Reader Week 1

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    1/45

    Selections from Aristotle, The Politics (Book 1)

    Part I

    Every state is a community of some kind, and every community is established with a

    view to some good; for mankind always act in order to obtain that which they think good.But, if all communities aim at some good, the state or political community, which is thehighest of all, and which embraces all the rest, aims at good in a greater degree than any

    other, and at the highest good.

    Some people think that the qualifications of a statesman, king, householder, and masterare the same, and that they differ, not in kind, but only in the number of their subjects.

    For example, the ruler over a few is called a master; over more, the manager of ahousehold; over a still larger number, a statesman or king, as if there were no difference

    between a great household and a small state. The distinction which is made between theking and the statesman is as follows: When the government is personal, the ruler is a

    king; when, according to the rules of the political science, the citizens rule and are ruledin turn, then he is called a statesman.

    But all this is a mistake; for governments differ in kind, as will be evident to any one who

    considers the matter according to the method which has hitherto guided us. As in otherdepartments of science, so in politics, the compound should always be resolved into the

    simple elements or least parts of the whole. We must therefore look at the elements ofwhich the state is composed, in order that we may see in what the different kinds of rule

    differ from one another, and whether any scientific result can be attained about each oneof them.

    Part II

    ...The family is the association established by nature for the supply of men's everyday

    wants, and the members of it are called by Charondas 'companions of the cupboard,' andby Epimenides the Cretan, 'companions of the manger.' But when several families are

    united, and the association aims at something more than the supply of daily needs, thefirst society to be formed is the village. And the most natural form of the village appears

    to be that of a colony from the family, composed of the children and grandchildren, whoare said to be suckled 'with the same milk.' And this is the reason why Hellenic states

    were originally governed by kings; because the Hellenes were under royal rule beforethey came together, as the barbarians still are. Every family is ruled by the eldest, and

    therefore in the colonies of the family the kingly form of government prevailed becausethey were of the same blood. As Homer says:

    "Each one gives law to his children and to his wives. "

    For they lived dispersedly, as was the manner in ancient times. Wherefore men say that

    the Gods have a king, because they themselves either are or were in ancient times underthe rule of a king. For they imagine, not only the forms of the Gods, but their ways of life

    to be like their own.

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    2/45

    When several villages are united in a single complete community, large enough to benearly or quite self-sufficing, the state comes into existence, originating in the bare needs

    of life, and continuing in existence for the sake of a good life. And therefore, if the earlierforms of society are natural, so is the state, for it is the end of them, and the nature of a

    thing is its end. For what each thing is when fully developed, we call its nature, whether

    we are speaking of a man, a horse, or a family. Besides, the final cause and end of a thingis the best, and to be self-sufficing is the end and the best.

    Hence it is evident that the state is a creation of nature, and that man is by nature apolitical animal. And he who by nature and not by mere accident is without a state, is

    either a bad man or above humanity; he is like the "Tribeless, lawless, hearthless one, "whom Homer denounces- the natural outcast is forthwith a lover of war; he may be

    compared to an isolated piece in checkers.

    Now, that man is more of a political animal than bees or any other gregarious animals isevident. Nature, as we often say, makes nothing in vain, and man is the only animal

    whom she has endowed with the gift of speech. And whereas mere voice is but anindication of pleasure or pain, and is therefore found in other animals (for their nature

    attains to the perception of pleasure and pain and the intimation of them to one another,and no further), the power of speech is intended to set forth the expedient and

    inexpedient, and therefore likewise the just and the unjust. And it is a characteristic ofman that he alone has any sense of good and evil, of just and unjust, and the like, and the

    association of living beings who have this sense makes a family and a state.

    Further, the state is by nature clearly prior to the family and to the individual, since thewhole is of necessity prior to the part; for example, if the whole body be destroyed, there

    will be no foot or hand, except in an equivocal sense, as we might speak of a stone hand;for when destroyed the hand will be no better than that. But things are defined by their

    working and power; and we ought not to say that they are the same when they no longerhave their proper quality, but only that they have the same name. The proof that the state

    is a creation of nature and prior to the individual is that the individual, when isolated, isnot self-sufficing; and therefore he is like a part in relation to the whole. But he who is

    unable to live in society, or who has no need because he is sufficient for himself, must beeither a beast or a god: he is no part of a state. A social instinct is implanted in all men by

    nature, and yet he who first founded the state was the greatest of benefactors. For man,when perfected, is the best of animals, but, when separated from law and justice, he is the

    worst of all; since armed injustice is the more dangerous, and he is equipped at birth witharms, meant to be used by intelligence and virtue, which he may use for the worst ends.

    Wherefore, if he have not virtue, he is the most unholy and the most savage of animals,and the most full of lust and gluttony. But justice is the bond of men in states, for the

    administration of justice, which is the determination of what is just, is the principle oforder in political society.

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    3/45

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    4/45

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    5/45

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    6/45

    7/8/13 Smaller States Find Outsize Clout Growing in Senate - Interactive - NYTimes.com

    www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#/#smallstate

    Search All NYTimes.com

    POLITICSHOME

    THE CAUCUSFIVETHIRTYEIGHT

    ELECTION2012

    INSIDECONGRESS

    POLLWATCH

    VIDEO

    Advertise o n NYTimes.com

    The disproportionate power enjoyed in the Senate by small states is playing a growing role in the political dynamic on

    issues as varied as gun control, immigration and campaign finance.

    By Adam Liptak

    FACEBOOK TWITTER GOOGLE+ E-MAIL SHAR

    HOME PAGE TODAY'S PAPER VIDEO MOST POPUL AR

    PoliticsWORLD U.S. N.Y. / REGION BUSINESS TECHNOLOGY SCIENCE HEALTH SPORTS OPINION ARTS STYLE TRAVEL JO BS REAL ESTATE AUTO

    Big State, Small State

    RUTLAND, Vt. In the four years after the financial crisis struck, a great

    wave of federal stimulus money washed over Rutland County. It helped

    pay for bridges, roads, preschool programs, a community health center,

    buses and fire trucks, water mains and tanks, even a project to make sure

    fish could still swim down the river while a bridge was being rebuilt.

    Just down Route 4, at the New York border, the landscape abruptly turns

    from spiffy to scruffy. Washington County, N.Y., which is home to about

    60,000 people just as Rutland is saw only a quarter as much money.

    We didnt receive a lot, said PeterAust, the president of the local

    chamber of commerce on the New York side. We never saw any ofthe

    positive impact of the stimulus funds.

    Vermonts 625,000 residents have two United States senators, and so doNew Yorks 19 million. That means that a Vermonter has 30 times the

    voting power in the Senate of a New Yorker just over the state line the

    biggest inequality between two adjacent states. The nations largest gap,

    between Wyoming and California, is more than double that.

    The difference in the fortunes of Rutland and Washington Counties

    reflects the growing disparity in their citizens voting power, and it is not

    an anomaly. The Constitution has always given residents of states with

    small populations a lift, but the size and importance of the gap has grown

    markedly in recent decades, in ways the framers probably never

    anticipated. It affects the political dynamic of issues as varied as gun

    control, immigration and campaign finance.

    In response, lawmakers, lawyers and watchdog groups have begun pushing

    for change. A lawsuit to curb the small-state advantage in the Senates

    rules is moving through the courts. The Senate has already made modest

    changes to rules concerning the filibuster, which has particularly benefited

    senators from small states. And eight states and the District of Columbia

    have endorsed a proposal to reduce the chances that the small-state

    advantage in the Electoral College will allow a loser of the popular vote to

    win the presidency.

    To be sure, some scholars and members of Congress view the small-state

    advantage as a vital part of the constitutional structure and say the growth

    of that advantage is no cause for worry. Others say it is an authentic but

    insoluble problem.

    Articles in this series are examining challenges to the

    American promise that all citizens have an equal voice

    in how they are governed.

    Previous Articles:

    How Maps Helped House Republicans

    The Vanishing Battleground

    Error and Fraud as Absentee Voting Rises

    TimesCast: The Times's Adam Liptak on the growing

    advantage less populated states enjoy in the Senate.

    Biggest Gap of All

    A Compromise

    Barrier to Change

    Small States Win

    Subscribe to Home Delivery Hejohn.hanley...U.S. Edition

    http://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/small-state-advantage.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/small-state-advantage.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/small-state-advantage.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/small-state-advantage.htmlhttp://thecaucus.blogs.nytimes.com/http://fivethirtyeight.blogs.nytimes.com/http://elections.nytimes.com/2012/results/presidenthttp://politics.nytimes.com/congress/http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/subjects/n/newyorktimes-poll-watch/index.htmlhttp://video.nytimes.com/video/playlist/politics/1194811622221/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/business/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/technology/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/science/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/health/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/sports/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/opinion/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/arts/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/style/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/travel/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/jobs/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/realestate/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/automobiles/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/politics/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#compromisehttp://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#smallstatehttp://www.nytimes.com/membercenter/sitehelp.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/adx/bin/adx_click.html?type=goto&opzn&page=www.nytimes.com/interactive/yr/mo/day/us/politics&pos=Bar1&sn2=c06650d3/a7b87cdd&sn1=bded043/be52c8d1&camp=nyt2013_hol_july4_hd_bar1_hp_ros_3K88R&ad=hol_july4_reg_bar1_hp_3K88R&goto=https%3A%2F%2Fnytimesathome%2Ecom%2Fhd%2F210%3FMediaCode%3DW22EJ%26CMP%3D3K88R%26adxc%3D219235%26adxa%3D341838%26page%3Dwww.nytimes.com/interactive/yr/mo/day/us/politics/democracy-tested.html%26pos%3DBar1%26campaignId%3D3K88Rhttp://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#smallstatehttp://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#changehttp://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#compromisehttp://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#biggestgaphttp://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/small-state-advantage.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/2012/10/07/us/politics/as-more-vote-by-mail-faulty-ballots-could-impact-elections.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/2012/11/04/sunday-review/the-vanishing-electoral-battleground.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/2012/12/15/us/politics/redistricting-helped-republicans-hold-onto-congress.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/automobiles/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/realestate/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/jobs/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/travel/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/style/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/arts/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/opinion/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/sports/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/health/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/science/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/technology/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/business/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/nyregion/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/national/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/world/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/politics/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/mostpopularhttp://www.nytimes.com/videohttp://www.nytimes.com/pages/todayspaper/index.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/http://www.nytimes.whsites.net/mediakit/http://video.nytimes.com/video/playlist/politics/1194811622221/index.htmlhttp://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/subjects/n/newyorktimes-poll-watch/index.htmlhttp://politics.nytimes.com/congress/http://elections.nytimes.com/2012/results/presidenthttp://fivethirtyeight.blogs.nytimes.com/http://thecaucus.blogs.nytimes.com/http://www.nytimes.com/politics/http://www.nytimes.com/
  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    7/45

    7/8/13 Smaller States Find Outsize Clout Growing in Senate - Interactive - NYTimes.com

    www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#/#smallstate

    What is certain is that the power of the smaller states is large and growing.

    Political scientists call it a striking exception to the democratic principle of

    one person, one vote. Indeed, they say, the Senate may be the least

    democratic legislative chamber in any developed nation.

    Nathaniel Brooks for The New York T imes

    At left, the view toward Vermont from Washington County, N.Y., left. Vermont got much more

    federal stimulus money than larger s tates. We never s aw any of the positive impact of the

    stimulus funds, said Peter Aust, top right, a chamber of commerce president for Washington

    County, N.Y. Bottom right, Rutland. Vt., has been a big recipient of federal aid, including for

    buses.

    Behind the growth of the advantage is an increase in population gap

    between large and small states, with large states adding many more people

    than small ones in the last half-century. There is a widening demographic

    split, too, with the larger states becoming more urban and liberal, and the

    smaller ones remaining rural and conservative, which lends a new

    significance to the disparity in their political power.

    The threat of the filibuster in the Senate, which has become far more

    common than in past decades, plays a role, too. Research by two political

    scientists, Lauren C. Bell and L. Marvin Overby, has found that small-state

    senators, often in leadership positions, have amplified their power by

    using the filibuster more often than their large-state counterparts.

    Beyond influencing government spending, these shifts generally benefit

    conservative causes and hurt liberal ones. When small states block or

    shape legislation backed by senators representing a majority of Americans,

    most of the senators on the winning side tend to be Republicans, because

    Republicans disproportionately live in small states and Democrats,

    especially African-Americans and Latinos, are more likely to live in large

    states like California, New York, Florida and Illinois. Among the nations

    five smallest states, only Vermont tilts liberal, while Alaska, Wyoming and

    the Dakotas have each voted Republican in every presidential election

    since 1968.

    Recent bills to overhaul the immigration system and increase disclosure of

    campaign spending have won the support of senators representing a

    majority of the population but have not yet passed. A sweeping climate

    bill, meant to raise the cost of carbon emissions, passed the House, where

    seats are allocated by population, but not the Senate.

    Each of those bills is a major Democratic Party priority. Throughout his

    second term, President Obama is likely to be lining up with a majority of

    large-state Congress members on his biggest goals and against a majority

    of small-state lawmakers.

    It is easiest to measure the small-state advantage in dollars. Over the past

    few years, as the federal government has spent hundreds of billions to

    respond to the financial crisis, it has done much more to assist the

    residents of small states than large ones. The top five per capita recipients

    of federal stimulus grants were states so small that they have only a single

    House member.

    From highway bills to homeland security, said Sarah A. Binder, a

    http://home.gwu.edu/~binder/http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/showelection.php?year=1968http://web.missouri.edu/~overbyl/http://faculty.rmc.edu/lbell/public_html/
  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    8/45

    7/8/13 Smaller States Find Outsize Clout Growing in Senate - Interactive - NYTimes.com

    www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#/#smallstate

    political scientist at George Washington University, small states make out

    like bandits.

    Here in Rutland, the federal government has spent $2,500 per person

    since early 2009, compared with $600 per person across the state border

    in Washington County.

    As the money started arriving, Senator Bernard Sanders, the Vermont

    independent, took credit for having delivered a hefty share of the national

    funding. Senator Kirsten Gillibrand, a New York Democrat,vowed to

    fight for her states fair share.

    As a matter of constitutional design, small states have punched above their

    weight politically for as long as the United States has existed. The founding

    of the country depended in part on the Great Compromise, which created a

    legislative chamber the Senate in which every state had the same

    political voice, regardless of population. The advantage small states enjoy

    in the Senate is echoed in the Electoral College, where each state is

    allocated votes not only for its House members (ref lecting the states

    population) but also for its senators (a two-vote bonus).

    No one expects the small-state advantage to disappear, given its

    constitutional roots. But its growing importance has caused some large-

    state policy makers and advocates for giving all citizens an equal voice in

    democracy to begin exploring ways to counteract it. Those pushing for

    change tend to be Democrats.

    One plan, enacted into law by eight states and the District of Columbia,

    would effectively cancel the small states Electoral College edge. The nine

    jurisdictions have pledged to allocate their 132 electoral votes to the

    winner of the national popular vote if they can persuade states with 138

    more votes to make the same commitment. (That would represent the bare

    majority of the 538 electoral votes needed for a presidential candidate to

    prevail.)

    The states that have agreed to the arrangement range in size from

    Vermont to California, and they are dominated by Democrats. But support

    for changing the Electoral College cuts across party lines. In a recent

    Gallup Poll, 61 percent of Republicans, 63 percent of independents and 66

    percent of Democrats said they favored abolishing the system andawarding the presidency to the winner of the popular vote.

    In 2000, had electoral votes been allocated by population, without the

    two-vote bonuses, Al Gore would have prevailed over George W. Bush.

    Alexander Keyssar, a historian of democracy at Harvard, said he would not

    be surprised if another Republican candidate won the presidency while

    losing the popular vote in coming decades, given the structure of the

    Electoral College.

    Critics of the outsize power of small states have also turned to the courts.

    In December, four House members and the advocacy group Common

    Cause filed an appeal in a lawsuit challenging the Senates filibuster rule on

    the ground that it upsets the balance in the Great Compromise that

    created the Senate.

    The filibuster has significantly increased the underrepresentation of

    people living in the most populous states, the suit said. But for the rule, it

    said, the Dream Act, which would have given some immigrants who arrived

    illegally as children a path to legalization, and the Disclose Act, requiring

    greater reporting of political spending, would be law.

    A federal judge in Washington dismissed the suit, saying he was powerless

    to address what he acknowledged was an important and controversial

    issue. The judge instead sided with lawyers for the Senate, who said that

    the challengers lacked standing to sue and that the courts lacked power to

    rule on the internal workings of another branch of the government.

    http://sblog.s3.amazonaws.com/wp-content/uploads/2012/12/Sullivan-filibuster-ruling-12-21-12.pdfhttp://www.hks.harvard.edu/about/faculty-staff-directory/alex-keyssarhttp://www.gallup.com/poll/159881/americans-call-term-limits-end-electoral-college.aspxhttp://www.nationalpopularvote.com/http://www.gillibrand.senate.gov/newsroom/press/release/senator-gillibrand-announces-more-than-194-million-for-community-health-centers-in-new-yorkhttp://www.sanders.senate.gov/newsroom/news/?id=3a5fc21e-8cd4-4df8-aebd-46e269e189c3
  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    9/45

    7/8/13 Smaller States Find Outsize Clout Growing in Senate - Interactive - NYTimes.com

    www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#/#smallstate

    However these individual efforts fare, the basic disparity between large

    and small states is wired into the constitutional framework. Some scholars

    say that this is as it should be and that the advantages enjoyed by small

    states are necessary to prevent them from becoming a voiceless minority.

    Without it, wealth and power would tend to flow to the prosperous coasts

    and cities and away from less-populated rural areas, said Stephen

    Macedo, a political scientist at Princeton.

    Gary L. Gregg II, a political scientist who holds the Mitch McConnell Chair

    in Leadership at the University of Louisville, similarly argued that urban

    areas already have enough power, as the home of most major governmentagencies, news media organizations, companies and universities. A

    simple, direct democracy will centralize all power, he wrote recently, in

    urban areas to the detriment of the rest of the nation.

    Others say the country needs to make changes to preserve its democratic

    vitality. They have called for an overhaul of the Constitution, as far-

    fetched an idea as that may be.

    The Senate constitutes a threat to the vitality o f the American political

    system in the 21st century, said Sanford Levinson, a law professor at the

    University of Texas, and it warrants a constitutional convention to rectify

    it.

    Frances E. Lee, a political scientist at the University of Maryland, said theproblem was as real as the solution elusive, adding that she and other

    scholars have tried without success to find a contemporary reason to

    exempt the Senate from the usual rules o f granting citizens an equal voice

    in their government. I cant think of any way to justify it based on

    democratic principles, Professor Lee said.

    The Biggest Gap of All

    Max Whittaker for The New York Times

    HOMELESS IN FRESNO The city of half a million suffers from an array of social problems.

    Fresno, Calif., is a city of a half-million people with a long list of problems,

    including 14 percent unemployment, the aftermath of a foreclosure crisis,

    homeless encampments that dot the sun-blasted landscape and worries

    about the safety o f the surrounding countys drinking water.

    A thousand miles away, a roughly comparable number of people inhabit

    the entire state of Wyoming. Like Fresno and its environs, Wyoming is

    rural, with an economy largely based on agriculture. It is also in much

    better shape than Fresno, with an unemployment rate around 5 percent.

    https://www.bsos.umd.edu/gvpt/lee/http://www.utexas.edu/law/faculty/svl55/http://www.politico.com/story/2012/12/keep-electoral-college-for-fair-presidential-votes-84651.htmlhttp://louisville.edu/mcconnellcenter/about/staff/gregghttp://www.princeton.edu/~macedo/
  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    10/45

    7/8/13 Smaller States Find Outsize Clout Growing in Senate - Interactive - NYTimes.com

    www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#/#smallstate

    Even so, Wyoming receives far more assistance from the federal

    government than Fresno does. The half-million residents of Wyoming also

    have much more sway over federal policy than the half-million residents of

    Fresno. The vote people in Fresno remember best was taken in 2007,

    when an immigration overhaul bill that included a guest worker program

    failed in the Senate. Both agricultural businesses and leaders of Fresnos

    large Hispanic population supported the bill, much as polls suggested a

    majority of Americans did.

    But the immigration bill died in the Senate after a 53-46 vote rejecting a

    bid to move the bill forward to final passage. Wyomings two senators

    were in the majority and Californias two senators on the losing side.

    Had the votes been allocated by population, the result would have been

    lopsided in the other direction, with 57 votes in favor and 43 against.

    Even 57 votes would not have been enough to overcome a f ilibuster, which

    requires 60. In the last few years, 41 senators representing as little as a

    third of the nations population have frequently blocked legislation, as the

    filibuster (or the threat of it) has become a routine part of Senate business.

    Beyond the filibuster, senators from Wyoming and other small states

    regularly oppose and often thwart programs popular in states with vastly

    bigger populations. The 38 million people who live in the nations 22

    smallest states, including Wyoming, are represented by 44 senators. The

    38 million residents of California are represented by two senators.

    In one of every 10 especially consequential votes in the Senate over the

    two decades ending in 2010, as chosen by Congressional Quarterly, the

    winning side would have lost had voting been allocated by population. And

    in 24 of the 27 such votes, the majority of the senators on the winning side

    were Republicans.

    David Mayhew, a political scientist at Yale, cautioned that the political

    benefit to Republicans is quite small as well as quite stable, adding that it

    is important not to lose sight of small blue states like Delaware, Hawaii,

    Rhode Island and Vermont. But he acknowledged that small states of both

    political stripes receive disproportionate federal benefits. Professor Lee,

    an author of Sizing Up the Senate: The Unequal Consequences of Equal

    Representation, argues that the partisan impact of the small-stateadvantage is larger. There is a Republican tilt in the Senate, she said.

    The way Republicans are distributed across the nation is more ef ficient,

    she added, referring to the more even allocation of Republican voters,

    allowing them to form majorities in small-population states. Democrats

    are more tightly clustered, especially in large metropolitan areas.

    Born of a Compromise

    http://press.uchicago.edu/ucp/books/book/chicago/S/bo3636044.htmlhttp://politicalscience.yale.edu/people/david-mayhewhttp://www.nytimes.com/2007/06/28/washington/28cnd-immig.html?_r=0http://www.nytimes.com/2007/05/25/us/25poll.html?pagewanted=all
  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    11/45

    7/8/13 Smaller States Find Outsize Clout Growing in Senate - Interactive - NYTimes.com

    www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#/#smallstate

    Jim Wilson/The New York Times

    OUTSIZE CLOUT Cody, Wyo., a state that enjoys disproportionate power in the Senate.

    Equal representation of the states in the Senate is a consequence of the

    Great Compromise, the 1787 deal that resolved a seemingly intractable

    dispute between the smaller states and a handful of large ones like

    Massachusetts, Pennsylvania and Virginia. But the country was very

    different then. The population was about four million, and the maximum

    disparity in voting power between states was perhaps 11 to 1. It is now six

    times greater than that. Even scholars who criticize how voting power is

    allocated in the Senate agree that parts of its design play an important role

    in the constitutional structure. With its longer terms and fewer members,

    the Senate can, in theory, be more collegial, take the long view and be

    insulated from passing passions.

    But those qualities do not depend on unequal representation among

    people who live in different states. The current allocation of power in the

    Senate, many legal scholars and political scientists say, does not protect

    minorities with distinctive characteristics, much less disadvantaged ones.

    To the contrary, the disproportionate voting power of small states is a sort

    of happenstance that has on occasion left a stain on the nations history.

    Robert A. Dahl, the Yale political scientist, who is 97 and has been studying

    American government for more than 70 years, has argued that slavery

    survived thanks to the disproportionate influence of small-populationSouthern states. The House passed eight antislavery measures between

    1800 and 1860; all died in the Senate. The civil rights movement of the

    mid-20th century, he added, was slowed by senators representing small-

    population states.

    As the population of the United States has grown a hundredfold since the

    founding, to more than 310 million, the Supreme Court has swept away

    most instances of unequal representation beyond the Senate. In a series of

    seminal cases in the 1960s, the court forbade states to give small-

    population counties or districts a larger voice than ones with more people,

    in both state legislatures and the House.

    The conception of political equality from the Declaration of

    Independence, to Lincolns Gettysburg Address, to the Fifteenth,Seventeenth, and Nineteenth Amendments can mean only one thing one

    person, one vote, Justice William O. Douglaswrote for the court in 1963,

    referr ing to the amendments that extended the franchise to blacks and

    women and required the popular election of the Senate.

    The rulings revolutionized American politics everywhere but in the

    Senate, which the Constitution protected from change and where the

    disparities in voting power have instead become more extreme.

    A Barrier to Change

    In his memoirs, Chief Justice Earl Warren described the cases from the

    1960s establishing the equality of each citizens vote as the most important

    achievement of the court he led for 16 years. That made them more

    important in his view than Brown v. Board of Education, which ordered

    the desegregation of public schools, and Gideon v. Wainwright, which

    guaranteed lawyers for poor people accused of serious crimes.

    Legislators represent people, not trees or acres, Chief Justice Warren

    wrote for the court in 1964, rejecting the argument that state senators, like

    federal ones, could represent geographic areas with varying populations.

    Legislators are elected by voters, not farms or cities or economic

    interests.

    http://www.law.cornell.edu/supct/html/historics/USSC_CR_0377_0533_ZS.htmlhttp://www.law.cornell.edu/supct/html/historics/USSC_CR_0372_0335_ZS.htmlhttp://www.law.cornell.edu/supct/html/historics/USSC_CR_0347_0483_ZS.htmlhttp://caselaw.lp.findlaw.com/scripts/getcase.pl?court=us&vol=372&invol=368http://politicalscience.yale.edu/people/robert-dahl
  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    12/45

    7/8/13 Smaller States Find Outsize Clout Growing in Senate - Interactive - NYTimes.com

    www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/03/11/us/politics/democracy-tested.html#/#smallstate

    AMANDA COX and DEREK WILLIS contributed reporting; Produced By NICKI JHABVALA

    2013 The New York T imes Company Site Map Pr ivacy Your Ad Choices Adver tise Terms of Sale Terms of Service Work With Us RSS Help Contact Us

    Site Feedback

    Applying that principle to the Senate would be very hard. Even an ordinary

    constitutional amendment would not do the trick, as the framers of the

    Constitution went out of their way to require states to agree before their

    power is diminished.Article V of the Constitution sets out the procedure

    for amendments and requires a two-thirds vote of both houses of

    Congress or action by two-thirds of state legislatures to get things started.

    But the article makes an exception for the Senate. No state, without its

    consent, shall be deprived of its equal suffrage in the Senate, the article

    concludes.

    The United States Senate is hardly the only legislature that does not stick

    strictly to the principle of equal representation. Political scientists use the

    term malapportioned to describe the phenomenon, and it is common

    around the world.

    But the Senate is in contention for the least democratic legislative

    chamber. In some other countries with federal systems, in which states or

    provinces have independent political power, a malapportioned upper

    house may have only a weak or advisory role. In the United States, the

    Senate is at least equal in power to the House, and it possesses some

    distinctive responsibilities, like treaty ratification and the approval of

    presidential appointments. A recent appeals court decision severely

    limiting the presidents power to make recess appointments, if it stands,

    will further increase the Senates power.

    Professor Dahl has calculated the difference between the local government

    unit with the most voting power and that with the least. The smallest ratio,

    1.5, was in Austria, while in Belgium, Spain, India, Germany, Australia and

    Canada the ratio was never higher than 21 to 1.

    In this country, the ratio between Wyomings representation and

    Californias is 66 to 1. By that measure, Professor Dahl found, only Brazil,

    Argentina and Russia had less democratic chambers. A separate analysis,

    byDavid Samuels and Richard Snyder, similarly found that geographically

    large countries with federal systems tend to overrepresent sparsely

    populated areas.

    This pattern has policy consequences, notably ones concerning the

    environment. Nations with malapportioned political systems have lower

    gasoline taxes (and lower pump prices) than nations with more equitable

    representation of urban constituencies, two political scientists, J.

    Lawrence Broz and Daniel Maliniak, wrote in a recent study. Such

    countries also took longer to ratify the Kyoto Protocol on climate change,

    if they ratified it at all. These differences were, they wrote, a consequence

    of the fact that rural voters in industrialized countries rely more heavily

    on fossil fuels than urban voters.

    In 2009, the House of Representatives narrowly approved a bill to address

    climate change, but only after months of horse-trading that granted

    concessions and money to rural states. That was an example, Mr. Broz and

    Mr. Maliniak said, of compensating rural residents for the burdens of

    reducing greenhouse-gas emissions.

    But it was not enough. The bill died in the Senate.

    http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1642499http://www.wm.edu/offices/itpir/trip/meet_the_team/maliniak_d.phphttp://polisci.ucsd.edu/faculty/broz.htmlhttp://brown.edu/Departments/Political_Science/people/snyder/http://www.polisci.umn.edu/people/profile.php?UID=dsamuelshttp://www.cadc.uscourts.gov/internet/opinions.nsf/D13E4C2A7B33B57A85257AFE00556B29/$file/12-1115-1417096.pdfhttp://www.law.cornell.edu/constitution/articlevhttps://myaccount.nytimes.com/membercenter/feedback.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/ref/membercenter/help/infoservdirectory.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/membercenter/sitehelp.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/rsshttp://www.nytco.com/careershttp://www.nytimes.com/ref/membercenter/help/agree.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/content/help/rights/sale/terms-of-sale.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.whsites.net/mediakit/http://www.nytimes.com/ref/membercenter/help/privacy.html#pphttp://www.nytimes.com/privacyhttp://spiderbites.nytimes.com/http://www.nytco.com/
  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    13/45

    Wickard v. Filburn

    317 U.S. 111 (1942)

    [editors note: It is quite common for advocates before the court to state a number of reasons why a

    given law is or isnt constitutional. Filburn has proposed three arguments. He says that the local

    decision to accept the quota is invalid because the Secretary of Agriculture provided farmers with

    incomplete informationthe Court could agree with Filburn without throwing out the law. But even

    if the Secretarys speech was okay, the Agricultural Adjustment Act might be unconstitutionalbecause the national government doesnt have the power to regulate what Filburn grows. And even

    if it can regulate what Filburn grows, it might not be able to do it in ways that violate Filburns due

    process rights.]

    Justice JACKSON delivered the opinion of the

    Court.

    1. The appellee filed his complaint against theSecretary of Agriculture of the UnitedStates, three members of the County

    Agricultural Conservation Committee forMontgomery County, Ohio, and a memberof the State Agricultural Conservation

    Committee for Ohio. He sought to enjoin

    enforcement against himself of themarketing penalty imposed by theamendment of May 26, 1941, to the

    Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938, upon

    that part of his 1941 wheat crop which wasavailable for marketing in excess of the

    marketing quota established for his farm.He also sought a declaratory judgment that

    the wheat marketing quota provisions of theAct as amended and applicable to him were

    unconstitutional because not sustainable

    under the Commerce Clause or consistentwith the Due Process Clause of the FifthAmendment.

    2. The Secretary moved to dismiss the actionagainst him for improper venue but laterwaived his objection and filed an answer.The other appellants moved to dismiss on

    the ground that they had no power or

    authority to enforce the wheat marketing

    quota provisions of the Act, and after theirmotion was denied they answered,reserving exceptions to the ruling on theirmotion to dismiss. The case was submitted

    for decision on the pleadings and upon a

    stipulation of facts.

    3. The appellee for many years past hasowned and operated a small farm inMontgomery County, Ohio, maintaining a

    herd of dairy cattle, selling milk, raising

    poultry, and selling poultry and eggs. It has

    been his practice to raise a small acreage ofwinter wheat, sown in the Fall andharvested in the following July; to sell a

    portion of the crop; to feed part to poultry

    and livestock on the farm, some of which issold; to use some in making flour for home

    consumption; and to keep the rest for thefollowing seeding. The intended dispositionof the crop here involved has not been

    expressly stated.

    4. In July of 1940, pursuant to the AgriculturalAdjustment Act of 1938, as then amended,there were established for the appellee's1941 crop a wheat acreage allotment of

    11.1 acres and a normal yield of 20.1

    bushels of wheat an acre. He was given

    notice of such allotment in July of 1940before the Fall planting of his 1941 crop ofwheat, and again in July of 1941, before it

    was harvested. He sowed, however, 23acres, and harvested from his 11.9 acres of

    excess acreage 239 bushels, which under

    the terms of the Act as amended on May26, 1941, constituted farm marketingexcess, subject to a penalty of 49 cents a

    bushel, or $117.11 in all. The appellee has

    not paid the penalty and he has notpostponed or avoided it by storing the

    excess under regulations of the Secretary ofAgriculture, or by delivering it up to theSecretary. The Committee, therefore,

    refused him a marketing card, which was,

    under the terms of Regulations promulgated

    by the Secretary, necessary to protect abuyer from liability to the penalty and uponits protecting lien.

    1

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    14/45

    5. The general scheme of the AgriculturalAdjustment Act of 1938 as related to wheat

    is to control the volume moving in

    interstate and foreign commerce in order to

    avoid surpluses and shortages and the

    consequent abnormally low or high wheat

    prices and obstructions to commerce.

    Within prescribed limits and by prescribed

    standards the Secretary of Agriculture isdirected to ascertain and proclaim each year

    a national acreage allotment for the next

    crop of wheat, which is then apportioned to

    the states and their counties, and is

    eventually broken up into allotments for

    individual farms. Loans and payments to

    wheat farmers are authorized in stated

    circumstances.

    6. The Act provides further that whenever itappears that the total supply of wheat as of

    the beginning of any marketing year,

    beginning July 1, will exceed a normalyear's domestic consumption and export by

    more than 35 per cent, the Secretary shall

    so proclaim not later than May 15 prior to

    the beginning of such marketing year; and

    that during the marketing year a

    compulsory national marketing quota shall

    be in effect with respect to the marketing of

    wheat. Between the issuance of the

    proclamation and June 10, the Secretary

    must, however, conduct a referendum of

    farmers who will be subject to the quota to

    determine whether they favor or oppose it;and if more than one-third of the farmers

    voting in the referendum do oppose, the

    Secretary must prior to the effective date of

    the quota by proclamation suspend its

    operation.

    7. On May 19, 1941 the Secretary ofAgriculture made a radio address to the

    wheat farmers of the United States in which

    he advocated approval of the quotas and

    called attention to the pendency of the

    amendment of May 26, 1941, which had at

    the time been sent by Congress to the WhiteHouse, and pointed out its provision for an

    increase in the loans on wheat to 85 per

    cent of parity. He made no mention of the

    fact that it also increased the penalty from

    15 cents a bushel to one-half of the parity

    loan rate of about 98 cents, but stated that

    'Because of the uncertain world situation,

    we deliberately planted several million

    extra acres of wheat. . . . Farmers should

    not be penalized because they have

    provided insurance against shortages of

    food.' [In other words, Filburn is arguing

    that the farmers vote is invalid because

    the Secretary omitted key information in

    his radio addressed.]

    8. Pursuant to the Act, the referendum ofwheat growers was held on May 31, 1941.

    According to the required publishedstatement of the Secretary of Agriculture,

    81 per cent of those voting favored the

    marketing quota, with 19 per cent opposed.

    9. The court below held, with one judgedissenting, that the speech of the Secretary

    invalidated the referendum; and that the

    amendment of May 26, 1941, 'in so far as it

    increased the penalty for the farm

    marketing excess over the fifteen cents per

    bushel prevailing at the time of planting

    and subjected the entire crop to a lien for

    the payment thereof,' should not be appliedto the appellee because as so applied it was

    retroactive and in violation of the Fifth

    Amendment; and, alternatively, because the

    equities of the case so required. Filburn v.

    Helke , D.C., 43 F.Supp. 1017. Its judgment

    permanently enjoined appellants from

    collecting a marketing penalty of more than

    15 cents a bushel on the farm marketing

    excess of appellee's 1941 wheat crop, from

    subjecting appellee's entire 1941 crop to a

    lien for the payment of the penalty, and

    from collecting a 15-cent penalty except inaccordance with the provisions of 339 of

    the Act as that section stood prior to the

    amendment of May 26, 1941. The Secretary

    and his co-defendants have appealed.

    I.

    10.[Part I dismisses the argument that thewhat the Secretary said in the radio

    program matters hereed.]

    II.

    11.It is urged that under the Commerce Clauseof the Constitution, Article I, 8, clause 3,Congress does not possess the power it has

    in this instance sought to exercise. The

    question would merit little consideration

    since our decision in United States v. Darby ,

    312 U.S. 100, 61 S.Ct. 451, 132 A.L.R.

    1430, sustaining the federal power to

    regulate production of goods for commerce

    except for the fact that this Act extends

    federal regulation to production not

    2

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    15/45

    intended in any part for commerce but

    wholly for consumption on the farm. The

    Act includes a definition of 'market' and its

    derivatives so that as related to wheat in

    addition to its conventional meaning it also

    means to dispose of 'by feeding (in any

    form) to poultry or livestock which, or the

    products of which, are sold, bartered, or

    exchanged, or to be so disposed of.' Hence,marketing quotas not only embrace all that

    may be sold without penalty but also what

    may be consumed on the premises. Wheat

    produced on excess acreage is designated as

    'available for marketing' as so defined and

    the penalty is imposed thereon. Penalties do

    not depend upon whether any part of the

    wheat either within or without the quota is

    sold or intended to be sold. The sum of this

    is that the Federal Government fixes a

    quota including all that the farmer may

    harvest for sale or for his own farm needs,and declares that wheat produced on excess

    acreage may neither be disposed of nor

    used except upon payment of the penalty or

    except it is stored as required by the Act or

    delivered to the Secretary of Agriculture.

    12.Appellee says that this is a regulation ofproduction and consumption of wheat. Such

    activities are, he urges, beyond the reach of

    Congressional power under the Commerce

    Clause, since they are local in character,

    and their effects upon interstate commerce

    are at most 'indirect.' In answer theGovernment argues that

    the statute regulates

    neither production nor

    consumption, but only

    marketing; and, in the

    alternative, that if the

    Act does go beyond the

    regulation of marketing

    it is sustainable as a

    'necessary and proper'

    implementation of the

    power of Congress overinterstate commerce.

    13.The Government'sconcern lest the Act be

    held to be a regulation of

    production or consumption rather than of

    marketing is attributable to a few dicta and

    decisions of this Court which might be

    understood to lay it down that activities

    such as 'production,' 'manufacturing,' and

    'mining' are strictly 'local' and, except in

    special circumstances which are not present

    here, cannot be regulated under the

    commerce power because their effects upon

    interstate commerce are, as matter of law,

    only 'indirect.' Even today, when this power

    has been held to have great latitude, there is

    no decision of this Court that such activities

    may be regulated where no part of theproduct is intended for interstate commerce

    or intermingled with the subjects thereof.

    We believe that a review of the course of

    decision under the Commerce Clause will

    make plain, however, that questions of the

    power of Congress are not to be decided by

    reference to any formula which would give

    controlling force to nomenclature such as

    'production' and 'indirect' and foreclose

    consideration of the actual effects of the

    activity in question upon interstate

    commerce.14.At the beginning Chief Justice Marshall

    described the Federal commerce power

    with a breadth never yet exceeded. Gibbons

    v. Ogden , 9 Wheat. 1, 194, 195. He made

    emphatic the embracing and penetrating

    nature of this power by warning that

    effective restraints on its exercise must

    proceed from political rather than from

    judicial processes. 9 Wheat. at page 197.

    For nearly a century, however, decisions of

    this Court under the Commerce Clause

    dealt rarely with questions of whatCongress might do in the

    exercise of its granted

    power under the Clause

    and almost entirely with

    the permissibility of state

    activity which it was

    claimed discriminated

    against or burdened

    interstate commerce.

    During this period there

    was perhaps little

    occasion for theaffirmative exercise of the

    commerce power, and the

    influence of the Clause on

    American life and law

    was a negative one,

    resulting almost wholly from its operation

    as a restraint upon the powers of the states.

    In discussion and decision the point of

    reference instead of being what was

    For nearly a century,however, decis ions of thisCourt under the CommerceClause dealt rarely withquest ions of whatCongress might do in theexercise of i ts grantedpowerthe inf luence of theClause on American l i feand law was a negat iveone, result ing almostwhol ly from its operat ion asa restraint upon the powersof the states.

    3

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    16/45

    'necessary and proper' to the exercise by

    Congress of its granted power, was often

    some concept of sovereignty thought to be

    implicit in the status of statehood. Certain

    activities such as 'production,'

    'manufacturing,' and 'mining' were

    occasionally said to be within the province

    of state governments and beyond the power

    of Congress under the Commerce Clause.15.It was not until 1887 with the enactment of

    the Interstate Commerce Act that the

    interstate commerce power began to exert

    positive influence in American law and life.

    This first important federal resort to the

    commerce power was followed in 1890 by

    the Sherman Anti-Trust Act and, thereafter,

    mainly after 1903, by many others. These

    statutes ushered in new phases of

    adjudication, which required the Court to

    approach the interpretation of the

    Commerce Clause in the light of an actualexercise by Congress of its power

    thereunder.

    16.When it first dealt with this new legislation,the Court adhered to its earlier

    pronouncements, and allowed but little

    scope to the power of Congress. United

    States v. E. C. Knight Co ., 156 U.S. 1, 15

    S.Ct. 249. These earlier pronouncements

    also played an important part in several of

    the five cases in which this Court later held

    that Acts of Congress under the Commerce

    Clause were in excess of its power.

    17.Even while important opinions in this lineof restrictive authority were being written,

    however, other cases called

    forth broader interpretations

    of the Commerce Clause

    destined to supersede the

    earlier ones, and to bring

    about a return to the

    principles first enunciated by

    Chief Justice Marshall in

    Gibbons v. Ogden , supra.

    18.In the Shreveport Rate Cases(Houston, E. & W.T.R. Co. v. United

    States), 234 U.S. 342, 34 S.Ct. 833, the

    Court held that railroad rates of an

    admittedly intrastate character and fixed by

    authority of the state might, nevertheless,

    be revised by the Federal Government

    because of the economic effects which they

    had upon interstate commerce. The opinion

    of Mr. Justice Hughes found federal

    intervention constitutionally authorized

    because of 'matters having such a close and

    substantial relation to interstate traffic that

    the control is essential or appropriate to the

    security of that traffic, to the efficiency of

    the interstate service, and to the

    maintenance of the conditions under which

    interstate commerce may be conductedupon fair terms and without molestation or

    hindrance.' 234 U.S. at page 351, 34 S.Ct.

    at page 836.

    19.The Court's recognition of the relevance ofthe economic effects in the application of

    the Commerce Clause exemplified by this

    statement has made the mechanical

    application of legal formulas no longer

    feasible. Once an economic measure of the

    reach of the power granted to Congress in

    the Commerce Clause is accepted,

    questions of federal power cannot bedecided simply by finding the activity in

    question to be 'production' nor can

    consideration of its economic effects be

    foreclosed by calling them 'indirect.' The

    present Chief Justice has said in summary

    of the present state of the law: 'The

    commerce power is not confined in its

    exercise to the regulation of commerce

    among the states. It extends to those

    activities intrastate which so affect

    interstate commerce, or the exertion of the

    power of Congress over it, as to makeregulation of them appropriate means to the

    attainment of a legitimate end, the effective

    execution of the granted power to regulate

    interstate commerce.

    ... The power of

    Congress over

    interstate commerce

    is plenary and

    complete in itself,

    may be exercised to

    its utmost extent, and

    acknowledges nolimitations other than are prescribed in the

    Constitution. ... It follows that no form of

    state activity can constitutionally thwart the

    regulatory power granted by the commerce

    clause to Congress. Hence the reach of that

    power extends to those intrastate activities

    which in a substantial way interfere with or

    obstruct the exercise of the granted power.'

    Whether the subject of theregulat ion in quest ion wasproduct ion, consumption,or market ing is, therefore,not materia l for purposes ofdeciding the quest ion offederal power before us.

    4

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    17/45

    United States v. Wrightwood Dairy Co ., 315

    U.S. 110, 119, 62 S.Ct. 523, 526.

    20.Whether the subject of the regulation inquestion was 'production,' 'consumption,' or'marketing' is, therefore, not material for

    purposes of deciding the question of federal

    power before us. That an activity is of localcharacter may help in a doubtful case to

    determine whether Congress intended toreach it. The same consideration might help

    in determining whether in the absence ofCongressional action it would be

    permissible for the state to exert its power

    on the subject matter, even though in sodoing it to some degree affected interstatecommerce. But even if appellee's activity

    be local and though it may not be regardedas commerce, it may still, whatever its

    nature, be reached by Congress if it exerts a

    substantial economic effect on interstate

    commerce and this irrespective of whethersuch effect is what might at some earlier

    time have been defined as 'direct' or

    'indirect.'

    21.The parties have stipulated a summary ofthe economics of the wheat industry.Commerce among the states in wheat is

    large and important. Although wheat is

    raised in every state but one, production inmost states is not equal to consumption.Sixteen states on average have had a

    surplus of wheat above their own

    requirements for feed, seed, and food.Thirty-two states and the District of

    Columbia, where production has beenbelow consumption, have looked to thesesurplus-producing states for their supply as

    well as for wheat for export and carryover.

    22.The wheat industry has been a problemindustry for some years. Largely as a resultof increased foreign production and importrestrictions, annual exports of wheat and

    flour from the United States during the ten-

    year period ending in 1940 averaged lessthan 10 per cent of total production, whileduring the 1920's they averaged more than25 per cent. The decline in the export trade

    has left a large surplus in production whichin connection with an abnormally large

    supply of wheat and other grains in recent

    years caused congestion in a number ofmarkets; tied up railroad cars; and causedelevators in some instances to turn away

    grains, and railroads to institute embargoes

    to prevent further congestion.

    23.Many countries, both importing andexporting, have sought to modify theimpact of the world market conditions on

    their own economy. Importing countries

    have taken measures to stimulateproduction and self-sufficiency. The four

    large exporting countries of Argentina,Australia, Canada, and the United States

    have all undertaken various programs forthe relief of growers. Such measures have

    been designed in part at least to protect the

    domestic price received by producers. Suchplans have generally evolved towardscontrol by the central government.

    24.In the absence of regulation the price ofwheat in the United States would be much

    affected by world conditions. During 1941producers who cooperated with the

    Agricultural Adjustment program receivedan average price on the farm of about $1.16a bushel as compared with the world

    market price of 40 cents a bushel.

    25.Differences in farming conditions,however, make these benefits mean

    different things to different wheat growers.

    There are several large areas ofspecialization in wheat, and the

    concentration on this crop reaches 27percent of the crop land, and the averageharvest runs as high as 155 acres. Except

    for some use of wheat as stock feed and for

    seed, the practice is to sell the crop forcash. Wheat from such areas constitutes the

    bulk of the interstate commerce therein.

    26.On the other hand, in some New Englandstates less than one percent of the crop land

    is devoted to wheat, and the average harvestis less than five acres per farm. In 1940 the

    average percentage of the total wheatproduction that was sold in each state as

    measured by value ranged from 29 per cent

    thereof in Wisconsin to 90 per cent inWashington. Except in regions of large-

    scale production, wheat is usually grown inrotation with other crops; for a nurse cropfor grass seeding; and as a cover crop to

    prevent soil erosion and leaching. Some issold, some kept for seed, and a percentage

    of the total production much larger than in

    areas of specialization is consumed on thefarm and grown for such purpose. Such

    5

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    18/45

    farmers, while growing some wheat, may

    even find the balance of their interest on the

    consumer's side.

    27.The effect of consumption of homegrownwheat on interstate commerce is due to the

    fact that it constitutes the most variable

    factor in the disappearance of the wheat

    crop. Consumption on the farm where

    grown appears to vary in an amount greaterthan 20 per cent of average production. The

    total amount of wheat consumed as food

    varies but relatively little, and use as seed is

    relatively constant.

    28.The maintenance by government regulationof a price for wheat undoubtedly can be

    accomplished as effectively by sustaining

    or increasing the demand as by limiting the

    supply. The effect of the statute before us is

    to restrict the amount which may be

    produced for market and the extent as well

    to which one may forestall resort to themarket by producing to meet his own

    needs. That appellee's own contribution to

    the demand for wheat may be trivial by

    itself is not enough to remove him from the

    scope of federal regulation where, as here,

    his contribution, taken together with that of

    many others similarly situated, is far from

    trivial. National Labor Relations Board v.

    Fainblatt , 306 U.S. 601, 606, et seq., 307

    U.S. 609, 59 S.Ct. 668; United States v.

    Darby, supra, 312 U.S. at page 123, 61

    S.Ct. 461, 132 A.L.R. 1430.

    29.It is well established by decisions of thisCourt that the power to regulate commerce

    includes the power to regulate the prices at

    which commodities in that commerce are

    dealt in and practices affecting such prices.

    One of the primary purposes of the Act in

    question was to increase the market price of

    wheat and to that end to limit the volume

    thereof that could affect the market. It can

    hardly be denied that a factor of such

    volume and variability as home-consumed

    wheat would have a substantial influence

    on price and market conditions. This may

    arise because being in marketable condition

    such wheat overhangs the market and if

    induced by rising prices tends to flow into

    the market and check price increases. But if

    we assume that it is never marketed, it

    supplies a need of the man who grew it

    which would otherwise be reflected by

    purchases in the open market. Home-grown

    wheat in this sense competes with wheat incommerce. The stimulation of commerce is

    a use of the regulatory function quite as

    definitely as prohibitions or restrictions

    thereon. This record leaves us in no doubt

    that Congress may properly have

    considered that wheat consumed on the

    farm where grown if wholly outside the

    scheme of regulation would have a

    substantial effect in defeating and

    obstructing its purpose to stimulate trade

    therein at increased prices.

    30.It is said, however, that this Act, forcingsome farmers into the market to buy what

    they could provide for themselves, is an

    unfair promotion of the markets and pricesof specializing wheat growers. It is of the

    essence of regulation that it lays a

    restraining hand on the self-interest of the

    regulated and that advantages from the

    regulation commonly fall to others. The

    conflicts of economic interest between the

    regulated and those who advantage by it are

    wisely left under our system to resolution

    by the Congress under its more flexible and

    responsible legislative process. Such

    conflicts rarely lend themselves to judicial

    determination. And with the wisdom,workability, or fairness, of the plan of

    regulation we have nothing to do.

    III.

    31.[This part deals with the argument thatthe government violated Filburns due

    process rights by assessing him penalties

    he couldnt avoided.] The statute is also

    challenged as a deprivation of property

    without due process of law contrary to the

    The conf l icts of economicinterest between the regulatedand those who advantage by i tare wisely left under our systemto resolut ion by the Congressunder i ts more f lexible andresponsible legis lat ive process.

    The st imulat ion of commerce is ause of the regulatory funct ion quiteas def ini te ly as prohibit ions orrestr ict ions thereon.

    6

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    19/45

    Fifth Amendment, both because of its

    regulatory effect on the appellee and

    because of its alleged retroactive effect.

    The court below sustained the plea on the

    ground of forbidden retroactivity 'or in the

    alternative, that the equities of the case as

    shown by the record favor the plaintiff.' 43

    F.Supp. 1017, 1019. An Act of Congress is

    not to be refused application by the courtsas arbitrary and capricious and forbidden by

    the Due Process Clause merely because it is

    deemed in a particular case to work an

    inequitable result.

    32.Appellee's claim that the Act works adeprivation of due process even apart from

    its allegedly retroactive effect is not

    persuasive. Control of total supply, upon

    which the whole statutory plan is based,

    depends upon control of individual supply.

    Appellee's claim is not that his quota

    represented less than a fair share of thenational quota, but that the Fifth

    Amendment requires that he be free from

    penalty for planting wheat and disposing of

    his crop as he sees fit.

    33.We do not agree. In its effort to controltotal supply, the Government gave the

    farmer a choice which was, of course,

    designed to encourage cooperation and

    discourage non-cooperation. The farmer

    who planted within his allotment was in

    effect guaranteed a minimum return much

    above what his wheat would have broughtif sold on a world market basis. Exemption

    from the applicability of quotas was made

    in favor of small producers. The farmer

    who produced in excess of his quota might

    escape penalty by delivering his wheat to

    the Secretary or by storing it with the

    privilege of sale without penalty in a later

    year to fill out his quota, or irrespective of

    quotas if they are no longer in effect, and he

    could obtain a loan of 60 per cent of the

    rate for cooperators, or about 59 cents a

    bushel, on so much of his wheat as wouldbe subject to penalty if marketed. Finally,

    he might make other disposition of his

    wheat, subject to the penalty. It is agreed

    that as the result of the wheat programs he

    is able to market his wheat at a price 'far

    above any world price based on the natural

    reaction of supply and demand.' We can

    hardly find a denial of due process in these

    circumstances, particularly since it is even

    doubtful that appellee's burdens under the

    program outweigh his benefits. It is hardly

    lack of due process for the Government to

    regulate that which it subsidizes.

    34.The penalty provided by the amendmentcan be postponed or avoided only by

    storing the farm marketing excess

    according to regulations promulgated by

    the Secretary or by delivering it to himwithout compensation; and the penalty is

    incurred and becomes due on threshing.

    Thus the penalty was contingent upon an

    act which appellee committed not before

    but after the enactment of the statute, and

    had he chosen to cut his excess and cure it

    or feed it as hay, or to reap and feed it with

    the head and straw together, no penalty

    would have been demanded. Such manner

    of consumption is not uncommon. Only

    when he threshed and thereby made it a part

    of the bulk of wheat overhanging themarket did he become subject to penalty.

    He has made no effort to show that the

    value of his excess wheat consumed

    without threshing was less than it would

    have been had it been threshed while

    subject to the statutory provisions in force

    at the time of planting. Concurrently with

    the increase in the amount of the penalty

    Congress authorized a substantial increase

    in the amount of the loan which might be

    made to cooperators upon stored farm

    marketing excess wheat. That appellee isthe worse off for the aggregate of this

    legislation does not appear; it only appears

    that if he could get all that the Government

    gives and do nothing that the Government

    asks, he would be better off than this law

    allows. To deny him this is not to deny him

    due process of law. Cf. Mulford v. Smith ,

    307 U.S. 38, 59 S.Ct. 648.

    35.Reversed.

    7

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    20/45

    1

    Gonzales v. Raich

    Argued November 29, 2004

    Decided June 6, 2005

    California's Compassionate Use Act authorizes

    limited marijuana use for medicinal purposes.Respondents Raich and Monson are California

    residents who both use doctor-recommended

    marijuana for serious medical conditions. After

    federal Drug Enforcement Administration (DEA)

    agents seized and destroyed all six of Monson'scannabis plants, respondents brought this action

    seeking injunctive and declaratory relief

    prohibiting the enforcement of the federal

    Controlled Substances Act (CSA) to the extent it

    prevents them from possessing, obtaining, or

    manufacturing cannabis for their personal

    medical use. Respondents claim that enforcing

    the CSA against them would violate theCommerce Clause and other constitutional

    provisions.

    Justice Stevens delivered the opinion of the

    Court.

    1. California is one of at least nine Statesthat authorize the use of marijuana for

    medicinal purposes.1 The question

    presented in this case is whether the

    power vested in Congress by Article I, 8,of the Constitution "[t]o make all Laws

    which shall be necessary and proper for

    carrying into Execution" its authority to

    "regulate Commerce with foreign

    Nations, and among the several States"

    includes the power to prohibit the local

    cultivation and use of marijuana in

    compliance with California law.

    I

    2. California has been a pioneer in theregulation of marijuana. In 1913,

    California was one of the first States toprohibit the sale and possession of

    marijuana, and at the end of the century,

    California became the first State to

    authorize limited use of the drug for

    medicinal purposes. In 1996, California

    voters passed Proposition 215, now

    codified as the Compassionate Use Act

    of 1996. The proposition was designed to

    ensure that "seriously ill" residents of the

    State have access to marijuana for

    medical purposes, and to encourage

    Federal and State Governments to take

    steps towards ensuring the safe and

    affordable distribution of the drug to

    patients in need. The Act creates anexemption from criminal prosecution for

    physicians, as well as for patients and

    primary caregivers who possess or

    cultivate marijuana for medicinal

    purposes with the recommendation or

    approval of a physician. A "primary

    caregiver" is a person who has

    consistently assumed responsibility for

    the housing, health, or safety of the

    patient.

    3. Respondents Angel Raich and DianeMonson are California residents whosuffer from a variety of serious medical

    conditions and have sought to avail

    themselves of medical marijuana

    pursuant to the terms of the

    Compassionate Use Act. They are being

    treated by licensed, board-certified

    family practitioners, who have

    concluded, after prescribing a host of

    conventional medicines to treat

    respondents' conditions and to alleviate

    their associated symptoms, that

    marijuana is the only drug available thatprovides effective treatment. Both

    women have been using marijuana as a

    medication for several years pursuant to

    their doctors' recommendation, and both

    rely heavily on cannabis to function on a

    daily basis. Indeed, Raich's physician

    believes that forgoing cannabis

    treatments would certainly cause Raich

    excruciating pain and could very well

    prove fatal.

    4. Respondent Monson cultivates her ownmarijuana, and ingests the drug in a

    variety of ways including smoking and

    using a vaporizer. Respondent Raich, by

    contrast, is unable to cultivate her own,

    and thus relies on two caregivers,

    litigating as "John Does," to provide her

    with locally grown marijuana at no

    charge. These caregivers also process the

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    21/45

    2

    cannabis into hashish or keif, and Raich

    herself processes some of the marijuana

    into oils, balms, and foods for

    consumption.

    5. On August 15, 2002, county deputysheriffs and agents from the federal Drug

    Enforcement Administration (DEA)

    came to Monson's home. After a

    thorough investigation, the county

    officials concluded that her use of

    marijuana was entirely lawful as a matter

    of California law. Nevertheless, after a 3-

    hour standoff, the federal agents seized

    and destroyed all six of her cannabis

    plants.

    6. Respondents thereafter brought thisaction against the Attorney General of

    the United States and the head of the

    DEA seeking injunctive and declaratory

    relief prohibiting the enforcement of the

    federal Controlled Substances Act

    (CSA), to the extent it prevents them

    from possessing, obtaining, or

    manufacturing cannabis for their

    personal medical use. In their complaint

    and supporting affidavits, Raich and

    Monson described the severity of their

    afflictions, their repeatedly futile

    attempts to obtain relief with

    conventional medications, and the

    opinions of their doctors concerning their

    need to use marijuana. Respondents

    claimed that enforcing the CSA against

    them would violate the Commerce

    Clause, the Due Process Clause of the

    Fifth Amendment, the Ninth and Tenth

    Amendments of the Constitution, and the

    doctrine of medical necessity.

    7. The District Court denied respondents'motion for a preliminary injunction.

    Although the court found that the federal

    enforcement interests "wane[d]" whencompared to the harm that California

    residents would suffer if denied access to

    medically necessary marijuana, it

    concluded that respondents could not

    demonstrate a likelihood of success on

    the merits of their legal claims.

    8. A divided panel of the Court of Appealsfor the Ninth Circuit reversed and

    ordered the District Court to enter a

    preliminary injunction. The court found

    that respondents had "demonstrated a

    strong likelihood of success on their

    claim that, as applied to them, the CSA is

    an unconstitutional exercise of Congress'

    Commerce Clause authority." The Courtof Appeals distinguished prior Circuit

    cases upholding the CSA in the face of

    Commerce Clause challenges by

    focusing on what it deemed to be the

    "separate and distinct class of activities"

    at issue in this case: "the intrastate,

    noncommercial cultivation and

    possession of cannabis for personal

    medical purposes as recommended by a

    patient's physician pursuant to valid

    California state law." The court found the

    latter class of activities "different in kindfrom drug trafficking" because

    interposing a physician's

    recommendation raises different health

    and safety concerns, and because "this

    limited use is clearly distinct from the

    broader illicit drug market--as well as

    any broader commercial market for

    medicinal marijuana--insofar as the

    medicinal marijuana at issue in this case

    is not intended for, nor does it enter, the

    stream of commerce."

    9. The majority placed heavy reliance onour decisions in United States v. Lopez,

    (1995), and United States v. Morrison,

    (2000), as interpreted by recent Circuit

    precedent, to hold that this separate class

    of purely local activities was beyond the

    reach of federal power. In contrast, the

    dissenting judge concluded that the CSA,

    as applied to respondents, was clearly

    valid under Lopez and Morrison;

    moreover, he thought it "simply

    impossible to distinguish the relevant

    conduct surrounding the cultivation anduse of the marijuana crop at issue in this

    case from the cultivation and use of the

    wheat crop that affected interstate

    commerce in Wickard v. Filburn."

    10.The obvious importance of the caseprompted our grant of certiorari. The

    case is made difficult by respondents'

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    22/45

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    23/45

    4

    international and interstate traffic in

    illicit drugs. The main objectives of the

    CSA were to conquer drug abuse and to

    control the legitimate and illegitimate

    traffic in controlled substances. Congress

    was particularly concerned with the need

    to prevent the diversion of drugs fromlegitimate to illicit channels.

    16.To effectuate these goals, Congressdevised a closed regulatory system

    making it unlawful to manufacture,

    distribute, dispense, or possess any

    controlled substance except in a manner

    authorized by the CSA. ...

    III

    17.Respondents in this case do not disputethat passage of the CSA, as part of the

    Comprehensive Drug Abuse Preventionand Control Act, was well within

    Congress' commerce power. ... Nor do

    they contend that any provision or

    section of the CSA amounts to an

    unconstitutional exercise of

    congressional authority. Rather,

    respondents' challenge is actually quite

    limited; they argue that the CSA's

    categorical prohibition of the

    manufacture and possession of marijuana

    as applied to the intrastate manufacture

    and possession of marijuana for medicalpurposes pursuant to California law

    exceeds Congress' authority under the

    Commerce Clause.

    18.In assessing the validity of congressionalregulation, none of our Commerce

    Clause cases can be viewed in isolation.

    As charted in considerable detail inUnited States v. Lopez, our

    understanding of the reach of the

    Commerce Clause, as well as Congress'

    assertion of authority thereunder, has

    evolved over time. ... For the first centuryof our history, the primary use of the

    Clause was to preclude the kind of

    discriminatory state legislation that had

    once been permissible. Then, in response

    to rapid industrial development and an

    increasingly interdependent national

    economy, Congress "ushered in a new

    era of federal regulation under the

    commerce power," beginning with the

    enactment of the Interstate Commerce

    Act in 1887....

    19.Cases decided during that "new era,"which now spans more than a century,

    have identified three general categories

    of regulation in which Congress is

    authorized to engage under its commerce

    power. First, Congress can regulate the

    channels of interstate commerce. Perez v.

    United States (1971). Second, Congress

    has authority to regulate and protect the

    instrumentalities of interstate commerce,

    and persons or things in interstate

    commerce. Ibid. Third, Congress has the

    power to regulate activities that

    substantially affect interstate commerce.

    Ibid.; NLRB v. Jones & Laughlin Steel

    Corp. (1937). Only the third category isimplicated in the case at hand.

    20.Our case law firmly establishesCongress' power to regulate purely local

    activities that are part of an economic

    "class of activities" that have a

    substantial effect on interstate commerce.

    ... As we stated in Wickard, "even if

    appellee's activity be local and though it

    may not be regarded as commerce, it

    may still, whatever its nature, be reached

    by Congress if it exerts a substantial

    economic effect on interstate commerce."

    We have never required Congress to

    legislate with scientific exactitude. When

    Congress decides that the "'total

    incidence'" of a practice poses a threat to

    a national market, it may regulate the

    entire class. ..

    21.Wickard ... establishes that Congress canregulate purely intrastate activity that is

    not itself "commercial," in that it is not

    produced for sale, if it concludes that

    failure to regulate that class of activitywould undercut the regulation of the

    interstate market in that commodity.

    22.The similarities between this case andWickard are striking. Like the farmer in

    Wickard, respondents are cultivating, for

    home consumption, a fungible

    commodity for which there is an

    established, albeit illegal, interstate

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    24/45

    5

    market. Just as the Agricultural

    Adjustment Act was designed "to control

    the volume [of wheat] moving in

    interstate and foreign commerce in order

    to avoid surpluses ..." and consequently

    control the market price, a primary

    purpose of the CSA is to control thesupply and demand of controlled

    substances in both lawful and unlawful

    drug markets. In Wickard, we had no

    difficulty concluding that Congress had a

    rational basis for believing that, when

    viewed in the aggregate, leaving home-

    consumed wheat outside the regulatory

    scheme would have a substantial

    influence on price and market conditions.

    Here too, Congress had a rational basis

    for concluding that leaving home-

    consumed marijuana outside federalcontrol would similarly affect price and

    market conditions.

    23.More concretely, one concern promptinginclusion of wheat grown for home

    consumption in the 1938 Act was that

    rising market prices could draw such

    wheat into the interstate market, resulting

    in lower market prices. The parallel

    concern making it appropriate to include

    marijuana grown for home consumption

    in the CSA is the likelihood that the high

    demand in the interstate market will drawsuch marijuana into that market. While

    the diversion of homegrown wheat

    tended to frustrate the federal interest in

    stabilizing prices by regulating the

    volume of commercial transactions in the

    interstate market, the diversion of

    homegrown marijuana tends to frustrate

    the federal interest in eliminating

    commercial transactions in the interstate

    market in their entirety. In both cases, the

    regulation is squarely within Congress'

    commerce power because production ofthe commodity meant for home

    consumption, be it wheat or marijuana,

    has a substantial effect on supply and

    demand in the national market for that

    commodity.

    24.Nonetheless, respondents suggest thatWickard differs from this case in three

    respects: (1) the Agricultural Adjustment

    Act, unlike the CSA, exempted small

    farming operations; (2) Wickard

    involved a "quintessential economic

    activity"--a commercial farm--whereas

    respondents do not sell marijuana; and

    (3) the Wickard record made it clear thatthe aggregate production of wheat for use

    on farms had a significant impact on

    market prices. Those differences, though

    factually accurate, do not diminish the

    precedential force of this Court's

    reasoning. ....

    IV

    25.To support their contrary submission,respondents rely heavily on two of our

    more recent Commerce Clause cases. In

    their myopic focus, they overlook the

    larger context of modern-era Commerce

    Clause jurisprudence preserved by those

    cases. Moreover, even in the narrow

    prism of respondents' creation, they read

    those cases far too broadly. Those two

    cases, of course, are Lopez and Morrison.

    As an initial matter, the statutory

    challenges at issue in those cases were

    markedly different from the challenge

    respondents pursue in the case at hand.

    Here, respondents ask us to excise

    individual applications of a concededly

    valid statutory scheme. In contrast, in

    both Lopez and Morrison, the parties

    asserted that a particular statute or

    provision fell outside Congress'

    commerce power in its entirety. This

    distinction is pivotal for we have often

    reiterated that "[w]here the class of

    activities is regulated and that class is

    within the reach of federal power, the

    courts have no power 'to excise, as

    trivial, individual instances' of the class."

    26.Unlike those at issue in Lopez andMorrison, the activities regulated by the

    CSA are quintessentially economic.

    "Economics" refers to "the production,

    distribution, and consumption of

    commodities." Webster's Third New

    International Dictionary 720 (1966). The

    CSA is a statute that regulates the

  • 7/28/2019 Reader Week 1

    25/45

    6

    production, distribution, and

    consumption of commodities for which

    there is an established, and lucrative,

    interstate market. Prohibiting the

    intrastate possession or manufacture of

    an article of commerce is a rational (and

    commonly utilized) means of regulatingcommerce in that product....

    27.First, the fact that marijuana is used "forpersonal medical purposes on the advice

    of a physician" cannot itself serve as a

    distinguishing factor. The CSA

    designates marijuana as contraband for

    any purpose; in fact, by characterizing

    marijuana as a Schedule I drug, Congress

    expressly found that the drug has no

    acceptable medical uses. Moreover, the

    CSA is a comprehensive regulatory

    regime specifically designed to regulatewhich controlled substances can be

    utilized for medicinal purposes, and in

    what manner. Indeed, most of the

    substances classified in the CSA "have a

    useful and legitimate medical purpose."

    Thus, even if respondents are correct that

    marijuana does have accepted medical

    uses and thus should be redesignated as a

    lesser schedule drug, the CSA would still

    impose controls beyond what is required

    by California law ... the mere fact that

    marijuana--like virtually every othercontrolled substance regulated by t