SSRN-id1021070

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    1/39

    i

    A Discrete Choice Model of Dividend Reinvestment Plans:

    Classification and Prediction

    by

    Thomas P. Boehm Ramon P. DeGennaroSunTrust Professor of Finance CBA Professor of FinanceThe University of Tennessee The University of TennesseeKnoxville, TN 37996-0540 Knoxville, TN 37996-0540865-974-1723 [email protected] [email protected]

    Abstract

    We use a discrete choice recursive model to classify 629 companies with dividendreinvestment plans (DRIPs) in 1999 and 514 companies without them. Our modelclassifies 72.0% of companies correctly. We interpret misclassified companies as beinglikely to switch their plan status. For example, if financial data erroneously suggest that acompany should have had a DRIP in 1999, then we expect that it would be more likely toinstitute a plan than other companies in the sample. Data from 2004 support this conjecturefor firms that add DRIPs. Companies that add DRIPs tend to have higher levels of

    variables that control for management entrenchment except for common shares outstandingwhich tend to be lower, higher levels of variables that control for the ability to paydividends and higher payout ratios. Other factors that impact the likelihood of a companyhaving a DRIP include industry effects and the exchange on which the companys sharesare traded.

    August 2010

    Keywords: Dividend Reinvestment, Discrete Choice, Recursive.

    Not for quotation without permission.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    2/39

    - 1 -

    1. Introduction

    Dividend reinvestmentplans (DRIPs) allow investors to reinvest their dividends in

    additional shares of the same stock that paid the dividend.1

    Previous research suggests that

    firms that offer such plans differ from those that do not in systematic ways (DeGennaro,

    2003). Is it possible to use financial data to determine whether a firm will or will not offer

    a plan? And is it possible to take the next step and predict which firms will or will not offer

    plans in later years? The answer to both is yes. The financial characteristics of companies

    that offer DRIPs dodiffer from those that do not offer them. In addition, financial

    statements foreshadow changes in plan status up to five years before management adds a

    DRIP. If our model makes a correct prediction in 1999 then the chances are quite high that

    the prediction will hold for five years. If our model makes an incorrect prediction that a

    company should offer a DRIP, though, then the odds are much higher that there will be a

    reversal (in the model's favor) in five years such companies are much more likely to offer

    a DRIP. We interpret this as evidence that financial statements foreshadow changes in plan

    status.

    Our paper is therefore different in spirit from previous research on DRIPs. For

    example, some researchers have studied the value of specific plan terms to investors. Two

    key examples are Dammon and Spatt (1992), who calculate the value of an option implicit

    in share-purchase terms of certain DRIPs, and Scholes and Wolfson (1989), who analyze

    and report the success of their efforts to exploit a price discount provision incorporated in

    other plans. Another strand of research studies stock prices of companies that announce

    1For a thorough description of these plans and a discussion of why firms offer them, see DeGennaro (2003)and the references therein.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    3/39

    - 2 -

    plans (e.g. Dubofsky and Bierman (1988), Perumpral et al.(1991) and Dhillon et al.,

    (1992)). Still others have explored the interaction of DRIPs and the tax code. Chang and

    Nichols (1992), for example, investigate whether Internal Revenue Code Section 305(e)

    affects qualifying utilities. They study the cost of equity capital, leverage ratios and stock

    price reactions for firms offering DRIPs around the time of the changes in the tax code.

    Todd and Domian (1997) conduct a survey to relate plan characteristics to shareholder

    participation rates. To our knowledge, though, none has attempted to predict whether or

    not a company will have a DRIP in the future.

    These other lines of research are a perfect complement to our paper. We show that

    predictions of plan changes are possible using financial statements; previous papers show

    why our results are important. Our paper has useful managerial implications: Companies

    that administer direct investment plans, such as The Bank of New York Mellon

    Corporation, can identify firms most likely to be interested in becoming customers. The

    results of Dubofsky and Bierman (1988), Perumpral et al. (1991) and Dhillon et al., (1992)

    suggest that investors using our approach might be able to develop profitable trading

    strategies. Thus, our paper has potential wealth effects for investors as well as immediate

    managerial implications.

    We find that companies that have DRIPs tend to have higher payout ratios, higher

    returns on assets, higher earnings per share, more common shareholders, more common

    shares outstanding, but fewer common shares traded. These financial variables are shown

    to increase the likelihood that companies pay dividends and that they pay higher levels of

    dividends. The more likely it is that a company pays a dividend and the larger the dividend

    the greater the probability that the company will have a DRIP. In addition, we find that the

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    4/39

    - 3 -

    exchange in which a companys shares are traded and the industry in which it operates

    influence the likelihood that it will have a DRIP both indirectly through its impact on

    dividends and directly on the probability of a company having a DRIP. This is the first

    empirical evidence that dividend reinvestment plans might serve to insulate management

    from outside control.

    2. Data and Methodology

    Data are from The Guide to Dividend Reinvestment Plans(1999, 2004) and the

    Compustat and CRSP databases. We begin with 852 firms with available data in 1999 that

    offered DRIPs. Because DRIP firms tend to be much larger in terms of total assets than

    companies without such plans (DeGennaro, 2003), we match these 852 DRIP companies to

    a sample of firms without such plans, for a total of 1704 companies. We use total assets in

    1999 as our matching variable.

    Because the dependent variable in our analysis is discrete (1 = company had a DRIP

    at a particular time, 0 otherwise) Ordinary Least Squares regression is inappropriate for two

    reasons. First, because the regression analysis is linear, it is quite possible to estimate

    probabilities in the sample that are outside the (0,1) interval. In addition, the error terms in

    such a regression would be heteroskedastic. To avoid these problems we use a maximum

    likelihood logit model. This is the standard way to handle these problems. The logit model

    has the following form:

    PDRIP= 1/ (1 + e-Xii), (1)

    where: PDRIP = the probability the firm has a DRIP,

    Xi= a set of variables hypothesized to influence PDRIP,

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    5/39

    - 4 -

    i= a set of coefficients which represent the estimated impact of X ion PDRIP,

    Xii= 0+ X11+ X22+ + Xnn.

    Classification methods have a long history of productive uses in business and

    finance. These methods include models that use continuous variables as well as those that

    use discrete choice variables. Discrete choice models are probably more common. One

    form of discrete choice model is cluster analysis. Shaffer (1991), for example, studies

    federal deposit insurance funding and considers its influence on taxpayers. Multinomial

    logit, another discrete choice approach, has been used at least as far back as Holman and

    Marley (in Luce and Suppes, 1965). The development of multinomial logit estimation for

    use in the social sciences can be traced to the work of Dominic and McFadden (1975).

    3. Sample Statistics

    Table 1 presents the number of firms in each category partitioned by year and by

    plan status. In 1999 we have a size-matched sample of 852 companies, one of each pair

    offering a DRIP and one not offering a DRIP, for a total of 1704 companies. By 2004 the

    sample has shrunk considerably for typical reasons. Mergers or other corporate

    combinations along with delisting due to financial distress head the list. Only 916 firms

    with useable data remain in the sample. Of these, 465 have a plan and 451 do not. Of

    course, this masks movement across groups. Table 2 shows that most companies maintain

    their plan status, either not offering a plan in either year (387 of 916) or retaining a plan

    five years later (394 of 916). A moderate number do change their plan status, though. A

    total of 71 companies, or about 7.75 percent, add a plan within the five years and 64 of the

    916, or 6.99 percent, drop their plans.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    6/39

    - 5 -

    Factors Affecting the Likelihood of Having a DRIP

    Table 3 lists the independent variables included in our analysis. It also shows

    whether we expect companies that offer DRIPs to have higher or lower values in univariate

    tests (left column) and multivariate tests such as our recursive logit model (right column).

    Excluding total assets (the matching variable) and the categorical industry variables that we

    include as controls, our variables fall into four categories. These rely on DeGennaro

    (2003). We call variables in the first categoryfundamental variables, not in the sense of

    fundamental economic value, but rather because their economic meanings are

    fundamentally changed by a reinvestment plan. These are the payout ratio and the dividend

    yield. Consider two companies which are identical except that one has a plan and one does

    not. Suppose that the optimal dividend yield is 4 percent for both. The company without a

    DRIP simply pays a 4 percent yield. The DRIP company, though, cannot expect plan

    participants to retain all of their dividends. The DRIP company must offer a higher explicit

    yield to have an effective yield of 4 percent. The same reasoning applies to the payout

    ratio. All else equal, we expect DRIP companies to have higher explicit payout ratios and

    dividend yields.

    We call variables in the second group ability variablesbecause they control for the

    ability to pay dividends all else equal, firms that earn more can pay more . These

    variables are after-tax return on total assets (ROA) and earnings per share (EPS). Although

    the ability to pay dividends may not be directly related to the probability of having a DRIP,

    we expect the dividend yield itself to be a strong predictor of having a plan. These ability

    variables offer something that the yield itself does not. Specifically, to the extent that the

    ability to pay dividends affects the dividend yield in the future, these variables contain

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    7/39

    - 6 -

    information about future dividends that is not captured by the current yield. Therefore, the

    ability variables could provide indirect information about the likelihood of having a DRIP

    in the future.

    The third group controls for managerial entrenchment. DeGennaro (2003)

    speculates that one reason for the existence of DRIPs is that they can insulate management

    from threats to its control. Four variables fit this category: The number of common

    shareholders, the number of common shares outstanding, the number of common shares

    traded, and the number of employees. First, if management worries about retaining its

    control, then it prefers a diffuse shareholder base with many small shareholders. Because

    voting a proxy takes time, small shareholders are less likely to vote their shares. Second, as

    long as small shareholders do not get a large enough position to become activist

    shareholders, management wants them to have more voting shares. Third, our evidence

    shows that these small shareholders who participate in DRIPs tend to trade less frequently.

    Fourth, because employees jobs are often at risk during corporate reorganizations,

    employees have incentives to support current management in takeover battles. The

    anecdotal evidence in Rosen and Young (1991) supports the intuitive result that employees

    probably tend to vote with management in takeover battles. This means that management

    wants employees to be shareholders, too, so companies with many employees are more

    likely to institute a DRIP (in fact, sometimes plans have features that are quite favorable to

    employees and sometimes even restrict participation to employees). DRIP companies,

    therefore, should tend to have higher values for all of these variables except for the number

    of shares traded, which should be lower for DRIP firms.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    8/39

    - 7 -

    Finally, we control for the stocks trading venue. NASDAQ stocks are known to

    have higher trading volumes because they are traded differently than on exchanges such as

    the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) or the American Stock Exchange (AMEX). This

    could affect the estimated coefficient on the variable that controls for the number of

    common shares traded. Tests (not reported for space reasons) show that the influence of

    the NYSE and AMEX are comparable but differ from the NASDAQ and Other markets. In

    our logistic regression we control forNASDAQand Otherwhile the NYSE and AMEX

    serve as the excluded categories to prevent high collinearity.2 BecauseNASDAQand Other

    firms tend to be younger we expect the coefficient on these categories to be negative.

    Table 4 presents sample statistics and univariate tests. The first line for each

    variable is for all companies (up to 1704 non-missing values). The second line presents

    two numbers for each statistic; the first of each pair is for DRIP companies and the second

    is for No-DRIP companies. As is to be expected, most observations have missing

    observations for certain variables. Still, for the full sample of 1704 companies in 1999, we

    have upwards of 1300 observations for all variables. Most have more than 1550

    observations. Almost all observations on all variables lie within a reasonable range.

    Exceptions occur for certain ratios with denominators near zero. For example, Compustat

    defines the Payout Ratioas essentially the dollar amount of dividends paid to common

    shareholders divided by earnings. Because earnings can be near zero, ratios can be large in

    absolute value. Even these cases, though, are relatively rare. To overcome this problem in

    our tests below we report median tests as well as t-tests.

    2As a robustness check we experimented with a set of maturity variables comprising net sales, the debt ratio,the market-to-book ratio, and the price/earnings ratio (measured at fiscal year-end). These did not havestatistically reliable explanatory power.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    9/39

    - 8 -

    The second line for each variable lists the statistics for the DRIP sample and the No-

    DRIP sample. A superscripted asterisk on the No-DRIP mean indicates that the values

    differ at least at the 5 percent level according to a t-test and a superscripted pounds sign

    means that they differ at least at the 5 percent level according to a two-sample medians test.

    Ten t-tests are significant. Two of these are the fundamental variables, the Payout Ratio

    and theDividend Yield. This is no surprise; after all, we call these fundamental variables

    because the economic meaning of these variables is economically different for DRIP

    companies compared to No-DRIP companies. As expected given Table 3, the DRIP values

    are statistically and economically much higher. DRIP companies have an average payout

    ratio that is almost three times higher than No-DRIP companies (almost 52 percent

    compared to 18 percent). The average dividend yield for DRIP companies is about 2.5

    times higher (3.5 to 1.4). The effective payout ratios and dividend yields of DRIP

    companies, of course, are lower because some investors immediately reinvest a portion of

    the dividends in the companies stock.

    Both ability variables conform to the predictions of Table 3. After-Tax Return on

    Assetsis significantly higher for DRIP firms than for No-DRIP firms according to both the

    t-test and the medians test. The point estimate ofEarnings Per Shareis higher for DRIP

    firms, and the difference is significant according to the medians test.

    All four of the managerial entrenchment variables have the relationship predicted in

    Table 3, and three of the four are statistically significant according to the t-tests. DRIP

    companies have significantly more common shareholders, significantly fewer common

    shares traded, and significantly more employees. These can help entrench management if

    the additional shareholders tend to hold smaller stakes and trade less. These are well-

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    10/39

    - 9 -

    known traits of DRIP investors. This result also supports Rosen and Youngs (1991)

    suggestion that employees probably tend to vote with management in takeover battles.

    The variables that control for the trading venue for the stocks are also statistically

    different between DRIP and No-DRIP firms. Stocks which trade on NASDAQ or fit in the

    Othercategory (that is, stocks not on NASDAQ, the New York Stock Exchange, or the

    American Stock Exchange) are statistically less likely to have a DRIP.

    Finally, DeGennaro (2003) shows that DRIP firms cluster by industry. To control

    for this we include variables that control for SIC code. Table 4 contains sample statistics

    for the following eight one-digit SIC categories: (1) Mining, oil production and

    construction, (2) Materials processing, (3) Manufacturing, (4) Transportation utilities and

    waste disposal, (5) Wholesale and retail activity, (6) Financial services, (7) Other services,

    and (8) Other miscellaneous. It is important to note that the dummy variable that we

    exclude from the regression, Other services, includes medical legal, social and

    accounting services.3 We include these industry variables in our subsequent multivariate

    analysis as control variables.

    The medians tests generally agree with the t-tests. They differ for three variables

    plus one industry control. Medians tests find a significant difference for earnings per share.

    They fail to find significance in the number of common shares traded and the number of

    employees. Among the industry controls, the t-test and medians test disagree only for

    Manufacturing. Manufacturing firms have significantly higher incidences of DRIPS

    according to the medians test.

    3There are so few in this category that they would not have provided meaningful results.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    11/39

    - 10 -

    Table 5 contains Pearson correlations for the variables. Statistically significant

    correlations are pervasive for most variables. The Payout Ratiohas the fewest significant

    correlations, with two. Finding that many variables are highly correlated is not surprising

    given that many variables are ratios which share either a numerator or denominator with

    other variables. For example, after-tax earnings are in the denominator of the payout ratio

    as well as in the numerator ofAfter-Tax ROA. This could produce multicollinearity in our

    regressions, which would inflate the standard errors. Fortunately, this is a question of

    power, not consistency. Our multivariate logit estimates will still be unbiased and

    consistent.

    4. Logit Results

    Table 4 shows that certain firm-specific variables systematically differ between

    DRIP firms and no-DRIP firms. DeGennaro (2003) shows that DRIP firms cluster by

    industry. Based on this information it might seem as if a reasonable logit specification

    would be:

    0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

    18

    8 9 10 11 12

    i i i i i i i i

    i i i i j i

    DRIP TA PR DY ROA EPS CS CSout

    CST Emp NASDAQ Other Industry

    (1)

    where the subscript isignifies the company and:

    DRIPi= 1 if company ihas a DRIP;else 0

    CSouti= number of common sharesoutstanding (000,000)

    TAi= total assets ($000,000) CSTi= number of common shares traded

    (000,000/yr.)PRi= payout ratio (%) Empi= number of employees (000)DYi= dividend yield (%) NASDAQi= unity if traded on NASDAQ; else

    zeroROAi= after-tax return on total assets (%) Otheri= unity if not traded on NYSE, AMEX

    or NASDAQ; else zeroEPSi= earnings per share ($) 22

    16 jIndustry = seven one-digit SIC codes

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    12/39

    - 11 -

    (see text)CSi= number of common shareholders(000)

    i = logistically i.i.d.error term

    This specification is problematic, though. Whether or not a firm pays a dividend

    (i.e., has some positive dividend yield as opposed to having a dividend yield of zero) might

    be expected to be a primary determinant of whether or not a firm would be expected to

    have a DRIP. In addition, the remaining variables in equation (1) above might be expected

    to be predictors of the likelihood that a firm pays a dividend and the magnitude of the

    dividends they pay. Finally, the relationship between a firms dividend yield and the

    likelihood of having a DRIP might be non-linear, that is, the difference between a yield of 0

    percent and 0.1 percent is probably much more influential than the difference between, say,

    2.0 percent and 2.1 percent.4 Consequently, for the purpose of this analysis we represent

    the dividend yield as a categorical variable based on its distribution in our sample. Each

    firm falls into one of four dividend yield categories: 1) zero dividend yield, 2) dividend

    yield greater than zero, but less than or equal to 1.5 percent, 3) dividend yield greater than

    1.5 percent, but less than or equal to 3.3 percent, and 4) dividend yield greater than 3.3

    percent. We choose these three categories of dividend yield to allocate an equal number of

    the dividend-paying stocks to each category. Our model then is specified to be recursive in

    nature. Specifically, initially the probability of a firm being in one of the dividend yield

    categories is estimated to be a function of the variables other than dividend yield in

    equation (1) above. Subsequently, the likelihood of a firm having a DRIP is estimated to be

    4Fourteen companies had a DRIP in 1999, dropped it by 2004 and did not pay a dividend in 2004. Forcomparison, only one company that had a zero yield in 1999 dropped its plan and had a positive yield in 2004.Three companies had a zero yield in 1999, added a plan and had a positive yield in 2004. Finally, twocompanies had a positive yield in 1999, added plan and had a zero yield in 2004.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    13/39

    - 12 -

    a function of their dividend yield category and a subset of the financial variables in

    equation (1) above.5 A recursive structure implies that one decision precedes another. In

    this case, it seems reasonable that a firms managers would only consider instituting a

    DRIP if the company were paying dividends, or had made a decision to do so. For an

    excellent discussion of recursive models with qualitative endogenous variables, see

    Maddala and Lee (1976).

    This structure proves to predict whether or not firms have plans quite well and also

    allows us to compute the marginal influence of variables on the decision. Formally, our

    logit model that predicts whether a company offers a DRIP is:

    0 1 2 3 4

    12

    5 6,

    L M H

    i i i i i

    i j i i

    DRIP DIV DIV DIV NASDAQ

    Other Industry

    where:

    L

    iDIV = 1 if 0 < dividend yield of stock i1.5%, else 0;M

    iDIV = 1 if 1.5% < dividend yield of stock i3.3%, else 0;

    HiDIV = 1 if 3.3% < dividend yield of stock i, else 0;

    iNASDAQ = 1 if stock itrades on NASDAQ, else 0;

    iOther=1 if stock itrades does not trade on NASDAQ, NYSE or AMEX, else 0;

    iIndustry = 1 if stock iis a member of Mining, Oil and Construction; Materials

    Processing; Manufacturing; Transportation, Utilities and Waste Disposal;Wholesale and Retail; Financial Services; Other Miscellaneous;respectively, else 0.

    The second part of the recursive structure models the three categories of dividend

    yield. This logit model writes the dividend yield as a function of the variables in Table 3.

    The model is:

    5Initially, all variables were included in the estimation and only those were retained that were demonstratedto have a statistically significant direct impact on DRIP when the dividend yield variables were included inthe equation.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    14/39

    - 13 -

    0 1 2 3 4 5 6

    16

    7 8 9 10

    i i i i i i i

    i i i j i

    DividendYield PR ROA EPS CS CSout CST

    Emp NASDAQ Other Industry

    Intuitively, the recursive structure models the decision to offer a DRIP as a function

    of variables including the dividend yield category; the dividend yield category is in turn

    modeled as a function of the fundamental variables, ability variables, managerial

    entrenchment variables, the stocks trading venue, and industry effects.

    Companies with a dividend yield of zero comprise the excluded category for the

    logit model. The first column of Table 6A contains the results using 1999 data. The

    middle column contains the logit coefficient estimate and the third column contains

    asymptotic t-statistics. This portion of the recursive model produces anR2of over 50

    percent and the coefficients on the dividend yield categories and exchange have the

    predicted signs (we have no predicted signs for industry variables). In addition, the higher

    the dividend yield category, the larger the coefficient. Stocks that pay higher dividends are

    more likely to have DRIPs. The gradual increase in the size of the coefficients as the

    magnitude of the dividend yield increases is exactly what one would expect (3.103, 3.583,

    and 4.334). Three of the seven industry effects are significant at least at the 5 percent level

    and another is significant at the 10 percent level. Both exchange variables have negative

    signs and Otheris significant at the 1% level.

    Table 6B reports the results of the model that predicts the dividend yield category

    for each stock. Again, stocks with a dividend yield of zero comprise the excluded category.

    The model produces anR2of almost 48%. Excluding Industry Effect variables, all

    variables are significant at least at the 5 percent level for at least one dividend category. All

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    15/39

    - 14 -

    except the number of employees are significant for at least two dividend categories.

    Overall, 22 of 27 coefficients are significant at least at the 5 percent level. Because all

    dividend categories in Table 6A have positive coefficients, the coefficients in Table 6B

    should have the signs predicted in Table 3. For example, the Payout Ratio has a positive

    influence on the dividend yield, which in turn has a positive influence on the likelihood of

    having a DRIP. This means that the Payout Ratio has a positive influence on the likelihood

    of having a DRIP. Table 6B shows that all but one of the 27 coefficients have the predicted

    sign.

    How can we best interpret these results? Analyzing each group of variables is a

    good starting point. All four of the variable groups conform quite well to our predictions in

    Table 3. For example, the Payout Ratio is correctly signed for all three categories and the

    statistical reliability is very strong in the two higher dividend yield categories (we address

    economic significance in Table 7). Five of the six coefficients on the ability variables are

    correctly signed, with EPS for the highest dividend yield the only coefficient signed

    incorrectly in the entire table. The single incorrect coefficient is economically small and

    statistically insignificant. A possible explanation is that EPS is highly correlated with

    another variable or combination of variables, making it difficult to separate their

    contributions to explaining variation. All nine of the management entrenchment variables

    dealing with ownership (the number of common shareholders, the number of common

    shares outstanding and the number of common shares traded) are correctly signed and

    significant, most at well beyond the one-percent critical value. The fourth variable in this

    category, the number of employees, is correctly signed for all three dividend yield

    categories and is significant for the highest dividend yield category. The Exchange

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    16/39

    - 15 -

    variables are always correctly signed and statistically significant. Companies that trade on

    NASDAQ or Other (not on NASDAQ, NYSE or AMEX) are less likely to have DRIPs.

    The recursive model in Tables 6A and 6B correctly classifies companies with

    DRIPs slightly better than companies without them. For DRIP firms the correct

    classification rate is 69.2 percent (435 out of 629) and for No-DRIP firms the rate is 75.5

    percent (388 out of 514). Overall, the rate of correct classifications is 72.0 percent (823 out

    of 1143).

    Which Groups of Independent Variables Drive the Result?

    Table 7 uses the recursive model in Tables 6A and 6B and 1999 data to present two

    other ways to gain insight about the implications of our model. Panel A reports results for

    companies with no DRIP in 1999 and Panel B reports results for companies with a DRIP in

    1999. The top part of each panel reports the mean predicted probability of having a DRIP

    for companies that had no plan five years later, in 2004 (second column), and for

    companies that did have one in 2004 (third column).

    The 464 companies that did not have a DRIP in 2004 had a predicted mean

    probability of having a DRIP of 30.06 percent, whereas the 50 companies that did have a

    DRIP in 2004 had a mean probability of having a DRIP of 56.25 percent. The t-statistic for

    the difference in these means is 3.84. and the difference is also an economically significant

    26.2 percentage points. This means that on average, misclassified firms are much closer to

    being correctly classified than the correct classifications are to being misclassified. This is

    evidence that the model is picking up factors in the financial statements that foreshadow the

    change in DRIP status.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    17/39

    - 16 -

    The second parts of Panel A and Panel B report the contribution of each of the five

    variable subgroups (fundamental, ability, managerial entrenchment, exchange, and industry

    effects) to the difference between those mean predicted probabilities. This difference in

    these predicted probabilities of having a DRIP derives from the differences in mean values

    for the independent variables rather than the estimated coefficients in the model. For

    example, given the positive coefficient on the payout ratio, a higher payout ratio implies

    that there is a higher probability of having a DRIP. Thus we can calculate the impact of

    each variable group on this difference between the 30.06 percent average likelihood of not

    having a DRIP and the 56.25 percent average likelihood of having a DRIP. In the second

    part of Panel A in Table 7,we see that differences in Managerial Entrenchment variables

    (11.49 percentage points) are the largest component of this differential. This implies that if

    the mean values for the Fundamental variables for No-DRIP firms in 2004 are increased to

    the level of firms that have a DRIP in 2004, their predicted likelihood of having a DRIP

    increases by 11.49 percentage points. This would increase the predicted probability of

    having a DRIP for this group by more than a third (an 11.49 percentage point increase over

    the 30.06 percent probability for firms adding a DRIP by 2004). The changes associated

    with the other classes of variables are smaller although still important, ranging from 3.37

    percentage points for the Exchange variables to 5.64 percentage points for the Industry

    Effects variables.

    The results for firms that did have a DRIP in 1999 are in Panel B of Table 7. The

    mean predicted probability of having a DRIP is lower for firms that drop their DRIP

    (second column) compared to those that retain a DRIP in 2004 (third column), although the

    difference is statistically insignificant. The difference is 63.86 percent versus 67.91

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    18/39

    - 17 -

    percent, with a t-statistic of 0.14. Although the recursive model misclassifies almost a

    quarter of the DRIP companies in 2004 using 1999 data (150 out of 629), those companies

    do have a lower likelihood of having a DRIP.

    As is true for the companies that have a DRIP in 1999, the variables controlling for

    Managerial Entrenchment are the most important, although the contributions are much

    smaller. The 1.65 percentage point influence accounts for 40.72 percent of the difference

    between the two means. The second most influential set of variables are those that control

    for the ability to pay a dividend, which accounts for 1.34 percentage points, or 33.09

    percent, of the differential.

    The importance of managerial entrenchment variables in the decision to add or drop

    a DRIP merits mention because entrenched management has been linked to lower firm

    value. Bebchuk and Cohen (2005), for example, show that staggered boards (a common

    governance arrangement that insulates managers from dismissal) are associated with lower

    corporate values. Ryngaert (1988) finds similar (though weaker) results for poison pills.

    Futureresearch would do well to explore whether companies that institute a DRIP to

    entrench management suffer stock price declines while those that do so for other reasons do

    not. This might explain the conflicting evidence researchers have found concerning the

    stock price reaction around the announcement that a company will institute a DRIP. For

    example, Dubofsky and Bierman (1988) and Perumpral et al.(1991) find evidence of

    positive abnormal returns when companies announce that they will institute a DRIP while

    Dhillon et al.(1992) find evidence of losses. Peterson et al.(1987) find mixed results.

    Perhaps these latter studies had higher proportions of firms that instituted plans for reasons

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    19/39

    - 18 -

    of corporate control. Estimating abnormal returns after controlling for the reason for

    instituting the DRIP is likely to be fruitful.

    Our analysis demonstrates that a firms payout ratio, its ability to pay dividends, the

    degree of a firms managerial entrenchment, the trading venue of a firms equity shares, and

    the industry in which it operates influence whether or not dividends are paid and the

    magnitude of those dividends. Thus, they indirectly influence the likelihood that a firm has

    a DRIP. In the case of the firms stock trading venue and industry there is also a direct

    impact on the likelihood that a firm will have a DRIP holding dividends constant. Given

    these results, the question that remains is how well can we predict changes in plan status?

    Predicting Changes in DRIP Status

    Consider companies that the logistic model misclassifies; either the model says that

    they should have a plan and they do not, or it says that they should not have a plan and they

    do. How do we interpret this? One way is to conclude that the model simply fails in such

    cases. An alternative interpretation is that financial statements contain information about

    futureplan status as well as currentplan status. Under this interpretation, misclassified

    companies are more likely to switch their plan status. That is, if the firms financial data

    suggest that a company should have had a dividend reinvestment plan in 1999 but it did

    not, then we expect that it would be more likely to institute a plan than the other companies

    in the sample. Conversely, if it did have a plan but the financial data suggest that it should

    not, then we expect that the company would be more likely to drop the plan. Put

    differently, misclassifications in 1999 include predictions of changes in plan status as well

    as classification errors.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    20/39

    - 19 -

    Do the data support this interpretation? For No-DRIP companies the answer is yes.

    Figure 1 illustrates the result. A total of 641 companies have data available in both 1999

    and 2004. Figure 1 shows the transition matrix of these 641 firms. First, consider the left

    side of Figure 1.

    Our model uses data from financial statements available in 1999 to classify 641

    firms that survived and have data through 2004. These include 288 No-DRIP firms and

    353 DRIP firms in 1999. Of these, a total of 438 (203 No-DRIP firms plus 235 DRIP

    firms) are classified correctly and 203 (118 DRIP firms plus 85 No-DRIP firms) are

    classified incorrectly, for an overall classification accuracy of 68.33 percent, which is

    almost exactly the same as the classification rate of 66.50 percent for all firms in 1999.

    One interpretation of this is that the model has simply made 203 mistakes, putting No-

    DRIP firms in the DRIP category and vice versa. Another interpretation, though, is that the

    1999 financial statements of these companies already foreshadow changes in the

    companies characteristics changes that would place the firms in the other DRIP category

    by 2004. This would be the case if some firms gradually adopt the economic traits that

    characterize the other class and if the financial statements reflect this drift before

    management decides to change plan status and implements the decision.

    The right side of Figure 1 shows that this interpretation has merit. For No-DRIP

    firms, 21.2 percent of those predicted to have a DRIP in 1999 establish one by 2004 while

    only 9.9 percent of firms correctly classified as No-DRIP in 1999 establish a DRIP by

    2004. This means that if the model incorrectly says that a company looks like a DRIP firm,

    then that firm is more than twice as likely to establish a DRIP as a company that was

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    21/39

    - 20 -

    correctly classified as a No-DRIP firm. Apparently, the firms financial statements begin to

    foreshadow the transition to a DRIP firm before management institutes a plan.

    For DRIP firms, the model correctly classifies 235 of the 353 surviving DRIP firms,

    leaving 118 misclassifications in 1999, for a success rate of 66.6 percent. Almost 6 percent

    of the incorrectly classified DRIP firms discontinue their DRIP programs by 2004 while

    10.6 percent of the correct predictions on DRIP firms in 1999 no longer have a DRIP by

    2004. This means that if the model incorrectly says that a company looks like a No-DRIP

    firm, then it is less likely to eliminate its DRIP than a company that was correctly classified

    as a DRIP firm. The model cannot predict which companies will eliminate DRIPS.

    Overall, 25 of 203 (12.3 percent) misclassifications in 1999 self-correct by 2004,

    which is two percentage points higher than the percentage of classifications that go bad.

    Only 45 of 438 (10.3 percent) of correct classifications go bad during the same period.

    Figure 1 shows that if our model makes a correct prediction in 1999 then the chances are

    quite high that the prediction will hold for five years. If our model makes an incorrect

    prediction, though, the odds are much higher that there will be a reversal (in the model's

    favor) in five years. Financial statements apparently do foreshadow changes in plan status.

    The ability to predict changes in plan status is concentrated entirely on companies that add

    DRIPs.

    To investigate this formally we conduct a two-pronged experiment. In the first part,

    we consider the companies that do not have a DRIP in 1999 and explore whether they add

    one by 2004. In the second part, we consider companies that have a DRIP in 1999 and

    explore whether they drop it by 2004. These two groups of firms should have different

    financial characteristics.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    22/39

    - 21 -

    In the first part of this experiment we partition the 288 surviving companies that did

    not have a DRIP in 1999 into those that our model correctly classifies and those that it

    misclassifies. We compute the proportion of each group that added a plan by 2004 and test

    the difference between them. If the 1999 financial statements contain information about

    future plan status, then the companies that the model misclassifies as having a plan in 1999

    should add plans significantly more often. To perform the second part of this experiment

    we partition the 353 surviving companies that had a DRIP in 1999 into those that the model

    correctly classifies and those that it misclassifies. We then compute the proportion of each

    group that dropped their plans by 2004 and test the difference between them. If the 1999

    financial statements contain information about future plan status, then the companies that

    the model misclassifies as not having a plan in 1999 should drop their plans significantly

    more often.

    Table 8 reports the results of this experiment. If our model does a good job of

    prediction, then we would expect that firms that actually had a DRIP in 2004 would be

    more likely to be predicted to have a DRIP by our model. That clearly is the case for the

    No-DRIP sub-sample (Panel A). Specifically, 18 of the 38 companies that did not have a

    DRIP in 1999 but were predicted to have one initiated a DRIP by 2004 (47.37%); while

    only 67 of 250 firms that did not have a DRIP by 2004 were incorrectly predicted to have

    one (26.80%). This difference in proportions is statistically significant (t-ratio = -2.59). In

    contrast, Panel B shows that 25 of the 32 firms that the model predicted to have a DRIP did

    not have one in 2004 even though they had a DRIP in 1999 (78.13 percent); whereas 210 of

    321 firms that that had a DRIP in 1999 and 2004 were predicted to have a DRIP (65.42

    percent). This means that the model fails to improve predictions of which firms will drop

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    23/39

    - 22 -

    their DRIPs. Our model obviously does a much better job of differentiating between those

    firms that might be expected to establish a DRIP program versus those that would be

    predicted to drop an existing DRIP.

    These results have an immediate managerial implication. Suppose that a firm which

    manages DRIPs wants to solicit new business. Can our model help? The answer is yes.

    To demonstrate this, suppose that we identify a large number of firms that currently do not

    have a DRIP program, but which (because of their financial position) we expect to survive

    for up to five years. We would like to identify potential clients because such solicitation is

    a costly process. If we were to contact allof the 288 firms we identified that currently do

    not have a DRIP, we would find that only about 38 (13.2 percent) would establish a DRIP

    over the next 5 years. However, if we used our model to determine which firms to target,

    we would contact only 85 firms (about 29.5 percent) of the 288 No-DRIP firms. Of those

    85 firms, 18 (21.1 percent) would actually add a DRIP. These 18 firms would represent

    about 47.4 percent (18 of 38) of the entire population of No-DRIP firms that might be

    expected to actually establish a DRIP program over the next several five years. In short, we

    would uncover almost half of the companies that do eventually adopt a DRIP despite

    contacting fewer than 30 percent of the likely customers. This would represent a huge

    reduction in search costs and seems to be an effective way to minimize marketing expenses.

    5. Summary

    Most research on dividend reinvestment plans has focused on stock-price responses

    to the announcements of such plans or has attempted to value certain plan features. To

    date, little research has attempted to determine which type of firm adopts a plan, and none

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    24/39

    - 23 -

    has attempted to predict whether companies will have a plan in the future. This paper fills

    that void. We use discrete choice methods to predict the classification of 1704 companies:

    A sample of 852 companies with dividend reinvestment plans in 1999 matched by total

    assets to a sample of 852 companies without such plans. We develop a logit model that

    successfully classifies over 72 percent (823 of 1143) of these companies yet uses only

    readily available contemporaneous financial data. Our analysis demonstrates that a firms

    Payout Ratio, a set of variables measuring the firms ability to pay dividends, a set of

    variables measuring the degree of managerial entrenchment for a given firm, the trading

    venue of a firms equity, and the industry in which the firm operates play a role in

    determining whether or not the firm has a DRIP. The channel of influence is through

    dividends -- these variables influence whether the firm pays a dividend and the magnitude

    of the dividend paid (Table 6B). In turn, these categorical dividend-yield variables are of

    primary importance in explaining the presence of a DRIP (Table 6A). In addition to these

    indirect effects through variables that control for the dividend yield, variables that control

    for the trading venue of the firms equity and industry differentials have a significant direct

    influence on the likelihood that a firm has a DRIP as well.

    In addition, by interpreting the misclassified companies as those being likely to

    switch their plan status, we can then test whether the model can predict changes in plan

    status. The underlying premise is that a companys current financial data contain

    information not only about whether a company currently has a dividend reinvestment plan,

    but also that they contain information about future plan status. We use data from 1999 and

    2004 to explore this conjecture. We find that our model can predict plan adoption over the

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    25/39

    - 24 -

    next five years. This implies that financial statements contain information about changes in

    plan status at least five year in the future.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    26/39

    - 25 -

    References

    Chang, Otto H. and Donald R. Nichols. 1992. Tax Incentives and Capital Structures: The

    Case of the Dividend Reinvestment Plan.Journal of Accounting Research30: 109-125.

    Dammon, Robert M. and Chester S. Spatt. 1992. An Option-Theoretic Approach to theValuation of Dividend Reinvestment and Voluntary Purchase Plans. The Journal ofFinance47: 331-347.

    DeGennaro, Ramon P. 2003. Direct Investments: A Primer.Economic Review88: 1-14.

    Dhillon, Upinder S., Dennis J. Lasser and Gabriel G. Ramirez. 1992. DividendReinvestment Plans: An Empirical Analysis.Review of Quantitative Finance and

    Accounting : 205-213.

    Dubofsky, D. and Bierman, L. 1988. The Effect of Discount Dividend Reinvestment PlanAnnouncements on Equity Value.Akron Business and Economic Review 1 :58-68.

    Dominic, T. and McFadden, D. 1975. Urban Travel Demand: A Behavioral Analysis. InContributions to Economic AnalysisJ. Tinbergen, D. W. Jorgenson, and J. Waelbroeck(ed.) North-Holland / American Elsevier: New York.

    Guide to Dividend Reinvestment Plans (1999). Temper of the Times Communications, Inc.New York.

    Guide to Dividend Reinvestment Plans (2004). Temper of the Times Communications, Inc.New York.

    Luce, R. D. and Suppes, P. 1965. Preference, Utility and Subjective Probability. InHandbook of Mathematical PsychologyR. D. Luce, R. R. Bush, and E. Galanter (ed).J. Wiley and Sons: New York.

    Maddala G.S. and Lung-Fei Lee. 1976. Recursive Models with Qualitative EndogenousVariables. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 5: 525-546.

    Perumpral, Shalini, Arthur J. Keown and John Pinkerton. 1991. Market Reaction to theFormulation of Automatic Dividend Reinvestment Plans.Review of Business andEconomic Research 26 :48-58.

    Peterson, Pamela P., David R. Peterson and Norman H. Moore. 1987. The Adoption ofNew-Issue Dividend Reinvestment Plans and Shareholder Wealth.TheFinancialReview22 : 221-232.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    27/39

    - 26 -

    Rosen, Corey M. and Karen M. Young. Understanding employee ownership. CornellUniversity, Ithaca, NY. 1991.

    Ryngaert, Michael. 1988. The Effect of Poison Pill Securities on Shareholder Wealth.Journal of Financial Economics 20: 377-417.

    Scholes, Myron S. and Mark A. Wolfson. 1989. Decentralized Investment Banking: theCase of Discount Dividend-Reinvestment and Stock-Purchase Plans.Journal ofFinancial Economics 23: 7-35.

    Shaffer, Sherrill. 1991. Aggregate Deposit Insurance Funding and Taxpayer Bailouts.Journal of Banking and Finance 15 : 1019-1037.

    Smith, Clifford W., Jr. and Ross L. Watts. 1992. The Investment Opportunity Set andCorporate Financing, Dividend, and Compensation Policies.Journal of FinancialEconomics 32 : 263-292.

    Todd, Janet M. and Dale L. Domian. 1997. Participations Rates of Dividend ReinvestmentPlans: Differences Between Utility and Nonutility Firms.Review of FinancialEconomics 6: 121-135.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    28/39

    - 27 -

    288 No-DRIP firms

    641 firms with data for the logit model in both years

    203 correct

    classifications

    85 incorrect

    classifications

    Status in 2004

    183 correct

    classifications

    Status in 1999

    20 incorrect classifications

    67 incorrect classifications

    18 correct classifications

    Establish DRIP

    (Go bad): 9.9%

    Establish DRIP

    (Self-correcting): 21.2%

    353 DRIP firms

    235 correct

    classifications

    118 incorrect

    classifications

    Eliminate DRIP

    (Go bad): 10.6%

    Eliminate DRIP

    (Self-correcting): 5.9%

    210 correct

    classifications

    25 incorrect classifications

    118 incorrect classifications7 correct classifications

    Figure 1

    Apparent model error, or forecasting?

    Among firms with complete data for the logit model, a total of 288 firms do not have a

    DRIP in 1999 and survive through 2004. Of these, the model correctly classifies 203 firmsas not having a DRIP in 1999. Only 9.9 percent of these add a DRIP by 2004. In contrast,the model incorrectly classifies 85 firms as having a DRIP in 1999. Of these, 21.2 percentestablish a DRIP by 2004. This means that if the model incorrectly says that a companylooks like a DRIP firm, then that firm is more than twice as likely to add a DRIP as acompany that was correctly classified as a No-DRIP firm.

    Among firms with complete data for the logit model, a total of 353 firms have a DRIP in1999 and survive through 2004. Of these, the model correctly classifies 235 firms ashaving a DRIP in 1999. Only 10.6 percent of these eliminate their DRIP by 2004. Incontrast, the model incorrectly classifies 118 firms as not having a DRIP in 1999. Of these,5.9 percent eliminate their DRIP by 2004. This means that if the model incorrectly saysthat a company looks like a No-DRIP firm, then that firm is less likely to eliminate itsDRIP than a company that was correctly classified as a DRIP firm.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    29/39

    - 28 -

    Table 1

    Number of firms by year and plan status

    Number of Companies

    Year

    with Dividend

    Reinvestment Plans

    without Dividend

    Reinvestment Plans

    Total

    1999 852 852 1704

    2004 465 451 916

    Table 2

    Plan status of the 916 surviving firms in 1999 and 2004

    Plan Status in

    Years 1999 and 2004

    Number of

    companies

    Percent of

    total surviving

    firms

    Neither 1999 nor 2004 387 42.25%

    Not 1999 but 2004 71 7.75%

    1999 but not 2004 64 6.99%

    Both 1999 and 2004 394 43.01%

    Total Surviving Companies 916 100%

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    30/39

    - 29 -

    Table 3

    Expected relation between financial statement data for companies with DRIPs

    compared to companies without DRIPs in univariate and multivariate tests

    Variable

    Expected relation between variable and

    the likelihood of having a DRIP

    Univariate Tests Multivariate Tests

    TotalAssets N/A (matching variable)

    Fundamental Variables

    Payout Ratio Higher Higher

    Dividend Yield Higher Higher

    Ability Variables

    After Tax Return on Total Assets Higher Higher

    Earnings Per Share Higher Higher

    Managerial Entrenchment Variables

    Number of Common Shareholders Higher Higher

    Number of Common Shares Outstanding Higher Higher

    Number of Common Shares Traded Lower Lower

    Number of Employees Higher Higher

    Trading Venue Variables

    NASDAQ Lower Lower

    Other Lower Lower

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    31/39

    - 30 -

    Table 4Sample Statistics, 1999 Data, 1704 Firms in Operation in 1999

    Variable N Mean

    TotalAssets ($MM) Full Sample 1703 14,648

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 851 14,353 14,944 45,27Fundamental Variables

    Payout Ratio (%) Full Sample 1649 35.02

    DRIP,No DRIP 827 822 51.81 18.12*# 112.7Dividend Yield (%) Full Sample 1576 2.55

    DRIP,No DRIP 851 725 3.53 1.40*# 3.60

    Ability VariablesAfter Tax Return on Total Assets (%) Full Sample 1704 2.65

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 852 3.87 1.43*# 7.21Earnings Per Share ($) Full Sample 1621 1.69

    DRIP,No DRIP 851 770 1.73 1.64# 1.97

    Managerial Entrenchment Variables

    Common Shareholders (000) Full Sample 1303 38.14 DRIP,No DRIP 666 637 51.44 24.23*# 202.2

    Common Shares Outstanding (000,000)Full Sample

    1657 198.80

    DRIP,No DRIP 849 808 211.86 185.09 507.8Common Shares Traded (000,000/yr.)Full Sample 1574 168.98

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 722 144.93 197.36* 389.4Employees (000) Full Sample 1526 21.91

    DRIP,No DRIP 771 755 24.69 19.07* 66.14

    Exchange VariablesNASDAQ Full Sample 1704 0.26

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 852 0.23 0.30*# 0.42Other Full Sample 1704 0.09

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 852 0.00 0.18*# 0.05

    Industry Effects Variables Mining, Oil, & Construction Full Sample 1704 0.03

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 852 0.03 0.04 0.16

    Table continues on the next page

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    32/39

    - 31 -

    Continued from the previous page

    Materials Processing Full Sample 1704 0.15

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 852 0.19 0.12*# 0.39Manufacturing Full Sample 1704 0.17

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 852 0.18 0.15#

    0.39Transportation, Utilities, and Waste Disposal

    Full Sample1704 0.17

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 852 0.17 0.17 0.38Wholesale and Retail Full Sample 1704 0.07

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 852 0.07 0.07 0.25Financial Services Full Sample 1704 0.31

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 852 0.31 0.31 0.46Other Services Full Sample 1704 0.06

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 852 0.02 0.10*# 0.16Other Miscellaneous Full Sample 1704 0.01

    DRIP,No DRIP 852 852 0.01 0.01 0.08

    The top line of each variable contains values for the full sample of DRIP and No-DRIP firms. The second line The first of the pair pertains to DRIP firms and the second to No-DRIP firms.*indicates that the difference between the DRIP and No-DRIP means is significant at least at the 5% level using a t-test.#indicates that the difference between the DRIP and No-DRIP medians is significant at least at the 5% level using a two-s

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    33/39

    - 32 -

    Table 5

    Pearson Correlations

    TotalAssets

    PayoutRatio

    DividendYield

    After-TaxROA

    EPS# Common

    Shareholders

    # CommonShares

    Outstanding

    # CommonSharesTraded

    Number ofEmployees NAS

    TotalAssets 1

    Payout Ratio 0.010 1

    DividendYield

    -0.039 0.138* 1

    After Tax ROA -0.008 0.032 0.063* 1

    EPS 0.046 0.010 0.011 0.156* 1

    # CommonShareholders

    0.260* 0.021 -0.016 0.058* 0.021 1

    # CommonShares

    Outstanding0.373* 0.014 -0.010* 0.167* -0.006 0.528* 1

    # CommonSharesTraded

    0.171* -0.023 -0.133* 0.155* -0.011 0.285* 0.668* 1

    # Employees 0.308* 0.006 -0.078* 0.093* 0.013 0.300* 0.482* 0.247* 1

    NASDAQ -0.140* -0.035 -0.127* -0.140* -0.068* -0.079* -0.115* 0.046 -0.148*

    Other 0.097* -0.051* -0.101* -0.138* 0.134* -0.035 0.000 -0.028 0.035 -0.1

    *indicates significance at the 5% level.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    34/39

    - 33 -

    Table 6A12

    0 1 2 3 4 5 6,L M Hi i i i i i j i i

    DRIP DIV DIV DIV NASDAQ Other Industry Logit Coefficients and

    Asymptot ic t-statistics

    Pr(Drip=1)1999 Data

    Variable Coefficient t-statistic

    Intercept -3.061 -8.347***

    Fundamental Variables

    0< Dividend Yield.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    35/39

    - 34 -

    Table 6B

    0 1 2 3 4 5

    16

    6 7 8 9 10

    i i i i i

    i i i i j i

    DividendYield PR ROA EPS CS CSout

    CST Emp NASDAQ Other Industry

    Logit Coefficients and Asymptotic t-statistics

    Excluded Category: Dividend Yield = 0

    1999 Data

    0< Div. Yld.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    36/39

    - 35 -

    Industry Effects VariablesMining, Oil, and Construction 0.944 1.916* 1.151 1.909* 0.917

    Materials Processing 1.001 2.621*** 2.238 4.859*** 1.474

    Manufacturing 0.779 2.148** 2.033 4.543*** 1.340

    Transportation, Utilities,

    and Waste Disposal

    0.067 0.154 0.962 1.920* 2.672

    Wholesale and Retail 0.071 0.171 0.574 1.111 0.523

    Financial Services 1.631 4.185*** 2.447 5.180*** 3.163

    Other Miscellaneous 1.665 0.957 2.941 1.732* 2.245

    Nagelkerke Pseudo R2 0.478

    Number of observations 1,143

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    37/39

    - 36 -

    Table 7Mean Probabilities of DRIP

    and

    Impact of Variable Group Changes

    1999 DataPanel A: Companies with No DRIP in 1999

    No DRIP in 2004 DRIP in 2004

    Mean Predicted Probability ofhaving a DRIP

    30.06% 56.25%

    Number of Observations 464 50

    t-statistic for Difference in Means 3.84***

    Change in No DRIP versus DRIP in 2004

    Pr(DRIP in '04 | No DRIP in '99)

    Percentage Points % of Total

    Payout Ratio 4.88 18.64%

    Ability Variables 4.04 15.41%

    Managerial Entrenchment Variables 11.49 43.86%

    Exchange Effects Variables 3.37 21.54%

    Industry Effects Variables 5.64 12.87%

    Panel B: Companies with DRIP in 1999

    No DRIP in 2004 DRIP in 2004

    Mean Predicted Probability ofhaving a DRIP

    63.86% 67.91%

    Number of Observations 150 479

    t-statistic for Difference in Means 0.14

    Change in No DRIP versus DRIP in 2004Pr(DRIP in '04 | DRIP in '99)

    Percentage Points % of Total

    Payout Ratio 0.76 18.82%

    Ability Variables 1.34 33.09%

    Managerial Entrenchment Variables 1.65 40.72%

    Exchange Effects Variables 1.24 30.61%

    Industry Effects Variables -0.44 -10.87%

    the individual percentage point changes do not sum exactly to the total probability differential becauseof the non-linear (logit) form of the probability calculations.*** indicates significance at the 1% level.

    Panel A reports results for companies with no DRIP in 1999 and Panel B reports results for companies with aDRIP in 1999. The top part of each panel reports the mean predicted probability of having a DRIP forcompanies that had no DRIP in 2004 (second column) and for companies that did have one in 2004 (thirdcolumn). The second part of each panel reports the contribution of each of the five variable subgroups(fundamental, ability, managerial entrenchment, exchange and industry effects) to the difference in the meanpredicted probabilities.

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    38/39

    - 37 -

    Table 8

    Transition Matrix: Using 1999 Data to Predict DRIP Status in 2004Panel A: Companies that Did Not Have a DRIP in 1999

    Total Firms

    with data in2004

    Firms with

    Data that HadDRIP in 2004

    Firms with Data

    that Had NoDRIP in 2004

    Non-existentfirms in 2004 TotalFirms

    Number Predictedto Have a DRIP

    85 18 67 41 126

    ProportionPredicted toHave a DRIP

    47.37% 26.80%

    Number PredictedNotto Have a DRIP

    203 20 183 185 388

    ProportionPredicted to NotHave a DRIP

    52.63% 73.20%

    Total Number 288 38 250 226 514

    t-statistic for theDifference inProportions

    -2.59**

    Panel B: Companies that Had a DRIP in 1999

    Total Firmswith data in

    2004

    Firms withData that HadDRIP in 2004

    Firms with Datathat Had No

    DRIP in 2004

    Non-existentfirms in 2004

    TotalFirms

    Number Predictedto Have a DRIP

    235 210 25 200 435

    ProportionPredicted toHave a DRIP

    65.42% 78.13%

    Number PredictedNotto Have a DRIP

    118 111 7 76 194

    ProportionPredicted to NotHave a DRIP

    34.58% 21.88%

    Total Number 353 321 32 276 629

    t-statistic for theDifference inProportions

    1.453

    Panel A reports the transition data for 288 companies that did not have a DRIP in 1999. Of these, 85 wereincorrectly predicted by the logit model to have a DRIP, while 203 were correctly predicted not to have aDRIP. By 2004, a significantly higher proportion (t-statistic of -2.59) of firms that had a DRIP in 2004 werepredicted to have one (47.37% versus 26.80%) as compared to firms that had no DRIP in 2004.

    Specifically, 18 of the 38 companies that did not have a DRIP in 1999 but were predicted to have one initiateda DRIP by 2004 (47.37%); while only 67 of 250 firms that did not have a DRIP by 2004 were incorrectlypredicted to have one (26.80%). This difference in proportions is statistically significant (t-statistic = -2.59).

  • 8/13/2019 SSRN-id1021070

    39/39

    Panel B reports the transition data for 353 companies that had a DRIP in 1999. Of these, 235 were predictedby the logit model to have a DRIP and 118 firms were predicted not to have a DRIP. By 2004, aninsignificantly lower proportion (t-statistic of 1.453) of firms that had no DRIP in 2004 were predicted not tohave one (21.88% versus 34.58%) as compared to firms that did have a DRIP in 2004.