65
Similarity in Bond Covenants* Gus De Franco Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto 105 St. George Street, Toronto, M5S 3E6, Canada [email protected] Florin P. Vasvari London Business School Regent’s Park, London, NW1 4SA, United Kingdom [email protected] Dushyantkumar Vyas Department of Management UTM & Rotman School of Management University of Toronto 105 St. George Street, Toronto, M5S 3E6, Canada [email protected] Regina Wittenberg-Moerman The University of Southern California 3660 Trousdale Parkway, Los Angeles, CA, USA [email protected] September, 2015 * We have benefited from the comments and suggestions of Phil Berger, Doug Diamond, Doug Skinner and seminar participants at Bocconi University, HEC Paris, London Business School, Tel-Aviv University, the University of Chicago, the University of Mannheim, the University of Miami, the University of Minnesota, the University of Southern California and the University of Toronto. We gratefully acknowledge the financial support of The Initiative on Global Markets at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, Rotman School of Management, the University of Toronto, Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota, the AXA Research Fund, and the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada. This paper was previously circulated under the title “Sticky Covenants.”

Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

Similarity in Bond Covenants*

Gus De Franco

Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto

105 St. George Street, Toronto, M5S 3E6, Canada

[email protected]

Florin P. Vasvari

London Business School

Regent’s Park, London, NW1 4SA, United Kingdom

[email protected]

Dushyantkumar Vyas

Department of Management – UTM & Rotman School of Management

University of Toronto

105 St. George Street, Toronto, M5S 3E6, Canada

[email protected]

Regina Wittenberg-Moerman

The University of Southern California

3660 Trousdale Parkway, Los Angeles, CA, USA

[email protected]

September, 2015

* We have benefited from the comments and suggestions of Phil Berger, Doug Diamond, Doug Skinner

and seminar participants at Bocconi University, HEC Paris, London Business School, Tel-Aviv

University, the University of Chicago, the University of Mannheim, the University of Miami, the

University of Minnesota, the University of Southern California and the University of Toronto. We

gratefully acknowledge the financial support of The Initiative on Global Markets at the University of

Chicago Booth School of Business, Rotman School of Management, the University of Toronto, Carlson

School of Management, University of Minnesota, the AXA Research Fund, and the Social Sciences and

Humanities Research Council of Canada. This paper was previously circulated under the title “Sticky

Covenants.”

Page 2: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

Similarity in Bond Covenants

Abstract

We examine the economic consequences associated with the inclusion of covenants with

similar terms in bond contracts. Using a unique Moody’s dataset that provides credit

analysts’ views on the restrictiveness of covenant terms, we develop measures that

capture similarity in bond covenant terms by comparing the restrictiveness of a bond’s

covenants with the covenant restrictiveness of previously issued peer bonds. Consistent

with a similarity in covenants reducing contracting and comparability costs to

bondholders, we document that bonds with more similar covenant restrictiveness receive

significantly lower yields at issuance. These bonds are also characterized by greater

liquidity in the secondary market and are more likely to be held by long-term bond

investors, such as insurance companies. Our results highlight an important trade-off

between the contracting and comparability costs of changing the restrictiveness of bond

covenants and the monitoring benefits provided by a more tailored set of bond covenants.

JEL classifications: G12, G14, G32, M49

Keywords: Bond Covenants, Covenant Restrictiveness, Similarity, Primary

Bond Prices, Secondary Bond Liquidity.

Page 3: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

1

1. Introduction

Bondholders demand mainly event risk covenants (or “incurrence-based” covenants) that

restrict aggressive investments, asset sales, additional borrowings, excessive payments of

dividends, stock repurchases or distributions to junior debtholders. Although the terms of these

covenants display a high degree of similarity relative to previously issued bonds, as the corporate

law literature highlights (e.g., Kahan and Klausner 1993; Bratton 2006; Choi and Triantis 2012),

the economic determinants and consequences of this similarity have not been explored. Because

covenants are one of the primary contractual mechanisms employed by bond holders to protect

their wealth, in this paper we examine similarity in the restrictiveness (strength) of covenant

terms.

We hypothesize that bondholders will prefer the restrictiveness of a bond’s covenants to

be similar to that of previously issued peer bonds to avoid the significant costs associated with

modifying covenant specifications. One important set of such costs is the contracting cost, which

is caused by the need to spend more time and effort assessing how the amended covenants

protect bondholders’ wealth (e.g., Kahan and Klausner 1993, 1997; Bratton 2006; Wood 2011;

Choi and Triantis 2012). This cost is also the result of the greater litigation risk that arises from

new covenant restrictiveness terms. Because the diffused ownership of bond securities leads to

high contract renegotiation costs when covenants are breached, bondholders typically prefer

restrictiveness terms that have been previously interpreted, scrutinized and enforced by the

courts (Choi and Triantis 2012). Further, less similar (i.e., more unique) covenant terms lead to

higher comparability costs. In contrast to commonly used restrictiveness terms, new terms cannot

be benchmarked to the terms of previously issued bonds, leading to a loss of comparability. Less

comparability relative to other bonds in the market increases the information processing costs for

Page 4: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

2

bond investors as they need to exert more effort to evaluate the extent to which new covenant

specifications protect against credit risk and affect bond pricing (Kahan and Klausner, 1997).

Nonetheless, while similar bond covenants may provide savings with respect to

contractual and comparability costs, they could also increase bondholders’ risk by being less

effective in monitoring idiosyncratic agency problems specific to a particular borrower.

Consequently, because bond covenants protect against firm managers’ opportunistic actions on

behalf of shareholders, bond investors may prefer less similar (or more tailored) covenant

structures. We thus examine whether more similar covenant restrictiveness terms in new bond

contracts provide net benefits or costs to bondholders, as reflected in the bonds’ issuance yields.

In our tests, we employ a measure of covenant restrictiveness developed by Moody’s that

is available through the Moody’s Covenant Assessment database. Moody’s credit analysts

summarize the principal strengths and structural gaps in the protection provided by individual

bond covenants based on a detailed analysis of the covenants’ specifications. The typical

specification of each bond covenant begins with a prohibitory section that establishes the scope

of the restrictions. This section is followed by a provision, labeled proviso, which allows for an

exception to the restrictions in the prohibitory section, usually subject to conditions such as a

financial ratio test. The last section in the covenant specification presents the carve-outs, which

are additional exceptions to the prohibitory paragraph that are not required to satisfy the

proviso’s conditions. The proviso and the carve-out terms may significantly dilute a covenant’s

ability to protect bondholders. Each term used in the bond contract section that describes the

covenants, including the financial accounting terms and the ratios used, has an extensive

definition in a glossary, which varies across issues and sometimes across different covenants in

the same issue. Moody’s analysts use their market experience to assess a bond covenant’s

Page 5: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

3

restrictiveness based on the comprehensiveness of the restrictions in the prohibitory section, the

strictness of contractual terms’ definitions (e.g., whether the financial ratio definitions provide

scope for managerial discretion), the flexibility in the financial ratios in the proviso section, and

the extent to which covenants provide both qualitative and quantitative carve-outs.

To measure covenant similarity, we compare the restrictiveness of a bond’s covenants, as

assessed by Moody’s analysts, to the restrictiveness of the respective covenants of bonds issued

by peer firms in the last 12 months. Because this restrictiveness measure captures the strength of

protection provided by each individual covenant, variation in this measure allows us to more

precisely capture the similarity in covenant restrictiveness than would a comparison between the

existence of a covenant in a bond contract and the existence of a covenant in a peer firm’s bond.

A firm is considered a peer if it is in the same sector and has similar credit risk (i.e., investment

or speculative grade rating category) as the firm under consideration. Our sample consists of 996

bonds for which we can estimate the relative similarity of bond covenant restrictiveness using the

Moody’s database. These bonds are issued by U.S. firms over the period from 2000 to 2009.

We start by investigating the determinants of similarity in bond covenants’

restrictiveness. We document that when a firm uses the same legal counsel as its peer companies,

covenant similarity is greater. In terms of economic significance, two bonds that are issued by

the same legal counsel have covenant similarity scores that are greater by approximately a one-

third standard deviation than the covenant similarity scores across two bonds that do not share

legal counsel. This result supports arguments in the corporate law literature that debt market

intermediaries contribute to the standardization and rigidity of debt contractual terms (Kahan and

Klausner 1993, 1997; Choi and Triantis 2012). We test but do not find evidence that covenant

similarity is greater if firms share the same underwriter with their peers, suggesting that

Page 6: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

4

underwriters exhibit greater flexibility in adapting to new covenant terms relative to legal

advisers. We also find that firms with more comparable characteristics, such as size and

tangibility, have more similar covenants, consistent with the notion that firms with more similar

agency problems have more similar covenant structures.

In our primary analyses, we find that similarity in covenant restrictiveness is associated

with significantly lower bond yields at issuance. A one-standard-deviation increase in the

similarity of bond covenants’ restrictiveness to that of peer bonds is associated with a reduction

in bond spreads of 0.12% (or 5.7% of the mean spread in our sample). Given the average

principal value and maturity of our sample bonds, this effect translates into approximately $4

million in interest savings over the life of the bond issue. The negative association between

covenant similarity and bond yields at issuance is robust to the use of an instrumental variable

approach that accounts for the potential endogeneity of covenant terms with respect to bond

yields. Our findings suggest that, ceteris paribus, bond investors view positively covenant

restrictiveness terms that are more similar to the terms in previously issued bonds, as such terms

potentially contribute to lower contracting costs. Similar covenant restrictiveness terms also

increase comparability across different bonds, lowering the information processing costs for

bond investors. We also provide evidence that the similarity across the most elaborate and

complex covenants in the bond contracts — the covenants restricting payments to shareholders,

borrowings, and transactions involving the firm’s assets — is driving the bond yield results.

These covenant specific results provide additional support for the conclusion that the contracting

and comparability costs of changing bond covenant restrictiveness terms potentially exceed the

credit risk protection benefits provided by a more tailored set of bond covenants.

In supplementary tests that aim to better understand how similarity in covenant terms

Page 7: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

5

affects bond yields, we investigate whether insurance companies, the largest bond investors in

the market, are more likely to own bonds with similar covenant restrictiveness. If a bond is

preferred by insurance companies, we expect this increased demand to lower its pricing. A

typical insurance company invests in a large number of bonds, usually holds them until maturity

with limited portfolio rebalancing and incurs capital penalties from regulators if the bonds

subsequently underperform. Therefore, it is likely to prefer bonds whose terms, along with the

expected level of credit protection, are comparable and involve predictable litigation risks.

Consistent with this conjecture, we find that bonds with more similar covenant restrictiveness

terms are characterized by a higher level of insurance company ownership in the quarter

following the bond’s issuance. In terms of economic significance, a one-standard-deviation

increase in similarity increases the share of the bonds absorbed by insurance companies by

2.96% (or 5.5% of the sample average of 53.9%). This finding reinforces the idea that covenant

similarity decreases the contracting and comparability costs incurred by bond investors.

We next investigate whether similarity in covenants’ restrictiveness terms is associated

with greater bond liquidity in the secondary market during the period immediately following a

bond’s issuance. We expect higher secondary market liquidity to provide a further partial

explanation for lower bond yields because investors demand illiquidity premiums when pricing

bonds (e.g., Chen, Lesmond and Wei 2006; Mahanti et al. 2008). We document that bonds with

more similar covenant restrictiveness relative to peers are indeed traded more often and to a

greater extent. In terms of economic significance, a one-standard-deviation increase in the

similarity of covenant restrictiveness is associated with a 6% increase in the mean bond trading

volume and a 19% increase in the mean number of transactions in our sample. Like the insurance

holdings results above, these bond trading results are consistent with the notion that covenant

Page 8: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

6

similarity decreases investors’ information processing costs in the secondary bond market.

In the final set of supplementary analyses, we develop a time-series-based measure of

similarity in covenant restrictiveness by comparing the restrictiveness of a bond’s covenants with

that in bonds previously issued by the same firm. The economic trade-offs we investigate using

our main similarity measure—reducing contracting and comparability costs versus receiving less

customized credit protection—are also valid for time-series covenant similarity. Our ‘time-

series-based’ sample consists of 845 bonds for which we can estimate the similarity relative to

previous bond issues. We replicate our main determinants and yield tests using this time-series-

based measure and find robust results, strengthening the inferences from our main findings.

Our study contributes to the literature on covenant structure in debt contracts across

several dimensions. First, the extant prior literature has explored covenant structure primarily by

investigating the determinants of specific covenants and the number of covenants included in

debt agreements or the tightness of covenants in private loan contracts (e.g., Dichev and Skinner,

2002; Bradley and Roberts, 2004; Christensen and Nikolaev 2012; Chava and Roberts, 2008;

Drucker and Puri, 2009; Demerjian, 2011; Chava, Kumar and Warga 2010; Murfin 2012; Li et

al. 2015). Our study differs from and complements this other work by focusing on the important

role of a novel covenant characteristic, the similarity in covenant restrictiveness across different

bond issues. In particular, we find that similarity in covenant restrictiveness brings significant

economic benefits to the issuing firms, such as lower bond yields, greater secondary bond market

liquidity and greater interest from long-term investors such as insurance companies. The analysis

of insurance companies’ bond ownership is relatively unique given that there is very limited

evidence on how bond contract characteristics affect the investor base of bond securities at the

time of their issuance.

Page 9: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

7

Second, the prior literature motivates bond covenants primarily from the agency theory

perspective (e.g., Jensen and Meckling 1976; Myers 1977; Smith and Warner 1979; Masulis

1980; Dichev and Skinner 2002). To the best of our knowledge, our paper is the first to focus on

non-agency-based explanations for bond covenant structure (i.e., the contracting and

comparability costs associated with changes in covenant structure).1 More specifically, we

provide new evidence that emphasizes the importance of the economic trade-off between the

costs of changing the restrictiveness of bond covenants due to contracting and comparability and

the benefits arising from the higher credit protection provided by a tailored covenant structure.

Our findings that the costs associated with modifying covenant structures may outweigh the

benefits of a more tailored covenant structure suggest that the costs of modifying covenants may

be substantially larger than what the prior literature presumes.

Last, to the best of our knowledge, our study is also the first to describe the detailed

specification of bond covenants and to consider the strictness and comprehensiveness of

covenant terms when measuring the strength of bond covenants’ protection. Prior studies focused

on the inclusion of individual covenants in bond contracts or indices that count the number of

bond covenants (Malitz 1986; Begley 1994; Kahan and Yermack 1998; Nash, Netter and Poulsen

2003; Billett, King and Mauer 2007; Chava, Kumar and Warga 2010). Although prior literature

has advanced in exploring the specific terms of covenant structure in private loan agreements

(e.g., Beatty et al. 2008; Li 2012; Li et al. 2015), there is little evidence on how covenants are

structured in public bond indentures. We document the multifaceted structure of bond covenants

and highlight that the inclusion of individual covenants or the covenant count measures

1 Although the incomplete contracting theory provides additional explanations for the determinants of covenant

structure (e.g., Grossman and Hart 1986; Hart and Moore 1988; Aghion and Bolton 1992), it relates primarily to the

financial covenants used in private debt agreements (e.g., Christensen et al. 2015).

Page 10: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

8

employed by prior studies may not appropriately capture the strength of bond covenants’

protection, given that covenants may include a weak prohibitory section or allow significant

exceptions to the restrictions they impose.

The next section develops our research question and reviews the related literature.

Section 3 describes our data and the measurement of covenant similarity. Section 4 presents an

analysis of the determinants of covenant similarity. It also discusses our primary tests and the

results of the consequences of covenant similarity in terms of yield spreads. Section 5 provides a

supplementary analysis of the additional consequences—secondary market liquidity and

insurance companies’ holdings—of covenant similarity. Our analysis using the time-series-based

measure of covenant similarity is in Section 6. Section 7 concludes.

2. Background and Hypotheses Development

2.1. Background on Bond Covenants

A bond’s covenant package is the primary contractual instrument available to

bondholders for protecting the value of their investment in the borrowing firm. The presence of

covenants mitigates the conflicts of interest between bondholders and equity holders by

preventing excessively risky activities, limiting cash flow diversions to equity holders and

preserving the relative priority of debtholders’ claims (e.g., Jensen and Meckling 1976; Myers

1977; Smith and Warner 1979; Aghion and Bolton 1992; Haugen and Senbet 1988). While

covenants provide credit protection benefits to bondholders, they also need to be flexible enough

to allow borrowers to efficiently run their financial, investment and operational activities during

the term of the bond. If bond covenants are not sufficiently flexible, they are likely to be violated

even if the borrower is financially healthy, leading to significant losses for bondholders.2

2 For instance, Grossman et al. (1997) find that the recovery rates on subordinated bonds that default is around 40%.

The low bond recovery rates in liquidation proceedings are mainly due to the presence of senior bank claims.

Page 11: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

9

Bond issuances typically involve a large number of investors with limited incentives to

monitor the borrower on a continuous basis (Diamond 1984; Ramakrishnan and Thakor 1984).

The dispersion of these investors leads to high coordination costs and free riding incentives that

make renegotiations with borrowers in default extremely difficult and costly (Gertner and

Scharfstein 1991; Bolton and Scharfstein 1996). Consequently, bond investors prefer to use

relatively easy-to-monitor “incurrence-based” covenants that restrict specific investment and

financing activities of the bond issuers (e.g., restrictions on issuing more debt, distributing cash

to shareholders, selling assets, engaging in mergers and acquisitions, lending to subsidiaries).

Issuers only have to comply with these covenants if they proactively intend to take an action that

might break them. In contrast to bank lenders, bondholders do not typically include

“maintenance” (financial) covenants, which require the issuer to comply with specified financial

ratios on a regular basis.3 While these covenants could provide “early warning signals” about

credit risk changes, if they are breached when the issuer’s financial condition is not significantly

worsening, bondholders will find it costly to agree, on short notice, to covenant renegotiations.4

Bond contracts include three major groups of “incurrence-based” covenants that control

conflicts of interest between bondholders and equity holders. The first group restricts cash

distributions to shareholders via dividend payments or share repurchases. These covenants limit

outright expropriation as cash disbursements leave fewer assets to protect bondholders’ claims.

Retained cash can instead be made available to service the debt.5 The second group of covenants

3 Covenant packages in loan agreements include both maintenance and incurrence-based covenants. The relatively

small number of lenders in bank syndicates, high individual bank exposure, and the fact that these lenders operate

under reputational constraints, facilitate renegotiations of the loan agreements. Thus, bank lenders set maintenance

covenants tightly, triggering violations that allow ongoing loan renegotiations (Dichev and Skinner 2002; Chava and

Roberts 2008; Roberts and Sufi 2009; Nini, Smith and Sufi 2009, 2012; Roberts 2014). 4Although bondholders are represented by a trustee, its role is largely administrative. The bond trustee does not have

a fiduciary duty and cannot materially renegotiate a bond indenture on behalf of the bondholders. 5 These covenants can also help to resolve the managers’ incentives to under invest in growth opportunities (Myers

1977; Kalay 1982).

Page 12: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

10

places limits on additional borrowing and the issuance of certain types of debt (e.g., secured or

senior debt). These covenants prevent an increase in default risk, which is associated with higher

leverage, ensuring that borrowers have the capacity to service their current debt obligations and

limit the dilution of bondholders’ claims generated by the issuance of debt that is equal to or

more senior than the bond. The third group restricts borrowers’ investment/divestment activities,

ranging from prohibitions on certain types of transactions, such as mergers, acquisitions or

sale/leasebacks, to restrictions on the disposition of assets, particularly at prices less than their

equivalent value. These covenants are designed to protect bondholders from transactions that

substitute less risky assets for riskier ones (Jensen and Meckling 1976; Galai and Masulis 1976).6

Covenants that restrict investments also mitigate shareholders’ incentives to overinvest in

negative present value projects instead of paying down the debt.

All bond covenants discussed above are “negative” covenants because they prohibit the

issuer from certain actions.7 The specification of each negative covenant in the bond contract

almost always begins with a prohibitory section that establishes the scope of the restrictions. For

example, the covenant might state that the issuer will not incur any additional indebtedness. The

prohibitory paragraph is typically followed by a provision section, labeled proviso, which allows

for an exception to the restriction in the prohibitory paragraph if certain conditions are met, such

as passing a financial ratio test. Continuing the previous example, the proviso could state that the

issuer can incur additional indebtedness if the consolidated fixed charge coverage ratio (CFCCR)

computed after the additional debt is taken remains above a specific threshold, such as 2:1. The

6 Some of these transactions often compound the risk by using excessive leverage to finance the purchase of risky

assets. For example, Asquith and Wizman (1990) and Warga and Welch (1993) provide evidence concerning the

negative effects on bondholder wealth that occurred during the leveraged buyout wave of the 1980s. 7 One covenant exception that requires affirmative action is the requirement for periodic financial reports. This

requirement ensures a steady flow of readily accessible information to current and prospective bondholders and is

present in almost all bonds in our sample.

Page 13: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

11

last section in the specification of the bond covenant presents a set of carve-outs, which are

exceptions to the prohibitory paragraph in addition to the financial ratio exception set out in the

proviso. For instance, a typical carve-out for the covenant above is to allow the firm to issue

bank debt. Another common carve-out is to allow the firm to issue public debt with a face value

that is lower than a certain percentage of its consolidated tangible assets. The proviso and the

carve-outs have the potential to significantly dilute a covenant’s ability to protect bondholders

from wealth expropriation by equity holders or lenders with more senior claims to bondholders.

The descriptions of bond covenants’ terms and conditions in the bond contract are

extensive and, based on our reading of bond indentures, often span more than 20 pages. We

measure the restrictiveness of the covenants’ terms by relying on the views of Moody’s credit

analysts. Moody’s analysts critically review covenants’ terms and summarize the principal

protections and structural gaps of each individual covenant in a bond contract (Moody’s 2010).

For instance, to gauge the level of protection offered by a covenant that limits additional debt

issuance for a particular bond issue, Moody’s analysts evaluate a variety of qualitative and

quantitative factors, such as current credit market conditions, the financial condition of the

borrower and the actual specification of the covenant’s terms.

When assessing the terms of a covenant that sets limits on additional borrowings,

Moody’s analysts first pay attention to the definition of the financial ratios in the proviso. As

such, they negatively view covenants whose EBITDA definition allows add-backs of non-cash

charges and other items that give management the discretion to adjust the ratio in order to issue

more debt. For example, the assessment of the quality of the debt incurrence covenant in the

bond indenture of Atlas Pipeline Partners from February 2009 emphasizes that “certain

undefined terms such as ‘non-recurring items’ and ‘non-cash items’ give discretion to the issuer

Page 14: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

12

in determining the presumptive cash flow under the covenant.”

Second, Moody’s analysts consider the headroom of the financial ratio in the proviso (the

difference between the ratio’s threshold and the ratio at the time of bond issuance). Third,

Moody’s analysts evaluate whether the carve-outs attached to the covenant are limited or

extensive. As examples, we summarize the headroom estimation and carve-out assessments for

the additional borrowing restriction covenant in the bond indentures of Meritage Homes

Corporation from October 2008 and K. Hovnanian Enterprises, Inc., from October 2007.

Appendix A provides the detailed calculations. Meritage Homes Corporation’s indenture

specifies that only one of the two financial ratios in the proviso section, either the CFCCR or the

consolidated net worth ratio, needs to be met. Under the first ratio test, the headroom is negative,

as the CFCCR of 0.52 at the time of bond issuance is below the ratio’s threshold of 2. This

negative headroom indicates that the firm cannot issue additional debt under the CFCCR test.

However, the consolidated net worth ratio test reveals sizeable positive headroom that allows

Meritage Homes Corporation substantial flexibility in issuing additional debt. Moody’s analysts

indicate that this flexibility significantly reduces the protection that the debt incurrence covenant

provides to bondholders. In contrast, for the Hovnanian Enterprises, Inc.’s indenture, there is

only one financial ratio test, CFCCR, which is set relatively tight (i.e., the headroom is relatively

low). Thus, the protection provided by the debt incurrence covenant is substantially enhanced.

The carve-outs of the Meritage Homes Corporation’s indenture are extensive and allow

the company to issue an additional $505.7M of debt (relative to consolidated total assets of

$1,619.8M), while still meeting the CFCCR or the consolidated net worth ratio tests in the

proviso section. For K. Hovnanian Enterprises, Inc., the carve-out allows the issuance of only

$60M of additional debt (relative to consolidated total assets of $5,363M), while still meeting the

Page 15: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

13

CFCCR test, which further contributes to the strength of the covenant.

The measurement of covenant restrictiveness in public debt contracts and the extent to

which certain levels of covenant restrictiveness are common across firms have not yet received

any attention in the literature, mainly because of the difficulty in assessing the terms of

incurrence-based bond covenants. Prior empirical work has measured covenant restrictiveness by

relying on the total number of covenants or the presence of specific individual covenants (Billett,

King and Mauer 2007; Chava, Kumar and Warga 2010). However, an index that counts the

number of covenants or the presence of a covenant cannot fully capture the true level of the

covenant protection provided to bond investors. As illustrated above, bond contracts may include

poorly specified covenants (e.g., covenants with loose financial ratio definitions) or those with

substantial exceptions that render them ineffective. Hence, an evaluation of the covenant

restrictiveness and the comparative analysis of covenant structures across different bonds and

over time require a detailed examination of the covenants’ specifications.8

2.2. Consequences of Bond Covenants’ Similarity

We argue that bondholders will prefer bonds with covenant restrictiveness terms that are

similar to the restrictiveness terms of other bonds that were previously issued by a borrower’s

peers because more unique covenants could lead to higher costs of contracting and

comparability. The corporate law literature contends that parties involved in bond issuance

contribute to the rigidity of bond contractual terms because they incur high costs when

modifying these terms (e.g., Kahan and Klausner 1993, 1997; Bratton 2006; Wood 2011; Choi

8 A number of studies examine the covenant restrictiveness of syndicated loans by assessing the slack in financial

covenants (Dichev and Skinner 2002; Beatty and Weber 2006; Chava and Roberts 2008; Drucker and Puri 2009;

Demiroglu and James 2010; Murfin 2012). However, the slack can only be estimated with significant measurement

error due to the fact that lenders often make substantial adjustments to GAAP numbers when defining covenant

thresholds (Leftwich 1983; Dichev and Skinner 2002; Beatty et al. 2008; Li 2012). These adjustments also vary

across both different covenants in the same loan contract and different loan contracts. Further complicating the slack

estimation, financial covenant thresholds frequently change over the life of the loan (Li, Vasvari and Wittenberg-

Moerman 2015).

Page 16: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

14

and Triantis 2012). Changes in bonds’ terms relative to terms that are widely used are likely to

involve additional time and effort because bondholders, especially those that have experience

with prior bonds, will need to understand and assess the implications of these adjustments.

An additional contracting cost of deviating from commonly used covenant restrictiveness

terms is the higher expected cost of litigating future disputes. Bond investors might be reluctant

to risk investing in bonds whose terms depart from contractual provisions that have been

previously interpreted, scrutinized and enforced by the courts (Choi and Triantis 2012).9 Judicial

opinions on prior commonly used covenants reduce uncertainty regarding the validity and

meaning of their covenant restrictiveness terms and the interaction of these terms with relevant

requirements in corporate, securities, and bankruptcy laws. This concern is particularly important

to bond investors, given that the diffused ownership of a bond security leads to high bond

contract renegotiation costs when covenants are breached.

In addition to inducing higher contracting costs, covenant restrictiveness terms that deviate

from common covenant specifications may significantly limit bond investors’ ability to compare

different bond securities. Kahan and Klausner (1997) argue that, by facilitating comparisons with

other bond issues, the use of common contractual terms reduces both the information collection

and processing costs that investors incur when evaluating a firm’s bond indentures. More

generally, studies such as De Franco, Kothari, and Verdi (2011) argue that the availability of

comparable information lowers the cost of acquiring information and increases the overall

quantity and quality of available information. Better comparable information allows investors to

exert less time and effort. In the primary bond market, familiar covenant terms in the bond

offering prospectus are likely to allow bond investors to quickly assess the risks relative to other

9 For example, in a series of cases, courts have clarified how an indenture clause should be worded in order to

subordinate the claims of junior creditors to unsecured senior creditors' claims for interest accrued after a bankruptcy

petition is filed (Kahan and Klausner 1997).

Page 17: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

15

bond investments and decide whether and how much to invest in a new bond issue. In the

secondary market, for similar reasons, we expect these information processing efficiencies to

increase bond liquidity.10

Common covenant restrictiveness terms also facilitate more reliable

and comparable credit ratings across different bond issues since rating agencies use standardized

credit models that may fail to capture significant deviations in covenants’ terms (e.g., Benmelech

and Dlugosz 2009; Bozanic, Loumioti and Vasvari 2015). As a result, the ratings will provide

more relevant information to bond investors making investment decisions when covenant

restrictiveness terms are in line with previous bond issues.

We hypothesize that if bondholders save on these contracting and comparability costs when

the covenant restrictiveness terms of a new bond issue are more similar to those of the previous

bonds, then these cost savings will be reflected, at least partially, in lower bond yields. Our

prediction is motivated by the fact that more bond investors are likely to be attracted to bonds

with familiar terms. The competition generated by this larger set of investors increases the

demand for these bonds and lowers their pricing.

We note, however, that our empirical prediction regarding the impact of covenant

similarity on bond yields is not straightforward. To more effectively deal with borrower specific

agency problems, bond investors might prefer that a new bond issue include covenants tailored

to the borrower’s financial and operating condition. Such covenant terms may bring substantial

benefits to bondholders that offset the higher contracting costs of modifying covenant

specifications and the larger information collection costs triggered by the lower comparability of

tailored covenants. For instance, if the firm is operating in a volatile environment, a more

idiosyncratic covenant package can help preserve operating flexibility and avoid inefficient and

10

As another example, Benmelech and Dlugosz (2009) study the collateralized loan obligation (CLO) market and

observe significant uniformity in CLO structures, as investors demand. They suggest that uniformity reduces the

amount of time investors must spend analyzing new deals.

Page 18: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

16

bond-value-destroying defaults. Similarly, if the firm’s financial condition contributes to a more

pronounced debt-equity-holder conflict of interest, a set of customized covenants terms that

deviate from the covenant terms used in the prior bonds of firms that do not face similar conflicts

is likely to be more effective in protecting bond investors’ interests. In sum, these arguments

suggest that more similar covenant restrictiveness terms could lead to higher bond yields if

bondholders are concerned that similar covenants may not provide effective protection against

firm specific agency problems.

3. Measurement of Similarity in Covenant Restrictiveness

In this section, we discuss how we measure the restrictiveness of covenant terms and how

we validate this measurement process. We then describe our measure of similarity in covenant

restrictiveness, our primary variable of interest.

3.1. Covenant Restrictiveness

We capture the restrictiveness of bond covenants using a novel dataset of individual bond

covenants’ assessments by Moody’s covenant analysts. Moody’s Covenant Quality Assessment

(CQA) service evaluates the covenant restrictiveness of each new bond issue, with the aim of

helping institutional investors make better investment decisions. Moody’s covenant analysts

assess eight key bond covenants that fit into the three covenant groups we discussed in Section

2.1. In the group that restricts distributions to shareholders, Moody’s includes restrictions on

payments to shareholders and other parties (Restricted Payments). In the group that limits

additional borrowing and the issuance of certain types of debt, Moody’s includes: restrictions on

debt issuance, reclassifications or retirement through asset sales (Debt Incurrence), restrictions

on debt issuance, reclassifications or retirement by any subsidiaries (Subsidiary Debt Incurrence)

and restrictions on the issuances of pledges to secure other subordinated debt (Liens). Finally, in

Page 19: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

17

the group that restricts risky investment activities, Moody’s includes: restrictions on the sale of

assets (Asset Sales), restrictions on sale and leaseback transactions (Sale/Leaseback), restrictions

on mergers or asset conveyance (Mergers) and restrictions on changes in the ownership of the

issuer (Change of Control). In Appendix B, we define these covenants and provide a discussion

of how Moody’s assesses the quality of each. Depending on the level of protection provided, the

Moody’s CQA individual covenant scores receive values of 0 (does not exist), 1 (minimal

protection), 2 (moderate protection), or 3 (strong protection).

Since the measurement of covenant restrictiveness for bond contracts is a complex

exercise and involves subjective judgments, it is important to establish the validity of Moody’s

CQA scores.11

First, to help establish internal validity, in untabulated analyses we document a

strong correlation between carve-outs (an objective numerical measure) and CQA scores for a

subsample of covenants assessed by Moody’s for which we have both covenant quality scores

and quantitative information on carve-outs (i.e., the ratio of the carve-out amounts to total

assets). This test is conducted at both the individual covenant level and a combined level across

the three covenants in which there are significant carve-outs. The pairwise Pearson correlation

coefficients between the CQA scores and carve-outs for payment restrictions, debt restrictions,

investment restrictions, and at the combined level are -0.39, -0.58, -0.33 and -0.49, respectively

(all are significant at the 1% level). This negative correlation indicates that, as expected, greater

carve-out amounts lead to weaker covenant protection scores.

Second, to help establish external validity, in untabulated analyses we compare Moody’s

CQA scores to similar covenant quality scores provided by Xtract Research LLC, who also

11

Moody’s initiated the CQA database in 2006. Moody’s evaluated the covenant restrictiveness of bond securities

issued prior to 2006 and still outstanding as well as of those issued after 2006. Because the majority of bonds in our

research sample are issued prior to the initiation of CQA, it is unlikely that the covenant restrictiveness terms are set

in order to meet Moody’s covenant strictness standards.

Page 20: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

18

assess covenant quality for speculative grade bonds. We match 328 bonds from these two

datasets and observe a strong positive correlation between the covenant quality assessments

provided by these two independent firms. As Xtract has only two categories, weak and normal,

we convert our Moody’s CQA scores to a binary score, using the median value of Covenant

Restrictiveness by rating category. We find that the scores of Moody’s and Xtract correspond to

each other in 79.6 % of cases (i.e., either both scores are weak or both scores are normal).

Finally, we establish additional construct validity by regressing Covenant Restrictiveness

on firm characteristics that prior research suggests are associated with debt covenants (e.g.,

Costello and Wittenberg-Moerman 2011; Christensen and Nikolaev 2012). Not surprisingly, we

find that covenant restrictiveness increases with firm credit riskiness: firm size and asset

tangibility are negatively related to covenant restrictiveness, while financial leverage is

positively related to covenant restrictiveness (untabulated). Further imparting construct validity

to the measure, we observe that covenant restrictiveness is lower (higher) for bonds that are rated

in the investment grade (high yield) category.

3.2. Measurement of Covenant Similarity

To measure the similarity of covenant restrictiveness, we compare the restrictiveness of a

firm’s bond covenants to the restrictiveness of a peer firm’s bond covenants. Relative to the

simple comparison of the existence of a covenant for a firm’s bond with the existence of a

covenant for its peer firm’s bonds, our approach of comparing covenant restrictiveness, a more

granular measure of covenant strength, should better capture the underlying construct of

similarity in covenant terms.

We develop the variable Covenant Similarity as follows. The measure is computed for

each firm i – peer j pair of bonds. A bond issue is included as a peer if it was issued over the past

Page 21: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

19

12 months by a firm in the same sector and the same rating category (i.e., investment grade or

high yield) as those of the firm. The choice of peer is based on the idea that firms with similar

economic characteristics should have similar covenant structures. Bonds with no peer issues are

excluded from the analysis. For each of the eight covenants in the database, we take the absolute

difference of firm i’s and peer j’s bond covenant scores. For example, if both firm i’s bond and

its peer’s bond have identical covenant scores, the absolute difference is 0. If the firm’s bond has

a covenant score of 3 and the peer’s bond score is 1 (or vice versa) then the absolute difference is

2. This difference is calculated for each of the eight covenants and then the eight differences are

added up to create an aggregate absolute difference. This implicitly weights each covenant

difference equally. Last, we multiply the aggregated difference by -1, so that higher values

represent greater covenant similarity. To create a single firm i-level covenant similarity measure,

we take the mean of the scores across the firm i's – peer j's bonds for all peer issues of firm i.

This firm i-level variable, Covenant Similarity, is the primary measure used in our analysis of the

determinants of covenant similarity as well as the effects of covenant similarity on bond spreads.

The Moody’s CQA database covers 3,075 bonds issued during the 2000 – 2009 period.

After conditioning the sample on bonds issued by U.S. borrowers and those that require the

availability of the bond- and firm-level control variables used in our tests, we obtain an

underlying sample of 1,727 bond issues. Using these bond issues, we create the Covenant

Similarity values for a sample of 943 bond i observations for which we can obtain a peer that

meets the criteria discussed above. Table 1 summarizes the sample selection process.

4. Main Results

4.1. Descriptive Statistics

We provide descriptive statistics for the main variables used in our tests in Table 2. Panel

Page 22: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

20

A presents our similarity-based variables at the bond i level. The overall covenant similarity

score indicates an on-average dissimilarity of 0.36 per covenant (= -2.842 total/8 covenants) for a

bond and its cross-sectional peers. In other words, the average dissimilarity per covenant is

approximately 1/10th

of the theoretical maximum possible dissimilarity of 3 (i.e., an extreme

situation where a bond has been assigned a covenant restrictiveness of 3 by Moody’s, whereas its

peers have been assigned a score of zero, or vice versa). We also notice that, on average, 12%

and 15% of the bonds are issued by the same legal counsel and underwriter, respectively. Panel

B presents the results of the firm and bond characteristics at the bond i level. The average bond

issue has about five covenants, a maturity of 13 years, and an offering amount of $587 million.

The average yield spread is 2.2%. Sample firms have a mean leverage ratio of 28% and

tangibility ratio of 74%.

In Panel C, we investigate the similarity in each individual covenant to determine which

covenants explain the overall covenant similarity score to a greater extent. The panel presents the

distribution of covenant similarity scores, which range from 0 to 3. For example, in the first row,

for covenant similarity calculated versus peer j’s bonds, in 11% of observations the covenant

restrictiveness is the same as the firm’s peers across all eight covenants. Concentrating on the

individual covenants, we notice that leaseback, change of control covenants, and liens are

relatively more dissimilar compared with the other covenants. For instance, in 30% of

observations the leaseback covenant restrictiveness is identical to that of its peers. In contrast, for

asset sales, mergers, payment, and debt restrictions, in over 80% of observations the firm’s

covenant restrictiveness is identical to that of its peers. The fact that a large proportion of the

covenants have the same level of restrictiveness as the covenants of previously issued bonds is

consistent with the ideas of debt contract rigidity (e.g., Bratton 2006; Kahan and Klausner 1993).

Page 23: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

21

4.2. Determinants of Similarity in Covenant Restrictiveness

4.2.1. Tests. We start our analysis by examining the determinants of the covenant

restrictiveness similarity with respect to firm’s peers. Changes of covenant terms from prior bond

issues require legal advisors to spend more time reviewing, discussing and approving the new

terms. Given the institutional features of the legal profession such as hourly billing, additional

legal time translates into higher legal fees for the borrowing firms. Underwriters should also

prefer to have similar terms, all else equal. For example, if an underwriter needs to place a bond

issue with covenant restrictiveness terms that are different from those used in previously issued

bonds, the underwriter would need to spend additional time drafting the new covenants and

explaining them to investors. Given that legal counsels and underwriters would incur additional

costs for writing the debt contract if they were to draft different covenant terms for a new bond,

we expect that covenant restrictiveness similarity will be higher if a bond and its peers share the

same legal counsel or underwriter. We also expect that covenants’ restrictiveness will be more

similar when bond issuers face similar agency problems (i.e., the borrower and the peers have

similar characteristics). To investigate these predictions, we estimate the following regression:

Covenant Similarity = 0 +1 Similar Legal Counsel +2 Similar Underwriter

+ 3 Similar Firm Characteristics + 4 Firm Characteristics

+ 5 Bond Characteristics + 6 Lender Power + .

(1)

The first two independent variables capture the effect of external advisers on the

similarity in covenant restrictiveness. Similar Legal Counsel is first measured at the bond i-peer j

level. It is an indicator variable that captures whether the firm’s bond and its peers’ bonds are

advised by the same legal counsel, zero otherwise. To create the firm i-level variable, we take the

mean of the scores across the firm i-peer j bonds for all peers of firm i. The variable Similar

Underwriter is created analogously. We first assign it the value one at the bond i-peer j level if

Page 24: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

22

the bonds share the same lead underwriter, and then we take the mean of these indicator

variables to calculate our firm i-level value. A positive coefficient on either variable is consistent

with corporate law literature predictions that debt market intermediaries contribute to the

standardization and rigidity of debt contractual terms (Kahan and Klausner 1993, 1997; Choi and

Triantis 2012).

As indicated above, covenant similarity is likely to be driven by the similarity of firms’

characteristics. Although we choose peers based on similar economic fundamentals (same sector

and same rating category and close in time to the bond issue), we further control for economic

similarity not captured by our choice of peers along the dimensions of firm size, tangibility,

leverage, and interest coverage. These differences are calculated between each firm i-peer j pair

of companies, and then we take the mean of these absolute differences and multiply by -1, so that

these measures capture similarity in firm fundamentals. We expect all these similarity variables

to obtain a positive coefficient, consistent with more similarity across firm characteristics being

positively associated with a higher similarity in covenant restrictiveness.

We also control for firm and bond characteristics associated with a borrower’s credit

riskiness and agency cost of debt. These variables are measured simply at the firm or bond level

and as such we do not have specific predictions for their coefficients, given that our variable of

interest is the similarity in covenant restrictiveness. (Untabulated analyses indicate that our

results are not sensitive to their exclusion.) Firm Characteristics include the firm’s size,

tangibility, leverage and interest coverage. Our Bond Characteristics include the time to

maturity, the principal amount of the bond offering, the number of covenants and whether the

debt is rated investment grade by at least one of the three major credit rating agencies. Last, we

control for Lender Power, which is an indicator variable for the years of tight credit supply as

Page 25: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

23

proxied by the financial crisis period. During periods of a tight credit supply, bond investors are

likely to have stronger bargaining power and can therefore influence covenant structure to a

greater extent. We do not have a specific prediction for the Lender Power coefficient because

bond holders can benefit from both lower contracting and comparability costs via more similar

covenant restrictiveness as well as from stronger protection via more tailored (i.e., less similar)

covenants. For a more detailed description of these and other variables used in our tests, see

Appendix C. For all our tests, we cluster the standard errors at the firm level.

4.2.2. Results. We present the analysis of determinants of the similarity in bond covenant

restrictiveness in Table 3. Columns 1 to 3 present the results of estimating equation 1. We start

by examining the effect of debt market agents—legal counsel and underwriters—on covenant

similarity. In column 1, we exclude Similar Legal Counsel while column 2 excludes Similar

Underwriter. In column 3, we include both variables. As the results are similar across columns,

we focus on the column 3 results. The coefficient on Similar Legal Counsel is 0.975 and is

statistically significant (t-statistic = 2.25), consistent with firms who share the same legal

advisers having more similar covenant structures. In terms of economic significance, two bonds

that are issued by the same legal counsel have covenant similarity scores that are approximately

one-third standard deviation greater than covenant similarity scores across two bonds that do not

share the same legal counsel. We do not, however, find evidence that covenant structures are

more similar for two firms sharing the same lead underwriter. This evidence is consistent with

the notion that underwriters exhibit greater flexibility in adapting to new covenant terms relative

to legal advisers. In terms of similarity in firm characteristics, we provide evidence that similar

fundamentals (and hence potentially similar debt agency conflicts) lead to similar covenants. The

Similar Size and Similar Tangibility coefficients are both positive and statistically significant.

Page 26: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

24

For the other control variables, we observe that covenant restrictiveness is less similar for

bonds with larger offering amounts. We surmise that since large bonds have a higher credit risk

and face more significant agency conflicts, bondholders are more likely to demand idiosyncratic

protection features, decreasing the similarity of the covenant restrictiveness terms. Further, large

bond issues are likely to be purchased by a more diverse group of investors, each with different

protection needs and levels of exposure that potentially contribute to more dissimilarity in the

restrictiveness of the covenant structures. Also, if the costs of adjusting the covenants are mainly

fixed, then these costs may be relatively less economically important for larger offering amounts.

Covenant structures are also more similar for firms with investment grade bonds. These bonds

tend to have lower levels of covenant restrictiveness in general and hence less opportunity to

differ between bonds. Investment grade bonds are also less risky, which may further decrease

bondholders’ demand for idiosyncratic protection terms.

As a robustness test, in column 4, we estimate the same specification but instead of at the

firm i level with one observation per bond, we estimate the specification at the bond i-peer j

level, with one observation for each bond i-peer j pair of bond issues. This increases the total

number of observations in the test to 7,308. We continue, however, to cluster the standard errors

at the firm level. The advantage of this specification is that we maximize the variation in the

measurement of our similarity variables, as opposed to the specification in column 1 where we

average the similarity scores for each bond issue. Inferences from this specification for the most

part mirror those in column 1. The coefficient on Similar Legal Counsel is positive and

statistically significant, consistent with firms who share the same legal adviser having similar

covenant structures. Similarity in firm size, tangibility and leverage is positively related to

covenant similarity. As in column one, bonds with larger offering amounts have less similar and

Page 27: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

25

investment grade bonds have more similar covenant restrictiveness.

Overall, as expected, we find that bond covenant restrictiveness is more similar relative

to covenant restrictiveness in peer firms’ bond contracts when the same legal advisors are used

and when firm characteristics are more similar. This latter result suggests that when firms have

similar agency conflicts the covenant structures are more similar.

4.3. Covenant Similarity Consequences: Yield Spread

4.3.1. Tests. To determine whether similarity in covenant restrictiveness has significant

economic consequences, we examine the implications of the covenant similarity with respect to

the pricing of the bonds in the primary market. We estimate the following regression:

Spread = 0 +1 Covenant Similarity +2 Market Spread

+ 3 Firm Characteristics + 4 Bond Characteristics + .

(2)

Spread is the difference between offering yield of the bond issue minus the yield on the Treasury

bill with the closest maturity, obtained from Mergent FISD. The average yield spread is 2.2%.

This relatively tight spread is indicative of the predominance of investment grade bonds in our

sample. Our variable of interest is Covenant Similarity. We expect that greater covenant

similarity should be negatively associated with bond spreads if more similar covenant

restrictiveness provides net benefits to bondholders. Market Spread is the mean spread by rating

category for a particular quarter when the bond was issued, where the rating spectrum is divided

into four broad rating categories (i.e., AAA to Aaa2, Aa3 to A2, A3 to Baa2, and Baa3 to D). It

controls for market-wide fluctuations in spreads driven by macroeconomic factors as well as

differences in spreads that capture credit risk premiums across rating categories. Our firm

characteristics and bond characteristics include the same variables as in the previous test.

We estimate model 2 in two ways. Our first estimation uses OLS. We acknowledge the

difficulties in isolating the effect of similarity in covenants’ restrictiveness on yields due to the

Page 28: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

26

potential endogeneity in the relation between covenant terms and bond pricing (e.g., Smith and

Warner 1979; Bradley and Roberts 2004; Costello and Wittenberg-Moerman 2011). To address

this concern, we employ an instrumental variable (IV) approach. This approach is based on the

simultaneous estimation of the covenant similarity determinants model (equation 1) and the

model of covenant similarity consequences (equation 2). To instrument covenant similarity, we

rely on Similar Legal Counsel, which reflects whether the bond and its peer bonds are issued by

the same legal advisor. In terms of strength and validity of the first stage, we find that Shea’s

Partial R2 for the first stage is relatively high at 32.17%. Further, we find that the Cragg and

Donald (1993) minimum eigenvalue statistic of 57.66 exceeds the most conservative Stock and

Yogo (2005) 5%-relative-bias critical value of 20.25, thereby rejecting the null hypothesis of a

weak instrument. As we report in column 1 of Table 3, this variable is a significant determinant

of covenant similarity. We do not expect this variable to be directly related to bond yields, as

there is no obvious reason to expect a strong association between the bond yield and the fact that

the legal advisor of the bond issue is the same as the advisor of the bonds of the peer firms.

4.3.2. Results. Table 4, Panel A, present the results of estimating equation 2. Column 1

presents the OLS results. Consistent with our predictions, we find that covenant similarity is

negatively related to bond spreads. The coefficient on Covenant Similarity is -0.046 with a t-

statistic of -2.86. In other words, a one-standard-deviation increase in the similarity of covenants’

restrictiveness is associated with a 0.12% reduction in the spreads (or 5.7% of the mean spread in

our sample). Given that the average bond issue in our sample has a principal value of $412

million and an average maturity of 8.27 years, the effect translates into savings for the borrower

of approximately $4 million over the life of the bond issue. This result indicates that similarity in

covenant restrictiveness leads to positive economic consequences for firms in terms of a reduced

Page 29: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

27

cost of debt. In column 2, we present the 2SLS results. We notice a slightly reduced sample in

this test compared with OLS due to additional Compustat data requirements for peer firms to

calculate the first-stage bond covenant similarity scores. The results largely parallel the OLS

results. The variables that load in the OLS specification have comparable coefficients and

magnitudes of statistical significance in the 2SLS specification. In particular, the coefficient on

Covenant Similarity is -0.066 with a t-statistic of -2.33, consistent with a negative relation

between covenant restrictiveness similarity and bond spreads.

In terms of control variables, as expected, Market Spread is positively correlated with the

bonds’ Spread. We also observe that spreads are negatively related to tangibility and interest

coverage, but positively related to the bond’s maturity. These results are generally consistent

with prior research on debt pricing (e.g., Booth 1992; Beatty et al. 2002; Bharath et al. 2008;

Zhang 2008). Note that we do not find a significant relation between the yield and some other

firm-level characteristics. This is due to our control for market spread by rating category, which

subsumes the effect of firm characteristics on spread to the extent that these characteristics are

reflected in the rating. As support for this assertion, untabulated tests demonstrate that these firm

characteristics load in the expected direction if Market Spread is excluded from the specification.

4.3.3. Robustness. We perform a series of robustness tests that are presented in Panel B of

Table 4. Our equation 2 results that covenant similarity leads to reduced yield spreads are robust

to each of the following tests. First, firm i-level observations will vary in the number of peers

used to calculate Covenant Similarity. In column 1, we augment our test with the number of

peers. Second, in column two, we control for the level of covenant restrictiveness to make sure

that it, instead of the similarity in covenant restrictiveness, is not driving our result.12

Third,

12

Although we would expect stronger covenant protection to reduce debt pricing, empirical studies typically find an

insignificant coefficient on the variable reflecting the number of covenants or covenant restrictiveness in the debt

Page 30: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

28

when calculating the aggregate covenant similarity, instead of weighing each covenant equally,

in column 3 we weigh each covenant based on the covenant importance suggested by Moody’s

(2013) and by our conversation with a Moody’s analyst.13

In additional untabulated analyses, we

also verify that the results reported in all three columns of Panel B are not affected by potential

endogeneity between yield and similarity in covenant restrictiveness. We repeat all analyses by

estimating 2SLS specification and find that the results are unchanged.

4.3.4. Tests by Individual Covenant. To provide further validity to the impact of covenant

similarity on bond spreads, in the next set of analyses we examine the effect of the similarity in

each individual covenant versus the bonds issued by peers. If covenant similarity is important

with respect to contracting and comparability costs, we should observe that an effect on yield

would also hold at the individual covenant level, especially for particularly complex covenants.

We re-estimate the regression in equation 2 using the similarity of each covenant. That is, we

replace the aggregate covenant similarity variable with a particular individual covenant similarity

value. All other independent and the dependent variables remain the same.

Table 5 provides the results from each regression by covenant. We find that of the eight

covenants, all coefficients on Covenant Similarity are negative as expected and four of them are

statistically significant. The consequences of covenant similarity are driven by the covenants that

pertain to payment restrictions, debt, liens and asset sales, suggesting that bondholders care about

similarity in different types of covenants, ranging from cash distribution to indebtedness and

capital expenditures. Three of these four covenants — the restrictions on payments, additional

pricing regressions (e.g., Bradley and Roberts, 2004) An insignificant coefficient on these covenant measures is

likely to be attributed to the endogenous relationship between debt pricing and the strength of covenant protection

(Costello and Wittenberg-Moerman 2011). 13

Our re-weighted measure uses the following weights for each covenant type: payment restrictions (25%), debt

incurrence (25%), change of control (5%), merger restrictions (5%), liens restrictions (20%), asset sales restrictions

(5%), leaseback restrictions (5%) and limits on subsidiary debt (10%).

Page 31: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

29

debt and asset transactions — have the most complex specification and terms based on our

analysis of a random sample of 30 bond prospectuses. For example, for payment restrictions, the

terms of these covenants are at least 1000 words in length and reach 2700 words (on average).

Moody’s analysts also consider these covenants to be relatively more important than the others

(Moody’s 2013). Therefore, this evidence provides further support for our proposition that

covenant similarity potentially helps bond market participants save on information acquisition

and processing costs.

5. Additional Consequences of Covenant Similarity

In this section, we provide complementary analyses of how covenant similarity could

lead to reduced bond yields at issuance. In particular, we expect the effect of higher contracting

and the comparability costs associated with changes in covenant restrictiveness to also manifest

in the holdings of insurance companies and secondary trading. We expect these analyses to

reinforce our prediction that covenant similarity has important economic consequences.

5.1. Insurance Company Holdings

We analyze whether the presence of covenants with similar terms is associated with

higher bond ownership by insurance companies who are important long-term investors in the

corporate bond market. Schultz (2001) estimates that insurance companies collectively hold up

to 40% of U.S. investment grade corporate bonds. Becker and Ivashina (2014) also show that

insurance companies are the largest institutional holder of corporate and foreign bonds, with

bond holdings that in 2010 were $2.3 trillion more than those of mutual and pension funds

combined.14

Further, over 90% of insurance companies’ holdings are in fixed income securities

(Nissim 2010). If a bond attracts insurance companies, we expect this increased demand for the

14

Bessembinder, Maxwell and Venkataraman (2006) find that insurance companies are responsible for a significant

percentage of trading volume. Using data from TRACE during the second half of 2002, they document that

insurance companies have completed about 12.5% of the dollar trading volume.

Page 32: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

30

security to significantly lower its pricing.

Insurance companies invest in a large number of bonds and hold them until maturity with

limited portfolio rebalancing. They also potentially incur capital penalties from regulators if the

bonds subsequently underperform. Given the significant and long-term investments being made,

insurance companies are likely to prefer bonds whose terms, along with the expected level of

credit protection, are comparable and involve predictable litigation risks. As a result, we expect

that they will be more likely to invest in bond issues with more similar covenants. To test this

notion, we use our peer-based sample to estimate the following regression:

Insurance Holdings = 0 + 1 Covenant Similarity + 2 Market Insurance Holdings

+ 3 Firm Characteristics + 4 Bond Characteristics + .

(3)

Insurance Holdings is the ratio of the par value of a bond held by insurance companies to the

total par value held by institutional investors in the quarter following the issuance of the bond.

We focus on the first quarter after bond issuance because as a bond becomes more seasoned, it

becomes less liquid, because inactive investors progressively absorb the original bond issue in

their portfolio and trading becomes thinner (Warga 1992). Untabulated analyses show that our

results are robust to the use of horizons of up to 12 months. Market Insurance Holdings is

measured analogously to the market-wide control variables in equation 2. Our firm and bond

characteristics remain the same as in previous tests.

We obtain bond ownership information from the National Association of Insurance

Commissioners (NAIC) starting from 2001 and match this data with bond specific data in the

Mergent Fixed Income Securities Database (Mergent FISD). NAIC provides detailed

information on every bond holding for each insurer at the end of each year and every bond

transaction that occurred in that year for each insurer. This dataset allows us to compute the

percentage of ownership by insurance firms in a particular bond following its issuance.

Page 33: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

31

Descriptive statistics in Table 2 indicate that more than half of the par value of the bond is

typically owned by insurance companies during the quarter immediately after the issuance.

Column 1 of Table 6 presents the results of estimating equation 3 using OLS. The

Covenant Similarity coefficient is 0.011 and is statistically significant (t-statistic = 3.27). The

results are economically significant: a one-standard-deviation increase in similarity increases the

share of the bonds absorbed by insurance companies by 2.96% (or 5.5% of the sample average of

53.9%). This result supports our prediction that insurance companies prefer to invest in bonds

with covenant restrictiveness that is more easily comparable to the covenant restrictiveness of

peer bonds. This evidence is consistent with lower contracting and comparability costs incurred

by insurance companies when investing in bonds with similar covenant restrictiveness terms.

With respect to the control variables, in addition to the market-based variable of insurance

holdings, which is loading positively, insurance holdings are negatively related to firm size, the

number of covenants and the offering amount, and positively related to interest coverage and

bond’s time to maturity. Column 2 of Table 6 provides the 2SLS results, which are very similar

to the column 1 OLS results and produce comparable inferences.

Overall, the evidence indicates that when covenant restrictiveness is more similar to the

covenant restrictiveness in peer firms’ bonds, long-term investors such as insurance firms are

more likely to invest in bonds with these covenants. This finding provides a partial explanation

for our results that bond issuance yields are lower for bonds with more similar covenants.

5.2. Trading

If similarity in covenant restrictiveness eases the effort exerted by investors in

understanding the nuances of a bond contract, we would also expect it to reduce investors’

information processing costs. Hence, we predict that covenant restrictiveness similarity is

Page 34: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

32

positively associated with the extent of bond trading and secondary market liquidity. Evidence

consistent with this prediction provides a further partial explanation for lower spreads because

greater liquidity should decrease expected illiquidity premiums and lead to lower yields at

issuance (e.g., Chen, Lesmond and Wei 2006; Mahanti et al. 2008).

To test this idea, we use our peer-based sample to estimate the following regression:

Trading = 0 +1 Covenant Similarity +2 Market Trading

+ 3 Firm Characteristics + 4 Bond Characteristics + .

(4)

Trading consists of two variables, Volume and Transactions, measured using bond trading data

provided by the Trade Reporting and Compliance Engine (TRACE) and NAIC.15

Volume is the

logarithm of the trading volume in the 30 days following the bond issuance, while Transactions

is the logarithm of the number of transactions over this period. We focus on a 30-day period

because the bonds are absorbed promptly into the portfolios of buy-and-hold large institutional

investors (e.g., insurance companies and pension funds) and do not trade (Warga 1992).16 The

average total volume traded during the 30-day period immediately after the issuance of a bond in

our sample is high: it reaches $263 million, which represents approximately 173 transactions.

We expect that increased covenant similarity is positively associated with bond trading. Market

Trading is measured analogously to the market-wide control variables in equation 2. When the

dependent variable is Volume, Market Trading is the mean trading volume by rating category for

a particular quarter, and it controls for market-wide fluctuations in trading volume as well as

differences in volume across rating categories. When the dependent variable is Transactions,

then Market Trading is defined analogously but by using trading transactions instead of volume.

15

TRACE did not cover all bonds trading in the secondary market until February 2005. As a result, we add bond

transaction data from NAIC, which is provided by the Mergent FISD database. If on a certain day, a bond issue does

not have any trades reported in TRACE but Mergent FISD indicates that a trade occurred, we include the Mergent

FISD trade information in our tests. 16

Our results are robust to shorter periods, such as 14 days.

Page 35: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

33

Our firm and bond characteristics remain the same as in previous tests.

The results are presented in Table 7. The first two columns present the results when

Volume is the dependent variable, and the second two columns provide results when the

dependent variable is Transactions. The first and third columns are OLS, while the second and

fourth columns are 2SLS. The results are highly consistent across all columns, so for parsimony

we discuss the first and third column results. Covenant Similarity is positively related to Trading,

as hypothesized. The Covenant Similarity coefficient is 0.291 and statistically significant, albeit

at more modest levels (t-statistic = 1.75). In terms of economic significance, a one-standard-

deviation increase in similarity is associated with an increase in Volume of 0.796 (or 6% of the

average volume in our sample). Economic significance is much higher when trading is measured

as number of transactions, with a one-standard-deviation increase in similarity being associated

with an increase in Transactions that is 19% of the mean. As expected, Market Trading is a very

important determinant of firm-level trading. In terms of other control variables, bond trading is

greater for the bonds of firms that are larger and have lower leverage and those of larger

amounts, consistent with findings in the prior literature on bond liquidity (Chen, Lesmond and

Wei 2006; Mahanti et al. 2008).

In sum, our results show that more similar bonds are associated with higher trading,

likely due to low information acquisition and comparability costs. Consistent with bond investors

pricing secondary market liquidity, this increased liquidity provides a partial explanation for our

results that bonds with more similar covenants have lower bond yields at issuance.

6. Time-Series Covenant Similarity

While our primary tests are based on similarity to the bonds of peers, we also develop a

time-series-based measure of similarity in the covenant restrictiveness over time for a given firm.

Page 36: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

34

The economic trade-offs we investigate in the above tests—reducing contracting and

comparability costs versus receiving less customized credit protection—are also valid for time-

series covenant similarity. On one hand, bondholders may benefit from lower information

collection and processing costs as well as higher comparability when the covenant restrictiveness

in the current bond is similar to that in a firm’s previously issued bonds with which bondholders

are already familiar. On the other hand, changes in firm fundamentals may encourage

bondholders to demand adjustments to covenant restrictiveness of the new bond issues.

We replicate our primary analyses of the determinants of covenant similarity and yield

spread tests using the time-series measure of similarity in covenant restrictiveness in Table 8.

Our time-series measure is calculated analogously to the peers’ covenant similarity measure

above, except that instead of comparing a bond to one issued by a peer firm, it is compared with

one issued by the same firm during the five years prior to the bond issue under consideration.

The five-year period allows for sufficient time to pass and increases the chances of the firm

having issued more than one bond over the period. For these tests, the other similarity

variables—Similar Legal Counsel, Similar Underwriter and Similar Firm Characteristics—are

calculated in an analogous manner to the time-series-based dependent variable. For example,

Similar Legal Counsel is an indicator variable that indicates whether the firm’s current and

previous bonds are advised by the same legal counsel, zero otherwise. Likewise, when we

calculate Similar Firm Size, the difference between the firm’s size when it issued the bond versus

its size when it issued the previous bond. The absolute difference is then multiplied by -1 to

capture similarity in covenant restrictiveness. Other Similar Firm Characteristics are calculated

the same way. Our expectations about the relationships between covenant similarity and its

determinants, as well as yield spread, remain unchanged. Our sample consists of 845 bond i

Page 37: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

35

observations for the yield tests in which the firm has issued a previous bond that meets our

criteria. Data requirements for the construction of the time-series-peers-based similarity measure

yield a slightly smaller sample than that used for the cross-sectional peers-based tests.

Panel A of Table 8 provides some descriptive statistics for the time-series similarity

variables. The average covenant similarity of -0.768 calculated using time-series comparisons

with the firm’s previously issued bonds is close to four times higher than the average covenant

similarity calculated using cross-sectional peers of -2.842 (from Table 2). The overall covenant

time-series similarity score indicates an on-average dissimilarity of only 0.10 per covenant

(= -0.768 total/8 covenants) for a bond. In other words, covenants are “sticky” with respect to

bonds previously issued by the same firm compared to bonds issued by its peers. Sticky covenant

quality is likely to reflect sticky firm fundamentals. Similarly, we see significant time-series

stickiness in the choice of legal counsels and underwriters for bonds issued by the same firm. On

average, 47% and 20% of the bonds are issued by the same legal counsel and underwriter

respectively. As expected, the closeness in firm characteristics based on comparisons with the

same firm when it issued its previous bonds reflects higher similarity than when it is measured

against its peers (from Table 2).

Panel B provides the results of our determinants test, which focuses on factors that

explain the time-series-based measure of similarity in covenant restrictiveness. This time-series

specification is comparable to that of equation 1 except that the similarity variables, as described

above, are time-series-based. Our Panel B results provide further validating evidence, as the

inferences from these tests are highly comparable to those in our main determinants test in Table

3. The positive and statistically significant coefficient on Similar Legal Counsel shows that if the

firm used the same legal counsel for its previous bond issue, then the covenant restrictiveness of

Page 38: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

36

the current bond is more similar to that of the firm’s previous bond. For the other control

variables, results are also generally consistent with the Table 3 results.

We next conduct the analysis of spreads using the time-series-based Covenant Similarity

measure. Except for this variable, all other independent and dependent variables remain the same

as those in equation 2. Panel C of Table 8 presents the results using our time-series version of

Covenant Similarity. The first column is based on OLS. The second column is based on 2SLS.

Across the two regressions, both coefficients on Covenant Similarity are negative and

statistically significant, as expected. In terms of economic significance, based on the coefficient

on Covenant Similarity in column 1, a one-standard-deviation increase in time-series similarity is

associated with a 0.24% reduction in spread (or 11% of the mean spread in our sample). This

result is consistent with (and slightly stronger than) the main yield spread test in Table 4.

Therefore, similarity in covenant restrictiveness over time also provides firms with a reduced

cost of debt. Overall, these tests using time-series covenant similarity provide results that are

parallel to those using our main measure of covenant similarity, reinforcing our main findings.

In untabulated robustness analyses, we examine whether the similarity in covenant

restrictiveness relative to that of covenants in bonds previously issued by the same firm is

partially due to bond shelf registrations under Rule 415 (SEC 1982). Shelf registrations permit

firms to file a single all-encompassing registration statement over a period of up to three years,

as opposed to individual registration statements for every security offering. While the covenant

structure is not part of the shelf registration prospectus, it is possible that bonds issued under the

same prospectus are more likely to have similar covenant restrictiveness. We control for this

effect by augmenting our Panel C test with a dichotomous variable that indicates whether the

bonds are issued within a span of three years from each other, which proxies for bonds issued

Page 39: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

37

under Rule 415. Our results and inferences are robust to controlling for this variable.

7. Conclusion

We investigate the factors affecting the similarity of covenant restrictiveness terms across

bond issues and examine whether it is priced in the bonds’ yields to maturity at issuance. While

tailored and less similar bond covenants are potentially more effective in monitoring a borrower,

bondholders might prefer similar covenant terms to mitigate contractual and comparability costs.

These costs are generated when covenant terms are modified relative to the terms used in peers’

previously issued bonds.

Using a measure of covenant restrictiveness developed by Moody’s, which highlights the

principal strengths and structural gaps in the protection provided by individual bond covenants,

we show that covenant similarity is greater when bond issuers share the same legal counsel. We

also find that firms with similar economic features and business models have similar covenant

structures. In our primary set of analyses, we document that similarity in covenant restrictiveness

is associated with significantly lower bond yields at issuance, suggesting that bond investors

view more similar covenant terms positively, as such terms potentially lower contracting and

comparability costs across different bonds. Additional tests show that bonds with similar

covenant restrictiveness terms are characterized by a higher level of bond ownership by long-

term bond investors, such as insurance companies, and that for these bonds the secondary market

bond liquidity is greater following the bond’s issuance. These latter findings provide a partial

explanation for the lower bond issuance yields.

Our findings add to the literature on the covenant structure in debt contracts. We

highlight the important role of the similarity of covenant restrictiveness terms across different

bond issues. We show that similarity in covenant restrictiveness have significant economic

Page 40: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

38

consequences for both bondholders and issuing firms, such as lower bond yields, greater

secondary bond market liquidity and greater interest from long term investors such as insurance

companies. We also emphasize non-agency-based explanations for the bond covenant structure.

In particular, we show that the contracting and comparability costs of changing covenant

restrictiveness terms may exceed the credit risk protection benefits that more tailored covenants

provide. We also offer new evidence on the multifaceted structure of bond covenants and the

comprehensiveness of the protection they offer. We thus extend studies on public bond

agreements that have focused on the inclusion of individual covenants in bond contracts or

indices that count the number of bond covenants, which are unlikely to accurately capture the

strength of bond covenant protection.

Page 41: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

39

References

Aghion, P., and P. Bolton, 1992. An incomplete contracts approach to financial contracting. Review of

Economic Studies 59: 473–94.

Asquith, P., and T. Wizman, 1990. Event risk, covenants, and bondholder returns in leveraged buyouts.

Journal of Financial Economics 27: 195–213.

Beatty, A., K. Ramesh, and J. Weber, 2002. The importance of accounting changes in debt contracts: The

cost of flexibility in covenant calculations. Journal of Accounting and Economics 33: 205–227.

Beatty, A., and J. Weber, 2006. Accounting discretion in fair value estimates: An examination of SFAS

142 goodwill impairments. Journal of Accounting Research 44: 257–288.

Beatty, A., J. Weber, and J. Yu, 2008. Conservatism and debt. Journal of Accounting and Economics 45:

154–174.

Becker, B., and V. Ivashina, 2014. Reaching for yield in the bond market. Forthcoming in Journal of

Finance.

Begley, J., 1994. Restrictive covenants included in public debt agreements: An empirical investigation.

Unpublished Manuscript, University of British Columbia.

Benmelech, E., and J. Dlugosz, 2009. The alchemy of CDO credit ratings. Journal of Monetary

Economics 56: 617–634.

Bessembinder, H., W. F. Maxwell, and K. Venkataraman, 2006. Market transparency, liquidity

externalities, and institutional trading costs in corporate bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 82:

251–288.

Bharath, S.T., J. Sunder, S. Sunder, 2008. Accounting quality and debt contracting. The Accounting

Review 83: 1–28.

Billett, M., T. King, and D. Mauer, 2007. Bondholder wealth effects in mergers and acquisitions: New

evidence from 1980s and 1990s. Journal of Finance 59: 107–135.

Bolton, P., and D. Scharfstein, 1996. Optimal debt structure and the number of creditors. Journal of

Political Economy 104: 1–25.

Booth, J.R., 1992. Contract costs, bank loans, and the cross-monitoring hypothesis. Journal of Financial

Economics 31: 25-41.

Bozanic, Z., M. Loumioti and F. Vasvari, 2015. Corporate loan securitization and the standardization of

financial covenants. Working Paper.

Bradley, M., and M. Roberts, 2004. The structure and pricing of corporate debt covenants, Working

Paper.

Bratton, W., 2006. Bond covenants and creditor protection: Economics and law, theory and practice,

substance and process. Georgetown Business, Economics and Regulatory Law Research Paper No.

902910.

Chava, S., P. Kumar, and A. Warga, 2010. Managerial agency and bond covenants. Review of Financial

Studies 23: 1120–1148.

Chava, S., and M. R. Roberts, 2008. How does financing impact investment? The role of debt covenants.

Journal of Finance 63: 2085–121.

Chen, L., D.A. Lesmond, J. Wei, 2006. Corporate yield spreads and bond liquidity. Journal of Finance 62

(1): 119–149.

Choi, A., and G. Triantis, 2012. Market conditions and contract design: Variations in debt covenants and

collateral. Working Paper, NYU Law School.

Christensen, H., and V. Nikolaev, 2012. Capital versus performance covenants in debt contracts. Journal

of Accounting Research 50: 75–116.

Christensen, H., V. Nikolaev, and R. Wittenberg-Moerman, 2015. Accounting information in financial

contracting: The incomplete contract theory perspective. Working Paper.

Page 42: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

40

Costello, A., and R. Wittenberg Moerman, 2011. The impact of financial reporting quality on debt

contracting: Evidence from internal control weakness reports. Journal of Accounting Research 49:

97–136.

Cragg, J.G. and S.G. Donald, 1993. Testing identifiability and specification in instrumental variable

models. Econometric Theory 9: 222 – 240.

De Franco, G., S.P. Kothari, and R. Verdi, 2011. The benefits of financial statement comparability.

Journal of Accounting Research 49 (4): 895–931.

Demerjian, P.R., 2011. Accounting standards and debt covenants: Has the ‘balance sheet approach’ led to

a decline in the use of balance sheet covenants? Journal of Accounting and Economics 52 (2–3):

178–202.

Demiroglu, C., and C. James, 2010. The information content of bank loan covenants. Review of Financial

Studies 23: 3700–37.

Diamond, D., 1984. Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. Review of Economic Studies 51:

393–414.

Dichev, I. D., and D. J. Skinner, 2002. Large-sample evidence on the debt covenant hypothesis. Journal of

Accounting Research 40: 1091–123.

Drucker, S., and M. Puri, 2009. On loan sales, loan contracting, and lending relationships. Review of

Financial Studies 22: 2835–2872.

Fitch Ratings, 2007. U.S. Leveraged Loan Covenant Decline Accelerating in 2007. June 20th.

Galai, D., and R. Masulis, 1976. The option pricing model and the risk factor of stock. Journal of

Financial Economics 3: 53–81.

Gertner, R., and D. Scharfstein, 1991. A theory of workouts and the effects of reorganization law. Journal

of Finance 46: 1189–1222.

Grossman, R. J., Brennan, W. T., Wento, J. 1997. Syndicated bank loan recovery study. Fitch Research.

Haugen, R., and L. W. Senbet, 1988. Bankruptcy and agency costs: Their significance to the theory of

optimal capital structure. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 23: 27–38.

Jensen, M., and W. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and

ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–360.

Kahan, M., and M. Klausner, 1993. Anti-takeover provisions in bonds: Bondholder protection or

management retrenchment? UCLA Law Review 40: 931.

Kahan, M., and M. Klausner, 1997. Standardization and innovation in corporate contracting (or ‘The

economics of boilerplate’). Virginia Law Review 83: 713–771.

Kahan, M., and D. Yermack, 1998. Investment opportunities and the design of debt securities. Journal of

Law, Economics, and Organization 14: 136–151.

Kalay, A., 1982, Stockholder–bondholder conflict and dividend constraints. Journal of Financial

Economics 10: 211–233.

Leftwich, R., 1983. Accounting information in private markets: Evidence from private lending

agreements. Accounting Review 58: 23–42.

Li, N., 2012. Performance measures in earnings-based financial covenants in debt contracts. Working

Paper, London Business School.

Li, N., F. Vasvari, and R. Wittenberg-Moerman, 2015. Dynamic threshold values in earnings-based

covenants. Forthcoming. Journal of Accounting and Economics.

Mahanti, S., A. Nashikkar, M. Subrahmanyam, G. Chacko, and G. Mallik, 2008. Latent liquidity: A new

measure of liquidity, with an application to corporate bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 88

(2): 272–98.

Malitz, I., 1986. On financial contracting: The determinants of bond covenants. Financial Management 15

(2): 18–25.

Page 43: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

41

Masulis, R. W., 1980. The effects of capital structure change on security prices: A study of exchange

offers, Journal of Financial Economics 8: 139–178.

Moody’s Investors Service, 2010. A User's Guide to Moody’s Covenant Quality Snapshots. September.

Moody’s Investors Service, 2013. User’s Guide: Moody’s High-Yield Covenant Database. February.

Murfin, J., 2012. The supply side determinants of loan contract strictness. Journal of Finance 67 (5):

1565–1601.

Myers, S. C., 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics 5: 147–75.

Nash, C. R., J. M. Netter, and A. B. Poulsen, 2003. Determinants of contractual relations between

shareholders and bondholders: Investment opportunities and restrictive covenants. Journal of

Corporate Finance 9: 201–232.

Nini, G., D. Smith, and A. Sufi, 2009. Creditor control rights and firm investment policy. Journal of

Financial Economics 92: 400–420.

Nini, G., D. C. Smith, and A. Sufi, 2012. Creditor control rights, corporate governance, and firm value.

Review of Financial Studies 25: 1713-1761.

Nissim, D., 2010, Analysis and Valuation of Insurance Companies. Center for Excellence in Accounting

and Security Analysis.

Ramakrishnan, R., and A. Thakor, 1984. Information reliability and a theory of financial intermediation.

Journal of Finance 34: 372–88.

Roberts, M. R., and A. Sufi. 2009. Control rights and capital structure: An empirical investigation.

Journal of Finance 66: 1657–95.

Roberts, M. R., 2014. The role of dynamic renegotiation and asymmetric information in financial

contracting. Journal of Financial Economics 116: 61–81.

Schultz, P., 2001. Corporate bond trading costs: A peek behind the curtain. Journal of Finance 56: 677–

698.

SEC 1982. Federal Register, March 16, 1982, 11438-1143.

Skinner, D., 2011. Discussion of ‘‘Accounting standards and debt covenants: Has the ‘‘Balance Sheet

Approach’’ led to a decline in the use of balance sheet covenants?’’ Journal of Accounting and

Economics 52: 203–208.

Smith, C. W., and J. B. Warner, 1979. On financial contracting: An analysis of bond covenants. Journal

of Financial Economics 7: 117–6.

Stock, J.H., and M. Yogo, 2005. Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression, in

D.W.K.Andrews and J.H. Stock, eds., Identification and Inference for Econometric Models: Essays

in Honor of Thomas Rothenberg, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 80-108.

Warga, A. 1992. Bond returns, liquidity, and missing data. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis

27: 605–617.

Warga, A., and I. Welch, 1993. Bondholder losses in leveraged buyouts. Review of Financial Studies 4:

959–982.

Wood, P., 2011. Bondholders and banks—why the difference in protections? Capital Markets Law

Journal 6 (2): 188–196.

Zhang, J., 2008. The contracting benefits of accounting conservatism to lenders and borrowers. Journal of

Accounting and Economics 46: 27–54.

Page 44: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

42

APPENDIX A

Examples of headroom and carve-out estimations

Covenant Quality Assessment October 2, 2008

Meritage Homes Corporation

Limitation on Debt Incurrence

Headroom

The issuer shall not, and shall not permit any restricted subsidiary to, directly or indirectly, incur any

“indebtedness”, provided that the issuer or any restricted subsidiary may incur additional indebtedness (including

“acquired indebtedness”) if no default shall have occurred and be continuing at the time of or as a consequence of

the incurrence of the indebtedness and if, after giving effect thereto, either:

(a) the “consolidated fixed charge coverage ratio” would be at least 2.00 to 1.00; or

(b) the ratio of “consolidated indebtedness” to “consolidated tangible net worth” would be less than 3.00 to

1.00 (either (a) or (b), the “ratio exception”).

*Amounts in thousands

1. Consolidated fixed charge coverage ratio

“Consolidated fixed charge coverage ratio” means the ratio of

• “consolidated cash flow available for fixed charges” during the most recent four consecutive full fiscal quarters

for which financial statements are available (the “four-quarter period”) ending on or prior to the date of the

transaction giving rise to the need to calculate the consolidated fixed charge coverage ratio (the “transaction

date”) to

• “consolidated interest” incurred for the four-quarter period.

Estimation

*The indenture provides extensive definitions of “consolidated cash flow available for fixed charges” and

“consolidated interest,” which determine the estimation of these terms.

CONSOLIDATED CASH FLOW

AVAILABLE FOR FIXED CHARGES

Last Twelve Months

Net Income (316,164)

Provision for income taxes (178,676)

Amortization + Depreciation 15,338

Consolidated interest expense

Interest expense 17,625

Interest incurred 56,005

Other non-cash items reducing

net income

Real-estate related impairments 323,950

Goodwill-related impairments 102,538

Stock-based comp. 6,801

Tender-offer stock comp. exp. 10,866

Total 38,283

Consolidated fixed charge coverage ratio (CFCCR) = 38,283/ (17,625 + 56,005) = 38,283/ 73,630 = 0.52x

Thus, estimated headroom is 0.52x - 2.00x = (1.5)x, or null under the CFCCR Incurrence test.

2. Consolidated net worth ratio

“Consolidated net worth ratio” means the ratio of

• “consolidated indebtedness (long-term debt)” to

• “consolidated tangible net worth”

Page 45: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

43

Estimation

*The indenture provides extensive definitions of “consolidated indebtedness (long-term debt)” and “consolidated

tangible net worth,” which determine the estimation of these terms.

Consolidated indebtedness = loans payable and other borrowings + senior and senior subordinated notes = 6,091 +

628,885 = 634,976

Consolidated tangible net worth = consolidated stockholders’ equity – consolidated intangible assets = 746,794 –

7,137 = 739,657

Consolidated indebtedness/ consolidated tangible net worth = 634,976/ 739,657 = 0.86x

Thus, estimated headroom is 3.00-0.9 = 2.1x under the consolidated net worth test.

Carve-outs [quantitative]

Notwithstanding the above, so long as no default shall have occurred and be continuing at the time of or as a

consequence of the incurrence of the following indebtedness, each of the following shall be permitted (the

“permitted indebtedness”):

• Indebtedness of the issuer and any restricted subsidiary under the “credit facilities” in an aggregate

amount at any time outstanding (whether incurred under the ratio exception or as permitted indebtedness)

not exceeding the greater of:

- $600.0 million; and

- the amount of the “borrowing base” as of the date of such incurrence;

• Indebtedness of the issuer or any restricted subsidiary in an aggregate amount not to exceed $25.0 million

at any time outstanding.

“Borrowing base” means, at any time of determination, the sum of the following without duplication:

(1) 100% of all cash and cash equivalents held by the issuer or any restricted subsidiary;

(2) 75% of the book value of “developed land” for which no construction has occurred;

(3) 95% of the cost of the land and construction costs including capitalized interest (as reasonably allocated

by the issuer) for all “units” for which there is an executed purchase contract with a buyer not affiliated

with the issuer, less any deposits, down payments or earnest money;

(4) 80% of the cost of the land and construction costs including capitalized interest (as reasonably allocated

by the issuer) for all units for which construction has begun and for which there is not an executed purchase

agreement with a buyer not affiliated with the issuer; and

(5) 50% of the costs of “entitled land” (other than developed land) on which improvements have not

commenced, less mortgage indebtedness (other than under a “credit facility”) applicable to such land.

Estimation

Borrowing base Corresponding item in

financial statement

Gross

Amount

x factor

100% of cash and cash equivalents Same 115,153 115,153

75% of book value of “developed land” (no construction) Finished lots and land

under dev.

544,191 408,143

95% of costs related to “units” (executed contracts) Homes under contract 357,304 339,439

80% of costs related to “units” (construction begun) Unsold homes 137,785 110,228

50% of costs of “entitled land” (improvements not begun) Land held for dev. 15,389 7,694.5

Total 980,658

Debt capacity under credit facility carve-out Amount

Total carve-out = greater of 600,000 and 980,658 980,658

Less

Credit facility (committed) (amended July 18, 2008) 500,000

Total debt capacity 480,658

Page 46: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

44

Covenant Carve-out Amount

Indebtedness under the credit facilities in an aggregate

amount at any time outstanding (whether incurred under

the ratio exception or as permitted indebtedness) not

exceeding greater of $600.0 million and the amount of the

borrowing base (see borrowing base calculation below)

480,658

Indebtedness of the issuer or any restricted subsidiary 25,000

Total debt capacity 505,658

Total consolidated assets = 1,619,810

Total debt capacity = 505,658

Indenture carve-out as a percentage of total consolidated assets = 505,658/1,619,810 = 31.2%

Covenant Quality Assessment October 12, 2007

K. Hovnanian Enterprises, Inc.

Limitation on Debt Incurrence

Headroom

The issuer will not and will not permit any restricted subsidiary, directly or indirectly, to create, incur or assume

liability for or guarantee the payment of any indebtedness unless the FCCR (defined above) would be at least 2.0 to

1.0.

*Amounts in thousands

Consolidated fixed charge coverage ratio

“Consolidated fixed charge coverage ratio” means with respect to any determination date, the ratio of:

“consolidated cash flow available for fixed charges” for the prior four full fiscal quarters (the four quarter

period) for which financial results have been reported immediately preceding the determination date (the

“transaction date”), to

the aggregate “consolidated interest incurred” for the four quarter period.

Estimation

*The indenture provides extensive definitions of “consolidated cash flow available for fixed charges” and

“consolidated interest,” which determine the estimation of these terms.

CONSOLIDATED CASH FLOW AVAILABLE

FOR FIXED CHARGES Last twelve months

Consolidated Net Income (275,785)

Income Taxes (143,955)

Cost of sales interest 131,361

Depreciation 17,826

Intangible Amortization 94,854

Amortization of Bond Discounts 1,118

Other Interest 10,492

Compensation from Stock Options and Awards 21,135

Loss on Sale and Retirement of Property and Assets 307

Loss (Income) from Unconsolidated Joint Ventures 32,202

Impairment and Land Option Deposit Write-Offs 499,646

Total 389,201

Page 47: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

45

CONSOLIDATED INTEREST INCURRED Last twelve months

Cost of Sales Interest 131,361

Other Interest 10,492

Amortization of Bond Discounts 1,118

Total 142,971

Consolidated Cash Flow Available for Fixed Charges / Consolidated Interest Incurred = 389,201 / 142,971 = 2.7

Thus, headroom is 2.7x – 2.0x = .7x under the Consolidated Fixed Charge Coverage Ratio.

Carve-outs [quantitative]

Notwithstanding the above, so long as no default shall have occurred and be continuing at the time of or as a

consequence of the incurrence of the following indebtedness, each of the following shall be permitted (the

“permitted indebtedness”):

Indebtedness under credit facilities in an aggregate amount not exceeding $1.5 billion; Indebtedness secured only by office buildings owned or occupied by Hovnanian or any restricted

subsidiary in an aggregate amount not exceeding $10 million; and

All other indebtedness of Hovnanian or any restricted subsidiary in an aggregate amount not exceeding $50

million

Estimation

Debt capacity under credit facility carve-out Amount

Total carve-out 1,500,000

Less:

$1.5 billion (unsecured revolving credit agreement through

May 11)

1,500,000

Total debt capacity 0

Covenant Carve-out Amount

Indebtedness under credit facilities not exceeding $1.5

billion

0

Indebtedness secured only by office buildings owned or

occupied by Hovnanian or any restricted subsidiary in an

aggregate amount not exceeding

10,000

All other indebtedness of Hovnanian or any restricted

subsidiary in an aggregate amount not exceeding

50,000

Total debt capacity 60,000

Total consolidated assets = 5,362,762

Total debt capacity = 60,000

Indenture carve-out as a percentage of total consolidated assets = 60,000/5,362,762 = 1.12%

Page 48: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

46

APPENDIX B

Discussion of Primary Covenants

Moody’s evaluates how bond covenants mitigate risk in several areas. They focus on the

following covenants, which are the most common in bond indentures. We define these covenants below

and provide a discussion of how Moody’s assesses the quality of each.

Restricted Payments. The restricted payment covenant group is focused on limiting what the

issuer is allowed to do with cash or other assets. Bondholders want the firm to retain the cash and other

assets of the issuer and its restricted subsidiaries and allow them to exit the company only under limited

circumstances. Bondholders are concerned if cash transfers go to equity and subordinated creditors,

especially at a time when such distributions decrease the issuer’s ability to service its debt, increasing the

default risk and reducing the recovery prospects in liquidation. However, Moody’s view is that a value

transfer from bondholders can also occur more indirectly, through management’s valuation of non-cash

assets, transactions with its affiliates or the designation of non-restricted subsidiaries.17

The restricted payments covenant has the most complex structure. In the prohibitory paragraph,

the covenant may prohibit dividends on capital stock, stock repurchases, the early purchase or redemption

of debt that is subordinated to the bonds and the making of some investments.18

The covenant allows

some restricted payments in the proviso and the carve-outs; the amount that can be paid out by the issuer

as a restricted payment at any time is often referred to as the “restricted payment basket.” The covenant's

proviso often specifies that a restricted payment can be made conditional on a debt incurrence ratio test

(e.g., an interest coverage threshold is met). The restricted payment basket may be increased by a certain

percentage of the consolidated positive net income of the issuer and restricted subsidiaries (e.g., 50%), by

the issuance of equity or by the conversion of debt into equity; it will be reduced by the amount of

restricted payments actually made over time or by the consolidated negative net income of the issuer and

the restricted subsidiaries.

A strong restricted payment covenant allows the issuer to only begin making restricted payments

when the income basket is beginning to build up. In contrast, a weak structure would have a start date for

making restricted payments (which is typically the bond issue date) that follows the buildup date. This

weak structure will allow the income basket to accumulate income before the bond issuance date,

facilitating larger restricted payments. The covenant also provides limited protection if it includes

numerous and sizable carve-outs, facilitates managers’ opportunistic valuation of the non-cash assets in

the income basket or fails to limit transactions with affiliate entities that are not restricted. Transactions

with some affiliates may circumvent the restricted payment covenant by disguising a dividend-like

transaction with the form of a business transaction (e.g., royalty payments).19

A protective

17

Bond covenants limit the activities of the bond issuer, but only certain of its subsidiaries. Subsidiaries subject to

covenants are called “restricted subsidiaries” since their cash flows are contractually required to service the bond

debt. “Unrestricted subsidiaries” are subsidiaries that are not limited by bond covenants and their cash flows are not

contractually available to service the bond debt. They are excluded from covenant financial ratio definitions and

calculations. 18

These investment restrictions typically refer to investments in the debt or equity of other companies, even

providing guarantees for another company's debt. Capital expenditures or acquisitions of productive assets are not

restricted by this covenant. 19

Restrictions on transactions with affiliates are particularly important when the issuer is a private company

controlled by a small group of shareholders. A private company issuer is likely to request carve-outs for fees paid to

financial sponsors.

Page 49: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

47

APPENDIX B (Continued)

Discussion of Primary Covenants

structure would permit only those transactions done on an arm’s length basis and, if above a reasonably

low threshold, would require a third-party fairness opinion. A Restricted Payment covenant will also

provide a weak protection if the designation of unrestricted subsidiaries does not need to comply with the

covenant.

Debt Incurrence. Increased leverage can negatively impact bondholders by reducing the cushion

of cash flow, increasing default risk as well as increasing management’s incentives to engage in

shareholder friendly actions. Restrictions on the incurrence of indebtedness are designed to protect

bondholders from these incremental risks by limiting the issuance of additional debt unless the issuer has

the demonstrated capacity to service all its debt, including the proposed new debt. Indebtedness is defined

more generally and includes debt, lease obligations, reimbursement obligations with respect to letters of

credit, obligations to redeem stock and guarantees provided by the issuer with respect to the indebtedness

of other entities.

The capacity to service the debt (including the new debt) specified in the proviso is usually tested

based on a comparison of cash flows to interest expense; this test is known as the “coverage” or “debt

incurrence” test. The basic incurrence test allows the issuer to incur additional debt if the issuer has a ratio

of EBITDA to cash and non-cash interest expense of at least 2 to 1. An alternative is a leverage test,

which evaluates the relationship of the issuer’s consolidated debt to its trailing 12-month EBITDA on a

pro forma basis.

Debt incurrence covenants may contain several carve-outs. First, most debt covenants allow an

exception for the issuer to incur bank debt (constructed around the issuer’s borrowing base using the level

of inventories and accounts receivables or limited to a specified dollar amount) and intercompany debt

with its restricted subsidiaries. Second, the covenant might permit the issuer to refinance debt outstanding

at the time of the indenture or issued after the indenture in order to limit the possibility of a default when

this debt matures. When refinancing debt, the issuer is typically not allowed to increase the principal

amount (except to the extent needed to pay related costs, e.g., accrued interest, premium and other

retirement costs), shorten the average life of the debt refinanced or refinance subordinated debt with

senior debt. Third, the covenant might specify a so-called “debt basket”, which is the dollar amount of

indebtedness that can be issued without regard as to whether the issuer has the necessary interest coverage

ratio.20

This basket is intended to protect the issuer in case of an “emergency”, in which it might need to

incur additional debt. Fourth, indentures include other exceptions that apply to a specific issuer. For

instance, an issuer that historically has acquired capital assets through capital leases might negotiate for

an additional exception that would permit such transactions in the future.

Moody’s classifies debt incurrence covenants as being more protective if the covenant has caps

on bank credit facilities, debt issued by restricted subsidiaries that guarantee the issuer’s debt or on

operating leases. Moody’s negatively views covenants whose EBITDA ratio in the debt incurrence test

allows add-backs of “non-cash charges” and other items that give management the discretion to adjust the

ratio in order to issue more debt or covenants that allow debt reclassifications (e.g., that reclassify debt

that falls under the debt basket carve-out into debt that falls under the debt incurrence ratio).

20

As these baskets are based on a percentage of consolidated total (or tangible) assets, they fluctuate with the

balance sheet.

Page 50: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

48

APPENDIX B (Continued)

Discussion of Primary Covenants

Subsidiary Debt Incurrence. The discussion of the debt incurrence above is applicable here as

well, but instead of the parent firm, the perspective is that of any subsidiary of the parent company.

Liens. The limitation on liens covenant has primary importance when it comes to limiting the

dilution of bondholders’ claims. Bondholders do not want other creditors to have senior claims on assets

should the issuer become insolvent. In a subordinated note offering, the holders typically insist that the

issuer does not grant any liens to secure other subordinated debt. Conversely, the holders of senior notes,

in an effort to remain as senior as possible with respect to the issuer’s assets, restrict the issuer from

incurring liens (which include security interests, mortgages and similar contractual or legal

encumbrances) on its assets except for limited permitted exceptions, or unless it has a proviso stating that

the issuer should simultaneously grant an equal lien for the benefit of the bondholders.

Carve-outs with these exceptions usually appear in the definition of permitted liens. The bank

credit facility carve-out is the principal and usually the largest carve-out. Other typical carve-outs are

capital expenditures (“capex”) and a liens catch-all basket. In addition to these, carve-outs can deal with

financings under one or more of the categories of permitted debt, pre-existing or acquired liens, and

refinancings of already secured debt. An important point is to determine whether the assets that are

permitted to be subject to the liens should be limited (e.g., for asset finance, only the asset acquired

should be permitted to secure this debt, but for permitted bank debt, any assets of the issuer or its

restricted subsidiaries are typically permitted collateral).

The broader the scope of the prohibitory paragraph, the stronger the limitation of liens covenant

is, conditional that the carve-outs are not excessive. Protective covenants limit the secured credit facility

debt and specify that bank credit facilities cannot be refinanced with bonds of longer duration. These

secured bonds may subordinate the original bondholders.

Asset Sales. The limitation on asset divestitures covenant restricts the non-ordinary sales of assets

in the prohibitory paragraph unless, as stated in the proviso, certain use-of-proceeds criteria are met, such

as sales proceeds being used to either pay down debt or reinvest in assets that service the debt and that are

related to the issuer’s core business. Asset divestitures are a major concern because they could remove

core revenue-generating assets that support the debt service. Although the covenant requires that sales of

assets be made at fair value and a large percentage of the consideration be received in cash, the main

purpose of the covenant is to limit the uses of proceeds in the event that the issuer does sell assets.

A high quality asset sales covenant stipulates that about 70% of the income received from the sale

is in cash or “cash equivalents” and that this cash is retained in the company for a period of one year or is

used to pay down senior debt / pari passu debt and sets a reasonably low threshold for the carve-outs. A

weak asset sales covenant includes a substantial carve-out from the “cash equivalent” consideration or no

annual caps on asset sales.

Sale/Leaseback. This covenant limits the issuer’s ability to enter into sale-leaseback transactions.

A sale-leaseback transaction, in which the issuer sells an asset and immediately leases it back, is

economically very similar to a secured financing, since the issuer will receive sale proceeds (similar to

loan proceeds) and will make rental payments over the life of the lease (similar to loan repayments). The

proviso of this covenant generally permits an issuer to enter into sale-leaseback transactions only if the

Page 51: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

49

APPENDIX B (Continued)

Discussion of Primary Covenants

issuer has the ability to incur the related indebtedness represented by the lease obligation and is able to

incur the lien on the property securing the lease.

Since the asset has been sold and is therefore not part of the issuer’s consolidated assets

subsequent to the sale (unlike a secured financing), this covenant contains the added requirement that the

issuer treat the sale proceeds as it would in connection to any other asset sale in which the use-of-

proceeds criteria may apply. Therefore, the assessment of the level of protection provided by this

covenant is similar to that of the asset sales covenant.

Mergers. The merger / asset conveyance covenant provides important event-risk protection

against increased leveraging. It is designed to ensure that the successor company in any major M&A

transaction involving the issuer assumes the obligations with respect to the bonds (i.e., that the bond

obligations follow the assets). The covenant's proviso allows mergers if the issuer is able to incur

indebtedness under a financial ratio test on a pro forma basis. This test may allow the issuer to engage in a

merger only if the debt incurrence ratio in the Debt Incurrence covenant is improving after the

transaction. Moody’s views the protection provided by this covenant as strong if the financial ratio test is

based on multiple financial ratios (e.g., a debt incurrence ratio test and an earnings-based test, computed

both before and after the transaction). Also, the protection is better if the debt incurrence test allows an

additional dollar of debt for each additional dollar of equity proceeds. More aggressive structures have

ratios of 2 to 1.

Change of Control. The change of the indenture’s control provisions are designed to allow the

bondholder, upon a change in the ownership of the issuer, to re-evaluate the investment in the issuer

represented by the bonds. The change of control covenant protects investors against a fundamental

corporate change as well as the risk of a highly leveraged transaction. If the bondholders for any reason

prefers to exit the investment when a change in control occurs, then the issuer is required to redeem the

bonds at a purchase price that is typically slightly above the principal amount of the bond. As a result, this

covenant is also called the change of control “put.” The change in ownership is deemed to occur if a

designated group of controlling shareholders fails to continue to own at any time a majority of the

outstanding voting stock of the issuer, if the issuer is liquidated or engages in a merger or acquisition that

substantially changes the ownership structure. In the case of public issuers, the permitted holders’

ownership may fall below 50% and could, in fact, fall all the way to zero in terms of voting percentage

ownership, without triggering a change of control. In this situation, a change of control would occur only

if persons other than the permitted holders acquire (typically) 35% or more of the voting power of the

issuer.

The covenant may include a proviso stating that a change of control occurs if a merger takes

place and the company is downgraded (the negative rating condition). The covenant might also specify a

carve-out that specifies a set of permitted holders. If a majority permitted holder sells to a minority

permitted holder, the bondholder cannot exercise its put option even though a change in control has

occurred.

A change of control covenant with strong protection is one that is triggered when “all or

substantially all” of the issuer’s assets are sold, a majority of the board is replaced or a liquidation /

merger occurs. The protection is enhanced when the covenant also includes “stock for stock” mergers.

Page 52: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

50

APPENDIX C

Variable Definitions

Variable Definition

Similarity Variables

Covenant Similarity = For each bond issue, the sum of the individual covenant similarity scores, computed as

described below.

Covenant Similarity

Pay

= For bond issue-level tests, the average of the pairwise absolute differences between

restricted payments covenant strictness score assigned to a particular bond issue by

Moody's, and its peer bonds (cross-sectional or time-series peers). The covenant

strictness scores score range from 0 to 3, with higher values indicating better covenant

protection. For the ‘peer-based’ sample, a peer bond is defined as a bond within the

same sector and broad rating category (investment grade or high yield) issued within

the calendar year prior to the issuance of a bond under consideration. For the ‘time-

series-based’ sample, a peer bond is defined as a bond issued by the same firm within

five calendar years prior to the bond issue under consideration. The similarity scores are

multiplied by -1, so that higher values indicate higher similarity.

Covenant Similarity

Change of Control

= Covenant similarity score for the Change of Control covenant, calculated for each bond

using a method similar to the Covenant Similarity Pay score described above.

Covenant Similarity

Merger

= Covenant similarity score for the Merger covenant, calculated for each bond using a

method similar to the Covenant Similarity Pay score described above.

Covenant Similarity

Debt

= Covenant similarity score for the Debt covenant, calculated for each bond using a

method similar to the Covenant Similarity Pay score described above.

Covenant Similarity

Subsidiary Debt

= Covenant similarity score for the Subsidiary Debt covenant, calculated for each bond

using a method similar to the Covenant Similarity Pay score described above.

Covenant Similarity

Liens

= Covenant similarity score for the Liens covenant, calculated for each bond using a

method similar to the Covenant Similarity Pay score described above.

Covenant Similarity

Asset Sale

= Covenant similarity score for the Asset Sale covenant, calculated for each bond using a

method similar to the Covenant Similarity Pay score described above.

Covenant Similarity

Leaseback

= Covenant similarity score for the Leaseback covenant, calculated for each bond using a

method similar to the Covenant Similarity Pay score described above.

Similar Legal Counsel

(Underwriter)

= For bond issue-level tests, the average of an indicator variable that takes on a value of

one if the legal counsel (lead underwriter) for a firm issuing a particular bond issue and

its peer bond (cross-sectional or time-series peers) is the same, zero otherwise.

Similar Size (Tangibility)

[Leverage] {Interest

Coverage}

= For bond issue-level tests, the average of the pairwise absolute differences in Size

(Tangibility) [Leverage] {Interest Coverage} for a particular bond issue and its peer

bonds (cross-sectional or time-series peers). A cross-sectional peer bond is defined as a

bond within the same sector and broad rating category (investment grade or high yield)

issued within the calendar year prior to the issuance of a bond under consideration. A

time-series peer is defined as a bond issued by the same firm within five calendar years

prior to the bond issue under consideration. The similarity scores are multiplied by -1,

so that higher values indicate higher similarity.

(Continued)

Page 53: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

51

APPENDIX C (Continued)

Variable Definitions

Variable Definition

Firm/Bond level Variables

Size = Logarithm of the firm’s total assets, from the quarter preceding the bond issuance.

Tangibility = Ratio of fixed assets to total assets, from the quarter preceding the bond issuance.

Leverage = Long-term debt to total assets ratio, from the quarter preceding the bond issuance.

Interest Coverage = Interest coverage ratio from the quarter preceding the bond issuance, calculated as

EBITDA over interest expense.

Investment Grade = Indicator variable that takes a value of one if the issue is rated investment grade by at

least one of the three major credit rating agencies, zero otherwise.

Covenant Restrictiveness = Sum of the bond-level covenant restrictiveness scores provided by Moody's ( i.e., the

sum of covenant strictness scores pertaining to payment restrictions, merger

restrictions, change of control, asset sales, sale-leaseback, debt, subsidiary debt, and

liens. The individual scores range from 0 to 3, with higher values indicating better

covenant protection (see Appendix A for details on each covenant).

Covenant Restrictiveness

Re-weighted

= Sum of the bond-level reweighted covenant restrictiveness scores. The covenant scores

are described in the definition of Covenant Restrictiveness above. Our re-weighted

measure uses the following weights for each covenant type: payment restrictions (25%),

debt incurrence (25%), change of control (5%), merger restrictions (5%), liens

restrictions (20%), asset sales restrictions (5%), leaseback restrictions (5%) and limits

on subsidiary debt (10%).

Number Covenants = Total number of bond covenants, as identified in the Mergent FISD database.

Offering Amount = Logarithm of principal amount of the bond offering.

Maturity = Logarithm of time to maturity, in number of years.

Lender Power = Indicator variable that takes a value of one if the bond is issued during the recent

financial crisis from 2007 to 2009.

Spread = Initial yield to maturity at the time of bond issuance, minus the yield to maturity of a

treasury-bill with the closest maturity.

Volume = Logarithm of total trading volume of a bond during 30 days immediately after issuance.

.Transactions = Logarithm of total number of trading transactions of a bond during 30 days

immediately after issuance.

Insurance Holdings = Proportion of the dollar par value of the bond held by insurance companies at the

quarter end after the bond issuance quarter.

Market Spread = Mean Spread for a particular quarter and rating category to which the bond belongs at

issuance. The four rating categories are as follows: AAA to Aaa2, Aa3 to A2, A3 to

Baa2, and Baa3 to D.

Market Volume = Mean Volume for a particular quarter and rating category to which the bond belongs at

issuance. The four rating categories are as follows: AAA to Aaa2, Aa3 to A2, A3 to

Baa2, and Baa3 to D.

Market Transactions = Mean Transactions for a particular quarter and rating category to which the bond

belongs at issuance. The four rating categories are as follows: AAA to Aaa2, Aa3 to

A2, A3 to Baa2, and Baa3 to D.

Page 54: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

52

Market Insurance Holdings = Mean Insurance Holdings for a particular quarter and rating category to which the bond

belongs at issuance. The four rating categories are as follows: AAA to Aaa2, Aa3 to

A2, A3 to Baa2, and Baa3 to D.

Number of Peers = The number of peer bonds used to compute the covenant similarity score as described

in the definition of Covenant Similarity.

Page 55: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

53

TABLE 1

Sample Selection

This table presents the sample selection procedure.

Total number of bond issues in Moody’s CQA database 3,075

Sample after deleting international and financial sector bonds 2,427

Sample after availability of bond-level variables 2,207

Sample of bond issues for which cross-sectional similarity scores could be computed 1,727

Sample after conditioning on availability of firm-level controls 996

Page 56: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

54

TABLE 2

Descriptive Statistics

This table provides descriptive statistics for the variables used in our tests. Panel A presents the variables that

measure similarity relative to peer j’s bonds. Panel B presents the other variables that are measured at the firm i

level. Panel C presents the frequency distribution of covenant similarity variables. Variables are defined in

Appendix C.

Panel A: Similarity Variables

N Mean Median Std. Dev.

Covenant Similarity 996 -2.842 -2.053 2.732

Similar Legal Counsel 943 0.123 0.000 0.248

Similar Underwriter 943 0.149 0.000 0.233

Similar Size 943 -0.941 -0.868 0.609

Similar Tangibility 943 -0.202 0.170 0.165

Similar Leverage 943 -0.108 -0.082 0.197

Similar Interest Coverage 943 -8.568 -2.585 27.271

Panel B: Bond i-level Variables

Size 996 9.582 9.625 1.190

Tangibility 996 0.736 0.755 0.373

Leverage 996 0.277 0.260 0.140

Interest Coverage 996 5.051 2.693 9.107

Investment Grade 996 0.843 1.000 0.364

Number Covenants 996 5.080 5.000 3.476

Offering Amount 996 12.929 12.899 0.939

Maturity 996 8.274 8.205 0.620

Lender Power 996 0.126 0.000 0.331

Spread 996 2.235 1.787 1.615

Volume 996 12.899 18.635 10.858

Transactions 996 1.770 3.970 4.922

Insurance Holdings 877 0.539 0.617 0.334

Market Spread 996 2.326 2.001 1.339

Market Volume 996 18.306 19.313 4.503

Market Transactions 996 4.277 4.578 2.303

Market Insurance Holdings 877 0.454 0.474 0.255

Panel C: Frequency Distribution of Covenant Similarity Measures

Interval

0 (0,-1] (-1,-2] (-2,-3]

Covenant Similarity (scaled by eight) 11% 84% 6% 0%

Covenant Similarity Pay 83% 8% 5% 4%

Covenant Similarity Change of Control 44% 40% 13% 3%

Covenant Similarity Merger 86% 13% 1% 0%

Covenant Similarity Debt 82% 10% 5% 3%

Covenant Similarity Subsidiary Debt 70% 18% 7% 4%

Covenant Similarity Liens 49% 28% 16% 7%

Covenant Similarity Asset Sale 89% 8% 2% 1%

Covenant Similarity Leaseback 30% 43% 16% 12%

Page 57: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

55

TABLE 3

Determinants of Covenant Similarity

This table investigates the determinants of similarity in covenant restrictiveness. We regress Covenant Similarity on

variables that measure similarity in intermediaries, similarity in firm characteristics, as well as the level of firm

characteristics and bond characteristics. In columns 1 to 3, Covenant Similarity is measured at the firm i level, in

which we take the mean of the covenant similarity scores across each firm i – peer j pair for all j peers of firm i. In

column 4, Covenant Similarity is the individual similarity scores across each firm i – peer j pair. We estimate OLS

regressions as a panel and cluster the standard errors at the firm level. Robust t-statistics are in brackets. ***, **, and

* denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively, using two-tailed tests. Variables are defined in

Appendix C.

Firm i level Firm i level Firm i level Firm i-Peer j level

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Similar Legal Counsel 0.988** 0.975** 1.212***

[2.27] [2.25] [7.49]

Similar Underwriter 0.223 0.111 0.116

[0.64] [0.32] [1.11]

Similar Size 0.700** 0.777*** 0.700** 0.383***

[2.49] [2.82] [2.48] [5.93]

Similar Tangibility 1.943*** 2.234*** 1.928*** 1.842***

[2.71] [3.10] [2.68] [6.27]

Similar Leverage 0.634 0.785 0.631 3.138**

[0.72] [0.84] [0.72] [2.10]

Similar Interest Coverage 0.001 0.001 0.001 -0.005

[0.23] [0.26] [0.23] [-1.48]

Size 0.017 0.012 0.016 -0.093*

[0.12] [0.08] [0.11] [-1.65]

Tangibility 0.108 0.143 0.107 -0.245

[0.28] [0.37] [0.27] [-1.09]

Leverage -0.137 0.056 -0.137 -0.862

[-0.11] [0.05] [-0.11] [-1.24]

Interest Coverage 0.003 0.000 0.003 -0.011*

[0.25] [0.01] [0.22] [-1.76]

Number Covenants 0.013 0.026 0.013 -0.149***

[0.28] [0.54] [0.26] [-4.46]

Offering Amount -0.357*** -0.339*** -0.355*** -0.199***

[-3.98] [-3.53] [-3.91] [-3.77]

Maturity 0.118 0.100 0.118 0.031

[1.23] [1.07] [1.23] [0.40]

Investment Grade 4.511*** 4.529*** 4.511*** 3.766***

[7.99] [8.03] [7.98] [9.79]

Lender Power -0.062 -0.098 -0.073 0.300*

[-0.28] [-0.46] [-0.34] [1.82]

Constant -2.336 -2.266 -2.359 -0.729

[-1.21] [-1.13] [-1.22] [-0.70]

Observations 943 943 943 7,308

Adj. R2 (%)

43.5% 42.8% 43.4% 28.9%

Page 58: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

56

TABLE 4

Consequences of Covenant Similarity: Yield Spread

This table investigates the yield spread consequences of similarity in covenant restrictiveness. In Panel A, we

regress the bond’s offering yield on Covenant Similarity, controlling for market-wide spread, firm characteristics,

and bond characteristics. We estimate both OLS and 2SLS regressions. Covenant Similarity is measured at the firm i

level, in which we take the mean of the covenant similarity scores across each firm i – peer j pair for all peers of

firm i. In Panel B, we provide a set of robustness tests in which we augment the model with additional control

variables or use a different aggregation method to calculate Covenant Similarity. We estimate each regression as a

panel and cluster the standard errors at the firm level. Robust t-statistics are in brackets. ***, **, and * denote

significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively, using two-tailed tests. Variables are defined in Appendix

C.

Panel A: Main Test OLS 2SLS

(1) (2)

Covenant Similarity -0.046*** -0.066**

[-2.86] [-2.33]

Market Spread 0.979*** 0.959***

[20.82] [19.31]

Size -0.023 -0.013

[-0.72] [-0.39]

Tangibility -0.240** -0.237**

[-2.34] [-2.15]

Leverage -0.577 -0.670*

[-1.50] [-1.74]

Interest Coverage -0.011*** -0.011***

[-2.84] [-2.76]

Number Covenants 0.001 0.004

[0.09] [0.20]

Offering Amount 0.020 0.003

[0.54] [0.08]

Maturity 0.310*** 0.306***

[5.79] [5.35]

Constant -2.389*** -2.235***

[-3.84] [-3.48]

Observations 996 943

Adj. R2 (%)

67.3% 65.9%

(Continued)

Page 59: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

57

TABLE 4 (Continued)

Consequences of Covenant Similarity: Yield Spread

Panel B: Robustness Tests

(1) (2) (3)

Covenant Similarity -0.047*** -0.047***

[-2.92] [-2.88]

Number of Peers 0.011***

[2.75]

Covenant Restrictiveness -0.020

[-1.22]

Covenant Similarity Re-Weighted -0.363***

[-3.36]

Market Spread 0.978*** 0.987*** 0.975***

[20.84] [20.63] [20.70]

Size -0.024 -0.027 -0.026

[-0.80] [-0.85] [-0.84]

Tangibility -0.292*** -0.267** -0.263**

[-2.89] [-2.51] [-2.55]

Leverage -0.525 -0.539 -0.629*

[-1.37] [-1.39] [-1.66]

Interest Coverage -0.011*** -0.011*** -0.011***

[-2.63] [-2.70] [-2.74]

Number Covenants 0.007 0.013 -0.002

[0.45] [0.69] [-0.10]

Offering Amount 0.024 0.014 0.025

[0.70] [0.40] [0.70]

Maturity 0.294*** 0.304*** 0.304***

[5.44] [5.70] [5.72]

Constant -2.413*** -2.085*** -2.326***

[-3.91] [-3.08] [-3.81]

Observations 996 996 996

Adj. R2 (%)

67.5% 67.3% 67.5%

Page 60: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

58

TABLE 5

Yield Spread Test by Individual Covenant

This table investigates the yield spread consequences of similarity in individual covenant restrictiveness. We estimate the same OLS model as in Panel A of

Table 4 but use the covenant similarity score calculated for a single covenant relative to the respective covenant for its peers. Each column corresponds to a

single covenant similarity value. We estimate each regression as a panel and cluster the standard errors at the firm level. Robust t-statistics are in brackets. ***,

**, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively, using two-tailed tests. Variables are defined in Appendix C.

Covenant Similarity calculated for

Pay

Covenant

Change of

Control

Covenant

Merger

Covenant

Debt

Covenant

Subsidiary

Debt

Covenant

Liens

Covenant

Asset Sale

Covenant

Leaseback

Covenant

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Covenant Similarity -0.197** -0.000 -0.245 -0.204*** -0.088 -0.134*** -0.221*** -0.023

[-2.51] [-0.01] [-1.55] [-2.63] [-1.29] [-2.96] [-2.87] [-0.57]

Market Spread 0.974*** 0.993*** 0.985*** 0.975*** 0.986*** 1.000*** 0.988*** 0.992***

[20.20] [22.08] [21.20] [20.35] [21.06] [22.35] [21.77] [21.88]

Size -0.024 -0.030 -0.026 -0.027 -0.027 -0.035 -0.037 -0.028

[-0.74] [-0.91] [-0.80] [-0.86] [-0.83] [-1.15] [-1.15] [-0.86]

Tangibility -0.222** -0.211** -0.224** -0.232** -0.228** -0.274*** -0.231** -0.205**

[-2.17] [-2.04] [-2.14] [-2.24] [-2.18] [-2.67] [-2.29] [-2.00]

Leverage -0.640* -0.502 -0.557 -0.596 -0.517 -0.527 -0.476 -0.499

[-1.67] [-1.21] [-1.40] [-1.53] [-1.28] [-1.29] [-1.18] [-1.21]

Interest Coverage -0.011*** -0.011*** -0.011*** -0.011*** -0.011*** -0.011** -0.011*** -0.011***

[-2.83] [-2.72] [-2.71] [-2.69] [-2.76] [-2.57] [-2.66] [-2.78]

Number Covenants -0.001 0.009 0.003 -0.002 0.004 0.012 0.008 0.009

[-0.08] [0.57] [0.21] [-0.13] [0.25] [0.76] [0.49] [0.59]

Offering Amount 0.035 0.039 0.035 0.034 0.037 0.033 0.036 0.036

[0.94] [1.07] [0.93] [0.92] [1.00] [0.88] [0.95] [0.96]

Maturity 0.303*** 0.298*** 0.301*** 0.303*** 0.306*** 0.289*** 0.303*** 0.300***

[5.70] [5.55] [5.64] [5.71] [5.67] [5.36] [5.64] [5.57]

Constant -2.406*** -2.458*** -2.415*** -2.367*** -2.494*** -2.310*** -2.386*** -2.467***

[-3.86] [-3.86] [-3.81] [-3.82] [-3.90] [-3.69] [-3.86] [-3.86]

Observations 996 996 996 996 996 996 996 996

Adj. R2 (%)

67.2% 66.8% 66.9% 67.2% 66.9% 67.1% 67.0% 66.8%

Page 61: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

59

TABLE 6

Consequences of Covenant Similarity: Insurance Company Holdings

This table investigates the consequences for insurance company holdings of similarity in covenant restrictiveness

relative to the covenants of peer companies. We regress the holdings of insurance companies on Covenant

Similarity, controlling for market-wide insurance holdings, firm characteristics, and bond characteristics. We

estimate each regression as a panel and cluster the standard errors at the firm level. Robust t-statistics are in

brackets. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively, using two-tailed tests.

Variables are defined in Appendix C.

OLS 2SLS

(1) (2)

Covenant Similarity 0.011*** 0.022***

[3.27] [3.31]

Market Insurance Holdings 0.883*** 0.865***

[-25.99] [22.77]

Size -0.031*** -0.040***

[-3.51] [-4.38]

Tangibility -0.009 -0.003

[-0.37] [-0.12]

Leverage -0.059 -0.009

[-0.93] [-0.13]

Interest Coverage 0.003*** 0.003***

[3.27] [3.24]

Number Covenants -0.009*** -0.008***

[-3.37] [-2.88]

Offering Amount -0.047*** -0.035***

[-4.27] [-2.98]

Maturity 0.053*** 0.047***

[4.65] [4.02]

Constant 0.689*** 0.683***

[3.57] [3.55]

Observations 877 825

Adj. R2 (%)

67.4% 67.0%

Page 62: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

60

TABLE 7

Consequences of Covenant Similarity: Trading

This table investigates the trading consequences of similarity in covenant restrictiveness relative to the covenants of

peer companies. We regress the bond’s trading volume and number of transactions on Covenant Similarity,

controlling for market-wide trading, firm characteristics, and bond characteristics. We estimate each regression as a

panel and cluster the standard errors at the firm level. Robust t-statistics are in brackets. ***, **, and * denote

significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively, using two-tailed tests. Variables are defined in Appendix

C.

Dependent Variable = Volume Dependent Variable = Transactions

OLS 2SLS OLS 2SLS

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Covenant Similarity 0.291* 0.740* 0.130* 0.323*

[1.75] [1.90] [1.79] [1.95]

Market Volume 0.806*** 0.843***

[15.06] [14.67]

Market Transactions 0.805*** 0.833***

[13.80] [12.97]

Size 1.399*** 1.288*** 0.741*** 0.696***

[3.35] [2.88] [4.06] [3.57]

Tangibility 0.676 1.212 0.389 0.624

[0.59] [0.98] [0.77] [1.16]

Leverage -20.759*** -19.755*** -8.595*** -8.235***

[-5.03] [-4.09] [-4.86] [-3.97]

Interest Coverage -0.057 -0.058 -0.030 -0.032

[-1.09] [-1.08] [-1.21] [-1.27]

Number Covenants 0.160 0.264 0.094 0.144

[0.97] [1.31] [1.28] [1.60]

Offering Amount 0.818* 1.007** 0.588*** 0.678***

[1.89] [2.12] [2.82] [3.05]

Maturity -0.145 -0.386 -0.242 -0.338

[-0.30] [-0.77] [-1.18] [-1.56]

Constant -19.082*** -19.071** -12.234*** -12.256***

[-2.61] [-2.47] [-3.80] [-3.61]

Observations 996 943 996 943

Adj. R2 (%)

27.5% 24.6% 34.5% 32.0%

Page 63: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

61

TABLE 8

Time-Series Covenant Similarity This table replicates the main determinants and yield spread analyses using a ‘time-series-based’ measure of

Covenant Similarity, which compares the restrictiveness of a bond’s covenants to the covenant terms in bonds

previously issued by the same firm. This sample consists of 845 bonds for which we can estimate the similarity

relative to previous bond issues. Panel A presents the descriptive statistics for the similarity variables, which are

measured relative to firm i’s previous bond. Panel B presents the determinants analysis. Panel C presents the yield

spread analyses. We estimate OLS regressions as a panel and cluster the standard errors at the firm level. Robust t-

statistics are in brackets. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively, using two-

tailed tests. Variables are defined in Appendix C.

Panel A: Descriptive Statistics

N Mean Median Std. Dev.

Similarity Variables

Covenant Similarity 845 -0.768 0.000 2.017

Similar Legal Counsel 783 0.471 0.500 0.441

Similar Underwriter 783 0.199 0.000 0.306

Similar Size 783 -0.306 -0.216 0.296

Similar Tangibility 783 -0.082 -0.059 0.089

Similar Leverage 783 -0.060 -0.045 0.058

Similar Interest Coverage 783 -4.886 -1.884 9.840

(Continued)

Page 64: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

62

TABLE 8 (Continued)

Time-Series Covenant Similarity

Panel B: Determinants of Covenant Similarity

Firm i level

(1)

Firm i level

(2)

Firm i level

(3)

Similar Legal Counsel 0.508** 0.513**

[2.38] [2.47]

Similar Underwriter -0.076 -0.123

[-0.26] [-0.43]

Similar Size 0.735 0.628 0.727

[1.31] [1.10] [1.31]

Similar Tangibility 0.241 0.391 0.275

[0.18] [0.30] [0.21]

Similar Leverage 4.174 4.498 4.236

[1.55] [1.61] [1.58]

Similar Interest Coverage 0.005 0.005 0.005

[0.44] [0.37] [0.44]

Size 0.060 0.021 0.059

[0.62] [0.21] [0.61]

Tangibility 0.697* 0.692 0.699*

[1.70] [1.65] [1.70]

Leverage -0.114 -0.010 -0.12

[-0.11] [-0.01] [-0.12]

Interest Coverage 0.007 0.006 0.008

[0.52] [0.47] [0.53]

Investment Grade 0.023 0.035 1.552**

[0.33] [0.50] [2.23]

Number Covenants -0.184* -0.147 0.024

[-1.76] [-1.38] [0.34]

Offering Amount 0.151** 0.142** -0.186*

[2.38] [2.32] [-1.77]

Maturity 1.554** 1.622** 0.155**

[2.22] [2.37] [2.55]

Lender Power -0.241 -0.254 -0.235

[-1.07] [-1.11] [-1.05]

Constant -1.828 -1.744 -1.817

[-1.34] [-1.25] [-1.34]

Observations 783 783 783

Adj. R2 (%)

17.4% 16.2% 17.4%

(Continued)

Page 65: Similarity in Bond Covenants* - BC

63

TABLE 8 (Continued)

Time-Series Covenant Similarity

Panel C: Consequences of Covenant Similarity: Yield Spread

OLS 2SLS

(1) (2)

Covenant Similarity -0.097*** -0.241**

[-3.09] [-2.30]

Market Spread 0.989*** 0.943***

[18.43] [15.68]

Size -0.035 -0.016

[-0.79] [-0.31]

Tangibility -0.213* -0.101

[-1.70] [-0.58]

Leverage -0.600 -1.089*

[-1.15] [-1.90]

Interest Coverage -0.015*** -0.015**

[-2.62] [-2.30]

Number Covenants 0.005 -0.002

[0.23] [-0.09]

Offering Amount -0.002 -0.042

[-0.05] [-0.73]

Maturity 0.356*** 0.365***

[5.97] [5.78]

Constant -2.352*** -2.018**

[-2.92] [-2.15]

Observations 845 783

Adj. R2 (%)

65.7% 61.4%