112
REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL VIOLATIONS IN CANADA by Emilia Ganslandt Thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Degree of Bachelor of Arts with Honours in Economics Acadia University April, 2020 © Copyright by Emilia Ganslandt, 2020

REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL VIOLATIONS

IN CANADA

by

Emilia Ganslandt

Thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the

requirements for the Degree of

Bachelor of Arts with

Honours in Economics

Acadia University

April, 2020

© Copyright by Emilia Ganslandt, 2020

Page 2: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

ii

Page 3: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

iii

This thesis by Emilia Ganslandt

is accepted in its present form by the

Department of Economics

as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of

Bachelor of Arts with Honours

Approved by the Thesis Supervisor

__________________________ ____________________

Dr. Andrew Davis Date

Approved by the Head of the Department

__________________________ ____________________

Dr. Burc Kayahan Date

Approved by the Honours Committee

__________________________ ____________________

Dr. Joseph Hayes Date

Page 4: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

iv

Page 5: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

v

I, Emilia Ganslandt, grant permission to the University Librarian at Acadia University to

reproduce, loan or distribute copies of my thesis in microform, paper or electronic formats on a

non-profit basis. I, however, retain the copyright in my thesis.

_________________________________ Signature of Author

_________________________________ Date

Page 6: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

vi

Page 7: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

vii

Acknowledgements I would like to thank my supervisor Dr. Andrew Davis for his support and patience during the

development of this thesis. I would further like to thank Dr. Justin Beaudoin for his helpful input

and assistance, and Dr. Stephen Maclean for helping me compile the data I needed. Thank you to

my family for proofreading and providing emotional support, not only during this process but

throughout my degree. Lastly, I would like to thank the entire Department of Economics and

Environmental & Sustainability Studies for believing in me and providing me with this

opportunity.

Page 8: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

viii

Page 9: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

ix

Table of Contents

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ....................................................................................................... VII

LIST OF TABLES ....................................................................................................................... XI

LIST OF FIGURES .................................................................................................................. XIII

ABSTRACT ................................................................................................................................. XV

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION .................................................................................................. 1

CHAPTER 2: LITERATURE REVIEW ..................................................................................... 7

2.1REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT IN CANADA ............................................................................. 7

2.2 REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT IN THE UNITED STATES AND ABROAD ................................. 11

2.3EVENT STUDY METHODOLOGY ............................................................................................ 14

2.4IMPACT OF SOCIAL MEDIA .................................................................................................... 19

CHAPTER 3: DATASET INFORMATION .............................................................................. 23

3.1 ENVIRONMENTAL VIOLATIONS ............................................................................................. 23

3.2 STOCK MARKET DATA .......................................................................................................... 28

3.3 SOCIAL MEDIA DATA ............................................................................................................ 31

3.4 MARKET CAP DATA .............................................................................................................. 37

CHAPTER 4: EMPIRICAL METHOD ..................................................................................... 39

CHAPTER 5: RESULTS ............................................................................................................. 45

5.1 REGRESSION RESULTS USING FINE SIZE AS AN INDEPENDENT VARIABLE ........................... 45

5.1.1 The Fine Variable.......................................................................................................... 49

5.1.2 Reputational Punishment............................................................................................... 52

5.2 REGRESSION RESULTS INCLUDING SOCIAL MEDIA AS AN INDEPENDENT VARIABLE. ......... 53

5.2.1 Social media variable.................................................................................................... 57

5.3 REGRESSION RESULTS USING RELATIVE FINE SIZE AS AN INDEPENDENT VARIABLE .......... 58

5.3.1 Relative Fine Variable................................................................................................... 61

CHAPTER 6: CONCLUSION .................................................................................................... 63

APPENDIX A: REGRESSION RESULTS DAY -30 TO -1 ......................................................... 67

APPENDIX B: REGRESSION RESULTS DAY -1 TO 0 ............................................................. 68

Page 10: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

x

APPENDIX C: REGRESSION RESULTS DAY 0 TO 30 ............................................................ 69

APPENDIX D: REGRESSION RESULTS DAY -30 TO -1 WITH SOCIAL MEDIA ................ 70

APPENDIX E: REGRESSION RESULTS DAY -1 TO 0 WITH SOCIAL MEDIA .................... 71

APPENDIX F: REGRESSION RESULTS DAY 0 TO 30 WITH SOCIAL MEDIA ................... 72

APPENDIX G: REGRESSION RESULTS DAY -30 TO -1 WITH RELATIVE FINE ............... 73

APPENDIX H: REGRESSION RESULTS DAY -1 TO 0 WITH RELATIVE FINE ................... 74

APPENDIX I: REGRESSION RESULTS DAY 0 TO 30 WITH RELATIVE FINE ................... 75

APPENDIX J: DATASET INFORMATION ................................................................................. 76

APPENDIX K: CHANGES IN STOCK RETURNS FOR FIRMS DAY -30 TO -1 ..................... 77

APPENDIX L: CHANGES IN STOCK RETURNS FOR FIRMS DAY -1 TO 0 ......................... 78

APPENDIX M: CHANGES IN STOCK RETURNS FOR FIRMS DAY 0 TO 30 ....................... 79

APPENDIX N: CHANGES IN INDEXES DAY -30 TO -1 .......................................................... 80

APPENDIX O: CHANGES IN INDEXES -1 TO 0 ....................................................................... 81

APPENDIX P: CHANGES IN INDEXES DAY 0 TO 30 ............................................................. 82

APPENDIX Q: SOCIAL MEDIA DATA FOR SAMPLE ............................................................ 83

APPENDIX R: ABNORMAL RETURNS DAY -30 TO -1 .......................................................... 84

APPENDIX S: ABNORMAL RETURNS DAY -1 TO 0 .............................................................. 85

APPENDIX T: ABNORMAL RETURNS DAY 0 TO 30 ............................................................. 86

APPENDIX U: RELATIVE FINE DATA ..................................................................................... 87

GLOSSARY .................................................................................................................................. 89

REFERENCES .............................................................................................................................. 91

Page 11: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

xi

List of Tables TABLE 1: ENVIRONMENTAL VIOLATIONS SAMPLE ......................................................................................27

TABLE 2: SOCIAL MEDIA VARIABLE ...........................................................................................................33

TABLE 3: ABNORMAL RETURN REGRESSION FOR DAY -30 TO -1 ................................................................45

TABLE 4: ABNORMAL RETURN REGRESSION FOR DAY -1 TO 0 ...................................................................46

TABLE 5: ABNORMAL RETURN REGRESSION FOR DAY 0 TO 30 ..................................................................48

TABLE 6: ABNORMAL RETURN REGRESSION FOR DAY -30 TO -1 WITH SOCIAL MEDIA .............................53

TABLE 7: ABNORMAL RETURN REGRESSION FOR DAY -1 TO 0 WITH SOCIAL MEDIA ................................54

TABLE 8: ABNORMAL RETURN REGRESSION FOR DAY 0 TO 30 WITH SOCIAL MEDIA ................................56

TABLE 9: ABNORMAL RETURN REGRESSION FOR DAY -30 TO -1 WITH RELATIVE FINE SIZE ....................58

TABLE 10: ABNORMAL RETURN REGRESSION FOR DAY -1 TO 0 WITH RELATIVE FINE SIZE ......................59

TABLE 11: ABNORMAL RETURN REGRESSION FOR DAY 0 TO 30 WITH RELATIVE FINE SIZE .....................60

Page 12: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

xii

Page 13: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

xiii

List of Figures FIGURE 1: NUMBER OF ENVIRONMENTAL VIOLATIONS PER YEAR IN THE SAMPLE ...................................26

FIGURE 2: AVERAGE FINE SIZE PER YEAR ...................................................................................................30

FIGURE 3: NUMBER OF NEWS ARTICLES BASED ON SOURCE ......................................................................32

FIGURE 4: AVERAGE FACEBOOK INTERACTIONS IN SAMPLE ......................................................................35

FIGURE 5: AVERAGE FACEBOOK INTERACTIONS BY YEAR FOR ALL NOTIFICATIONS ................................36

Page 14: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

xiv

Page 15: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

xv

Abstract

This thesis examines to what extent market-imposed sanctions, i.e. “reputational

penalties”, impose significant costs on firms that violate environmental regulations in Canada.

Determining the presence and size of reputational penalties is important for policy implications

as it can be used to determine whether legal fines are adequately punishing firms that violate

environmental regulations and, in combination with market-imposed sanctions, become a

sufficient deterrent of corporate behavior causing negative externalities on the environment.

The empirical method used to determine the changes in public attitudes following an

environmental violation is the standard event study methodology. The dependent variable is the

abnormal returns on shares of the company, or the difference between the security’s expected

return and its actual return. The event for this study was the release of the enforcement

notification (i.e. the notification of the fine that the firm has to pay). After applying inclusion

criteria 28 cases of environmental violations between 2010- 2019 were noted.

The results suggest that there is some negative reputational effect on the day of the

notification. However, the results also suggest that there may be a positive effect of the event for

higher fines. This, somewhat unexpected result from a theoretical point of view, may be the

result of the fine being smaller than expected by the market or, alternatively, that the market

appreciates that uncertainty is removed, along with the risk of a drawn out and costly legal case.

Based on the results, the legal penalties in Canada appear to be too low and failing to impose the

intended and adequate cost on the firm. Therefore, the main policy recommendation is to

increase the explicit costs imposed on firms that violate environmental regulations.

Page 16: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

xvi

Page 17: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

1

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION

Environmental degradation and climate change have in the last decades become popular

and prominent topics of discussion in academia, media, politics and everyday life. Corporations

have become increasingly attuned to environmental concerns as well, with terms like “green”,

“sustainable”, and “environmentally responsible” commonly being used in business language

today. Corporations have also become increasingly involved in both local, national, and

international environmental politics.1 However, at the same time 100 companies are responsible

for 71 percent of the greenhouse gas emissions released since the late 1980s.2

In the 1960s and 70s, when environmentalism was increasingly becoming a topic of

discussion in North American society, environmental ideas were often viewed by business

leaders as hostile and suspicious.3 There seemed to be a clear trade-off between corporate

profitability and environmental protection, and the two were often believed to be mutually

exclusive.4 In the 1980s, the severity of environmental degradation was underlined by a number

of major industrial incidents.5 This significantly impacted the corporate sector and started to

pivot the relationship between environmental standards and corporations.6 Environmental

objectives became increasingly integrated into business operations and strategies, and some

1 Falkner, R. (2017) 2 Riley, T. (2017, July 10) 3 ibid 4 ibid 5 ibid 6 Falkner, R. (2017)

Page 18: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

2

corporations started to become increasingly involved in environmental politics.7 During the

1970s, 80s and 90s North American society saw a major shift towards firms becoming more

involved in caring for their shareholders and the market as a whole. These measures include the

Clean Air Act of 1970 and the sulfur dioxide trading program established under the Clean Air

Act Amendments (CAAA).8 Another turning point came in 1987 with the Montreal Protocol that

successfully reduced the depletion of the ozone layer. This was one of the first international

environmental protocols to attract support from the industries that had caused the issue to begin

with.9

In the last decades a diverse set of business strategies, approaches, and interests have

evolved in response to growing environmental concerns. Some corporations argue that

environmental regulations are a burden to their operations and therefore oppose their

implementation.10 Others are opposed to the restrictions that environmental standards and

regulations impose on their economic freedom.11 However, there is also a significant number of

companies and corporate leaders which have started to try and reconcile environmental standards

with economic development.12 Prior to the 2020 World Economic Forum, the organization

announced the “New Davos Manifest” which focused on firms’ social and environmental

responsibilities.13 The manifest states that:

7 Falkner, R. (2017) 8 ibid 9 Sunstein, C. (2007) 10 Falkner, R. (2017) 11 ibid 12 ibid 13 Schwab, K. (2019, December 1)

Page 19: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

3

A company is more than an economic unit generating wealth. It fulfils human and societal aspirations as part of the broader social system. Performance must be measured not only on the return to shareholders, but also on how it achieves its environmental, social and good governance objectives. Executive remuneration should reflect stakeholder responsibility.14

This new manifesto was released because political leaders, economists, policy makers, and

activists around the world agreed that the current form of capitalism was not sustainable.15 It

represents a shift in societal values and the role that people believe firms have in society. Given

this change in nature, it is not unexpected that firms’ environmental practices could also impact

its reputation and its shareholders. Environmental investments, awards, and green certification

could all have impact on public attitudes and stock prices.16 Sustainable operations and corporate

behavior that avoids harm to the environment give companies access to more favorable

financing, e.g. through green bonds and Environmental, Social, and Governance (ESG) funds.17

Furthermore, being sustainable and environmentally friendly may give the firm a competitive

advantage as it may have better access to certain markets and would be able to differentiate its

products.18 This suggests that the market is concerned with environmental practices and news

about a firm protecting or harming the environment affect its reputation and thus its stock prices.

While words like “green”, “sustainable”, “triple bottom line”, and “eco-friendly” seem to

be more common in both everyday conversations and in business reports, this is only one side of

the story. During the last few decades’ environmental violations have risen as well. Between

14 Schwab, K. (2019, December 2) 15 Schwab, K. (2019, December 1) 16 Lundgren, T., & Olsson, R. (2010) 17 Ambec, S., & Lanoie, P. (2008). 18 ibid

Page 20: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

4

1991 and 2009, larger environmental fines (> $75,000) and penalties issued in Canada totaled

$1.4 million on average.19 However, in the last decade the average size of large fines in Canada

has steadily increased and in 2015 it exceeded $3.2 million.20 This trend peaked in 2017, when

this number was $32 million.21 In 2015, 17 larger fines were issued in Canada averaging

$230,000 each. By 2017, the average value of the 28 large fines issued was $1.15 million each.22

Ignoring the Volkswagen fine, the average fine is still higher in 2017 than 2015 ($637,000 and

$230,000 respectively).23 In 2018, the number of issued larger fines and penalties increased to

34, however, the total fine amount decreased to $15.7 million.24

The question then becomes: if firms that behave responsible and environmentally-

friendly thereby improving their reputation, do firms that commit environmental violations harm

their reputation? The aim of this study is to investigate whether firms that pollute harm their

reputation, and what impact this has on their stock prices. This thesis will specifically focus on

Canadian firms between 2010 and 2019. This study is relevant, first and foremost, because of its

policy implications. According to optimal penalty theory, as discussed by Becker (1968), the

optimal expected total penalty for an illegal activity equals the activity’s total social cost. Since

total penalties are made up of the explicit costs imposed by the legal system and reputational

punishments, a reversed causality relationship should exist between these two costs. This would

mean that, in order for the optimal penalty theory to hold true, a violation causing a certain social

19 Berkley Canada. (2019). 20 ibid 21 ibid 22 Berkley Canada. (2019). 23 ibid 24 ibid

Page 21: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

5

cost should either result in smaller legal fines and larger reputational punishment or larger legal

fines and smaller reputational punishment. In real life, however, the fines may not adequately

punish the firms for their violation and the reputational punishment may be smaller than optimal.

Measuring the degree of reputational punishment can be used to determine whether legal fines

are adequate to punish firms that violate environmental regulations if one strives for the optimal

penalty to hold true. This study is also important, as to the best of my knowledge, no recent

studies have been conducted on the topic in Canada [and the most recent, previous study from

1994 reflecting conditions during an earlier era].

The latest influential cross-industry study done on reputational punishment in Canada by

Lanoie and Laplante (1994) used data from the late 1980s and early 1990s. In the three decades

since, the environmental impact of Canadian consumers has skyrocketed. Each Canadian

produces, on average, 22 tons of greenhouse gases. This is almost three times the G20 average.25

However, while Canadians are still emitting more greenhouse gases, people are also becoming

more aware and concerned about environmental issues. In September 2019, hundreds of

thousands of Canadians joined the “Fridays for the Future” climate strikes seen across the

country. Over 315,000 people joined in Montreal alone with the majority of the people being

children and youth.26 However, it is not just school children that are becoming more concerned

with climate change and environmental degradation. In a poll of voters conducted before the

Canadian federal election in the fall of 2019, one out of 10 Canadians identified climate change

as a key issue and a determining factor in how they planned on voting.27 This demonstrated

25 The Canadian Press. (2018, November 14)26 Murphy, J. (2019, September 28) 27 Shah, M. (2019, October 9)

Page 22: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

6

Canadians’ concern about anthropogenic impacts on the Earth. Another survey conducted at the

end of 2019 showed that 76 percent of the survey respondents believed that Canada needed to do

more to mitigate and adapt to climate change and 71 percent believed the country needed to

become a global leader in climate change action.28 However, the impact of these actions was less

optimistic. Half of the respondents reported that they did not believe Canada could significantly

reduce its emissions and 58 percent believed that environmental actions would cause economic

hardships for citizens.29 This same pessimism, on the other hand, does not appear to translate to

citizens actions with 18 percent of Canadians engaging in some form of voluntary or unpaid

action to help protect and conserve the environment.30

Given the increasing concern about environmental degradation and climate change, there

is reason to believe that the market may react differently to environmental news than it did in the

early 1990s. This study will not only attempt to analyze whether firms that pollute harm their

reputation but it will also provide newer data which can be used to determine whether the

reputational effect has changed in the last few decades. This makes this study both important

from a policy perspective and as a tool to analyze if fines are of appropriate size to effectively

punish violating firms as well as from a market behavior perspective as it can be used to

determine whether Canadian’s growing concern for the environment translates into harsher

punishment of firms that violate environmental regulations.

28 Russell, A. (2020, March 11) 29 ibid 30 Statistics Canada (2015)

Page 23: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

7

CHAPTER 2: LITERATURE REVIEW

2.1 Reputational Punishment in Canada

According to Klein and Leffler (1981), certain types of wrongdoings can be punished

through reputation because the firm internalizes this cost. Previous research suggests that

reputational costs are high for financial misrepresentation,31 false advertisement,32 lack of safety

procedures,33 punitive damages lawsuits,34 product recalls,35 and private fraud.36 Consistent with

these results, firms should be motivated to comply with environmental regulations to protect

their reputation. Drowning and Kimball (1996) argue that managers adhere to environmental

violations out of interest for the firms’ image. Cohen (1992) argues that customers’ perceptions

of the quality or safety of a firms’ products may be negatively affected by environmental

violations. The idea that firms could be punished by customers, suppliers, or government

agencies is further supported by several other studies (see Henriques & Sadorsky (1996), Decker

(2003), and Zerbe (1996)). Similarly, other studies suggest that shareholders can encourage

companies to comply with environmental regulations through punishments in the stock market.

While several papers have been written and published on reputational punishment for

environmental violations in the United States, the topic is far less explored in Canada. Laplante

and Lanoie (1994) investigated public reaction to environmental violations in Canada between

1983 and 1991, arguing that firms do suffer from lower stock prices than expected on the day

31 Karpoff, J. M., Lee, D. S., & Martin, G. S. (2008) 32 Peltzman, S. (1981) 33 Mitchell, M. L., & Maloney, M. T. (1989) 34 Karpoff, J. M., & Lott, Jr, J. R. (1999) 35 Jarrell, G., & Peltzman, S. (1985) 36 Karpoff, J. M., & Lott Jr, J. R. (1993)

Page 24: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

8

that environmental suit settlements were announced. This contrasts with research using firms

from the United States which saw negative impacts on the day of announced lawsuits but not suit

settlements.37 According to Laplante and Lanoie, this could be the result of Canada’s more

conciliatory approach to environmental violations, supporting the view that the enforcement of

environmental legislation in Canada is laxer, hence less effective, than in the United States.

To obtain their results, Laplante and Lanoie developed a theoretical model that is tested

using an event study approach. The authors obtain data on 47 events related to publicly traded

firms operating in Canada through Canadian print media (including the Globe and Mail and the

Financial Post). Upon collection, the events were also divided into subcategories based on the

type of announcement made. In terms of the event study methodology, the authors analyze the

public reaction to environmental violations using the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)

version of the standard event-study methodology, assuming that this methodology sufficiently

captures the changes in public attitudes following the environmental violation. To achieve a

baseline and establish the average abnormal return prior to the event, the authors use data for 210

days before the announcement of the violation.

The authors conclude that no significant abnormal returns arise after the announcement of

lawsuits or violations, which according to Laplante and Lanoie may be the result of stakeholders

not believing that the Canadian government will actually pursue a punishment that will force the

firm to comply with environmental standards. This is supported by the literature, which suggests

that Canadian lawsuits are commonly drawn out and if fines are issued they are relatively low.

37 Karpoff, Lott, and Wehrly (2005)

Page 25: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

9

The average penalty under the Quebec Environmental Quality Act between 1984-1988 was only

$667.16.38 Suit settlements that had the same media coverage (id est events that are presented in

a feature article), however, did cause abnormal losses on the day of the event. More specifically,

cases with the same media coverage saw abnormal losses of 1.65% while Canadian cases with

the same media exposure saw 2% losses on the day of public announcement. For the four cases

in which the authors have both a lawsuit announcement and a suit settlement announcement, an

average abnormal loss of 2.7% is observed on the day of the suit settlement while no losses are

observed on the day the lawsuit was announced. This, according to the authors, suggests that

fines come as a surprise to Canadian stakeholders, including shareholders, which does not appear

to be the case in the United States where firms experience abnormal losses on the day the lawsuit

was announced but not the day of the suit settlement.

In another article, Lanoie and Ambec (2008), the authors argue that being more

environmentally sustainable could also be beneficial for firms. They state that “customers may

be aware of a company’s environmental performance through its offer of green products, but

they are less likely to be familiar with its environmental performance as measured by its

emissions into water or the atmosphere”39, underlying the potential issue of asymmetric

information in the violation of environmental regulations. This could impact the size of the

abnormal returns. It further supports the idea that the announcement of an environmental

violation comes as news to the market, i.e. revelation of new information. However, according to

the authors, firms could benefit by reducing their environmental impact as it may improve the

38 Hétu, J. C. (1989) 39 Lanoie and Ambec (2008), pg.47

Page 26: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

10

image or prestige of a firm. They write that “reducing pollution and other environmental impacts

may improve the overall image or prestige of a company, and thus increase customers’ loyalty or

support sales efforts”40. Lanoie and Ambec (2008) further highlight a number of alternatives in

which a firm can benefit from improved environmental standards including increased revenues,

differentiating products, and cost reductions.

Research also suggests that more severe environmental regulations may actually benefit

firms directly. Using a sample of 17 manufacturing firms located in Quebec, Lanoie et al. (2008)

found that stricter regulations led to modest gains in productivity and that industries which were

highly exposed to outside competition benefited even more from this effect. In another study,

Lanoie and Tanguay (2000) collected 50 examples of firms over an eight year period whose cost

of resources, energy, and services has decreased at the same time as they were reducing their

pollution.41,42 In Lanoie and Ambec (2008), the authors use the event-study methodology to

investigate how stock markets react to either good or bad environmental news. Based on a

sample size of 14, the authors conclude that stock markets react significantly to both types of

news, with the average abnormal returns following a bad news story being 2.22%. Furthermore,

the authors argue that the significant effect is observed within the first five days following an

event which suggests that the market incorporate the information rather quickly. However, given

the small sample size it is hard to draw any unambiguous conclusions from the data.

40 Lanoie and Ambec (2008), pg.47 41 Lanoie, P., & Tanguay, G. A. (2000) 42 Lanoie, P., & Tanguay, G. A. (1998)

Page 27: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

11

2.2 Reputational Punishment in the United States and Abroad

The question of whether firms’ reputations are tarnished by polluting the environment is

one several researchers have investigated before and the previous section outlined some

Canadian examples. However, studies on reputational punishment has been done around the

world. Porter and Van der Linde (1995) argue that a polluting firm suffers financially in terms of

lower sales and higher costs. This is only one way in which polluting firms may be penalized by

other forces than law enforcement. Polluting firms can be punished for their environmental

violations through community pressures as well (see Konar and Cohen, 1997; Arora and Cason,

1996; and Pargal et al., 1997). Karpoff, Lott, and Wehrly (2005) investigate if market-imposed

sanctions, or “reputational penalties”, are significant for firms that violate environmental

regulations in the United States. The authors use a sample of 478 environmental violations

between 1980 and 2000 to investigate whether the announcement of environmental violations

significantly impacted the accused firms’ stock price. After running an event study the authors

find that the average abnormal stock return following the initial announcement of alleged

contamination is -1.69 percent while it is only -1.58 percent after an initial announcement that

the firm has been formally charged. These abnormal stock returns are, according to the authors,

both economically meaningful and statistically significant. The authors further argue that the

corresponding losses from the abnormal stock returns are similar in size to the legal penalties

that the firms faced.

Hamilton (1995) further supports the argument that firms are significantly impacted by

the announcement of negative environmental news. By studying the impact of the disclosure of

the 1989 Toxics Release Inventory (TRI), Hamilton found that shareholders in the TRI saw

Page 28: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

12

significant abnormal returns following the release of the index. Specifically, the author

calculated that these abnormal returns represented an average loss of $4.1 million on the day that

the pollution incident was disclosed.43 Building on the argument that information like the TRI

can serve as a quasi-regulatory mechanism. Konar and Cohen (1997) find empirical evidence

that firms which face the largest abnormal returns following the disclosure of negative

environmental behavior are quicker to change their polluting behaviors than other firms in the

industry, supporting the idea that financial markets may incentivize firms to change their

environmental behavior.44 The negative impact of an environmental disaster or pollution

announcement has been observed in specific sectors as well. Capelle-Blancard and Laguna

(2009), for example, observed a 1.3 percent decline in the market value of petrochemical firms

following the announcement of an explosion of a refinery or chemical plant.45 Furthermore, as

expected, studies specifically investigating significant disasters like the Bhopal chemical

explosion and the Exxon-Valdez oil spill report some of the largest negative abnormal returns in

the literature.46,47

Studies on the impact that environmental news has on shareholders has not only been

studied in the United States, but around the world. Gupta and Guldar (2005) studied the impact

of environmental ratings on stock prices, arguing that the announcement of negative

environmental behavior significantly impacted firms’ stock prices, observing a negative

43 Hamilton, J. T. (1995) 44 Konar, S., & Cohen, M. A. (1997) 45 Capelle-Blancard, G., & Laguna, M. A. (2010) 46 Herbst, A. F., Marshall, J. F., & Wingender, J. (1996) 47 Salinger, M. (1992)

Page 29: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

13

abnormal return of up to 30 percent.48 Korean firms that fail to comply with national

environmental standards and regulations also face significant abnormal losses.49 Stock prices in

Argentina, the Philippines, Chile, and Mexico are also negatively affected by bad environmental

news, going against the idea that low and middle-income countries are not incentivized to invest

in pollution control methods.50 Nakao et al. (2006) showed that Japanese firms’ financial

performance is impacted by their environmental behavior as well.51

While many authors argue that firms’ stock values are significantly impacted following

the announcement of environmental violations, the literature is still torn on this topic. Xu, Zeng,

and Tam (2011) found that the announcement of negative environmental events had only a weak

impact on stock prices.52 The authors continued to argue that the impact that the disclosure of

environmental violation events has on stock prices may be country-specific, with Chinese firms

facing lower reputational punishment than firms in other countries.53 Laplante and Lanoie

(1994), which was discussed in the previous section, found no abnormal returns following the

announcement of an environmental violation or lawsuit. Furthermore, Doonan, Lanoie, and

Laplante (2002) report survey results indicate that pollution outputs by pulp and paper mills are

not affected by negative news coverage. 54As Karpoff, Lott, and Wehrly (2005) states,

“environmental violations differ from frauds and other types of wrongdoing in that they impose

costs on parties other than those with whom the polluting firm does business”, underlining one of

48Gupta, S., & Goldar, B. (2005) 49 Mamingi, N., Dasgupta, S., Hong, J. H., & Laplante, B. (2004) 50 Dasgupta, S., Laplante, B., & Mamingi, N. (2001) 51 Nakao, Y., Amano, A., Matsumura, K., Genba, K., & Nakano, M. (2007) 52 ibid 53 Xu, X. D., Zeng, S. X., & Tam, C. M. (2012) 54 Doonan, J., Lanoie, P., & Laplante, B. (2002)

Page 30: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

14

the arguments supporting why reputational punishments may be small or nonexistent. Another

potential reason, highlighted by Laplante and Lanoie (1994), is that shareholders do not have

confidence that the firms will actually be punished for their behavior. This may be country

specific as well. As mentioned earlier, Karpoff et al. (2005) observed significant abnormal

returns in the United States on the day that a fine or lawsuit was announced, however, this was

not consistent with the Canadian data according to Lanoie and Laplante (1994). This suggests

that shareholders have higher confidence in the legal system in the United States and have a

stronger belief that the government will follow through with its prosecution. Canadian

shareholders, on the other hand, appear to not be as confident (based on the findings of Lanoie

and Laplante (1994)) that the Canadian government will follow through with its initial

announcement of a lawsuit or fine, making the announcement of a conviction unanticipated news

to the market.

2.3 Event Study Methodology

In simple terms, the event study methodology measures changes in public attitudes. For

the purpose of this thesis stock prices will be used to determine the firms’ abnormal returns, or

the difference between the observed returns and the expected return in the absence of an event,

representing changes in public attitudes (and ultimately the freedom of the company to operate,

realize new business opportunities and its cost of capital).55 The event study methodology

assumes that the capital market response sufficiently reflects the impact that new information (an

event) will have on firms’ future expected profits (Fama et al., 1969). The reaction to the event is

measured by predicting an expected return during a set period of time -- or an “event window”--

55 Cowan, A. R. (1992)

Page 31: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

15

and then subtracting it from the actual returns observed in the data.56 The event window depends

on the study but typically includes the day before the event, the day of the event, and a few days

after the event.57 The methodology, however, is only a useful tool for measuring changes in

public attitudes if the announcement of the event comes as news to the market.58 In a corporate

context, the methodology is useful because the magnitude of the abnormal return following an

event provides a measurement of the unanticipated impact that an event of this nature has on the

wealth of the firms’ shareholders. Ergo, the event study methodology provides a tool to better

understand corporate policy decisions. From a policy perspective, event studies can help provide

insight into the effectiveness of regulations and laws.

The methodology became a popular method in economics and accounting in 1969 when

Eugene Fama, Lawrence Fisher, Michael Jensen, and Richard Roll published their paper The

Adjustment of Stock Prices to New Information which used an event study approach to examine

the stock-split announcement effect.59 The paper was the first to investigate how quickly prices

adjusted to specific types of information.60 Since then, the event study methodology has been a

popular tool used in both business and economic studies.61 As Fama (1991) states: “in 1970 there

was little evidence on the central issues of corporate finance. Now we are overwhelmed with

results, mostly from event studies”.62 Watson and Arunachalam (2018) states in its discussion on

56 Lanoie and Ambec (2008) 57 ibid 58 Sorescu, A., Warren, N. L., & Ertekin, L. (2017) 59 Fama, E., Fisher, L., Jensen, M., & Roll, R. (1969) 60 ibid 61 Binder, J. (1998) 62 Fama (1991), pg.1600

Page 32: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

16

the methodology that “the logic is straightforward: Financial markets capitalize the expected

value that (social) policies confer on a firm. When we observe a change in the law, if a given set

of social policies are actually beneficial to firms’ performance, the associated increase in the

firm’s expected profits should be reflected in its stock price”.63 As seen in this quote, the event

study methodology allows stock prices to serve as proxies for firms’ expected profits following a

specific event. Watson and Arunachalam (2018) further state that the event study methodology

is particularly useful in analyzing firms’ interests when public statements might be strategic or

unreliable.64 The method has, for example, been used to determine that diamond firms benefit

from conflict based on market reactions to civil disruption.65,

According to Binder (1998), there are two main reasons for using the event study

methodology. The first main reason is to examine if new information is efficiently incorporated

by the market and the second is to establish the impact that a specific event has on a firm’s

equity holders. The purpose of this thesis is to investigate the impact that announcements of

environmental violation have on a firm’s stock prices which makes the event study methodology

an appropriate choice according to Binder. 66

The event study methodology makes three overarching assumptions. First, it assumes that

the market is efficient, or at least semi-efficient. Secondly, the methodology assumes that all

63 Watson, S., & Arunachalam, R. (2018), pg.1976 64 Watson, S., & Arunachalam, R. (2018) 65 Guidolin, M., La Ferrara, E. (2007) 66 Guidolin, M., La Ferrara, E. (2010)

Page 33: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

17

publicly available information is reflected in the stock prices.67 Thirdly, it assumes that stock

prices adjust instantaneously when new information becomes available.68 Under these

assumptions, the new informational content provided by an event makes the investors instantly

adjust their expectations of the focal firms’ expected future profits.69 These new expectations are

reflected in the firms’ stock prices which then captures the value added from the new

information that the announcement provided.70 As stated by Sorescu, Warren, and Ertekin

(2017), “This assumption of an instantaneous change in stock prices is perhaps the most

appealing feature of the event study methodology: it allows researchers to isolate, in a forward

looking manner, the expected value that the firm will derive from a corporate action that has just

been revealed to the public”.71 It is this instantaneous change that the authors underline in the

quote above which allows for the researcher to investigate the value72 of an event at the time of

the announcement even though the cash flow has not materialized yet. This gives the method a

comparative advantage over other performance metrics such as profits, ROI, and sales which are

only available at low frequencies (annually or quarterly), making it hard to isolate the impact of a

specific event.73 The short-comings of the method, however, is that the event has to be news to

the market and dating of an event can sometimes be difficult which increases the risk of the

market already being aware of the event. Furthermore, it is susceptible to exogenous changes

happening within the event window. Say for example that a study is investigating the impact of a

67 Sorescu, A., Warren, N. L., & Ertekin, L. (2017) 68 Malkiel & Fama, E. F. (1970) 69 Sorescu, A., Warren, N. L., & Ertekin, L. (2017) 70 ibid 71 Sorescu, A., Warren, N. L., & Ertekin, L. (2017), p.186 72 “measured as the sum of the incremental future cash flows expected from the corporate action, discounted to the current period” (Sorescu, Warren, and Ertekin (2017)) 73 ibid

Page 34: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

18

lawsuit towards a firm, however, during the event window the CEO resigns. This may result in

impacts on the abnormal return that are not related to the event in question. It is, therefore,

important to choose the length of the event window with caution as a longer event window

increases the risk of these exogenous events impacting the results.

Part of the event literature focuses on specifying the conditions which need to apply in

order for an effective and sound event study to be conducted. McWilliams and McWilliams

(2000), inspired by McWilliams and Siegel (1997)74, argue that there is a step-by-step process

that should be followed when conducting an event study.75 They argue that the researcher must

identify an event which provides the market with new information and then hypothesize the

market’s reaction based on the theoretical knowledge available.76 The next step is to identify the

firms which are expected to experience shifts in stock values and the date of the specific events

studied.77 Following this, the researcher must choose an event window that is justified and then

control for other events which might impact the change in stock prices to ensure that the results

reflect changes caused by the specific event in question.78 Lastly, the abnormal returns during the

event window must be calculated and tested for statistical significance.79 McWilliams and

McWilliams (2000) end by stating: “ the researcher should always be required to specify enough

detail about how and from what source data are identified so that any other interested party

could, with enough effort, replicate the reported study”, stressing the importance of transparent

74 McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. (1997). 75 McWilliams, T. P., & McWilliams, V. B. (2000) 76 ibid 77 ibid 78 McWilliams, T. P., & McWilliams, V. B. (2000) 79 ibid

Page 35: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

19

information which is not always the case.80 They argue that failing to provide information of this

nature is indefensible, but it does occur.81

In terms of environmental economics, the method has been used quite extensively as

well. One of the most influential studies of reputational punishments for environmental

violations is Karpoff et al. (2005), which was discussed in the previous section on reputational

punishment in the United States and abroad. This study empirically tests the reputational

penalties in the United States following over 400 environmental events. The method has also

been used to investigate how firms’ stock prices react to bad environmental news, for example

Gupta and Goldar (2005) investigate how the stock prices of Indian firms are affected by

environmental news82 (also see Xu et al.,2012; Klassen and McLaughlin, 1996; and Takeda and

Tomozawa, 2008). However, the event study methodology has also been used to investigate how

firms’ stock prices are affected by good environmental news, for example in response to awards,

environmental investments, and good green ratings.83

2.4 Impact of Social Media

In 2019, it was estimated that one-in-three people globally, or two-thirds of people

online, used social media platforms.84 In Canada, that number is significantly higher, with 94%

of Canadian Internet users being on at least one social media platform.85 This demonstrates how

80 ibid 81 ibid 82 Gupta, S., & Goldar, B. (2005) 83 Lundgren, T., & Olsson, R. (2010) 84 Ortiz-Ospina, E. (2019, September 18) 85 CBC News. (2018, March 9).

Page 36: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

20

social media has become an integrated part of most Canadians’ everyday life. Social media is

also becoming important for how people consume and interact with news. In 2012, the Pew

Research Center found that 34 percent of Americans under the age of 30 consumed their news

online, while only 13 percent read physical newspapers.86 During the same time the amount of

Americans consuming printed media declined from 26 percent in 2010 to only 23 percent in

2012.87 Furthermore, 75 percent of people consuming their news articles online found their

information through email or social media platforms, underlining the changing consumption of

news as well.88 However, people not only seem to consume their news through social media, but

they discuss and share news through these platforms as well.89,90 As suggested by Olmstead et al.

“if searching for news was the most important development of the last decade, sharing news may

be among the most important of the next” (2011, p. 10). According to Smith and Rainie (2010),

55 percent of Twitter users have shared links to news articles on their account. This demonstrates

how social media not only becomes a platform for news but a way of sharing, discussing, and

contributing to the news coverage of an event.

Social media is not only a forum for sharing information but it has become a commonly

utilized tool for marketing and business opportunities as well. Many studies indicate that social

media platforms can directly impact a firms’ performance as well. Paniagua and Sapena (2014)

argue that a significant social media presence can affect stock prices. For example in 2012, crude

86 Pew Research Center (2012) 87 ibid 88 Purcell, K., Rainie, L., Mitchell, A., Rosenstiel, T., & Olmstead, K. (2010) 89 Hermida, A., Fletcher, F., Korell, D., & Logan, D. (2012) 90 Purcell, K., Rainie, L., Mitchell, A., Rosenstiel, T., & Olmstead, K. (2010)

Page 37: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

21

oil futures bounced up over $1 following multiple retweets of a Twitters user’s impersonation of

a Russian minister.91 During that same year, Google’s earnings report went viral causing the

stock exchange to temporarily stop trading in Google stock.92 A more recent example is Tesla-

founder Elan Musk’s tweet in August 2018 discussing taking Tesla private, which initially

caused a soaring stock price but ultimately resulted in a $40 million penalty.93 This demonstrates

how social media can affect a firm's operation and performance.

Historically, studies investigating social discourse have focused on a variety of media

forms including print media, audio media, and visual media.94 However, as technology has

continued to advance in the last decades, the types of media influences have become more

diverse, including social media which is now a major communication tool.95 Social media differs

from traditional media in a number of ways. Since content can be user-created, firms may have

less control of the discourse following an accident or negative event than they would have if the

event was only spread through traditional media channels.96 As Seo et al. (2013) states “due to

the diverse forms of media serving as communication channels, the influence of media on the

general public is increasing”,97 supporting the incorporation of social media into this event study

as only using printed media would neglect this changing nature of media influence.

Given the changes seen in the last decades around how information and news are shared,

this thesis will be incorporating the impact of social media on stock prices following an event as

91 The Economist. (2013, January 12). 92 Efrati, A. (2012, October 19). 93 Wayland, M. (2019, August 8). 94McLuhan, M (1964) 95 Syed-Ahmad, S.F and Murphy, J (2010) 96 Palen, L(2008) 97 Seo, S., Jang, S. S., Miao, L., Almanza, B., & Behnke, C. (2013).

Page 38: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

22

well. According to Bastos (2014), this makes sense as journalism has fundamentally changed to

become more Internet-focused. Hermida et al. (2014) further strengthen this argument by stating

that social media is becoming central to the way that Canadians are consuming news. Given this

changing nature of media consumption, social media could impact the public perception of firms

as well. This thesis will therefore incorporate social media to determine its impact on changes in

public attitudes following an environmental violation.

While previous studies on the impact of negative environmental events on Canadian

firms have not incorporated the impact of social media on stock prices, event studies in other

fields have. Seo et al. (2013) incorporated the impact that social media had on stock prices

following food safety events, finding that high media attention resulted in greater abnormal

returns. Khatua and Khatua (2016) investigated the impact that social media had on stock prices

following the 2015 Indian Budget announcement, finding that the overall positive tweets about

the budget increased stock market indicators.98 Sinanaj, Muntermann and Cziesla (2015) argue

that a firm reputation can be negatively affected by data breach events becoming public in social

media.99 These examples show that the integration of social media in event studies is becoming

an emerging part of the literature.

98 Khatua, A., & Khatua, A. (2015). 99 Sinanaj, G., Muntermann, J., & Cziesla, T. (2010)

Page 39: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

23

CHAPTER 3: DATASET INFORMATION

3.1 Environmental Violations

The data on environmental incidents used for this study was compiled using enforcement

notifications published by Environment and Climate Change Canada.100 The notifications are

available to the public and contain all successfully issued fines, including provincial ones. The

enforcement notifications outline the size of the fine, the violation(s) that the firm was fined

under, and details about the violation committed.

Several previous studies done on reputational punishment for environmental violations

have relied on printed media and then manually compiled their dataset using certain search terms

or by manually going through the data (see Lanoie and Laplante, and Karpoff et al.). As

mentioned above, however, the data for this study was compiled using government data provided

online. The benefit of this approach is that it reduces the risk of selective data collection as the

enforcement notifications contain all successful prosecutions during the chosen time period for

this study. Furthermore, while print media is dependent on reader engagement and may only

cover incidents that are believed to spark readers’ interest, the enforcement notifications have no

such objective and cover all infractions equally. The enforcement notifications also provide

unbiased and credible information on incidents, including when the conviction took place, what

environmental act or legislation was broken, and the size of the fine. A slight disadvantage of

using the governmental enforcement notifications to compile the data set is that it does not give

an idea of the media coverage that the incident received.

100 https://www.canada.ca/en/environment-climate-change/services/environmental-enforcement/notifications.html

Page 40: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

24

In their study from 1994, Lanoie and Laplante argue that an incident’s media exposure is

an important part of the results produced, arguing that “event studies should be based on events

that have the same extent of coverage in the media” (pg.669). The authors even go as far as to

create sub-categories based on the level of media exposure that each incident received. This was

a straightforward grouping alternative as they used printed media to assemble their data and

therefore had an idea of the level of media exposure of each incident. However, the enforcement

notifications do not provide any insight into media exposure as it reports equally on all incidents

and therefore the events cannot be grouped based on this criterion.

In Karpoff et al. (2005) the authors also use printed media to collect the initial

information on the incident and then support this data with additional information from the

Factiva database. The authors do not include media presence in their analysis but rather group

their events based on the type of violation. The violation type will be included as a control

variable in this study as well (see Table 1 for the breakdown of different violations).

The enforcement notifications contain hundreds of successful fines from the last 14 years,

however I applied multiple criteria for which events would be included in the study. First of all, I

limited my data to only publicly traded companies. This is a requirement for the event study

methodology to be implemented as I am using stock prices and abnormal returns to measure

public attitudes. I limited this even further to only include firms that have stocks or are owned by

a company that has stocks on the Toronto Stock Exchange, excluding any foreign-listed

companies operating in Canada. This was done to reduce the impact of asymmetric information.

Page 41: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

25

The focus of this study is reputational punishment. Given the increased degrees of separation, it

is likely that a foreign company operating in Canada or owning a Canadian company is less

affected by changes in public attitudes. The foreign company may also be more likely to have

foreign investors that are not aware of the company’s environmental violation in Canada.

Secondly, it creates a more homogenous data set as all stock prices are from the same stock

market.

The second restriction I made was to only include events where the fines were equal to

or larger than $100,000. This was done to ensure that the fine had non-negligible consequences

for the company. This is of relevance as many of the firms are large corporations and smaller

fines would not have imposed any real economic sanction. The fines varied significantly in size

from five incidents with fines of $100,000 to eight incidents with fines in the millions. The two

largest fines in the sample, of $3 million each, were imposed on Syncrude Canada Ltd. in 2010

and Teck Metals Ltd. in 2016 (see Figure 2 for average fine size per year). In total, after

imposing these restrictions, I was left with 28 incidents between 2010 and 2019 (see Figure 1 for

number of Environmental violations per year and Appendix J for full information on the dataset).

Most of these incidents involved companies in the energy sector (39.29%) or in the mining

industry (46.43%) (see Table 1 for more descriptive statistics).

It is worth noting that the event chosen for this study is the release of the enforcement

notification. This is the first time that the size of fine that the firm has to pay is released,

however, in most of the cases it is not the first time that the market hears about the firms’

Page 42: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

26

environmentally harmful practices. In some of the cases, the market has been aware of the

infraction for years before the enforcement notification is released.

Figure 1: Number of Environmental Violations Per Year in the Sample

Figure 1: This graph compares the number of violations committed each year in

the sample. The sample includes 28 incidents between 2010 and 2019 (Information on the incidents can be found in Appendix J)

Page 43: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

27

Table 1: Environmental Violations Sample

Event Classification Number:

Size of fine:

>1,000,000 28.57% (8)

500,000-999,999 7.14% (2)

100,000-499,999 64.29% (18)

Total: 100 (28)

Act Violated:

Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA)

5

Migratory Birds Convention Act, 1994 4

Pollution Prevention provisions (subsection 36(3)) of the Fisheries Act

17

Multiple acts violated 2

Total 28

Industry:

Materials 46.43% (13)

Energy 39.29% (11)

Other 14.28% (4)

Total 100 (28)

Note.—Descriptive statistics of 28 environmental violation events identified from enforcement notifications published by Environment and Climate Change Canada during the period 2010-2019. CEPA=Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA); MBCA=Migratory Birds Convention Act, 1994 (see Appendix J for entire dataset)

Page 44: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

28

3.2 Stock Market Data

The second set of data used in this study is from the Toronto Stock Exchange. For each

incident four data points are gathered which are the stock prices from 30 days before the

incident, the day before the incident, the day of the incident, and 30 days after. This study

assumed that the event (id est the release of the enforcement notification) comes as news to the

market, however this may not be the case in the real world. Hence, the 30 days and the 1 day

before is included to control for the market already being aware of the fine size before the release

of the enforcement notification, a situation known as leakage. It also controls for other impacts

that are not related to the event. The 30 days after is chosen as this is the window used by

Laplante and Lanoie in their study. Furthermore, this thesis predicts that firms will incorporate

the new information from the enforcement notification on the initial day that the event is

announced and that this is the day on which the most impact will be observed. The data for day

30 is included to test this hypothesis and to examine if there are any persistent impact the firms’

infraction would have on its stock prices.

Many of the firms in the sample are in very volatile industries and their stock prices could

change significantly from day to day. Furthermore, given that the study looks at dates within a

two-month window there could also be other events impacting the firms’ stock prices. To control

for market trends, I used data from industry specific indexes on the same dates as the incidents

(id est day -30, -1, 0, and 30). Specifically, I used the S&P/TSX Capped Energy Index101 for the

oil and gas companies, and the S&P/TSX Capped Materials Index102 for the mineral and natural

101 S&P/TSX Capped Energy Index [^TTEN] - Toronto Stock Exchange Index 102 S&P/TSX Capped Materials Index [^TTMT] - Toronto Stock Exchange Index

Page 45: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

29

resource companies. For the two incidents involving Canadian National Railway I used Canadian

Pacific Railway as it is the other dominant national railway company in Canada and together the

two companies capture the entire railway market. Given the duopoly nature of the Canadian

railway market, the general market effects unrelated to the incidents should be captured by the

stock price of the other railway company, hence the decision to use the Canadian Pacific Railway

data to capture market effects on the dates of the Canadian National Railway incidents. For the

environmental violation committed by Hudson’s Bay Company the S&P/TSX Capped Consumer

Discretionary Index103 was used and for the Bentall Kennedy incident the S&P/TSX Capped

Real Estate Index104 was utilized (see Appendix N, O, and P for more information on the returns

of the Indexes during the event window).

Using industry specific indexes was a deviation from previous influential studies. Lanoie

and Laplante (1994) used the CAPM model in which they calculate the expected return by

including the rate of return of the Canadian federal government 90-day Treasury Bill, historic

prices and the rate of return of the Toronto Stock market. Karpoff, Lott, and Wehrly (2005) on

the other hand use the CRSP equal-weighted index as a control for market trends in the CAPM

model in their study. While broader indexes like these can be used as a benchmark, I believe that

using the industry specific indexes provides a more accurate picture of the market trends

especially given the volatile nature of the energy and mineral markets, which makes up the

majority of my sample. Furthermore, the historic stock prices used in the CAPM may not be a

good prediction of future stock prices. The risk-free rate derived from the short-term government

103 S&P/TSX Capped Consumer Discretionary Index [^TTCD] - Toronto Stock Exchange Index 104 S&P/TSX Capped Real Estate Index [^TTRE] - Toronto Stock Exchange Index

Page 46: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

30

securities may also change on a daily basis which would introduce volatility to this variable

which the CAPM model does not account for.

Figure 2: Average Fine Size per Year

Figure 2: This graph compares the average fine size for each year in the sample. The

sample includes 28 incidents between 2010 and 2019. The fine size is given in thousands of Canadian dollars. It is worth noting that 2010 only includes one incident

and the average fine is therefore a reflection of Syncrude Canada Ltd.’s fine of $3 million (See Appendix J for full list of events in the sample).

Page 47: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

31

3.3 Social Media Data

As mentioned earlier, Lanoie and Laplante (1994) argued for the importance of media

exposure and the fact that the enforcement notifications did not capture media exposure was a

potential downside of the data collection method used in this thesis. To account for this, and the

changing nature of media, a social media variable will be used in the study as well. While Lanoie

and Laplante (1994) grouped the events based on if the violation was a featured article, this

variable is another measure of media presence and is based on the presence that the event had in

social media.

In this thesis, the social media platform used is Facebook. Facebook has in recent years

become a popular place for people to share and interact with news. To determine the amount of

interactions a news article had, SharedCount105 was used. This platform provided not only data

for how many people shared the news article, but also how many people interacted with those

shared links (i.e. liked, commented, or re-shared the link). For each event, I searched for the

name of the firm, “environmental fine”, and the year.106 The top news article on Google was

then used to determine the social media presence of that event. If no news article existed or was

not found on the first page of Google, the event was assumed to have 0 social media interaction.

If the incident had multiple articles published about it, the top result was used. In terms of the

news article source, 14 articles were published in national newspaper, 6 were found in local ones,

and 8 events did not have news articles published about them (see Figure 3). Some of the events

105 https://www.sharedcount.com/ 106 For example: Syncrude Canada Ltd. Environmental fine 2010

Page 48: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

32

were published in both national and regional newspapers, however, when this was the case the

top story on Google was used to determine the social media presence.

Figure 3: Number of News Articles Based on Source

Figure 3: This graph demonstrates the source that the articles in the sample were

retrieved for. The sample includes 28 incidents between 2010 and 2019. The three categories are local, national, and no news article found (see Appendix Q for entire

social media dataset).

Page 49: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

33

The social media variable also includes the amount of Facebook interactions that the

event notification itself received. This was done to measure the social media interactions of

events that did not have articles written about them. The Facebook interactions of the event

notification and the news article where then combined to make the social media variable.

Table 2: Social Media Variable

Social Media Average Interaction:

Size of fine:

>1,000,000 849.5

500,000-999,999 48

100,000-499,999 9.44

Act Violated:

Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA)

70.8

Migratory Birds Convention Act, 1994 656.67

Pollution Prevention provisions (subsection 36(3)) of the Fisheries Act

13.28

Multiple acts violated 2249.5

Industry:

Materials 18.38

Energy 592.64

Other 76

Note.—The average amount of interactions on Facebook (including shares, comments, and likes) for 28 environmental violation events identified from the enforcement notifications published by Environment and Climate Change Canada during the period 2010-2019 (see Appendix Q for more information about the social media dataset).

Page 50: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

34

Table 2 summaries some of the key characteristics of the social media data. As expected,

the number of interactions increase with the size of the fine. For fines over $1 million the

average interaction is 849.5 while for fines under $500,000 this number is only 9.44 (see

Appendix Q for more information about the social media dataset). The highest number of

interactions was for Husky Oil Operations Limited’s violation in 2019 which had 4436

interactions. The events in which the firm violated multiple regulations also saw more

interactions, however, this number is driven up by the Husky Oil incidents and therefore not too

much value should be placed on this. The second highest number of interactions was for MBCA

that had an average of 656.67 interactions. In terms of industry differences, energy saw the

highest number of interactions with an average of 592.64 interactions per event. Firms in the

materials industry saw an average of 18.36 interactions, and other industries had an average of

76 interactions (See Appendix Q for full list of interactions).

There is also a significant difference in interactions between the years in the sample.

There are no interactions with either news articles or enforcement notifications before 2016.

After 2016, the average number of interactions increase for each year and in 2019 the number of

interactions is 2127 (see Figure 4). This follows the same trend as can be seen for the 74

enforcement notifications published between 2010 and 2019 (both publicly and private firms).

Besides one case in 2013 that had 65 interactions, no news article before 2016 received any

interactions and 2019 had the highest amount of interactions (see Figure 5).

Page 51: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

35

Figure 4: Average Facebook Interactions in Sample

Figure 4: This graph compares the average amount of interaction on Facebook for each

year in the sample. The sample includes 28 incidents between 2010 and 2019. The average interactions include shares, comments, and likes of both a news article (if

found) and the enforcement notification.

Page 52: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

36

Figure 5: Average Facebook Interactions by Year for All Notifications

Figure 5: This graph compares the amount of Facebook interactions by year for all enforcement

notifications published by the Government of Canada that contain fines larger or equal to $100,000. This includes 74 incidents between 2010 and 2019. It is worth noting that 2013 only

includes one incident that received any Facebook interactions and the average is therefore a reflection of the 65 reactions that the Kelly Cove Salmon Ltd.’s incident received.

Page 53: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

37

3.4 Market Cap Data

The fourth set of data is the firms’ market cap data which will be used to determine the

relative fine size. The relative fine size will be used as an alternative to the fine size. This

variable will account for differences in firm sizes which may impact the abnormal returns as

well. A large fine, for example, may impact a small firm’s abnormal returns more than a large

firm as shareholders may believe that the larger firm has more reserves and a larger revenue

stream to deal with the fine. The two sets of data used to determine the relative fine size is the

size of the fine and the size of the firm. The firms’ market cap from the Toronto Stock Exchange

on the day the enforcement notification was released will be used to determine the size of the

firm. To determine the relative fine size, the size of the fine will be divided by the firm’s market

cap for the day of the event.

Page 54: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

38

Page 55: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

39

CHAPTER 4: EMPIRICAL METHOD

In order to determine whether firms that pollute harm their reputation and whether the

public cares about it, this thesis will use the event study methodology. As mentioned in previous

sections, this methodology is used by other influential studies on reputational punishment

including Laplante and Lanoie (1994) and Karpoff et al. (2005).

For the purpose of this thesis the event in question is the release of the enforcement

notification. An enforcement notification is released by the Government of Canada and follows a

firm being successfully fined for an environmental violation. It outlines the violation(s) that the

firm committed and the fine that the company has to pay. The release of the enforcement

notification was chosen for two reasons. The first reason is based on the assumption that

shareholders are not aware of the fine the firm will receive for its environmental violation prior

to conviction which makes the enforcement notification news to the market. This is a standard

assumption of the event study methodology, however, it may not be true in reality. To control for

potential leakage, the 30 days and the day before is included in this study. The second reason that

the enforcement notification was chosen was because it outlines the actual explicit cost that the

firm has to pay. According to Becker (1968) the optimal penalty theory states that the expected

total penalty for an illegal activity should equal the activity’s total social cost. The author further

argues that total penalties are made up of the explicit costs imposed by the legal system (in terms

of fines and required improvement to environmental standards) and reputational punishments.107

If regulators strive to achieve optimal penalty theory then smaller legal fines should result in

107 Becker (1968)

Page 56: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

40

larger reputational punishments and larger legal fines in smaller reputational punishments.

However, this may not hold in practice. The fines may not be large enough to significantly

punish the firm for their social cost. This thesis may guide regulators that strive for optimal

penalties to determine whether legal fines are adequate to punish firms that violate

environmental regulations or if they do not impose the economic sanction intended in which case

the optimal penalty theory does not hold true.

This thesis considers three separate specifications, with three regressions run under each

specification. All three specifications will be used to determine the reputational effects of firms

violating environmental regulations. The dependent variable for all three specifications is the

abnormal return. The abnormal return is the difference between the actual return of a firm’s

security and the expected return. The expected return is based on the return of the industry

specific indexes mentioned earlier. The abnormal return specification is given as:

ARit = Rit - E(Rit) (1)

Where ARit is the abnormal return for security i on day t, Rit is the actual return for

security i on day t, and E(Rit) is the expected return for security i on day t based on the return of

the firm’s industry index.

The three specifications all try to determine the change in public attitudes following an

event. This will be done utilizing ordinary least squares (OLS). They then vary in which

independent variable are included. For each specification, three regressions will be used all of

Page 57: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

41

which will use abnormal returns as the dependent variable. For the purpose of this thesis, the

abnormal return is the difference between the stock returns for two dates (i.e. -30 to -1, -1 to 0,

and 0 to 30), not the average daily abnormal return during those periods. The first regression is

with the abnormal return from day -30 to day -1, the second is with the abnormal return from day

-1 and 0, and the third regression is with the abnormal return from day 0 to 30. The specification

for these regressions are as follows:

ARit = β0 + β1 (size of fine)i + β2 (violation dummy)i + β3(sector dummy)i + 𝜺it (2)

As can be seen above, the independent variables for this regression specification are the

size of the fine, the violation dummy, and the sector dummy. The size of the fine is the explicit

monetary cost to the firm. This variable is included to determine how much of the abnormal

return can be explained, ceteris paribus, by the size of the fine. The violation dummy is to

control for any effects related to the specific act or regulation that the firm violated. Furthermore,

the public may view different infractions differently and the inclusion of the violation dummy

helps examine if this is the case. For this thesis, violations under the Canadian Environmental

Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA) will take the value of 1 and all other violations will take the value

of 0. The sector dummy is included to account for any impacts that are related to the industry

that the firm is in. This dummy is included as stakeholders may assume that there are inherent

risks of environmental violations in some industries and therefore not punish them as severely

based on that. For this thesis, firms in the energy sector will take a value of 1 and all other

industries will take a value of 0.

Page 58: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

42

To determine the impact that social media has on the firms’ abnormal returns a

modification of equation 2 will be used. The dependent variable remains the same with the only

difference from the previous specification being the inclusion of social media. Again, the three

regressions will be ran using OLS. The regression specification used to determine the impact that

social media plays on changes in public attitudes towards violating firms’ is as follows:

ARit = β0 + β1 (size of fine)i + β2 (violation dummy)i + β3(sector dummy)i +

β4(social media)i +𝜺it

(3)

As seen above, the independent variables now include the size of the fine, the violation

dummy, the sector dummy, and the social media variable. The first three variables will remain

the same as in equation 2. The social media variable is based on the number of interactions that

the news of each event had. This variable is included to determine the impact that social media

has on the changes in public attitudes following the event. The variable will also be used to

determine the impact of the changing nature of media consumption. Furthermore, this variable

helps control for media exposure which Lanoie and Laplante (1994) argue is important for event

studies of this nature.

The fines in the sample vary largely in size from $100,000 to several millions, however,

the size of the firms’ fined vary greatly as well. This could potentially result in different

responses to an event as a fine would impose a greater economic sanction on a smaller firm than

a larger one. To control for differences in firm sizes, three regressions will be used where the

relative fine size is used as one of the independent variables instead of the sum of the fine. The

Page 59: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

43

dependent variable will still be the abnormal returns. For the purpose of this thesis, the abnormal

return is the difference in stock prices from two days (id est -30 to -1, -1 to 0, and 0 to 30), not

the average daily abnormal return during those periods. The first regression is with the abnormal

return from day -30 to day -1, the second is with the abnormal return from day -1 and 0, and the

third regression is with the abnormal return from day 0 to 30. The specification for these

regressions are as follows:

ARit = β0 + β1 (relative size of fine)i + β2 (violation dummy)i + β3(sector dummy)i +

β4(social media)i +𝜺it

(4)

As seen above, the specification still includes independent variables for the violation

dummy, the sector dummy, and social media. The only independent variable that changes from

specification 3 is the fine being relative to the size of the firm. For this thesis, the size of the firm

is assumed to be the market cap from the Toronto Stock Exchange on the day of the event. The

relative fine size is then calculated by dividing the fine by the size of the firm. This variable is, as

mentioned above, included to account for potential discrepancies in abnormal returns resulting

from differences in firms’ sizes.

The results of specifications (2) - (4), and its implications, will be discussed in the

following section.

Page 60: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

44

Page 61: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

45

CHAPTER 5: RESULTS

This section will present the empirical results on the impact that the announcement of the

enforcement notification had on a firms’ abnormal returns. The results will be separated based on

the independent variables included and the point in time that they analyse. Variables of

importance will be further discussed at the end of each section.

5.1 Regression Results using Fine Size as an Independent Variable

Table 3:Abnormal Return Regression for Day -30 to -1

Dependent Variable:

Abnormal Return

Fine 3.68E-06 (1.21)

Sector -2.83 (-0.48)

Violation -0.75 (-0.11)

Constant 0.90 (0.21)

Observations 28

R2 0.06

Adjusted R2 -0.05 Note: The t-statistics is in brackets * p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01 The fine variable is measured in dollars. The sector dummy takes 1 for firms in the energy sector and 0 for other sectors. The violation dummy takes 1 for Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA) and 0 for other violations

Table 3 outlines the results for equation 2 with abnormal returns from the day -30 to -1 as

the dependent variable (see Appendix A for full results). As can be seen above, none of the

Page 62: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

46

variables are statistically significant at any normal level of confidence. This matches the

expected results for this regression. The R2 is also very low which may suggest that the market is

not aware of, and does not expect, the event. If little to no leakage occurs, there should not be

any significant variables in this regression as the fine has not been announced yet and therefore

should not affect the abnormal returns. It is also worth noting that the constant is positive and

very close to zero as well. This further suggests that the market is not aware of the current

situation and is not predicting the release of the enforcement notification. This aligns with my

initial assumption that the enforcement notification is news to the market.

Table 4: Abnormal Return Regression for Day -1 to 0

Dependent Variable:

Abnormal Return

Fine 8.90E-07** (2.19)

Sector -0.33 (-0.41)

Violation 0.35 (0.37)

Constant -0.46 (-0.79)

Observations 28

R2 0.17

Adjusted R2 0.07 Note: The t-statistics is in brackets * p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01 The fine variable is measured in dollars. The sector dummy takes 1 for firms in the energy sector and 0 for other sectors. The violation dummy takes 1 for Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA) and 0 for other violations

Page 63: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

47

The table above outlines the results of equation 2 using the abnormal returns from the day

of the event as the dependent variable (see Appendix B for the full results). The results show that

neither the sector nor the violation variable are of statistical significance. This suggest that the

market does not react differently based on which violation the firm broke or what sector it

belongs to. The constant variable, although not significant at the 10 percent level of confidence,

is negative which does suggest that there is some initial reputational punishment for the event

that is not explained by the fine size, the sector that the firm is in, or the violation it was

convicted for. In terms of the fine variable, it is positive and statistically significant at a 5 percent

level of confidence. The value of the variable is 8.90E-07 which suggests that, ceteris paribus,

an increase of 1.1 million in the fine size will result in a 1 percentage point increase in the

abnormal return. This was not the expected result, a priori, but it is of great importance. The

implication of this result will be discussed in detail below. It is further worth noting that the R2

increased significantly between day -30 to -1 when it was 0.06 and day -1 to 0 when it was 0.17.

This suggest that the event came as news to the market and that little leakage occurred.

Page 64: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

48

Table 5: Abnormal Return Regression for Day 0 to 30

Dependent Variable:

Abnormal Return

Fine -2.64E-06 (-0.84)

Sector 1.99 (0.32)

Violation -10.06 (-1.38)

Constant 5.66 (1.24)

Observations 28

R2 0.10

Adjusted R2 -0.01 Note: The t-statistics is in brackets * p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01 The fine variable is measured in dollars. The sector dummy takes 1 for firms in the energy sector and 0 for other sectors. The violation dummy takes 1 for Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA) and 0 for other violations

Table 5 shows the results for equation 2 using the abnormal returns from day 0 to day 30

as the dependent variable (see Appendix C for full results). As seen above, the variable for the

sector and violation are still insignificant. The fact that the sector and violation variables are not

statistically significant for this regression suggest that the public does not have different views

based on the violation or sector. The results further suggest that the event does not impact the

abnormal returns 30 days after the event as neither the fine nor the constant are of statistical

significance. This is interesting as there was some impact seen on the day of the event. While the

Page 65: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

49

fine variable is not of statistical significance it is still of economic significance. Since the sign of

the fine variable is negative this suggest that the fine variable may have a negative effect on the

firm in the long-run. It is worth noting that the R2 has decreased again from 0.17 which was

observed in the previous regression, to 0.10 in this regression. One potential explanation for this

is the difference in window size for these regressions. For the regression using the abnormal

returns from day -1 to 0 as the dependent variable, the window observed is only one day. During

this one day, the event is probably one of the most significant impacts of the stock prices.

However, in the regression using the abnormal return from day 0 to 30 as the dependent variable,

the window is 30 days. This makes the stock prices more susceptible to exogenous changes and

volatility in price that is unrelated to the event. This makes it harder to identify the impact of the

event on the abnormal return during the 30-day window following the event than the day before

to the day of the event. This is an inherent feature of the event study methodology which

produces the most robust results when the event window is rather narrow and less influenced by

other market events.

5.1.1 The Fine Variable The purpose of this thesis is to investigate the reputational effect of the release of the

enforcement notification. However, as previously mentioned this is not the first time that the

market becomes aware of the violation committed. For many of the violations, the market has

been aware of the firms’ environmental practice for years or since the investigation of the firm

began. Therefore, there are two possible outcomes for the firm. Either the firm gets away with

the environmental discrepancy or it gets punished. If the latter is true than it could either receive

a fine or face a trial.

Page 66: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

50

As mentioned earlier, the fine variable on day 0 is positive and statistically significant.

More specifically, holding everything else constant the abnormal return increases by 1

percentage point for each increase in the fine size of 1.1 million. This result is interesting as it

suggests that the fine comes as positive news to the financial market, especially for the firms that

receive higher fines. Theoretically this should not be the case. The fact that the firm was fined

should come as bad news to the market as the alternative was that the firm got away with the

behavior. Given that the fine variable is positive, the news of the size of the fine must have a

greater positive magnitude than the negative effect coming from the firm being fined to begin

with. There are three potential explanations for these results. First of all, the market may not like

uncertainty. For many of the violations, the market has been aware of the firm being under

investigation for several years and the news that the firm has been fined may therefore be

positive news as it removes the uncertainty related to the investigation. This helps explain why

the fine may come as positive news but not why a larger fine would result in higher abnormal

returns than a lower fine.

The second potential explanation is that the fine was lower than expected. For example,

for violations convicted under CEPA (under which 5 out of 28 of the violations in the sample

were) the maximum fine for a first time offending firm is $6 million and for second or

subsequent offences the fine can be as high as $12 million.108 The highest fine under CEPA in

the sample for this thesis is the 2018 Canadian National Railway Co fine of $1,126,627. The

same goes for the Fisheries Act (under which 17 out of 28 violations in the sample were fined

108 Climate Change Canada. (2019, July 4)

Page 67: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

51

under) and the MBCA (under which 4 out of 28 violations were fined under) where the minimum

fine for first time offenders fined on indictment is $75,000 if the firm is deemed a small revenue

corporation109 and $500,000 for a larger corporation.110,111 The maximum fine under the

Fisheries Act and the MBCA is again $6 million for first time offenders.112 ,113 For second and

subsequent offences the minimum fine is $1 million and the maximum is $12 million.114 ,115 The

largest fine under the Fisheries Act (not including events where a firm was fined under multiple

acts) in the sample is the 2016 Teck Metals Ltd. fine of $3 million. Under MBCA the largest fine

is the 2010 Syncrude Canada Ltd. fine of $3 million. This means that none of the firms fined

under CEPA, MBCA, and the Fisheries Act received the maximum fine. The positive fine

variable may therefore be the result of the fine being lower than expected. Higher fines would

suggest that the firm committed a more serious violation. Hence, firms that received higher fines

would have had even more reason to expect an even higher fine and therefore the abnormal

return is positively correlated with the size of the fine.

109 A small revenue corporation is defined as a firm which gross revenues does not exceed $5 million for the year before the fined was issued 110 Legislative Services Branch. (2020, March 11). Consolidated Federal Laws of Canada, Fisheries Act. 111 Legislative Services Branch. (2020, March 11). Consolidated Federal Laws of Canada, Migratory Birds Convention Act, 1994 112 Legislative Services Branch. (2020, March 11). Consolidated Federal Laws of Canada, Fisheries Act. 113Legislative Services Branch. (2020, March 11). Consolidated Federal Laws of Canada, Migratory Birds Convention Act, 1994 114 Legislative Services Branch. (2020, March 11). Consolidated Federal Laws of Canada, Fisheries Act. 115 Legislative Services Branch. (2020, March 11). Consolidated Federal Laws of Canada, Migratory Birds Convention Act, 1994

Page 68: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

52

The third potential reason that the fine variable is positive is that the release of the fine

removes the threat of an expensive and drawn out legal case. This would help explain why the

abnormal returns increased with the size of the fine. The larger the fine, the greater the initial

violation was. This would mean that the firms that received larger fines would also be more

likely to have a lawsuit against them. Therefore, the news of a fine would be even more positive

to firms with larger violations as their greater risk of a lawsuit is removed. Furthermore, the fines

do not come with compliance requirements or seizure of production or profits which a lawsuit

might. This would make it even more beneficial for the firm to avoid a lawsuit.

5.1.2 Reputational Punishment

As seen in the results above, the constant is negative on day 0 which could suggest some

reputational punishment for the event. For this study, the event in question is the release of the

enforcement notification. This was chosen as it is the date when the firms’ explicit cost for their

violation becomes known, however, it is not the first time that the market may have heard about

the firms’ violation. In most of the cases, the market has been aware that the firm is under

investigation for months or years. The fact that the constant is insignificant while the firm

variable is significant could suggest that the reputational punishment is already embedded in

stock prices since the release of the information on the firm being under investigation. In other

words, the market already knows that the firm harmed the environment and violated regulations,

however, it does not know what punishment the firm will receive. Therefore, the news to the

market following the release of the enforcement notification is not that the firm violated an

environmental violation but rather the explicit cost associated with that violation. This could

explain why the fine variable is of such significance for this study.

Page 69: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

53

5.2 Regression Results Including Social Media as an Independent Variable

Table 6: Abnormal Return Regression for Day -30 to -1 with Social Media

Dependent Variable:

Abnormal Return

Fine -2.37E-06 (-0.65)

Sector 2.33 (0.35)

Violation -10.28 (-0.36)

Media -0.001 (-0.15)

Constant 5.54 (1.17)

Observations 28

R2 0.10

Adjusted R2 -0.05

Note: The t-statistics is in brackets * p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01 The fine variable is measured in dollars. The sector dummy takes 1 for firms in the energy sector and 0 for other sectors. The violation dummy takes 1 for Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA) and 0 for other violations. The social media variable is measured in number of interactions

Table 6 shows the results for equation 3 with the abnormal returns from between day -30

and -1 as the dependent variable (see Appendix D for full results). The independent variables are

the same as in equation 2 besides the addition of the social media variable. As seen above, none

of the variables are statistically or economically significant. This is expected as the purpose of

this regression was to control for leakage. If the market is unaware of the event, then no effects

Page 70: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

54

should be observed. These results also align with the results from equation 2 using abnormal

returns from day -1 as the dependent variable (see Table 3).

Table 7: Abnormal Return Regression for Day -1 to 0 with Social Media

Dependent Variable:

Abnormal Return

Fine 1.02E-06** (2.177)

Sector -0.16 (-0.19)

Violation 0.24 (0.25)

Media -0.0003 (-0.59)

Constant -0.52 (-0.86)

Observations 28

R2 0.19

Adjusted R2 0.04 Note: The t-statistics is in brackets * p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01 The fine variable is measured in dollars. The sector dummy takes 1 for firms in the energy sector and 0 for other sectors. The violation dummy takes 1 for Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA) and 0 for other violations. The social media variable is measured in number of interactions

The table above summarizes the results from equation 3 using the abnormal returns from

day -1 to day 0 (see Appendix E for full results). The sector and violation variables are still

insignificant. The constant, on the other hand, is negative which again suggests that, ceteris

paribus, there is some reputational punishment for the firms violating environmental regulations.

Page 71: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

55

The media variable, while not significant, is negative which suggests that increased social media

awareness of the event might negatively impact a firms’ abnormal return. The R2 value has

increased from 0.10 when the dependent variable was the abnormal returns from day -1 (see

table 6) to 0.19 for this regression. This increase further supports the hypothesis that the market

is unaware of the fine being issued and suggests that little leakage has occurred. The fine

variable is both positive and statistically significant at a 5 percent level of confidence. The value

of the variable is 1.02E-06 which suggests that, holding everything else constant, an increase of

$1 million in the fine size will result in a 1 percentage point increase in the abnormal return. As

can be seen, the magnitude of the fine variable did not change much from the specification not

including the social media variable (see table 4 for results). Again this was not the expected

result but it is consistent with the results from the regression that omitted the social media

variable. As mentioned above, this could be the result of uncertainty being removed or that the

fine was not as high as expected. Furthermore, firms that received higher fines may have feared

that they would be tied up in a legal case and therefore prefer the fine.

Page 72: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

56

Table 8: Abnormal Return Regression for Day 0 to 30 with Social Media

Dependent Variable:

Abnormal Return

Fine -2.37E-06 (-0.65)

Sector 2.33 (0.35)

Violation -10.28 (-1.36)

Media -0.001 (-0.15)

Constant 5.54 (1.17)

Observations 28

R2 0.10

Adjusted R2 -0.05 Note: The t-statistics is in brackets * p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01 The fine variable is measured in dollars. The sector dummy takes 1 for firms in the energy sector and 0 for other sectors. The violation dummy takes 1 for Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA) and 0 for other violations. The social media variable is measured in number of interactions

Table 8 summarizes the results from equation 3 with the dependent variable being the

abnormal return from day 0 to day 30 (see Appendix F for full results). The violation and sector

variable are still insignificant which suggest that the industry that the firm is in and the regulation

that it violated has little impact on the abnormal returns of the firms in question. The fine

variable is negative which could suggest that in the long-run a higher fine does negatively impact

the firm. The social media variable is still negative but still not significant.

Page 73: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

57

5.2.1 Social media variable As seen in the results above, the social media variable is negative for all three

regressions. This may suggest that there is some leakage occurring that results in the social

media variable being negative for the regression using the abnormal returns from day -30 to -1 as

the dependent variable. However, the social media variable is statistically insignificant for all

three regressions and it cannot be ruled out that the effect of this variable is equal to zero. This

could be the result of either social media not having an impact on the abnormal returns of a firm

or because the sample size in this study is too small. The effect of the latter is further worsened

by the fact that the usage of Facebook has changed both in scope and nature during the sample

period. This resulted in more than half of the events having no social media presence. Hence,

further research is needed to determine social media’s impact on changes in public attitudes

following environmental violation events

While the social media variable is not of statistical significance, it could have some

economic significance. For the regression using the abnormal returns from day -1 to day 0 as the

dependent variable, the social media variable is equal to -0.0003. This would mean that, holding

everything else constant, an increase in social media interactions by approximately 3300 would

result in a decrease of abnormal returns by 1 percentage point. Furthermore, for the regression

using the abnormal return from day 0 to day 30, the social media variable equals -0.001. This

would suggest that, ceteris paribus, an increase in social media interactions by 1000 would result

in a 1 percentage point decrease in the abnormal return. This would suggest that it takes the

market a little longer to react to and incorporate the events social media presences.

Page 74: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

58

5.3 Regression Results using Relative Fine Size as an Independent Variable

Table 9: Abnormal Return Regression for Day -30 to -1 with Relative Fine Size

Dependent Variable:

Abnormal Return

Relative Fine -0.02 (-0.13)

Sector -2.57 (-0.38)

Violation -0.54 (-0.07)

Media 0.001 (0.13)

Constant 3.49 (0.86)

Observations 28

R2 0.01

Adjusted R2 -0.17 Note: The t-statistics is in brackets * p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01 The relative fine variable is the fine size divided by the firm’s market cap on the day of the event. The sector dummy takes 1 for firms in the energy sector and 0 for other sectors. The violation dummy takes 1 for Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA) and 0 for other violations. The social media variable is measured in number of interactions Table 9 summarizes the results for equation 4 with the dependent variable being the

abnormal returns for day -30 to day -1 (see Appendix G for full results). The independent

variables are the same as equation 3 besides the fine variable which has been exchanged for a

relative fine variable. The relative fine is included as a variable in the regression to control for

differences in firm sizes. None of the variables in this regression are statistically significant. This

aligns with expectations of what would happen as the event has not occurred yet and if the

Page 75: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

59

variables were significant this would indicate that the market was somewhat aware of what was

going to happen.

Table 10: Abnormal Return Regression for Day -1 to 0 with Relative Fine Size

Dependent Variable:

Abnormal Return

Relative Fine 0.03 (1.22)

Sector -0.09 (-0.10)

Violation 0.58 (0.56)

Media -0.001 (-0.87)

Constant -0.02 (-0.03)

Observations 28

R2 0.08

Adjusted R2 -0.08 Note: The t-statistics is in brackets * p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01 The relative fine variable is the fine size divided by the firm’s market cap on the day of the event. The sector dummy takes 1 for firms in the energy sector and 0 for other sectors. The violation dummy takes 1 for Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA) and 0 for other violations. The social media variable is measured in number of interactions The table above shows the results from equation 4 using the abnormal returns from

day -1 to day 0 as the dependent variable (see Appendix H for full results). The sector and

violation variable are statistically insignificant which aligns with the results of the previous

regressions as well. The media variable is negative, as expected, but it is not significant. The

Page 76: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

60

relative fine is still positive but compared to the fine variable for equation 2 and 3, the variable is

no longer statistically significant. This suggest that the abnormal return is more influenced by the

explicit cost imposed by the fine than its relative size to the firm. The implications of this result

will be discussed further in a later subsection. The R2 also increased from 0.01 from regression 9

(see table 9) to 0.08 in this regression. This is a substantial increase but not as great as seen in

previous cases.

Table 11: Abnormal Return Regression for Day 0 to 30 with Relative Fine Size

Dependent Variable:

Abnormal Return

Relative Fine -0.07 (-0.43)

Sector 2.09 (0.31)

Violation -11.07 (-1.46)

Media 0.001 (0.14)

Constant 4.40 (1.04)

Observations 28

R2 0.09

Adjusted R2 -0.07 Note: The t-statistics is in brackets * p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01 The relative fine variable is the fine size divided by the firm’s market cap on the day of the event. The sector dummy takes 1 for firms in the energy sector and 0 for other sectors. The violation dummy takes 1 for Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA) and 0 for other violations. The social media variable is measured in number of interactions

Page 77: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

61

Table 11 summarizes the results from equation 4 with the abnormal return from day 0 to

day 30 as the dependent variable (see Appendix I for full results). Neither the sector variable nor

the violation variable are statistically significant. The media variable is positive, which may

suggest that the media effect is not persistent. The relative fine variable is, while not statistically

significant, of the expected sign. The fact that the relative fine variable is negative in may

suggest that in the long run it is more important how large the fine is in relation to the firms’ size

than in the short run. This could be because for a small firm the fine would have larger

implications for their operations than it would for a larger firm.

5.3.1 Relative Fine Variable

As seen in the regression results above, the relative fine variable is positive using the

abnormal returns from day -1 to 0 as the dependent variable and negative using the abnormal

returns from day 0 to -1. This could suggest that the fines relative size is more important in the

long run. This could be the result of a large fine impacting the operations of a smaller firm more

in the long run than it would a larger firm. However, the relative fine variable is not statistically

significant for any of the regressions. This separates it from the fine variable that was statistically

significant at the 5% level of confidence using the abnormal returns from day -1 to 0 as the

dependent variable. This could suggest that the market cares more about the explicit cost that the

fine imposes rather than its size in relation to the firm.

One potential reason for this somewhat unexpected result may be that the public and the

market have an easier time comprehending an explicit fine. Everyone knows what a $1 million

fine, for example, implies and acts the same way regardless of the size of the firm that received

the fine. Furthermore, the public may not be aware of the size of the firm at the day of the event

Page 78: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

62

and therefore not know the size of the relative fine. This could result in the fine variable being of

statistical significance while the relative fine variable is not.

Overall, the results from this study suggests that the market cares about the explicit cost

of the fine following an environmental violation, not the relative size of the fine to the firm. The

market does not place different judgement based on the violation that the firm was fined under or

the sector which it operates in. Social media did not appear to be of statistical significance,

however, it could be of economic significance with just a few thousand interactions resulting in a

quite significant loss of abnormal returns. There appears to be some inherent reputational penalty

from the market, however, it is outweighed by the positive effect of the fine variable using the

abnormal returns from day -1 to day 0. There are a number of potential reasons for this, which

have been discussed throughout this paper, including the market being relieved that the

uncertainty is gone, and with it the threat of a long drawn out and costly legal case. Furthermore,

the fine may have been smaller than the market expected and therefore the size of the fine comes

as positive news to shareholders. Lastly, for many of the events the market would have been

aware about the firm’s environmental violation for years, however, the uncertainty was related to

if and how the firm would be penalized. Therefore, the reputational penalty may already be

embedded in the stock prices of the violating firm.

Page 79: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

63

CHAPTER 6: CONCLUSION

This thesis has investigated the changes in public attitudes, i.e. the stock market reaction,

following the news of a firm violating an environmental regulation using data on 28 Canadian

events between 2010 and 2019. This thesis uses a standard-event study methodology with the

event in question being the release of the enforcement notification which includes the monetary

fine.

This thesis used three separate specifications to investigate the changes in public attitudes

following a firm being successfully fined for an environmental violation. Under each

specification, three regressions are used to see if the results are different over time. The results

show when using the specification with abnormal return as the dependent variable and the fine

size, the sector, and the violation as the independent variables then none of the variables are of

statistical significance for the regression using data from day -30 to -1. However, the fine

variable is positive and statistically significant when using the abnormal return from day -1 to 0

as the dependent variable. More specifically, it suggests that, holding everything else constant,

for every $1.1 million that the fine size increases by the abnormal return increases by 1

percentage point. There are at least three potential explanations for this including that the

uncertainty is removed, the fine is smaller than expected, or the threat of an expensive and

drawn-out lawsuit is removed. These results do not align with Lanoie and Laplante (1994) which

found negative abnormal returns on the day that the suit settlement was announced. Karpoff et al

(2005), on the other hand, found no negative results on the day that the settlement was

announced but they did find negative abnormal returns on the day the lawsuit was announced.

Page 80: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

64

While their study was conducted in the United States, it does highlight a limitation in this thesis.

The event chosen for this thesis was, as mentioned before, the release of the enforcement

notification, however, as Karpoff et al (2005) highlights other results may have been found if the

announcement of the violation was used as the event rather than the date of the enforcement

notification release. The reason that the fine variable was of such significance and the

reputational punishment insignificant may be because the reputational effect is already

embedded in the stock prices. Further research should be done using the announcement of the

violation rather than the enforcement notification to determine whether this hypothesis holds true

in real life. The R2 also increase significantly between the regression using data from day -30 to

day -1 and the regression with the abnormal return from day -1 to day 0 as the dependent

variable. This suggests that little leakage has occurred before the event and the enforcement

notification comes as news to the market. For the regression using the abnormal returns from day

0 to day 30 as the dependent variable, none of the variables are of statistical significance.

When including social media in the specification, the variables remain statistically

insignificant for the regression using the abnormal return from day -30 to -1 as the dependent

variable. For the regression using the abnormal return between day -1 and day 0, the fine variable

is of statistical significance and very close in magnitude to the fine variable for the earlier

specification. More specifically, an increase in the fine size by $1 million will result in an

increase of 1 percentage point in the abnormal return, holding everything else constant. For the

regression using the abnormal returns from day 0 to day 30, none of the variables are of

statistical significance.

Page 81: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

65

The last specification includes the relative fine size (the size of the fine divided by the

size of the firm) instead of the size of the firm. When changing the explicit fine size for the

relative size of the fine in comparison to the firm, the variable is no longer significant. This

suggest that the market is more reactive to the explicit fine size than the relative size of the fine.

While the relative size was expected to be of more importance, the results show that this is not

the case. This could be because explicit costs are easier for the market to understand and

incorporate. For example, a fine of $1 million feels like a large fine and would be interpreted the

same regardless of the size of the firm. Furthermore, the market may not be aware of the size of

the firm when the enforcement notification is released and therefore may not know the relative

fine size. This could help explain the results found in this thesis.

Some other limitations of this study include the fact that the sample is rather limited.

When collecting the events for this study, certain restrictions of the events were implemented.

These included the firm having to be publicly traded in the Toronto Stock Exchange, the fine

size being equal to or larger than $100,000, and the enforcement notification being released

between 2010 and 2019. This resulted in 28 events from across Canada which is on the smaller

side of an event study. This small sample size could have resulted in some variables being

interpreted as insignificant while this was not the case. Another limitation of this study is that it

only uses four points in time (i.e. 30 days before the event, the day before the event, the day of

the event, and 30 days after the event) while Lanoie and Laplante (1994) uses data from every

day from 30 days before the event and 30 days after. Including more dates in the study would

Page 82: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

66

have made it easier to determine how persistent the impact of the fine was on the firms’ stock

prices following the event. The last major limitation was related to the social media variable.

Given the small sample size to begin with and the fact that Facebook only appear to be of

importance for spreading news in the last few years of the sample, it is hard to make any robust

conclusions from this data. It was hard to determine whether the social media variable was

insignificant due to the small sample size or because Facebook interactions does not impact a

firm’s abnormal return. Furthermore, this was to the best of my knowledge the first time that

social media was incorporated into an event study analyzing environmental violations.

Therefore, further research into the impact of social media on the changes in public attitudes

following an environmental violation is needed in order to determine whether Facebook

interactions affect a firm’s abnormal returns.

In sum, this thesis has started to provide insight into a gap in the reputational punishment

literature in Canada. This is to the best of my knowledge the first study done on environmental

violations since the 1990s and therefore provides more up to date data. Given the results, it does

not appear that even though Canadians are more environmentally concerned they punish the

firms harder than they did three decades ago. Furthermore, the positive fine variable indicates

that fines may be too low to adequately punish firms for violating environmental regulations and

it is therefore recommended that fines be increased to impose larger economic sanctions and

better reflect the social cost of the violation.

Page 83: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

67

Appendix A: Regression Results Day -30 to -1

See Table 3 for discussion of results

Page 84: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

68

Appendix B: Regression Results Day -1 to 0

See Table 4 for discussion of results

Page 85: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

69

Appendix C: Regression Results Day 0 to 30

See Table 5 for discussion of results

Page 86: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

70

Appendix D: Regression Results Day -30 to -1 with Social Media

See Table 6 for discussion of results

Page 87: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

71

Appendix E: Regression Results Day -1 to 0 with Social Media

See Table 7 for discussion of results

Page 88: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

72

Appendix F: Regression Results Day 0 to 30 with Social Media

See Table 8 for discussion of results

Page 89: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

73

Appendix G: Regression Results Day -30 to -1 with Relative Fine

See Table 9 for discussion of results

Page 90: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

74

Appendix H: Regression Results Day -1 to 0 with Relative Fine

See Table 10 for discussion of results

Page 91: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

75

Appendix I: Regression Results Day 0 to 30 with Relative Fine

See Table 11 for discussion of results

Page 92: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

76

Appendix J: Dataset information

Page 93: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

77

Appendix K: Changes in Stock Returns for Firms Day -30 to -1

Page 94: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

78

Appendix L: Changes in Stock Returns for Firms Day -1 to 0

Page 95: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

79

Appendix M: Changes in Stock Returns for Firms Day 0 to 30

Page 96: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

80

Appendix N: Changes in Indexes Day -30 to -1

Page 97: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

81

Appendix O: Changes in Indexes -1 to 0

Page 98: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

82

Appendix P: Changes in Indexes Day 0 to 30

Page 99: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

83

Appendix Q: Social Media Data for Sample

Page 100: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

84

Appendix R: Abnormal Returns Day -30 to -1

Page 101: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

85

Appendix S: Abnormal Returns Day -1 to 0

Page 102: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

86

Appendix T: Abnormal Returns Day 0 to 30

Page 103: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

87

Appendix U: Relative Fine Data

Page 104: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

88

Page 105: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

89

Glossary AR - Abnormal Return

CAAA- Clean Air Act Amendments

CAPM- Capital Assets Pricing Model

CEPA- Canadian Environmental Protection Act, 1999 (CEPA)

ESG funds - Environmental, Social, and Governance funds

MBCA- Migratory Birds Convention Act, 1994

OLS- Ordinary Least Square

TRI- Toxics Release Inventory

Page 106: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

90

Page 107: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

91

References Ambec, S., & Lanoie, P. (2008). Does it pay to be green? A systematic overview. The Academy of Management Perspectives, 45-62. Arora, S., & Cason, T. N. (1996). Why do firms volunteer to exceed environmental regulations? Understanding participation in EPA's 33/50 program. Land Economics, 413-432. Becker, G. S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. In The Economic Dimensions of Crime (pp. 13-68). Palgrave Macmillan, London. Berkley Canada. (2019). Environmental Fines and Penalties 2018 Update Report. Binder, J. (1998). The event study methodology since 1969. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 11(2), 111-137 Capelle-Blancard, G., & Laguna, M. A. (2010). How does the stock market respond to chemical disasters?. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 59(2), 192-205. CBC News. (2018, March 9). How does your social media use stack up against other Canadians? | CBC Radio. Retrieved November 12, 2019, from https://www.cbc.ca/radio/spark/388-pokemon-go-for-ecologists-fake-videos-and-more-1.4569277/how-does-your-social-media-use-stack-up-against-other-canadians-1.4569280. Climate Change Canada. (2019, July 4). Guide to understanding the Canadian Environmental Protection Act: chapter 14. Retrieved from https://www.canada.ca/en/environment-climate-change/services/canadian-environmental-protection-act-registry/publications/guide-to-understanding/chapter-14.html Cohen, M. A. (1991). Environmental crime and punishment: Legal/economic theory and empirical evidence on enforcement of federal environmental statutes. J. Crim. L. & Criminology, 82, 1054. Cowan, A. R. (1992). Nonparametric event study tests. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 2(4), 343-358. Dasgupta, S., Laplante, B., & Mamingi, N. (2001). Pollution and capital markets in developing countries. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 42(3), 310–335. Decker, C. S. (2003). Corporate environmentalism and environmental statutory permitting. The Journal of Law and Economics, 46(1), 103-129. Doonan, J., Lanoie, P., & Laplante, B. (2002). Environmental Performance of Canadian Pulp and Paper Plants: Why Some Do Well and Others Do Not?. Cahier de recherche no IEA, 2, 01.

Page 108: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

92

Downing, P. B., & Kimball, J. N. (1983). Enforcing pollution control laws in the United States. In International Comparisons in Implementing Pollution Laws (pp. 249-263). Springer, Dordrecht. Efrati, A. (2012, October 19). Google hit by weak results. The Wall Street Journal. Retrieved from http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10000872396390443684104578064671358259436.html Fama, E. F. (1991). Efficient capital markets: II. The Journal of Finance, 46(5), 1575-1617. Fama, E., Fisher, L., Jensen, M., & Roll, R. (1969). The Adjustment of Stock Prices to New Information. International Economic Review, 10(1), 1-21. doi:10.2307/2525569 Guidolin, M., La Ferrara, E. (2007). Diamonds are forever, wars are not: Is conflict bad for private firms? American Economic Review, 97, 1978-1995. Guidolin, M., La Ferrara, E. (2010). The economic effects of violent conflict: Evidence from asset market reactions. Journal of Peace Research, 47, 671-684. Gupta, S., & Goldar, B. (2005). Do stock markets penalize environment-unfriendly behaviour? Evidence from India. Ecological Economics, 52(1), 81-95. Hamilton, J. T. (1995). Pollution as news: Media and stock market reactions to the toxics release inventory data. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 28(1), 98-113. Henriques, I., & Sadorsky, P. (1996). The determinants of an environmentally responsive firm: An empirical approach. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 30(3), 381-395. Herbst, A. F., Marshall, J. F., & Wingender, J. (1996). An analysis of the stock market's response to the Exxon Valdez disaster. Global Finance Journal, 7(1), 101-114. Hermida, A., Fletcher, F., Korell, D., & Logan, D. (2012). Share, Like, Recommend. Journalism Studies, 13(5-6), 815–824. doi: 10.1080/1461670x.2012.664430 Hétu, J. C. (1989). Les sanctions pénales et la protection de l'environnement. https://aisel.aisnet.org/wi2015/61 Jarrell, G., & Peltzman, S. (1985). The impact of product recalls on the wealth of sellers. Journal of Political Economy, 93(3), 512-536. Karpoff, J. M., & Lott Jr, J. R. (1993). The reputational penalty firms bear from committing criminal fraud. The Journal of Law and Economics, 36(2), 757-802. Karpoff, J. M., & Lott, Jr, J. R. (1999). On the determinants and importance of punitive damage awards. The Journal of Law and Economics, 42(S1), 527-573.

Page 109: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

93

Karpoff, J. M., Lee, D. S., & Martin, G. S. (2008). The cost to firms of cooking the books. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 43(3), 581-611. Karpoff, J. M., Lott, Jr, J. R., & Wehrly, E. W. (2005). The reputational penalties for environmental violations: Empirical evidence. The Journal of Law and Economics, 48(2), 653-675. Khatua, A., & Khatua, A. (2015). How Stock Market Reacts to Budget Announcement? Through the Lens of Social Media in Indian Context. Management and Labour Studies, 40(3-4), 239-251. Klassen, R. D., & McLaughlin, C. P. (1996). The impact of environmental management on firm performance. Management Science, 42(8), 1199-1214.

Klein, B., & Leffler, K. B. (1981). The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance. Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), 615-641.

Konar, S., & Cohen, M. A. (1997). Information as regulation: The effect of community right to know laws on toxic emissions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 32(1), 109-124. Konar, S., & Cohen, M. A. (1997). Why do firms pollute (and reduce) toxic emissions. World Bank. Lanoie, P., & Tanguay, G. A. (1998). Dix exemples de rentabilité financière liés à une saine gestion environnementale. CIRANO. Lanoie, P., & Tanguay, G. A. (2000). Factors Leading to Green Profitability. Greener Management International, (31). Lanoie, P., Patry, M., & Lajeunesse, R. (2008). Environmental regulation and productivity: testing the porter hypothesis. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 30(2), 121-128. Laplante, B., & Lanoie, P. (1994). The market response to environmental incidents in Canada: a theoretical and empirical analysis. Southern Economic Journal, 657-672. Legislative Services Branch. (2020, March 11). Consolidated Federal Laws of Canada, Fisheries Act. Retrieved from https://laws-lois.justice.gc.ca/eng/acts/f-14/FullText.html Legislative Services Branch. (2020, March 11). Consolidated Federal Laws of Canada, Migratory Birds Convention Act, 1994. Retrieved from https://laws-lois.justice.gc.ca/eng/acts/m-7.01/FullText.html Lundgren, T., & Olsson, R. (2010). Environmental incidents and firm value–international evidence using a multi-factor event study framework. Applied Financial Economics, 20(16), 1293-1307.

Page 110: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

94

Malkiel, B. G., & Fama, E. F. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. The Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383-417. Mamingi, N., Dasgupta, S., Hong, J. H., & Laplante, B. (2004). Disclosure of Environmental Violations and the Stock Market in the Republic of Korea. McLuhan, M. (1994). Understanding media: The extensions of man. MIT press. McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. (1997). Event studies in management research: Theoretical and empirical issues. Academy of Management Journal, 40(3), 626-657. McWilliams, T. P., & McWilliams, V. B. (2000). Another look at theoretical and em-pirical issues in event study methodology. Journal of Applied Business Research (JABR), 16(3). Mitchell, M. L., & Maloney, M. T. (1989). Crisis in the cockpit? The role of market forces in promoting air travel safety. The Journal of Law and Economics, 32(2, Part 1), 329-355. Murphy, J. (2019, September 28). Hundreds of thousands join Canada climate strikes. Retrieved from https://www.bbc.com/news/world-us-canada-49856860 Nakao, Y., Amano, A., Matsumura, K., Genba, K., & Nakano, M. (2007). Relationship between environmental performance and financial performance: an empirical analysis of Japanese corporations. Business Strategy and the Environment, 16(2), 106-118. Olmstead, K., Mitchell, A., & Rosenstiel, T. (2011). Navigating news online: Where people go, how they get there and what lures them away. Pew Research Center’s Project for Excellence in Journalism, 9, 1-30. Ortiz-Ospina, E. (2019, September 18). The rise of social media. Retrieved November 12, 2019, from https://ourworldindata.org/rise-of-social-media. Palen, L. (2008). Online social media in crisis events. Educause Quarterly, 31(3), 76-78. Paniagua, J., & Sapena, J. (2014). Business performance and social media: Love or hate?. Business Horizons, 57(6), 719-728. Pargal, S., Hettige, H., Singh, M., & Wheeler, D. (1997). Formal and informal regulation of industrial pollution: comparative evidence from Indonesia and the United States. The World Bank Economic Review, 11(3), 433-450. Peltzman, S. (1981). The effects of FTC advertising regulation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 24(3), 403-448. Pew Research Center (2012). In Changing News Landscape, Even Television is Vulnerable. Trends in News Consumption.

Page 111: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

95

Purcell, K., Rainie, L., Mitchell, A., Rosenstiel, T., & Olmstead, K. (2010). Understanding the participatory news consumer. Pew Internet and American Life Project, 1, 19-21. Riley, T. (2017, July 10). Just 100 companies responsible for 71% of global emissions, study says. Retrieved from https://www.theguardian.com/sustainable-business/2017/jul/10/100-fossil-fuel-companies-investors-responsible-71-global-emissions-cdp-study-climate-change Russell, A. (2020, March 11). Canadians want more action on climate change, but are worried about 'economic hardship'. Retrieved from https://globalnews.ca/news/6312773/canada-climate-change-poll/ Salinger, M. (1992). Value event studies. The review of economics and statistics, 74(4), 671-677. Schwab, K. (2019, December 2). Davos Manifesto 2020: The Universal Purpose of a Company in the Fourth Industrial Revolution. Retrieved from https://www.weforum.org/agenda/2019/12/davos-manifesto-2020-the-universal-purpose-of-a-company-in-the-fourth-industrial-revolution/ Schwab, K. (2019, December 1). Why we need the 'Davos Manifesto' for a better kind of capitalism. Retrieved from https://www.weforum.org/agenda/2019/12/why-we-need-the-davos-manifesto-for-better-kind-of-capitalism/ Seo, S., Jang, S. S., Miao, L., Almanza, B., & Behnke, C. (2013). The impact of food safety events on the value of food-related firms: An event study approach. International Journal of Hospitality Management, 33, 153-165. Shah, M. (2019, October 9). Climate change emerges as one of the top ballot-box issues among voters: Ipsos poll. Retrieved from https://globalnews.ca/news/6006868/climate-change-federal-election-issue-poll/ Sinanaj, G., Muntermann, J., & Cziesla, T. (2015). How Data Breaches Ruin Firm Reputation on Social Media!-Insights from a Sentiment-based Event Study. Wirtschaftsinformatik, 902-916. Smith, A., & Rainie, L. (2010). 8% of online Americans use Twitter. Retrieved from https://www.pewresearch.org/internet/2010/12/09/8-of-online-americans-use-twitter/ Sorescu, A., Warren, N. L., & Ertekin, L. (2017). Event study methodology in the marketing literature: An overview. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 45(2), 186-207. Statistics Canada. (2015, November 27). Canadians and Nature: Environmental engagement, 2013. Retrieved from https://www150.statcan.gc.ca/n1/pub/16-508-x/16-508-x2015004-eng.htm Sunstein, C. (2007). Of Montreal and Kyoto: A Tale of Two Protocols. The Harvard Environmental Law Review, 31(1), 1-65. Retrieved March 14, 2019.

Page 112: REPUTATIONAL PUNISHMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL …€¦ · is accepted in its present form by the Department of Economics as satisfying the thesis requirements for the degree of Bachelor

96

Syed-Ahmad, S. F., & Murphy, J. (2010). Social networking as a marketing tool: the case of a small Australian company. Journal of Hospitality Marketing & Management, 19(7), 700-716. Takeda, F., & Tomozawa, T. (2008). A change in market responses to the environmental management ranking in Japan. Ecological Economics, 67(3), 465-472. The Canadian Press. (2018, November 14). Canadians produce three times more greenhouse gas emissions than G20 average. Retrieved from https://www.theglobeandmail.com/canada/article-canada-found-to-produce-most-greenhouse-gas-emissions-per-person-among/ The Economist. (2013, January 12). A world of trouble. Retrieved January 25, 2013, from http://www.economist.com/news/business/21569361-which-risks-loom-largest-businesses-2013-world-trouble Watson, S., & Arunachalam, R. (2018). Firms and Social Protection: An Event Study. Comparative Political Studies, 51(14), 1974-2021. Xu, X. D., Zeng, S. X., & Tam, C. M. (2012). Stock market’s reaction to disclosure of environmental violations: evidence from China. Journal of Business Ethics, 107(2), 227-237. Zerbe, P. M. (1996). Evaluation of predominant environmental management practices in the Canadian pulp and paper industry (Doctoral dissertation, University of British Columbia).