Smart Metering FINAL Revised

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/8/2019 Smart Metering FINAL Revised

    1/2

    art metering

    In the next decade every home and small

    business in Britain will have smart gas and

    electricity meters installed. The plan is

    the result of a business case produced by

    the Department of Energy and Climate Change

    (Decc) which forecasts that over the next 20 years

    the project will cost in excess of 9 billion, and

    deliver benefits of more than 17 billion.

    This seems to be exactly the kind of invest-

    ment Britain needs right now an economically

    advantageous long-term investment in critical

    infrastructure, helping the country move to a more

    sustainable low-carbon future. But is the business

    case convincing enough? Are the proposed costs

    and benefits consistent with experiences else-

    where in the world? Who should foot the up-front

    bill? And is it possible to make the business case

    for smart metering even more compelling?

    It is widely accepted that installing smart

    meters will be expensive. Government estimates

    are that this will cost 9.2 billion over the next 20

    years, and two-thirds of this relates to the very vis-

    ible components of the deployment the purchas-

    ing and installation of meters and communications

    infrastructure. The remainder covers new operat-

    ing costs, the cost of the change programme, and

    inefficiencies from operating smart and traditional

    meters in parallel during deployment.

    To consider whether these estimates are rea-

    sonable, Britain can draw on the experiences of

    other markets, where millions of smart meters

    have been or are currently being installed. IBMs

    analysis of 27 smart metering projects in North

    America shows that the up-front costs for deploy-

    ments delivering a similar scope to that proposed

    for Britain range from 102 to 242 per meter.

    This covers the purchase and installation of the

    meter and communication assets, IT changes and

    project management. The estimate for Britain is

    139 per meter.

    This appears sensible. Britain has complexi-

    ties such as indoor metering, which will increase

    costs, but also opportunities to be more efficient

    such as deploying smart gas and electricity meters

    simultaneously. Britain should also reap the ben-

    efits of expected decreases in smart meter compo-

    nent costs, which IBM analysis shows as falling

    by 5-10 per cent each year.

    In a similar manner it is possible to compare

    the detailed cost assumptions made. For exam-

    ple, Decc has assumed a purchase cost of 56

    per smart gas meter. This is a conservative esti-

    mate compared with the 43 per meter Italy has

    assumed for its planned deployment of smart gas

    meters with similar functionality, due to com-

    mence in 2012. Further comparisons reveal simi-

    lar answers Deccs assumptions appear robust,

    with a slight overall tendency towards being

    conservative.

    These analyses show that both the overall and

    detailed cost estimates for Britain appear reason-

    able and are consistent with other global deploy-

    ments. Therefore the key question should no

    longer be, are the cost estimates correct? but

    instead, are there sufficient benefits to justify

    the cost?

    The government has identified 17.4 billion

    of expected benefits from smart metering over

    the coming two decades, the lions share of which

    comes from operational efficiency improvements

    for suppliers, consumer energy reductions, and

    carbon savings.

    Smart meters enable consumption to be read

    remotely and with much greater accuracy. For

    suppliers this should mean reduced manual meter

    reading costs, and reduced costs associated with

    having fewer estimated and inaccurate bills. It

    should also no longer ever be necessary to replace

    the meter when a customer changes supplier or

    moves on to a prepayment tariff.

    Hard efficiency benefits such as these are

    estimated at more than 5 billion. Experience

    from elsewhere is that these benefits are achiev-

    able. Enel in Italy has publicly stated that it has

    seen a dramatic reduction in cash-cost per cus-

    tomer, with operational savings of 49 per cus-

    tomer per year more than four times the forecast

    British savings.

    Integral to the smart metering benefits case is

    the premise that providing customers with more

    accurate and timely information will result in

    behaviour change: consumers using less energy

    and shifting consumption to times when power

    is cheaper and greener. This should help save

    money in the short term and reduce the level of

    generation and network asset investment required

    in the future. The British business case assumes a

    reduction in domestic energy consumption of 2.8

    per cent. This is consistent, even slightly conserv-

    ative, when compared with publicly available datasuch as analysis by the US Pacific North West

    National Laboratory (PNNL). This estimates a 6

    per cent reduction.

    There is, however, a question mark about the

    longevity of changes in consumer behaviour, so

    provision of better information must be seen as a

    first step. To ensure that the full potential benefits

    are realised, effective consumer incentivisation

    through cost-reflective tariffs and smart devices

    which consume energy in a more intelligent way

    are necessary future steps.

    When such changes are put in place, the ben-

    efits can increase significantly. A pilot project run

    by PNNL integrating smart meters with smart

    devices and smart grids delivered reductions of 15

    per cent in peak power demand and 10 per cent in

    consumer energy bills.

    So it would seem that the expected benefits

    are achievable; conservative when compared with

    other deployments; and sufficient to justify the

    costs of introducing smart metering in Britain.

    Perhaps the subject that has attracted the most

    column inches is who should pay for smart meter-ing. Really, this is not the right question, because

    while the benefits to energy suppliers will cover

    some costs, ultimately most costs will be borne

    by the consumer. The right questions to ask are:

    who should finance the programme, and how and

    when should any costs not paid for by supplier

    benefits be passed on to consumers?

    Again, this is an area where Britain can learn

    from other markets, such as Ontario. Here, the

    regulator considered three payment options

    general taxation, up-front consumer payment,

    and financing with tariff-based recovery from

    consumers. They chose a tariff recovery model.

    utility week 18 June 2010 19lity week 18 June 2010 www.utilityweek.co.ukwww.utilityweek.co.uk

    The subject

    that has

    attracted the

    most column

    inches

    is whoshould pay

    for smart

    metering

    continued overleaf

    The onlyway is up

    ths s h frh n a mnh srs

    f ars n smar mrng

    n assan h

    International

    comparisons and

    research back

    up government

    gures suggesting

    the benefits of

    smart meters faroutweigh their

    costs, says Will

    Siddall

  • 8/8/2019 Smart Metering FINAL Revised

    2/2

    For Britain, payment through taxation is incon-

    sistent with a competitive utilities market, and

    asking consumers for up-front payment would

    be unpalatable and hard to enforce. It is therefore

    reasonable to assume a similar solution in Britain

    industry paying the bill with recovery over time

    from consumers.

    N

    ine billion pounds is a hefty bill for

    industry to foot, especially at a time

    of huge investment in areas such

    as nuclear power and renewables.

    This raises the likelihood of new investors being

    required. Attracting this investment should be

    achievable, but key to attracting finance at reason-

    able rates will be ensuring that the investment is

    seen as low risk. This will require a clear long-

    term industry plan, a stable and agreed functional

    specification, commercial meter interoperability

    and regulatory stability.

    Of course, even a great business case does not

    always translate into a successful project that ena-

    bles the benefits originally envisaged. Success isdependent on recognising and acting now in key

    areas to minimise cost and risk, and maximise

    benefits.

    One of the most significant assumptions made

    is the timing of deployment. Any delay to the

    expected 2013 start date will significantly reduce

    the benefits achieved. This requires an efficient

    and effective change programme with a strong

    central industry design function. Actions can also

    be taken to accelerate the deployment start date

    for example, defining the meter specification now.

    Once rollout has commenced, targets must be

    set that ensure suppliers do not delay deployment.

    Furthermore, Britain should be more aggressive

    in its deployment timescales. IBM analysis of 48

    global deployments shows a typical duration of

    four to six years, and that additional net benefits

    of more than 1 billion could be achieved if the

    British deployment was delivered in five years, not

    eight as proposed. Achieving this would require

    delivery excellence from suppliers, and appropri-

    ate incentives (and penalties) for them to install in

    those timeframes but again, this is nothing that

    has not already been achieved elsewhere.

    Imperative to efficient deployment and achiev-

    ing enduring energy and carbon savings is effec-

    tive consumer engagement. Government rightly

    identifies the value of consumer awareness cam-

    paigns and real-time energy displays in achieving

    this, but more is needed. Crucially, there must begreater awareness of the differences in behaviour

    among consumers. For example, IBM research

    shows that 27 per cent of consumers say that nei-

    ther money nor environmental concerns will make

    them change their consumption of energy. Would

    installing a real-time energy display in these cus-

    tomers homes deliver any benefit? Conversely,

    22 per cent of consumers want to take actions to

    change their energy usage, but are constrained

    by their available income. Should smart meter

    deployment target these customers first?

    If energy retailers in Britain are to see engage-

    ment with all consumer segments, they will need

    a range of approaches, from providing real-time

    consumption information to those who want to

    become engaged, to embedding energy man-

    agement intelligence in the consumer goods of

    those who have neither the time nor inclination to

    change their consumption behaviour.

    Finally, the opportunity for smart metering to

    act as a catalyst for improvements in the structure

    and processes of the utilities industry must not be

    overlooked. Changes such as harmonising gas andelectricity processes and data flows, improving

    the time it takes for a customer to change suppli-

    er, and ensuring infrastructure is able to support

    future smart water meters, are all changes that

    should be recognised now, even if they are deliv-

    ered in a later phase of work.

    So, does this business case for smart metering

    stack up? The answer has to be yes. The respon-

    sibility on government and the utilities industry

    now is to deliver, and deliver quickly.l

    Will Siddall is advanced analytics & optimisation

    leader, energy & utilities industry, IBM Global

    Business Services

    Email: [email protected]

    20 utility week 18 June 2010

    Smart metering

    continued from previous page

    wh shd fnan smar

    mrs, and h shd

    h ss b rvrd

    frm nsmrs?

    Hav r sa:...

    Key toattracting

    finance at

    reasonable

    rates willbe ensuring

    that the

    investment

    is seen aslow risk

    Sng s bvng: ra-m

    mnrng shd nrag

    nsmrs s ss nrg