33
IFS public economics lectures David Sturrock 5 January 2018 Savings, pensions and retirement

Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    10

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

IFS public economics lectures David Sturrock 5 January 2018

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 2: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

The UK’s ageing population

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

1980

19

83

1986

19

89

1992

19

95

1998

20

01

2004

20

07

2010

20

13

2016

20

19

2022

20

25

2028

20

31

2034

20

37

2040

20

43

2046

20

49

2052

20

55

2058

20

61

2064

20

67

Year that turn 60

Life expectancy at 60

Savings, pensions and retirement

Source: ONS

Men Women

Page 3: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

The UK’s ageing population

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0.30

0.35

0.40

0.45

2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027 2029 2031 2033 2035 2037 2039 2041 2043 2045 2047 Year

Projected old-age dependency ratio

Savings, pensions and retirement

Source: ONS Note: Old age dependency ratio is calculated as the total projected population aged 65 and above divided by the total projected population aged 16-65.

Page 4: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 5: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

How will we cope? Is it really all that bad?

Big changes are taking place. These raise questions:

1. What does ageing mean for the sustainability of pensions systems?

2. How should the government respond?

3. Are people able to save enough and prepare for retirement?

4. Are today’s young people going to find it harder to provide for themselves in retirement than in previous generations?

Using UK data, but lessons apply in many advanced economies

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 6: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

State pensions and the challenge of demographics

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 7: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

State pension in the UK

1. State pension

• Paid at a fixed rate to everyone with sufficient years of eligible activities

• Around £120 per week for a single individual

• Eligible activities include paid work (leading to payment of National Insurance contributions) but also child caring, receipt of disability benefits and other activities.

• Paid out of current taxation (“Pay as you go”)

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 8: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

The economics of an ageing population

Increasing longevity makes “pay-as-you-go” systems less affordable

• Same number of people working to fund more pensioners for longer

For the state pension system, this requires one or more of:

• Increase in taxation for those working

• Increase in government debt (which means higher taxes or lower spending later)

• Reduction in generosity of state pensions:

‒ Pension paid at a lower rate

‒ Higher taxation of pension income

‒ Increase in the state pension age

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 9: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Government’s response to demographic challenges

Government has responded by reducing generosity of pensions:

• Move to “single tier” state pension: Elimination of earnings-related components of the state pension

• State pension age (SPA) increasing:

‒ SPA for both men and women will reach 66 in 2020

‒ Rise to 67 by 2028

‒ Rise to 68 recently brought forward to 2039

‒ Next review considering further rises will report by 2023

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 10: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Government’s response to demographic challenges

4.0%

4.5%

5.0%

5.5%

6.0%

6.5%

7.0%

7.5%

8.0%

2016

-17

2018

-19

2020

-21

2022

-23

2024

-25

2026

-27

2028

-29

2030

-31

2032

-33

2034

-35

2036

-37

2038

-39

2040

-41

2042

-43

2044

-45

2046

-47

2048

-49

2050

-51

2052

-53

2054

-55

2056

-57

2058

-59

2060

-61

2062

-63

2064

-65

2066

-67

Year

Projected state pension spending as a percentage of GDP

Central Only legislated changes to SPA No triple lock

Savings, pensions and retirement

Source: OBR Fiscal Sustainability Report

Page 11: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

How do individuals provide for their retirement?

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 12: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Employer and individual provided pensions

1. Employer provided pension

• Public sector: mostly defined benefit - pays an amount that depends on earnings according to some rule; pay-as-you-go

• Private sector defined benefit: becoming less common; fully funded.

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 13: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Employer and individual provided pensions

Savings, pensions and retirement

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

16 - 21 22 - 29 30 - 39 40 - 49 50 - 54 55 - 59 60 - 64 Age-group of employee

Percentage of employee jobs in a defined benefit pension scheme

1997

2016

Source: ONS

Page 14: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Employer and individual provided pensions

1. Employer provided pension

• Public sector: mostly defined benefit - pays an amount that depends on earnings according to some rule; pay-as-you-go

• Private sector defined benefit: becoming less common; fully funded.

• Private sector defined contribution: standard for new employees. Employee decides how much to contribute. Fully funded - pension depends on fund performance

2. Other private savings

• Personal pension

• Stocks and shares, ISAs, housing wealth

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 15: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Are we ready?

Individuals increasingly responsible for providing for own retirement

• Imagine a simple model with no uncertainty:

‒ Work for k years

‒ Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement)

‒ Earn income during working life and save for retirement

Individuals equate marginal utility of consumption over their life

Their savings are invested so assets back their pension

Savings, pensions and retirement

T

kt

r

t

tk

t

w

t

t cucu1

1

1

1 )()(U

Page 16: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Are we ready?

Is this simple model realistic? What about:

• Impatience

• Over-optimism or pessimism about the future

• Asymmetric information about risks to survival, health costs

• Difficulties understanding financial products or planning

We will look at 3 specific departures from the simple model:

• Impatience/procrastination (“present bias”)

• Uncertainty about mortality: the role of information asymmetries

• Uncertainty about mortality: the role of survival pessimism

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 17: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Impatience and procrastination

Individuals tend to give extra “weight” to today when making decisions – “present bias”

• Implication for behaviour depend on whether individuals realise their preferences will change tomorrow (“sophisticated”) or not (“naïve”)

• Naïvety implies that individuals suboptimally defer choices that are costly now and bring benefits in the future e.g. beginning to save

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 18: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Impatience and procrastination: policy

Policy response has been to automatically enrol workers into workplace pension scheme

• US analysed in Madrian and Shea (2001), Thaler and Benartzi (2004)

• In UK, Pensions Act (2005):

‒ Default contribution rate of 1% for both employer and employee

‒ Individuals can still choose to leave scheme if they wish

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 19: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Impatience and procrastination: policy

Workplace pension membership rates amongst private sector employees eligible for automatic enrolment by firm size in 2012

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 20: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Uncertainty about mortality

We don’t (usually!) know exactly when we are going to die

• What are the implications for saving and use of wealth in retirement?

• If individuals are risk averse then

‒ Precautionary saving

‒ Assets left over

‒ Consume less than they “could”

Uncertainty about length of retirement is a risk like any other – can be insured

• An annuity is a product which can be purchased with pension wealth and pays out a fixed income until time of death

• “Actuarially fair” annuity has price equal to its expected payout

• A risk-averse individual would want to buy a fairly priced annuity

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 21: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Uncertainty about mortality: asymmetric info

Asymmetric information can pose problems for annuities markets

• Insurers can tailor annuity rates based on what they know about individuals’ chances of living to different ages

• Individuals normally know more about their mortality than do insurers

• Those who don’t expect to live long will not purchase an annuity

Adverse selection

There is evidence that this drives behaviour and market outcomes (Finkelstein and Poterba, 2004)

• Individuals who bought annuities where payments were more “backloaded”, i.e. inflation linked, lived longer

• “Money’s worth” of these annuities was higher suggesting insurers take into account who is buying different products when setting price

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 22: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Uncertainty about mortality: survival pessimism

Discussion so far assumed that individuals’ expectations about how long they will live are not systematically biased

• How can we test this?

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 23: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Uncertainty about mortality: survival pessimism

Savings, pensions and retirement

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85

Prob

abili

ty s

urvi

ve to

at

leas

t tha

t age

Age of respondent

“Subjective” and “objective” survival expectations (women born 1930-39)

75 - subjective

75 - life table

80 - subjective

80 - life table

85 - subjective

85 - life table

90 - subjective

90 - life table

95 - subjective

95 - life table

Page 24: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Uncertainty about mortality: survival pessimism

Discussion so far assumed that individuals’ expectations about how long they will live are not systematically biased

• How can we test this?

Pessimism about survival up to 85/90 and optimism for oldest ages

• What does this mean for economic behaviour, particularly annuities?

• What do individuals perceive to be a “fair” annuity rate?

• Annuity rate is the rate at which can turn stock of wealth into guaranteed income

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 25: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Uncertainty about mortality: survival pessimism

Savings, pensions and retirement

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

8%

9%

10%

2% 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% 8% 9% 10%

“Sub

ject

ive”

ann

uity

rate

“Objective” annuity rate

Comparison of “subjective” and “objective” annuity rates

Page 26: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Uncertainty about mortality: policy

What does this all mean for policy?

• Until 2015, essentially compulsory to annuitise DC wealth in UK

• 2015 “Pensions freedoms” promised to give consumers more choice about use of wealth at retirement

• What consequences will this have?

Economics tells us there is a risk that annuities markets will unravel

• Cannon et al., (2016) estimate annuities demand fallen by 75% since policy change

• Coincided with low interest rates and other regulatory changes

• Might consumers be left unable to purchase products that they actually did want?

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 27: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Concluding thoughts: Where does this leave us?

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 28: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Do individuals save enough?

Most individuals currently reaching retirement can maintain income (Crawford and O’Dea, 2012)

Savings, pensions and retirement

retirement before income

incomepension wealth of valueannuitised ratet Replacemen

Page 29: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Do individuals save enough?

Savings, pensions and retirement

Distribution of replacement rates at state pension age (2008-09, aged 50-SPA)

Source: Crawford and O’Dea (2012)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

0 50 100 150 200

Perc

enta

ge o

f ind

ivid

uals

Replacement of total net family income (%)

State and private pensions

...plus annuitised non-pension wealth and housing

Page 30: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Do individuals save enough?

Most individuals currently reaching retirement can maintain income (Crawford and O’Dea, 2012)

But these generations saved in very different circumstances

• DB pensions much more common, and more generous in public sector

• House price growth

• Higher real interest rates than are expected in future

• More limited ability to draw down and spend pension wealth early

Younger generations already look to be building up less wealth than earlier cohorts had at same age

Savings, pensions and retirement

retirement before income

incomepension wealth of valueannuitised ratet Replacemen

Page 31: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Do individuals save enough?

Savings, pensions and retirement

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

500

25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60

£'00

0, 2

014-

15 p

rice

s

Median age of cohort

Wealth position of different cohorts by age

Pension wealth

Net financial wealth

Net property wealth

1970s

1960s

1980s

1950s

Source: Cribb, Hood and Joyce (2016)

Page 32: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Summary

Demographic change presents challenges

• Rising dependency ratio poses problems for sustainability of state pensions and defined benefit schemes

• The government is reacting by increasing the state pension age and firms increasingly offer defined contribution pension schemes

• Providing for retirement is increasingly the responsibility of individuals

Greater reliance on individual provision has its own challenges

• Accumulation: procrastination tackled with automatic enrolment

• Decumulation: adverse selection, survival pessimism raise questions

Important to monitor how younger generations are saving

• In addition to the challenges above, low interest rates and smaller amounts of housing wealth may make saving a greater challenge

Savings, pensions and retirement

Page 33: Savings, pensions and retirement · ‒Die after T years (so T-k years in retirement) ‒Earn income during working life and save for retirement t Individuals equate marginal utility

Further links

The adequacy of wealth amongst those approaching retirement (IFS)

https://www.ifs.org.uk/comms/r72.pdf

Economic circumstances of different generations (IFS):

https://www.ifs.org.uk/uploads/publications/bns/bn187.pdf

TED talk on “Save more tomorrow” (Shlomo Benartzi)

https://www.ted.com/talks/shlomo_benartzi_saving_more_tomorrow

Savings, pensions and retirement