credit and investment corporation and industrial finance corporation

were formed in 1948. Consequently, the involvement of industrial sector in GDP was 6.9%

in 1950. (Husain, 2005)

Industrial Development Corporation (PIDC) was established in 1950 to fulfill the industrial

needs of the country, especially in the areas where the private sector was reluctant to invest.

Many fresh industries were installed in the country to increase the manufacturing capacity of

Page 25: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

6

units like jute, paper, and fertilizers due to availability of local raw material. In 1958 export

bonus scheme was announced which enhanced the exports volume of manufactured items of

the country and export duties were dropped. The growth of industries especially the textile

products and agricultural processing food products were considerable. The contribution of

the industrial sector in GDP of the country improved from 9.7% to 11.9% in 1954-55 (Saeed,

2015).

In 1960 there was a modification in the formation of the industries related to consumer goods

into heavy industries like electrical complex, machine tools, iron and steel and

petrochemical. For the duration of the second five years plan performance of the industry in

terms of productivity, progress and export volume was increased. From 1960 to 1965 the

contribution industrial sector of the country’s GNP was increased to 11.8%.

Industrial performance progress, productivity and export volume was disappointing during

the era of 1971-1977. There were several reasons for the poor performance of the industrial

sector of the country including the separation of East Pakistan (now Bangladesh) in addition

to war against India. Production of heavy industries declined due to damages in the

indigenous market. In addition to that, nationalization of the industry, interruption of foreign

aid, depreciation of the currency to the level of 131%, decrease in exports volume, labor

unrest, nationalization of the industries, floods, the adverse climate for investment that

demotivated the investment and recession in the world trade were also responsible. During

that period, the annual progress rate of the industrial sector of the country cut down to 2.8%

annually (Saeed, 2015).

In order to help the economy to recover, the units of cotton ginning, flour, and rice husking

were denationalized by the government in July 1977 to 1980. Private sector investors started

to invest in large scale industries. In 1989 the annual growth rate in manufacturing industry

was 8.2%. In 1990 the progress rate of large-scale manufacturing industries declined to 4.7%

in the first half and further to 2.5% in second half due to political instability draught in

second half (Husain, 2005).

Page 26: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

7

During the period of 2000 to 2010, more attention was paid to the industrial sector, so its

share in GDP increased significantly. Due to the diversification of economy from agriculture

sector to industrial sector its share in GDP increased by 21% on average, while this sector

itself grew by 2% on average. Details of the growth rate of industrial sector during different

decades are given in the figure. It is very clear from the figure 1.2 that during the decade of

1950-1960, there was an appreciable increase as compared to 1947. In 1960-1970, when

industrial reforms were taken into consideration, the industrial sector growth was maximum.

In 1970’s it declined again to 6.13% but again the industrial sector experienced an increasing

trend in 1980’s. It declined during 1990’s but stabilized during the 2001-2015 time period

(Government of Pakistan, Various Issues).

Figure 0.2: History of Industrial Sector Growth

Source: Federal Bureau of Statistics, Government of Pakistan (2015-16)

1.1.3 Services Sector

In the modern world, service sector contributes a lion’s share in the GDP of any economy

and plays a significant role in increasing/establishing the growth rate (Singh, 2010). It

contributes 53.3% of GDP in the economy of Pakistan and 44% of labor force is employed in

this sector. This sector not only provides the services in the form of industry and business but

also provides public services governed by the government. This sector is a symbol of the

development of the human capital and good governance. It not only includes the education or

health services but also the services of transport and communication, law and order, and

environment which are truly based on quality are included. Many financial services on the

other hand, like, financial regulations which are also known as e-governance are also part of

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

1950-60 1960-70 1970-80 1980-90 1990-00 2000-10 2010-15

8.16

11.02

6.13

9.5

2.97 4.3 4.5

Page 27: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

8

it. By means of e-governance, the government information is readily available for the people

which not only decrease the time and costs of transactions but also increases the quality of

the governance. Additionally, it helps to clear the working image of the government. The

service sector of Pakistan deals with many fields including public administration and

defense, possession of houses/apartments, wholesale and retail business, finance and trade,

the insurance industry, telecommunication social and personal services (for details, please

see figure 1.3 below).

Figure 0.3: Components of Services Sector

Source: Author’s own design

During the tenure of economy breakdown when most of the revenue generation sectors of the

Pakistan economy faced a huge decline in their growth, the service sector of Pakistan kept on

growing even at that time. The cross-country data analysis reveals different stages of the

structural transformation. This transformation consists of two stages. At the first stage, the

share of industrial sector increased exactly equal to the decrease in agricultural sector in

services sector

Wholesale and

Retailing

Transport and

Communication

Finance &

Insurance

Housing Services

General Administ

ration

Other Private

Services

Page 28: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

9

value. At second stage, substitutions were implanted in the service sector and industry

whereas the agriculture sector remained unchanged (Zaidi, 2015).

In case of Pakistan, the transformation is based on only one stage that is from agriculture

sector to services. The service sector of Pakistan grew at a faster rate of 5.46% during 1975 -

76 to 2009-10 whereas the growth rate of industrial sector was 5.7%. It dropped down to

4.1% during 2010-11 and further declined to 2.9% in previous year. Figure 1.3 indicates that

services sector grew constantly since early years of independence. It was at its peak during

1960-70, after reaching its maximum point during next decade it declined to 2.8% on

average. Then again it starts increasing from 1980 and the growth rate is reasonable good.

Figure 0.4: Growth Rate of Services Sector of Pakistan

Source: Pakistan Economic Survey (various issues)

1.1.4 Pakistan’s Trade Statistics

Pakistan stands at 70th

position in the list of export economies. Trade patterns are very

similar throughout the history of the economy. It is firmly believed that exports are the

engine of the economy (Baier & Bergstrand, 2009). The theme of the export-led growth was

followed by the government. The economies with higher export growth have higher growth

rates and vice versa (Tekin, 2012). Exports performance of Pakistan remained impressive in

the past. The above discussion concludes that economic structure of the economy has

changed over the passage of time. If we carefully examine the trade statistics, it is evident

that Pakistan always faced trade deficit (Raana, 2008) owing mainly to inconsistency in trade

policies as well as of political stability. The statistics presented in the table below tells the

story of export performance.

0

2

4

6

8

1950-60 1960-70 1970-80 1980-90 1990-00 2000-10 2010-15

2.8

6.73

2.8

5.93 4.5

5.3 4.55

Page 29: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

10

Table 0.3: Trade Performance of Pakistan (US$ Million)

Years Exports Imports Trade

Balance

1985-86 3,070 5,634 -2,564

1990-91 6,131 7,619 -1,488

1995-96 8,707 11,805 -3,098

2000-01 9,202 10,729 -1,527

2005-06 16,451 28,581 -12,130

2010-11 24,810 40,414 -15,604

2014-15 25,369 45,826 -20,457

Source: Pakistan Bureau of Statistics, 2015

Pakistan’s current trade data imitates the spillover effects in the growth of both imports and

exports. Pakistan’s top 10 importing destinations represent 78 percent of the total import

share and if we narrow it to the top 5, the ratio accounted for 70 percent of the total imports.

These figures show the fact that imports are subjected to high vulnerability to external

shocks. Table 1.4 shows Pakistan’s top 10 importing countries and total import value during

the years of 2011 to 2015.

Table 0.4: Pakistan Top 10 Importing countries (US $ Million)

Region(Country)/Year 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Percentage of total

Exports (2015)

EU 6,346 5,306 6,273 7,224 7,523 31.23

U. S. A. 4,102 3,949 3,887 4,440 3,960 16.44

China 1,645 2,085 2,699 2,688 2,321 9.63

Afghanistan 1,865 1,380 1,059 1,245 1,696 7.04

United Arab Emirates 1,855 1,947 1,936 1,715 1,295 5.38

Bangladesh 908 663 680 724 689 2.86

Saudi Arabia 426 456 512 502 496 2.06

India 287 333 329 423 415 1.72

Turkey 751 609 414 366 323 1.34

South Korea 415,466 500,906 408,366 379,070 336,423 0.4

Total Exports of

Pakistan 25,369 24,718 24,802 25,078 24,088

Source: State Bank of Pakistan, 2015

Page 30: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

11

Pakistan’s top 5 five export commodities account for 60.67 percent of total exports while if

we step up to the top 10 this share is 73 percent of total exports. Due to the sluggish behavior

of the world trading activities in 2012 added with weak global demand, local energy dearth

and a tapered export base underwrite Pakistan’s high trade deficit. The energy crises are

playing a key role in increasing the trade deficit.

Pakistan’s major export destinations are EU, USA, and China with a share of 31.23 percent,

16.44 percent and 9.63 percent in total exports during the fiscal year 2014-15 (see table 1.5).

Tables 1.4 and 1.5 illustrate Pakistan’s top 10 exporting destinations and top 10 exporting

commodities and their contribution is the total exports during different fiscal years with

percentages.

Table 0.5: Pakistan’s Top Ten Exports to the World (US $ Millions)

S.

No.

Code

HS2 Chapter Description 2012 2013 2014 % age

1 '52 Cotton 5.226 5.334 4.731 18.87

2 '63 Other made textile articles, sets, worn clothing etc 3.285 3.686 3.907 15.58

3 '61 Articles of apparel, accessories, knit or crochet 2.006 2.105 2.403 9.58

4 '10 Cereals 2.061 2.181 2.211 8.82

5 '62 Articles of apparel, accessories, not knit or crochet 1.694 1.855 1.985 7.91

6 '42

Articles of leather, animal gut, harness, travel

goods 0.674 0.744 0.742 2.96

7 '25 Salt, sulphur, earth, stone, plaster, lime and cement 0.714 0.723 0.694 2.77

8 '27 Mineral fuels, oils, distillation products, etc 0.331 0.527 0.648 2.58

9 '41

Raw hides and skins (other than furskins) and

leather 0.457 0.530 0.547 2.18

10 '17 Sugars and sugar confectionery 0.254 0.634 0.439 1.75

Source: Pakistan Business Council, (various issues)

Although, the industry is continuously shifting from primary goods to secondary and finished

goods but the progress of shift is very impassive. Pakistan displays a strong comparative

advantage in beverage and tobacco, crude materials, vegetable oil and fats and basic

manufactures and comparative advantage to some extent in food and live animals. On the

Page 31: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

12

other side, data shows that Pakistan has a strong comparative disadvantage in all the

categories of capital intensive goods like mineral fuels, chemicals and machine, tools,

transport equipment, miscellaneous manufactured, etc (Zaidi, 2015). Table 1.4 and 1.5

further reveals that Pakistan’s exports are country and commodity concentrated. This lack of

diversity is also threatening the growth of exports.

An important conclusion to be drawn from above discussion is that a country’s pattern of

foreign trade, the composition of exports and the direction of exports depends on both supply

and demand conditions. The determinants of supply and demand are continuously changing

as the resources are ran down or made outdated by technological changes (and changed

factor endowments) elsewhere. Costs fall as output expands and knowledge builds up,

bringing innovations or technological breakthroughs. Changes in the size, age and sex

composition also alter the relationship between labor and physical capital and the stock of

different kinds of human capital. The outcome is that comparative advantage or disadvantage

of a country is ever changing. The analysis of Pakistan’s net composition of foreign trade

clearly points out the changing comparative advantage and comparative disadvantage as well as

its changing pattern of foreign trade. It reveals that the attainment of capital goods and

technology have been enabling Pakistan to decrease its comparative disadvantage in capital

intensive categories of traded goods.

1.2 European Union (EU28) and Position of Pakistan

The European Union has gradually expanded its external trade relations with the passage of

time. In practical terms, this means that EU’s external trade regime has been extended to new

subjects as integration progressed through the stages (Molle & Mourik, 1988). The EU’s

external trade policy regime is highly complex and complicated. The very complexity of

trade regime governing access to EU market can be seen as the number of trade barriers

operative in itself. This section is devoted to identifying the instruments of EU’s external

trade regime operative to regulate trade flows between its trading partners and examine their

application.

Page 32: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

13

1.2.1 Principles and Objectives

The external trade policy of EU is centered to various theoretical principles (Brenton, 2003).

The literature on trade relationships indicates that trade openness helps an economy to grow

faster. This openness keeps the domestic firms under the pressure of imports and the

competition of foreign firms which is not possible in a closed economy. The trade regime of

EU has been in line with these theoretical recipes (Yanikkaya, 2003).

The Treaty of Rome explains the importance of Common Commercial Policy (CCP) that

may help to remove the tariffs on international trade. The Treaty (Article 27) gives the

following motives:

The need to stimulate trade between member states as well as non-members.

The possible improvement in the competitive capability of the undertakings.

The avoidance of competitive distortions in finished goods markets, related to

supplies of inputs and secondary products.

The avoidance of serious disturbances in the member states’ economies, while

ensuring the growth of production and consumption within the EU.

The common commercial policy (Article 133) covers not only tariffs but other trade

instruments as well. So, all powers regarding export policy, the achievements of uniform

liberalization, tariff rates changes, anti-dumping or countervailing duties and trade agreement

conclusions etc, are within the competence of EU institution. Nevertheless, the mixed nature

of their economies caused member countries to use independently all sorts of instruments on

the borderline of trade policy. The EU’s external trade regime worked out over the years is

examined as under:

1.2.2 EU’s Trade Policy: Fan of Instruments

This section identifies the instruments of the external trade policy of EU, to be used to

regulate trade flows between the EU and rest of the world. The instruments of the EU’s CCP

can be categorized into tariff and Non-Tariff Barriers (NTBs). A brief detail is as follows:

Page 33: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

14

1.2.2.1 Common External Tariff (CET)

The CET of the EU was established for each category as the arithmetic averages of the tariffs

applied by all the member states. Thus, the first CET reflected the whole story of the trade

relations of all member states. The EU has effectively moved towards free trade, as in line

with the guidelines given in the Treaty of Rome. The EU’s trade regime under custom union

will help to improve the common interest areas, to smoothen the world trade, to remove the

trade restrictions gradually and dropping the customs tariffs (Reinisch, 2013).

Some major reductions in customs tariffs have been made in the framework of General

Agreement on Tariff and Trade (GATT). The so called ’Dillion Round’ of 1960-62 and the

subsequent ‘Kennedy Round’ of the mid-1960s cut the tariffs by about half. A further tariff

cut of some 30 per cent of the 1978 level was agreed upon during the so called ‘Tokyo

Round’ of the mid-1970s. The recent Uruguay Round has resulted in further cuts.

Consequently, the general level of tariff protection of the EU is now very low, about 4

percent in the most favored nations (MFN). For many manufactured products applied tariffs

the EU are actually now nil or negligible. Moreover, the dispersion has become very narrow;

only very few tariffs on manufactures exceed 11 percent (Naeem, 2006).

1.2.2.2 Non-Tariff Barriers (NTBs)

Less visible than tariffs but no less effective as instruments of trade policy are the so called

‘non-tariff barriers’ (NTBs) (Molle, 2006). In line with the EU’s policy objectives (internal

obligations set by the Treaty of Rome and external obligations set by international

institutions like the GATT/WTO), the EU has tried over the years to free its external trade

from NTBs. The various types of NTBs implemented by the EU as instruments of its trade

policy are identified and analyzed as follows (European Constitution, 2004):

Quotas: Many quotas applied to imports from non-EU members date from pre-EU times.

Other quotas have been introduced over the last decades with the objective of protecting the

so called ‘sensitive sectors’1. Quantitative restrictions (QRs) are limits put on the volume of

1 Sensitive sectors are composed of low-technology manufacturers, using relatively standardized, labor

intensive production technologies, the very sectors in which LDCs have been gaining increasing comparative

advantage. Paramount amount among them is the textile and clothing sector. Under the Multi-Fiber

Page 34: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

15

imports of a certain good allowed into the EU in a certain period (usually for one year),

sometimes expressed in monetary values. A special type is the so called ‘tariff quota or tariff

ceilings’ (TQs/TCs)1. TQs/TCs is the maximum quantity which may be imported at a certain

lower or no tariff ( as under GSP), all quantities beyond that come under normal common

higher tariffs.

Voluntary Export Restraints (VERs) and Orderly Marketing Arrangements (OMAs)2:

VERs/OMAs existed outside the GATT framework, and were, therefore, a form of a political

point of view, more expedient than quotas. They have been widely used to restrict trade

flows. The discipline of VERs was imposed by the EU mostly on textile imports from the

GSP beneficiaries and OMAs from the Mediterranean or associated countries. VERs/OMAs

forced the exporting countries to restrict their exports voluntarily and keep them within the

agreed limits.

Anti-Dumping/Subsidies: GATT/WTO rules allow the importing country to take protective

measures against unfair trade practices such as dumping, subsidies, etc. In this case, countries

are allowed to impose anti-dumping or anti-subsidy duties, as the case may be, level

offsetting the difference between the selling prices the dumping firm charges in its home and

export markets or off the negative effects of subsidies. Such measures are allowed to be taken

if there is a sudden substantial surge in imports; there is a substantial price difference

between home and export prices of the exporter/substantial negative effects of subsidies, and

the imports cause material injury to the home producers.

Arrangement (MFA), negotiated between the EU and the principle textile exporting developing countries, the

latter have agreed to a voluntary restriction of their textile exports to the EU. In practice, within the framework

of MFA, the EU members signed agreement and fixed the quantities of textile products they will import from

each separate exporting country.

1 The difference between these two types of restrictions i.e., tariff quotas and tariff ceiling is a technical/legal

one. Tariff ceilings are like a tariff quotas with the difference that the normal tariffs is not re-imposed

automatically, as in the case of quotas, once the ceilings is exhausted but is subject to negotiation between the

EU member states.

2 The difference between VERs and OMAs is also a technical/legal one. OMAs are the multilateral

arrangements; while the VERs are negotiated bilaterally. Under these arrangements, instead of the importing

country imposing quantitative restrictions (quotas) or raising tariffs, the exporting country ‘voluntarily’ agrees

to restrict its exports up to the agreed limits. VERS are existed mostly between the EU and GSP beneficiaries

and OMAs between the EU and Mediterranean or associated countries.

Page 35: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

16

These GATT/WTO rules have inspired the EU to frame anti-dumping/ countervailing

regulation (Regulation 2423/88; 3283/94; 384/96). The procedure is as under:

A complaint is lodged by firms directly concerned; the regulation indicates in detail

what information the EU requires;

Verification by the EU of the information given by the complaining party.

If a dumping margin is found to exist and if the injury has been done, the EC may

either accept the exporter’s offer to adjust prices and / or subsidize, if the adjustment

is insufficient, then impose a duty.

Other Non-Tariff Barriers: It deals with the preferential treatment over imported products

within EU market along with other treatments like safeguard clause1, safety norms, fiscal

treatment, state monopolies or public tenders, legal regulations etc.

1.2.3 EU’s Trade Policy: Differentiation by Area

The above mentioned regulatory instruments of the EU’s trade policy, with the exception of

anti-dumping and countervailing duties, were designed, at the initial stage, to apply to all

imports irrespective of their country of origin or consignment. However, with the passage of

time and with the possibility of associate agreements with non-members (please see article

238 of the Treaty of Rome for further details). The more complex application of the CCP has

been explored. In this case, the EU’s approach has been rationalistic rather than global one

(Bollen, Ville, & Orbie, 2016).

1.2.3.1 Preferential Trading and Cooperation Agreements (PTCA)

The most important regional instrument of the EU’s CCP is the conclusion of ‘preferential

trading and cooperation agreements’. These agreements provide a range of special

advantages to specific groups of countries with which the EU wanted to retain special

1 The EU’s GSP scheme has been governed by a general a ‘safeguard clause’. This clause empower the EU to

suspend tariff preferences and restore the customs duty partially or fully if the quantities or prices of imports are

deemed to be causing serious disruption of the domestic market. This could also be invoked to prevent the

interest of countries enjoying special preferences in the EU market. The normal customs duty is restored, for the

product or origin concerned, by the means of a Commission regulation.

Page 36: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

17

economic relations due to economic and political reasons. Such special and differential

treatments now play quite an important role in determining the scope and direction of EU’s

trade relations with the non-members within the regional context (Ford, 2013).

Table 1.6 shows a summary idea of a highly differentiate system of EU’s trade relations that

has been evolved over the years. It is often commented that the EU’s different trade

arrangement with its trading partners adds up to a hierarchy of trade preferences - referred to

as ‘pyramid’ of trade privileges (Stevens, 1981). At the apex of this hierarchy comes intra-

EU trade (trade between the member states of EU) that is free from all sorts of quotas and

tariffs. Next to this are the ‘Association Agreements’ that are signed with Meditatrian

countries under the preferential trade agreements. Next, comes the ACP (African, Caribbean,

and Pacific) countries with unlimited duty-free access for exports of manufactures and

(almost all) agricultural goods not covered by the Common Agriculture Policy (CAP).

Table 0.6: The Pyramid of the EU Trade Relations

S.No Countries

Concerned Forms of Relationship

Share in EU

external

Trade (%)

Population

(Millions)

1 EU Member

Countries

Treaty of Rome/ Treat of

Accession …… 455

2 Mediterranean Association Agreements 10 230

3 ACP Lome Convention 03 580

4 Other Third World Generalised Preferences 25 4000

5 US, Japan, CIS,

etc. Most Favored Nation (MFN) 38 850

Source: Compiled from the European World Yearbook.

The next tier consists of non-ACP developing countries which qualify for GSP treatments.

The EU has concluded a number of non-preferential trade agreements with Asian and Latin

American economies bilaterally (meaning no trade preferences apart from those available

under the GSP). And has also signed some regional framework agreements with ASEAN

(Association of Southeast Asian Nations), Central American and with the Gulf states. Below

the GSP beneficiaries comes the other GATT/WTO signatories which qualify for Most

Page 37: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

18

Favored Nations (for details, please see Mishalani et al (1981), Hine (1985), Pomfret (1986),

and Naeem, (1994)).

At the apex of the pyramid are EU’s member countries. The number of EU members has

gradually been increased over the years. At present there are 28 countries (EU28) - members

of the EU and many have applied for membership1. The EU being a customs union - trade

among members is free from all types of barriers.

The trade relation of the EU with the Mediterranean countries has been of special nature due

to historical, political and economic reasons (Shlaim & Yannopoulos, 2008 and Pomfret,

1986). The EU has trade agreements with the Mashreq (Egypt, Lebanon, Jordan, and Syria)

and the Maghreb (Morocco, Algeria and Tunisia) economies. The parts concerned with trade

were in the form of one-way preference scheme, which means that these countries have

tariff-free access for industrial goods but in the case of agriculture goods, they have

preferential access to the EU market. For some sensitive products, the imports into the EU

market were limited by import quotas or import ceilings under OMAs as discussed in the

previous section (Nabli, 1997). The EU has association agreement - leading towards full

membership – with Turkey and Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia. Under these arrangements,

these countries have obtained non-restricted access for manufactured goods to the EU

market. These agreements aspired to a full-fledged customs union, which has recently been

realized between Turkey and the EU. Similarly, the EU has a free-trade agreement, on the

principle of full reciprocity with Israel (Hoekman & Djankov, 1997).

Right from the start, the EU has taken over the responsibility for easy access of products of

the former French colonies in sub-Saharan Africa. After the UK joining the EU in 1973, the

schemes were extended to the former British colonies as well. The EU also has signed an

1 The EEC was created in March 1957 with the signing of Treaty of Rome with six members Italy, West

Germany, France and Benelux States (EU6). The number of member countries of the EU has gradually been

increased from EU6 in 1957 to EU9 in 1973 when the United Kingdom, Denmark and Ireland left the EFTA

and joined EEC. Greece joined in 1981 and Portugal in 1986 (EC12). In 1993 Sweden, Finland and Austria

joined (EC15). In 2004 ten more countries, like, Slovenia, Latvia, Czech Republic, Slovakia, Poland, Hungary,

Estonia, Lithuania, and Malta became the member increasing its membership from EU15 to EU25. In 2007

Bulgaria and Romania joined while in 2013 Croatia joined the camp making it EU28. Turkey and Yugoslav

Republic of Macedonia have also applied for membership.

Page 38: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

19

agreement with the ACP (African, Caribbean and Pacific) countries called the Lome

Convention. The economic structure of this agreement resembles with that of the association

agreements. The present Lome Convention applies to some 70 ACP states1 (Archer & Butler,

1996). The main provision of the agreements are:

Tariff preferences are fairly generous for ACP countries; indeed, almost their entire

exports have access to the EU market free from any tariff or quota. In that sense the

ACP countries have a more favorable deal as compared to GSP countries- which are

subject to formal and informal quantitative restrictions as we will discuss below2.

The EU tariffs preferences are non-reciprocal; the agreements stipulates only that the

ACP countries grant imports from the EU the same favorable treatment that is

allowed to the most favored developed countries. The ACP’s agricultural exports to

the EU market coming under the CAP receive, within some quantitative limits, a

reduction of the levies, which the EU puts on many agricultural imports.

The Lome Convention also provides the procedure for stabilizing the export earnings

of the ACP states which are heavily dependent upon primary export products. This

scheme is known as ‘STABEX’. Similarly, a complementary scheme to the STABEX

called SYSMIN’ (also referred to as MINEX) was introduced. SYSMIN was meant to

stabilize the export earnings of the ACP states to maintain their ‘export capacity’ of

exportable minerals like aluminum, uranium, cobalt, etc. (Archer & Butler, 1996).

1 The signatories of Lome Convention (ACP states) are: “Angola, Antigua, Barbuda, Bahamas, Barbados,

Belize, Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cape Verde Central African Republic, Chad,

Comoros, Congo, Cote d’Ivore, Djibouti, Dominica, Dominican Republic, Equatorial Guinea, Ethiopia, Fiji,

Gabon, Gambia, Ghana, Grenada, Guinea, Guinea Bissau, Guyana, Haiti, Jamaica, Kenya, Kiribati, Lesotho,

Liberia, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritania, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Niger, Nigeria, Papua New

Guinea, Rwanda, St Christopher and Nevis, St Lucia, St Vincent and Grenadines, Sao Tome and Principe,

Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leon, Solomon Island, Somalia, Sudan, Suriname, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo,

Tonga, Trinidad and Tobago, Tuvalu, Uganda, Western Samoa, Vanuatu, Zaire, Zambia, Mozambique”.

2 The EU’s GSP scheme was put into effect in July, 1971 by Council Regulation (OJL, No.142 of 28.06.1971)

which granted non-reciprocal tariff preferences to all finished and non-finished industrial products originating

from the developing countries with focus on the objectives (i) to help the poor economies in increasing their

export earnings (ii) to help their industries to grow, (iii) and to speed up their rate of economic growth. Since

then the scheme has been improved from time to time. The GSP scheme of EU is currently covering some 124

developing countries and 23 dependent territories in Asia, the Far East and Latin America.

Page 39: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

20

At the bottom of the pyramid, there is a group of countries that gets treatment of the Most

Favored Nation (MFN) from the EU. This group belongs to all non-European industrialized

countries, like the USA, Japan, Australia, Russia, etc.

1.3 GSP plus Status and Pakistan

A number of changes were approved in the existing Generalized System of Preferences on

31st October 2012 into the European Parliament. Revision to the qualification criteria in the

system generated opportunity for Pakistan to gain GSP plus status that enabled Pakistani

exporters to take the opportunity and have open access to EU markets for GSP-eligible

products. Pakistan had to face a stiff competition to countries gaining benefits from GSP like

China, India, Vietnam, especially in textile and apparel industry. On the other hand, some

LDCs like Bangladesh after gaining the status of EBA1, are also creating problems for

Pakistani exporters (TRTAP, 2013). Hence Pakistan’s inculcation2 in the list of GSP plus

beneficiary makes Pakistan second largest3 textile and garment exporter in the South East

Asian Region (PBC, 2014). Pakistan Business council has forecasted that it is not only the

textiles and garments sector but Pakistan may gain benefits from most of the products listed

in the GSP plus. The European Union (EU) granted Generalized System of Preferences

(GSP) Plus status to Pakistan in December 2013 (Awan, Sarwar, & Siddique, 2015).

1.4 Motivation of the Study

International trade is suffering from the state of instability. This is the primary concern for

many countries and especially the developing ones. Many bilateral and regional trade

liberalization agreements are in an awful situation that promotes the understanding of World

Trade Organization (WTO) being unable to achieve the expected pace of success to promote

the multilateral agreements. Some support the idea that trade should be free for all

1EBA (Everything But Arms) is a status granted to the LDCs to export every kind of products except arms

without any quota or duty restrictions to the EU market (7,140 Tariff lines). 48 LDCs are included into this

category (Kennedy, 2011, European Commission, 2011).

2 “Regulation (EU) No 978/2012 of the European parliament and of the Council of 25 October 2012 applying a

scheme of generalized tariff preferences and repealing Council Regulation (EC) No 732/2008”.

3 Some of the competitors do not qualify for the GSP plus status in the EU (India, Colombia, China, Vietnam

and Thailand). On the other hand India has graduated from textiles section and China has graduated from both

textiles and garments of the standard GSP.

Page 40: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

21

(Acharyya, 2011) but others suggest that many countries especially the poor regions are not

prepared to face this competition of liberalization (Hur & Park, 2012) and one should

consider the special conditions for such countries. So the trading rules should be based on

different stages of development (Freres & Mold, 2004) and (Baldwin & Jaimovich, 2012).

Economic integration is a process in which the independent economies gradually unify by

removing trade restrictions and allowing movement of factors of production. Consequently,

the extent to which economic integration occurs in any specific arrangement is determined

principally by the degree to which restrictions on the mobility of goods, services, capital and

labor are removed. While economic integration theory focuses on the economic gains and

losses accruing to countries as barriers to trade and factor mobility are removed. In fact, in

the case of economic integration we discuss trade arrangements that involve preferential

liberalization of trade between limited numbers of countries within the international

community. The nations forming economic integration desire to capture the economic

benefits associated with the dismantlement of barriers between their economies and the

international economy. However, the extent of economic integration is determined

principally by the degree to which restrictions on the mutual trade and movement of factors

of production are eliminated (Ulasan, 2015). The gradual process of reducing barriers to

trade, i.e., progressive economic integration, is one of the most important forces that has

shaped the world economy post 1960s (Brulhart & Mathews, 2007).

European Union (EU) under the umbrella of General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade

(GATT)1, launched the Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) in 1971. It is a unique

system of different trade agreements favorable to developing countries. The basic purpose of

GSP was to promote the efficient usage of resources for production activities in developing

economies. Ultimate purpose was to transfer the international resources from developed

countries to developing countries by using the facilities of international trade. On the other

hand, the preferences given to the developing economies impaired the multilateral

liberalization. The World Bank report of 2003 argued that the non-reciprocal system of

1 Current WTO (World Trade Organization) is modified form of GATT.

Page 41: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

22

preferences like GSP are mere a “Faustian bargain” because the damage is greater than the

benefits. (Dowlah, 2008).

With the steps to control imports, the EU also adopted measures aimed to facilitate the

imports from other developing countries not included in the Lome Convention. The most

important step taken in this regard was the provision of special tariff preferences to these

developing countries under the Generalized System of Preferences (GSP). The motive of the

GSP was to help them in solving their economic problems. With this aim, the EU established

preferential trade relations with the Asian and Latin American economies under the GSP

scheme. Under this scheme, the EU waived customs duties on imports of the products from

these developing countries (with the exception of so-called of sensitive products) and the

duties on agriculture and food products were also reduced which do not compete with the

ACP. Some 124 developing countries and 23 dependent territories in Asia, the Far East and

Latin American countries are now covered by the EU’s GSP scheme (Sapir & Langhammer,

1987) and (Naeem, 2006). The GSP system of the EU has the following distinctive features:

The GSP is not a uniform world system, applied in the same way by all the developed

countries; on the contrary, the EU, the USA, Japan and others have created their own

systems, albeit broadly on the same principles. The EU version of GSP is

autonomously granted to a number of beneficiary countries. As it is not an agreement

conducted between two or more parties after negotiations, the EU can unilaterally

decide to change it or even withdraw it completely.

The GSP scheme offers a tariff preference, in general. Exportable goods coming

under GSP are imported into the EU tariff-free, whereas non-GSP countries face the

full CET. There are no reciprocity, EU exports to GSP countries receiving MFN

treatment.

The GSP scheme is confined to semi-manufactured and manufactured goods

excluding agriculture. For ‘sensitive product’ it is used to be limited to sometimes

fairly restricted quotas.

Page 42: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

23

The GSP is in principle available to all developing countries, but the EU has signed

bilateral agreements those to which it agree to give GSP status. This scheme is also

run under the safeguard measures and social clause. In practice, some countries

coming under the GSP, such as ACP and Mediterranean countries, prefer another,

more advantageous scheme as discussed earlier; that leaves Latin American and

Asian countries as the most important beneficiaries.

The European Union (EU) is not only the largest single operating market of the world but

also the biggest trading partner of Pakistan. Approximately one-third of Pakistan’s total trade

volume is running with EU. One should keep in mind the two remarks before trying to find

out the position of Pakistan in EU (Khorana, et al., 2012). First, Pakistan is not part of EU’s

rationalistic approach that includes the “Lome Convention” or EU’s policy towards some

regions like Mashreq, Maghreb, and Meditatrian economies. Second, Pakistan appears in the

front line of the EU's global approach (GSP Scheme) (Gillespie, 2013).

The above considerations motivated this study that intends to develop an analytical

framework to incorporate the latest GSP status of Pakistan and to see the effects of Pakistan’s

GSP Plus access in the EU28. The findings of the research may help in policy formulation

for the government of Pakistan to reduce the budget deficit, inequality and unemployment

from Pakistan.

1.5 Research Problem

Joining and signing of any FTA brings changes in the economy by altering the relative prices

and income distribution. These measures cause shifts of resources among sectors in order to

adopt the structure of the economy according to the changes in national and international

economic environments. It has been proved by many studies that in developing countries,

natural resources have been related to unsatisfactory economic growth (Kanji & Barrientos,

2002). International trade is an integral part of the development of an economy that results

efficient use of natural resources in order to compete at international level. In this regard,

trade liberalization produces opportunities as well as challenges for many countries and

Pakistan is no exception. Similarly, economies get benefits through economic integrations.

Page 43: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

24

The European Union is the largest export destination for Pakistan. Recently, EU granted GSP

plus status to Pakistan. Our main research problem is to investigate the likely impact of GSP

Plus on Pakistan’s exports to the European Union and hence its resulting effects on economic

development. The impact can be underestimated or overestimated if one tries to capture the

impact of FTA like GSP plus by applying partial equilibrium analysis. As all the sectors of

the economy are interlinked, so any shock in one sector leads to changes in other sectors. So,

the main objective of the study is to find out the impact of GSP plus status of Pakistan in the

EU - on Economic growth of the country. To capture the impact of these measures,

Computable General Equilibrium models are an ideal tool (Naqvi, 2010).

The study will apply the global version of the CGE (GTAP) keeping in mind the sectoral

linkages of the economy to identify and quantify the direction and the magnitude of the short

run implications of this trade opportunity on the household welfare. More precisely, the study

intends to look at the effects of this export opportunity on macro variables, industry level

variables and household level. As we want to investigate the possible outcomes from a series

of different policy experiments, the resulting likelihood of far-reaching economy-wide

implications makes the adoption of a CGE model suitable here. The specific objectives of the

study define as:

1.5.1 Objectives of the Study

1. To develop a global CGE model primarily linked with income inequality in Pakistan.

2. To study the economy-wide impact of European GSP plus status to Pakistan.

3. To identify the policy options to minimize the negative impacts of the GSP Plus

status on the marginalized population in Pakistan.

1.6 Research Questions

Based on the CGE model, this study lays out general and specific question alongside with

experiments to help us respond to these questions. From a general perspective, the current

work is aimed at examining the following:

Page 44: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

25

1.6.1 The General Questions

1. What is the interaction between trade with EU and the rest of the economy after GSP

Plus status in terms of change in GDP, trade flows and other macroeconomic

aggregates?

2. How the trade with EU after GSP plus status is likely to affect the domestic market in

the short-run?

3. How can a national trade policy be formulated and implemented to benefit the

country?

4. How can we allocate the export revenue to maximize people’s welfare?

1.6.2 Specific Research Questions

1. Historically, how has the state acted to manage the economy?

2. With respect to trade annexes with the European Union, how is Pakistan

performing?

3. How are the internal shocks in the production process likely to affect the

economy?

4. How are the external shocks in the international market with respect to EU, likely

to affect the economy?

Page 45: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

26

2 CHAPTER 2: THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

International trade theories concerned with the gains accruing to trading partners on their

mutual trade if tradable goods are produced according to the principle of comparative

advantage based on their factor endowments. Economies at national or international level pay

special attention towards the production structures while considering the trade policy

instruments. Tariffs and quotas are the instruments of trade policy that affect the relative

prices of the goods in any given economy. The demand for inputs changes when the

economy changes the mix of produced goods and services. Hence, it is difficult to predict

that any given change in trade policy will affect only one sector of the economy. The

backward and forward linkages in the economy bring a change in the sectoral output mix

according to the strength of the linkages. (Karingi, Lang, Oulmane, Perez, Jallab, &

Hammouda, 2005).

In the desire of economic growth, many developing economies have espoused external

economic liberalization policies. It is based on a common fabrication that countries with

fewer trade restrictions have fast-paced economies and vice-versa. Trade liberalization has an

inherent tendency to raise employment elasticity of economic growth thereby creating a

better impact. However, critics of globalization find a chance to underline that growth

benefits might possibly be unevenly spread; as a result, the impingements of distributions

could also affect the poor adversely (Krueger, 1998).

Trade liberalization can be the reason for better economic growth. Benefits of total factor

productivity gained by the economies of scale alongside enhanced efficiency; have a

powerful potential to be transformed into an immense rise in potential output. The studies

conducted by Freund & Bolaky (2008) and Changa, Kaltanic, & Loayza, (2009) showed that

the growth effect of trade openness is significantly positive provided that partner countries

successful in achieving regulatory reforms like business rules, financial developments,

expansion in better education or rule of law, increase in employment opportunities labor

market flexibility, etc. Otherwise, trade is not associated with long-run growth in such

economies. In addition, due to the tendency of attracting Foreign Direct Investment (FDI)

and larger access to regional markets, liberalized trade becomes a place of interest for foreign

Page 46: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

27

investment prospects. A higher value of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) consequently, may

also pave the way for a large-scale technology transfer (Chanda , 1997 ) and inter-industry

linkages (Wang, 2011) as well as total factor productivity.

2.1 International Trade and Growth Theories

The implications for the association between economic growth and trade can be traced from

the endogenous growth theory which is also known as new growth theory. However, many

other approaches have also used the notation of new growth theory and investigated the same

relationship with a different perspective. Lucas (1988) focused on the perspective of

comparative advantage and learning by experience, to study the relationship between trade

and economic growth. Consequently, a country having comparative advantage in human

capital will specialize in producing such goods where human capital is involved. This

specialization will be reinforced with earned experience. Similarly, Research and

Development (R&D) and innovation were also taken into account while studying the

relationship between economic growth and foreign trade. The R&D and innovation were

considered as the base of economic growth when analyzing the economic growth in open and

closed economies in particular. Another study conducted by Grossman & Helpman (1991)

observed that international trade helps an economy to develop its technology base which

reduces the cost of producing things and ultimately results into economic growth. The new

technology also helps an economy to diversify the production capacity. Significantly, it is

international trade that forces the economies to perform under strong competition that

enables them to innovate and produce at economies of scale (Afonso, 2001).

Furthermore, there is a group of researchers that investigated the role of international trade in

capital accumulation and changes in the investment patterns. International trade helps the

economies to obtain advanced technology and other factors of production from other

countries. The domestic product will become an additional factor of production which due to

accumulated capital and advanced technology will be converted into advanced featured

product (Afonso, 2001). In other words, the international trade helps the economy to utilize

the domestic resources at maximum by widening the availability of capital equipment and

intermediate goods.

Page 47: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

28

The import of capital goods from advanced countries also helps the developing countries to

get access to the advanced technology. In addition to this, it is international trade that helps

the domestic producers to produce at economies of scale which helps the producer to achieve

increasing return to scale. In this way, international trade helps to reduce the cost of

production and increase the production and consumption at the domestic level (Hamori &

Razafimahefa, 2003).

Generally, it is believed that it is technology that affects the productivity at maximum which

ultimately results into economic growth of an economy. It means the imported technology is

a very important component of economic growth. The argument is further supported with the

assumption that foreign trade facilitates the developing countries to adopt the advanced

technology which ultimately leads to the growth of TFP (Yapraklı, 2007).

2.2 Brief History of Modern Trade Agreements

The emergence of “General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)” in January 1948 is

considered to be the beginning of the modern trade history. The General Agreement on

Tariffs and Trade (GATT) used to play very important role in world trade sphere since it

became effective in January 1948. The Articles of the GATT were originally agreed in 1947

(referred to as GATT 1947) and subsequently, with some revisions, in 1994 (referred to as

GATT 1994) as part of the Uruguay Round negotiations that created the “World Trade

Organization (WTO)” (World Bank, 2000). The principles of the GATT became the basic

rules and regulations of international trade. The main purpose of the GATT was to promote

free trade with the abolition of tariffs and reduction in quota tariffs. GATT promoted the

smooth flow of international trade under its clause of “Most Favored Nation (MFN)” status

(all member countries enjoy equal concessions) (World Trade Organization, 1995).

It was the beginning of the decade of the 1950s when some European countries decided to

establish regional cooperation that ultimately push the Europe to establish a continental

integration. In 1951, coal and steel treaty was signed by the Germany, France, Italy,

Netherland, Belgium and Luxembourg. The agreement was re-negotiated and resulted in the

establishment of “European Economic Community (EEC)” in 1957. It was 1973 when the

Page 48: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

29

United Kingdom along with Denmark and Ireland joined the EEC and started working on

political and economic cooperation (Winters A. L., 1994). The name was changed to

European Union (EU) in 1992 and working was started to launch a single currency. The Euro

was launched in 1999 as the common currency for EU countries except the United Kingdom,

Sweden and Denmark. EU has a complex system of preferential and non- preferential trade

agreements (For more details please see chapter 1). The EEC inspired the other regions of the

world to establish PTAs (Preferential Trade Agreements) and FTAs (Free Trade

Agreements). The EU has established different bilateral agreements with developed

countries, Meditatrian countries, African Caribbean and Pacific (ACP) countries and

developing countries (Winters, 2016).

It was the EEC that inspired the developing countries in Africa, Central and South America

and the Pacific to establish their own regional agreements. The most common agreements

were the Central American Common Market and the East African Community that collapsed

by the end of the 1970s (de Melo, Panagariya, & Rodrik, 1993). During the last decade of

20th

century, EU has signed a number of bilateral agreements with countries in the Middle

East (Israel, Jordan, Lebanon and the Palestinian Authority) as well as in North Africa

(Egypt, Tunisia, Algeria and Morocco) aiming to form a free trade area similar to the “North

American Free Trade Area (NAFTA)” (Ojeda, Sherman, & Lewis, 1995).

It was 1985 when the United States shifted its approach of multilateralism to bilateralism by

signing a free trade agreement with Israel and a more comprehensive agreement with Canada

in 1988. This Canada-US free trade agreement then converted to NAFTA in 1994 with the

inclusion of Mexico (Ojeda, Sherman, & Lewis, 1995). Old arrangements in Latin America

i.e. the “Andean Community” and the “Central American Common Market” were re-

established with a broader vision. The most common example is the agreement between the

Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and Uruguay, known as MERCOSUR which started working as

custom union.

This wave of regionalism also affected the African countries resulting into the establishment

of the “Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA)” with focus to realize

Page 49: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

30

the economies as part of Africa, “the East African Community (EAC)” that includes the

Kenya, United Republic of Tanzania and the Uganda with focus to cooperate in

industrialization and economic development, “Economic Community of West African

States (ECOWAS)” with similar objectives and the “Southern African Development

Community (SADC)”, an attempt to integrate the South Africa into regional economies . The

focus of all these agreements was the maximum economic cooperation (Osman R. M., 2011).

It was 1983 when New Zealand and Australia decided to sign a free trade agreement known

as “Closer Economic Relation (CER).” The purpose of this agreement was to deepen the

trade relations between both economies. This agreement helped the New Zealand economy to

access better dairy products from Australia and Australia achieved the goal to maximize the

export of dairy products to New Zealand. There is no tariff or quantitative restriction exists

and the goods and services between both countries can move freely (Scollay, Findlay, &

Kaufmann, 2010).

In Asia, the most prominent example is the Association of Southeast Asian Nations

(ASEAN) which was established in 1967 to cooperate with member countries during crises

and to increase the economic cooperation especially in the fields of agriculture, financial

services, tourism and science and technology. Currently, the ASEAN community consists of

ten member countries including the Indonesia, Thailand, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore,

Vietnam, Myanmar, Cambodia, Laos and the Brunei and all are working to promote peace,

prosperity and research (Hansakul, 2013).

The second important free trade agreement is known as South Asian Free Trade Area

(SAFTA). SAFTA is a trade agreement among SAARC (South Asian Association for

Regional Cooperation) countries. SAFTA was initially signed in 1993 as “South Asian

Preferential trading Arrangement (SAPTA)” and started working in 1995 with aim to

promote peace and economic cooperation among member states i.e. Afghanistan,

Bangladesh, Bhutan, India, Maldives, Nepal, Pakistan and Sri Lanka (Srinivasan, Kalaivani,

& Ibrahim, 2011)

Page 50: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

31

2.3 Preferential and Free Trade Agreements of Pakistan

The terms PTA (Preferential Trade Agreement) and FTA (Free Trade Agreement) are same

in a sense that they both deal with the ease of international trade. The term FTA is used in

when two or more economies sign an agreement of trade liberalization to facilitate each other

in the flow of goods and services and investment. The economies integrate with each other

by removing trade barriers while the PTA aims to reduce the tariff not completely abolish it

in order to ease the international trade (Baldwin & Freund, 2011).

Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) became famous globally after the failure of WTO in

resolving the issues of international trade flows. Pakistan is a developing economy with the

aim to grow its international trade relationships. For this purpose, the country has signed

different bilateral and multilateral trade agreements with the economies of the South Asian

region as well as in the regions of Europe, Latin American, South East Asia and Asia Pacific.

The purpose of signing different PTAs/FTAs was to facilitate the trade with different

economies around the globe and stimulate the investment opportunities for improvement in

the exports and economic growth (Taniguchi & Yanovic, 2007). Pakistan is also adopting an

export-led development policy for which the market share at international level is crucial and

to get such market entry Pakistan had to establish such preferential and free trade

arrangements.

The FTA between Pakistan and China holds a great significance as it offers a great

opportunity to the goods and services. The FTA further enables the manufacturers in Pakistan

to have access to machinery and chemicals at zero tariff rates. This free trade agreement is

covering the areas of investment and trade in goods and services. The agreement of trade in

goods and investment was signed in 2006 while the agreement on trade in services was

signed in 2009 (Kataria & Naveed, 2014).

China has market access in Pakistan in 11 sectors and 107 sub-sectors while China has given

access to Pakistan in 11 Sectors and 133 sub-sectors. This agreement provides full security to

Chinese investment and China did a lot of investment in Pakistan using Pakistan’s cheap and

Page 51: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

32

hardworking labor force. Pakistan also provides a lot of investment opportunities to China

(Kataria & Naveed, 2014).

Afghanistan is Pakistan’s second largest trading partner following USA. So Pakistan is

perusing to have an FTA with Afghanistan, Iran, and Turkey while it already had a PTA with

Iran in 2006, under this agreement Pakistan offered a concession of 338 tariff lines to Iran

and Iran on the other hand offered 309 concession of tariff lines to Pakistan. Pakistan also

signed PTA with Indonesia and Morocco, being a Muslim country the PTA agreement

between Indonesia and Pakistan helped to further strengthened the economic integration and

trade between both countries. This agreement was signed in 2012 (Kataria & Naveed, 2014).

The operation of PTA between Pakistan and Indonesia follows the mutual recognition

agreement on plants and Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary (SPS) measures. This agreement

considers Pakistan as pest free area for kinnow and allows its entry to Indonesia through the

port of Jakarta which assists Pakistan to increase the market share of its agriculture products

in Indonesia (Kawai & Wignaraja, 2011).

Pakistan and Morocco signed the PTA and FTA negotiations jointly in 2008 in the first

session of Joint Ministerial Commission (JMC) to improve commercial co-operation and

heighten their trade. Pakistan and Singapore free trade agreement was announced in May

2005 and since then three rounds of negotiations have been held. Pakistan-Singapore FTA

helped Pakistan to get access to service sector in Singapore and improved it’s exportation of

manpower and also help to enhance the market share of SME’s (Kawai & Wignaraja, 2011).

Pakistan signed a trade agreement on June 12, 2005, with fellow SAARC nation, Sri Lanka.

According to this agreement, both countries arranged to give preferential access to each

partner’s export goods by giving away tariff concessions. Sri Lanka enjoys the duty-free

access to the Pakistani market for its 206 products including tea, rubber, and coconut. On the

other hand, Sri Lanka has granted duty-free access to 102 Pakistani products including

basmati rice, oranges, and engineering products. This agreement includes the removal of

Page 52: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

33

tariffs, para-tariffs, safeguard measures and settlements of disputes etc. (Shaikh & Rahpoto,

2009)

Pakistan and Malaysia also signed free trade agreement on November 8, 2007, at Kuala

Lumpur Malaysia, the first bilateral agreement between the two members of Organization of

Islamic Cooperation (OIC). Pakistan is one of the major importers of palm oil after China

and after this free trade agreement there was 99.5 percent increase in the importation of palm

oil from Malaysia due to lower duty on Malaysia palm oil but it has been found that the trade

balance is in favor of Malaysia, not Pakistan (Butt, 2006).

Pakistan and Mauritius also signed preferential trade agreements on July 2007 in Mauritius in

which Mauritius has given a concession to Pakistan on 102 items and Pakistan in turn gave

concession on130 items and this bilateral agreement was in favor of Pakistan as it can

augment its food exports. The final objective of this preferential trade agreement was to give

a path to free trade agreement which includes all trade, products, and services but this has not

been occurred yet (Butt, 2006).

The most important trade agreement for Pakistan that was signed between Pakistan and

European Union (EU) on December 2013 is GSP Plus. Although Pakistan is enjoying trade

relationships with EU under the umbrella of Generalized System of Preference (GSP) ever

since its emergence in 1971. The current status grants duty-free and quota-free access to most

of the Pakistani products (Naeem, 2006).

2.3.1 External Trade Regime of EU and Pakistan

The European Union has gradually expanded its external trade relations with the passage of

time. In practical terms, this means that EU’s external trade regime has been extended to new

subjects as integration progressed through the stages (Molle & Mourik, 1988). The EU’s

external trade policy regime is highly complex and complicated. The very complexity of

trade regime governing access to EU market can be seen as the number of trade barriers

operative in itself.

Page 53: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

34

The rapid increase in trade and economic relations of Pakistan with EU is starting in 1973

when UK becomes the part of EEC. By the analysis of EU’s trade statement, it point outs two

closely related points:

The agreement explains the continuation and extension of trade with

developing countries based on regions. Lome Convention and association

agreements with the countries of Mediterranean and East and West.

To apply the policy at world level, which consists of an instrument like GSP

agreement, provision of financial and technical support, food aid, etc.

Commercial Cooperation Agreement was signed between Pakistan and EU in June 1976 gave

trade benefits to Pakistan. The agreement provided the opportunity to Pakistan to build a

strong trade and economic relationship with EU. This agreement was limited to trade only. In

1986, a new agreement was signed under the name of “Commercial Cooperation and

Economic Development”1.This agreement was in the favor of both as it was broader in vision

and almost covered all the aspects including economic, scientific, technology and financial

cooperation (Naeem, Trade Implications for Pakistan in the European Union Market in the

Milieu of EU Enlargement from EU15 to EU25, 2006). The third agreement between

Pakistan and EU was signed on November 24, 2001 with some reduced financial benefits to

Pakistan but covered more areas including joint declaration of intellectual, industrial and

commercial property and taking the responsibility by Pakistan to arrange re-admission

agreements with the member states of the EU (European Constitution, 2004).

EU is considered as the biggest trading partner of Pakistan. For instance, during 2014-15,

31.23% of the total trade of Pakistan was with EU nations while the USA is left behind with

16.44%. Garments, cotton, textile are considered the major exporting sectors of Pakistan. To

conclude, since 1971, Pakistan is the country that takes most of the benefit of this EU GSP

agreement, and all the instruments written in the agreement has been applied to the Pakistan.

Besides the benefits, the position of Pakistan is not very strong in the hierarchy set by the

1 The agreement was signed by both the countries will automatically be renewed after its expiry. But if any

party in the agreement wants to cancel it, that party have to inform the authorized body

Page 54: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

35

EU’s agreements of trade preferences, as compared to the ACP and Mediterranean countries

(Sincai, 2014).

2.3.2 The Evolution of the GSP plus Arrangements

The standard GSP provides generous access to the developing countries into the EU through

partial or full tariff relieves. During October 2012, the European parliament made some

amendments into the standard GSP through the establishment of European Parliament's

Regulation No. 978/2012. New scheme is called GSP plus that allows considerable growth to

that country which is not economecally strong and complies with its binding undertakings.

The beneficiary country has to implement and maintain 27 core international conventions

that are related to human and labour rights, good governance and environment protection.

The countries, already being benefited by this agreement have to prove themselves by

meeting the conditions written on the agreement. That specific country has also to meet the

standards of “rules of origin” which means that if a particular product is made in multiple

stages and the inputs are imported from different countries, it has to meet the rigid

requirements (Cuyvers & Soeng, 2013).

Initially, the countries used to graduate (exclude from the preferential treatment list) from the

beneficiary list after achieving certain diversification in export items. The latest scheme of

GSP plus has abolished this condition of graduating by sections. Moreover, a country may

apply for GSP plus status at any time during a year instead of waiting for every month. The

preference margin between normal GSP and GSP plus is quite significant and rates of

utilization of this margin are quite high in GSP plus scheme (Onguglo, 2010).

2.4 Justification for Using CGE Modeling

By using various modeling methods the effect of tariff reduction on the four regions of

Pakistan can be calculated. Econometric models, I-O model and CGE models, these three

models can be used to calculate the effects of policy options. Dick et al. (1983), Shoven &

Whalley (1984), Wong (1990), Bandara (1991), Baldwin and Venables (1995) and Karingi

(1998) all identified in their studies that all the techniques have their own strengths and

Page 55: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

36

weaknesses. In the light of these studies, it is easy to predict which technique is most useful

in a given situation as compared to others.

2.4.1 Econometric Models vs. CGE Models

Econometric models are more useful when results of a policy are affecting a specific industry

(Chow, 1977). Econometric approaches are very simple. However, these models are not

based on neoclassical microeconomic theories so they may not focus on the consumer

behavior, utility, and profit maximization (Lucas R., 1976). Moreover, the econometric

technique is based on large time series, cross-sectional and panel data especially which are

not very easy to find particularly in a less developed country and at micro level. The data

limitations make the econometric models less useful when studying the inter-sectoral

linkages. A brief summary of comparison between CGE models and Econometric Models is

given below.

Table 2.1: Comparison between CGE Models and Econometric Models

Econometric Models CGE Models

They are not based on neoclassical

microeconomics theories.

CGE models are based on equilibrium

theory.

Econometric techniques are more helpful

when feedback effects to a particular

industry.

CGE techniques are more helpful when the

effect of feedback is more in general or for

the whole economy.

Econometric models are stochastic in

nature.

CGE models are deterministic in nature.

They are mainly based on macroeconomic

formation.

They are mainly based on macroeconomic

structure.

Long-term time series data requirements

reduce the chances to identify inter-sectoral

linkages.

These techniques are able to identify the

linkages between industries and

commodities within the country or between

the country and the world.

It requires long term cross-sectional data

which is not easy to find.

While CGE (comparative static) models

require only standard year only.

Page 56: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

37

Statistical testing is there in econometric

techniques.

CGE techniques don’t have statistical

testing.

Source: Dick et al. (1984); Shoven & Whalley (1984); Bandara (1991); Baldwin & Venables

(1995); Karingi & Siriwardana (2003); and Butt (2006)

CGE models are based on equilibrium theory which is helpful when a situation arises due to

changes in tax and trade policy. These models can establish the linkages between

commodities, industries in the domestic economy or with the whole world. Bandara (1989, p.

45) uses this argument to find the impact of tariff cuts.

“To analyze the detailed effects of tariffs one must examine quantitatively the

chain of events that take place when tariffs are cut, as follows. A cut in tariffs

alters consumption patterns in a tariff-reducing country. Then, imports rise

and the relative prices of imports and domestic goods change. Consequently,

changes in tariffs cannot be considered in isolation. Their repercussions are

propagated throughout the economy as they affect production, investment and

consumption decisions. Clearly, a partial equilibrium approach cannot fully

capture this chain of events and their interactions.”

CGE model is more reliable than to the econometric model in order to find out the effects of

GSP plus the status of Pakistan in the EU on the economy as a whole. Because CGE model

requires only benchmark year data while econometric model requires long term cross-

sectional data which is very difficult. So there is no doubt in it that CGE model is more

suitable to identify the effects of tariffs cut off EU on Pakistan’s economy as compared to the

econometric model.

Considering the case of Pakistan, there is not known single study which has focused on Free

Trade Agreement (FTA) between Pakistan and any regional block. There is only one study

conducted by Shaikh &Rahpoto (2009) which calculated the impact of SAFTA on Pakistan

economy being part of it. Similarly, the GTAP used by previous studies did not represent

Page 57: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

38

Pakistan as a separate country. This study is using the latest version of GTAP (9), to

calculate the impact of existing EU trade agreements on Pakistan economy.

Page 58: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

39

3 CHAPTER 3: REVIEW OF LITERATURE

3.1 Introduction

It passed more than two decades that International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank

has engaged the international economic community with the worldwide campaign of

economic reforms through the economic stabilization and structural adjustment programs.

However, the debate shifted its focus to international economic integration through fair

international competition and trade liberalization from structural adjustment and stabilization

(Hassan, 1997).

International economics is considered to be the oldest study branch of the economics

discipline. Economic activities within an economy and between two economies have been

accepted as separate issues. Both types of the economies have differences not only in

customs, population and consumptions patterns but also the trading economies have tax and

currency system for the traded products. The ancient problems not only exist today but also

many other problems joined them (Hogendorn & Brown, 1979).

Nature has distributed the resources in such a way that some goods are available in one

community and other community may have some other goods. For example, every country

needs oil to run the economy but very few countries are self-sufficient, so others have to

import it. These sorts of patterns of trade hardly need explanation. Similarly, many

commodities that are traded among different countries are produced at many places, so the

patterns of trade are unique according to the availability and nature of land and labor. These

factors directly affect the cost of production that provides acompetitive edge on the other

countries (Naqvi, 2010).

Changes in the worldwide economic, political and legal framework not only brought many

opportunities but also restrictions to many economies of the world. Especially the

development during Uruguay Round of negotiations on the General Agreement on Tariffs

and Trade (GATT) that focused more on market orientation rather following the traditional

approach of control and central planning. Similarly, expansion of European Union (EU)

brought many threats and opportunities for the developing economies. Different agreements

Page 59: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

40

of the EU are aimed to promote the economic activities in the developing world (Naeem,

2006).

The objective of this chapter is to investigate the literature to come up with a methodology to

analyze the impact of trade agreements on economic development, household welfare, and

inequality. It is suggested by trade-related literature that there exists a relationship between

trade policy and poverty. Various researchers have used different conceptual and empirical

approaches to examine this relationship. These approaches may have their own weaknesses,

which could eventually affect the results. Therefore, the empirical evidence should be viewed

in the light of the strengths and the flaws of the adopted conceptual and empirical approach.

This research is focused on Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) modeling approach.

CGE model is an empirical counterpart of the well-known theoretical general equilibrium

model, which has become the most widely applied counterfactual analytical tool.

3.2 International Trade and Economic Growth

A lot of discussions have been made on the role of trade liberalization in poverty reduction.

Many researchers tried to investigate the potential impacts of trade liberalization on the

development and poverty reduction in developing economies. Similarly, classical and neo-

classical trade theories also forecast that trade liberalization increases the general welfare

level in an economy but these theories failed to explain the links between welfare and trade

liberalization (Michaely, 1977). In this context, a two country, two goods and two factors

theory presented by Heckscher & Ohlin (1919) states that if an economy desires to increase

the exports and production, it has to focus on enhancing the productivity. Even today, the

developing economies have abundant unskilled labor force and that can be compensated by

increasing the trade and price of produced goods (Paudel & Perera, 2009).

Modern theories of trade suggest that trade liberalization brings efficiency through

economies of scale, technological improvements, access to the information and spillover

effects. It is unfortunate that these theories fail to explain the effects of liberalization on non-

tradable and non-homogenous goods along with some explicit factors or segments of the

labor market (Winters, 2002).

Page 60: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

41

One can find a large number of studies that have investigated the impact of foreign trade on

the economic growth of an economy. Grossman & Helpman (1991); Frankel & Romer

(1999); Rodriguez & Rodrik (2000); Wacziarg & Welch (2003) and Alcala & Ciccone

(2004) consider the foreign trade as the prime factor of economic growth. Similarly, the work

of Sachs & Warner (1995) concluded that the economies with free trade experienced higher

growth rate as compared to the economies without free trade. Edwards (1998) attempted to

investigate the link between Total Factor Productivity (TFP) and foreign trade in 93 countries

and concluded that the growth rate of TFP is higher in the open economies as compared to

the economies with limited trade openness.

It has been observed that the role of exports in economic growth has been studied possibly

because of the rapidly growing role of export-led growth strategies adopted by many

countries. A group of researchers including Krueger (1998; Chenery (1979); Tyler (1981);

Kavoussi (1984); Balassa (1985); Ram (1985); Fosu (1990); and Salvatore & Hacter (1991)

argues that it is economic growth that enhances the exports while others like Kwan &

Cotsomitis (1990); Ahmad & Kwan (1991); Yaghmaian (1994)suggest that it is export that

results into increased economic growth. The results provided by the empirical study

conducted by Vohra (2001) suggest that export influences the economic growth in an

economy only when it achieves a certain level of economic development. Similarly, Subasat

(2002) suggested that the middle-income country in influenced greater by the export-led

growth strategy than a country with less focus on this strategy. The study further discovered

that the middle-income country grows faster with growth-led strategy than low and high-

income countries.

Reductions of discriminatory tariffs also change the terms of trade not only in the domestic

country but also in the trading partners and other regional group members. Mundell (1964)

investigated the impact of discriminatory tariff reductions on the terms of trade, assuming the

availability of substitutes, discovered that the tariff reduction by a regional member not only

improves the terms of trade in that country but also brings benefits for the other member

countries. He further concluded that higher tariff rates before liberation bring greater gains

for the partners in terms of trade.

Page 61: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

42

3.3 Exports and Economic Growth Nexus

The relationship between economic growth and foreign trade is generally studied by keeping

in mind that it is exports that help to grow an economy (Emery, 1967). The assumption that

exports lead to economic growth has been studied by many researchers. There are mainly

two reasons for the development of studies on exports-led growth. The new growth theory is

one of them that help to build a model to calculate the impact of growth factors on the export

performance of an economy. The second reason is the new developments in the econometric

tests such as co-integration and causality. These tests are widely used to calculate the

relationship between trade and economic growth (Lee & Huang, 2002).

Redding & Venables (2004) classified determinants of export into two groups internal and

external determinants in order to investigate them. They measured the effects of geological

area, overseas and domestic market coverage and bureaucratic qualities on export

performance of sub-Saharan Africa. According to this study the geological region of a

country directly affect its trade with the overseas market and trade performance is determined

by overseas coverage of a country. High overseas market coverage results in superior export

performance. According to this study, two factors influence export performance firstly

geological location of the country, secondly population of oversea countries that are adjacent

to your border. Finally bureaucratic abilities or institutional factors also influence trade with

foreign markets.

Din et al. (2009) discussed the decisive factors of firm level Pakistan’s export performance

according to the survey organized on four export segments: “leather products, textile, and

apparel, fisheries and agri-food”. The study applied practical OLS technique. The study

calculated contact of every illustrative inconsistent variable. The findings indicated that level

of investment in client-oriented technology, executive capability and valuable position of

organizations had positive impact on the export act. At the same time lack of certification to

fulfill the supply capacity with process standards and global product quality, proved to be

constraints and had an informal impact. Foreign-owned firms perform better than the

domestic firms due to better managerial skills, improved technology and easy access to

foreign markets for exports.

Page 62: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

43

Rehman et. el. (2011) analyzed and estimated Pakistan’s exports trends towards relative

price, exchange rates, and gross domestic products over thirty years. The study determined

pros and cons of export trends and found plus and minus impact on exports and concluded

positive and negative correlations. To ensure stationary, the study examined “Augmented

Dickey and Fuller (ADF)” and found that data wasn’t stationary. To analyze the integration

between variables the study applied “Augmented Engle-Granger (AEG)” approach and found

that variables are co-integrated. The study showed and verified that the export performance

of the country is influenced by GDP, exchange rate, and related prices. Furthermore, the

conclusion of the study indicated that if GDP of developing country like Pakistan increases it

can enhance exports. Further, the findings indicated that high value of related prices results in

positive export outcomes. Besides, GDP and exchange rate were considerable while related

prices were inconsequential.

Shahbaz et al. (2011) analyzed Pakistan - a developing country economy. The study

examined the role of exports in economic growth by using quarterly data of 28 years. The

study by using ADRL approach found that export expansion resulted to overall economic

growth. Furthermore the working capital is found the leading determinant of the economy.

Depreciation of currency enhanced the exports and hence economic growth. The study

suggested that textile and agriculture sectors are correlated and in order to maximize the

exports, government have to focuss on both.

Portugal-Perez & Wilson (2012) choose more than 100 developing countries to check the

influence of soft and hard infrastructure on the export performance for the period of 2004-

2007. The study concluded that in these countries, export performance is positively affected

by the trade facilitations. Further, the study found that in countries with higher per capita

income, marginal effects of improvement in transportation and business environment is

decreasing but in the case of physical infrastructure and information technology it is

increasing.

Ratnaike (2012) studied the OECD countries to check the influence of trade liberalization

along with domestic competitiveness and world demand on the export performance by using

Page 63: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

44

panel data approach. The results of the study showed that world demand and domestic

competitiveness strongly influence the export performance while trade policy has

aninsignificant impact on it. The study revealed that increased world demand resulted in

improved export performance. On the other hand, the cost of producing exportable

commodities decreased due to domestic competition which further helped to increase the

exports. It was more interesting to note that domestic demand has significant negative impact

on the export performance of these economies.

Khondoker & Kalirajan (2012) explained wide-ranging factors that influence the export

performance of nations which are in developing phase on products which need a higher

number of labors with the usage of the cross-country panel data. According to the findings of

the study developing nations should focus on their organizational frameworks to build labor-

friendly environment because this can result in industrial growth on all sort of industries even

smaller industries like garments. Although it is necessary for all developing countries to

increase their exports but keeping in mind that these countries have access labor force. So, if

they consider installing new industries with higher labor count this can help them enhancing

employment opportunities and exports.

Auera & Mehrotrab (2014) discovered that the Asian economies with higher trade intensity

and close trade relations experience more close movements of consumer and producer price

inflations. The study further highlighted the importance of supply chain management for the

price spillovers at cross-border sectoral level while using the data set of the “World Input-

Output Database (WIOD)”. It was further discovered by the study that Asia-Pacific region

economies are realizing the increasing importance of imported intermediate inputs and its

impact on the prices of domestically produced goods.

Gulzar & Ghani (2014) analyzed the causal relationship between PSDP (Public Sector

Development Programme) expenditures, trade in service, both public and private investments

and economic development of Pakistan. The study discussed it in the context of the

Keynesian theory of government expenditures, supply-side hypothesis of Neo-classical,

Wagner’s economic growth theory along with high mass consumption demand pull and

Page 64: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

45

export-led well-known theory while considering the issues of security, stability, and

governance. Unit root and co-integration methods were applied to check stationary issue and

long run relationships respectively. Vector Auto Regressive (VAR) approach was adopted for

multivariate analysis. The study found that a big push is required in private investment and

trade in service to enhance the economic growth.

3.4 Computable General Equilibrium Models and the Economy

Policy makers usually check the indirect and direct effects through CGE about certain

policies, for instance they check that if a specific policy is formed then which sectors and

how much percent of the benefit we can gain or losses we can bear. The advantage of using

CGE is that it uses general equilibrium, helps in the adjustment of policy issues and after a

micro and macro analysis none of the fields is left untouched. Models effectively portray the

view of an economy as a whole, they are being used for prediction and these predictions are

according to the results obtained. The basic objective of the policy makers is to see the real

picture of the economy through theories and form models according to that for future

prediction. In order to check the authenticity of theories, we run models to judge them and

also come to know about implications of the theories and can address different policy issues.

There were many surveys conducted regarding CGE and every author according to his field

of interest studied different portion of it. Like for example, Pereira & Shoven (1988) studied

the national taxation portion of dynamic CGE, Shoven & Whalley (1984) focused on trade

and taxation portion and De Melo (1988) focused on developing countries, studied the trade

scenario quantification and CGE’s contribution in it. Robinson et al. (1999) did a survey on

CGE model and especially focused on its application side. Bandra (1991) surveyed the

policies in LDC’s through CGE. Kraybill (1993) compared by analyzing the input-output and

regional issues. Through CGE many issues of taxes and public finance, environmental and

energy policies, tariff and other trade policies and developmental policies have been

addressed.

According to the statement of Shoven & Whalley (1992), once the general equilibrium is

formed it then becomes quite easy to check for all the possible policy changes. Now when

Page 65: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

46

the concept of liberalization policies got attention at the same time CGE got its importance in

front of developing economies, because they had to check the effects of these policies of

different forms on their economy. CGE incorporates all the interactions that are market-based

and through its results, it shows that which kind of policy would be more appropriate for a

certain economy. The reason why CGE is more appropriate than all its predecessors because

it eliminates the linearity constraint which was an issue in all the previous models. But every

model has a certain implication. CGE models, unlike other models, no doubt solves the

complexity of micro-macro analysis to a greater extent but still this issue is not solved

completely as none of the models can address all the issues in adjustment programs. CGE

models have been classified from most simple to complex depending on the study.

CGE models usually help in a way that we come to know that which policy is affecting the

economy in positive and negative terms and its extent can also be checked. Janvry et.al

(1991) developed a CGE model for Ecuador to study the policies to be adopted and

incorporated using financial portfolio and took inflation and interest rates as endogenous

variables. Through simulation results, it was observed that if the current expenditures are

reduced then it would benefit the economy in the long run. But the contractionary monetary

policy would discourage the private investors due to a rise in interest rates, which would

reduce growth in the present. Different effects of the above-mentioned policies were seen on

sectoral poverty. If we check the rural sector it benefited from this policy of reduced

expenditure but the urban sector is affected badly as it has to face the exchange rate

devaluation, demand contraction and the losses in public goods benefit. The study concluded

at the end that reduced fiscal expenditure benefited the poor sector of Ecuador.

Adelman & Robinson (1988) worked on the rules of macro closure, for this, a CGE model

was formed. The study found that insensitivity occurred regarding the size of distribution

while sensitivity was observed in functional distribution regarding the rule. It concluded that

balance of payment has equal importance as of saving-investment closure rule. Simulation

results in every country vary, if some policies are going well for one country, it is not

necessary that same results would be observed for another country. It is because each country

has a different adjustment pattern of market mechanism and institutional structure.

Page 66: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

47

Bourguignon et al. (1989) worked on two economies by developing a macro model. The two

economies were middle income Latin America and low-income African country, the results

they obtained clearly explained that the devaluation of exchange benefits the low-income

people as they are in located export markets while affects the middle income because when

the Government reduces its expenditures uniformly it has fewer effects on low-income

people but greater effects on middle-income as through this inequality accruing of premium

occurs on capital.

Once a financial CGE model had been developed by Bourguignon, Branson, & Melo (1989)

and then was further extended by Fargeix & Sadoulet (1990) as they represented all the

advancement in the field of structural adjustment policies regarding modeling on income

distribution and performance of the economy. Further extension of them was made in such a

way that they incorporated the market for loanable funds. Countries start adopting the

policies of structural adjustment in order to have a sustained growth rate. But some studies

revealed that adoption of these programs affect the poor people a lot so these policies may

not be fully applied.

Diao et al. (1998) attempted to investigate the impact of research and development (R&D)

activities and trade protections on the economic growth of Japanese economy by using the

CGE model. The model used the real data for calibration and estimated the transitional

equilibrium and steady state results. The results of steady state equilibrium were found odd

showing a week effect of tariff imposition on the production of domestic final products. The

study justified the strange results with two reasons: first, it is due to limitations of the model

and second, final good producers did not compete with R&D activities for resources

allocation. The model designed for the study was unable to detect the impacts of technology

improvements accrued from trade. On the other hand, the transitional equilibrium showed a

substantial impact of protection trade policies on the output growth of the economy.

Adam & O’Connell (2004) considered the aid and trade options to investigate and compare

its impact on developing African economies. The study employed CGE model arguing that

Page 67: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

48

econometric models were unable to detect the “Dutch disease1” effects on these economies.

The results of the simulations showed that gains from trade were more than the gains from

aid. The study encouraged those transfers (whether through aid or trade) that helped to

accumulate the capital in the economy. This accumulated capital will help to shift the exports

from raw to manufactured goods that ultimately result into increased household welfare. It

was interesting to note that transfers through aid adversely affected the exports and domestic

productivity while the trade helped to increase not only the domestic output but also the

consumption level. Similarly, the distortions attached with aid were found more important

than the trade. It was due to the fact that subsidies given for export promotion will increase

the fiscal burden ultimately.

Siddiqui (2007) employed both static and dynamic CGE to calculate the impact of agriculture

trade liberalization both at domestic and abroad on the economic growth of Pakistan. For this

purpose, the study used SAM for the year of 2002 for Pakistan. The findings of the

simulation revealed a positive impact of agriculture trade liberalization both at domestic and

international level on economic growth of Pakistan. Further, it was explored that the impact

of liberalization at international level was stronger than domestic level liberalization. The

study concluded that this agriculture trade liberalization was more beneficiary for a rural

household in the long run than for urban household while in the case of income distribution,

it revealed positive impact in the short run but the adverse negative impact in long run.

Cockburn et al. (2008) employed CGE model to calculate the impact of trade liberalization

on different economic indicators by giving more attention to the patterns of income,

consumption, trade and production patterns along with basic tariff structure and the role of

relative factor endowments. The study compared seven African and Asian economies to

check the effects. The study found that trade liberalization affected different commodities

and household sectors in different manners. Further, the urban household was found befitting

from liberalization while rural household was losing, similarly agriculture sector seemed

1 “Dutch disease” is a term that is used when an economy faces the negative impact of anything such as

discovery of natural resources (oil, gas etc.), that causes a rapid inflow of foreign currencies which appreciates

the domestic currency resulting into decline in exports of other goods due to increased prices in the foreign

markets.

Page 68: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

49

losing its growth rate while manufacturing sector gaining. Overall the trade liberalization

helped to reduce poverty and increase the household welfare. Wages and prices increased and

interestingly, increase in wage rate was more than the increase in price level. Trade

liberalization brought pro-urban effects which were considered due to a major reduction in

the land returns.

Gilbert (2008) applied CGE model to calculate the impact of SAFTA on South Asian

economies in terms of poverty, household welfare, and inequality. The study reviewed all the

economies in the region that make it unique contribution in the existing literature. The study

found that due to similar product mix all economies except Bangladesh will get the benefit at

moderate level due to trade liberalization. This liberalization will increase the household

welfare in general. The study suggested that in the case of Bangladesh, unilateral trade

reforms are a better solution. For India and Bangladesh, the study found that the trade

liberalization under SAFTA will help to increase the income inequality and increase poverty

level.

Panda & Kumar (2009) employed the CGE model by using SAM of 2003-04 of India to

investigate the impacts of trade liberalization on GDP growth. The study showed a negative

impact on the GDP growth of India due to liberalization. It was further explored that it was

only agriculture sector that benefitted from the unilateral and multilateral agreements while

in the case of non-agricultural products, the growth was only possible if the agreement was

unilateral. In both cases, wages and prices increased and interestingly, increase in wage rate

was more than the increase in price level resulting an increase in real income of the

household. The study concluded that lower income group of people either rural or urban,

adversely affected in terms of food intake (calories) while other group improved benefits.

Ahmed & O’Donoghue (2010) employed CGE model to check the effects of external balance

variations on different sectors of Pakistan economy. The economy was aggregated into 33

sectors that measured the impact of changes in external savings and import prices on these

sectors. The results showed that if foreign saving is increased (50%), it causes an increase in

imports and reduction in exports of the economy. The most affected sectors were livestock,

Page 69: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

50

cement, textile and leather in export reduction area while the income of unskilled labor (non-

agriculture) and agriculture labor was increased. The reduction in export was the result of an

increased prices of imported inputs especially petroleum prices. The results further explored

that it will also excavate the poverty and income inequality.

Bouet et al. (2010) used MIRAGE which is a global CGE model to investigate the gains and

losses of SAFTA (South Asia from South Asian Free Trade Agreement) to members of and

non-member countries. The study analyzed both the situations of including and excluding the

products of the sensitive list in the process of trade liberalization. The results revealed that if

trade if liberalized at its full strength (including all products); it simply results into trade

diversion effect. This liberalization did not seem to be in favor of LDCs of the region. It was

interesting to note that it was Sri Lanka which obtained maximum benefits from SAFTA, it is

because the country already imposed minimum tariff rates in the region. Further, it was

discovered that this liberalization is increasing the income of unskilled labor at a higher rate.

The study concluded that SAFTA is promising a low tariff income for all member countries.

Naqvi et al. (2011) tried to explore the impact of agricultural income tax on income

inequality and welfare of household in Pakistan. The purpose of the study was to estimate the

possibility and validity of employing an agriculture income tax and estimating the possible

effects occurring at the micro and macro level in the country. The study applied a CGE

model for analyzing the situation of agricultural income tax and reduction in sales tax for

production activities to adjust the budget surplus. The experiment was based on the two

elements. The results suggested the implementation of agricultural income tax was beneficial

for the economy in terms of household welfare at the macro level and very important tool for

the development strategies of future.

Osman (2011) discussed the trade relationship between EU and Southern Africa by using the

comparative static multi-region, multi-sector CGE globe model as a tool for conducting

various simulation scenarios in order to examine the effects of the envisaged EU-SADC

(Southern African Development Community) EPAs (Economic Partnership Agreements) on

individual SADC economies. The modeling work utilized the most recent GTAP database.

Page 70: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

51

The simulation results suggested that a comprehensive EPA scenario is essential welfare-

improving for many SADC members. The agreements, however, did not serve as a stumbling

block towards more integration for SADC members into the world markets. The study further

suggested that a comprehensive EPA scenario is the best option vis-à-vis the WTO-

compatible alternatives for SADC non-LDCs.

Ahmed et al. (2013) by using the dynamic CGE model analyzed the impact of public

expenditures (macro-micro) on the economic growth in Pakistan. The study considered two

approaches in the simulation for public investment. Infrastructure investment for financed by

production taxes in the first approach and in the second approach it was financed by foreign

borrowings. It was important to note that the impact of both approaches was same especially

when considering the long run goals of poverty reduction and macroeconomic gains. The

study further discovered that financing by tax puts stress on output in the short run at

industrial level while financing through foreign borrowing have to impact like “Dutch

Disease” in the short run.

Bhatti et al. (2014) used the simple Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) to discuss the

role of fiscal policy in poverty reduction in Pakistan. The CGE model takes into account

market interaction, it creates ripples in the whole economy by showing the outcome effects

of pricing in one market and other markets. Further, the model even shows the quantity

effects of pricing in the original market. The study used SAM 2002 developed by (Dorosh et

al. 2006). The study found that a policy mix of sales tax, income tax and government

expenditure help to reduce income inequality while at the same lessens the economy’s

financial dependency.

3.5 Computable General Equilibrium Models and Trade Liberalization

Some researchers have also used the CGE model to investigate the impacts of trade

liberalization. Trade liberalization can be categorized into unilateral, bilateral or multilateral

trade liberalization. Under the unilateral trade liberalization, economies are assumed to

eliminate/reduce tariffs against rest of the world economies but the later do not need to do so.

The bilateral trade liberalization is possible under the free trade agreement between two

Page 71: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

52

economies in which each one is agreed to reduce/eliminate the tariff on its import from its

trade partner. Under the multilateral trade liberalization, every member country of the free

trade agreement (FTA) reduces or eliminates tariff against all the members of the FTA. Some

of the studies based on the trade liberalization are reviewed as follows.

In a broad review about the outcomes of trade liberalization on poverty, authors Hertel &

Reimer, (2005), concluded that both micro and macro methodological approaches should be

considered. The study concluded that to quantify the impact of trade liberalization on

poverty, there are possible four methodological groups namely (a) cross-country regression

analysis, (b) partial equilibrium or cost of living analysis, (c) the general equilibrium analysis

using different simulations and (d) mixed approach (combination of micro-macro analysis), it

is also known as the post simulation analysis of the simulations of general equilibrium. All

the four groups include the traditions of “bottom-up” or “top-down” associated with experts

of trade and poverty analysis. The “bottom-up” approaches based on household expenditure

data in detail while top-down” approaches based on the data of national accounts. The study

concluded that any analysis of trade and poverty needs to be reported by both perspectives

and even many studies did so in “micro-macro” approach. The study suggested that further

research needs to be directed towards the factor markets improvements, taxes, transfer

payments and costs associated with domestic marketing. Further, the household surveys also

need to be reconciled with the data of national accounts.

While conducting a survey on impacts of trade reforms on the poverty Kraev & Akolgo,

(2005) pointed out the need of certain properties in a model while calculating the

distributional impacts of macroeconomic policy reforms. The study stressed that these

properties should be used in all four types of models namely CGE, econometric,

microsumulation and fixed ratio that are commonly used for assessing the impact of such

policy options. The five recommended properties namely; (i) representing specific policy

controls employed by policy packages, (ii) providing pliability in modelling production and

employment nest, (iii) representing connections among macroeconomic variables and

production nest, (iv) representing short term and medium term dynamics instead of long term

and (v) producing procedures of confidence for the model’s output. The study concluded

Page 72: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

53

that despite lacking short term analysis and weakness of non-verifiability, the CGE models

still provides the best results among others when considering the said criteria.

The study based on literature review of 16 studies has assessed the impact of world full trade

liberalization using CGE modeling application was conducted by Bouet & Krasniqi (2006).

Despite having found distinctive underlying assumptions in the model and the scenarios

stimulated, it was concluded that trade reform has a positive effect on world welfare.

However, trade liberalization in the agricultural sector might have a negative impact on

welfare for countries that import agricultural products or have preferential access to some

markets. These models were designed to gauge the detailed impact of trade liberalization on

welfare at either global level or at the country level. Nonetheless, they ignored variables such

as changes in income distribution and poverty level at a micro level. Different strategies and

techniques have developed and applied to overcome these shortcomings.

To summarize the contribution of CGE modeling in assessing the impact of trade

liberalization on poverty and welfare, a detailed literature survey was conducted by Cloutier

et al (2008). The literature review shows that different results can be obtained using CGE

modeling depending on the structure of a model and the different policy scenarios simulated

in the model. Policy scenarios such as reducing or eliminating tariffs and quotas to all or

some sectors result in different policy simulations. To overcome revenue lost due to

elimination or reduction of tariffs or quotas, different compensatory mechanisms are adopted

by the countries.

Combining dynamic CGE model to a representative household model in Vietnam Wong

(2008) developed a macro-micro analytical approach. The results showed a significant

increase in economic growth with both gains from liberalizing trade against ASEAN and also

a remarkable boost when expanding it to cover rest of the world. He also concluded that

capital investment and human capital accumulation see a rise as soon as Vietnam expands its

trade with other countries. In addition, although poverty in Vietnam falls due to the

substantial lift in the economic growth but in the rural sector, income inequality increases

tremendously in most vulnerable households when liberalizing trade.

Page 73: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

54

To study the trade liberalization impact on poverty, Nahar & Siriwardana (2009) developed a

CGE model with different simulation for Bangladesh. The result indicated that total

elimination of tariffs favors export-oriented sectors in the economy. In the short run, both

rural and urban states experienced in the overall reduction in the short run with a marginal

increase in poverty gap was projected for urban areas. In contrast, the trade liberalization

reduced absolute poverty both in urban and rural areas during long-run.

While studying the changes in distribution of income due to foreign trade, Ahmed &

O'Donoghue (2010) showed that overall consumption increased with increase in the foreign

savings but decreased with increase in the import price of petroleum and industrial raw

materials. The study used the SAM (2002) in which activities were aggregated into three

major groups including agriculture (12 sectors), industrial (16 sectors) and service (6 sectors)

with disaggregation of labor into ten categories based on size, type of employment (agri/non-

agri) and skilled/unskilled. Households were grouped into urban and rural households

disaggregated into total 17 sub-categories based on farm size and poor/non poor (urban and

rural). The policy experiments included (i). 50 % increase in foreign savings (ii) 10%

increase in the import price of petroleum and (iii). 10 % increase in the import price of

industrial raw materials. The results showed that trade deficit increased due to increase in

foreign savings. The findings highlighted that the only losers are the large and medium size

farmers and the small farmers become better off. Poverty decreased and the Gini coefficient

showing a slight decrease. Manufacturing sector stands the worst among all the sectors.

Measuring the poverty and welfare impacts of trade liberalization in the CGE framework

using the SAM (1995-96)1 a study was conducted by Raihan (2010). The activities were

grouped into three groups; agriculture (7), industries (12) and services (6). The experimental

design consisted of (a). Elimination of all types of tariffs accompanied by an increase in

production tax and the imposition of new taxes on the construction sectors. (b). full tariff

elimination accompanied by an increase in income tax (c). Reduction in tariff rate to the

actual level of tariff reduction undertaken by the government. The results showed that the

1 The SAM consisted of 26 production sectors and 7 factors of production (6 types of labor and one capital).

HH were aggregated into 7 groups based on location, sociological and wealth criteria.

Page 74: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

55

import volume of many goods that included petroleum, chemical, clothing grains and

machinery increased. Demand for import substitutes decreased and for composite import

increased due to a decrease in import prices. The results of the second simulation are similar

to simulation 1 although they are lower in magnitudes. Exports price decreased which

resulted in anincrease in demand for exports. Labor and capital demand in the protected

sector (petroleum, chemical, and machinery) decreased whereas in the less protected sector

(ready-made garments and commercial) increased. Labor income in all simulations decreased

along with a decline in HH’s income with a larger reduction in the income of rural

households. Overall welfare decreased with greater loss in the welfare of rural households

than the urban and rich households. In the second simulation, the loss in the welfare of rich

households is higher than rural households whereas in the third simulation the overall

consumption of all the households increased leading to welfare gain to all the households.

Poverty level increased under the first simulation and decreased under the 2nd

and 3rd

simulations.

In Argentina with special emphasis on export taxes, Cicowiez, Bonilla, & Bonilla (2010)

studied both poverty and inequality due to trade reforms. The study used a national CGE

model combine it with a global economy-wide CGE model (World Bank LINKAGE Model),

and micro-simulations. They based the national CGE model on Social Accounting Matrix

(SAM) with 24 activities and 26 commodities. The results obtained show that full trade

liberalization of world excluding export taxes, the agricultural and non-agricultural goods,

decreases poverty and income inequality in Argentina. However the effects on poverty and

inequality were even deteriorating somewhat when only the agricultural goods were

considered.

In order to examine the effect of trade reforms and alternative global trade strategies on

poverty as inequality of various households by using the comprehensive micro data of

Brazilian states from 1987-2005, a study was conducted by Castilho et al. (2010). The results

demonstrate that the states directly affected by tariff cuts witnessed a decline in household

poverty and the inequality than the ones which received lesser exposure states. Liberalizing

trade helps to enhance household poverty and inequality in metropolitans and if one can link

Page 75: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

56

this into reductions in rural areas as during studies they found no significant effect on the

rural poverty. Added to that they observed that world market integration, import

dissemination will have a similar role to trade liberalization for both urban and rural states of

Brazil. However, increasing export exposure seems to have drastically reduced both useful

measures of household welfare.

In order to better capture the heterogeneous household response to trade Cockburn et al.

(2014) suggested the use of CGE models in conjunction with micro simulation models. The

study suggested that simplest approach to evaluate income & poverty effects using a CGE

model is to disaggregate the total representative households (RH) to get the true picture of

diverse learning patterns. The study further found that higher the number of RH, the more the

problem is minimized. The two techniques widely adopted to evaluate the effects on poverty

and income inequality are the RH approach and the micro simulation approach (MS).

Another detailed literature review was conducted by focusing on the studies that employed

CGE model by OH & Kyophilavong (2015). The study attempted to investigate the

relationship between poverty and trade liberalization through literature surveys. The study

concluded that since last two decades, researchers are more focused on this issue by applying

different methods but the CGE approach remained most successful among others. The study

further investigated different approaches of CGE and discovered that Global Trade Project

(GTAP) model is more sophisticated and popular among policy makers. The literature

concluded that the impacts of trade liberalization on poverty are mixed. It depends on the

type of liberalization (ASEAN integration, Bilateral agreements, and WTO), characteristics

of the economy, price phenomenon and factor markets, patterns of taxes and governments

spending and technological and economic development.

3.6 European Union (EU) and Trade Liberalization

Over the past two decades, the World Bank and International Monetary Fund (IMF) have

engaged the international economic community with the worldwide campaign of economic

reforms through the economic stabilization and structural adjustment programs. However, the

debate shifted its focus to international economic integration through fair international

Page 76: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

57

competition and trade liberalization from structural adjustment and stabilization (Hassan,

1997).

According to classical trade theory, trade liberalization is associated with the positive welfare

of the society. The two country, two goods and two factors model suggested by Heckscher-

Ohlin states “an increase in exports and production in the division that focuses more on the

production part of any economy”. Even today the developing nations have abundance

unskilled labors that can be improved with trade through more production of goods.

Although modern trade theories suggest that economic efficiency is the result of economies

of scale, liberalized trade, improved technology, access to information etc. but these theories

fail to answer the effects of trade liberalization on non-tradable goods, the goods that are not

homogenous and segmented labor market (Winters, 2002).

Lewis et al. (2001) attempted to investigate the impact of free trade agreement (FTA)

between South Africa and EU and the unilateral measures taken by EU to open its markets

for some countries of the South African region in 1999 by using the CGE model. The results

of the study revealed that although trade liberalization brought benefits for some countries

and some countries suffered but the overall gain for the region was more than the loss. This

trade creation that resulted due to trade liberalization strongly denied the “beggar thy

neighbor1” policy in the context of FTA. The study concluded that if real GDP growth rate

and real absorption are taken into account, the unilateral access of South African countries

into the EU market brought more benefits than the FTA of EU-SADC (South African

Development Community).

Monteagudo & Watanuki (2003) compared the gains from Mercosur free trade agreement

with Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA) and its FTA with European Union (EU) using

the CGE model with aggregation of regions and commodities into 12 regions and 13

commodity sectors. The standard CGE model was extended by incorporating externalities

(sectoral exports externality, import externality, and aggregate exports externality) and

1 It is an economics terminology used when an economy attempts to cure its economic problems in such a way

that it increases the problems of other economies.

Page 77: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

58

economies of scale in the manufacturing sectors1. The analysis was based on three types of

policy simulations: (a). Formation of FTAA and elimination of tariff on the intra-FTAA. (b).

FTA between Mercosur and EU with tariff-eliminating on the intra-regional trade. (c).

Simultaneous formation of FTAA and FTA between Mercosur and EU. Simulations showed

that exports of individual economies of Mercosur increased. The findings also revealed that

exports from the United States to Argentina and Brazil increased as a result o Mercosur FTA

with FTAA. Under the first experiment imports to Mercosur from EU and rest of the world

decreased due to the trade diversion effect. The gain to Mercosur in terms of exports

performance is higher in FTA with EU than FTA with FTAA with a more heterogeneous

growth in Mercosur exports in case of EU than the FTAA. However, gains to Mercosur from

the combined FTAs (simultaneously signing FTA with both EU and FTAA) were found to be

greater than the sum of gains from the two individual FTAs. The welfare gain to Mercosur in

terms of GDP growth rate was higher in the case of FTA with EU than the FTAA.

Chishti, Zulfiqar, & Naqvi (2008) employed the CGE model with Globe to calculate the

multi-countries and multi-sectors effects. The study investigated the impact of trade policy of

EU on Pakistan and on other Asian economies. The study found that Pakistan is getting

benefits only in the fields of textile and clothing and similar was true for rest of the Asian

economies. Similarly, EU-India free trade agreement showed negative effects for Pakistani

exports to EU. This is because Pakistan and India have same product basket for EU. In the

case of GSP, Pakistan is likely to get benefit only if other competitors are not benefitting

from the same products under the same scheme.

Osman (2011) discussed the trade relationship between EU and Southern Africa by using the

comparative static multi-region, multi-sector CGE globe model as a tool for conducting

various simulation scenarios in order to examine the effects of the envisaged EU-SADC

(Southern African Development Community) EPAs (Economic Partnership Agreements) on

individual SADC economies. The modeling work utilized the most recent GTAP database.

The simulation results suggested that a comprehensive EPA scenario is essential welfare-

1 Economies of scale means when a certain manufacturer produce a good in abundance, the cost of production

minimizes.

Page 78: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

59

improving for many SADC members. The agreements, however, did not serve as a stumbling

block towards more integration for SADC members into the world markets. The study further

suggested that a comprehensive EPA scenario is the best option vis-à-vis the WTO-

compatible alternatives for SADC non-LDCs.

Ahmad & Kalim (2014) examined the export competitiveness of the textile and clothing

sector of Pakistan. The study suggested in order to gain maximum benefits from the current

status of GSP Plus, Pakistan has to focus on the product diversification. By using maximum

likelihood method, the study analyzed the pre and post quota performance by using a time

series data from the period of 1980 to 2011. The study discovered that there was no

significant improvement in the performance of this sector. Several other factors like higher

input cost and price level higher than the competitors, played an important role in the week

performance of this sector.

Pakistan Business Council (PBC (2014)) estimated how much Pakistan can gain at zero

percent import duty in the EU market. The study estimated that maximum US$ 7.7 billion

imports are possible from Pakistan in the EU at the end of 2016 which is higher than the

2013 imports that were US$ 6.0 billion. It was further discovered that 74 items from Pakistan

with 6 digit HS code have more potential in the EU market. These high potential products

include those products that were exported to EU from Pakistan in 2013 with value of more

than US$ 1 million and 6% market share of total imports of EU from rest of the world in

same product lines while for rest of the world, the exports of these products were US$ 10

million in the same year. It is important for exporter from Pakistan to understand that per unit

cost of production is higher in Pakistan than the competitors in the region such as India,

Bangladesh, and China. This higher cost of production may minimize or nullify the zero

tariff advantage of Pakistan in the EU.

3.7 Trade Liberalization in the GTAP Framework

The following studies have relied on examining the impact of the bilateral and multilateral

trade agreements in the CGE framework.

Page 79: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

60

To assess the effects of multiregional trade liberalization of markets in 14 countries, Hertel et

al. (2004) used the dynamic CGE framework. The study combined global macro model also

known as GTAP model with a Microsimulation model. The Microsimulation model was

based on country level household surveys that simulated the effects on poverty for Indonesia.

In order to for this methodology to work the data source needed to be compatible with both

models. As shown in many previous studies that very rich households report their capital

income much lower than their actual income (Atkinson 1995 and Mistiaen & Ravaillon

2003). To offset this difference, the author’s adjusted non-agricultural profit-type returns for

richest of the households in the survey, to keep the ratio of agricultural and non-agricultural

income from GTAP database. Furthermore, they also adjusted GTAP database that would

reflect the factor composition of income from the household survey. This micro-simulation

model estimated poverty line which measures poverty as the level of utility as opposed to

identifying a basic bundle of goods within an LES consumption function for households.

To calculate the effect of Vietnam’s trade reforms with GTAP model, Vanzetti & Huong

(2006) developed CGE model. The results of the study revealed that both imports and

exports of all tradable sectors increase with the largest surge in textiles and apparel. While in

the case of unilateral liberalization total welfare gains increase substantially. Unskilled labor

income boosts up as much as 38 percent with the mainstream labor involves in the

manufacturing of textiles, apparel, wood products and telecommunications. However,

Vanzetti & Huong (2006) identified that these results appeared unrealistic and recommended

some kind of trade-off between labor use and wages as this closure will yield better results.

The framework of both partial and general equilibrium analysis was used by Abdelmalki,

Sandretto & Jallab (2007) to examine the potential impacts of FTA between the United Sates

and Morocco by using the GTAP (version. 6). The experimental design was consisted of

‘strongly asymmetric liberalization’, ‘intermediate asymmetric liberalization’ and ‘full

liberalization’. Under the partial equilibrium analysis, only a single scenario was tested, that

is; tariff reduction by Morocco on its imports from the United States. The findings of the 1st

and 2nd

scenarios under the CGE modeling indicate that US received higher gain than its

counterpart in terms of increase in GDP and welfare US continued to receive higher gains in

Page 80: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

61

the 3rd

simulation (full liberalization) whereas Morocco received negative gain in terms of

welfare. Rest of the world got suffered under all the three scenarios. Morocco benefitted in

many sectors with textile and clothing sectors are the biggest winners but faced loss in

transport and wheat production while the US stood gainer in wheat production and poultry.

The partial equilibrium analysis’ results indicated that Morocco received potential gains in

terms of increase in consumers’ welfare and increase in exports.

In order to assess the economic impacts of bilateral free trade agreements related to Japan

Abe (2007) employed the GTAP model (version. 6.2) with aggregation of sectors and regions

into 25 sectors and 24 regions. The experiments included simulations for all bilateral FTAs

of Japan and simulations for the regional/multilateral trade agreements related to Japan. The

first analysis was made for Japan’s bilateral FTAs with Malaysia, Singapore, and Mexico in

which Japan followed asymmetry in tariff elimination in terms of commodities while its

partners were assumed to abolish all their tariffs against Japan. The study showed that all the

bilateral FTAs’ partners of Japan gained from FTA in terms of increase in their GDPs and

EVs. Japan gained from FTA with Malaysia and Mexico only and experienced loss in its

welfare from its ‘FTA’ with Singapore. Rest of the world got suffered due to the loss in share

of the market in Japan and its FTA partners but overall world welfare increased. Mexico led

in gains in sectoral production as compared to the other economies. The study also carried

out a number of simulations to examine the static as well as dynamic impacts of all the

possible future bilateral FTAs of Japan as well as regional FTAs in the similar fashion. The

results revealed that Japan’s gain increased with increase in the number bilateral FTAs. Rest

of the world suffered due to lossof welfare gains.

Gilbert (2008) studied the application of SAFTA and its impacts on poverty and income

distribution. The study used GTAP 6 with the base year 2001 database and GAMS to run the

model. The experiment was performed in 20 percent tariff reduction and 10 percent in all

applied tariff. The study involved 10 households and16 commodities were used. The study

found mixed results in the case of poverty and inequality. The regional integration seems

against Bangladesh and India in terms of absolute poverty. The study concluded that the

welfare effect of SAFTA is positive but modest on overall south Asian countries. The study

Page 81: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

62

suggested that the gains from trade are always under government controls and the fruits of

liberalization should be distributed to the economy to maximize the welfare impact.

To assess the impacts of FTA between Mercosur and EU in the framework of CGE model

with the aggregation scheme of 33 commodity groups and 21 regions, Boyer & Schuschny

(2010) employed the GTAP (version.6). Two policy experiments were carried out; 1st: “full

liberalization” and 2nd

“partial liberalization”. The simulation results revealed that the inter-

regional as well as intra-regional trade increased along with an increase in GDP, exports and

imports of the Mercosur region with improvement in the terms of trade (TOT). However,

Mercosur experienced a negative impact on its trade balance with differential impacts on

various sectors across the member economies. The GDP of EU decreased while exports and

imports were increased with improvements in the trade balance. Trade flows to rest of the

world decreased for both the regions. The production of agriculture and light manufacturing

sectors increased and of the heavy manufactured decreased for Mercosur. Both the regions

gained as shown by efficiency changes in terms of re-allocation of resources, change in terms

of the TOT and change in saving-investment balance.

To assess the impacts of India’s FTA with ASEAN, Sikdar & Nag (2011) showed that

India’s exports to the AEAN member economies increased significantly. However, an

increase in imports was higher than exports and so India suffered due to a loss in its terms of

trade. This study employed the GTAP model (version07) with the re-aggregation of regions

and sectors into 20 regions and 35 sectors. The findings highlighted that Thailand, Singapore

and Malaysia welfare increased. Total production of the ASEAN region increased along with

an increase in input demand and input prices. The simulations results also pointed out that

rest of the world stood worst due to its loss in the market share in the ASEAN region.

Another study attempted to investigate the impacts of trade liberalization between Pakistan

and the SAFTA member economies by Shaikh et al (2012). The study utilized the modified

version of the GTAP (version.4) database with aggregation of regions into 10 regions and

Page 82: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

63

commodities into 10 commodity groups1. The policy experiments included ‘unilateral trade

liberalization’, ‘regional trade liberalization’ and simultaneously ‘unilateral and regional

trade liberalization’ with three additional experiments associated with one each to the initial

three experiments. The study also employed the conditional sensitivity analysis (CSSA)

associated with the three policy experiments to check the sensitivity results. The results

indicated that Pakistan received a welfare gain of 1.53 % in terms of increase in GDP.

Overall imports increased and exports decreased (textile exports increased while food,

mining and manufacturing exports decreased) with improvement in its terms of trade (TOT).

On the other hand, due to the regional trade liberalization or equivalently reduction in import

tariff by SAFTA, the volume of trade in the SAFTA region increased with highest welfare

gain to India followed by Pakistan which received relatively less gain. However, rest of the

Asia adversely affected due to the trade diversion effect. The results also showed that the

unilateral and regional trade liberalization simultaneously increased the welfare of both

Pakistan and India with greater improvement in TOT. Rest of the Asia got suffered fromloss

in their terms of trade (TOT) and trade volumes.

A CGE model for Mozambique was developed by Minor & Mureverwi (2013) to analyze the

impact of free trade agreement on poor households. The study employed MyGTAP

developed by Minor & Walmsley (2013) to investigate the distributional consequences of

three trade agreements namely Regional Economic Agreement (REA), Tripartite Free Trade

Agreement (TFTA) and African Continental Custom Union (ACCU). The study includes 21

Regions, 10 households, and 22 commodities. The results of the study found that the

completion of RECs have minimal effect on household’s income and loss of government

revenue. In the case of TFTA, sugar export has been increased and rendered positive effect

on the real income of the agriculture households. In addition to this, in the case of ACCU, the

poor household would suffer. Moreover, the projected income of the country would fall.

1 The 10 regions in GATP were, Pakistan, India, Rest of Asia, ASEAN, and rest of Asia, Japan, European

Union, NAFTA, Middle East and rest of the world. The 10 groups of commodities were agri-groups, mining

and quarrying, processed food, textile, wearing appraisal, petroleum and coal, machinery, transport, services

and others.

Page 83: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

64

To examined the potential trade effects between Pakistan and India, Raihan & De (2014)

conducted a study by using GTAP. The study discussed the major trade barriers to bilateral

trade as well as for regional trade. The research study involved GTAP analysis to judge the

welfare effect of Pakistan MFN status to India .The simulation has been studied in 10 regions

and 29 commodities. The study presented the comprehensive assessment of the trade

relations between India and Pakistan with detailed analysis of trade modalities. The study

concluded that the welfare effect of MFN status for both countries is higher if it is supported

by improved trade facilitation across the borders. This not only increase the trade volume but

also exports between the two countries. The GTAP simulation further analysed that Pak-

India trade cooperation would have positive affects for other South Asian countries.

To calculate the impact of food and nutrition security on multiple household of Ghana a

study was conducted by Kuiper & Shutes (2014). The study employed the newly developed

MyGTAP database of Minor & Walmsley (2013). The study involved multiple householdsto

study the effects of food policy on the most vulnerable sector of the society helping the

government to design intervention in order to provide relief to the poor segment of the

society. The study embedded 19 commodities and 9 households. In the study, the following

three approaches were used to incorporate multiple household data in GTAP database.

Firstly, user weights have been assigned to household and incorporate in GTAP. Secondly,

the study included household data through national SAM. Thirdly, they directly place

household survey in GTAP analysis. The result suggested that the removal of export subsidy

is useful to the poor people of Ghana.

To examine the impacts of trade liberalization between Pakistan and India another study was

conducted by Pohit & Saini (2015). The study employed the GTAP’ (version 8) with

aggregation of regions and commodities into 13 regions and 20 commodity sectors. The

policy simulations included (i) ‘full liberalization of trade against each other’, (ii)“simulation

1 plus 50% productivity improvement in all modes of transportation services” and

(iii)“simulation 2 plus full liberalization. The analysis revealed that due to trade

liberalization, the welfare of both India and Pakistan increased with a higher benefit to India

under policy experiment 1. Welfare increased for both the economies when a 50%

Page 84: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

65

productivity improvement was introduced in the modes of transportation engaged in trade

between Pakistan and India. The welfare for India increased by 4 times when full

liberalization was included in FTA whereas the welfare of Pakistan decreased as compared to

simulation 2. All the three types of policy experiments showed an increase in exports to each

other.

3.8 History of CGE Models Applied in Pakistan

Many authors have observed the literature on CGE models applied to less develop and

developing countries. In this section, we will focus on major CGE studies on Pakistan. The

strengths and weaknesses in these studies are mentioned in a useful manner in order to add

some new dimensions.

Fei (1962) constructed the first ever I-O table in Pakistan with the base year 1955. It was first

general equilibrium analysis with strength. It meant to focus on large-scale industry like

mining, large scale manufacturing sector and input structures of agriculture and ignored rest

of the production areas. The table classified the industry into 6 sectors (agriculture, mining,

industrial, unallocated, wage and foreign trade sector) ignoring the service sector. Since then,

in Pakistan, a large number of I-O tables and Social Accounting Matrices (SAM) have been

constructed. The first SAM was developed in 1962. However, despite the availability of the

I-O tables and SAMs at regular intervals since 1962, the first ever CGE model was developed

after 18 years by McCarthy and Taylor (1980). The latest SAM available for Pakistan is

available with the base year 2007-08 developed by Debowicz et al (2012).

McCathy & Taylor (1980) developed a CGE model by using SAM 1975-76 focusing on food

policy reforms and how they may influence the economic growth of Pakistan. The model was

an open economy with government sector where industrial sector was disaggregated into 11

and household into three sectors keeping in view the socio-economic groups for both urban

and rural. The major focus of the study was to observe the changes in patterns of household

consumption when prices and real income changes. The simulations were performed by

increasing government expenditures, removing subsidies on wheat, increasing subsidy on

Page 85: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

66

fertilizer, increasing wages and land reforms. The results revealed the maximum impact of

land reforms on the economic growth as compared to other simulation results.

Labus (1988) developed a behavioral CGE model (comparative static model) for the public

sector of Pakistan aiming to check the influence of state-owned manufacturing activities on

the economy. The model used the SAM 1983-84 and used only government, enterprises, and

household as institutions in order to check the impact of liberalized policy as well as the

policy of price in the public sector. The results of the simulations showed that liberalization

policy brings a positive change in the current account balance, it causes an increase in real

GDP and reduction in prices. Furthermore, the activities relating to exportable commodities

have been increased converting the losses into profits of public owned enterprises. The model

had nothing to do with the welfare impact of the household.

Naqvi (1998) used the SAM 1983-84 for the CGE model developed aiming to analyze the

economy-wide impact of energy policy. The results found by the simulation show that a

change in energy tax have varied influence on different commodities i.e. if distortions are

removed from taxes on petroleum products, it fulfill the objective of social equity while

removal of distortion in taxes of electricity have no impact on the consumption of rural

household while it showed a negative impact on urban household. On the other hand

applying a tax on natural gas brought a negative impact on the real consumption of the

household. It was further discovered that removing distortions not only increase the real GDP

but also bring a positive change in the trade balance. The model was simply a static model

aiming comparative analysis and had nothing to do with the furcating.

Vos (1998) developed financial CGE model for Pakistan by using SAM 1983-84 aiming to

calculate the impact of foreign aid and Dutch disease effect. The study found that during the

era of the 1980s, the economy of Pakistan was not a constraint to foreign aid rather it

generate strong Dutch disease effect by shrinking the exports, reducing commodity

competitiveness and jolting the structural adjustment efforts. The results further found that

additional depreciation of currency not only increase the cost push inflation but also reduce

the real income and aggregate demand. Also, a fiscal cut abroad brings deflation and a shift

Page 86: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

67

towards public investment from public consumption may bring a positive change in

economic growth similarly a reduction in debt also seemed positive for economic growth.

Siddiqui & Iqbal (1999) developed first CGE for Pakistan under MIMAP (Micro Impacts of

Macro- economic Adjustment Policies) project. When simulation occurred it was observed

that reduction in tariff also causes a reduction in wages and dividends of households. This

proportion of decline in income was observed through dividends than wages. It was

interesting to find that rich was more affected by the tariff reduction than the poor in the form

of wages because rich was getting profit in the form of dividends while poor was only getting

wages. The study further concluded that this tariff reduction reduces the income disparity

between urban and rural areas.

Kemal et al. (2001) developed a CGE model under MIMAP project to investigate the

changes in household income and other macro aggregates when tariff on industrial imports

are reduced. The results found that reduction in tariff reduces the prices of imported goods

that ultimately reduce the output price and the structure of input prices. It further increases

the gap between poor and rich household. There is an increase in consumption which showed

a positive welfare effect on household but this increase in consumption is greater in rich than

the poor. The study further argued that the government revenue also reduced due to low

investment which ultimately may affect the economic growth adversely.

Okuda & Brohi (2001) developed a CGE model for Pakistan by using GTAP 4 to investigate

the impact of roads and transport infrastructure on the economy. The study proposed a

multiregional CGE model in order to check the impact of new road network between Karachi

and Peshawar. The simulation results discovered that new road will bring positive change in

the industrial sector of Punjab and NWFP (North West Frontier Province, Now KPK (Khyber

Pakhtunkhwa)) provinces of Pakistan. The road network will increase the real income of

household that ultimately will increase the utility level in both provinces. The study further

concluded that this network will bring a positive change of 16% to GDP of the economy.

Page 87: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

68

Martine et al (2004) used CGE model by using GTAP 5.4 to measure the impact of quota

removal after the end of Multi-Fiber Arrangement (MFA). The study applied global CGE

model to calculate the impact of the Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC) on the

countries like Pakistan, Bangladesh, China, India, Hong Kong, Indonesia, and Taiwan, who

were initially getting quota from USA and EU. The major focus of the study is Pakistan to

calculate the gains and losses after quota removal. The results of the study showed that the

quota removal will bring changes in the formation of final goods as well as in the mix of

intermediate goods. The study concludes that Pakistan will get benefit from it only if it

employs its resources efficiently but there is fear of some welfare loss.

Siddiqui (2005) examined the trade liberalization by employing the CGE model and

adjustment in fiscal policy. The study extended the updated SAM of Siddiqui & Iqbal (1999)

applying the methodology of Fontana and Wood (2000). The study incorporated additional

sectors and sub-actors into the model and it also allowed the intra-household allocation of

resources. The SAM included nine categories of the HH with aggregation into male and

female and four education levels, nine social reproductive sectors and nine leisure sectors1.

The SAM considered two sources of household income: the value of labor used in production

sectors and adjusted income of the own account workers. The SAM also considered the

market and non-market sectors as well as the paid and unpaid sectors of the economy with

disaggregation of labor into male and female with further categorization in terms of four

education levels2. The production accounts were consisted of 4 major categories; the

agriculture (5 sectors), mining (1 sector), manufacturing (8 sectors) and others (7 sectors).

The results found that compensatory trade liberalization increases the employability of male

and female. It reduces the gap between the wages of male and female along with over

burdening the female in Pakistan. It also helps to empower the women with greater pace than

any other activity. The study suggested that with compensatory measures, the impact of

liberalization should also be measured on the household work and leisure along with other

market-based activities.

1 The study also incorporated the time allocation in market and non-market activities.

2 The four education levels are; no education, less than 5 year of education, 5 but less than 10 years and 10 and

above 10 years of education.

Page 88: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

69

Butt (2006) utilized the CGE model for Pakistan to calculate the impact of tariff cuts on the

regional disparities, output, employment, and exports by keeping in view different regions of

the country. The study developed a PAKREG database by utilizing the I-O table of 1990-91

developed by Federal Bureau of Statistics (FBS 2001). The study in this way helped the

GTAP to recognize Pakistan as a separate country. The results of the study revealed a

positive impact of trade liberalization on all regions of Pakistan in terms of improvement in

output, exports, and employment. The results further discovered a positive relationship

between trade liberalization and regional disparities during the military regimes and opposite

in the case of democratic governments. The cross-border tariff cuts seemed to help the

increment in real GDP slightly in the short run but significant in the long run.

Ahmed & Donoghue (2008) described the welfare effect of external balances on Pakistan

economy. The study used CGE model to capture the economy-wide impact of policies

simulation. Social accounting Matrix (2002) was used as a database and GAMS software to

run the model. The study encompassed 12 agriculture sector 16 industrial sector and 6

services sector. Households have been distributed in rural and urban. The rural households

have been further distributed into 17 categories. The experiment was performed through

trade liberalization simulations. The simulations were concerned with 50 percent increase in

foreign savings, 10 percent increase in overall import prices and 10 percent increase in the

import prices of petroleum etc. The result of the study suggested that the external oil price

possessed the high potential to affect Pakistan socio-economic condition. Increase in foreign

saving decrease poverty in the country. The analysis suggested that poverty is increasing with

the increase in import prices.

Shaikh & Rahpoto (2009) has studied the SAFTA implication on Pakistan economy using

GTAP model. The GTAP model is unable to examine the vibrant effect of trade liberalization

but it is very effective in the comparative static analysis in the case of any trade reforms. This

study used 10 regions and 10 commodities. The experiments are based on the unilateral trade

liberalization (uniform tariff rate 15 percent), regional trade liberalization, and unilateral

trade liberalization (15 percent) for the rest of the world. The study used GTAP model to

investigate the benefits and costs of granting MFN (Most Favored Nation) status to India and

Page 89: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

70

SAFTA. The results highlight the potential industries which are to be expanded or

contracted. Pakistan gained the highest welfare in case of SAFTA with the 15 percent

uniform external tariff. There is high demand in the international trade for Pakistani dates,

leather, and garments etc. The study identified a variety of industries in which a high

potential exists. The SAFTA role is important by giving the opportunity to member countries

to achieve economies of scale, diversify their exports net, improves competitiveness. The

study further explored that if SAFTA is fully integrated and Pakistan gets a tariff cut of 15%,

it would bring the highest welfare gains for the people.

Naqvi (2010) applied CGE model using SAM 2002 to investigate the fiscal strictness and

trade liberalization impact on household welfare and inequality. The study explored that

there are two principal effects of export taxes and tariffs. Firstly, they reduce trade volumes

on both the import and export sides. Secondly, they impose economic costs by inducing

resource misallocation. Therefore, if trade-related taxes are eliminated, an economy can

avoid production and consumption distortions. It is an established fact that free trade leads to

enhanced efficiency The case of efficiency for free trade is the converse process to Tariff’s

cost-benefit analysis. The study further discovered that for a small country like Pakistan,

imposing a tariff does not allow it to influence world prices. However, prices for domestic

consumers and domestic producers do rise as a result. Consequently, imports and

consumption are reduced and the production of import substitute increased.

Bouet et al. (2010) used CGE model to investigate the gains and losses of SAFTA (South

Asia from South Asian Free Trade Agreement) to members and non-member countries. The

study analyzed both the situations of including and excluding the products of the sensitive list

in the process of trade liberalization. The results revealed that if trade if liberalized at its full

strength (including all products), it simply results in trade diversion effect. This liberalization

did not seem to be in favor of LDCs of the region. Further, it was discovered that this

liberalization is increasing the income of unskilled labor at a higher rate. The study

concluded that SAFTA is promising a low tariff income for all member countries.

Page 90: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

71

Rashid (2013) utilized CGE models to measure the latest terms of trade for the agriculture

sector comparing it to the industrial sector in Pakistan during the years of 2000-2010 and to

study the impact of agriculture income tax on Pakistan economy by using social accounting

matrix (SAM 2002). The result of the experiment showed a 5% and 10% increase in the

government revenue through the imposition of agriculture tax. The study further elaborated

that manufacturing and imports flourished while construction and exports faced decline. The

labor demand in non-agriculture sector rose whereas the demand for labor in agriculture

sector reduced due to increase in the agriculture income tax.

Robinson and Gueneau (2013) attempted to describe an economy-wide linked CGE model

dynamic in nature and a regional water system model (RWSM). The study used this CGE-W

model to investigate the impact of water stress on the agriculture productivity. The main

focus of the study was to investigate the Indus river water basin water flow and shocks that

ultimately influence the agriculture productivity in Pakistan. The model (RWSM-Pak)

applied on Pakistan is newly developed by the World Bank. The experiments investigated the

changes in water supply due to changes in weather and found that water shocks adversely

affect the agriculture productivity. The study concluded that any change in water supply from

rivers due to weather changes may adversely affect the agriculture sector but the effects can

be minimized by building Diamer-Basha dam on the Indus basin.

Khan et al. (2015) developed a CGE model to investigate the impact of agriculture trade

liberalization (the elimination of import tariff and the removal of export subsidies) on income

inequality of Pakistan. The study adopted the newly developed MyGTAP model developed

by Minor and Walmsley (2013). The model used a two kind of database i.e. GTAP and SAM

(2007-08). This study deeply analyzed the impact of agriculture trade liberalization on

multiple households. The study encompassed 18 households, 12 regions, and 37 sectors. The

result of agriculture trade liberalization suggested that income inequality in Pakistan is

increased by 0.49% from the baseline. Medium and large household types are aided, and

there is a nominal increase in the real wages of medium and large agricultural labors. The

labor intensive crops are replaced by capital intensive and cheap imported products that

ultimately helped to enhance the income inequality in Pakistan.

Page 91: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

72

3.9 Drawbacks in Previous Studies

The study tries to find out the weaknesses and strengths of the previous studies with a focus

to build a foundation and to give new dimensions for future CGE studies on Pakistan and

also tries to avoid those drawbacks highlighted in previous studies.

3.9.1 Limited Focus on Trading Blocks and Especially the European Union

Pakistan is a member of World Trade Organizations (WTO) and like other less developed

countries it is restricted to continue trade liberalization. Only one known study conducted by

Shaikh & Rahpoto (2009) focussed on the impact of trade with a regional trading block

SAFTA by using GTAP database. As mentioned above around 9 studies in Pakistan focused

on trade liberalization. Almost 6 studies which were conducted by PIDE professionals have

tried to examine the impact of trade liberalization on poverty and income discrimination

under different situations. The researchers found that trade liberalization in Pakistan reduced

poverty in the country and increased the level of income for households. Another study on

trade liberalization by Martin et al (2004) used global CGE model and found that the

termination of textiles and clothing quotas from the EU, US, and Canada reduced the income

level in developing countries and especially Pakistan. The European Union is the biggest

trading partner of Pakistan but there is not a single known study that specifically focused on

the issue by using CGE models. CGE model used in this study for Pakistan is built with the

aim to tackle this drawback for the existing CGE literature in Pakistan. This model would be

able to measure the impact of the European Union current policies on the Pakistan economy

as a whole.

3.9.2 Usage of Inadequate Databases

About 9 studies of CGE on Pakistan used inadequate databases. 2 groups have been

developed from these 9 studies. The first group consists of 3 studies that use GTAP databases

and remaining 6 studies focused on trade liberalization and income discrimination that have

been conducted by the PIDE professionals.

The studies that have used GTAP database in Pakistan include (Okuda & Brohi, 2001;

Shaikh & Rahpoto 2009; and Martin et al., 2004). It raises some serious concerns if the

Page 92: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

73

GTAP database was used to develop an I-O table and to develop a global CGE model for

Pakistan. Okuda & Brohi (2001) used GTAP 4 database in order to deduct I-O table for

Pakistan. However, for a single country like Pakistan data was not available in GTAP 4

database. So in order to find out the data for Pakistan, Bangladesh and Maldives, the residual

database was used. So this data was not able to reflect the true image of Pakistan economy.

Martin (2004) developed a global CGE model for Pakistan by using GTAP 5.4 database.

Again the problem was unavailability of data as countries like Bangladesh, Maldives, Nepal

and Bhutan fell in residual data. So it is not certain that these residual values showed the true

image of Pakistan’s economy. Butt (2006) for the first time made serious efforts by

developing PAKREG to introduce Pakistan as a separate country in future GTAP databases.

Remaining studies which were focusing on trade liberalization were based on SAM ranging

from 1989-1990. Without having an import matrix in I-O framework the analysis of trade

liberalization raises doubts in the researcher about the reliability of these results. Khan (2015)

used MyGTAP to utilize the maximum updated SAM for Pakistan. So in order to cope with

this problem, the study is using latest GTAP 09 first time in Pakistan.

3.9.3 Poor Quality of Limited Number of Studies on Regional Issues

There is only one known study conducted by Okuda & Brohi (2001) that developed

multiregional CGE to analyze the impact of policies at the regional level of Pakistan. The

study has some serious drawbacks that may negatively affect the reliability of it for

policymakers. First of all the quality of the database was not very satisfactory. Secondly,

because the data was much aggregated in terms of macroeconomic and only 8 sectors were

identified so, the results were very limited in value terms. Thirdly the study did not identify

the impact of macroeconomic shocks on the variables like aggregate real investment,

aggregate real consumption, the balance of trade, government real expenditures and the

fluctuations in the stock exchange rates and trade policies. Fourthly, it seemed that long run

closure has been followed, but it did not provide information regarding the closure of the

model itself. So the researcher can conclude that no authentic and reliable study on regional

issues by using CGE has been applied till now. The current study is focusing on this issue

too.

Page 93: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

74

3.9.4 Single Model Repetition to Analyze Trade Liberalization

As mentioned above out of 9 studies on trade liberalization of Pakistan 6 were conducted by

the PIDE professionals. These studies were based on SAM but having different production

sectors except Martin at el (2004) used GTAP 5.4, Shaikh (2009) GTAP 07 database in their

study. Only one model cannot be used for analyzing trade liberalization of Pakistan. It was

only Khan (2015) who attempted to perform experiments with new and updated technique in

the absence of latest database with GTAP.

3.9.5 Contradictory Results of Some Studies on Trade liberalization

Siddiqui, et al (1999) from PIDE were the initial researchers who conducted the first study on

trade liberalization in Pakistan. The study found that due to trade liberalization income level

of each household decreased. Siddiqui & Iqbal, (2001) have indicated that as a result of trade

liberalization income level of the household would increase. Siddiqui & Kemal (2002);

Kemal et al (2001); Siddiqui & Kemal (2002) and Kemal et al., (2003) also found that trade

liberalization creates income discrimination but also enhance household welfare.

3.10 Proposed CGE Study in Light of Past Literature Review

In the previous section, many weaknesses have been described in the CGE studies in

Pakistan that create doubts in the minds of policy makers. So in order to remove the

drawbacks of the prior studies, the study is using the updated GTAP 09. There is not even a

single study that has used the impact of FTA between a trading block and Pakistan. This

study is attempting seriously to resolve this issue too. The comparative static CGE model is

more useful for Pakistan in order to find the impact of tariff cuts on Pakistan.

Page 94: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

75

3.11 Summary of Literature Employed CGE Models in Pakistan

Table 3.1 summarizes the history of studies that employed CGE model in the case of

Pakistan.

Table 3.1: Summary of CGE Models History in Pakistan

S.

No.

Author’s

Name and

Date

Policy Focus Identification

scheme Results

1 Fei et al

(1962)

Preliminary

Input-Output

table for industry

I-O table 1955

The first ever developed I-O table

for a large-scale industry which

ultimately helped the researchers to

develop SAM.

2

McCathy &

Taylor

(1980)

Planning food

policy

(subsidies)

SAM 1975-76 Land reforms showed maximum

redistribution effect.

3

Labus

(1988)

Incentives and

public sector

enterprises

SAM 1983-84

Decrease in Aggregate demand

results into declined wages and

rent. The enterprises are getting

profits due to incentives, prices are

going down and improvement in

the current account balance,

exports, and output.

4 Naqvi

(1998)

Energy sector tax

reforms SAM 1983-84

If social equality is not considered,

Kerosene oil is the best commodity

to increase tax revenue but it is

least desirable due to the

beneficiary for low-income people

and natural gas has least welfare

cost so tax revenue can be

increased by this.

Page 95: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

76

5 Vos (1998)

Dutch disease

effect of foreign

aid

SAM 1983-84

Depreciation above equilibrium

will result incost-push inflation

causing a reduction in real income

that ultimately will reduce the

aggregate demand in the economy.

Similarly, there would be strong

Dutch disease effect of foreign aid.

6

Siddiqui

and Iqbal

(1999)

Tariff reduction

and income

distribution

SAM 1989-90

The income reduces due to tariff

cuts but the reduction in poor’s

income is less than the rich

households.

7 Kemal et

al. (2001)

Tariff and

income

distribution

SAM 1989-90

Tariff reduction causing an increase

in imports and reduction in exports

by increasing prices of domestic

products and vice versa. It also

worsens the position of income

distribution but it causes an

increase in household

consumption.

8

Okuda &

Brohi

(2001)

Network of road

Transport and

regional effects

in Pakistan

GTAP 4.0

New road from Karachi to

Peshawar will bring positive

change in the industrial sector of

Punjab and NWFP and GDP will

increase by 16%.

9 Martin et

al (2004)

Consequences of

quota removal on

textile and

clothing

GTAP 5.4

It will bring changes in the

formation of final products and

Pakistan will get benefit from it

only if it employ its resources

efficiently but there is fear of some

welfare loss.

Page 96: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

77

10 Siddiqui

(2005)

Gender-based

impact of

Economic

reforms.

SAM 2000

Liberalization of Agriculture brings

Positive changes in household

income both in urban and rural

areas. It further improves the

economic growth and redistribution

of income in the short run (negative

in the long run).

11 Butt (2006)

Tariff cuts,

exports and

regional

disparities

PAKREG

There is a positive relationship

between tariff cuts and regional

disparities and the impact is greater

during military regimes. Further the

tariff cuts across the border causing

an increase in real GDP.

12

Ahmad

and

O’Donogh

ue (2008)

External Balance

impact on

welfare in

Pakistan

SAM 2002

The external oil price possessed the

high potential to affect Pakistan

socio-economic condition and an

increase in foreign saving decrease

poverty in the country and poverty

is increasing with the increase in

import prices.

13

Shaikh

and

Rahpoto

(2009)

SAFTA

implication on

Pakistan

economy

GTAP 4.0

If SAFTA is fully integrated and

Pakistan gets a tariff cut of 15%, it

would bring the highest welfare

gains for the people.

14 Naqvi

(2010)

Trade

Liberalization

and Fiscal

Strictness

SAM 2002

Trade liberalization through the

abolition of the tariffhas apositive

effect on household welfare and

inequality in Pakistan.

Page 97: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

78

15 Rashid

(2013)

Agriculture

income tax and

economic growth

SAM (2002)

Government revenue increased due

to agriculture income tax.

Manufacturing and imports

flourished while construction and

exports faced decline

1

6

Robinson

and

Gueneau

(2013)

Water Economy

Links

SAM 2006

(CGE-W)

Any change in water supply from

rivers due to weather changes may

adversely affect the agriculture

sector but the effects can be

minimized by building Diamer-

Basha dam on the Indus.

17 Khan (2015)

Agriculture

Trade

Liberalization

and Poverty

My GTAP

Income inequality in Pakistan is

increased by 0.49% from the

baseline. Medium and large

household types are aided, and

there is nominal increase in the real

wages of medium and large

agricultural labors

Page 98: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

79

CHAPTER 4: METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK

The liberalization of world trade and welfare of household living in developing countries are

the two prominent issues figured in international trade negotiations. The question arises that

will liberalized world trade benefit people who live in poverty? This question has motivated

policy debates, especially since the launched of the Doha Development Agenda (DDA)1 in

2001 (Corong, 2014). While assessments on the relationship between global trade

liberalization and poverty levels have proliferated during the last decade [(Hertel & Winters,

2006); (Harrison, 2007); (Anderson et al 2009)], meanwhile analysis on the differential trade

negotiations on the household welfare and economic development in developing countries

like Pakistan remained oblivious.

Any change in output or price of one commodity may bring changes in the output of other

products, government revenue, and expenditures, exports, imports and employment. To

understand the linkages between all sectors of the economy, Computable General

Equilibrium (CGE) models are an ideal tool that has been studied in detail focusing the

issues related to trade negotiations. These models link the factor and product market to the

macroeconomic linkages of saving and investment (Minor & Mureverwi, 2013). A change in

prices in one market can be linked to changes in other markets. Several types of CGE models

are employed for this purpose: some are dynamic, emphasizing the impacts of investment

and year-on-year growth rates in industry and trade (based on projections); others are static

modeling investment purchases, but not the impacts of investment on productive capacity

growth over time.

This chapter intends to explain the methodology for the research. The purpose of this chapter

is two fold: firstly, to develop an understanding of Computable general equilibrium modeling

by examining different definitions, evolution and historical background of CGE modeling;

secondly, discusses the Global Trade Analysis project (GTAP) along with MyGTAP, its

structure, the accounting relationships and the behavioral equations.

1 It is round of trade negotiation of the World Trade Organization’s (WTO) aiming to facilitate and increase the

world trade through removal of trade barriers.

Page 99: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

80

4.1 Historical Background of the CGE Modelling

History of CGE modeling starts from Johansen, (1960) when he presented the first model

containing a household sector with utility maximization and twenty industries with cost

minimizing. The model explained that production and consumption decisions are strongly

influenced by the price factor while the model determined the price using the market

equilibrium assumptions. Ultimately he developed a mathematical multi-sectoral model

describing the growth in Norway. The study applied Frisch’s (1959) additive utility model

while using the household price estimates and elasticity of income in the Input and Output (I-

O) data table. The researchers, later on, followed the work of Johansen (1960). The ORANI

model of Australia Dixon et al (1977) and Dixon et al (1982) was the succession of

Johansen’s model that ultimately became the reason of GTAP (Global Trade Analysis

Project) model having global linkages of the economy with rest of the world.

Extensive use of CGE model was witnessed by 1970s and 1980s. The modelers focused on

the analysis of economic development problems of the developing countries. By elaborating

the treatment of income distribution, foreign trade, and several policy instruments, these

models extended the coverage of CGE models. Beyond the concept of Walrasian, several

modelers1 extended the CGE model by adding ‘structuralist’ features in it. Development of

large number of CGE models and their use for analyzing policy is because of appropriate

software development and fast computers. Analysis of every policy like agricultural, major

tax reforms, the amendment in trade policy regimes and economic integration are included in

this application. In developing countries, there are several policy issues and to illuminate

them a great number of CGE models have been designed2.

The most important source of stimulation for CGE modeling was the primal-dual solution to

linear programming models of country wide resource allocation and its competitive general

equilibrium. For the economic policy analysis, there was the extensive usage of linear

programming models during the era of the 1960s and 1970s. A distinctive method of activity

1 For example, (Taylor & Black, 1974); Taylor & Lysy (1979).

2 The work of Devarajan et al (1997) for developing countries.

Page 100: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

81

analysis approach to CGE models was developed from linear programming tradition

(Ginsburgh & Waelbroeck, 1981).

Scarf (1969) made a great breakthrough in the history of CGE modeling by introducing an

algorithm for the solution of general equilibrium problems. Detailed and complex general

equilibrium models were developed in the early 1970s and these models could be solved

computationally. Steady progress in the power of computers made possible, how to give

solution and develop large models. After this advancement algorithm was improved and its

refined version was introduced. In mathematical economies, a new research area of

developing simpler and powerful version of general equilibrium was started but its real

essence or heart remains same as it was algorithm presented by Scarf (1969)1.

Shoven & Whalley (1972) presented the first applications of computational general

equilibrium. Computational models are allowed to be more sophisticated and practical

because of the flexibility of giving a solution to the algorithm and it leads to numerical

answering to complicated questions. Policy issues of tax reforms and international trade are

addressed by them and they follow earlier analytical models. Many modelers followed the

Shoven-Whalley version of CGE model and in this context, it mentions three lines of

research. The first one was followed by many representative articles and it included United

States economy’s multi-sector energy model which was developed by Jorgenson et al (1974)

and after that Jorgenson and several associates made amendments in it2.

Two significant

contributions were made by it even it was not similar to the original model of Walrasian, the

first contribution was the introduction of more accurate functional forms, having much

approximation to reality which leads to systematic treatment of technological progress and

other includes the dependency of the model on the economic estimation of various sub

model’s parameters.

The second line of research was started by Manne & Preckel (1983) who developed the

treatment of dynamic issues. By specifying the cost and constraints attached with fractional

1 For more details please see (Todd, 1984)

2 For details please see (Jorgenson & Fraumeni, 1981), (Jorgenson & Slesnick, 1985), Jorgenson (1984).

Page 101: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

82

adjustment on the part of economic agents and providing solutions to the model as a

complete inter-temporal optimization. Initially, it was focusing the area of energy policy only

but later it extended to the trade and development areas of the economy. The main

distinctiveness of these models was: a strong focus on dynamic issues, integration at a low

level and simple functional formation are the distinctive features of these models. Manne &

Preckel (1983) presented the model of economic growth with three regions with a simple

structure. This model provides the insight of trade issues between countries producing oil,

less developed, and developed ones.

The work done by Shoven & Whalley (1984) did not attain the same degree of details as

work of Jorgenson & Slesnick (1985) and Manne & Preckel (1983). Manne & Preckel

(1983) emphasized the pedagogical role of the model. It shows the comparatively better way

of presenting the importance of some interactions or feedback instead of attempting to

calculate the impact of policy issues. Furthermore, he tried to highlight the importance of

presenting those interactions or feedbacks that normally are not considered important during

policy debates. In this way, this factor becomes the most significant for the success of CGE

models and to answer why these models are more practical.

The third line of research was developed from the multi-sector planning models being

popularly used by development economists and supported by the World Bank (Blitzer et al

1975). This has contributed significantly to the development of the CGE models. To examine

the structural issues of the developing countries, the economists and policy makers have been

dealing with the disaggregated model. Extensions of the Leontief model complemented

sophisticated models of consumer expenditures. International trade was the basis of the initial

approach. The concept of Social Accounting Matrices (SAM)1 was developed to achieve a

completely consistent framework. It was simple and comprehensive to adopt the general

equilibrium assumptions. It further helped the policy makers to resolve the problems of

economic development in detail. Devarajan et al 1986) worked on the comprehensive

bibliography of this type of work.

1 SAM is a method of describing in detail whole transactions in the economy keeping in view the balance

between income and expenditures.

Page 102: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

83

CGE approach is very near to practical policy issues. The models are not meant to use as

policy measures for scientific or academic point, rather they provide assistance in the form of

recommendations to design a policy decision made by world bank or governments. These

models mainly address the questions related to international trade- i.e., the introduction of

export subsidies or tariffs in a particular country. The results obtained by these models

provide a better understanding of key factors through certain outcomes on one side may

check the outcomes of alternative options through simulation.

In addition to the three lines of research mentioned above, many researchers have applied

this approach to new problems and countries. Moreover, many modelers adopted the

approach of combining some advantages of three approaches. Goulder & Borges (1984)

made an attempt to combine the Shoven & Whalley (1984) custom with the more modern

adaptable practical structures utilized by Jorgenson & Slesnick (1985) as a part of their USA

energy policy model. They likewise utilized the particular constraints connected with the

presence of consumable assets. This research also provides the results associated with the

impact of higher energy prices along with the impact of taxes on energy prices and hence

economy.

To build the ORANI model a different approach was utilized, for this purposes a large model

with multi-purpose was built to address the large and small issues of the economy. This

model was considered most useful for policy options in Australia (Dixon et al 1982).

A new type of application was introduced by Mohammad & Whalley (1984), which tried to

measure the effects of government interventions and distortions associated with the agents on

the economic performance. This application played an important role in policy decisions.

This approach clearly benefited from the Shoven & Whalley (1984) model. It shows that

“rent seeking” behavior of the economic agent is not to maximize the national output or

income but to increase its own share in the national economy by using national resources and

creating distortions.

Page 103: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

84

The above discussion although did not cover the history of CGE models comprehensively.

The purpose of this section was to introduce some studies that utilized this approach by

applying different techniques and reasoning, to address different issues associated with

different economies. Hence it fulfilled its purpose of a brief history of CGE modeling.

4.2 Defining the CGE Model

There is no accurate definition of Computable General Equilibrium models1. It is a kind of

economic models that incorporates with economic data to estimate the effects of a policy

change, change in the technology of changes in external variables on the economy. It is a

multi-sector model based on real data from one or many economies. Secondly, the model

explains the explicit information about the behavior of economic agents. Further, it

represents the households as utility maximizers and firms as profit maximizers or cost

minimizers. The role of factor/commodity prices is highlighted through such optimized

assumptions. Decision made by firms and households for production and consumption are

influenced by price level that ultimately explains the mechanism of price setting through

demand and supply forces. At the end, the CGE models produce numerical results. Lastly,

the main advantage of CGE models is that they produce numerical results. The parameters

and coefficients in the related equations are estimated with reference to the numerical

database. The vital part of the data which is the base of the model is generally a set of inputs

and outputs; these are accounts that show the flow of factors and goods among industries for

a specific time period.

The most precise definition available in literature is by Shoven & Whalley (1984) and is as

follows:

“CGE model is one in which all market clear simultaneously”.

Although the definition by (Shoven & Whalley, 1984) has serious flaws it still gives the basic

idea about CGE models. In CGE models unemployment can be allowed, therefore, it does

not necessarily suggest that all markets are clear. The same criticism applies to the definition

1 Sometimes called Applied General Equilibrium (AGE) models. However, international trade theory normally

is considered as an application of CGE models.

Page 104: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

85

of Borges (1986) quoted in the subsequent discussion. According to Robinson (1988), if a

model strictly contains four elements then it is called a CGE model. These four elements are

as follows:

a) Well defined economic agents whose analysis of behavior is required.

b) Conditions and rules of their behavior, under which they function, for example, utility

maximization of consumer and profit maximization of producers, are clearly

identified.

c) Identification of the factors that affect the decision-making power of the economic

agents like prices.

d) Recognition of the prevalent structure of the economy such as perfect competition.

Another modeler, Borges (1986) defined the CGE in the following words:

“Based on the Walrasian tradition, applied general equilibrium models describe the

allocation of resources in a market economy as the result of the interaction of supply and

demand, leading to equilibrium prices. The building blocks of these models are equations

representing the behavior of the relevant agents -- consumers, producers, the government,

etc. Each one of these agent demands or supplies goods, services and factors of production,

as a function of their prices. Assuming that market forces will lead to equilibrium between

supply and demand, the general equilibrium model computes the prices that clear all

markets, and determines the allocation of resources and the distribution of incomes that

result from this equilibrium.”

Distinguishing characteristics of CGE model of an economy were described by Shoven &

Whalley (1984) as follows:

a) In an economy, there are n produced commodities in n markets.

b) By assuming that consumers maximize utility subjected to their budget limit, the

demand side of the economy can be derived.

c) Producers maximize their profits and by assuming that production side of the

economy is derived.

Page 105: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

86

d) Generally, non-increasing or constant return to scale technology is assumed

(Increasing returns to scale and imperfect competition can also be included into CGE

models; (see Harris (1984).

e) The demand for any commodity satisfies Walras’Law and is non-negative,

continuous, homogenous of degree zero and depends on all prices.

On the behalf of above discussion, it can be said that across market subject to instructional

and behavioral constraint CGE model simulates that interaction of different economics

agents. For further details, please see Dixon et al (1982) and Shoven & Whalley (1992).

Since modern version of Walras model of the competitive economy is CGE models. The

unique feature of general equilibrium modeling of considering the economy as a set of agents

is derived from Walrasian general economic equilibrium theory. Under a given set of income

distribution and initial endowment, these agents interact in several markets for an equal

number of commodities and by optimizing its own profit, cost objectives or utility every

agent defines its behavior of demand and supply. Walras Law i.e. “The global identity of

income and expenditure is fulfilled by the set of excess supply functions which is a yield of

their decisions. Supply and demand are hiring in equilibrium by a set of prices under same

general equilibrium conditions and this is proved by Arrow & Debreu (1954).

The real side of the economy is focused on CGE models, so financial assets markets are not

included in them, and this is among one of the several differences between CGE models and

others numerically based models (Ljungqvist & Sargent, 2000). Therefore relative product,

the real exchange rate, and factor prices are determined by CGE model usually, however,

nominal prices and nominal exchange rate cannot be determined by that. In other words,

CGE models do not aim to explain business cycle instead they are aimed at growth paths and

illustrating equilibrium resource allocation. On the relative prices of goods or factors and

equilibrium allocation of resources, the impact of specific policies is aimed by CGE models.

However, some modelers extended CGE model beyond the original Walrasian model to

cover the imperfection of markets. That is why, to highlight the flexibility of the computable

Page 106: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

87

general equilibrium models, some modelers used the term general equilibrium programming

(Zalai, 1982) or generalized equilibrium modeling (Nesbitt, 1984).

According to Savarad (2003), CGE Models are considered very useful tool if one tries to

investigate the consequences of policy reforms on the public in terms of poverty, inequality

etc. Different sectors of the economy are interlinked in the CGE framework. Contrarily, the

economic theory is unable to furnish such detailed analysis of the policy reforms. Winters et

al (2004) and Harrison et al (2010) confirmed that the economic theory is insufficient if one

tries to investigate the inter-sectoral effects of a government policy reform. Blake (1998)

indicated that in the neoclassical model, consumer intends to maximize its utility level while

the firms/producers are eager to maximize the profit by cost minimizing and adapting the

behavior of average pricing and CGE models follow the same behavior. There is a system of

equations on which the Computable General Equilibrium models are based that link the

different sectors of the economy as explained by Bandara (1991). Similarly, Shaikh et al

(2012) revealed that while capturing the inter-sectoral linkages or the interactions at the

macro level both CGE and AGE models are consistent internally. While Adams et al (1998)

further disclosed that the CGE model not only integrates different sectors but also contains a

lot of behavioral equations. When a change occurs in the price level, the system of equations

integrates to calculate the change in the behavior of consumer and producer. This system of

equations is solved by using different software packages like GAMS, GEMPACK,

MATLAB etc.

CGE models are considered more useful while analyzing the trade policy changes. When

government brings a change in the trade policy, the equations in the model instantly integrate

and calculate the possible outcomes in different sectors of the economy. Although the CGE

models are considered complex and artificial in nature but important to calculate the inter-

sectoral impact within an economy and between other economies (Kehoe & Kehoe, 1994).

Partial equilibrium models on the other hand based on time series data containing limited

endogenous variables.

Page 107: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

88

4.3 Multi-Country Models (GTAP Model)

Multi-country or global models consist of multiple countries or the total global economy

(Wobst, 2001). These models tend to have fewer sector details and are designed for analysis

of proposed multi-lateral policies such as free-trade agreements. Moreover, these models do

not maintain a single country model assumption of exogenising global or trading partner

effects. Therefore, the implications of these effects - coming from rest of the world or other

countries - have been endogenised. Any effects, transmitted to by means of various channels,

of policy changes in the rest of the world, would have direct in addition to indirect influence.

These models explicitly capture this transmission mechanism. Therefore, these models can

be applied in policy experiments of multilateral trade liberalization. The Global Trade

Analysis Project (GTAP) model is the most widely known modeling system of multi-country

models. GTAP is a multi-sector, multi-region, computable general equilibrium model1 with

perfect competition and returns to scale (McDougall et al 1998). This model is being

employed for a number of applications (international trade, agricultural analysis, labor

markets, etc).

The GTAP model is a linear model built on the neoclassical theories and is comparative

static in nature. In order to perform the analysis at the country level, it uses the common

global database. The model exhibits a utility maximizing and constant return to scale

condition for all households and firms profit and considers that all markets are perfectly

competitive. To solve the model, GEMPACK software is used (Harrison & Pearson, 1996).

In reality, the GTAP model is a multi-region CGE model aimed to deal with trade policy

reforms with the help of comparative static analysis as explained by Adams et al (1998).

The centerpiece of the GTAP model is the internally consistent database with a base year that

is provided by the individuals of the representative economies on input-output table. In

addition to that, the data related to trade, tariffs, quotas etc is provided by the experts. A

single regional household with aggregate utility functions is the governing tool of the GTAP.

This regional household is assumed to receive income from the domestic firm in exchange of

1 there are some applications to partial equilibrium analysis

Page 108: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

89

its endowment commodities. The regional expenditures are distributed among savings,

personal and government expenditures. To produce the goods for final demand, endowment

commodities are combined with the intermediate commodities by the firms. The produced

goods are assumed to be purchased by the government and private household that also

purchase the capital goods against the household savings. Open economy version further

includes the global bank and the transport and trade activities where global bank deals with

the regional investment and global saving by creating a composite investment good that is

supplied to the regional households to satisfy their saving demands.

The GTAP model includes a non-standard “Constant Difference of Elasticity (CDE)”

expenditure function. The advantages of a CDE function is that it models well a variety of

consumption patterns found at differing income levels. That is to say, it generates classical

"Engels" curves which are characterized by shifting consumption between necessities and

luxury goods. While the CDE provides a good basis for modeling private consumption across

a broad range of households and countries, it is not ideal for modeling extreme situations,

where poverty and subsistence expenditures are dominant. Subsistence expenditures are

defined as a share of expenditure being tied to a specific consumption bundle, which must be

consumed no matter what changes in prices and incomes may arise in the simulation (Minor

& Mureverwi, 2013).

In this study along with standard GTAP model, we will also use MyGTAP linking the

Pakistan economy with rest of the world. This model was developed by Walmsley and Minor

(2013) and is extended version of standard GTAP developed by (Hertel & Tsigas, 1997).

Single regional household along with related distribution parameters are eliminated in

MyGTAP and are replaced by directly linking the expenditures incurred by government and

private household to the income sources. Similarly, in order to analyze the distributional

impacts for policy recommendations, multiple households are placed instead of the single

private household. The extended model also helps the government to calculate the impact of

subsidies on the government budget that help the policy makers to decide the income

treatments. It further incorporates the regional remittances and capital income abroad (Siddig

et al, 2014).

Page 109: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

90

4.4 Working of GTAP 9 Database

Against the previous GTAP databases, the latest version that released in May 2015, contains

three reference years, 2004, 2007 and 2011. The GTAP 8 contained 2 reference years 2004,

and 2007 while all of the previous years had only one base year. Similarly, the latest database

contains 140 regions with 57 sectors as against of the previous version with 129 regions and

57 sectors. The standard countries have been increased to 244 from 226 and have been

aggregated into 140 regions. It is very important to note that latest version has updated the

database of Pakistan along with 18 other countries only, adjusting the other data with 2011

base year. For further details of the aggregation schemes, please see appendix 1.

The data on GDP, private consumption, government consumption and investment was taken

from the World Bank and was used for updating the input-output tables. Penn World Tables

version 8.0.3 provided the data on the physical stock and depreciation. International Energy

Agency (IEA) provided the energy data and agriculture export subsidy data was taken from

World Trade Organization (WTO), Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) and

International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI). Trade data for the GTAP member

economies was obtained from Comtrade and was combined with same data obtained from

IMF to improve the data quality. Protection data related to output subsidies, input subsidies,

land-based payments, labor-based payments and capital-based payments was obtained from

Institute for Prospective Technological Studies (IPTS).

4.5 GTAP Standard Model: Income Expenditure Global Accounts

A large number of equations are required for the GTAP model. The underlying equation

areof two types of which the first deals with the accounting relationship and its work is to

balance the receipts and expenditure of every agent in the economy, while the second type of

equations deals with the behavior of the optimizing agent.

Page 110: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

91

Figure 0.1: The Standard GTAP Model

Source: Walmsley & Minor 2013; Based on Brockmeier 1996.

4.5.5 The Standard GTAP Model and the Accounting Relationships

The basic notations and equations of the GTAP model will be discussed in this section along

with the intuition behind the GTAP model and offers a detailed picture of the accounting

relationships. The first segment of the accounting relationships in the GTAP model is the

distribution of the firm’s sale to the regional market. In the open economy version of the

GTAP model, firms combine primary factors (endowment commodities) with intermediate

inputs to produce final goods for sale to the domestic market as well as to the international

market. The model is derived from GTAP source developed by Hertel & Tsigas (2000).

4.5.6 Distribution of Sales to the Regional Markets

Sectors and commodities have one to one relationship in the GTAP model. The only single

output is assumed to be produced by each sector in the model. Firms produce and sell output

to domestic as well as to the regional markets. The value of firm’s output at the agent’s price

is given in the equation 4.1 in appendix 2.

Page 111: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

92

“VOA(i, r)” is the output value at the agent’s price that shows the payments received by

firms in region ‘r’ in the ith industry. “PS(i, r)” is the price index of ‘i’ in the region ‘r’ and

“QO(i, r)” is the quantity index of ‘i’ in region ‘r’. The model added the producer’s tax

“PTAX (i, r)” to obtain the value of the output at the market prices from the value of output.

The equation 4.2 in appendix 2 represents it where “VOM(i, r)” is the firm’s output value at

the market price which is the sum of the value of domestic sale “VDM(i, r), value of exports

of “i” from region ‘r’ to all the destinations in ‘s’ “VXMD(i, r, s) and sale to international

transport sector “VST(i, r)”. The exports tax (XTAX) in equation 4.3 in appendix 2 is added to

express exports as fob-based value. Similarly, the value “VXWD (i, r, s)” represent the

exports at the fob price of ‘i’ exported from region ‘r’ to ‘s’ and “VXMD(i, r, s)” shows the

of exports at the domestic market price.

4.5.6.1 International Transportation Margin

The international transportation margin is the difference when the value of import is

calculated with CIF (Cost, insurance, and freight) and value of export is calculated at FOB

(Freight on Board) as shown in equation 4.4 in appendix 2. Where “VIWS(i,r,s)” shows the

value of the world imports and “MTAX (i, r, s) represent the import tax that is added in the

“VIMS (i, r, s)” in order to calculate the value of transaction at international commodity in

domestic price. Hence we get equation 4.5 in appendix 2.

A single composite import good and its value are allocated among three sources of import

demand that consist of the imports of commodity ‘i’ to region ‘s’ from three different

sources. That is value of imports of ‘i’ in region ‘s’ imported by ‘private household’

evaluated at the market price “VIPM(i, s)” further the value of imports by firms in ‘s’

“VIFM((i, s)” and the value of imports at the market price by the government “VIGM(i, s)”.

This relationship is represented by equation 4.6 in appendix 2.Where, the value of imports of

industry ‘i’ from region ‘r’ to region‘s’ is represented by “VIM (i, s)”.

In the GTAP model, the accounting relationships also identify the sources of households’

purchases to establish a link between industrial output and household expenditure on that

Page 112: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

93

output. The following section explains the sources of household purchases in the GTAP

model.

4.5.7 Source of Household Purchases in the GTAP Model

In order to finalize the relationship between household purchases and industrial production in

the GTAP model, it is assumed to distribute the total household expenditures on good ‘i’ in

region ‘s’. Equation 4.7 in appendix 2 represents the value of household (private) purchases

“VPA (i, s)”of commodity ‘i’ from region ‘s’ at agent price. These household purchases

consist of expenditure of household on domestic commodities (VDP) as well as on the

composite imports (VIPA) at the agent price. The value of private purchases at market price

can be calculated very easily from the private purchases. In a similar way, we may model the

government purchases by distributing the government purchases into domestically produced

goods and composite imports.

4.5.8 Firm’s Purchase Sources

In the previous section, we highlighted the way, firm’s sale is allocated between firm’s sale

to the domestic market as well as its sale to the international market. The firm’s sale of ‘i’ of

region ‘r’ to region ‘s’ can also be termed as expenditure on imports in ‘s’ which is

distributed between private household, government and firm’s expenditure. Firms in region

‘s’ purchase primary factors of production as well as intermediate goods from the domestic

market. So total purchases of the firm in region ‘s’ can be decomposed into firm’s

expenditure on domestic inputs and firm’s expenditure on imported inputs.

Equation 4.8 in appendix 2 explains the Value of firm’s Purchase of ‘i’ in ‘s’ evaluated at

agents’ price where “VFA(i,j,s)” stands for the value of firm’s purchase in sector ‘j’ of input

‘i’ in region ‘s’ evaluated at agent’s price. The right hand side of the equation contains the

two terms that represent the two components of the firm’s purchases evaluated at the agent’s

price which can be expressed in terms of the market price by deducting the intermediate

input taxes ‘DFTAX(i,j,s)’ (tax on the purchase of domestic inputs of ‘i’ in sector ‘j’ in region

‘s’ and IFTAX(i,j,s)) (tax on the imports of intermediate and primary inputs from region ‘r’).

The endowment commodities in the GTAP model can also be evaluated both at agent as well

Page 113: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

94

as the market price which includes the firm’s purchases of non-tradable commodities like

land, labor and capital.

4.5.8.1 Linking the firm’s receipts and purchase and the zero profit condition

The equation 4.9 in the appendix 2 shows the above relation, where looking at the right-hand

side of the equation, the first term represents the firm’s expenditure on tradable commodities

summed over ‘i’ tradable inputs and the second term shows the total expenditure on its

purchase of the endowment commodities evaluated at the agent’s price. The left-hand side of

the equation is the firm’s total receipts by ‘sector ‘j’ in ‘s’ evaluated at the agent’s price from

its sale of output. It is worthy to note here that in GTAP model, all receipts of the firm must

be exhausted on firm’s expenditure in order to satisfy the zero profit condition.

4.5.9 Sources of Household (HH) Factors Service Income

The Endowment Commodities can be grouped into a mobile endowment that earns same

market returns and an immobile endowment that earn differential returns. See equations 4.10,

4.11 and 4.12 in appendix 2 along with brief details.

4.5.10 Regional Income and Border Involvement in the GTAP Framework

Border intervention by exports and border intervention by imports are included in the border

interventions in the GTAP model. In determining the regional income both interventions

have their concerns. When subsidy is given on exports, then the domestic price of exports

“PM(i,r)” is greater than the fob-based price of exports “PFOB(i,r,s)” and regional income

decreases. This border intervention by exports and its impact on regional income is

represented by the equation 4.13 in appendix 2. When tax is levied on exports of ‘i’ from

region ‘r’ to region ‘s’, the international price of exports is higher than the domestic price of

exports. The regional income increases because the government collects positive revenue

from tax on exportable goods.

Similarly, the case of border intervention with imports and regional income is represented by

equation 4.14 in appendix 2. When the market price of importable goods “PMS(i,r,s)” in the

market (s) is higher than the world price of importable goods PCIF(i,r,s), it indicates the

Page 114: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

95

presence of import tax on imports supplied from region ‘r’ to region ‘s’. In this case, the

import border intervention positively contributes to the regional income. The contribution in

government revenue and regional income is negative in case of subsidy on imports from

region ‘r’, the market price of imports in region ‘s’ supplied from the source region “r” is less

than their price in the source region.

4.5.11 The GTAP Model and the Global Sectors

4.5.11.1 Global Transport Sector

This sector is introduced in the GTAP model to account for the differences between the

values of exports of good ‘i’ supplied from region ‘r’ to region ‘s’ evaluated at the world

price (fob-based value) and the value of imports of the same good supplied from region ‘r’ to

region ‘s’ at the world price (cif-based value). The difference between the two values is

called the international transport margin shown in equation 4.15 in appendix 2, where “VIWS

(i,r,s)” is the value of imports of good ‘i’ from region ‘r’ to region ‘s’ evaluated at the world

price and “VXWD (i,r,s)” is the value of exports from ‘r’ to ‘s’ at the world domestic price.

This sector accumulates the regional exports of transport equipment along with the insurance

services to a make composite transport good that is used to carry the merchandise among the

regions. The individual regional economies export the transport services to the global

transport sector and the appropriate summation of these transport specific goods and all the

routes, yields the total demand for world transport services. Equation 4.16 in appendix 2

summarizes the relationships

4.5.11.2 The Global Bank

The Global Banking sector is required in the GTAP model as an intermediate between global

saving and investment. A composite investment good is produced in the global bank that is

based on net portfolio investments of the respective regions. The global bank offers these

composite investment goods to the regional households at a common price to meet their

saving demands. That is; the regional saver households face a common price of their savings

and by the virtue of Walras’ Law, global savings must equal to global investment to satisfy

the accounting relationships. Equation 4.17 in appendix 2 summarize this relationship and

Page 115: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

96

equation 4.18 in appendix 2 shows the value of ending capital stock. Further details are

available in the appendix 2.

4.5.12 Equilibrium Condition in the GTAP Model

In order to convert the GTAP model into general equilibrium model, economists have used

the terms of quantities rather using the values. Hertel et al (2010) showed the accounting

relationships in terms of values that have been discussed above, embody the equilibrium

conditions that make the model a general equilibrium model in nature. We can easily convert

these accounting relationships into exhaustive accounting relationship by converting into

quantities by considering a common domestic price. The equilibrium condition for traded

goods is given in the equation 4.19 in appendix 2 and accounting relationships in terms of

quantities by introducing a common price are given in equation 4.20 in appendix 2. Similar,

exercise can also be applied for non-tradable commodities to verify that and all the relations

are exhaustive in nature and satisfy the necessary general equilibrium conditions in the

GTAP Model.

4.5.13 Linearized Representation of Accounting Equations

The above-discussed accounting relationships in the GTAP model are nonlinear in nature.

However, the accounting relationships should be linearized in order to implement the GTAP

model. Hertel & Tsigas (1997) have shown that the linearization of the non-linearized model

involves total differentiation of the equations. The transformed equations are simply alinear

combination of the weighted price and quantity changes. To covert these transformed

equations into value terms, the equations are multiplied by the common price. The first

accounting equation in the GTAP model in this fashion is the equation for the tradable

market clearing condition equation 4.22 in appendix 2.

The variable is indexed over all tradable goods and all regions. The domestic market for

tradable commodities can be decomposed into ‘domestic market for imports from region ‘r’

and ‘domestic market for domestically produced goods’ in region ‘s’ in the GTAP model.

Page 116: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

97

Similarly, Market equilibrium in the domestic market for imports from region ‘r’ is

summarized in equation 4.23 in appendix 2 and Market equilibrium in the domestic market

for domestically produced goods is represented in equation 4.24 in appendix 2. The usage of

lower case letters in the equation shows the percentages changes in the respective variables

weighted by the values of respective quantities evaluated at the market price. The left-hand

side variable shows the percentage in the quantity of the domestically produced goods

weighted by the value of the domestically goods valued at the market price.

Equation 4.25 in appendix 2 represents the market clearing conditions for non-tradable

endowment commodities. The GTAP model decomposes primary factors (non-tradable

endowments) into mobile and sluggish factors. Further, the accounting relationships and

market clearing conditions in the new version for the two types of endowment commodities

(mobile and immobile) are explained in equation 4.25 and 4.26 in appendix 2.

4.5.14 Macroeconomic Closures

Most of the static AGE models deals with the macroeconomic policies and the issues related

to monetary policies but GTAP model simulates effects of the trade policy and the shocks

relating to the resources and calculates the impact on the international trade and production

patterns at the global level in the medium term. A number of macroeconomic closures are

required to be fixed to operationalize the GATP database and models. This model is neither

considered as an international one (McKibbin & Sachs, 1991) nor it is meant to obtain a

series of equilibrium (Burniaux & Mensbrugghe, 1994). There is nothing to capture the

impact of investment on the productivity in next time periods as well. However, it requires

some attention because keeping in mind the final demand, investment affects productivity

across the regions. Sen (1963) defined it the problem of “Macroeconomic closure” because

we are unable to find an international mechanism that may determine the investment. In

comparative static models, Dewatripont & Michel (1987) brought four possible solutions to

the investment indeterminist problem. The three closures are neoclassical in nature where

investment can be fixed simply and rest of the sources are allowed to adjust while in fourth

closure it is permitted to the investment to adjust but instead of adding an investment

relationship independently, it is adjusted according to the savings. There are some applied

Page 117: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

98

equilibrium models that have no such closure (Hertel & Tsigas 1997) rather they fix the

current account balance as macroeconomic closure allowing the domestic saving to move in

acircle with the changes in investment. It is important to understand the identity of national

income accounts suggested by Dornbusch (1980).

S - I X + R - M --------------(4.65)

The identity describes the difference between regional saving (S) and investment (I) which is

exactly equal to the current account surplus. ‘X’ represents exports and ‘M’ is for imports.

The term ‘R’ represents the receipts of international transfers. In our GTAP framework, there

is no ‘R’, so we set it equal to zero. If we fix the right-hand side (RHS) of the equation, the

left-hand side will also be fixed.

Equation 4.65 explains the above situation in detail where the RHS of the equation is fixed

on the regional basis. Although there is no global bank that may act as an intermediary to

balance the saving and investment at the global level, but the equality is assured at the global

level in the new equilibrium between the saving and investment. In short, the approach seems

neoclassical closure because investment is forced to change according to the changes in

regional savings as described by Dewatripont & Michel (1987).

In the GTAP framework, the global bank purchases the shares of regional investment goods

in the portfolio using the receipts coming from the homogenous savings commodities that are

assumably sold to the regional household. The global closure is neoclassical in nature in the

model because whenever there is any change in global savings, the portfolio adjusts to

accommodate it. Nevertheless, a little adjustment is permitted in the investment mix on

regional basis by including one more dimension in the model that may determine the change

in investment.

4.5.15 Data Sources Used in Creating the GTAP Database

According to Philip, (2013), two types of data sources are used in the GTAP database. The

regional input-output table received from the GTAP member economies and the data

collected from international organizations such as UN Comtrade database that provide the

Page 118: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

99

merchandise and service data for GTAP member economies, World Development Indicators

provide data for GDP, data on private consumption, gross fixed capital formation

government consumption, capital stock and depreciation data, data related to tariffs is taken

from International Tariff Commission and International Trade Center (ITC), energy data is

taken from International Energy Agency (IEA) and IMF and local governments provide data

related to income and taxes.

4.6 MyGTAP Database

The study has linked the latest available comprehensive Social Accounting Matrix (SAM)

2007-08 developed by International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) to the latest

extension of the standard GTAP to make it MyGTAP.

Figure 0.2: Flows of Income and Expenditures in MyGTAP Model

Source: Minor & Walmsley 2012.

Page 119: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

100

The newly developed MyGTAP1 explains that government collects revenue from taxes and

foreign aid to spend on government expenditures, funding foreign governments, providing

subsidies and transferring to households. Budget deficit or surplus is decided on the basis of

the difference between government spending and income. Income sources for private

households, on the other hand, are a function of returns to factor endowments (land, labor

and capital), net rent on foreign capital and foreign remittances, transfer payments made by

the government and other households. The household net income is either spent or save.

4.6.5 Relationships in MyGTAP Model

The study has already explained the source of the database in MyGTAP. As discussed earlier,

the standard GTAP is modified to make it MyGTAP where the single regional household is

replaced with the multiple private households along with a separate government sector for

one region (Walmsley & Minor, 2013). Just like in the case of standard GTAP, the private

households receive income from factors, but in MyGTAP, it also incorporates foreign

remittances and capital, which is further used for consumption and saving purpose. The new

model assumes that the government sector gains income (GOVINC) from taxes (TTAX) and

foreign aid in (AIDI). Government income is consumed on the transfers to the private

household (TRNG) and foreign aid out (AIDO). Moreover, government entertains the

receiving of foreign aid instead of the direct acceptance by the private households (Minor &

Walmsley (2012).

The income received by the government is used to fund government expenditure (equation

4.109) and government savings (equation 4.110).

1 Developed and used by Khan et al, (2015)

Page 120: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

101

The government faces deficit or saving on the basis of the difference between government

expenditures and income (equation 4.111). One can assume that the share of government

expenditure in income remains constant or can specify alternative assumptions by fixing the

government deficit.

(4.111)

In case of private households, the income is received from factors (EVOAH), then

depreciation (VDEPH) is subtracted, net foreign labor remittances (REMIH and REMOH)

and foreign capital income (FYIH and FYOH) is added, then added the transfers between

households (TRNH) and transfers from the government (TRNG) (Equation 4.112).

Using Cobb Douglas just like in the standard GTAP model, each private household’s income

is allocated to private consumption and savings. In similar way, regional savings are

calculated adding up all the private household savings with government’s savings (equation

4.113) and allocated across investment.

It is to be noted that the value of savings is no longer the same as that in the standard GTAP

database because remittances and other foreign transfers have altered incomes, while

expenditures on commodities remain the same. In order to ensure the balance between

expenditures and income, savings is adjusted (Minor & Walmsley, 2012).

Page 121: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

102

4.6.6 Inter-regional Transfers

The foreign income flows are not bilateral, instead, flows in and out of a country/region are

provided. The work was initially undertaken by Sonmez et al, (2011) and then utilized by

(Khan et al 2015).

4.6.6.1 Remittances

It is assumed that the remittances that flow out of a country (remoh), change with average

wages of skilled and unskilled labor (psh) and any changes in the endowment of labor (qoh)

(Equation 4.114).1

The remittances that flow in of every country (remih) are then adjusted (equation 4.115) to

ensure that total remittances “coming in” and “going out” are equal (Equations 4.116).

remohh,r (4.116)

Equation 4.116 determines ‘remih’ and all remittances in ‘remih’ change by the average

equation 4.115).2 By altering the closure remittances out can be fixed or remittances in can be

fixed and remittances out adjust to again ensure that total remittances in equal total

remittances out (Minor & Walmsley, 2012).

1 Variables ‘sremoh’ and ‘remavo’ are exogenous and equal to zero in the standard closure. (Minor &

Walmsley, 2012)

2 Variable ‘sremih’ is exogenous and equal to zero in the standard closure.

Page 122: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

103

4.6.6.2 Foreign Income

In the same way, foreign income in and out is determined, although capital and .rental rates

are used to determine foreign income out rather than wages and labor supply (equations

4.117, 4.118 and 4.119).

4.6.6.3 Foreign Aid

Similarly, the foreign income in and out is determined in the same way, although government

income is used to determine movements in foreign aid out (equations 4.120, 4.121 and

4.122).

4.6.7 Multiple Households and Endowments

The above discussion shows that the equations relating to private household income

(equation 4.112), foreign income and remittances are allocated across households. The

database of standard GTAP does not recognize multiple households, and hence there is only

one private household (again, figure 1 illustrates the regional household in the standard

GTAP model. The income of all factors is accrued and the whole consumption and saving is

Page 123: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

104

undertaken by that one household (the “Main Household” of this model)1. Using the

MyGTAP data program, multiple households can be added to one country or region of the

standard GTAP database. This program produces a large number of zeroes, for example

when a household or endowment does not exist for a particular region. This can cause some

structural singularity issues in the model (Minor & Walmsley, 2012).

In order to include multiple households, a number of changes are required to the model such

as:

a) To track the supply of household factor and ownership of factor endowments (income) and

possible unemployment of those factors.

b) The additional endowment types are needed to allow.

c) The need to accommodate transfers between households and to the government.

d) The possibility of differential income and commodity taxes.

At this point each household supplies endowments to firms. Hence the aggregate supply of

each endowment is the sum total of all endowments supplied by all households (equation

4.123). The household income is reduced by the appropriate amount of depreciation when we

know the ownership of capital by households (kbh) (equation 4.112).

We also include equations 4.124 and 4.125 to incorporate unemployment closures. ‘emplh

(i,h,r)’ and ‘empl (i,r)’ allow for us to consider employment on labor supplied by particular

households or all households equally. As it’s done in the standard GTAP model, once the

supply of every single endowment (qo(i,r)) is determined this endowment moves easily or

sluggishly between sectors depending on whether the endowment is defined as mobile or

sluggish (Minor & Walmsley, 2012).

1 Note that this Main household is not the Regional Household discussed in Hertel (1997) because it is a private

household. The GTAP regional household collects all income and allocates it to both private household and

government consumption and savings. In contrast, Main household in MyGTAP simply aggregates all private

households, excluding government transactions.

Page 124: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

105

The MyGTAP data program also allows the user to split endowments, since the existence of

multiple households may also necessitate the need to separate, not just the supply, but also

the demand for endowments. For example rural and urban households both supply unskilled

workers, however, it is unlikely that these are easily substitutable and hence the user may

want to separate the demand for rural unskilled and urban unskilled so as to reduce the

substitutability between them (creating two prices which move independently in the

processes). This is all achieved using the MyGTAP data program. Once the endowments are

split in the data and the endowment set extended, the standard GTAP equations still hold with

no change in the underlying model (Minor & Walmsley, 2012).

In order to accommodate potential income transfer between households and differential taxes,

the model also includes a number of additional variables. Two transfers are included in the

database and model, transfers between households ‘TRNH(k,h,r)’ is the transfer from

household k to household h in region ‘r’; and transfers from household ‘h’ to the government

(TRNG(h,r)). The value of transfers is considered zero in the MyGTAP data program, if it is

not specified by the user. These transfers are assumed to be exogenous in the model. To

allow for the differences in tax rates paid by households, the income taxes (toh) and

commodity taxes (‘tpdh’ and ‘tpmh’) are also included (Minor & Walmsley, 2012).

4.6.8 Expenditures of Private Household

To determine household consumption of each commodity, the model is set up so that the user

can define whether they want to use Constant Difference of Elasticity (CDE)1 or linear

expenditure system (LES). This means that in developed economies where the Frisch

parameter (“The marginal utility of income with respect to income”) is one, the user can opt

1 See Hertel (1997) for an explanation of the CDE function used in GTAP.

Page 125: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

106

to keep GTAP’s CDE, while imposing the LES in other regions where subsistence is

important.

With the help of a binary parameter (PRIVTYPE), the user defines the use of CDE or LES

that is read in from of (default.prm) in the ‘GTAPPARM’ file. In the MyGTAP data program

this takes the value of 1 for the special country where LES is to be used, and zero in all other

countries1. The user can change this using ‘ViewHAR’ but should be careful not to impose

the LES on countries where the FRISCH parameter is greater than -1.8. The set of regions is

then divided into two subsets:

Set REG_LES # Countries for which the LES system applies#

= (all,r,REG:PRIVTYPE(r)>0);

Set REG_CDE # Countries for which the CDE system applies#

= (all,r,REG: PRIVTYPE(r)=0);

Total private consumption expenditure (yph(h,r)) is determined by a Cobb-Douglas function

regardless of the choice of specification, as private household income is allocated across

private consumption and household savings in a similar way to which it is determined in the

standard GTAP model, albeit at the household level. Equation 4.126 summarizes it as:

It is worth mentioning that with respect to income, the elasticity of private expenditure

(UELASPRIV) is equal to 1 and under the specification of both CDE and LES, it is

endogenous. The elasticity remains unchanged under the specification of LES while the

elasticity changes due to any change in income and its allocation across commodities (with

different levels of income elasticity) under the CDE.

1 This is similar to the parameter SLUG which is used for determining sluggish verses mobile endowments.

(Minor & Walmsley, 2012b).

Page 126: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

107

4.6.9 Constant Difference of Elasticity (CDE)

The countries that traditionally use the CDE in the standard GTAP model apply the

traditional CDE with two differences (Equation 4.127). First, the equation only applies to the

subset of regions REG_CDE; and second, household private expenditure (yph(h,r)) is being

allocated across commodities only and not the total private expenditure of the regional

household (yp(r) in the standard GTAP).

4.6.10 LES

The ORANI model developed by Dixon et al (1982) is used for the codes to incorporate the

LES for the REG_LES subset of countries.

The MyGTAP model adds the first two parameters in the tab file:

1. The Frisch LES 'parameter' (FRISCH(h,r)) is calibrated from the income elasticity and

household consumption shares1 or read in from the parameters file, if the header exists:

2. Household expenditure elasticities (EPS(i,h,r)) are set equal to the income elasticities also

used in the CDE or read in from the parameters file, if the header exists.

These parameters can then be used to determine the average (equation 4.130) and marginal

(equation 4.131) share of luxury goods in total expenditure:

1 Calibration equations used are based on those taken from the CRUSOE suite developed by Mark Horridge.

“http://www.monash.edu.au/policy/crusoe.htm” and Minor & Walmsley (2012) also include an assertion that all

FRISCH parameters are less than -1.8 for REG_LES countries.

Page 127: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

108

With the share of luxury goods in total expenditure known from equations (4.130) and

(4.131) and total consumption expenditure determined by Equation (4.126) it is then a matter

of determining how this income will be divided across subsistence ((qph_sub(i,h,r))) and

luxury (qph_lux(i,h,r)) consumption. Total consumption (qph(i,h,r)) then depend on the sum

of these two demands for subsistence and luxury commodities (equation 4.132).

Following the LES methodology, subsistence consumption (qph_sub(i,h,r)) remains constant

and only changes with changes in the population or number of households (poph(h,r)) and

any taste changes (asub(i,h,r)). This is shown in equation 4.134.

Consumption of luxury commodities (qph_lux(i,h,r)) then depends on private expenditure left

over for luxury consumption (yph_lux(h,r)), prices (pph(i,h,r)) and a taste parameter

(alux(i,h,r)): Equation 4.134.

In order to determine how much of private expenditure is left for luxury goods (yph_lux)

after the subsistence, goods have been purchased we simply need to ensure that we are on our

budget constraint (equation 4.135). That is, we need to ensure that total expenditure (yph,

determined by equation 4.126) equals the sum of expenditures on all commodities, which

depends on real consumption (qph, determined by equation 4.132) and prices (pph).

Page 128: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

109

4.6.11 Armington Elasticity

The implementation region-specific Arminigtonselasticity is used. First ESUBD_R, the

standard GTAP region-generic elasticity is defined and read into the model from the GTAP

Database. Next, a region-specific elasticity is defined. This is initially set equal to the region-

generic, unless an additional header exists (ifheaderexists), “ESDR” containing region-

specific details. The implementation region-specific Arminigtons in the tab file is shown in

the box below1.

Coefficient (parameter)(all,i,TRAD_COMM)

ESUBD_R(i)

# region generic el. of sub. domestic/imported for all agents #;

Read

ESUBD_R fromfile GTAPPARM header"ESBD";

Coefficient (all,i,TRAD_COMM)(all,r,REG)

ESUBD(i,r) # region specific el. of sub. among imports of i in Armington

structure #;

Formula (all,i,TRAD_COMM)(all,r,REG)

ESUBD(i,r) = ESUBD_R(i) ;

Read (ifheaderexists)

ESUBD fromfile GTAPPARM header"ESDR";

In order to obtain region-specificArmingtons, the user can include them themselves directly

in the parameters file or they can modify “flexagg” to aggregate the GTAP elasticities using

region-specific weights. By using region-specific weights, the aggregated elasticities would

differ across regions.2

1 The code is also adjusted in a similar way for the elasticity of substitution between imports from different

regions. 2 There are plans to include this in the GTAPAgg program.

Page 129: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

110

4.6.12 Population

The percentage change in the population by household (poph(r)) is included in the model as

an exogenous variable. Since only the total population is known from the GTAP Database

and not the populations of each household type, we cannot determine the percentage change

in the total population from the changes by population; hence the percentage change in the

total population (pop(r)) is removed from the model. This means that ug(r) is no longer

defined as a per capita variable and hence we re-label it qgov(r) to show that it is now

defined as real government expenditure. At this stage, we do not have any equations related

to the migration of people between households.

4.6.13 Welfare

Since the regional household has been removed the current welfare decomposition needs to

be revised1. For the time being it has been removed.

4.7 MyGTAP Model Closure

Model closures are the starting point of this model that assumes perfect competition in all

sectors of the economy (Walmsley & Minor, 2013). Capital and labor as factors of

production are considered to be fully mobile among different sectors of the economy and

land along with natural resources is immobile. The economy of Pakistan faces the problem of

high unemployment rate, so we assumed that unskilled labor (LASKU)2 is unemployed.

Similarly, it is assumed that the factors prices influence the foreign income flows in the

respective country. The trade balance is endogenous and expected rate of return determines

the investment as in the case of standard GTAP model and total domestic savings by the

government budget deficit and sum of the private household savings.

Any country that gets GSP Plus status in the EU faces the annual growth capping mechanism

for products with higher growth rates (see results chapter for further details). The study

incorporated the capping mechanism with quota restrictions.

1 This is on the list for future work.

2 swap empl("LASKU","pakistan") = pfactreal("UnSkLab","pakistan") ;

Page 130: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

111

4.8 Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for MyGTAP

Pakistan Institute of Development Economics (PIDE) developed the first Social Accounting

Matrix (SAM) for Pakistan in 1985 with the base year 1979. Federal bureau of Statistics

(FBS) under Project “Improvement of National Accounting System (INAS) with

collaboration with the Netherland government developed the second SAM that was limited to

the only single household. Siddiqui & Iqbal (1999) constructed a new SAM for Pakistan with

the base year 1989-90 and aggregated the industrial classification in Input-Output (IO) table

into SAM with five production accounts. Dorosh, Niazi, & Nazli (2006) built a broad SAM

with 34 production accounts and 19 household groups with the base year 2001-02. These

household groups were disaggregated across provincial basis, hence most suited for policy

analysis that targets particular households. Waheed & Ezaki (2008) produced a financial

SAM for the year 1999–00. They disaggregate the workings of the loanable funds market

into disaggregated payments related to physical and financial flows among institutions (Khan

et. al 2015).

The latest available SAM that depends heavily on concomitant National Accounts and

household data was developed by Debowicz et.al (2012) with the base year 2007-08, under

the Pakistan Strategy Support Program (PSSP) funded by USAID aiming to support the

Government of Pakistan with evidence-based policy reform for pro-poor economic growth

and enhanced food security.

To implement a CGE model with an income distribution component, a consistent database is

required. MyGTAP in the study pursues the SAM (2007-08) desegregation of activities,

commodities, factors and institutions. The model follows the framework developed by

Lofgren et al. (2001). This model is a standard static model rather than dynamic CGE model.

Therefore the second-period effects of changes in investment expenditures are not taken into

account. Moreover, the model neither specific about the time horizon of the adjustment nor

how the adjustment is sequenced. Otherwise stated, the model cannot resolve whether

adjustment from the base to a new equilibrium takes place over any particular length of

time, or whether a large part of the adjustment occurs in a particular year (see appendix 4).

Page 131: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

112

Equations of the model are employed to describe inter-relationship of the macro economy.

SAM provides actual values for the coefficients in these equations through the calibration

process. The model will be solved primarily for equilibrium to make sure that the base year

dataset is reproduced. Afterward, it would be possible to shock the model with a change in

the value of one of the exogenous variables. The model will be resolved for equilibrium and

the changes in the values of the endogenous variables. Moreover, these values will be

compared to those of the base-year equilibrium to establish the impact of the exogenous

shock.

4.8.5 Framework of Macroeconomic Accounting

A SAM is a square matrix which presents monetary flows that reflect the all transaction of

receipts and payments between various agents in the economy. Furthermore, it follows a

framework of macroeconomic accounting which permits us to compute a variety of macro

identities. The study expresses macroeconomic accounting framework1 in the form of

algebraic equations which could be used in computing different macro identities. Further, all

institutions of the economy are divided into four - household (h), government (g), enterprises

(e) and rest of the world (r) - to state the macroeconomic framework.

The study denotes Yi for income in sector i, Si for saving in sector i and Ei for expenditure in

sector i. Moreover, all transactions among sectors are denoted by ijTR which specify the

direction of flows from sector i to sector j. For instance, hrTR shows the transfers from the

household (h) to rest of the world (r), whereas rhTR shows the transfers from rest of the world

to the household.

4.8.5.1 Household Sector

Household income ( hY ), household savings ( sY ), and household expenditures ( eY ) are the

main accounts of the household sector. The main source of household income is factor

income ( fY ), which is generated within the production activities. Moreover, they also obtain

1 Macroeconomic accounting framework is adopted from Warr & Azis (1997)

Page 132: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

113

income through transfers from the government ( hgTR , ) and rest of the world ( hrTR , ).

Income of household can be written as

hrhgfh TRTRYY ,,

where hY = household income,

fY = household factor income,

hgTR , = transfers from government to household,

hrTR , = transfers to the household from rest of the world.

Income of a household must be equal to the expenditure of household when talking about in

terms of accounting relationships. The income received by the household comprises of the

household factor income, the income that it receives from government and rest of the world.

Therefore, household consumption, transfers to government and rest of the world comprise

household’s total expenditure. The relationship can be expressed as:

rhghh TRTRCE ,,

where ghTR , = transfers from household to the government,

rhTR , = transfers from household to rest of the world,

C = consumption of the household.

Household saving can be expressed by the following identity

hhh EYS

where hS = saving of household,

fY = household factor income,

hE = expenditures of the household.

Substituting equation 4.136 and 4.137 in 4.138, we get

Page 133: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

114

hfh NTRCYS

where )()( ,,,, rhhrghhgh TRTRTRTRNTR

Where hNTR = total net transfers received by the household sector.

Therefore, three key accounts of the household sector can be expressed by equations (4.136),

(4.137) and (4.139).

4.8.5.2 Enterprise Sector

Resembling the households sector, the enterprise sector also consists of three accounts which

are income, expenditure and saving. The income of enterprise is mainly driven from

operating surplus. That is generated by deducting the consumption of fixed capital from the

total capital income within the production activities. Transfers by the government ( egTR , )

and rest of the world ( erTR , ) are other sources of income of enterprise. We can express

income and expenditure of enterprise as:

eregdeke TRTRSYY ,,,

where eY = enterprise income

ekY , = capital income of enterprise

= consumption of fixed capital (depreciation)

egTR , = transfer to the enterprise from the government

erTR , = transfer to the enterprise from the rest of the world

regehee TRTRTRE ,,,

Where

eE = expenditure of enterprise

heTR , = transfer of enterprise to household

dS

Page 134: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

115

geTR , = transfer of enterprise to government

reTR , = transfer of enterprise to rest of the world

Saving account can be obtained by subtracting expenditure from income of enterprise.

eee EYS

Substituting equation (4.140) and (1.141) in equation (1.142), we get

edeke NTRSYS ,

Where hegeegreere TRTRTRTRTRNTR ,.,,, )()(

Thus, Enterprise receipts (income), expenditure and saving can be expressed by equations

(4.140), (4.141) and (4.143) respectively.

4.8.5.3 Government Sector

The government sector, similar to household and enterprise sector, consists of three accounts,

i.e., government receipts (Revenues), government expenditure (Outlays) and government

saving. Government receipts include indirect taxes, income taxes from households, and

transfers from “rest of the world” ( grTR , ). While, government expenditures ( gE ) consist of

transfers to the households ( hgTR , ), transfers to “rest of the world” ( rgTR , ) and public

consumptions (G). We will denote total net transfers received through government by gNTR .

Equations for government receipts ( gY ), expenditures ( gE ) and savings ( gS ) are as follow:

grghtg TRTRIY ,,

where gY = government receipts

tI = indirect taxes

ghTR , = income taxes from households

Page 135: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

116

grTR , = transfers from “rest of the world”

rghgg TRTRGE ,,

where gE = government outlays

G = government consumption expenditure

hgTR , = transfer to the households from the government

rgTR , = transfers from government to rest of the world

ggg EYS

where gS = Government savings

By substituting equations (4.143) and (4.144) in (4.145), we obtain

ggg NTRGYS

where gNTR is net transfers received by governments and can be written mathematically as

)()( ,,,, rggrhgghg TRTRTRTRNTR

Therefore, total government revenues, expenditures and saving can be expressed by equation

(144). (145) and (147).

4.8.5.4 Rest of the World Sector

The sector “rest of the world” shows the supply of imports to and demand for our exports

from the rest of world. This sector consists of three main accounts. These are total payments

from foreigners to domestic agents (rE ), total receipts of foreigners from domestic agents (

rY ), and foreign savings. Major sources of receipts of foreigners are imports (M), transfers

from government ( rgTR , ) and transfer from households ( rhTR ,, ). While, total expenditure of

foreigners (rE ) consists of “transfers to households” ( hrTR , ), “transfers to government” (

grTR , ) and exports (E). Total receipts and expenditures of foreigner can be expressed as

follows:

Page 136: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

117

rhrgr TRTRMY ,,

where rY = total receipts of a foreigner from domestic agents

M = Imports

rgTR , = transfer from government to foreigners

rhTR , = transfer from households to foreigners

grhrr TRTRXE ,,

where rE = total payments from foreigners to domestic agents

X = total exports

hrTR , = transfer from foreigners to households

grTR , = transfers from foreigners to government

We can write identity of foreign savings as

rrr EYS

where rS is the foreign savings

By substituting equation (4.147) and (4.148) in equation (4.149), we obtain

rr NTRXMS

where rNTR is net transfers received by foreigners and can be written algebraically as

)()( ,,,, hrrhgrger TRTRTRTRNTR

Total foreigners receipts from domestic agents, total foreigners payments to domestic agents

and foreign saving can be expressed by equations (4.148), (4.149) and (4.151) respectively.

Page 137: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

118

4.8.6 The Macro Aggregates

In this section, we derive GDP at factor cost as well as market price. We estimate these

macro aggregates from the income and expenditure side and also from investment and saving

equilibrium. These aggregates can be obtained if we sum equation (4.139), (4.143), (4.147)

and (4.151) we get

EMGISYCYSSSS tdekfregh ,

Rearranging above equation we get

EMGIYCYSSSSS tekfdregh ,

As we know that Gross Domestic Product (GDP) at factor cost can be defined as

ekf YYYFC ,

and GDP at market price can be expressed, on the income side, as

tIYFCY

Or

tekf IYYY ,

by substituting GDP at market price(Y) in the equation (4.153), we get the following

expression:

EMGCYSSSSS dregh

Since, we can write the definition of GDP at market price on expenditure side as

MEGICY

where I = total value of the gross investment at market price.

Arranging above equation for I, we obtain

Page 138: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

119

EMGCYI

Hence, we can obtain the following equation by substituting value of I into the right-hand

side of equation (4.157)

EMGCYSSSS drgh

where I = total value of the gross investment at market price.

Therefore above equation shows the investment and saving equilibrium.

4.9 Data Sources for SAM 2007-08

The data was used from the following sources:

2007-08 National Accounts 2007-08

Value added by 15 sectors (Handbook of Statistics)

Macroeconomic Aggregates

1990-91 Input-Output Table (97 sectors)

2007-08 Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan

2007-08 Pakistan Integrated Household Survey

Commodity level trade data from the Ministry of Finance (MOF)

2000-2001 SAM for Pakistan

Please see appendix 3 for the detailed structure of SAM 2007-08.

Page 139: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

120

CHAPTER 5: RESULTS & DISCUSSION

Multi-country or global models consist of multiple countries or the total global economy.

These models are specifically designed to analyze the trade agreements. Moreover, these

models do not maintain a single country model assumption of exogenising global or trading

partner effects. Therefore, the implications of these effects - coming from rest of the world or

other countries - have been endogenized. Any effects, transmitted to by means of various

channels, of policy changes in the rest of the world, would have direct as well as indirect

influence. These models explicitly capture this transmission mechanism. Therefore, these

models can be applied in policy experiments of multilateral trade liberalization (Wobst,

2001).

The CGE model in its global version is supported by the Global Trade Analysis Project

(GTAP) model as it provides the modeling framework as well as the database to the CGE

model. That is; the main source of data for the global CGE model is the GTAP database. The

model of GTAP is the most commonly used and known software for the multi-country trade

analysis. It is Multi-region, multi-country and multi- sector CGE model which assumes

perfectly competitive markets and return to scale (Burfisher, 2011). GTAP 09 with reference

years 2004, 2007 and 2011, 140 regions, 57 sectors and 244 countries has been used to link

the Pakistan economy with rest of the world in general and European Union (EU28) in

particular.

The study has fully calibrated various policy experiments by varying the related parameters.

This chapter will discuss in detail the simulations performed and results of different scenarios

modeled for Pakistan keeping in view the objectives of the study. The chapter is organized as

follows; first, we will explain an overview of Pakistan trade with EU, then simulation design

of the scenarios carried out. The following section will represent the results. This will be

accompanied by brief discussion of overall results at the end.

5.1 Pakistan-EU Trade Relationships at a Glance

Since many years EU is the largest importer of Pakistani products. Total exports from

Pakistan to the EU during the year 2014 were US$ 8.13 billion which accounted 29 percent

Page 140: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

121

for the total exports. It was 21.5 percent in 2012 and 24 percent in 2011. Although EU is

considered to be the dominant importer for Pakistan but country always showed a sluggish

export growth, especially in terms of commodity diversification. On the other hand,

penetration into the EU market remained overdue comparing to other competitors (PBC,

2014).

Pakistan is a member of the preferential trading system of EU, ever since its evolution. The

examination evidents that external trade relations of the EU with the developing countries

has been conducted with a number of different channels, principally with the African

Caribbean and Pacific (ACP) states through the Lome Convention, Mediterranean countries

through the Global Mediterranean Policy (GMP) and with rest of Latin American and Asian

developing countries including Pakistan through the GSP scheme. This is evident from the

EU’s complex network of discriminatory tariff through generalized and country-specific or

region-specific trade preferences. While, trade relations with most industrialized countries

have been based on most-favored-nation treatment (Naeem, 2006).

The common commercial policy uses a spread of instruments to regulate trade among the EU

and its trade partners. It covers not only tariff but other trade instruments as well. A

complicated system of trade advantages, differentiated according to specific groups of

countries, has drawn up to a hierarchy of trade preferences called as ‘pyramid’ of trade

preferences. The examination of EU’s trade regime practice worked out over the years point

out that it uses fairly complicated procedures and very elaborate panoply of instruments.

Although the system has some of the economic effects hoped for and has been established for

political reasons; it seems advisable to simplify considerably in order to expand its benefits

largely according to’ trade not aid’ principle (Persson & Wilhelmsson, 2016).

5.2 Does GSP Plus is different from Normal GSP?

The basic and foremost objective of the preferential system known as Generalized System of

Preferences (GSP) is to help the economies to reduce the poverty, promote good governance

and sustainable economic growth. These preferences enable the economies to increase their

role in the international trade and especially the exports to the EU that ultimately help them

Page 141: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

122

to reduce the poverty and maintain a sustainable development. The GSP of EU covers the

following regimes (European Commission, 2013).

i) The standard/normal GSP that covers more than 6300 tariff lines, transports

preferences to 90 developing countries that have been reduced from 177 in 2013.

ii) GSP Plus that brings special arrangements to promote good governance and

sustained development in addition to offering duty-free access to more goods from

the vulnerable economies including Pakistan. The list includes 25 countries adding

9 more to the previous 16. The beneficiary economies have to implement and ratify

certain international conventions.

iii) The most attractive arrangements for the 50 Least Developed Economies (LDCs)

called Everything But Arms (EBA), provides duty-free and quota-free access to

nearly all commodities.

In addition to the preferential agreements, EU has established trade relations on the basis of

Most Favored Nation (MFN) treatment allowing all industrialized countries outside EU to

trade with.

5.3 Opportunities for Pakistan under GSP plus Arrangements

Pakistan is benefitting from EU (European Commission at that time) since 1976. Pakistan

was already enjoying the traditional status of GSP by paying 20% less duty than the MFNs to

the EU. This concession not only helped the Pakistani products to gain access but also to

sustain its position in the EU market. Despite all this, Pakistani products were facing tough

competition from efficient producers like China, India, Indonesia, Vietnam and Thailand at

one hand and at other hand the countries who gained duty-free and quota-free access through

EBA status were giving tough competition. So, the GSP plus status provided an opportunity

to Pakistani products to compete with others (PBC, 2014). Pakistan has the following

opportunities.

i) India, China, Indonesia, Vietnam, Colombia and Thailand are not eligible for the

GSP plus status.

Page 142: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

123

ii) In textile and clothing sector, China has already graduated and India has

graduated from the textile sector of the normal GSP providing an opportunity for

the textile and clothing sector of Pakistan.

iii) After Bangladesh, Pakistan will be the second country in the region enjoying

duty-free access in the EU market.

Keeping in view the above points and economic conditions of Pakistan, GSP plus status in

the EU is promising a lot of opportunities for Pakistan in terms of trade, investment,

institutional development, sustainable economic growth and employment generation etc.

5.4 Pakistan’s Major Competitors: Challenges vs. Opportunities

In December 2013, European Union granted GSP plus status and since January 2014,

Pakistan is enjoying this status. It is expected from the very beginning that the exports from

Pakistan are expected to increase in the EU market under GSP plus status. This status will

substantially increase Pakistan’s exports to the EU28, especially in textile, wearing apparel

and leather sectors.

Identification of “high potential” products of Pakistan in the EU after the GSP plus status is

the first step that should be followed by the identification of potential competitors with the

same status or even better. EU have a range of agreements with different countries including

GSP, GSP plus, Every Thing but Arms (EBA), Overseas Countries and Territories (OCT),

Economic Partnerships Agreement (EPA) and some more. While considering the competition

among developing economies, EBA is considered to be more attractive than the GSP plus

status (Carbone & Orbie, 2016).

Although, achieving the status of zero tariff on the export of all products is a huge

opportunity but the exports from Pakistan may not observe abrupt jump. It is because

Pakistan will continue to face a tough competition from countries enjoying the same or better

treatment in the EU market. The countries with GSP plus status will face an annual capping

mechanism while others with EBA status like Bangladesh will enjoy the tariff-free access

throughout the year. In addition to such status in the EU market, the commodity price,

Page 143: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

124

production capabilities and demand for the products will also play a key role in such

competitive environment. Table 5.1 below summarizes the position of Pakistan and its

competitors with similar status in the EU market.

Page 144: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

125

Table 0.1:Comparison of Imports by the EU (28) with GSP Plus Beneficiaries (US $ Million)

S.No Exporters 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

1 Peru 4535.426 5735.355 5757.745 4606.083 6964.311 9044.237 8245.533 7319.704 6829.214

2 Pakistan 4608.631 5299.239 6068.424 5295.437 5918.299 7485.797 6093.209 6868.222 7220.692

3 Paraguay 381.972 595.263 732.295 509.935 1312.965 1657.424 1225.061 1574.558 1527.568

4 Costa Rica 4385.611 4861.657 5446.408 4516.831 5309.968 6077.34 6790.581 6394.572 6118.975

5 Ecuador 2359.165 2795.452 3569.817 3078.315 3047.403 3712.947 3601 3897.129 4003.406

6 Georgia 644.582 663.565 908.006 604.577 886.863 923.853 762.903 916.273 907.527

7 Armenia 442.26 488.988 478.108 241.345 323.211 443.014 330.801 329.391 335.891

8 Bolivia 192.642 247.807 474.357 420.556 569.521 592.171 603.733 761.402 879.886

9 Mongolia 79.506 111.22 95.385 75.696 135.866 114.874 93.291 105.559 115.773

10 Cabo Verde 39.629 25.548 40.429 39.03 50.536 63.852 68.475 64.404 78.477

Source: International Trade Centre (ICT)

Page 145: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

126

5.5 Potential for Pakistani Imports after GSP plus Status

Currently, it seems that tariff-free access of Pakistan into the EU will bring a lot of

opportunities in terms of trade and economic growth. The statistics predict that product

diversification may bring more opportunities for Pakistan.

The products in which Pakistan is already enjoying high market access – import is 6% of the

total EU imports for the particular commodity may not be able to enjoy the zero-tariff status.

In addition to that, annual growth capping mechanism under GSP plus will also restrict the

imports from Pakistan. It is 17.5% for most of the products except textiles and ethanol where

it is 14.5% and 13.5% respectively (PBC, 2015).

Some of the products from Pakistan are already under duty-free access in the EU28 as

normal or general tariff is already zero e.g. rice, sports equipment, surgical goods, meat

products and fruits. It means after the GSP plus status, 90 percent of the products from

Pakistan will lie under the duty-free category (Pakistan Economic Survey 2013-14).

Table 0.2: Imports from Pakistan into the EU 28 (category wise) (US$ million)

Products/Year 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

Products of Vegetable 55.8 57.5 47.4 49.1 57.7 67.8

Prepared Foodstuffs 6.7 54.2 45.6 89 101.2 115.1

Mineral 3.3 5.1 5.5 7.1 8.4 9.9

Chemical/ Allied 1.2 1.1 1 1.5 1.8 2.1

Plastic Articles 78.9 46.9 32.1 41 48.2 56.6

Raw Hides 33.7 44.4 43.1 61.1 71.8 84.3

Textile Articles 1,466.40 1,920.00 1,816.00 1,569.20 1796.7 2057.2

Footwear 38 45.6 44 45.7 53.7 63.1

Natural Pearls 10.2 9.9 9.2 7.4 8.7 10.3

Base Metals and Articles 0 0 1.7 1.3 1.5 1.8

Miscellaneous Products 58.4 66.3 70.1 66.3 77.9 91.5

Total 1,752.60 2,251.00 2,115.70 1,938.70 2227.6 2559.7

Source: ITC and Authors Calculations

Page 146: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

127

There are approximately 74 items with 6 digit HS code that are identified as the potential

beneficiary products. The products included in the list are only those having export value

above 1 million US dollar in 2013. These products have not only less than 6% market share

in the EU market but also the exports in each product to the world market remained more

than 10 million US dollar for the same period. Detailed list of these products can be seen in

appendix 4 and 5.

In order to keep the things simple, the study has further spread the 74 potential products into

11 strategic sectors. Table 5.2 summarizes the story.

According to the study conducted by the Pakistan Business Council (2014 & 2015), there

would be a benefit of more than US$ 1 billion per annum to Pakistan. Duties and tariffs

on most of the products from Pakistan will be reduced to minimum or zero value.

Pakistan is already among the top ten exporters of EU28 having a comparative advantage

in the sectors of textiles, wearing apparel, leather and beverages. Table 5.3 shows that

Pakistan in the only country that have a comparative advantage in all categories. After

attaining the GSP Plus status, some better results are expected.

Table 0.3: Top 10 Exporters of EU28

Country Textiles Wearing

apparel Leather

Beverag

es

Current

Status

Market share

(Million

Euro)

Market

Share (%

age)

China √ √ GSP 302,049 17.93

Turkey √ Customs

Union

54,374 3.23

India √ √ GSP 37,120 2.2

Brazil √ MFN

tariff

30,996 1.84

Vietnam √ GSP 22,189 1.32

Indonesia √ GSP 14,432 0.86

Banglades

h

EBA 12,335 0.73

Pakistan √ √ √ √ GSP+ 5,510 0.33

Peru √ Free

Trade

Agreem

ent and

GSP+

4,930 0.29

Guatemal

a

√ Free

Trade

Agreem

ent

690 0.04

Source: Pakistan Business Council 2015

Page 147: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

128

5.6 Research Simulations Used in this Study

In order to implement any modeling technique, the study has to follow two stages. At the first

stage, the model is separated from the base without any alteration in the exogenous variables

or parameters. In the second stage, the base values are then compared with the simulation

results that are instigated. The exogenous variable is modified to illustrate a change in the

trade policy and the solution is then compared with the base model. In this way, we can

capture the impact of different import concessions provided by the EU28 on the economic

growth of Pakistan (The details of regional and sectoral aggregations are in appendix 1).

The study will run the three simulations using GTAP 09 (Base year 2011-12) and two

simulations with MyGTAP (with latest available SAM 2007-08) to study the impact of GSP

Plus on Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of Pakistan, exports, imports, real investment, terms

of trade, prices of imports and exports and prices at domestic level.

The study incorporates the MyGTAP model to calculate the impact of policy options on the

household income and real wages, as the standard GTAP model is not an appropriate tool for

this purpose. In order to look deep into the objectives of the study, each scenario/shock has a

set of simulations. The study will run the following simulations.

Simulation I: EU-28 GSP Plus status with other competitors: It allows duty-free and quota-

free imports from Pakistan. What would happen by applying tariff rate (based

on 2011-12) on other competitors in the sectors of textile, wearing apparel,

beverages and leather?

Simulation II: EU-28 GSP Plus status with quota restriction: What would happen if quota

restriction is applied on Pakistan to incorporate the capping mechanism of

the EU28?.

Simulation III: Potential EU28-EBA with Competitors: What would happen if Pakistan gets

the Everything But Arms (EBA) status in the EU28 with no Capping

mechanism/Quota restriction, with main competitor Bangladesh that already

enjoying the EBA status?

Page 148: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

129

5.7 Results of the Simulations with GTAP 09

The study used GTAP version 09 to obtain the results for all three simulations explained

above. The results of all three simulations are presented below showing a change in baseline

value. Different tables below explain the change in million dollars value as well as in

percentages.

5.7.1 Changes in GDP and Production of Pakistan

It is believed that trade openness and especially increases in exports, leads to increase in real

GDP and economic growth. Table 5.4 explains the impacts of our three simulations on the

real GDP of Pakistan that means, changes in output are measured at base prices. The impact

of all three simulations is positive and encouraging --- showing a positive change in the

baseline value.

Table 0.4: GDP Quantity Index, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent and Millions US$)

Simulations Base Value

(Millions US$)

Post Shock

Effects

Change

in GDP

Percentage

Change

GSP Plus status with

Competitors 213686.2 213956.031 269.828 0.126

GSP Plus Status with

Quota Restrictions 213686.2 213731.953 45.75 0.021

EBA Status 213686.2 213895.25 209.047 0.098

Source: Author’s simulation results using GTAP 09 program

The results of the first simulation revealed maximum gains while simulation two shows

minimum benefits for the GDP of Pakistan. In the first simulation by relaxing Pakistan from

tariffs after GSP Plus status as compared to its competitors in the EU28, GDP of Pakistan

gains benefit of US$269.828 million from the baseline value. While under the same status of

Pakistan in the EU28, when changes are applied by applying quota restrictions to calculate

the impact of EU capping mechanism, the gains are minimum among three simulations. In

this case, the GDP of Pakistan increases by US$45.75 million which is only 0.021 percent

positive change. The third simulation also produces very encouraging results with a positive

change of US$209.047 million in GDP.

Page 149: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

130

Changes in real output in different sectors of Pakistan are represented in table 5.5. The

results of all three simulations revealed mixed effects on the real output of commodities. The

results of the simulation when quota restriction is applied on imports from Pakistan into

EU28 have more winning sectors while the simulation where Pakistan is competing with

other rivals under GSP plus status have minimum winning sectors.

Table 0.5: Changes in Pakistan’s Real Out Put, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent and

Millions US$)

Commodity

Base

Value

(Millions

US$)

GSP Plus with

Competitors

GSP Plus with EU

Capping (Quota)

Potential EBA

Status

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Paddy rice 5259 -0.829 -0.02 0.073 0.001 0.287 0.005

Wheat 7853 -1.242 -0.02 -0.035 0.000 -1.083 -0.014

Plant-based

fibers 4765 1.921 0.04 -0.869 -0.018 1.4 0.029

Crops nec 583 -2.613 -0.45 -0.244 -0.042 -1.906 -0.327

Processed

rice 26562 -0.271 0.00 0.108 0.000 0.167 0.001

Oil seeds 4987 -0.112 0.00 0.067 0.001 -0.033 -0.001

Vegetables,

fruit, nuts 5051 -0.777 -0.02 0.019 0.000 -0.604 -0.012

Sugar cane,

sugar beet 2958 0.571 0.02 0.277 0.009 0.439 0.015

Leather

products 19420 0.431 0.00 0.23 0.001 0.174 0.001

Cereal grains

nec 538 -0.616 -0.11 -0.103 -0.019 -0.336 -0.062

Food

products nec 26297 0.272 0.00 0.234 0.001 0.245 0.001

Wool, silk-

worm

cocoons

125 3.459 2.77 -1.101 -0.881 2.49 1.992

Coal 276 -1.733 -0.63 -0.223 -0.081 -1.239 -0.449

Wearing

apparel 21474 6.15 0.03 0.037 0.000 4.149 0.019

Dairy

products 27416 0.449 0.00 0.253 0.001 0.299 0.001

Page 150: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

131

Textiles 17662 4.844 0.03 -1.044 -0.006 3.593 0.020

Meat

products nec 1332 0.473 0.04 0.269 0.020 0.361 0.027

Animal

products nec 1181 0.174 0.01 0.25 0.021 0.079 0.007

Raw milk 5992 0.388 0.01 0.216 0.004 0.181 0.003

Meat 4133 -0.284 -0.01 0.09 0.002 -0.306 -0.007

Cattle, sheep,

goats, horses 1496 0.248 0.02 0.181 0.012 0.054 0.004

Forestry 599 -1.615 -0.27 -0.2 -0.033 -1.242 -0.207

Fishing 2014 0.439 0.02 0.22 0.011 0.34 0.017

Oil 1979 -1.248 -0.06 -0.194 -0.010 -0.966 -0.049

Gas 1623 -1.271 -0.08 -0.2 -0.012 -0.972 -0.060

Sugar 8353 0.585 0.01 0.293 0.004 0.461 0.006

Wood

products 2281 -1.318 -0.06 -0.1 -0.004 -1.022 -0.045

Vegetable

oils and fats 5730 -2.172 -0.04 -0.166 -0.003 -1.749 -0.031

Beverages

and tobacco

products

3209 0.817 0.03 0.147 0.005 0.79 0.025

Petroleum,

coal products 8109 -0.175 0.00 0.039 0.000 -0.135 -0.002

Ferrous

metals 874 -5.155 -0.59 -0.819 -0.094 -4.147 -0.474

Electronic

equipment 4409 -1.471 -0.03 -0.1 -0.002 -1.13 -0.026

Paper

products,

publishing

4326 -1.08 -0.02 -0.196 -0.005 -0.957 -0.022

Metals nec 805 -11.243 -1.40 -1.788 -0.222 -9.084 -1.128

Minerals nec 5759 -0.917 -0.02 -0.103 -0.002 -0.717 -0.012

Metal

products 3743 -2.34 -0.06 -0.284 -0.008 -1.837 -0.049

Transport

equipment

nec

2751 -2.759 -0.10 -0.418 -0.015 -2.318 -0.084

Light

Manufactures 5719 -0.847 -0.01 -0.004 0.000 -0.699 -0.012

Chemical,

rubber, 15527 -3.202 -0.02 -0.611 -0.004 -2.452 -0.016

Page 151: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

132

plastic prods

Mineral

products nec 3431 -1.473 -0.04 -0.202 -0.006 -1.135 -0.033

Machinery

and

equipment

nec

10742 -3.102 -0.03 -0.439 -0.004 -2.517 -0.023

Manufactures

nec 2720 -5.918 -0.22 -0.763 -0.028 -4.413 -0.162

Electricity 41347 0.792 0.00 0.222 0.001 0.607 0.001

Transport and

communicati

on

103519 -0.191 0.00 0.005 0.000 -0.129 0.000

Services 80130 0.243 0.00 -0.011 0.000 0.602 0.001

Source: Author’s simulation results using GTAP 09 program

The case of first simulation i.e. relaxing Pakistan from tariffs as compared to competitors

shows more variations in real output. On a dollar value basis, the maximum gain in real put

is witnessed by the wearing apparel, with an increase of US$ 6.15 million (an increase of

0.03 percent from baseline value) followed by textile sector with US$ 4.844 million (0.03

percent from baseline). The other sectors that showed notable positive trend include wool

and silkworm cocoons US$ 3.45 million, plant-based fibers US$ 1.921 million, dairy

products US$ 0.449 million, sugar cane and sugar beet US$ 0.571 million, leather products

US$ 0.431 million, food product Not Elsewhere Classified (nec) US$ 0.272 million and

beverages and tobacco products US$ 0.817 million, meat product nec US$ 0.473 million,

animal products nec US$ 0.174 million, raw milk US$ 0.388 million, Cattle, sheep, goats,

horses US$ 0.248 million, fishing US$ 0.439 million, sugar US$ 0.585 million and

beverages and tobacco US$ 0.817 million. While all other sectoral output deteriorates. The

maximum decrease was seen in metals nec US$ -11.243 million. Other notable decrease was

seen in manufactures nec US$ -5.918 million, ferrous metals US$ -5.155 million, chemical,

rubber, plastic products US$ -3.202 million, machinery and equipment nec US$ -3.102

million, transport equipment nec US$ -2.759 million and metal products US$ - 2.34 million.

In the case of second simulation i.e. applying quota restrictions on imports from Pakistan to

calculate the impact of capping mechanism applied by EU28 shows more winning sectors as

Page 152: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

133

compared to the first simulation. There are twenty winning sectors as compared to the first

simulation, where these were 16 only. The maximum gain was seen in the sectors of sugar

with US$ 0.293 million followed by sugar cane and sugar beets with US$ 0.277 million,

meat products nec US$ 0.269 million, dairy product US$ 0.253 million, animal products

US$ 0.250 million. The other winning sectors include, paddy rice, processed rice, oilseeds,

vegetables, fruits, nuts etc, leather products, food products nec, wearing apparel, raw milk,

cattle, sheep, goat, horse, fishing, beverages and tobacco products, petroleum and coal

products, electricity and transport and communication. While there is a decrease in real out

in rest of the sectors. The prominent sectors with a decrease in output include metal nec with

US$ -1.788 million, wool and silk worm cocoons with US$ -1.0101, textiles with US$ -

1.044 million and plant based fiber with US$ -0.869 million.

The results of the third simulation i.e. if Pakistan gets the status of EBA in the EU28 show

increase in real output in 19 sectors of Pakistan. The results reveal that wearing apparel

sector is winner acquiring the first position with a gain of US$ 4.149 million followed by

textiles sector with a gain of US$ 3.593 million. Wool, silk worm, cocoons sector also shows

impressive performance with a gain of US$ 2.490 million.

The other winning sectors include, paddy rice, plant-based fiber, processed rice, sugar cane

and sugar beet, leather products, food products nec, dairy products, meat products nec,

animal products nec, raw milk, cattle, sheep, goat, horse, fishing, sugar, beverages and

tobacco products, electricity and services. While there is a decrease in real out in rest of the

sectors. The prominent sectors with a decrease in output include ferrous metals with US$ -

4.147 million, chemical, rubber and plastic products with US$ -2.452 million, transport

equipment with US$ -2.318 million, metal nec with US$ -1.749 million, electronic

equipment with US$ -1.130 million and forestry with US$ -1.242 million. Table 5.6

summarizes the story of all three simulations.

5.7.2 Changes in Exports and Imports of Pakistan

Trade balance always plays very important role in the process of economic growth for an

economy. Exports are normally considered the goods and services for which the foreigners

Page 153: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

134

pay the price to domestic economy and imports are considered to be the goods and services

for which domestic residents pay the price to the foreign economy (Mankiw, 2007).

Figure 0.1: Merchandise Exports and Imports of Pakistan¸ (Percent)

Source: Author’s simulation results using GTAP 09 program

After gaining tariff free and quota-free entry into the EU28, it is expected that the exports

from Pakistan may rise. Similarly, the flow of imports will also increase due to increased

demand for foreign inputs and resultant higher prices of many goods. Figure 5.1 explains the

results of all three simulations. The results of the first simulation revealed maximum gains

while simulation two shows losing position of Pakistan. In first simulation by relaxing

Pakistan from tariffs after GSP Plus status as compared to its competitors in the EU28, the

merchandise exports of Pakistan gain 1.318% from the baseline value while under the same

status of Pakistan in the EU28, when changes are applied by applying quota restrictions to

calculate the impact of EU capping mechanism, the gains are negative. In this case, the

merchandise exports of Pakistan decrease by -1.47 percent. The results of the third

simulation i.e. if Pakistan achieves EBA status in the EU28 also produces very encouraging

results with a positive change of 0.907 percent in exports.

On the other hand, imports of Pakistan increase in all three simulations. In the first

simulation, the merchandise imports of Pakistan gain 4.791 percent from the baseline value

while the second simulation reveals an increase in imports by 0.729 percent. The results of

1.318

-1.47

0.907

4.791

0.729

3.692

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

GSP Plus with Competitors GSP Plus with Quota Restrictions EBA Status

Exports Imports

Page 154: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

135

the third simulation i.e. if Pakistan achieves EBA status in the EU28 also produces a positive

change of 3.692 percent in merchandise imports of Pakistan.

After gaining the tariff free and quota free access in the EU28, the exports of different

products of Pakistan are expected to rise. Similarly, there are equal chances of increase in

prices in Pakistan that ultimately may result to increase the imports. This free access is

expected to bring positive change in the production of many goods along with the enhanced

availability of imported goods. Ultimately, the production of domestic goods may decrease

due to the availability of imported goods at a lesser price. This change in production may

differ across different sectors of the economy.

Tables 5.6 and 5.7 explain the changes in exports and imports of Pakistan after all

simulations. On the export side, table 5.6 shows that there are some positive changes in the

results of two simulations while there is no winning sector in one simulation. The results of

the first simulation when relaxing Pakistan from tariffs and quotas after GSP Plus status as

compared to its competitors in the EU28, shows only 3 sectors with again in exports. The

results in table 5.6 show maximum gains in the wearing apparel sector with US$ 32.401

million, followed by textile sector with US$ 8.212 million. The third sector with positive

gain is beverages and tobacco products that gain US$ 2.762 million from the baseline value.

While rest of the sectors are losers in terms of export performance. The prominent

deterioration has been seen in the sectors of wool, silkworm cocoon (US$ -27.079 million),

meat products nec (US$ -21.690 million), transport equipment (US$ -19.124 million),

machinery and equipment nec (US$ -18.103 million) and manufactures nec (US$ -15.814

million).

The results of the simulation 2 i.e. GSP plus status of Pakistan in the EU28 with quota

restrictions show no positive change in sectoral exports of Pakistan. It is mainly because the

quota (capping) restriction discourges the exports of the commodities where Pakistan has a

comparative advantage while in rest of the sectors, the performance is already poor. The

results of simulation 2 in table 5.6 show all sectors with a decline in exports. Major

deterioration is seen in sectors of meat products nec (US$ -3.793 million) followed by cattle,

Page 155: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

136

sheep, goats and horses (US$ -3.533 million), dairy products (US$ -2.849 million) and

metals nec (US$ -2.488 million).

The results of the simulation 3 i.e. if Pakistan achieves the status of EBA in the EU28, show

some winning sectors. Just like simulation 1, the maximum gain is shown in wearing apparel

sector with US$ 21.554 million from baseline followed by textiles sector with US$ 6.209

million. The other winning sectors include paddy rice (US$ 4.71 million) and beverages and

tobacco products that gain US$ 3.645 million. While rest of the sectors are losers in terms of

export performance. The prominent deterioration has been seen in the sectors of all services

(US$ -41.091 million), wool, silkworm cocoon (US$ -21.698 million), meat products nec

(US$ -17.345 million), transport equipment (US$ -15.898 million), machinery and

equipment nec (US$ -14.842 million) and electronic equipment (US$ -14.773 million).

Table 0.6: Aggregate Exports of Pakistan, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent and Millions

US$)

Commodity

Base

Value

(Millions

US$)

GSP Plus with

Competitors

GSP Plus with EU

Capping (Quota)

Potential EBA

Status

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Paddy rice 213 -13.864 -6.51 -0.727 -0.34 4.71 2.21

Wheat 839 -13.789 -1.64 -2.16 -0.26 -11.789 -1.41

Plant-based

fibers 330 -12.421 -3.76 -0.349 -0.11 -9.174 -2.78

Crops nec 115 -9.316 -8.1 -1.169 -1.02 -6.038 -5.25

Processed

rice 1989 -10.532 -0.53 -1.74 -0.09 -3.046 -0.15

Oil seeds 22.7 -9.795 -43.15 -1.331 -5.86 -8.103 -35.70

Vegetables,

fruit, nuts 657 -6.195 -0.94 -0.833 -0.13 -4.677 -0.71

Sugar cane,

sugar beet 0.011 -11.788

-

107163.64 -1.881 -17100.00 -9.912 -90109.09

Leather

products 632 -3.668 -0.58 -2.002 -0.32 -7.604 -1.20

Cereal grains

nec 71.3 -5.367 -7.53 -0.786 -1.10 -4.329 -6.07

Food 938 -8.906 -0.95 -1.446 -0.15 -5.745 -0.61

Page 156: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

137

products nec

Wool, silk-

worm

cocoons

2.74 -27.079 -988.28 -2.257 -82.37 -21.698 -791.90

Coal 0.82 -1.2 -146.34 -0.119 -14.51 -0.593 -72.32

Wearing

apparel 3679 32.401 0.88 -1.2 -0.03 21.554 0.59

Dairy

products 33.9 -17.27 -50.94 -2.849 -8.40 -1.46 -4.31

Textiles 10760 8.217 0.08 -1.512 -0.01 6.209 0.06

Meat

products nec 2.94 -21.69 -737.76 -3.793 -129.01 -17.345 -589.97

Animal

products nec 72 -5.461 -7.58 -0.303 -0.42 -4.688 -6.51

Raw milk 0.536 -15.613 -2912.87 -1.549 -288.99 -13.078 -2439.93

Meat 104 -18.811 -18.09 -3.533 -3.40 -13.685 -13.16

Cattle, sheep,

goats, horses 0.394 -8.459 -2146.95 -1.263 -320.56 -7.145 -1813.45

Forestry 7.44 -9.278 -124.7 -1.37 -18.41 -7.281 -97.86

Fishing 34.8 -7.69 -22.1 -1.901 -5.46 -5.955 -17.11

Oil 1.01 -2.92 -289.11 -0.621 -61.49 -2.244 -222.18

Gas 0.007 -8.489

-

121271.43 -1.495 -21357.14 -7.181 -102585.71

Sugar 29.4 -11.743 -39.94 -1.532 -5.21 -4.29 -14.59

Wood

products 21.8 -16.276 -74.66 -2.013 -9.23 -12.901 -59.18

Vegetable

oils and fats 29.2 -11.564 -39.6 -1.732 -5.93 -8.052 -27.58

Beverages

and tobacco

products

361 2.762 0.77 -0.779 -0.22 3.645 1.01

Petroleum,

coal products 401 -1.322 -0.33 -0.239 -0.06 -1.027 -0.26

Ferrous

metals 234 -9.922 -4.24 -1.616 -0.69 -8.004 -3.42

Electronic

equipment 71.9 -19.561 -27.21 -2.05 -2.85 -14.773 -20.55

Paper

products,

publishing

55.5 -13.058 -23.53 -2.171 -3.91 -10.685 -19.25

Metals nec 480 -15.681 -3.27 -2.488 -0.52 -12.671 -2.64

Minerals nec 303 -2.9 -0.96 -0.502 -0.17 -2.421 -0.80

Metal

products 238 -16.967 -7.13 -2.238 -0.94 -13.304 -5.59

Page 157: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

138

Transport

equipment

nec

38.3 -19.124 -49.93 -1.61 -4.20 -15.898 -41.51

Light

Manufactures 46 -12.64 -27.48 -1.554 -3.38 -9.976 -21.69

Chemical,

rubber,

plastic prods

839 -12.926 -1.54 -2.085 -0.25 -9.643 -1.15

Mineral

products nec 671 -6.517 -0.97 -1.124 -0.17 -5.069 -0.76

Machinery

and

equipment

nec

628 -18.103 -2.88 -2.467 -0.39 -14.842 -2.36

Manufactures

nec 921 -15.814 -1.72 -2.162 -0.23 -11.645 -1.26

Electricity 90.8 -8.398 -9.25 -0.965 -1.06 -6.894 -7.59

Transport and

communicati

on

1606 -8.468 -0.53 -0.928 -0.06 -6.884 -0.43

Services 3076 -9.931 -0.32 -1.371 -0.04 -41.091 -1.3359

Source: Author’s simulation results using GTAP 09 program

Table 5.7 illustrates the simulated changes in Pakistan's imports resulting from the three

simulations. Interestingly, the imports in coal sector deteriorated in all three simulations and

in the case of simulation 2, the imports of plant-based fibers decreased. While in the case of

all other sectors, the imports of Pakistan increased. The results of simulation 1 i.e. GSP Plus

status of Pakistan while maintaining the competitors at their existing positions show that the

only sector where imports decrease is coal where is decreased to US$ -1.18 million while in

rest of the sectors, the imports increased. The major increase is seen in the sectors of cattle,

sheep, goat and horses (US$ 11.763 million), leather products (US$ 11.553 million), dairy

products (US$ 11. 123 million), plant-based fibers (US$ 10.434 million) and electronic

equipment (US$ 10.121 million).

Page 158: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

139

Table 0.7: Aggregate Imports of Pakistan, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent and Millions

US$)

Commodity

Base

Value

(Millions

US$)

GSP Plus with

Competitors

GSP Plus with EU

Capping (Quota)

Potential EBA

Status

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Paddy rice 248 8.146 3.28 1.223 3.28 6.659 2.69

Wheat 913 9.781 1.07 1.474 1.07 7.61 0.83

Plant-based

fibers 354 10.434 2.95 -0.845 -2.95 7.832 2.21

Crops nec 147 1.461 0.99 0.283 0.99 1.294 0.88

Processed

rice 2578 7.49 0.29 1.383 0.29 5.978 0.23

Oil seeds 28.8 2.547 8.84 0.464 8.84 2.14 7.43

Vegetables,

fruit, nuts 938 4.385 0.47 0.759 0.47 3.396 0.36

Sugar cane,

sugar beet 0.013 2.362 18169.23 0.494 18169.23 2.168 16676.92

Leather

products 689 11.553 1.68 1.914 1.68 8.569 1.24

Cereal grains

nec 74 2.254 3.05 0.282 3.05 2.036 2.75

Food

products nec 1117 6.096 0.55 1.169 0.55 4.733 0.42

Wool, silk-

worm

cocoons

2.99 7.017 234.68 0.402 234.68 5.458 182.54

Coal 0.881 -1.18 -133.94 -0.163 -133.94 -0.963 -109.31

Wearing

apparel 4256 9.589 0.23 1.567 0.23 7.304 0.17

Dairy

products 40.2 11.123 27.67 2.064 27.67 8.902 22.14

Textiles 12412 9.781 0.08 0.926 0.08 6.995 0.06

Meat

products nec 3.6 7.894 219.28 0.784 219.28 6.053 168.14

Animal

products nec 77.4 3.165 4.09 0.644 4.09 2.533 3.27

Raw milk 0.536 9.443 1761.75 1.467 1761.75 7.455 1390.86

Meat 112 11.763 10.50 2.083 10.5 9.012 8.05

Page 159: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

140

Cattle, sheep,

goats, horses 0.4 4.857 1214.25 0.876 1214.25 3.91 977.50

Forestry 8.91 3.507 39.36 0.614 39.36 2.662 29.88

Fishing 40 4.562 11.41 1.213 11.41 3.532 8.83

Oil 1.04 0.259 24.90 0.133 24.9 0.201 19.33

Gas 0.007 4.245 60642.86 0.965 60642.86 3.606 51514.29

Sugar 35.4 8.042 22.72 1.443 22.72 6.229 17.60

Wood

products 25.7 9.194 35.77 1.6 35.77 7.164 27.88

Vegetable

oils and fats 37.6 5.103 13.57 0.985 13.57 4.029 10.72

Beverages

and tobacco

products

508 3.495 0.69 0.733 0.69 2.737 0.54

Petroleum,

coal products 434 0.591 0.14 0.195 0.14 0.468 0.11

Ferrous

metals 259 1.878 0.73 0.434 0.73 1.48 0.57

Electronic

equipment 73.8 10.121 13.71 1.736 13.71 7.773 10.53

Paper

products,

publishing

66.3 6.923 10.44 1.041 10.44 5.394 8.14

Metals nec 496 3.026 0.61 0.626 0.61 2.394 0.48

Minerals nec 393 1.824 0.46 0.406 0.46 1.425 0.36

Metal

products 264 8.82 3.34 1.474 3.34 6.806 2.58

Transport

equipment

nec

40.3 8.241 20.45 1.434 20.45 6.575 16.32

Light

Manufactures 50.2 6.238 12.43 1.157 12.43 4.909 9.78

Chemical,

rubber,

plastic prods

941 5.039 0.54 0.732 0.54 3.981 0.42

Mineral

products nec 1032 4.66 0.45 0.784 0.45 3.455 0.33

Machinery

and

equipment

nec

675 7.978 1.18 1.344 1.18 6.24 0.92

Manufactures 1023 8.014 0.78 1.451 0.78 6.186 0.60

Page 160: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

141

nec

Electricity 90.8 5.922 6.52 0.849 6.52 4.724 5.20

Transport and

communicati

on

1606 5.444 0.34 1.088 0.34 4.386 0.27

Services 3076 6.511 0.21 0.819 0.21 20.013 0.651

Source: Author’s simulation results using GTAP 09 program

The results of simulation 2 i.e. GSP plus status when quota restriction applied on imports

from Pakistan into the EU28 show that there two sectors where imports decreased. The

results of this simulation are more interesting and somehow better in terms of the trade

balance of Pakistan. In the sector of plant-based fibers, the decrease in imports is US$ -0.845

million and in the sector of coal, it is (US$ -0.163 million. While rest of sectors show a

positive change in the imports. The major gain in imports is shown in the sectors of cattle,

sheep, goat and horses (US$ 2.083 million), dairy products (US$ 2.064 million), leather

products (US$ 1.914 million), electronic equipment (US$ 1.736 million), wearing apparel

(US$ 1.567 million) and wheat (US$ 1.474 million).

The results of simulation 3 i.e. if Pakistan achieves the status of EBA in the EU28 just like

the status of Bangladesh, seem very similar to the simulation 1. Coal is the only sector that

showed deterioration in the imports with US$ -0.963 million. The rest of the sectors of the

economy showed again in the imports. Maximum gain in imports is seen in the sector of all

services where it increased by US$ 20.013 million. The other major sectors with an increase

in imports include dairy products (US$ 8.902 million), leather products (US$ 8.569 million),

plant-based fibers (US$ 7.832 million), electronic equipment (US$ 7.773 million) and wood

products (US$ 7.164 million).

Overall results of the simulations presented in figure 5.1, table 5.6 and table 5.7 show that

although some sectors of the Pakistan economy showed positive growth in exports but this

increase in exports is quite less than the increase in imports. In terms of trade balance of

Pakistan, the situation remained almost same i.e. trade deficit.

Page 161: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

142

5.7.3 Impact on Real Investment

Real investment is the money spends to purchase the machinery rather than securities and

financial instruments. The study under consideration designed three simulations using GTAP

version 09 to calculate their impact on the real investment. The results of the three

simulations are presented in table 5.8. All three simulations generated positive results. The

first simulation i.e. GSP plus status of Pakistan in the EU28 while relaxing Pakistan from all

tariffs and quotas as compared to its competitors, show a maximum change in real

investment (US$ 2.686 million). The results of the simulation 2 i.e. GSP plus status of

Pakistan when quota restrictions are applied on Pakistan to justify the capping mechanism in

the EU28 show a minimum positive change in real investment (US$ 0.507 million). The

results of simulation 3 i.e. if Pakistan gets the status of EBA in the EU28, are also positive

and similar to simulation 1. There is a positive change of US$ 2.106 million in the real

investment.

Table 0.8: Real Investment, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent and Millions US$)

Simulations Base Value

(Millions US$) Post Shock Effects

Change in Real

Investment

GSP Plus status with

Competitors 29000 29002.686 2.686

GSP Plus Status with

Quota Restrictions 29000 29000.507 0.507

EBA Status 29000 29002.106 2.106

Source: Author’s simulation results using GTAP 09 program

The positive results of all simulations show that after getting the status of a duty-free and

quota-free entry into the EU28, Pakistan needs to enhance the production capacity that is

only possible with improved real investment. In the case of the second simulation, when the

quota is applied on the imports from Pakistan in the EU28, the production capacity has been

limitised that resulted in less improvement in real investment.

Page 162: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

143

5.7.4 Change in Prices of Goods for Domestic Household

A country expects a change in the sectoral prices after sudden change in the trade balance.

The results of three simulations showed an increase in the exports of Pakistan that ultimately

may cause an increase in price level at the domestic market. The increase in exports not only

bring a pressure on the prices of inputs that ultimately result into increased output prices but

also cause an increase in the demand for imports in the neglected production sectors.

The results of the all three simulations are presented in table 5.9. Interestingly the results of

all three simulations show a negative growth in the price of sugar cane and sugar beet sector.

It is because exports from Pakistan in these sectors are already lower than the production

capacity. The maximum deterioration is seen in the simulation 1 i.e. GSP plus status of

Pakistan in the EU28 without restrictions, which is -3.996 percent. The rest of the sectors

showed an increase in the price level for all commodities. The maximum gain in price in

simulation 1 is shown in the sector of ferrous metals (3.514 percent). Other sectors with a

prominent increase in price level include oil seeds (3.301 percent), wheat (3.267 percent),

crops nec (3.208 percent), processed rice (3.129 percent) and minerals nec (2.953 percent).

The minimum increase in the price level is shown in electronic equipment with 0.297

percent.

The results of simulation 2 i.e. GSP plus status of Pakistan in the EU28 with quota

restrictions, showed a minimum increase in the price level among all three simulations. This

is because the quota restrictions control the exports in the EU28 that ultimately reduce the

shortage at domestic level. The sector of sugar cane and sugar beet affected in positive way

for the domestic residents. The price for this sector decreased by (-0.174 percent). Major

increase in prices is shown in the sectors of ferrous metals (0.859 percent), processed rice

(0.533 percent), oil seeds (0.508 percent), wheat (0.529 percent), vegetable oil and fats

(0.497 percent) and plant based fibers (0.493 percent). The minimum increase is seen in the

sector of cattle, sheep, goats and horses (0.019 percent).

The results of the simulation 3 i.e. EBA status of Pakistan in the EU28, are moderate. Just

like in other two simulations, the prices of sugar cane and sugar beet sector deteriorated (-

Page 163: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

144

3.17 percent) while there is a positive change in rest of the sectors. Major increase can be

seen in the sectors of ferrous metals (2.756 percent), oil seeds (2.583 percent), wheat (2.512

percent), processed rice (2.424 percent ( and minerals nec (2.327 percent) while just like

simulation 2, minimum increase is seen in the sector of cattle, sheep, goats and horses (0.088

percent).

Table 0.9: Changes in Prices of Goods in Domestic Market, Constant 2011 Prices

(Percent)

Commodity GSP Plus status

with Competitors

GSP Plus Status with

Quota Restrictions EBA Status

Paddy rice 1.72 0.154 1.738

Wheat 3.267 0.529 2.512

Plant-based fibers 2.831 0.493 2.219

Crops nec 3.208 0.333 2.547

Processed rice 3.129 0.533 2.424

Oil seeds 3.301 0.508 2.583

Vegetables, fruit, nuts 3.141 0.548 2.469

Sugar cane, sugar beet -3.996 -0.174 -3.17

Leather products 1.864 0.29 1.74

Cereal grains nec 1.947 0.282 1.623

Food products nec 2.576 0.088 2.104

Wool, silk-worm cocoons 1.648 0.234 1.479

Coal 2.618 0.439 2.125

Wearing apparel 2.309 0.335 1.925

Dairy products 2.187 0.33 1.815

Textiles 2.346 0.354 1.955

Meat products nec 2.666 0.435 2.133

Animal products nec 2.081 0.306 1.726

Raw milk 2.612 0.433 2.096

Meat 2.424 0.22 2.003

Cattle, sheep, goats, horses 0.12 0.019 0.088

Forestry 2.274 0.37 1.852

Fishing 2.864 0.484 2.259

Oil 2.422 0.323 1.948

Gas 2.869 0.49 2.262

Sugar 2.366 0.361 1.967

Wood products 2.33 0.338 1.939

Vegetable oils and fats 2.908 0.497 2.292

Page 164: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

145

Beverages and tobacco

products 2.274 0.329 1.889

Petroleum, coal products 2.241 0.412 1.777

Ferrous metals 3.514 0.859 2.756

Electronic equipment 0.297 0.062 0.222

Paper products, publishing 0.254 0.054 0.209

Metals nec 2.619 0.426 2.106

Minerals nec 2.953 0.491 2.327

Metal products 2.152 0.346 1.736

Transport equipment nec 2.546 0.423 2.052

Light Manufactures 0.332 0.059 0.253

Chemical, rubber, plastic

prods 1.939 0.327 1.539

Mineral products nec 2.499 0.423 1.996

Machinery and equipment

nec 2.64 0.445 2.105

Manufactures nec 2.106 0.358 1.668

Electricity 2.329 0.412 1.81

Transport and

communication 2.683 0.45 2.141

Services 2.613 0.435 2.088

Source: Author’s simulation results using GTAP 09 program

5.7.5 Changes in the Prices of Commodities Supplied

It is the price that a producer has to pay for its inputs used. A sudden increase in the price

level is expected after the increase in exports for certain inputs. The results of the simulations

are presented in table 5.10. The maximum percentage increase is observed in the results of

simulation 1 i.e. GSP plus Status of Pakistan in the EU28 with no restriction. The maximum

price that producer will pay for the inputs will be in the sector of fishing (3.514 percent). The

other sectors with prominent increase include wood products (2.953 percent), cattle, sheep,

goats and horses (2.908 percent), meat products (2.869 percent) and dairy products (2.864

percent). The minimum increase is shown in the field of coal (0.12 percent) followed by gas

(0.254 percent) and petroleum and coal products (0.332 percent).

The least increase in seen in the results of simulation 2 i.e. GSP plus status of Pakistan in the

EU28 with quota restriction. It is because the quota restrictions may not allow a smooth

increase in export flows of Pakistan that will limitise the prices to increase for the producers.

Page 165: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

146

The maximum in seen in the fishing sector (0.859 percent) followed by sector of cattle,

sheep, goat and horse (0.497 percent) and wood products (0.491 percent). The least increase

is observed in the coal sector (0.019 percent) and then gas (0.054 percent), petroleum and

coal products (0.059 percent) and oil sector (0.062 percent).

Table 0.10: Change in the Supply Price of Input, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent)

Commodity GSP Plus status

with Competitors

GSP Plus Status with

Quota Restrictions EBA Status

Paddy rice 1.864 0.29 1.74

Wheat 1.947 0.282 1.623

Plant-based fibers 2.576 0.088 2.104

Crops nec 1.648 0.234 1.479

Processed rice 2.618 0.439 2.125

Oil seeds 2.309 0.335 1.925

Vegetables, fruit, nuts 2.187 0.33 1.815

Sugar cane, sugar beet 2.346 0.354 1.955

Leather products 2.666 0.435 2.133

Cereal grains nec 2.081 0.306 1.726

Food products nec 2.612 0.433 2.096

Wool, silk-worm cocoons 2.424 0.22 2.003

Coal 0.12 0.019 0.088

Wearing apparel 2.274 0.37 1.852

Dairy products 2.864 0.484 2.259

Textiles 2.422 0.323 1.948

Meat products nec 2.869 0.49 2.262

Animal products nec 2.366 0.361 1.967

Raw milk 2.33 0.338 1.939

Meat 2.908 0.497 2.292

Cattle, sheep, goats,

horses 2.274 0.329 1.889

Forestry 2.241 0.412 1.777

Fishing 3.514 0.859 2.756

Oil 0.297 0.062 0.222

Gas 0.254 0.054 0.209

Sugar 2.619 0.426 2.106

Wood products 2.953 0.491 2.327

Vegetable oils and fats 2.152 0.346 1.736

Beverages and tobacco

products 2.546 0.423 2.052

Petroleum, coal products 0.332 0.059 0.253

Page 166: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

147

Ferrous metals 1.939 0.327 1.539

Electronic equipment 2.499 0.423 1.996

Paper products,

publishing 2.64 0.445 2.105

Metals nec 2.106 0.358 1.668

Minerals nec 2.329 0.412 1.81

Metal products 2.683 0.45 2.141

Transport equipment nec 2.613 0.435 2.088

Light Manufactures 2.604 0.439 2.076

Chemical, rubber, plastic

prods 2.308 0.384 1.836

Mineral products nec 1.611 0.278 1.277

Machinery and

equipment nec 2.584 0.433 2.062

Manufactures nec 2.423 0.409 1.932

Electricity 1.937 0.326 1.539

Transport and

communication 2.703 0.463 2.133

Services 2.831 0.475 11.31

Source: Author’s simulation results using GTAP 09 program

The results of the simulation 3 i.e. if Pakistan achieves the status of EBA in the EU28, shows

a moderate increase in prices for producers. Although service sector prices go very high

(11.31%) but rest of the sectors showed moderate increase with the fish sector (2.756

percent), wood products (2.327 percent), cattle, sheep, goat and horse sector (2.292 percent)

and dairy products (2.259 percent). The least increase in observed in the coal sector (0.088

percent) and then oil (0.222 percent) and gas sector (0.209 percent).

5.7.6 Changes in Prices of Imported Commodities

The prices of imports will also be directly affected by increased exports of Pakistan in all

three simulations. Thus, this will affect all other prices due to interconnection that exists in

the domestic economy. Most domestic prices are prone to fall, that will lead to a switch to

export production. Meanwhile, there is a possibility of a switchover to imported

commodities. This offsetting effect will change the production structure of the economy

which in turns alters the incomes of different institutions in the model.

Page 167: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

148

As predictable, the prices of most of the traded commodities have dropped under all three

simulations used in this study as shown in table 5.11. Construction prices will converge

into positive values for all scenarios but the increase is very marginal. The maximum

reduction in prices is shown by the simulation 1 which is in the sector of paddy rice (-

0.239 percent) and minimum reduction in beverages and tobacco products (-0.003

percent). No change in price is seen in oil seed sector while there is positive change in

price in the sectors of cattle, sheep, goats and horses (0.009 percent), petroleum and coal

products (0.003 percent), metals nec (0.004 percent), minerals nec (0.023 percent),

electricity (0.035 percent), oil (0.004 percent), transport equipment (0.002 percent),

transport and communication (0.047 percent) and services (0.051 percent).

In the case of simulation 2 (GSP plus with quota restriction), there are 8 sectors where

prices increase with the maximum rise in the sector of paddy rice (0.004 percent). There is

no change seen in the sectors of plant-based fibers, leather products, wool and silkworm

cocoons, wearing apparel, textiles, animal products, raw milk, sugar and vegetable oils and

fats. While there is deterioration in prices in rest of the sectors with a maximum decrease

in price in the sector of coal (-0.003 percent).

In the case of simulation 3 (EBA status of Pakistan), there are ten sectors of the economy that

are shown with an increase in price level with a maximum increase in the services sector

(2.319 percent). There is no change in the price level in the sectors of animal products nec

and raw milk. While a reduction in price level is shown in rest of the sectors. Maximum

deterioration in price is seen in the sector of coal (-0.015 percent) while gas, electricity and

transport and communication deteriorated with -0.01 percent.

Table 0.11: Changes in Prices of Imported Commodities, Constant 2011 Prices

(Percent)

Commodity GSP Plus status

with Competitors

GSP Plus Status with

Quota Restrictions EBA Status

Paddy rice -0.239 0.004 0.012

Wheat -0.111 0.002 0.006

Plant-based fibers -0.135 0 0.017

Page 168: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

149

Crops nec -0.083 0.001 0.004

Processed rice -0.01 0.003 0.009

Oil seeds 0 0.001 0.004

Vegetables, fruit, nuts -0.127 0.001 0.003

Sugar cane, sugar beet -0.014 0.001 0.002

Leather products -0.197 0 -0.005

Cereal grains nec -0.069 0.001 0.002

Food products nec -0.076 -0.001 -0.006

Wool, silk-worm

cocoons -0.038 0 -0.002

Coal -0.081 -0.003 -0.015

Wearing apparel -0.127 0 -0.007

Dairy products 0.074 -0.002 -0.008

Textiles -0.207 0 -0.003

Meat products nec -0.04 -0.001 -0.004

Animal products nec -0.022 0 0

Raw milk -0.056 0 0

Meat -0.01 -0.001 -0.004

Cattle, sheep, goats,

horses 0.009 0 0.001

Forestry -0.084 -0.001 -0.008

Fishing -0.051 -0.002 -0.007

Oil 0.004 -0.001 -0.004

Gas -0.005 -0.002 -0.01

Sugar -0.08 0 -0.003

Wood products -0.036 -0.002 -0.008

Vegetable oils and fats -0.028 0 -0.001

Beverages and tobacco

products -0.003 -0.002 -0.008

Petroleum, coal products 0.003 -0.001 -0.005

Ferrous metals -0.008 -0.002 -0.008

Electronic equipment -0.083 -0.002 -0.008

Paper products,

publishing -0.018 -0.002 -0.009

Metals nec 0.004 -0.002 -0.009

Minerals nec 0.023 -0.002 -0.007

Metal products -0.077 -0.001 -0.008

Transport equipment nec 0.002 -0.002 -0.009

Light Manufactures -0.01 -0.002 -0.008

Chemical, rubber, plastic

prods -0.044 -0.001 -0.008

Mineral products nec -0.106 -0.001 -0.008

Page 169: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

150

Machinery and

equipment nec -0.032 -0.002 -0.009

Manufactures nec -0.067 -0.001 -0.008

Electricity 0.035 -0.002 -0.01

Transport and

communication 0.047 -0.002 -0.01

Services 0.051 -0.003 2.319

Source: Author’s simulation results using GTAP 09 program

5.7.7 Impact on Pakistan’s Terms of Trade

It is the ratio of prices that a country receives and pays in exchange for its exports and

imports. It is considered important to understand the impact of changes in price on the

welfare of public generally. The current study investigated the impact of three different

simulations on the change in the price of imports and exports. Pakistan has already achieved

the status of GSP plus in the EU28, the restriction free exports of Pakistan in the case of GSP

plus and EBA may increase the export price of Pakistani products. Similarly, applying quota

restriction may increase the price level at a lower rate.

Figure 5.2 explains the effects of different simulations performed on the Pakistan’s terms-of-

trade. The results of all three simulations are positive. In the case of the first simulation the

export prices that Pakistan receives from EU28 are 0.024 percent higher than the import

prices that Pakistan pays to the EU28. The second simulation also produced positive results

but less than the results of simulation 1. When quota restrictions are applied on the imports of

Pakistan in the EU28, Pakistan is better off in terms of trade with 0.018 percent.

Highest gain is seen in the results of simulation 3, assuming that if Pakistan gets the status of

EBA in the EU28 just like Bangladesh. Due to this status, the exports from Pakistan may

increase rapidly resulting an increase in export prices. Hence, the results of this simulation

show that Pakistan would be 1.937 percent better off in terms of trade.

Page 170: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

151

Figure 0.2: Term of Trade (TOT) of Pakistan, Constant 2011 Prices (Percent)

Source: Author’s simulation results using GTAP 09 program

The results obtained by using GTAP 09 are very much similar to the previous studies that

conclude that output and exports are inter-related. It is very difficult for an economy to grow

without trade openness. Developing and semi-industrialized economies have to focus on the

efficient use of factors of production. When exports in an economy increase, it not only

increases the output level but also cause an increase in the prices at domestic level. Similarly,

increased production put a pressure on the imports of related inputs in the form of capital and

raw material. On the other hand, increased prices of domestic commodities due to export

pressure also cause an increase in the imports of similar commodities. The studies that

support the above argument include (Esfahani, 1991), (Senguptaa & Espanab, 1994),

(Ekanayake, 1999), (Jung & Marshall, 1985) and (Feasel, Kim, & Smith, 2001).

5.8 Results of the Simulations with MyGTAP

The study also used MyGTAP in order to calculate the impact of two simulations on the real

wage rate and household primarily. The base year used in MyGTAP is 2007, as the latest

available SAM for Pakistan is of the year 2007-08. In addition to calculating the impact of

simulations on household income and real wage rate, the study has also discussed some other

0.024 0.018

1.937

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

GSP Plus status with Competitors GSP Plus Status with Quota Restrictions

EBA Status

Page 171: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

152

areas of the economy. The study has only used the two following simulations for this

purpose.

Simulation I: EU-28 GSP Plus status with quota restriction: What would happen if quota

restriction is applied on Pakistan to incorporate the capping mechanism of

the EU28?

Simulation II: Potential EU28-EBA with Competitors: What would happen if Pakistan gets

the Everything But Arms (EBA) status in the EU28 with no Capping

mechanism/Quota restriction, with main competitor Bangladesh that already

enjoying the EBA status?

The results of these simulations are presented below.

5.8.1 Changes in GDP and Production of Pakistan

The results of the both simulations are presented in table 5.12 which show a positive change

in real GDP of Pakistan. In the case of the first simulation, the GDP of Pakistan increases by

US$21.594 million which is 0.015 percent positive change from the baseline value. The

results of the second simulation also very encouraging with positive change of US$ 884.047

million in GDP.

Table 0.12: GDP Quantity Index, Constant 2007 Prices (Percent and Millions US$)

Simulations

Base Value

(Millions

US$)

Post Shock

Effects

Change

in GDP

Percentage

Change

GSP Plus status with

Quota Restrictions 143169.594 143191.188 21.594 0.015

EBA Status 143169.594 144053.641 884.047 0.617

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

Similarly, table 5.13 presents the changes in the real output of different sectors of Pakistan

after both simulations. The results of both simulations reveal mixed effects on the real output

Page 172: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

153

of commodities. The results of the first simulation show that there are 13 sectors out of 38

where output level is increased with maximum increase in the services sector (US$ 0.383

million). The other major winning sectors are construction US$ 0.356 million, sugar US$

0.199 million, vegetable, fruit and nuts US$ 0.196 million, livestock and meat products US$

0.125 million. While there is decrease in the real out in rest of the sectors. The prominent

sectors with a decrease in output include machinery and equipment US$ -2.117 million,

metals and products US$ -1.875, leather products US$ -1.777 million and oil seeds with US$

-1.722 million.

The results of the second simulation show an increase in real output in 25 sectors of Pakistan.

The results reveal that paddy rice shows amaximum gain with US$ 2.080 million followed

by construction sector (US$ 1.14 million), services sector (US$ 1.26 million), mineral

products nec (US$ 0.96 million) and processed food (US$ 0.93 million). While there is

deterioration in the 11 sectors. The prominent sectors with a decrease in output include

leather products with US$ -1.99 million, plant-based fibers with US$ -1.60 million and

textiles with US$ -1.99 million.

The results of the second simulation are more encouraging than simulation 1 which means

that if Pakistan is allowed to export in the EU28 without any restriction, the real output level

will increase in most of the sectors of the economy. Table 5.13 summarizes the story of all

simulations.

Table 0.13: Changes in Pakistan’s Real Output, Constant 2007 Prices (Percent and

Millions US$)

Commodity Base Value

(Millions US$)

GSP Plus with EU Capping

(Quota) Potential EBA Status

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Changes in

Value

Change in

Percent

Paddy rice 1489.76 -0.205 -0.01 2.08 0.14

Wheat 2616.37 -0.102 0.00 -0.12 0.00

Cereal grains

nec 181.39 -0.02 -0.01 0.46 0.26

Vegetables, 7201.54 0.196 0.00 0.17 0.00

Page 173: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

154

fruit, nuts

Oil seeds 365.22 -1.722 -0.47 -0.76 -0.21

Sugar cane,

sugar beet 5895.70 0.087 0.00 -0.11 0.00

Plant-based

fibers 2953.45 -0.796 -0.03 -1.60 -0.05

Cattle,sheep,

goats,horses 4271.85 0.016 0.00 0.23 0.01

Livestock

and Meat

Products

20862.25 0.125 0.00 0.25 0.00

Forestry 291.25 0.027 0.01 -0.07 -0.02

Fishing 879.47 0.076 0.01 0.27 0.03

Minerals 630.01 -0.396 -0.06 0.20 0.03

Oil 1468.00 -0.318 -0.02 -0.23 -0.02

Processed

Food 5029.13 -0.357 -0.01 0.93 0.02

Vegetable

oils and fats 3506.79 -0.528 -0.02 -0.21 -0.01

Dairy

products 4373.73 0.073 0.00 0.62 0.01

Sugar 5333.85 0.199 0.00 0.65 0.01

Beverages

and tobacco

products

3618.37 0.117 0.00 0.67 0.02

Textiles 23984.30 -1.208 -0.01 -1.11 0.00

Wearing

apparel 4404.37 -1.296 -0.03 -0.91 -0.02

Leather

products 1203.00 -1.777 -0.15 -1.99 -0.17

Wood

products 2418.66 -0.628 -0.03 0.28 0.01

Petroleum,

coal products 8120.48 -0.24 0.00 0.53 0.01

Chemical,ru

bber,plastic

prods

4289.23 -1.07 -0.02 0.22 0.01

Mineral

products nec 5498.41 0.119 0.00 0.96 0.02

Metals and

Products 2107.05 -1.875 -0.09 0.19 0.01

Motor

vehicles and

parts

2733.24 -0.569 -0.02 0.55 0.02

Electronic 2672.30 -0.795 -0.03 0.58 0.02

Page 174: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

155

equipment

Machinery

and

equipment

nec

420.68 -2.117 -0.50 -0.94 -0.22

Manufacture

s nec 1111.31 -1.151 -0.10 0.28 0.03

other

utilitities 22303.91 -0.216 0.00 0.66 0.00

Construction 16914.60 0.356 0.00 1.14 0.01

Trade 21665.48 -0.133 0.00 0.39 0.00

Transport

equipment

nec

18768.37 -0.036 0.00 0.64 0.00

Communicat

ion 3009.44 0.058 0.00 0.76 0.03

All Services 55321.80 0.383 0.00 1.26 0.00

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

5.8.2 Changes in Exports and Imports of Pakistan

The duty-free and quota-free entry of Pakistan into the EU28 is expected to bring positive

effects on the exports of Pakistan. Similarly, the flow of imports will also increase due to

increased demand for foreign inputs and resultant higher prices of many goods. Figure 5.3

explains the results of the simulations. The results of both simulations show an increase in

imports and reduction in exports resulting disturbance in the trade balance. The exports of

Pakistan to EU28 reduced by -1.79 percent in the case of the first simulation while in the case

of the second simulation, the reduction is -1.282 percent. This reduction is export is due to

the production capacity of Pakistan in 2007 which was adversely affected by load shedding.

The adverse effects of energy crises increased the production cost in Pakistan resulting into

decline in exports. Due to this reason, the results of the simulations produced negative

impacts.

The results of both simulations show a positive increase in the imports of Pakistan. The

increase is 0.558 percent in the case of the first simulation, while in the case of the second

simulation, the increase is 1.153 percent. This increase in imports is also a result of increased

Page 175: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

156

cost of production in Pakistan. Similarly, in order to increase the production, Pakistan would

also require more inputs to import.

Figure 0.3: Merchandise Exports and Imports of Pakistan (Percent)

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

Figure 5.3 shows that the trade balance is highly deteriorated in case of the first simulation

while in the case of the second simulation, an increase in imports is slightly less than the

decrease in exports. This because the quota restriction will restrict exports to EU28, leaving

more products available for the domestic consumer to consume. Hence imports increased at

a lower rate. While in the case of EBA status, there is no restriction to export resulting into

reduced availability of domestic products. The reduction in availability with increased

demand for imported inputs increased the overall imports of the country.

Looking at the sectoral performance of Pakistan after the tariff free and quota free access in

the EU28, the exports of different products of Pakistan are expected to rise. The increased

exports increase the overall demand for domestic products that ultimately increase the price

level for domestic products. On the other hand, the imports are also expected to rise due to

increased prices of domestic products and demand for imported inputs. It is worth

mentioning that availability of imported goods at a price level lower than domestic goods

decrease the local productivity.

-1.79 -1.282

0.558

1.171

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

GSP Plus with Quota Restrictions EBA Status

Exports Imports

Page 176: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

157

Tables 5.14 and 5.15 explain the results of both simulations with base year 2007. On the

export side, table 5.14 explains the results of changes in exports at sectoral level for both

simulations. There are only 4 winning sectors in case of the first simulation while in the case

of second simulation, there are 5 winning sectors. Rest of the sectors face deterioration in

exports. The maximum gain is shown in the sectors of paddy rice (US$ 26.521 million) and

sugar (US$ 11.162 million) both in the case of second simulation while the minimum gain is

seen in the sector of cereal grain nec (US$ 0.034 million) which is in the case of simulation

one.

On the other hand, in case of the first simulation, maximum deterioration is seen in the sector

of dairy products (US$ -3.871 million) followed by the sector of cattle, sheep, goats, horses

(US$ -2.489 million) while minimum deterioration is seen in the sector of wheat (US$ -0.036

million). In the case of the second simulation, maximum deterioration is observed by the

sector of wheat (US$ -9.486 million) followed by livestock and meat products (US$ -9.552

million) and minimum deterioration is seen in the sector of utilities (US$ -0.22 million).

Table 0.14: Aggregate Exports of Pakistan, Constant 2007 Prices (Percent and Millions

US$)

Commodity

Base Value

(Millions

US$)

GSP Plus with EU Capping

(Quota) Potential EBA Status

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Paddy rice 75.77 0.363 0.48 26.521 35.00

Wheat 137.31 -0.036 -0.03 -9.486 -6.91

Cereal grains nec 2.58 0.034 1.32 -3.257 -126.24

Vegetables, fruit,

nuts 215.47 -0.169 -0.08 -1.46 -0.68

Oil seeds 20.63 -3.014 -14.61 -1.211 -5.87

Sugar cane, sugar

beet 54.5 0.645 1.18 -7.488 -13.74

Plant-based fibers 45.81 1.651 3.60 -4.195 -9.16

Cattle,sheep,goats,h

orses 1.39 -2.489 -179.06 -8.543 -614.60

Livestock and

Meat Products 36.51 -1.819 -4.98 -9.552 -26.16

Page 177: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

158

Forestry 5.36 0.785 14.65 -6.361 -118.68

Fishing 32.96 -2.093 -6.35 -3.799 -11.53

Minerals 106.24 -0.621 -0.58 -1.38 -1.30

Oil 0.52 -0.195 -37.50 -1.892 -363.85

Processed Food 1421.44 -1.234 -0.09 2.577 0.18

Vegetable oils

and fats 121.88 -3.058 -2.51 -3.119 -2.56

Dairy products 29.63 -3.871 -13.06 -4.244 -14.32

Sugar 30.39 -0.672 -2.21 11.162 36.73

Beverages and

tobacco products 141.04 -0.992 -0.70 -0.479 -0.34

Textiles 8367.7 -1.866 -0.02 -2.143 -0.03

Wearing apparel 2613.35 -1.838 -0.07 -1.629 -0.06

Leather products 468.46 -3.425 -0.73 -4.507 -0.96

Wood products 45.26 -2.547 -5.63 -1.953 -4.32

Petroleum, coal

products 623.81 -0.595 -0.10 -0.37 -0.06

Chemical,rubber,

plastic prods 374.53 -2.182 -0.58 1.301 0.35

Mineral products

nec 306.69 -2.111 -0.69 -2.05 -0.67

Metals and

Products 619.85 -3.232 -0.52 -0.638 -0.10

Motor vehicles

and parts 63.04 -1.606 -2.55 -0.323 -0.51

Electronic

equipment 28.06 -2.442 -8.70 -0.867 -3.09

Machinery and

equipment nec 370.78 -2.204 -0.59 -1.124 -0.30

Manufactures nec 472.9 -2.332 -0.49 -0.393 -0.08

other utilitities 0.52 -1.758 -338.08 -0.22 -42.31

Construction 66.98 -1.431 -2.14 -0.883 -1.32

Trade 51.44 -1.827 -3.55 0.601 1.17

Transport

equipment nec 1157.89 -0.971 -0.08 -0.36 -0.03

Communication 126.11 -1.166 -0.92 -1.799 -1.43

All Services 2483.34 -2.041 -0.08 -1.085 -0.04

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

Table 5.15 shows the results of the change in imports produced by both simulations. In the

case of the first simulation, there are only 6 sectors where imports deteriorated while rest of

the sectors show positive indication. The sectors where imports deteriorated include plant-

Page 178: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

159

based fibers (US$ -1.791 million), forestry (US$ -0.672 million), paddy rice (US$ -0.462

million), sugar cane, sugar beet (US$ -0.353 million), oil (US$ -0.215 million) and cereal

grain nec (US$ -065 million). While rest of the sectors showed positive indication with

maximum gain in imports in the sector of dairy products (US$ 2.449 million) followed by

livestock and meat products (US$ 2.435 million) and the minimum gain was seen in the

sector of wheat (US$ 0.026 million).

The results of simulation 2 shown in table 5.15 indicate that there are only 2 sectors that

show a reduction in imports which are oil seeds (US$ -0.06 million) and other utilities (US$ -

0.17 million) while in the case of rest of the sectors, the imports increased. The maximum

increase in imports in seen in the sector of paddy rice (US$ 8.74 million) followed by

livestock and meat products (US$ 6.67 million) while minimum progress was shown in the

sector of construction trade (US$ 0.09 million).

Table 0.15: Aggregate Imports of Pakistan, Constant 2007 Prices (Percent and Millions

US$)

Commodity Base Value

(Millions US$)

GSP Plus with EU Capping

(Quota) Potential EBA Status

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Changes

in Value

Change in

Percent

Paddy rice 90.12 -0.462 -0.51 8.74 9.70

Wheat 171.68 0.026 0.02 4.75 2.77

Cereal grains

nec 2.82 -0.065 -2.30 1.95 69.29

Vegetables,

fruit, nuts 296.05 0.326 0.11 2.76 0.93

Oil seeds 7.93 0.125 1.58 -0.06 -0.72

Sugar cane,

sugar beet 64.33 -0.353 -0.55 4.49 6.97

Plant-based

fibers 48.83 -1.791 -3.67 0.52 1.05

Cattle,sheep,

goats,horses 1.43 1.926 134.69 4.99 348.67

Livestock

and Meat

Products

39.60 2.435 6.15 6.67 16.85

Forestry 6.47 -0.672 -10.39 3.87 59.86

Page 179: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

160

Fishing 38.71 1.388 3.59 2.73 7.04

Minerals 136.61 0.204 0.15 1.34 0.98

Oil 0.55 -0.215 -39.09 0.77 140.73

Processed

Food 1825.23 0.775 0.04 3.08 0.17

Vegetable

oils and fats 139.84 1.294 0.93 1.71 1.22

Dairy

products 35.85 2.449 6.83 3.58 9.98

Sugar 42.92 1.445 3.37 2.50 5.81

Beverages

and tobacco

products

198.90 0.931 0.47 1.09 0.55

Textiles 9664.46 0.643 0.01 1.17 0.01

Wearing

apparel 3023.97 1.404 0.05 1.85 0.06

Leather

products 514.35 2.405 0.47 3.80 0.74

Wood

products 54.12 0.96 1.77 1.23 2.27

Petroleum,

coal products 689.53 0.109 0.02 0.80 0.12

Chemical,rub

ber,plastic

prods

426.52 0.534 0.13 0.68 0.16

Mineral

products nec 452.14 1.796 0.40 2.64 0.58

Metals and

Products 656.26 0.548 0.08 1.03 0.16

Motor

vehicles and

parts

68.84 0.623 0.90 1.19 1.73

Electronic

equipment 29.00 1.754 6.05 1.66 5.71

Machinery

and

equipment

nec

392.60 0.287 0.07 1.04 0.27

Manufacture

s nec 527.40 1.831 0.35 1.59 0.30

other

utilitities 0.52 0.833 160.19 -0.17 -31.92

Construction 66.98 1.142 1.70 1.18 1.76

Trade 51.44 1.415 2.75 0.09 0.18

Transport 1157.89 1.058 0.09 1.10 0.09

Page 180: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

161

equipment

nec

Communicati

on 126.11 1.409 1.12 1.74 1.38

All Services 2483.34 1.532 0.06 1.61 0.06

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

5.8.3 Impact on Real Investment

It is the amount of money spends to purchase of machinery rather than securities and

financial instruments. The study under consideration designed two simulations using

MyGTAP with the base year 2007 to calculate their impact on the real investment.

The results of the both simulations are positive and presented in figure 5.4. The results of the

simulation 1 show a positive change in real investment (US$ 0.378 million). The results of

simulation 2 are also positive and better than simulation 1. There is a positive change of US$

1.153 million in the real investment.

Figure 0.4: Changes in Real Investment, Constant 2007 Prices (Million US$)

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

0.378

1.153

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

1.1

1.2

1.3

GSP Plus Status with Quota Restrictions EBA Status

Page 181: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

162

The positive results of both simulations show that after getting the status of a duty-free and

quota-free entry into the EU28, Pakistan needs to enhance the production capacity that is

only possible with improved real investment.

5.8.4 Impact on Pakistan’s Terms of Trade

Terms of trade is defined as the ratio of prices that a country receives and pays in exchange

of its exports and imports. It is considered important to understand the impact of the change

in price on the welfare of public generally. The current study investigated the impact of two

different simulations on the change in the price of imports and exports. Pakistan has already

achieved the status of GSP plus in the EU28, the restriction free exports of Pakistan in the

case of GSP plus and EBA may increase the export price of Pakistani products. Similarly,

applying quota restriction may increase the price level at a lower rate.

Figure 5.5 explains the effects of different simulations performed on the Pakistan’s terms of

trade. The results of both simulations are positive but very different. In the case of first

simulation the export prices that Pakistan receives from EU28 are 0.019 percent higher than

the import prices that Pakistan pays to the EU28.

Figure 0.5: Changes in Term of Trade (TOT) of Pakistan, Constant 2007 Prices,

(Percent)

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

0.019

1.834

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.9

2

GSP Plus Status with Quota Restrictions EBA Status

Page 182: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

163

Highest gain is seen in the results of simulation 2, assuming that if Pakistan gets the status of

EBA in the EU28 just like Bangladesh. Due to this status, the exports from Pakistan may

increase rapidly resulting an increase in export prices. Hence, the results of this simulation

show that Pakistan is receiving 1.834 percent higher export price than it is paying for its

imports from EU28.

5.8.5 Changes in Household Income in Pakistan

The study has discussed the impact of three simulations by using GTAP 09 and two

simulations by using MyGTAP by focusing on the issues of trade, GDP, output and prices. A

unique feature of the MyGTAP model used in this study is the capability to disaggregate the

regional household into both private and government entities (Minor & Mureverwi, 2013).

The study disaggregated the regional household of standard GTAP model into 18 types to

conduct a detailed analysis. The simulations used in the study will calculate the effects on

household income distribution and expenditures. The data and weights required were

obtained from the latest comprehensive Pakistani Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) 2007-08

developed by International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) under Pakistan Strategy

Support Program (PSSP) project, Pakistan.

While conducting the welfare analysis, the studies that employ CGE models, normally show

all households are equally affected due to any change in the trade policy. In the case of

MyGTAP, the households are distributed into categories aiming to calculate the impact on

the marginalized population before designing a trade policy. Any change in the wage rate is

considered as change in the household income. Poverty is calculated on the basis of per-

capita income which is a key determinant of the economic status of a household. The

household income consists of income coming from different factors, so any change in the

income of factors means change in the income of households.

Page 183: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

164

Figure 0.6: Changes in Households Income in Pakistan, Constant 2007 Prices (Percent)

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

The results of both simulations are summarized in figure 5.6 which show a positive change in

the overall household income. There is a change of 0.74 percent in the case of the first

simulation but in the case of the second, the change is 2.17 percent which means that if

Pakistan is allowed to export duty-free and quota-free into the EU28, the household income

in Pakistan will rise.

The results below show a change in all 18 categories of households. The regional household

is divided into three categories, household in Punjab, a household in Sindh and household in

rest of the Pakistan. The results further reveal that every household is not equally affected.

There are some households better off and vice versa.

5.8.6 Household Income of Large and Medium Farm

Table 5.16 represents the results of both simulations in order to check their impact on the

income of a large and medium household of Pakistan. The results reveal that in the case of

the first simulation, the household other than Sindh and Punjab have a positive change of

0.029 percent in its income while the income of the household in Sindh is reduced by -0.478

percent and in Punjab by -0.239 percent. On the other hand, the income of all households

increases with maximum increase of 2.347 percent in rest of the Pakistan.

0.74

2.17

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

GSP Plus with Quota Potential EBA Status

Page 184: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

165

Table 0.16: Changes in Household Income of Large and Medium Farm, Constant 2007

Prices (Percent)

Household Types HH

Code

Population

(millions)

Income

shares

(percent)

GSP Plus

with Quota

Potential

EBA Status

Large and medium farm

Sindh H-MF1 0.8 1.5 -0.478 1.831

Large and medium farm

Punjab H-MF2 2.4 6.1 -0.239 1.613

Large and medium farm

other H-MF3 0.6 0.8 0.029 2.347

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

5.8.7 Income of Small Farm Household

The results of the both simulations are presented in table 5.17 which show the impact on the

small household living in Pakistan. The results reveal that small farmer living anywhere in

Pakistan is befitted in both cases. The results further reveal that the farmer living in parts

other than Sindh and Punjab is benefitting maximum in case of both simulations while the

small farm household in Sindh is getting minimum benefits in both cases. The maximum

benefit that small farm household of other Pakistan getting is 2.253 percent which is in case

of simulation 2 and small farm household of Sindh is getting minimum benefit of 0.331

percent in case of first simulation.

Table 0.17: Changes in Household Income of Small Farmers, Constant 2007 Prices

(Percent)

Household Types HH Code Population

(millions)

Income

Shares

(percent)

GSP Plus

with

Quota

Potential

EBA

Status

Small farm Sindh H-SF1 3.1 1.8 0.331 2.146

Small farm Punjab H-SF2 16 11.5 0.487 2.179

Small farm other

Pakistan H-SF3 5.6 3.3 0.885 2.253

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

Page 185: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

166

5.8.8 Income of Landless Farmer Household

In this section, we will discuss the rural household that is a farmer but does not own a piece

of agriculture land in any area of Pakistan. The results of both simulations are presented in

table 5.18 that show a positive change in income of all rural households that are landless but

are farmers. In the case of a first simulation landless farmer of Sindh is gaining minimum

(0.405 percent) while the landless farmer of rest of the Pakistan is gaining maximum (0.954

percent). The results of the second simulation show that landless farmer of Punjab is gaining

maximum (2.452 percent) while the landless farmer of Sindh is gaining minimum (2.08

percent).

Table 0.18: Changes in Household Income of Landless Farmers, Constant 2007 Prices

(Percent)

Household Types HH

Code

Population

(millions)

Income

shares

(percent)

GSP Plus

with

Quota

Potential

EBA

Status

Landless farmers Sindh H-0F1 2.5 1.4 0.405 2.08

Landless farmers Punjab H-0F2 3.6 1.8 0.68 2.452

Landless farmers other

Pakistan H-0F3 1.7 0.7 0.954 2.323

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

5.8.8.1 Income of Landless Labor

The household living in rural area of Pakistan working in agriculture farms as a laborer and

having no land is included in landless labor. The results showing the impact of both

simulations on the household income of landless agriculture labor of Pakistan are presented

in table 5.19. The results show a maximum gain for the landless labor of whole Pakistan in

both simulations as compared to any other household. In the case of the first simulation,

maximum gain is shown for the landless agriculture labor of Sindh (1.563 percent) while the

landless agriculture labor of Punjab is getting minimum gain (1.432 percent). In the case of

the second simulation, the results are quite similar with maximum gain again in case of

landless agriculture labor of Sindh (4.136 percent) while the landless agriculture labor of

Punjab is getting minimum gain (3.512 percent).

Page 186: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

167

Table 0.19: Changes in Household Income of Rural Agricultural Labor, Constant 2007

Prices (Percent)

Household Types HH

Code

Population

(millions)

Income

shares

(percent)

GSP Plus

with Quota

Potential

EBA Status

Landless agri. Lab Sindh H-AGW1 3 1.5 1.563 4.136

Landless agri. Lab Punjab H-AGW2 3.3 1.4 1.432 3.512

Landless agri. Lab other

Pakistan H-AGW3 0.4 0.2 1.498 3.944

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

5.8.8.2 Income of Rural Non-farm Household

In rural areas of Pakistan, there are households that have no direct connection with

agriculture farming. The results shown in table 5.20 reveal the impact of both simulations on

the income of non-farm rural households. The rural non-farm household of Sindh gets

minimum gain (0.994 percent) in the case of the first simulation while rest of the rural non-

farm households in Pakistan gain similar amount (0.997 percent). Similarly, in the case of the

second simulation, rural non-farm households of Sindh get maximum gain (1.569 percent)

and minimum gain (1.356 percent) in the case of rural non-farm households of rest of the

Pakistan.

Table 0.20: Changes in Household Income of Rural Non-farm Household, Constant

2007 Prices (Percent)

Household Types HH Code Population

(millions)

Income

shares

(percent)

GSP Plus

with Quota

Potential

EBA Status

Rural non-farm quintile 1 H-NFQ1 8.2 2.8 0.994 1.569

Rural non-form quintile 2 H-NFQ2 8.9 3.3 0.997 1.539

Rural non-farm quintile

other H-NFOTH 27.7 17.3 0.997 1.356

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

Page 187: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

168

5.8.8.3 Income of Urban Household

Table 5.21 shows the impact of both simulations on the urban household of Pakistan. The

urban household of Sindh is showing maximum gain in both simulations (0.935 percent and

1.342 percent respectively) while the minimum gain is seen in the income of an urban

household of rest of the Pakistan in the case of both simulations (0.86 percent and 1.162

percent respectively).

Table 0.21: Changes in Household income of Urban Household, Constant 2007 Prices

(Percent)

Household Types HH

Code

Population

(millions)

Income

shares

(percent)

GSP Plus

with Quota

Potential

EBA

Status

Urban quintile 1 H-UQ1 8.6 2.6 0.935 1.342

Urban quintile 2 H-UQ2 8.6 3.4 0.927 1.265

Urban other H-UOTH 25.7 38.7 0.86 1.162

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

Overall, factor income remains positive for almost all households. If there is no tariff and

quota restriction from EU28, the income of every household type will increase. Primarily, it

is because the increased exports of Pakistan will definitely increase the economic activities in

the economy and the backward and forward linkages of the industry will bring positive

change in the income of every household.

5.9 Effects on Real Returns to Factors in Pakistan

Increased trade and especially exports increase the rate of return to factors. According to the

Heckscher-Ohlin model (although it is workable only in the economies where the amount of

goods and the number of production factors is equal (Suranovic S. , 2010)), the products are

assumed to be homogeneous, despite many markets in the world are represented in a better

way with differentiated products. In the case of Pakistan, the model suggests that Pakistan

faces a capital deficit as compared to its competitors and this deficit decreases the return to

capital (Khan et al, 2015).

Page 188: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

169

The model used for the calculation of effects on real returns to factors is the extension of

standard GTAP model and uses the Armington assumption that categories the products on

the basis of country of origin. Furthermore, assimilation could disturb the rate of return on

capital by virtue of the prices of transitional and capital goods.

The labor force of Pakistan is more than 65 million. The unemployment rate in Pakistan is

about 6 percent (GOP, 2015). Despite tremendous government efforts for ensuring minimum

wages in Pakistan “Minimum Wages Ordinance 1961, the Punjab Minimum wages for

unskilled Workers Ordinance 1969, Minimum wages Board,” etc ensure that government is

dedicated to support the low-income groups.

The results of both simulations show the change in factor prices with regards to the price

index for private consumption expenditure. However, it fails to consider the impact of

changes in government’s revenue, and government’s capacity to redistribute tax income to

individuals, whether it is through transfer payments or provision of public goods (Khan et al,

2015).

5.9.1 Wages of Large Agriculture Land Owned Labor

The results of both simulations are presented in the table 5.22 showing changes in the wages

of household that owns the large agricultural land. The results reveal that in the case of the

first simulation, the wage of labor decrease by -1.45 percent while in the case of the second

simulation, it increased by 0.283 percent.

Table 0.22: Change in Real Wages of Large Agriculture Land Owned Labor (Percent)

Factor RF Code Description GSP Plus with

Quota

Potential EBA

Status

Labor LA-AGL Labor - agric (own)-large -1.45 0.283

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

Page 189: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

170

5.9.2 Wages of Medium Agriculture Land Owned Labor

The results in table 5.23 show the changes in the wages of labor that own medium size piece

of agriculture land, after performing both simulations.

Table 0.23: Change in Real Wages of Medium Agriculture Land Owned Labor

(Percent)

Factor RF Code Description GSP Plus with

Quota

Potential EBA

Status

Labor

LA-MF1 Labor - agric (own)-med Sindh -1.244 1.184

LA-MF2 Labor - agric (own)-med Punjab -1.335 0.285

LA-MF3 Labor - agric (own)-med OPak -0.956 1.487

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

The results show that in the case of the first simulation, the wage of labor with medium sized

agriculture land decreased by -1.335 percent in the region of Punjab. The results of the

second simulation show that wage of all households with medium sized agriculture land

increased with maximum increase in the case of labor living in parts of Pakistan other than

Punjab and Sindh and that is 1.487 percent.

5.9.3 Wages of Small Agriculture Land Owned Labor

In the case of farmers having a small area of agriculture land in all areas of Pakistan, the

results seem quite similar to the case of farmers having medium sized agriculture land. The

results of both simulations are shown in table 5.24. According to the results, the wages of the

labor with small size agriculture farm decreased everywhere in Pakistan when the country

faces quota restrictions in the EU while a positive change can be seen in the case of

simulation 2 i.e. if Pakistan gets the status of EBA in the EU28.

Page 190: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

171

Table 0.24: Change in Real Wages of Small Agriculture Land Owned Labor (Percent)

Factor RF Code Description GSP Plus with

Quota

Potential EBA

Status

Labor

LA-SF1 Labor - agric (own)-sm Sindh -1.227 1.136

LA-SF2 Labor - agric (own)-sm Punjab -1.017 0.851

LA-SF3 Labor - agric (own)-sm OPak -0.454 1.577

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

5.9.4 Wages of Skilled and Unskilled Labor

One additional simulation is added in the study by assuming unskilled labor is unemployed in

the model and then performing both simulations to check what would be the impact on real

wages of other types of labors. The impact of both simulations on the wage of skilled and

unskilled labor is shown in the table 5.25. The results show that in the case of the first

simulation, the wage of agriculture labor, in general, is increased by 1.355 percent, in the

case of unskilled non-agriculture labor, the wage increased by 0.286 percent and in the case

of skilled non-agriculture labor, it is increased by 0.304 percent.

The results of the second simulation are quite different where the wage of non-agriculture

unskilled labor is decreased by -1.851 percent while a maximum increase is seen in the

agriculture labor (5.366 percent)

Table 0.25: Change in Real Wages of Skilled and Unskilled Labor (Percent)

Factor RF Code Description GSP Plus with

Quota

Potential EBA

Status

Labor

LA-AGW Labor - agric (wage) 1.355 5.366

LA-SKU Labor - non-ag (unsk) 0.286 -1.851

LA-SK Labor - non-ag (skilled) 0.304 0.075

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

It is worthy to note that the supply of labor is fixed in the agriculture sector, so any decrease

in demand may decrease the wage of the agriculture labor. The results of the simulations

Page 191: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

172

show that the increase in the wage of skilled labor is greater than the increase in the wage of

unskilled labor. Similarly, the supply of production labor is also fixed which results into

increase in wage rate as the production demand increases. The results of the simulations

show that increased exports will increase the wage rate which opposes the theory that

liberalized trade may reduce the wage rate. For further information, please see (Stiglitz,

1970), (Davis, 1996), (Feenstra & Hanson, 1997), (Topalova, 2007), (Harrison A. , 2007).

The majority of the exports from Pakistan are textile and agricultural products so increased

volume of exports due to GSP plus and EBA status in the EU28 might shift labor from the

agriculture to industry. This is primarily due to the fact that land is sector specific but labor is

inter-sectorally mobile. So this offset effect might lead industrialization in Pakistan.

5.9.5 Real Return to Land of Large Agriculture Farms

After labor, land is another factor of production, the rent paid to land is also affected by

certain changes in the trade. The source land is fixed, so any change in demand for the

production of goods requiring more land may result into achange in return to land. The

results shown is table 5.26 reveal the effects of both simulations on the large land farms. The

results of the first simulation show a negative change in the real return to land in case of large

farms everywhere in Pakistan but in case of simulation 2, the large land farm of Punjab is

losing in return while a positive change is seen in the farms of Sindh (0.464 percent) and rest

of the Pakistan (2.053 percent) which is maximum gain.

Table 0.26: Change in Real Return to Land of Large Farms (Percent)

Factor RF Code Description GSP Plus with

Quota

Potential EBA

Status

Land

LN-LG1 Land - large- Sindh -1.252 0.464

LN-LG2 Land - large- Punjab -1.639 -0.175

LN-LG3 Land - large - OthPak -1.085 2.053

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

Page 192: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

173

5.9.6 Real Return to Land of Medium Agriculture Farms

The case of a change in areal return to the land of medium farms is a little bit different than

the previous case. The results of both simulations are presented in the table 5.27 that show a

reduction in return to the land of medium farms in the case of first simulation.

Table 0.27: Change in Real Return to Land of Medium Farms (Percent)

Factor RF Code Description GSP Plus

with Quota

Potential

EBA Status

Land

LN-MD1 Land - irrigated - med Sindh -1.228 1

LN-MD2 Land - irrigated - med Punjab -1.338 0.359

LN-MD3 Land - irrigated - med OthPak -0.951 1.467

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

The maximum reduction in return is seen in the province of Punjab (-1.338 percent). While

in the case of the second simulation, the results are quite encouraging. There is gain in return

to the land of medium farms in all areas of Pakistan with maximum gain in return of 1.467

percent in the region other than Punjab and Sindh.

5.9.7 Real Return to the Land of Small Agriculture Farms

The results of both simulations relating to change in return to the land of small farms are

presented in table 5.28 which are quite similar to the results of medium size farms. The gain

is negative in case of the first simulation for all regions of Pakistan with a maximum loss in

return in the province of Sindh (-1.215 percent). The results of the second simulation are

opposite to the first simulation that shows gain in return to the land of small farms in all areas

of Pakistan. The maximum gain is seen in the areas other than provinces of Punjab and Sindh

that is 1.613 percent.

Table 0.28: Change in Real Return to Land of Small Farms (Percent)

Factor RF Code Description GSP Plus with

Quota

Potential EBA

Status

Land

LN-SM1 Land - irrigated - sm Sindh -1.215 0.977

LN-SM2 Land - irrigated - sm Punjab -1.022 0.942

LN-SM3 Land - irrigated - sm OthPak -0.399 1.613

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

Page 193: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

174

5.9.8 Real Return to the Land of Non-irrigated Agriculture Farms

There are certain areas in Pakistan where traditional canal system is not activated to irrigate

the agriculture land. Those farms are called non-irrigated farms. The results of both

simulations are presented in table 5.29 to show the return to the land of non-irrigated farms.

Interestingly the results are very similar to the results of previous two cases (land of medium

and small farms). In the case of the first simulation, there is a negative gain in all areas of

Pakistan where non-irrigated farms exist with the loss of -1.12 percent in the province of

Sindh while in rest of the Pakistan the non-irrigated land suffered from the loss of -1.337

percent in return. The case of the second simulation shows gain in return of the non-irrigated

land with maximum gain in the Sindh province (0.821 percent) whereas in rest of the

Pakistan, the non-irrigated land gains 0.708 percent in return.

Table 0.29: Change in Real Return to Land of Non-irrigated Farms (Percent)

Factor RF Code Description GSP Plus with

Quota

Potential EBA

Status

Land

LN-DR1 Land non-irrig - sm/m Sindh -1.12 0.821

LN-DR2 Land non-irrig - sm/m Punjab -1.337 0.708

LN-DR3 Land non-irrig - sm/m OthPak -1.337 0.708

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

It is interesting to note that the results of the first simulation suggest a negative gain in return

to land which also support the results of Magee (1972) while working on USA economy. The

results are contradictory with the findings of Hong (1993) which suggested that protection

increases the return as resources shift towards agricultural productivity. The gain is not

possible without technology whether the economy is facing restrictions or not (Ghosh, 2003).

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem which is based on the famous Heckscher-Ohlin model also

supports the results that liberalized trade lead to increase in return to land (Leamer, 1995).

Similarly, a large number of researchers support the results that return on land increases if

there are no restrictions on the exports of an economy, for example, see [(Runge & Halbach,

1990) and (Chang, 1979)].

Page 194: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

175

5.9.9 Real Return to the Capital

We have already discussed the impact of both simulations on the return to labor and land. In

this section, we will focus on the factor of capital. The study has divided the capital into four

categories and results along with categories are presented in table 5.30. The results of both

simulations show gain in return to capital in most of the types except capital other than

agriculture (-1.106 percent in the case of quota restriction on Pakistan) and capital formation

(-0.054 percent in case if Pakistan gets EBA status in the EU28). In the case of both

simulations, the maximum gain is seen in capital livestock, 1.818 percent when the quota is

applied on exports from Pakistan to justify the capping mechanism of EU28 and 6.24 percent

gain in return if Pakistan gets the status of EBA in the EU28.

Table 0.30: Change in Real Return to Capital (Percent)

Factor RF Code Description GSP Plus with

Quota

Potential EBA

Status

Capital

K-LVST Capital livestock 1.818 6.24

K-AGR Capital other agriculture -1.106 0.798

KFORM Capital formal 0.105 0.105

KINF Capital informal 0.28 -0.054

Source: Author simulation results using MyGTAP program

The results of both simulations suggest that there is gain in return to capital in most of the

cases which support the work of researchers like (Hong, 1993), (Chang, 1979) and

(Thompson, 2016). Minor & Mureverwi (2013) and Khan et al (2015) also produced the

same results while studying the Mozambique and Pakistan economy respectively. Although

Ghosh, (2003) also support this but adds that gain to return to the capital can be maximized

with continuous improvement in the technology.

Page 195: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

176

CHAPTER 6: SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION

6.1 Introduction

The study attempted to examine the development experience and the changing character of

Pakistan’s economy over the years in brief. In earlier years, a significant proportion of its

GDP was accounted for by its agriculture sector. But the structure of Pakistan’s economy has

shown a remarkable transformation in its economic structure and now has become more

industrialized. The relative importance of manufactured exports increased substantially as

opposed to traditional ones. The manufacturing sector of Pakistan in the case of exportable

commodities is not diversified.

The evolution of Pakistan’s trade relations with the EU dates back with the establishment of

diplomatic relations in 1962. Currently, the EU is by far the country’s single largest trading

partner absorbing approximately one-third of its total exports; the principle supplier of capital

goods and the leading donor of foreign capital assistance. Historically, the export

performance of Pakistan in the EU market showed encouraging trends. In comparison,

Pakistan export performance (measured in terms of growth and market share) has been far

better in contrast to many GSP, the ACP and Mediterranean countries.

The Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) plus status of Pakistan in the EU28 remained

the main focus of the study. Among the EU’s system of preferences, GSP plus status is

considered a vital opportunity for any economy engaged in trade with EU. Pakistan is among

those countries that are enjoying this status. Although, most of the commodities are

exportable to the EU28 without any tariff or quota under the system of GSP plus but still it is

behind the Everything But Arms (EBA) status of EU granted to Bangladesh.

6.2 Summary of Research Findings and Policy Implications

This section intends to summarize the major findings of the results. The study analyzed the

impact of GSP plus status of Pakistan in the EU through a number of simulation experiments.

The study employed standard GTAP to analyze the impact of GSP plus at the macro level.

Most of the studies conducted previously have found modest and mixed impacts resulting

Page 196: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

177

from tariff elimination on a continental wide basis (for more details please see Mold &

Mukwaya (2015), Alam (2015) and Mevel & Karingi (2012)). Aggregated welfare impacts

were calculated for a single "regional" household representative of the government, private

households, and investors. Recognizing that aggregate or "regional" welfare analysis may not

illustrate the impact of different simulations on households, this research also employs an

alternative CGE model called MyGTAP initially developed by Minor & Walmsley (2012)

and then Khan (2015) for Pakistan that disaggregates the regional household into separate

entities.

The standard GTAP examines the impact of trade policies at the macro level, so the study

introduced the MyGTAP model to calculate the effects at household and regional level. It

pays special attention to the labor market according to the skills and region of the labor.

There are numerous studies that employed GTAP model with the assumption of perfect

competition and constant return to scale (Hertel, 1998), in this study, the simulations were

run by using standard GTAP and MyGTAP. The summarized results of standard GTAP are:

The results of all simulations show a positive change in the real GDP ranging from

US$45.75 million (0.021 percent from baseline) in the case of the second simulation.

Maximum positive change is US$269.828 million (0.126 percent) in second

simulation. In the case of the third simulation, the real GDP increases with

US$209.047 million (0.098 percent).

The results of all three simulations revealed mixed effects on the real output of

commodities. On a dollar value basis, Textile, Wearing apparel and wool, silk-worm

cocoons are impacted the most, with a US$ 6.15 million increase (0.03 percent from

baseline) in output for wearing apparel sector when Pakistan achieved GSP plus

status and compared with competitors. Under same status textiles sector improves

with US$ 4.844 million and wool, silk-worm cocoons with US$ 3.459 million. The

notable decrease was seen in the output of metals nec and ferrous metals. The

maximum decline is seen in metals nec (-1.40 percent) under GSP plus status when

comparing with other competitors and -1.128 percent if Pakistan gets EBA status.

Page 197: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

178

Similarly, in the case of ferrous metals, the decline is -0.59 percent under GSP plus

with competitors and -0.474 percent under EBA status. The maximum decrease under

GSP plus with quota mechanism is seen in wool and silk-worm cocoons which is -

0.881 percent from baseline.

A positive change is seen in real investment under all three simulations. The first

simulation i.e. GSP plus status of Pakistan in the EU28 while relaxing Pakistan from

all tariffs and quotas as compared to its competitors, show a maximum change in real

investment (US$ 2.686 million). The results of the simulation 2 i.e. GSP plus status of

Pakistan when quota restrictions are applied on Pakistan to justify the capping

mechanism in the EU28 show a minimum positive change in real investment (US$

0.507 million). The results of simulation 3 i.e. if Pakistan gets the status of EBA in

the EU28, are also positive and similar to simulation 1. There is a positive change of

US$ 2.106 million in the real investment.

The merchandise imports of Pakistan increase under all simulations with 4.791

percent under the first simulation, 0.729 percent under second and 3.692 percent

positive change from baseline in case of the third simulation. Similarly, an increase in

imports is seen in all sectors except plant base fiber and coal. The maximum decrease

is seen in coal sector (-133.94 percent) under both cases of GSP status. It decreased

by -109.94 percent under EBA status. A decrease of -2.95 percent is seen in the sector

of plant base fiber under quota restrictions in the EU after GSP plus. GSP Plus status

of Pakistan while maintaining the competitors at their existing positions show that the

major increase is seen in the sectors of cattle, sheep, goat and horses (US$ 11.763

million), leather products (US$ 11.553 million) and dairy products (US$ 11. 123

million. The GSP plus status when quota restriction applied on imports from Pakistan

into the EU28 shows amajor gain in imports in the sectors of cattle, sheep, goat and

horses (US$ 2.083 million), dairy products (US$ 2.064 million) and leather products

(US$ 1.914 million). Similarly, if Pakistan gets EBA status in the EU28 just like the

status of Bangladesh, the major gain in imports is seen in the sector of all services

where it increased by US$ 20.013 million. The other major sectors with an increase in

Page 198: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

179

imports include dairy products (US$ 8.902 million), leather products (US$ 8.569

million) and plant based fibers (US$ 7.832 million).

A decrease of -1.47 percent in merchandise exports is seen when quota restriction is

applied in the EU, while exports increase by 1.318 percent when comparing with

competitors in the EU and 0.907 percent increase if Pakistan gets EBA status. A

positive change is seen in the sectors of textiles, wearing apparel, beverage &tobacco

and paddy rice while rest of the sectors experience a decline. The maximum gains are

seen in the wearing apparel sector with US$ 32.401 million in case of simulation 2.

There is no winning sector under GSP plus the status of Pakistan in the EU28 with

quota restrictions. The results of the simulation 3 show some winning sectors with

maximum gain in wearing apparel sector with US$ 21.554 million from baseline

followed by textiles sector with US$ 6.209 million. The maximum decrease is seen in

the service sector (US$ -41.091 percent) if Pakistan gets EBA status in the EU.

A positive change in terms of trade is seen in all three simulations. In the case of the

first simulation the export prices that Pakistan receives from EU28 are 0.024 percent

higher than the import prices that Pakistan pays to the EU28. When quota restrictions

are applied on the imports of Pakistan in the EU28, Pakistan is better off in terms of

trade with 0.018 percent. While thehighest gain is seen in the results of simulation 3,

assuming that if Pakistan gets the status of EBA in the EU28 just like Bangladesh.

The results of this simulation show that Pakistan would 1.937 percent better off.

A sudden increase in the price level is seen in the prices of inputs that producer have

to pay. The maximum percentage increase is observed in the results of simulation 1.

The maximum price that producer will pay for the inputs will be in the sector of

fishing (3.514 percent). The least increase in seen in the results of simulation. The

maximum in seen in the fishing sector (0.859 percent). The results of the simulation

3, show a moderate increase in prices for producers. Although service sector prices

go very high (11.31%) but rest of the sectors showed moderate increase.

Page 199: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

180

The prices of most of the traded (imported) commodities have dropped under all

three simulations used in this study. Construction prices will converge into positive

values for all scenarios but the increase very marginal. The maximum reduction in

prices is shown by the simulation 1 which is in the sector of paddy rice (-0.239

percent) and minimum reduction in beverages and tobacco products (-0.003

percent). No change in price is seen oilseed sector. While in the case of simulation

2 (GSP plus with quota restriction), there is a maximum rise in the sector of paddy

rice (0.004 percent). There is no change seen in the sectors of plant-based fibers,

leather products, wool and silkworm cocoons, wearing apparel, textiles, animal

products, raw milk, sugar and vegetable oils and fats. While there is deterioration

in prices in rest of the sectors with a maximum decrease in price in the sector of

coal (-0.003 percent). In case Pakistan gets EBA status in the EU, there is an increase

in price level with a maximum increase in the services sector (2.319 percent). There

is no change in the price level in the sectors of animal products nec and raw milk.

While rest of the sectors are shown with a decrease in the price level. Maximum

deterioration in price is seen in the sector of coal (-0.015 percent) while gas,

electricity and transport and communication deteriorated with -0.01 percent.

The summarized results with MyGTAP are as follow:

The results of the both simulations show a positive change in real GDP of Pakistan.

The GDP of Pakistan increases by US$21.594 million (0.015 percent) when quota

restrictions are applied on imports from Pakistan in the EU under GSP plus status

while a positive change of US$ 884.047 million (0.617 percent) in real GDP in seen

if Pakistan achieves the status of EBA in the EU.

The results of both simulations show mixed effects in the sectoral output. The results

of the second simulation show better performance than the first. The maximum

increase in theservices sector (US$ 0.383 million) when quota restrictions are applied

on imports from Pakistan in the EU. On the other hand, under same simulation

maximum decrease in real output is seen in the sector of machinery and equipment

Page 200: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

181

US$ -2.117 million. The results of the simulation if Pakistan gets the EBA status

reveal that paddy rice shows amaximum gain with US$ 2.080 million. The prominent

sectors with a decrease in output include leather products with US$ -1.99 million,

plant-based fibers with US$ -1.60 million and textiles with US$ -1.99 million.

The results of both simulations show an increase in merchandise imports and

reduction in merchandise exports resulting disturbance in the trade balance. The

exports of Pakistan to EU28 reduced by -1.79 percent in the case of the first

simulation while in the case of the second simulation, the reduction is -1.282 percent.

This reduction is export is due to the production capacity of Pakistan in 2007 which

was adversely affected by load shedding which increased the production cost in

Pakistan resulting in adecline in exports. The results of both simulations show a

positive increase in the imports of Pakistan. The increase is 0.558 percent in the case

of the first simulation, while in the case of the second simulation, the increase is

1.153 percent. This increase in imports is also a result of increased cost of production

in Pakistan. Similarly, in order to increase the production, Pakistan would also require

more inputs to import.

The sectoral change in exports is also not encouraging in both cases. The results of

the simulation when quota restrictions are applied on Pakistani imports in the EU

show only four winning sectors with maximum gain in exports in the sector of plant-

based fiber (US$ 1.651 million). The maximum deterioration is seen in the sector of

dairy products (US$ -3.871 million). The results of the second simulation, if Pakistan

gets the EBA status in the EU, show only 5 winning sectors with maximum gain in

the sector of paddy rice (US$ 26.521 million). The maximum deterioration is

observed by the sector of wheat (US$ -9.486 million) and minimum deterioration is

seen in the sector of utilities (US$ -0.22 million).

When quota restrictions are applied on the Pakistani imports in the EU, the results

show that there are only 6 sectors where imports deteriorated that include plant-based

fibers (US$ -1.791 million), forestry (US$ -0.672 million), paddy rice (US$ -0.462

Page 201: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

182

million), sugar cane, sugar beet (US$ -0.353 million), oil (US$ -0.215 million) and

cereal grain nec (US$ -065 million). While rest of the sectors showed positive

indication with maximum gain in imports in the sector of dairy products (US$ 2.449

million). The results of the simulation, when EBA status is given to Pakistan indicate

that there are only 2 sectors that show reduction in imports which are oil seeds (US$ -

0.06 million) and other utilities (US$ -0.17 million) while in case of rest of the

sectors, the imports increased with maximum increase in the sector of paddy rice

(US$ 8.74 million).

The results of both simulations show gain in terms of trade with maximum gain in

case of second simulation i.e. if Pakistan gets the status of EBA in the EU28 just like

Bangladesh, show that Pakistan is receiving 1.834 percent higher export price than it

is paying for its imports from EU28. In the case of the first simulation the export

prices that Pakistan receives from EU28 are 0.019 percent higher than the import

prices that Pakistan pays to the EU28.

The results of both simulations show an increase in real investment. The results of the

simulation 1 show positive change in real investment (US$ 0.378 million) and the

results of simulation 2 are also positive and better than simulation 1. There is a

positive change of US$ 1.153 million in the real investment.

The results of both simulations show a positive change in overall household income.

There is a change of 0.74 percent in case of first simulation, but in case of second

simulation, the change is 2.17 percent which means that if Pakistan is allowed to

export duty free and quota free into the EU28, the household income in Pakistan will

rise. In the case of the first simulation, the household income of medium and a large

farm of Sindh is reduced by -0.478 percent and in Punjab by -0.239 percent, while the

household income of all other households increases under both simulations. The

maximum gain is seen in the income of landless agriculture labor of Pakistan. The

landless farmer is better off than the small farm owners of Pakistan under both

simulations. Similarly, the results of both simulations show that income of small farm

Page 202: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

183

owners is better than the income of medium and large farm owners. Interestingly, the

household income of non-agriculture rural and urban population is increased

maximum under the first simulation and under the second simulation, the maximum

gain in household income is seen by the landless agriculture labor.

Factor income of in most of the cases decreased in case of the first simulation while it

is opposite in the case of the second simulation. In the case of first simulation, the

wages of labor increase having no agriculture land, skilled and unskilled non-

agriculture labor. Also the income of livestock capital and formal capital increased.

The results of the simulation 2 show opposite trend. The income of non-agriculture

unskilled labor, land of large agriculture farms in Punjab and informal capital

decreases while rest of the sectors show an increase in the income. The maximum

gain is seen in the wages of agriculture labor (5.366 percent), the income of large

farm land increases by 2.053 percent in the areas of Pakistan other than Punjab and

Sindh and the income of livestock capital rises by 6.24 percent. The overall increase

in income of all factors in the case of the second simulation is due to increased output

in Pakistan.

The policy implications for the study are straight forward and related to trade policy which is

also the main concern of the thesis. Any attempt to improve competitiveness in view of

increased competition after the GSP plus implementation will have to start from one basic

acknowledgment: it is the firms themselves that have the key to success in their hands. Only

if they adopt the right strategies, based on a clear vision of what and how they are producing,

for whom they are producing and in which target market they intend to export and why do

they have a chance of succeeding? Therefore, those firms/enterprises wishing to be proactive

require a supportive environment daring firms to compete within a tougher competition

environment to come. Public authorities have an important role to play in restoring hope

through creating and monitoring a safe and healthy business environment where Pakistan’s

firms can effectively compete domestically and then in the world market.

Page 203: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

184

The production activities of the country are concentrated towards the sectors of textiles,

wearing apparel, beverages and tobacco and leather products that need to be diversified with

cost effective methods. Similarly, China is the largest competitor of Pakistan in the EU28.

Along with China, India, Turkey and Bangladesh are also major competitors for Pakistan. A

country cannot supply every kind of the products to the world market. While looking at the

weaknesses of its competitors Pakistan can provide better products to the importers.

Moreover, Pakistan can focus on those markets where its competitors have a small share.

Bangladesh is already enjoying the status of EBA in the EU market, China is enjoying least

cost production techniques and Turkey along with modern technology is benefitting from

transportation cost. The results of different simulations revealed that there are many sectors

of the economy where Pakistan is not performing well. It is time to redesign the policies and

educate the industry to invest in those areas where country is lacking behind. The fruits of

GSP Plus or EBA status can only be enjoyed if the industry realizes the hidden potential in

various sectors of the economies.

6.3 Limitations of the Study

Parallel to many empirical studies, this study was constrained by a variety of factors which

could be considered as limitations. The first and the most important limitation is the database,

similar to most other studies which adopt CGE models. The current study used the database

of standard GTAP v9.0 with the base year 2011-12 to calculate the effects of GSP plus status

at the macro level. In order to calculate the effects of GSP plus at the household level, the

study used GTAP v9.0 and Social Accounting Matrix with the base year 2007-08. This

extension of standard GTAP model is known as MyGTAP which provided the parameters

related to trade elasticity but these parameters are not estimated econometrically. Although a

reasonable level of confidence can be attached to the conclusions of the model simulations,

as the results are robust with different Armington parameter values. It is noted that household

welfare results are sensitive to parameter values assumed in the model. Likewise, a superior

understanding of implications at household level could have been achieved if we had been

able to use more disaggregated data at the household level.

Page 204: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

185

Another limitation of the study was that the model could only be simulated for comparative

static results rather than the dynamics ones. This could be used to understand the path that

changes the income and expenditure of households over time. It would have been ideal to use

a recursive dynamic model to track the policy implications, given the nature of the

fundamental research problem. Construction of a recursive dynamic CGE of Pakistan model

was severely constrained by relevant data such as capital stock at the industry level and other

time series forecasts for exogenous variables.

Regional disparities play an important role to determine the potential for growth in Pakistan.

It can be seen from the nature of opportunities available in the country by keeping in mind

the regional disparities and look into the regional development aspects with respect to trade

opportunities. It would have been ideal if we had evaluated the policy issues using a regional

CGE model. However, availability of reliable data at the regional level is a major constraint

in constructing a regional CGE model for Pakistan.

Despite the above mentioned limitations, the global CGE model (standard GTAP) generated

reasonable good results at macro level for the country and the MyGTAP model with the most

latest constructed SAM (2007-08) for Pakistan and the other database, generated plausible

empirical results in analyzing the impact of GSP plus status (and EBA) on household welfare

within the context of Pakistan.

6.4 Recommendations for Further Research

The recommendations for further research are directly or indirectly inspired by the above-

mentioned limitations of the current study. Some recommendations for further extension of

the study are as followed:

a) The data available in standard GTAP and SAM is not updated regularly, it would be useful

to spend more time, effort and resources into developing an inclusive database for a more

recent base year. Furthermore, the database should include some of the key features, for

instance, regional level industry and macro data – regional Input-Out out (IO) tables, industry

Page 205: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

186

level capital stocks data and time series forecasts for different exogenous variables in the

present model.

b) The GTAP can be enlarged for Pakistan to include features, such as regional extensions in

tracking regional disparities, recursive dynamics in making conditional forecasts, and to

include features of imperfect competition in some of the markets - in order to better capture

the ground realities in Pakistan markets. Introducing imperfection feature of markets will

ensure more realistic simulation results with respect to trade concessions provided by the EU

in terms of implications in the long run within the Pakistan context.

c) Developing an econometrically estimated household level micro-simulation model and

linking it with the CGE model would be an ideal way to obtain welfare impacts of the GSP

plus and other trade opportunities.

6.5 Concluding Observations

The study has attempted to calculate whether the GSP plus status of Pakistan in the EU28

produce positive change in the economic growth in the presence of other competitors with

same or different product mix. The study attempted to calculate the effects of different

potential and current opportunities for Pakistan by using standard GTAP. It further used the

MyGTAP model that is an extension of standard GTAP model, developed by Khan (2015)

for Pakistan that helped to calculate the effects of policy shocks not only at the aggregate

level but also at household income and real wages. The latest standard GTAP used the base

year 2011 while MyGTAP employed the latest available Social Accounting Matrix (SAM)

with the base year 2007-08. The study used GTAP for three simulation experiments (GSP

plus status of Pakistan with respect to its competitors, GSP Plus of Pakistan in the EU28 with

quota restrictions to justify the capping mechanism and if Pakistan gets EBA status in the

EU28) and MyGTAP for two simulation experiments (GSP Plus of Pakistan in the EU28

with quota restrictions to justify the capping mechanism and if Pakistan gets EBA status in

the EU28).

Page 206: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

187

The descriptive analysis of the results of different simulations using both standard GTAP and

MyGTAP reveal that there is an overall increase in the GDP of Pakistan. The incentive to

export in the EU28 will increase the production level in the Pakistan. Similarly, the

improvement in production also increases the real wages and household income. Despite

some limitations, the Global CGE model developed in this study produces plausible results

that would help to shed some light on the current debate about the GSP plus effects on

production, exports and household in Pakistan. The results of all simulations by using

standard GTAP 09 suggest a positive change in the real GDP, real investment, merchandise

imports and terms of trade of Pakistan. The merchandise exports of Pakistan increase in first

and third simulation but in case of the second simulation, it shows a decline in merchandise

exports. Further, a positive change in the output of many commodities is seen in the case of

all three simulations.

The main findings of the both simulations, run under MyGTAP model also show a positive

change in real GDP, merchandise imports, real investment and terms of trade while the first

simulation shows a negative change in merchandise exports. Similarly, – EBA status of

Pakistan in the EU28 show an increase in the household income with maximum gain by the

household of rural Sindh with no agriculture land and a positive change in real wages of

most of the factors. However, the large and medium agricultural household types show a

negative change in household income in case of the first simulation. Comparatively low

improvement in the urban and non-farm household of rural areas. Therefore, empirical

evidence in terms of the household welfare from this study supports the overall view that

Pakistan can gradually gain from GSP plus status.

Page 207: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

188

Bibliography

Abbas, M., & Raza, H. (2013). Effect of Trade Deficit on the Economy of Pakistan.

Interdisciplinary Journal of Contemporary Research in Business Institute of Interdisciplinary

Business Research , 4 (11), 176-215.

Abdelkmalki, L., Jallab, M. S., & Sandretto, R. (2007). The Free Trade Agreement Between

the United States and Morocco, the Importance of Gradual and Asymmetric Agreement.

Working paper du GATE 2007-02, Groupe d’Analysis et de Theorie Economique (GATE).

Abe, K. (2007). Japan’s Official Development Assistance in the Future: Economic Model

Forecast and its Implication. FASID Discussion Paper on Development Assistance No.11.

Acharyya, R. (2011). A note on quantitative trade restrictions, income effects and wage

inequality. Economic Modelling , 28 (1), 2628–2633.

Adam, C. S., & O’Connell, S. A. (2004). Aid versus trade revisited: Donor and recipient

policies in the presence of learning-by-doing. The Economic Journal , 150-173.

Adams, P. D., Horridge, M., Parmenter, B. R., & Zhang, X. G. (1998). Long-run Effects on

China of APEC Trade Liberalization. Monash University. The Centre of Policy Studies

(COPS).

Adelman, I., & Robinson, S. (1988). Macroeconomic adjustment and income distribution :

Alternative models applied to two economies. Journal of Development Economics , 29 (1),

23-44.

Afonso, O. (2001). The Impact of International Trade on Economic Growth. FEP Working

Papers 106, Universidade do Porto, Faculdade de Economia do Porto.

Agenor, P. R. (2002). Macroeconomic Adjustment and the Poor: Analytical Issues and

Cross-Country Evidence. Washington DC.

Ahmad, N. (1992). Liberalization of foreign trade and international competitiveness. In N.

Ahmed, Financing Pakistan development in the 1990s. Oxford University Press.

Ahmad, N., & Kalim, R. (2014). Implications of Export Competitiveness, and Performance

of Textile and Clothing Sector of Pakistan: Pre and Post Quota Analysis. Pakistan Journal of

Commerce and Social Sciences , 8 (3), 696-714.

Ahmed, V., & Amjad, R. (1984). The Management of Pakistan’s Economy, 1947-82.

Karachi, Pakistan: Oxford University Press.

Ahmed, V., & O’ Donoghue , C. (2008). Welfare impact of external balance in Pakistan:

CGE-microsimulation analysis. Eleventh Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis.

Marina Congress Centre in Helsinki, Finland.

Ahmed, V., & O’Donoghue, C. (2009). Redistributive Effect of Personal Income Taxation in

Pakistan. Pakistan Economic and Social Review , 47 (1), 1-17.

Ahmed, V., & O'Donoghue, C. (2010). External Shocks in a Small Open Economy: A CGE -

Microsimulation Analysis. Lahore Journal of Economics , 15 (1), 45-90.

Ahmed, V., Abbas, A., & Ahmed, S. (2013). Public Infrastructure and Economic Growth in

Pakistan: A Dynamic CGE-microsimulation Analysis. working paper 2013-01 , Partnership

for Economic Policy (PEP).

Akbar, F., & Chauveau, T. (2009). An Analysis of Exchange Rate Risk Exposure Related to

Public Debt Portfolio of Pakistan: Beyond Delta-Normal VAR Approach. SBP Working

Paper Series No. 30, State Bank of Pakistan.

Page 208: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

189

Alam, S. (2015). The Effect of Preferential Trade Agreements on Pakistan’s Export

Performance. CREDIT Research Paper, University of Nottingham, Centre for Research in

Economic Development and International Trade.

Alan, W. L., McCulloch, N., & McKay, A. (2004). Trade liberalization and poverty: The

Evidence So Far. Journal of Economic Literature , 42 (1), 72-115.

Alcala, F., & Ciccone, A. (2004). Trade and Productivity. Quarterly Journal of Economics ,

119 (02), 613-646.

Alex, S. (2000). Analysing policy for sustainable livelihoods. Brighton: Institute of

Development studies.

Ali, S., & Ahmad, N. (2010). The Effects of Fiscal Policy on Economic Growth: Empirical

Evidences Based on Time Series Data from Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review , 49

(4), 497–512.

Anderson , K., Cockburn, J., & Martin, W. (2009). Agricultural Price Distortions, Inequality

and Poverty. Agricultural Distortions Working Paper 94, World Bank.

Anwar, T. (2001.). Impact of Globalization and Liberalization on Growth, Employment and

Poverty: A Case Study of Pakistan. UNU/WIDER Development Conference on Growth and

Poverty. Helsinki.

Archer, C., & Butler, F. (1996). The European Union: Structure and Process. New York:

Saint Martin's Press.

Arrow, K. J., & Debreu, G. (1954). Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy.

Econometrica , 22 (3), 265-290.

Asian Development Bank. (1985). Strategies for Economic Growth and Development: The

Bank’s Role in Pakistan. Manila: Asian Development Bank.

Atkinson, A. B. (1995). "Income Distribution in Europe and the United States. University of

Oxford, Nuffield College, . Economics Group.

Auera, R. A., & Mehrotrab, A. (2014). Trade linkages and the globalisation of inflation in

Asia and the Pacific. Journal of International Money and Finance , 129–151.

Awan, A. g., Sarwar, G., & Siddique, K. (2015). The Impact of Generalized Scheme of

Preference (GSP+) on Pakistan’s Textile Exports. International Journal of Economics,

Commerce and Management , 1, 1-27.

Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. (2009). Estimating the effects of free trade agreements on

international trade flows using matching econometrics. Journal of International Economics ,

77 (1), 63-76.

Balassa, B. (1985). Exports, Policy Choices, and Economic Growth in developing Countries

After the 1973 oil Shock. Journal of Development Economics , 18, 23-35.

Baldwin, R. E., & Venables, A. J. (1995). Regional economic integration. In G. M.

Grossman, & K. Rogoff, Handbook of International Economics (1 ed., Vol. 3, pp. 1597-

1644). Elsevier.

Baldwin, R., & Freund, C. (2011). Preferential Trade Agreements and Multilateral

Liberalization. In J. P. Chauffour, & J. C. Maur, Preferential Trade Agreement Policies for

Development: A Handbook (pp. 121–141). The World Bank Group.

Baldwin, R., & Jaimovich, D. (2012). Are Free Trade Agreements contagious? Journal of

International Economics , 88 (1), 1-16.

Bandara, J. S. (1991). Computable general equilibrium models for development policy

analysis in LDCs. Journal of economic surveys , 5 (1), 3–69.

Page 209: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

190

Bannister, G. J., & Thugge, K. (2001). International Trade and Poverty Alleviation. IMF

Working Paper No. 01/54.

Barro, R. J., & Martin, X. S.-i. (2004). Economic Growth (Second Edition ed.). London: The

MIT Press.

Bhatti, A. A., Naqvi, H. A., & Batool, Z. (2014). Fiscal Policy and its Role in Reducing

Income Inequality: A CGE Analysis for Pakistan. 30st Annual General Meeting and

Conference, Pakistan Society of development Economists (PSDE). Islamabad.

Blake, A. (1998). Computable General Equilibrium Modelling and the Evaluation of

Agricultural Policy. PhD Thesis, University of Nottingham, Nottingham.

Blitzer , C. R., Clark, P. B., & Taylor, L. (1975). Economy-Wide Models and Development

Planning. Oxford University Press.

Bollen, Y., Ville, F. D., & Orbie, J. (2016). EU trade policy: persistent liberalisation,

contentious protectionism. Journal of European Integration , 38 (3), 279-294.

Borges, A. M. (1986). Applied General Equilibrium Models: An Assessment of Their

Usefulness for Policy Analysis. OECD Economic Studies No. 7.

Bouët, A., & Krasniqi , V. B. (2006). Is Trade Pessimism Justified? Opening the “Black

Box” of Trade Modeling. Modeling the Gains from Trade Liberalization. Geneva,

Switzerland: International Food Policy Research Institute.

Bouet, A., Debucquet, D. L., Dienesch, E., & Elliott, K. (2010). The Costs and Benefits of

Duty-Free, Quota-Free Market Access for Poor Countries: Who and What Matters. Working

Paper 206, Center for Global Development.

Bourguignon, F., Branson, W. H., & Melo, J. (1989). Macroeconomic adjustment and

income distribution: A macro-micro simulation model. Paris: OECD.

Boyer, I., & Schuschny, A. (2010). Quantitative assessment of a free trade agreement

between Mercosur and the European Union. CEPAL - Serie estudios estadísticos y

prospectivos No. 69, Natural Resources and Infrastructure Division, Statistics and Economic

Projections Division.

Brenton, P. (2003). Integrating the Least Developed Countries into the World Trading

System: The Current Impact of EU Preferences under Everything But Arms. Journal of

World Trade , 37 (03), Vol. 37, No. 3, pp. 623-646.623-646.

Brockmeier, M. (2001). A Graphical Exposition of the GTAP Model. GTAP Technical Paper

No. 8 2001.

Brulhart, M., & Mathews, A. (2007). EU External Trade Policy. In A. M. El-Agraa, The

European Union: Economics & Policies (pp. 921-967). Cambridge University Press.

Burfisher, M. E. (2011). Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models.

Cambridge University Press.

Burniaux, J. M., & Mensbrugghe, D. v. (1994). The RUNS Global Trade Model. Economic

& Financial Modelling , 161-282.

Butt, M. S. (2006). Impact of tariff cuts on Pakistan: a computable general equilibrium

analysis with particular focus on main exports and regional disparities. PhD Thesis, Griffith

University.

Carbone, M., & Orbie, J. (2016). The Trade-Development Nexus in the European Union:

Differentiation, Coherence and Norms. Routledge, Taylor and Francis Group.

Castilho, M., Menendez, M., & Sztulman, A. (2010). Trade Liberalization, Inequality and

Poverty in Brazilian States. DIAL (Développement, Institutions et Mondialisation).

Page 210: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

191

Chanda , R. (1997 ). Impact of Trade Liberalization on Foreign Direct Investment in

Producer Services . Paper No. 103, IIM Bangalore Research .

Chang, W. (1979). Some Theorems of Trade and General Equilibri um with Many Goods

and Factors. Econometrica , 709 - 26.

Changa, R., Kaltanic, L., & Loayza, N. V. (2009). Openness can be good for growth: The

role of policy complementarities. Journal of Development Economics , 90 (1), 33–49.

Chaudhry, M. G., & Chaudhry, G. M. (1997). Pakistan’s Agricultural Development since

Independence: Intertemporal Trends and Explanations. The Pakistan Development Review ,

36 (4), 593-612.

Chenery, H. B. (1979). Structural Change and Development Policy. New York: Oxford

University Press.

Chishti, A., Zulfiqar, M., & Naqvi, Z. (2008). The impact of trade policies on Pakistan's

preferential access to the European Union. Working Paper No. TRADE08/C3/C18, Centre

for the Analysis of Regional Integration at Sussex.

Chow, G. C. (1977). Effective use of econometric models in macroeconomic policy

formulation. Econometric Research Program, Research Memorandum No. 206.

Cicowiez, M., Bonilla, C. D., & Bonilla, E. D. (2010). Impacts of Trade Liberalization on

Poverty and Inequality in Argentina: Policy Insights from a Non-parametric CGE

Microsimulation Analysis. International Journal Of Microsimulation , 3 (1), 118-122.

Clarete, R. L., & Roumasset, J. A. (1986). CGE models and development policy analysis:

problems, pitfalls, and challenges. American Journal of Agricultural Economics , 86 (5),

1212-1216.

Cloutier , M. H., Cockburn , J., & Decaluwe , B. (2008). Education and Poverty in Vietnam:

A Computable General Equilibrium Analysis. Working Paper No. 08-04, CIRPEE .

Cockburn, J., Decaluwé, B., & Robichaud, V. (2008). Trade Liberalization and Poverty: A

CGE Analysis of the 1990s.

Cockburn, J., Savard, L., & Tiberti, L. (2014). Macro-Micro Models. In C. O'Donoghue, The

Handbook of Microsimulation Modelling (pp. 251-274). Emerald Group Publishing Limited.

Corong, E. l. (2014). Tariff Elimination, Gender and Poverty in the Philippines: A

Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Microsimulation Analysis. Monash University.

Faculty of Business and Economics. Centre of Policy Studies.

Cuyvers, L., & Soeng, R. (2013). The impact of the EU Generalized System of Preferences

on exports and GSP utilization by Asian and Latin American countries. Journal of

International Trade Law and Policy , 12 (1), 80 - 97.

Davis, D. (1996). Trade liberalization and income distribution. The National Bureau of

Economic Research.

De Melo, J. (1988). CGE Models for the Analysis of Trade policy in the Developing

Countries. World Bank.

de Melo, J., Panagariya, A., & Rodrik, D. (1993). The new regionalism : A country

perspective. World Bank.

Debowicz, D., Dorosh, P., Haider, H., & Sherman Robinson , S. (2012). A Social Accounting

Matrix for Pakistan, 2007-08. International Food Policy Research Institute. Islamabad:

Pakistan Strategy Support Program.

Devarajan, S., Go, D. S., Lewis, J. D., Robinson, S., & Sinko, P. (1997). Simple General

Equilibrium Modeling. In J. F. Francois, & K. A. Reinert, Applied Methods for Trade Policy

Analysis: A Handbook (pp. 156-185). Cambridge University Press.

Page 211: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

192

Devarajan, S., Lewis, J. D., & Robinson, S. (1986). A Bibliography of Computable General

Equilibrium (CGE) Models Applied to Developing Countries. Gianinni Foundation, Division

of Agriculture and Natural Resources. Berkeley: University of California.

Dewatripont, M., & Michel, G. (1987). On Closure Rules, Homogeneity and Dynamics in

Applied General Equilibrium Model. Journal of Development Economics , 26 (1), 65—76.

Diao, X., Elbasha, E. H., Roe, T. L., & Yeldan, A. E. (1996). A Dynamic CGE Model: An

Application of R&D- Based Endogenous Growth Model Theory. Bulletin No 96/1, University

of Minnesota, Economic Development Center.

Diao, X., Yeldan, E., & Roe, T. L. (1998). A Simple Dynamic Applied General Equilibrium

Model ofa Small Open Economy: Transitional Dynamics and Trade Policy. journal of

economic development , 23, 77-101.

Dick, H., Gerken, E., Mayer, T., & Vincent, D. (1984). Stabilisation strategies in primary

commodity exporting countries: A case study of Chile. Journal of Development Economics ,

14 (1-3), 47-75.

Din, M. U., Ghani, E., & Mahmood, T. (2009). Determinants of Export Performance of

Pakistan: Evidence from the Firm-Level Data. The Pakistan Development Review , 48 (3),

227–240.

Dixon, P. B., Parmenter , B. R., Ryland, G. J., & Sutton, J. M. (1977). ORANI, A General

Equi¬librium Model of the Australian Economy: Current Specification and Illustrations of

Use for Policy Analysis. First Progress Report of the IMPACT Project, Vol 2, Australian

Government Publishing Service, Canmberra.

Dixon, P. B., Parmenter, B. R., Sutton, J., & Vincent, D. P. (1982). ORANI: A Multisectoral

Model of the Australian Economy. Amsterdam: North Holland.

Dixon, P., Parmenter, B., Sutton, J., & Vincent, D. (1982). ORANI: A multisectoral model of

the Australian Economy. North-Holland.

Does Export Promotion Increase Economic Growth? Some Cross-Section Evidence. (2002).

Development Policy Review , 20 (03), 333–349.

Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2004). Trade, growth and poverty. Economic Journal , 22-49.

Dornbusch, R. (1980). Open Economy Macroeconomics. Basic Book Publisher Inc.

Dorosh, P., Niazi, M. K., & Nazli, H. (2006). A Social Accounting Matrix for Pakistan, 2001-

02: Methodology and Results. PIDE Working Papers, Pakistan Institute of Development

Economics, Islamabad.

Dowlah, C. (2008). The Generalized System of Preferences of the United States: Does It

Promote Industrialization and Economic Growth in Least Developed Countries? The Law

and Development Review. 1: 1(5) , 1 (1), 71- 96.

Edwards, S. (1997). Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We Really Know?

National Bureau of Economic Research.

Ekanayake, E. M. (1999). Exports and Economic Growth in Asian Developing Countries:

Cointegration and Error-Correction Models. Journal of Economic Development , 24 (2), 43-

56.

Emery, R. F. (1967). The Relation of Exports and Economic Growth. International Review

for Social Sciences , 20 (04), 470-486.

Esfahani, H. (1991). Exports, imports, and economic growth in semi-industrialized countries.

Journal of Development Economics , 35 (1), 93-116.

Ethier, W. J. (1974). Some of the Theorems of International Trade with Many Goods and

Factors. Journal of International Economics , 4 (2), 199-206.

Page 212: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

193

European Commission. (2013). The EU’s new Generalised Scheme of Preferences (GSP).

European Commission. (2011). The Review of the Generalised System of Preferences.

Available:.

European Constitution. (2004, October 29). Treaty Establishing a Constitution for Europe.

Retrieved from University of Minnesota :

https://www1.umn.edu/humanrts/instree/europeanconstitution.html

Fargeix, A., & Sadoulet, E. (1990). A Financial Computable General Equilibrium Model for

the the Analysis of Ecuador's Stabilization Program. OECD Development Centre.

Feasel, E., Kim, Y., & Smith, S. C. (2001). Investment, Exports and Output in South Korea:

A VAR Approach to Growth Empirics. Review of Development Economics , 5 (3), 421–432.

Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (1997). Foreign Direct Investment and Relative Wages:

Evidence from Mexico's Maquiladoras. Journal of International Economics , 42 (2), 371-

393.

Fei, J. C., Ahmad, I., Rahman, A., Khan, M. I., Khan, R. A., & Naseem, S. M. (1962). A

Preliminary Input-Output Table for Large Scale Industries in Pakistan. Pakistan

Development Review , 1, 47-83.

Feltenstein, A., Lopes, L., Mendoza , J. P., & Wallace, S. (2013). The Impact of Micro-

simulation and CGE modeling on Tax Reform and Tax Advice in Developing Countries”: A

Survey of Alternative Approaches and an Application to Pakistan. Working Paper 13-09,

International Center for Public Policy.

Fontana, M., & Wood, A. (2000). Modeling the Effects of Trade on Women, at Work and at

Home. World Development , 28 (7), 1173–1190.

Ford, L. (2013). EU Trade Governance and Policy: A Critical Perspective. Journal of

Contemporary , 4, 578-596.

Foster, M., & Norton, A. (2001). The potential of using sustainable livelihoods approaches

in poverty reduction strategy papers. Overseas Development Institute, Centre for Aid and

Public Expenditure, London.

Fosu, A. K. (1990). Export Composition and the Impact of Export on Economic Growth of

Developing Economies. Economic Letters , 34, 67-71.

Frankel, J. A., & Romer, D. (1999). Does Trade Cause Growth? The American Economic

Review , 89 (03), 379-399.

Freres, C., & Mold, A. (2004). European Union Trade Policy and the Poor. Towards

Improving the Poverty Impact of the GSP in Latin America (working paper 02/04). Madrid:

Association for Research and Study of Iberoamerican Issues.

Freund, C., & Bolaky, B. (2008). Trade, regulations, and income. Journal of Development

Economics , 87 (2), 309–321.

Frisch, R. (1959). A Complete Scheme for Computing All Direct and Cross Demand

Elasticities in a Model with Many Sectors. Econometrica , 27 (2), 177-196.

Ghosh, N. (2003). Impact of Trade Liberalization on Returns from Land: A Regional Study of

Indian Agriculture. World Institute for Development Economics Research. Institute of

Economic Growth.

Gilbert, J. (2008). Poverty and income distribution in computable general equilibrium

models: An application to the South Asia Free Trade Agreement. Macao Regional

Knowledge Hub.

Gillespie, R. (2013). The Euro-Mediterranean Partnership: Political and Economic

Perspectives. New York: Frank Cass Publishers.

Page 213: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

194

Ginsburgh, V., & Waelbroeck , J. L. (1981). Activity Analysis and General Equilibrium

Modelling (Contributions to Economic Analysis). Elsevier Science Ltd.

Goulder, L. H., & Borges, M. A. (1984). Decomposing the impact of higher energy prices on

longterm. In H. E. Scarf, & J. B. Shoven, Applied General Equilibrium Analysis. Cambridge

University Press.

Government of Pakistan. (2014-15). Pakistan Economic Survey. Islamabad: Misintry of

Finance.

Government of Pakistan. (Various Issues). Pakistan Economic Survey. Islamabad: Misintry

of Finance.

Government of Pakistan. (2015, 7 10). Statistics. Retrieved from Pakistan Bureau of

Statistics: http://www.pbs.gov.pk/

Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1991). Quality Ladders in the Theory of Growth. The

Review of Economic Studies , 58 (1), 43-61.

Guisinger, S., & Scully, G. (1991). Pakistan. In D. Papageorgiou. In M. Michaely, & A. M.

Choksi, Liberalising Foreign Trade: Lessons of Experience in the Developing World (pp.

197–282). London: Oxford University Press.

Hamori, S., & Razafimahefa, I. F. (2003). Trade and Growth Relationship: Some Evidence

from Comoros, Madagascar, Mauritius and Seychelles. Departmental Bulletin Paper, Kyoto

University.

Hanoch, G. (1975). Production and Demand Models in Direct or Indirect Implicit Additivity.

Econometrica , 43 (3), 395-419.

Hansakul, S. (2013). ASEAN Economic Community (AEC) A potential game changer for

ASEAN countries. Deutsche Bank Research Report.

Harris , R. (1984). Applied General Equilibrium Analysis of Small Open Economies with

Scale Economies and Imperfect Competition. The American Economic Review , 74 (5), 1016-

1032.

Harrison, A. (2007). Globalization and poverty: An introduction. In A. Harrison,

Globalization and poverty. University of Chicago Press.

Harrison, W. G., Humphrey, J. S., & Verschoor, A. (2010). Choice under uncertainty:

evidence from Ethiopia, India and Uganda. The Economic Journal , 80-104.

Harrison, W. J., & Pearson, K. R. (1996). Computing solutions for large general equilibrium

models using GEMPACK. Computational Economics , 9 (2), 83-127.

Hassan, R. M. (1997). Trade liberalization and the environment: The case of agriculture in

South Africa. Agrekon Search , 36 (4), 407-425.

Heckscher, E. (1919). The Effect of Foreign Trade on the Distribution of Income. Reprinted

as Chapter 13 in A.E.A. (1949). Readings in the Theory of International Trade , 272-300

(Philadelphia: Blakist on) with a Translation in H. Flam and M. J. Flanders (Eds.). 1991.

Heckscher-Ohlin Trade Theory , 43-69. Cambridge: MIT Press.

Hertel , T. W., & Reimer, J. J. (2005). Predicting the poverty impacts of trade reform. The

Journal of International Trade & Economic Development , 14 (4), 377-405.

Hertel, T. W. (1998). Global Trade Analysis: Modelling and Applications. Campridge

University Press.

Hertel, T. W., & Tsigas, M. E. (1997). Structure of GTAP. Center for Global Trade Analysis.

Hertel, T. W., & Winters, L. A. (2006). Poverty and the WTO: Impacts of the Doha

Development Agenda. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.

Page 214: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

195

Hertel, T. W., Ivanic, M., Preckel, P., & Cranfield , J. (2004). The Earnings Effects of

Multilateral Trade Liberalization. World Bank Economic Review , 18 (2), 205-236.

Hertel, T. W., Martin, W., & Leiste, A. M. (2010). Potential Implications of a Special

Safeguard Mechanism in the WTO : The Case of Wheat. Policy Research Working Paper

5334, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Hertel, T., & Marinos , T. (2000). Structure of GTAP. Centre for Global Trade Analysis

Project.

Hine, R. C. (1985). The Political Economy of European Trade: An Introduction to the Trade

Policies of the EEC. Harvester-Wheatsheaf.

Hoekman, B., & Djankov, S. (1997). Towards a Free Trade Agreement with the European

Union: Issues and Policy Options for Egypt. Working Paper No. 10, Universtiy of Michigan.

Hogendorn, J. S., & Brown, W. H. (1979). The New International Economics. Addison-

Wesley series in economics.

Hong, W. (1993). Export-Oriented Growth and Equity in Korea. In T. Ito, & A. O. Krueger,

rade and Protectionism (pp. 413 - 436). University of Chicago Press.

Hur, J., & Park, C. (2012). Do Free Trade Agreements Increase Economic Growth of the

Member Countries? World Development , 1283-1284.

Husain, I. (2005). Current issues in Pakistan's economy. State Bank of Pakistan.

Hussain, I. (1999). Pakistan: The Economy of an Elitist State. Karachi, Pakistan: Oxford

University Press.

Hussain, S. (2008). Sources of Real Exchange Rate Misalignment Evidence from Pakistan.

SBP Working Paper Series No. 26, State Bank of Pakistan.

IFPRI. (2007-08). Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for Pakistan. International Food Policy

Research institute. Pakistan Strategy Support Program (PSSP) Project.

Iqbal, M. S. (2008). Impact of Globalization on the Textiles sector of Pakistan. Glasgow:

University of Strathclyde.

Janvry, A., Sadoulet, E., & Fargeix, A. (1991). Politically Feasible and Equitable

Adjustment: Some Alternatives for Ecuador. World Development , 19 (11), 1577-1594.

Javed, A. Y., & Arif, U. (2009). Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending in

Pakistan’s Economy. The Pakistan Development Review , 48 (4), 973–988.

Johansen, L. (1960). A Multi-Sectoral Study of Economic Growth, (2nd enlarged edition

1974. North-Holland Publishing Company.

Jones, R. W. (1971). A Three Factor Model in Theory, Trade, and History. In J. Bhagwati, R.

Jones, R. Mundell, & J. Vanek, Trade, the Balance of payments, and Growth. Amsterdam:

North Holland.

Jones, R. W., & Scheinkman, J. A. (1977). The Relevance of the Two-Sector Production

Model in Trade Theory. Journal of Political Economy , 85 (5), 909-936.

Jorgenson, D. W. (1984). Econometric methods for applied general equilibrium analysis. In

H. E. Scarf, & J. B. Shoven, Applied general equilibrium analysis. Ann Arbor: University of

Michigan.

Jorgenson, D. W., & Fraumeni, B. M. (1981). Relative Prices and Technical Change. In E.

Berndt, & B. Field, Modeling and Measuring Natural Resource Substitution (pp. 17-47).

Cambridge: M.I.T. Press.

Jorgenson, D. W., & Slesnick, D. T. (1985). Efficiency versus equity in economic policy

evaluation. In J. Piggot, & J. Whalley, New Developments in Applied General Equilibrium

Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Page 215: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

196

Jorgenson, Dale, & Hudson, E. A. (1974). U.S. Energy Policy and Economic Growth, 1975-

2000. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science , 5 (2), 461-514.

Jung, W. S., & Marshall, P. J. (1985). Exports, growth and causality in developing countries.

Journal of Development Economics , 18 (1), 1-12.

Kanji, N., & Barrientos, S. (2002). Trade Liberalisation, Poverty and Livelihoods:

Understanding the Linkages. Brighton: Institute of Development Studies.

Karingi, S. N., & Siriwardana, M. (2003). A CGE model analysis of effects of adjustment to

terms of trade shocks on agriculture and income distribution in Kenya. Journal of Developing

Areas , 37 (1), 87-108.

Karingi, S., Lang, R., Oulmane, N., Perez, R., Jallab, M. S., & Hammouda, H. B. (2005).

Economic and Welfare Impacts. African Trade Policy Centre.

Kataria, J. R., & Naveed, A. (2014). Pakistan - China Social and Economic Relations. A

Research Journal of South Asian Studies , 29 (2), 395-410.

Kavoussi, R. M. (1984). Export Expansion and Economic Growth: Further Empirical

Evidence. Journal of Development Economics , 14, 241-250.

Kawai, M., & Wignaraja, G. (2011). Asian FTAs: Trends, prospects and challenges. Journal

of Asian Economics , 22 (1), 1-22.

Kehoe, P. J., & Kehoe, T. J. (1994). A Primer on Static Applied General Equilibrium

Models. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review , 18 (2).

Kemal, A. R., Siddiqui, R., & Siddiqui, R. (2003). An Assessment of the Impact of Trade

Liberalis ation on Welfare in Pakistan: A General Equilibrium Analysis. MIMAP Technical

Paper Series No.16, Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.

Kemal, A. R., Siddiqui, R., & Siddiqui, R. (2001). Tariff Reduction and Income Distribution:

A CGE-Based Anal ysis for Urban and Rural Households in Pakistan. MIMAP Technical

Paper Series N o.11, Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.

Kemal, A. R., Siddiqui, R., & Siddiqui, R. (2001). Tariff Reduction and Income Distribution:

A CGE-based Analysis for Urban and Rural Households in Pakistan. MIMAP Technical

Paper Series No. 11, Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.

Kennedy, K. C. (2011). The Generalized System of Preferences After Four Decades:

Conditionality And The Shrinking Margin of Preference. Michigan State University Journal

of International Law , 19.

Khan, A. H. (1998). The Experience of Trade Liberalization in Pakistan. The Pakistan

Development Review , 37 (4), 661-685.

Khan, J. (2012). The Role of Human Capital Income in Economic Growth of Pakistan (1971-

2008). PhD Thesis, University of Peshawar, Department of Economics.

Khan, M. A. (2015). Impact of Trade Liberalization on Poverty and Income Inequality in

Pakistan. PhD Thesis, PMAS Arid Agriculture University, Rawalpindi, Pakistan.

Khan, M. A., Saboor, A. A., & Mohsin, A. Q. (2015). Impact of agricultural trade

liberalization on Income inequality in Pakistan. Journal of Agricultural Research , 28 (1), 28-

37.

Khondoker, M., & Kalirajan, K. (2012). Determinants of Labor-intensive exports by the

Developing Countries : A Cross Country Analysis. East Asian Bureau of Economic Research.

Khorana, S., Yeung, M. T., Kerr, W. A., & Perdikis, N. (2012). The Battle over the EU’s

Proposed Humanitarian Trade Preferences for Pakistan: A Case Study in Multifaceted

Protectionism. Journal of World Trade , 46 (1), 33–59.

Page 216: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

197

Koenig, P., Mayneris, F., & Poncet, S. (2010). Local export spillovers in France. European

Economic Review , 1-20.

Kraev, E., & Akolgo, B. (2005). Assessing Modelling Approaches to the Distributional

Effects of Macroeconomic Policy. Development Policy Review , 23 (3), 299–312.

Kraybill, D. S. (1993). Computable General Equilibrium Analysis at the Regional Level. In

D. M. Otto, & T. G. Johnson, Microcomputer-based Input-Output Modeling Applications to

Economic Development (pp. 198-215). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

Krueger, A. O. (1998). Why Trade Liberalisation is Good for Growth. The Economic Journal

, 108 (450), 1513–1522.

Kuiper, M., & Shutes, L. (2014). Expanding the household coverage of global simulation

models: an application to Ghana. FOODSECURE for Policies that matter.

Kuznets, S. (1955). Economic Growth and Income Inequality. The American Economic

Review , XLV (1), 1-28.

Kwan, A. C., & Cotsomitis, J. A. (1990). Kawan, A. C. C and J Cotsomitis,

(1990),"Economic growth and the Expanding Export Sector: China 1952-1985. International

Economic Review , 5 (1), 105-117.

Labus, M. (1988). The Pakistan Economy: A CGE Approach to Price Liberalisation Policy

and Public Sector Losses. University of Belgrade.

Leamer, E. E. (1995). The Heckscher-Ohlin Model in Theory and Practice. International

Finance Section, Department of Economics. New Jersey: Princeton University Princeton.

Lee, C. H., & Huang, B.-N. (2002). The Relationship Between Exports and Economic

Growth in East Asian Countries: A Multivariate Threshold Autoregressive Approach.

Journal of Economic Development , 27 (02), 45-68.

Lee, H. H., Lee, H. A., & Liew, V. K.-S. (2007). India-ASEAN-5 Economic Integration:

Impact of Liberalization. The IUP Journal of Applied Economics , 6 (6), 7-20.

Lewis, J. D., Robinson, S., & Thierfelder, K. (2001). Free trade agreements and the SADC

economies. TMD Discussion paper No. 80, The World Bank, The World Bank.

Lewis, S. R. (1969). Economic Policy and Industrial Growth in Pakistan. London: Allen &

Unwin.

Ljungqvist, L., & Sargent, T. J. (2000). Recursive Macroeconomic Theory. Cambridge: MIT

Press.

Lofgren, H., Chulu, O., Sichinga, O., & Simtowe, F. (2001). External Shocks and Domestic

Poverty Alleviation: Simulations with CGE Model of Malawi. International Food Policy

Research Institute (IFPRI).

Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the Mechanics of Economic Development. Journal of Monetary

Economics , 22, 3–42.

Lucas, R. (1976). Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique. In K. Brunner, & A. Meltze,

The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public

Policy. 1. (pp. 19-46). New York: American Elsevier.

Madni, G. R. (2013). Instrumental Effects of Fiscal Policy for Pakistan Economy. The

Romanian Economic Journal , 27-50.

Magee, S. P. (1972). The Welfare Effects of Restrictions on U.S. Trade. Brookings , pp. 645-

707.

Magee, S. P., Deardorff, A. V., & Stern, R. M. (1994). The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem: A

Golden Jubilee. University of Michigan Press.

Mankiw, N. G. (2007). Macroeconomics. New York: Worth Publishers.

Page 217: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

198

Manne, A. S., & Preckel, P. V. (1983). A three-region intertemporal model of energy,

international trade and capital flows. Mathematical Programming Study , 56-74.

Martin, W., Manole, V., & Mensbrugghe, V. M. (2004). Dealing with Diversity: Analyzing

the Consequences of Textile Quota Abolition. 7th Annual Conference on Global Economic

Analysis, Trade, Poverty and Environment. Washington DC.

McCathy, D., & Taylor, L. (1980). Macro Food Policy Planning: A General Equilibrium

Model for Pakistan. The Review of Economics and Statistics , 62 (1), 107-121.

McCulluch, N., & Calandrina, M. (2001). Poverty Dynamics in Rural Sichuan between 1991

and 1995. International Economics Conference. ESRC Development Economics Nottingham

University.

McDougall, R., Elbehri, A., & Truo, T. P. (1998). Global Trade, Assistance, and Protection:

The GTAP 4 Data Base. Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University.

McKibbin, W. J., & Sachs, J. D. (1991). Global Linkages: Macroeconomic Interdependence

and Cooperation in the World Economy. Washington D.C.: The Brookings Institutions.

Metzler, L. A. (1949). Tariffs, International Demand, and Domestic Prices. Journal of

Political Economy , 57 (4), 345-351.

Mevel, S., & Karingi, S. (2012). Deepening Regional Integration in Africa: A Computable

General Equilibrium Assessment of the Establishment of a Continental Free Trade Area foll

owed by a Continental Customs Union. 7 th African Economic Conference. Kigali, Rwanda.

Michaely, M. (1977). Exports and Growth: An Empirical Investig ation. Journal of

Development Economics , 1, 49-53.

Minabe , N. (1974). The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem and the Metzler Paradox. Oxford

Economic Papers New Series , 26 (3), 329-333.

Minor, P., & Mureverwi , B. (2013). A Household Level Analysis of African Trade

Liberalization: The Case of Mozambique, Venerability of Low Income Households. World

Bank, BNPP Program.

Minor, P., & Walmsley, T. (2013). MyGTAP Data Program: A Program for Customizing

and extending the GTAP Database. GTAP Working Paper No. 79, Purdue University,

GTAP.

Minor, P., & Walmsley, T. (2012). MyGTAP Data Program: A Program for Customizing and

Extending the GTAP Database: Multiple Households, Split Factors, Remittances, Foreign

Aid Transfers. 15th Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis . Geneva, Switzerland.

Minot, N., & Goletti, F. (2000). Rice Market Liberalization and Poverty in Viet Nam. IFPRI

Research Report No. 114, International Food Policy Research Institute.

Mishalani, P., Robert, A., Stevens , C., & Weston, A. (1981). The Pyramid of Privilege. In C.

Stevens, EEC and the Third World: A Survey . London: Hodder and Stoughton.

Mishalani, P., Robert, A., Stevens, C., & Weston, A. (1981). The Pyramid of Privilege. In C.

Stevens, EEC and the Third World: A Survey (Vol. 1). London: Hodder and Stoughton.

Mistiaen, J. A., & Ravallion, M. (2003). Survey compliance and the distribution of income,.

Policy Research Working Paper Series 2956, The World Bank.

Mistiaen, J., & Ravallion, M. (2003). Survey Compliance and Distribution of Income. World

Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2956, The World Bank.

Mohammad, S., & Whalley, J. (1984). Rent Seeking in India: Its Costs and Policy

Significance. Kyklos , 37 (3), 387–413.

Page 218: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

199

Mold, A., & Mukwaya, R. (2015). The Effects of the Tripartite Free Trade Area: Towards a

New Economic Geography in Southern, Eastern and Northern Africa? University of

Nottingham, Centre for Research in Economic Development and International Trade.

Molle, W. (2006). The Economics of European Integration: Theory, Practice, Policy. Hants,

England: Ashgate Publishing, Ltd.

Molle, W., & Mourik, A. V. (1988). International Movements of Labour under Conditions of

Economic Integration: The Case of Western Europe. Journal of Common Market Studies , 26

(3), 317–340.

Monteagudo , J., & Watanuki , M. (2003). Regional Trade Agreements for MERCOSUR: A

comparison between The FTAA and FTA with the European Union. Économie internationale

2/2003 (n° 94-95) , 53-76.

MPDR. (2015). Ministry of Planning, Development & Reform. Government of Pakistan.

Mundell, R. A. (1964). Tariff Preferences and the Terms of Trade. The Manchester School ,

32 (1), 1-13.

Mussa , M. (1974). Tariffs and the Distribution of Income: The Importance of Factor

Specificity, Substitutability, and Intensity in the Short and Long Run. Journal of Political

Economy , 82 (6), 1191-1203.

Nabli, M. K. (1997). Trade Liberalisation in the Maghreb Countries in the Context of the

Free Trade Area Agreements with Europe in a comparative perspective. Journal of Economic

Cooperation Among Islamic Countries , 18 (4), 1-22.

Naeem, A. R. (1994). A Study of Pakistan’s Trade and Economic Relations with the

European Community in the Context of EC’s Trade and Development Policies. PhD Thesis,

University of Glasgow, Glasgow.

Naeem, A. R. (2006). Trade Implications for Pakistan in the European Union Market in the

Milieu of EU Enlargement from EU15 to EU25. Glasgow: University of Glasgow, U.K.

Nahar, B., & Siriwardana, M. (2009). Impact of Trade Liberalization on Poverty in

Bangladesh: A Quantitative Assessment. South Asia Economic Journal , 10 (02), 325-369.

Naqvi, F. (1998). A Computable General Equilibrium Model of Energy, Economy and

Equity Interactions in Pakistan. Energy Economics , 347-373.

Naqvi, H. A. (2010). The Potential Impact of Trade Liberalization and Fiscal Strictness on

Households' Welfare and Inequality in Pakistan. PhD Thesis, University of Dundee.

Naqvi, H. A., Hakeem, M. M., & Naeem, A. R. (2011). Impact of Agricultural Income Tax

on Household Welfare and Inequality: Pakistan A Case-in-Point. International Journal of

Business and Social Science , 2 (6), 103 -118.

Nasir, J. (2012). IMF Programs in Pakistan (1988-2008) – An Analysis. Journal for Policy

Formulation on Pivotal Issues , 6 (4).

Neary, J. P. (2004). The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem. Prepared for Encyclopaedia of world

Trade, University College Dublin and CEPR.

Nesbitt, D. M. (1984). The Economic Foundation of Generalized Equilibrium Modeling.

Operations Research , 32 (6), 1240 - 1267.

Norton, A., & Foster, M. (2000). The potential of using sustainable livelihoods approaches

in poverty reduction strategy papers. London: Overseas Development Institute, Centre for

Aid and Public Expenditure.

OH, J.-S., & Kyophilavong, P. (2015). Trade Liberalization and Poverty in Developing

Countries: Literature Survey. International Journal of Economics and Empirical Research , 3

(2), 86-94.

Page 219: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

200

Ohlin, B. (1933). Interregional and International Trade. Cambridge: Harvard University

Press.

Ojeda, R. H., Sherman, R., & Lewis, J. D. (1995). Regional Integration Options for Central

America and the Caribbean after NAFTA. The North American Journal of Economics and

Finance , 6 (2), 121-148.

Okuda, T., & Brohi, K. M. (2001). An Applied General Equilibrium Analysis on Economic

Impacts of Road Transport Network in Pakistan. Journal of the Eastern Asia Society for

Transportation Studies , 4 (6), 17-32.

Onguglo, B. (2010). A More Dynamic & Transformative South-South Trade. International

Trade Forum , 46 (2), 22-24.

Osakwe, E. (2009, May 18). Cotton Fact Sheet Pakistan. Retrieved from International Cotton

Advisory Committee: https://www.icac.org/econ_stats/country_facts/e_pakistan.pdf

Osman, R. M. (2011). The EU Economic Partnership Agreements with Southern Africa

Southern Africa A Computable General Equilibrium Analysis. PhD Thesis, University of

Sussex.

Osman, R. M. (2011). The EU Economic Partnership Agreements with Southern Africa: A

Computable General Equilibrium Analysis. DPhil thesis, University of Sussex .

Panda, M., & Kumar, A. G. (2009). Trade Liberalization, Poverty, and Food Security in

India. IFPRI.

Paudel, R. C., & Perera, N. (2009). F oreign Debt, Trade Openness, Labor Force and

Economic Gr owth: Evidence from Sri Lanka. The ICFAI Journal of Applied Economics , 8

(1), The IC FAI Journal of Applied Economics.

PBC. (2014). A Road Map For Optimizing Pakistan’s GSP Plus Status. Pakistan Business

Council.

PBC. (2015). Pakistan’s EU GSP+ Status: First Year Performance & Future Potential. The

Pakistan Business Council.

Pereira, A. M., & Shoven, J. B. (1988). survey of dynamic computational general equilibrium

models for tax policy evaluation. Journal of Policy Modeling , 401-436.

Pereira, A., & Shoven, J. B. (1988). Survey of dynamic computational general equilibrium

models for tax policy evaluation. Journal of Policy Modeling , 10 (3), 401-436.

Persson, M., & Wilhelmsson , F. (2013). EU Trade Preferences and Export Diversification .

Working Paper 2013:32. Department of Economics, School of Economics and Management,

Lund University.

Persson, M., & Wilhelmsson, F. (2016). EU Trade Preferences and Export Diversification.

The World Economy , 39 (1), 16-53.

Philip, H. (2013). The GTAP Data Base Construction Procedure. GTAP Working Paper No.

76.

Planning Commission of Pakistan. (2015). Pakistan Vision 2025. Islamabad: Ministry of

Planning, Development and Reforms, Goverment of Pakistan.

PLGMEA. (2013). Pakistan Leather Garments Manufacturers & Exporter Association.

Retrieved from http://www.plgmea.pk/

Pohit, S., & Saini, R. (2015). India-Pakistan Trade Liberalization: A CGE Modeling

Approach. In India-Pakistan Trade (pp. 127-146). Springer.

Pomfret, R. T. (1986). The Economics of Regional Trading Arrangements. Oxford University

Press.

Page 220: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

201

Portugal-Perez, A., & Wilson , J. S. (2012). Export Performance and Trade Facilitation

Reform: Hard and Soft Infrastructure. World Development , 40 (7), 1295-1307.

Raana, A. (2008). International Trade Challenges And Opportunities For Pakistan Cotton-

textile And Apparel Sector. PhD Thesis, National University of Modern Languages, Faculty

of Advanced Integrated Studies & Research , Islamabad.

Raihan, S. (2010). Welfare and Poverty Impacts of Trade Liberalization: A Dynamic CGE

Microsimulation Analysis. International Journal of Microsimulation , 3 (1), 123-126.

Raihan, S., & De, P. (2014). India–Pakistan Economic Co-operation: Implications for

Regional Integration in South Asia . Commonwealth Trade Policy Discussion Papers, No.

2014/05, Commonwealth Secretariat, London.

Ram, R. (1985). Exports and Economic Growth: Some Additional Evidence. Ecnomic

Development and Cultural Change , 33, 415-423.

Rashid, S. (2013). Domestic Terms of Trade for Agriculture in Pakistan and Agricultural

Income Tax. IFPRI.

Ratnaike, Y. C. (2012). Is there an empirical link between trade liberalisation and export

performance? Economics Letters 117 (2012) , 375–378.

Redding, S., & Venables, A. J. (2004). Economic geography and international inequality.

Journal of International Economics , 53-82.

Rehman, H. u., Awan, A., & Asghar, N. (2011). The Impact of Exchange Rate, Fiscal Deficit

and Terms of Trade on External Debt of Pakistan: A Cointegration and Causality Analysis.

Australian Journal of Business and Management Research , 1 (3), 10-24.

Reimer, J. J. (2002). Estimating the Poverty Impacts of trade liberalization. Indiana: Centre

for Global Trade analysis, Purdue university.

Reinisch, A. (2013). The Future Shape of EU Investment Agreements. ICSID Review , 28

(1), 179-196.

Robinson, S. (1988). Multisectoral Models. In H. Chenery, & T. N. Srinivasan, Handbook of

Development Economics (pp. 885-947). Elsevier Science Publishers.

Robinson, S., & Arthur Gueneau, A. (2013). CGE-W: an Integrated Modeling Framework

for Analyzing Water-Economy Links Applied to Pakistan. Shangai: GTAP.

Robinson, S., Yunez-Nuade, A., Hinojosa-Ojeda, R., Lewis, J. D., & Shantayanan, D. (1999).

From Stylized to Applied Models: Building Multisector CGE Models for Policy. North

American Journal of Economics and Finance , 5-38.

Rodriguez, F., & Rodrik, D. (2000). Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic's Guide

to the Cross-National Evidence. In B. S. Bernanke, & K. Rogoff, NBER Macroeconomics

Annual (Vol. 15). MIT Press.

Runge, C. F., & Halbach, D. (1990). Export Demand, U.S. Farm Income, and Land Prices:

1949-1985. Land Economics , 66 (2), 150–162.

Sachs, J. D., & Warner, A. M. (1995). The Big Rush, Natural Resource Booms And Growth.

National Bureau of Economic Research.

Saeed, K. A. (2015). The Economy of Pakistan. Oxford University Press.

Salvatore, D., & Hatcher, T. (1991). Salvatore, D., and T. Hatcher, (1991),“Inward Oriented

and Outward Oriented Trade Stratagies. The Journal of Development Studies , 27 (03), 7-25.

Samuelson, P., & Stolper, W. (1941). Protection and Real Wages. Review of Economic

Studies , 91, 58-73.

Sapir, A., & Langhammer, R. (1987). Economic Impact of Generalized Tariff Preferences.

London: Gower Publishing.

Page 221: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

202

Savarad, L. (2003). Poverty and Income Distribution in a CGE-Household Micro-Simulation

Model: Top-Down/Bottom Up Approach. CIRPEE Working Paper No. 03-43, International

Development Research Centre , Dakar.

Scarf , H. (1969). An Example of an Algorithm for Calculating General Equilibrium Prices.

The American Economic Review , 59 (4), 669-677.

Scollay, R., Findlay, C., & Kaufmann, U. (2010). Australia New Zealand Closer Economic

Relations Trade Agreement (ANZCERTA) and Regional Integration. ISEAS Publishers.

Sen, A. K. (1963). Neo-classical and Neo-Keynesian Theories of Distribution. Economic

Record , 39 (85), 54-64.

Senguptaa, J. K., & Espanab, J. R. (1994). Exports and economic growth in Asian NICs: an

econometric analysis for Korea. Applied Economics , 26 (1), 41-51.

Sethi, H. N. (2007). The Environment of Pakistan. Peak Publishing.

Shahbaz, M., Azim, P., & Ahmad, K. (2011). Exports-Led Growth Hypothesis in Pakistan:

Further Evidence. Asian Economic and Financial Review , 1 (3), 182-197.

Shaikh, F. M., & Rahpoto, S. M. (2009). Impact of Trade Liberalization and SAFTA on

Pakistan’s Economy by Using CGE Model. International Journal of Business and

Management , 4 (4), 192-209.

Shaikh, F. M., Syed, A. A., Shah, H., & Shah, A. A. (2012). Observing Impact of SAFTA on

Pakistan’s Economy by Using CGE Model. Pak. J. Commer. Soc. Sci. , 6 (2), 185-209.

Shankland, A. (2000). Analyzing policy for sustainable livelihoods. IDS Research Report 49,

Institute of Development studies, Brighton.

Shlaim, A., & Yannopoulos, G. N. (2008). The EEC and the Mediterranean Countries.

Cambridge University Press.

Shoven, J. B., & Whalley, J. (1972). A general equilibrium calculation of the effects of

differential taxation of income from capital in the US. Journal of public economics , 1 (3),

281-321.

Shoven, J. B., & Whalley, J. (1992). Applying General Equilibrium. Cambridge University

Press.

Siddig, K., Aguiar, A., Grethe, H., Minor, P., & Walmsley, T. (2014). Impacts of removing

fuel import subsidies in Nigeria on poverty. Energy Policy , 69, 165-178.

Siddiqui , R., & Iqbal, Z. (2001). Tariff Reduction and Functional Income Distribution in

Pakistan: A CGE Model. MIMAP Technical Paper Series No. 10 , Pakistan Institute of

Development Economics.

Siddiqui, R. (2007). Dynamic Effects of Agriculture Trade in the Context of Domestic and

Global Liberalisation: A CGE Analysis for Pakistan. PIDE Working Papers no. 38, Pakistan

Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.

Siddiqui, R. (2005). Modelling Gender Dimensions of the Impact of Economic Reforms on

Time Allocation among Market, Household, and Leisure Activities in Pakistan. Pakistan

Development Review , 44 (4), 615-639.

Siddiqui, R., & Iqbal, Z. (1999). Tariff Reduction and Functional Income Distribution in

Pakistan: A CGE Model. Islamabad: PIDE.

Siddiqui, R., & Kemal, A. R. (2002). Poverty Reducing or Poverty Inducing? A CGE Based

Analysis of Foreign Capital Infl ows in Pakistan. Islamabad: PakisInstitute of Development

Economics.

Page 222: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

203

Siddiqui, R., & Kemal, A. R. (2002). Remittances, Trade Liberalisation, and Poverty in

Pakistan: The Role of Exclude d Variables in Poverty Change Analysis. Islamabad: Pakistan

Institute of Development Economics .

Sikdar, C., & Nag, B. (2011). Impact of India-ASEAN Free Trade Agreement : a cross-

country analysis using applied general equilibrium modelling. ARTNeT.

Sincai, I. M. (2014). Gauging The Vertical Specialization In Eu Trade. Global Economic

Observer , 2 (2), 130-139.

Singh, T. (2010). Services sector and economic growth in India. Applied Economics , 42

(30), 3925-3941.

Sonmez, Y., McDonald, S., & Walmsley, T. (2011). Augmenting the GTAP Database: Are

the Data on Intra Institutional Transactions Important? . 14 th Global Economic Analysis

Conference, ‘Governing Global Challenges: Climate Change, Trade, Finance and Deve

lopment. Venice, Italy: Ca' Foscari University of Venice.

Srinivasan, P., Kalaivani, M., & Ibrahim, P. (2011). An empirical investigation of foreign

direct investment and economic growth in SAARC nations. Journal of Asia Business Studies

, 5 (2), 232 - 248.

State Bank of Pakistan. (2006). Implications of Liberalizing Trade and Investment with India.

Karachi: Research and Economic Policy Department.

State Bank of Pakistan. (2015). Statistics and Data Warehouse Department. Government of

Pakistan.

Stevens, C. (1981). EEC and the Third World: a survey 1. Institute of Development Studies,

Overseas Development Inst. London, UK: Hodder and Stoughton.

Stevens, C., & Kennan, J. (2001). The Impact of the EU’s “Everything But Arms” Proposal:

A Report to Oxfam, Final Report. Institute of Development Studies.

Stiglitz, J. E. (1970). Factor price equalization in a dynamic economy. Journal of Political

Economy , 78 (03), 456-488.

Suranovic, S. (2010). A Moderate Compromise: Economic Policy Choice in an Era of

Globalization. Palgrave McMillan.

Suranovic, S. M. (2006). International Trade Theory and Policy. The George Washington

University.

Taniguchi, Y., & Yanovic, A. (2007). The WTO in the Twenty-first Century : Dispute

Settlement, Negotiations, and Regionalism in Asia. Cambridge University Press.

Taylor, L., & Black, S. L. (1974). Practical general equilibrium estimation of resource pulls

under trade liberalization. Journal of International Economics , 4 (1), 37–58.

Taylor, L., & Lysy, F. (1975). Brazilian Income Distribution, 1960-1970: Confronting the

Conflicting Interpretations. The econometric society, Third World Congress. Toronto.

Tekin, R. B. (2012). Economic growth, exports and foreign direct investment in Least

Developed Countries: A panel Granger causality analysis. Economic Modelling , 29 (03),

868–878.

Thompson, H. (2016). Tariffs and Wages in Trade Theory. Review of Development

Economics , 20 (02), 399–405.

Todd, M. J. (1984). Efficient Methods of Computing Economic Equilibria. In H. E. Scarf, &

J. B. Shoven, Applied general equilibrium analysis. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan.

Topalova, P. (2007). Trade Liberalization, Poverty and Inequality: Evidence from Indian

Districts. In A. Harrison, Globalization and Poverty. University of Chicago Press.

Page 223: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

204

Townsend, I. (2008). EU trade preferences for developing countries: the GSP & ‘Everything

But Arms’. Standard Note No. SN/EP/3369, House of Commons Library.

TRTAP. (2013). Enhancing Pakistan’s trading benefits from the proposed EU GSP plus

scheme. Trade Related Technical Assistance Program.

Tyler, W. G. (1981). Growth and Export Expansion in Developing Countries: Some

Empirical Evidence. Journal of Development Economics , 9, 121-130.

Ulasan, B. (2015). Trade openness and economic growth: Panel evidence. Applied

Economics Letters , 22 (2), 163-167.

UNCTAD. (2008). The Least Developed Countries Report 2008, Growth, Poverty and the

Terms of Development Partnership. New York and Geneva.

Vanzetti, D., & Huong, P. L. (2006). Vietnam's Trade Policy Dilemmas. The Ninth Annual

Conference on Global Economic Analysis. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.

Vincent, D. P. (1986). Applied general equilibrium modelling in the Australian Industries

Assistance Commission : perspectives of a policy analyst. Task Force on Applied General

Equilibrium Modelling sponsored by the International Institute of Applied Systems Analysis.

Laxenburg, Austria.

Vohra, R. (2001). Export and economic growth: Further time series evidence from less-

developed countries. International Advances in Economic Research , 07 (03), 345–350.

Vos, R. (1998). Aid Flows and Dutch Disease in a General Equilibrium Framework for

Pakistan. Journal of Policy Modeling , 20 (1), 77-109.

Wacziarg, R., & Welch, K. H. (2003). Trade Liberalization and Growth: New Evidence.

National Bureau of Economic Research.

Waheed, A., & Ezaki, M. (2008). Aggregated and Compact Disaggregated Financial Social

Accounting Matrices for Pakistan. Journal of Economic Cooperation , 29 (4), 17–36.

Waldenberger, F. (2012). The Political Economy of Trade Conflicts: The Management of

Trade Relations in the US-EU-Japan Triad. Springer Science & Business Media.

Walmsley, T., & Minor , P. (2013). MyGTAP Model: A Model for Employing Data from the

MyGTAP Data Application—Multiple Households, Split Factors, Remittances, Foreign Aid

and Transfers. GTAP Working Paper No. 78.

Wang, Y. (2011). International Trade, Industrial Dynamics, and Economic Growth.

Tsinghua-HKU conference on International Trade. Bejing: Tsinghua University.

Warr, P. G., & Azis, M. (1997). Indosam: A alanced and disaggregated, 1993 social

accounting matrix for Indonesia,. Working paper 97.06, ACIAR Indonesia Research Project.

Winters, A. L. (2016). International trade regulation and job creation. IZA World of Labor.

Winters, A. L. (1994). The Liberalization of European Steel Trade. Centre for Economic

Policy Research.

Winters, L. A. (2000). Trade and Poverty: Is there a Connection? Geneva: WTO.

Winters, L. A. (2002). Trade Liberalization and Poverty: What are the Links? The World

Economy , 25 (09), 1339–1367.

Winters, L. A., McCulloch, N., & McKay, A. (2004). Trade liberalization and poverty: the

evidence so far. Journal of Economic Literature , 72-115.

Wobst, P. (2001). Structural Adjustment and Intersectoral Shifts in Tanzania: A Computable

General Equilibrium Analysis. International Food Policy Research Institute.

Wong, M. O. (2008). The Impact of Trade Liberalisation on Growth, Poverty and Income

Distribution: A Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium Analysis with an Application to

Vietnam. University of New South Wales.

Page 224: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC GAINS FROM GSP PLUS ...prr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/8228/1/Shahzad...Muhammad Shahzad Iqbal . Registration No: . 2012-GCUF-09408 . v CERTIFICATE BY SUPERVISORY

205

World Bank. (2003). Sustainable Development in a Dynamic World--Transforming

Institutions, Growth, and Quality of Life. World Bank.

World Bank. (2000). Trade Blocs. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

World Trade Organization. (1995). Regionalism and the World Trading System. Geneva:

World Trade Organization.

WTO. (1998). Agreement Establishing the WTO. Geneva: World Trade Organization.

Yaghmaian, B. (1994). An Empirical Investigation of Exports, Development, and Growth in

Developing Countries: Challenging the Neoclassical Theory of Export- Led Growth. World

Development , 1977-1995.

Yanikkaya, H. (2003). Trade Openness and Economic Growth: A Cross-country Empirical

Investigation. Journal of Development Economics , 57–89.

Yapraklı, S. (2007). The Relationship Between Trade and Financial Openness And Economic

Growth: Evidence of Turkey. İstanbul University Journal of Econometrics and Statistics , 5,

67-89.

Yasin, K., & Ramzan, M. (2013). The Impact of Foreign Direct investment on Pakistan

Economic Growth. Interdisciplinary journal of contemporary research in business , 11, 287-

296.

Yu, Y. (2008). Circumvention and Anti-circumvention Measures: The Impact on Anti-

dumping Practice in International Trade. Kluwer Law International.

Zaidi, S. A. (2015). Issues in Pakistan Economy. Oxford University Press.

Zalai, E. (1982). Computable General Equilibrium Models: An Optimal planning

perspective. Mathematical Modelling , 3 (5), 437-451.