26
The St. Petersburg Paradox and Capital Asset Pricing Assaf Eisdorfer* Carmelo Giaccotto* June 2015 ABSTRACT Durand (1957) shows that the classical St. Petersburg paradox can apply to the valuation of a firm whose dividends grow at a constant rate forever. To capture a more realistic pattern of dividends, we model the dividend growth rate as a mean reverting process, and then use the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) to derive the risk-adjusted present value. The model generates an equivalent St. Petersburg game. The long-run growth rate of the payoffs (dividends) is dominant in driving the value of the game (firm), and the condition under which the value is finite is less restrictive than that of the standard game. Keywords: Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM); Stochastic Dividends; St. Petersburg paradox JEL Classification: G0, G1 *University of Connecticut. We thank Iskandar Arifin, John Clapp, John Harding, Po-Hsuan Hsu, Jose Martinez, Efdal Misirli, Tom O’Brien, Scott Roark, Jim Sfiridis, and participants at the finance seminar series at the University of Connecticut for valuable comments and suggestions. Please send all correspondence to Carmelo Giaccotto. Mailing address: University of Connecticut, School of Business, 2100 Hillside Road, Storrs, CT 06269-1041. Tel.: (860) 486-4360. E-mail: [email protected].

St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    5

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

The St. Petersburg Paradox

and Capital Asset Pricing

Assaf Eisdorfer* Carmelo Giaccotto*

June 2015

ABSTRACT

Durand (1957) shows that the classical St. Petersburg paradox can apply to the valuation of a firm

whose dividends grow at a constant rate forever. To capture a more realistic pattern of dividends,

we model the dividend growth rate as a mean reverting process, and then use the Capital Asset

Pricing Model (CAPM) to derive the risk-adjusted present value. The model generates an

equivalent St. Petersburg game. The long-run growth rate of the payoffs (dividends) is dominant

in driving the value of the game (firm), and the condition under which the value is finite is less

restrictive than that of the standard game.

Keywords: Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM); Stochastic Dividends; St. Petersburg paradox

JEL Classification: G0, G1

*University of Connecticut. We thank Iskandar Arifin, John Clapp, John Harding, Po-Hsuan Hsu,

Jose Martinez, Efdal Misirli, Tom O’Brien, Scott Roark, Jim Sfiridis, and participants at the

finance seminar series at the University of Connecticut for valuable comments and suggestions.

Please send all correspondence to Carmelo Giaccotto. Mailing address: University of Connecticut,

School of Business, 2100 Hillside Road, Storrs, CT 06269-1041. Tel.: (860) 486-4360. E-mail:

[email protected].

Page 2: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

The St. Petersburg Paradox and Capital Asset Pricing

1. Introduction

The St. Petersburg paradox is one of the most well-known and interesting problems in the

history of financial economics. The paradox describes a situation where a simple game of chance

offers an infinite expected payoff, and yet any reasonable investor will pay no more than a few

dollars to participate in the game. Since the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it

has attracted a great deal of interest, mainly by theorists who provide solutions and derive its

implications.

One of the applications of the paradox is in the area of financial asset pricing. Durand (1957)

shows that the St. Petersburg game can be transformed to describe a conventional stock pricing

model for growth firms. The analogy is based on the assumption that the firm’s future dividends

(as the game’s future payoffs) grow at a constant rate. Economic intuition and the historical

evidence suggest, however, that the very high growth rates experienced by many young firms (e.g.,

firms in the high-tech industry) are expected to decline over time. Hence, the short-run growth rate

is typically much greater than the expected long-run rate. In this study we model the dividend

growth rate as a mean reverting process; we then find the risk-adjusted growth rate under the

equilibrium setting of the classical Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), and derive its equivalent

modified St. Petersburg game.1

Our paper has several interesting results. First, we assume an autoregressive process for the

dividend growth rate, and then use the CAPM to derive a closed form solution for the price of a

growth stock. This result is a significant contribution to the asset pricing literature; it extends

1 Assuming a stochastic dividend growth is rather common in asset pricing studies; see, for example, Bansal and Yaron

(2004), and Bhamra and Strebulaev (2010).

Page 3: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

2

Rubenstein’s (1976) single factor arbitrage-free present value model by allowing mean reverting

growth.

Second, by distinguishing between the short-run and long-run growth rates, the model shows

that the latter is the dominant factor in driving the value of a growth stock, and in turn, the

properties of the St. Petersburg game, including its value. Third, we derive the condition under

which the expected payoff of the game (or equivalently, the value of a growth firm) is finite; as

expected, this condition is much less restrictive than the one required under constant growth.

Fourth, and last, our solution to the paradox extends the work of Aase (2001) who framed the

paradox as an arbitrage problem. His solution requires, in part, that economic agents discount

future cash flows at a constant rate. By using the Capital Asset Pricing Model we are able to derive

the required equilibrium discount factor, and show that the game price is finite. The rest of this

paper is organized as follows. In the next section we describe the paradox and a number of

solutions proposed over the years; in section 3 we describe the correspondence between the St.

Petersburg paradox and the value of growth stocks – the original contribution of Durand (1957).

Section 4 presents our stochastic dividend growth model and derive the valuation model implied

by the CAPM. We find that the restriction to insure a finite asset value is by far less restrictive

than the original one. In section 5 we present a modified St. Petersburg game for stochastic growth

stocks, and in section 6 we consider two extensions of the basic valuation model along with the

conditions necessary to preclude a St. Petersburg type paradox. The conclusion is in section 7.

2. The paradox and its common solutions

The St. Petersburg paradox is based on the following simple game. A fair coin is tossed

repeatedly until the first time it falls on ‘head’. The player’s payoff is n2 dollars (‘ducats’ in the

Page 4: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

3

original Bernoulli’s paper), where n is the number of tosses. Since n is a geometric random variable

with p=0.5, the expected payoff of the game is:

∞=+++=+×+×+×= ...111...88

14

4

12

2

1E (1)

Yet, while this game offers an expected payoff of infinite dollars, a typical player will pay no

more than a few dollars to participate in the game, reasoning that there is a very small probability

to earn a significant amount of money. For example, the chance to earn at least 32 dollars is

03125.02 5 =− , and at least 128 dollars is 00713.02 7 =− ; hence, paying a game fee of even 1,000

dollars seems unreasonable.

A number of solutions proposed to resolve the paradox rely on the concept of utility.2 The basic

idea is that the relative satisfaction from an additional dollar decreases with the total amount of

money received. Thus, the game fee should be based on the expected utility from the dollars

earned, rather than the expected amount of dollars. Bernoulli himself suggested the log utility

function; in this case, the expected value of the game is:

∞<==+×+×+×= ∑∞

=

)2ln(22

)2ln(...)8ln(

8

1)4ln(

4

1)2ln(

2

1)(

1nn

n

UE (2)

It turns out, however, that the utility-based solutions are incomplete: the game can be converted

to a convex stream of payoffs, and this change reverses the benefit of a concave utility function.

For example, if instead ofn2 , the game’s payoff is

n

e2 , then for the log utility just considered, the

expected value again tends toward infinity. In general, for every unbounded utility function the

payoffs can be changed such that the expected utility will be infinite. This generalization of the

game often goes by the name “super St. Petersburg paradox.”

2 See Senetti (1976) on solving the paradox using expected utility in light of modern portfolio theory, and Sz´ekely

and Richards (2004) for other suggested solutions to the paradox.

Page 5: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

4

Proposed solutions to the super game rely on the concept of risk aversion (Friedman and

Savage (1948), and Pratt (1964)); that is, holding everything else constant, a typical player prefers

less risk, and therefore is willing to pay a lower fee for high-risk games. Weirich (1984) shows

that, while the game may offer an expected infinite sum of money, it involves also an infinite

amount of risk. This is because the dispersion of the possible payoffs results in an infinite standard

deviation. Thus, the fair game fee resembles the difference between an infinite expected payoff

and an infinite measure of risk. While the answer may actually be finite, it does not explain the

low amounts typical players are willing to pay, which range between 2 to 25 dollars.

Aase (2001) proposes an interesting solution by reframing the paradox as an arbitrage problem.

He then shows that if (a) economic agents have finite credit at their disposal, and (b) agents

discount cash flows to the present at a constant discount rate, then any arbitrage opportunity will

disappear and the price of the game becomes finite. Our contribution is to frame the paradox as a

growth stock – in the spirit of the Gordon dividend discount model, and then use the CAPM to

derive the appropriate discount factor.

3. Application of the paradox to growth stocks

One of the applications of the St. Petersburg paradox is in the area of asset pricing. Durand

(1957) shows that with some modifications, the paradox can describe a conventional stock pricing

model. A growth firm expects to generate an increasing stream of future earnings, and thus to pay

an increasing stream of dividends. The value of such a firm is given by the present value of all

future dividends:

∑∞

= +=+

++

+=

12

210

)1(...

)1()1( tt

t

r

D

r

D

r

DP (3)

Page 6: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

5

where tD is the per-share dividend of year t and r is the discount rate. The constant growth model,

also known as the Gordon (1962) model, assumes that future dividends grow at a constant rate (g);

i.e., the dividend stream is ...,)1(),1(, 2111 gDgDD ++ for the years 1, 2, 3,… In that case, the

present value of this growing perpetual future dividend stream equals:

≥∞

<−=

+

+=∑

=

rgif

rgifgr

D

r

gDP

tt

t

,

,

)1(

)1(1

1

11

0 (4)

Thus, the firm value is finite only if the growth rate is lower than the discount rate.

Durand derives the St. Petersburg analogue of the constant growth model using the following

analysis. Consider the St. Petersburg game, where instead of a fair coin, the probability that a

‘head’ appears is )1( rr + , where 0>r . Assume further that instead of earning a single payment

when the game ends (i.e., when ‘head’ appears in the first time), the player earns a specific amount

of dollars as long as the game continues. Specifically, the player will earn 1D if the first toss is

‘tail’, )1(1 gD + if the second toss is ‘tail’, 21 )1( gD + if the third toss is ‘tail’, and so on. That is,

if the game lasts for n tosses, instead of earningn2 , the player will earn

g

gDgD

nn

j

j ]1)1[()1(

11

1

1

11

−+=+

−−

=

−∑ . Therefore, the expected payoff of the game is:

≥∞

<−=

+

+=

−+

+= ∑∑

=

−∞

=

rgif

rgifgr

D

r

gD

g

gD

r

rE

nn

n

n

n

n

,

,)(

)1(

)1(]1)1[(

)1(

1

1

11

1

11 (5)

which is identical to the value of a constant dividend growth firm (as appears in Equation 4).

Note that the analogy is based on the translation of the discount rate r to the coin probability

)1( rr + . That is, while in the original St. Petersburg game any future payment will be paid with

some probability, in the modified game, which is equivalent to the dividend stream generated by

Page 7: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

6

growth firms, any future payment will be paid for sure, but will be evaluated with a discount factor.

This analogy helps explaining the condition under which the expected payoff of the game is

infinite. The value of the stock is infinite only when the dividend grows at an equal or higher rate

than the discount rate; and in the same way, the expected payoff of the game is infinite only when

the payoffs are increasing at an equal or higher rate than the rate at which the correspondent

probabilities are decreasing.

We believe the paradox arises for two reasons. First, the assumption that the dividend stream

will grow at a constant rate permanently is unrealistic. For example, economic intuition, as well

as the historical evidence, suggests that high growth tech firms (such as IBM, Microsoft and now

Google or Facebook) may grow very rapidly in the short run. But nothing attracts competition like

market success; therefore, in the long run new market entrants will force the earnings growth rate

to slow down (almost surely) to a level consistent with the growth rate of the overall economy.

The second reason is that the degree of risk implicit in the dividend stream may cause investors to

change the risk-adjusted discount rate, i.e., the probability of actually receiving the expected

dividends.

In the next section we formalize these ideas within the context of the Capital Asset Pricing

Model of Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965). We model the dividend growth rate as a mean

reverting process so that the current rate can be very large but the long run rate is expected to be

much lower. We then use the CAPM to derive the appropriate risk-adjusted present value. We find

that the equity price can be finite without the unreasonable condition required by the constant

growth model.

Page 8: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

7

4. Stochastic dividend valuation in the CAPM world

Let tD be the time-t value of dividends or earnings (for simplicity we will use these two terms

interchangeably), and assume these values grow at rate 1+tg : ttg

t De D )( 11

++ = . We use a first order

autoregressive process ( AR(1) ) to model mean reversion:

11 )1( ++ ++−= ttt gg g εφφ (6)

where g is the long run (unconditional) mean growth rate and φ is the autoregressive coefficient

(we assume 10 <≤ φ to be consistent with the smooth behavior of dividends). We make the usual

assumptions to insure the process is stationary and the growth rate is mean reverting. The

innovation terms 1+tε are normally distributed random variables with mean zero, variance 2εσ , no

serial correlation, and constant covariance with the market portfolio return. The major implication

of the mean-reverting dividend model is that while the current growth rate can be abnormally large,

in the long run earnings growth should slow down to a lower rate. Intuitively, we expect g to be

close to the growth rate for the overall economy because of competitive pressures brought about

by new startup companies.

To obtain the risk-adjusted present value of each future dividend we use the CAPM of Sharpe

(1964) and Lintner (1965):

RORfmf RERR ER β][ −+= (7)

where ER is the single period expected rate of return on the asset, fR is the risk-free rate of interest,

[ mER - fR ] is the expected excess market portfolio return, and market risk is measured by the rate

of return beta )( RORβ . Then, the CAPM price for an asset that pays a stochastic dividend stream

∞=+ 1}{ ττtD is given by the sum of expected future dividends adjusted for market risk, and

Page 9: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

8

discounted to the present at the riskless rate of interest (Equations 8 and 9 are derived in the

Appendix):

( ) [ ]

( )∑∏∞

=

=+

+

−−

=1

1

1

)(1

ττ

τ

τ β

f

j

gjfmtt

tR

zRERDE

P (8)

where the deterministic variable zj captures the effect of mean reversion on cash flows and the

market risk. It may be computed recursively as: 11 += −jj z z φ for j=1, 2, … and starting value

00 =z . The growth rate beta, gβ , is defined as the covariance between the growth rate innovation

(εt+1) and the market return, divided by the variance of the market return. The expected dividend

series is an exponential affine function of the current dividend growth rate and long run growth:

tgCgBAttt eDDE

)()()( ττττ

+++ = (9)

and ∑==

τεστ

1

22 )2/()(j

jzA , ∑−==

τφτ

1

)1()(j

jzB , and τφτ zC =)( ,

Equations (8) and (9) show that the current price depends on the current growth gt, and the

long run rate g ; however, the impact of the latter is much stronger because it is multiplied by

)(τB (the sum of zj). We note that jz converges to )1/(1 φ−=z for large τ, thus )(τB increases

with the time horizon. On the other hand, )(τC converges to a constant finite value )1/( φφ − .

Intuitively, stronger mean reversion implies faster reversal to the long run mean; therefore, a

currently high growth rate has only a transitory impact on the equity price. The permanent

component of price is driven by long run dividend growth.

Today’s price depends also on the appropriate risk adjustment. Since the market risk,

represented by gjz β , increases with j -- up to )1/( φβ −g , the adjustment for risk becomes

increasingly larger for distant expected dividends, and this helps obtain a finite present value.

Page 10: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

9

Two special cases of the general model are worth mentioning. The first is Gordon’s

deterministic growth model which is obtained by setting 0=φ and 02 =εσ . In this case, dividends

are expected to grow in a deterministic fashion at a constant rate g . The beta factor

( gβ ) equals zero and the discount rate r equals the riskless rate fR .

The second, originally developed by Rubenstein (1976) within the context of a single factor

arbitrage-free model, allows stochastic growth but no serial correlation: 11 ++ += tt g g ε . In this

case, (log) earnings or dividends follow a random walk with drift, and the stock price has a closed-

form solution similar to Durand’s formula: *

*)(g

gt

ter

eD P

−= , where the discount rate r is given by

gfm

f

RER

R

β)(1

)1(

−−

+, and the adjusted growth rate is 2/* 2

εσ+= g g . The major drawback of these

two models is that unlike our autoregressive model, they do not allow a distinction between current

growth – which can be abnormally high, and long-run growth.

We can now derive the condition under which the asset price is finite. Observe that for large j,

jz converges to a constant value of )1(1 φ− ; therefore, the expected future dividend will evolve

along the path

Tg

e

−+

2

2

)1(2

1

φ

σε

. Also, for dividends far into the future, the risk-adjusted present

value factor may be approximated by

T

f

gfm

R

RER

+

−−−

1

)1()(1 φβ. Therefore, the present value

of a single dividend TD , for large T, may be approximated as follows:

TRERRg

tt

gfmf

eD V

−−+−

−+

≈)1(

)()1(2

1

2

2

φ

β

φ

σε

(10)

Page 11: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

10

This value will converge to zero, and thereby the sum of the present values of all future dividends

(i.e., the firm value) will be finite, provided the expression inside the square brackets is negative.

Thus, the restriction on long term growth is:

2

2

)1(2

1

)1()(

φσ

φ

β ε

−−

−−+≤ g

fmf RERRg (11)

The right hand side of this expression is similar to the CAPM risk-adjusted return with two

modifications. First, risk is measured by the growth rate beta adjusted by the degree of

predictability in the dividend stream, and second, since the growth rate is continuously

compounded, we need to subtract one half the long-run variance of dividend shocks. Clearly this

condition is less restrictive than for constant growth (i.e., rg < ); and, more importantly, it imposes

no restrictions on the short term dividend growth rate.

Figure 1 illustrates the upper bound condition described by Equation (11). We vary the level

of mean reversion, φ , on the horizontal axis from 0.0 (strong) to 0.6 (weak), and include three

levels of gβ : 0.5, 1.0, and 1.5. To set the riskless rate and the market risk premium, we use data

from Professor Ken French’s website. We have 037.0=fR and 0804.0)( =− fm RRE , which

correspond to the sample averages from 1927 thru 2013. Last, 2εσ is set arbitrarily at 0.01 because

its exact value has a marginal effect on the upper bound.

The horizontal line at 3.7% corresponds to the constant growth Gordon model; clearly this is

a low bar for the long run growth rate. The more realistic cases reflect varying degrees of mean

reversion. In the strongest case, where φ = 0.0, the upper bound increases with beta. When gβ =

0.5, the risk-adjusted upper bound is 7.2%, and increases to 11.2% for gβ = 1.0, and to 15.3% for

gβ = 1.5. Figure 1 shows that these upper bounds increase even faster as mean reversion weakens.

No firm can be expected to grow permanently at such high rates.

Page 12: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

11

5. A modified St. Petersburg game for stochastic growth stocks

As Durand (1957) shows, the classical St. Petersburg game (with some modifications) can

describe an investment in a stock with a constant dividend growth rate. To capture the more

realistic pattern of growth firms (as outlined in the previous section), we present a modified St.

Petersburg game that is analogous to a stock with a mean reverting dividend growth rate in the

equilibrium setting of the CAPM.

Consider the St. Petersburg game, where instead of a constant probability that the coin will fall

on ‘head’, the probability is different for every toss; specifically, the probability that ‘head’ appears

at the jth toss is of the formjj aa )1( − , where 1>ja j∀ . Assume further that the player earns a

different amount of dollars every toss, as long as the game continues: 1D if the first toss is ‘tail’,

2D if the second toss is ‘tail’, 3D if the third toss is ‘tail’, and so on. That is, if the game lasts for

n tosses, the player will earn ∑−

=

1

1

n

j

jD dollars. The expected payoff of the game is:

∏∑∑∏

∑=

=

+=

=

=

=−

=n

j jn

n

njj

k

k

j

n

na

D

a

aDE

111

1

1

11 (12)

Assume now that the stream of payoffs, as the stream of dividends discussed above, grows at

a mean reverting growth rate 1+tg (Equation 6). Note that the expected payoff for the nth toss,

nDE0 , is equivalent to the one appearing in Equation (9). Next, define the ratio

gjfm

f

jzRER

Ra

β)(1

)1(

−−

+= ; since the risk-free rate, fR , and the market risk-premium,

gjfm zRER β)( − , are both positive, ja is greater than 1. This guarantees a probability of ‘head’

between 0 and 1. Therefore, the expected payoff of the game is:

Page 13: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

12

( ) [ ]

( )∑∏∞

=

=

+

−−

=1

1

0

1

)(1

nn

f

n

j

gjfmn

R

zRERDE

E

β

(13)

which matches exactly the stock value in the CAPM world (Equation 8).

The condition under which the value of the game is finite, therefore, is identical to the one that

makes the stock price finite, as given in Equation (11). Since this condition is less restrictive than

the classical St. Petersburg game (as discussed above), it provides an indirect solution to the

paradox. That is, under the more realistic setup of a stochastic mean reverting growth rate, it is

more likely that the value of the game is finite, and therefore the game fee the players are willing

to pay is finite.

6. Extensions

In this section we consider two extensions of the basic valuation model (Equations 8 and 9) and

derive the conditions necessary to preclude a St. Petersburg paradox. The first extension relaxes

the assumption of a constant long-run mean dividend growth rate; while the second deals with

firms that may or may not pay dividends.

6.1 Valuation when long-run growth varies with the business cycle

In section 4, for simplicity of exposition, we modeled dividend growth as a first order mean

reverting process with constant long run dividend growth. But as the economy moves across the

business cycle, g may be time-varying. Let tg~ be the long run dividend growth rate, then we

rewrite Equation (6) as tttt gg g εφφ ++−= −1~)1( . It can be easily shown that if tg~ is itself mean

reverting (e.g., AR(1) ), then the reduced form model for dividend growth becomes ARMA(2, 1),

that is second order autoregressive process with a first order moving average component:

Page 14: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

13

1221121 )1( −−− −+++−−= ttttt ggg g εθεφφφφ (14)

where ),,( 21 θφφ are, respectively, the autoregressive and moving-average coefficients.3 Again,

we assume the process is stationary and shocks to the growth rate have constant covariance with

the market return.

To compute asset prices we need to define two sets of auxiliary equations to account for the

autoregressive and moving average components of serial correlation in the cumulative growth rate.

The two sequences are: 1−−= jjj zz w θ , and 12211 ++= −− jjj zz z φφ , with a starting value of

00 =z . Then, the time-t price is given by (proofs of Equations (15) and (16) are provided in the

appendix):

( ) [ ]

( )∑∏∞

=

=+

+

−−

=1

1

0

1

)(1

ττ

τ

τ β

f

j

gjfmt

tR

wRERDE

P (15)

and the expected future dividend is

1222 )()()(2/])([ −++++

+ = tt gDgCgBzAttt eDDE

τττσθττ

ετ (16)

The other parameters are defined as: ∑==

ττ

1

2)(j

jwA , ∑−−==

τφφτ

121 )1()(

jjzB ,

121)( −+= ττ φφτ zzC , and τφτ zD 2)( = .

Using numerical derivatives, one may show that this asset pricing model has some interesting

characteristics. First, the current price increases with both the current and long run dividend growth

rates. However, as was the case for the AR(1) model, price is much more sensitive to long run than

short run dividend growth. Second, price decreases with growth rate beta and the market risk

3 Fama and French (2000) provide empirical evidence for mean reversion in profitability. They find that

the strength of mean reversion varies depending on whether profitability is above or below its mean. To the

extent that dividends follow earnings, the ARMA(2,1) model captures these dynamics.

Page 15: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

14

premium. And third, growth rate volatility has a positive impact on price because of the convexity

of compounded cash flows.

The condition under which the asset price is finite is very similar to that of the constant long

run dividend growth (Equation 11). We note that for long horizon cash flows, jz converges to a

constant value of )1(1 21 φφ −− , and jw converges to )1/()1( 21 φφθ −−− . Thus, for large τ, both

)(τC and )(τD play a negligible role. B(τ) increases linearly with τ ; and )(τA converges to

τφφ

θσε

)1(

)1)(2/(

21

2

−−−

.

The expected dividend series will evolve along the path

Tg

e

−−

−+

221

2

)1(

)1(

2

1

φφ

θσε

, while the risk-

adjusted discount factor converges to

T

f

gfm

R

RER

+

−−−−−

1

)1()1()(1 21 φφθβ. Therefore, for

large T, the present value of a single dividend TD may be approximated as:

TRERRg

tt

gfmf

eD V

−−

−−+−

−−

−+

≈)1(

)1()(

)1(

)1(

2

1

212

21

22

φφ

θβ

φφ

θσε

(17)

Finite pricing of assets requires that the following restriction holds for long term growth:

221

22

21 )1(

)1(

2

1

)1(

)1()(

φφθσ

φφ

θβ ε

−−

−−

−−

−−+≤ g

fmf RERRg (18)

The right hand side of Equation (18) again consists of three terms: the first two represent the

CAPM risk-adjusted return with a modified beta to account for predictability in the dividend

stream. The third term is needed because the analysis is in terms of continuously compounded

dividend growth. Once again we find that the condition is less restrictive than a simple rg < ;

furthermore, there is no restriction on short term dividend growth.

Page 16: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

15

6.2 Valuation of Non-Dividend Paying Firms

In this section we generalize the model to the universe of firms that may or may not pay dividends.

We show that the main results hold provided we take into account mean reversion in profitability.

The foundation for this analysis is the “Clean Surplus” identity for a firm that is financed by equity

only and expects no new equity issues. This accounting relationship then states that the current

book value of equity equals last period’s book value plus current income minus current dividends.

tttt DIBB −+= −1 .

There are many ways to model dividend payments. For example, one may choose a dividend

rate set at a constant fraction of earnings; but earnings may be negative from time to time and

negative dividends would be inappropriate. Also earnings are quite volatile over the business cycle,

and a constant relationship would make dividends quite erratic. Because dividends are typically

smooth, we assume that dividends are paid as a percent of book value, and examine the

implications for valuation by the CAPM.

Let c be the constant proportion of book equity paid out as a periodic dividend: Dt+1 = cBt.

Setting c = 0 allows us to model firms that pay no dividends. We define the accounting rate of

return on book equity (ROE) ρt+1 as firm’s earnings – at end of period t+1, divided by book value

of equity as of period t. Then, the clean surplus relation implies that book equity grows as:4

( ) tc

t Be B t −+

+= 11

ρ (19)

To model the profitability rate, we assume a first order autoregressive process:

11 )1( ++ ++−= ttt ζρφρφρ , where ρ represents long run mean profitability. Shocks to the

4 The clean surplus relationship implies that the rate of growth in book value is ( ) ( ) t

c

t

c

t Be Be B tt −−++

++ ≈= 11 )1ln(

1

ρρ.

The approximation is exact only in continuous time.

Page 17: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

16

accounting profitability rate 1+tζ are modeled as a white noise process with zero mean, variance

2ζσ , and constant covariance with the market portfolio. This covariance -- divided by the variance

of the market return, defines the profitability rate beta βρ. To complete the model, we assume that

at a future date T competition will force abnormal returns down to the point where market value

and book value equal one another: MT = BT .5

It is rather surprising that the traditional CAPM leads to a straightforward relationship between

the market to book ratio and the accounting measure of profitability. To show this result, suppose

the CAPM holds, and the time series behavior of the profitability rate follows an AR(1) model

with a long run profitability rate ρ . Define the autocovariance variable 11 −+= jj z z φ for j=1, …

, T and with starting values z0 = 0. Then, the market to book ratio is given by (the derivation of

Equation (20) is analogous to that of (8) and (9) in the appendix):

∑∏−

=

=

−++

+

−−

++

=1

1

1

)()()(

)1(

))(1()(

1

T

f

j

jfmcCBA

ft

t

R

zRERe

cR

c

B

M

t

ττ

τ

ρτρτρττ β

T

f

T

j

jfmcTTCTBTA

R

zRERe

t

)1(

))(1()(1

)()()(

+

−−

+∏=

−++ρ

ρρ β

(20)

where ∑==

τζστ

1

22 )2/()(j

jzA , ∑−==

τφτ

1

)1()(j

jzB , and τφτ zC =)( .

Consistent with intuition, we find that the ratio of market to book value is positively related to

the current ROE rate ρt , the long run mean rate ρ , and the volatility of accounting profits. An

increase in the risk-free rate, the market risk premium, or profitability rate beta lead to a lower

5 Pastor and Veronesi (2003) present this model in continuous time, and discuss the assumption of a fixed time horizon

T at length.

Page 18: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

17

market to book ratio. Interestingly, Pastor and Veronesi (2003) obtain similar results with a

continuous time model and a stochastic discount factor, whereas ours are based on the CAPM.

For non-dividend paying firms we set c=0, and obtain the market to book ratio as:

T

f

T

j

jfmTCTBTA

t

t

R

zRERe

B

M

t

)1(

))(1()(1

)()()(

+

−−

=∏=

++ρ

ρρ β

(21)

The condition for a finite market to book ratio is roughly identical to the stochastic dividend growth

model. Provided T is large, the restriction on long term profitability is:

2

2

)1(2

1

)1()(

φ

σ

φ

βρ ζρ

−−

−−+≤ fmf RERR (22)

The right hand side of this expression is similar to the condition (11); however, the profitability

beta replaces the growth rate beta adjusted by the degree of predictability in the book equity and

the long-run variance of ROE shocks. Once again there is no restrictions on the short run ROE.

7. Conclusions

The St. Petersburg paradox describes a simple game of chance with infinite expected payoff,

and yet any reasonable investor will pay no more than a few dollars to participate in the game.

Researchers throughout history have provided a number of solutions as well as variations of the

original paradox. One of these, developed by Durand (1957), shows that the standard St.

Petersburg game can describe an investment in a firm with a constant growth rate of dividends.

To capture a more realistic growth pattern, we present a model that allows mean reversion in

dividends. We then derive the risk adjustment required in a CAPM environment, and propose an

equivalent St. Petersburg game. We show that the expected payoff of the modified game (or

Page 19: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

18

equivalently, the value of growth firms) is driven mainly by the long-run growth rate of the payoffs

(dividends), while the short-term growth rate has a minor effect on the properties of the game or

the firm. The model further shows that the condition under which the value of the game or the firm

is finite is much less restrictive than that of the classical St. Petersburg game, and this might

provide an indirect solution to the paradox.

Page 20: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

19

References

Aase, K., 2001, “On the St. Petersburg Paradox,” Scandinavian Actuarial Journal 1, 69-78.

Ali, M., 1977, “Analysis of Autoregressive-Moving Average Models: Estimation and Prediction,”

Biometrika 64, 535-545.

Bansal, R., and A. Yaron, 2004, “Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing

Puzzles,” Journal of Finance 59, 1481-1509.

Bernoulli, D., 1738, “Specimen Theoriae Novae de Mensura Sortis,” Commentarii Academiae

Scientiarum Imperialis Petropolitanea V, 175-192. Translated and republished as “Exposition

of a New Theory on the Measurement of Risk,” 1954, Econometrica 22, 23-36.

Bhamra, H., Kuehn, L., and I. Strebulaev, 2010, “The Levered Equity Risk Premium and Credit

Spreads: A Unified Framework,” Review of Financial Studies 23, 645-703.

Durand, D., 1957, “Growth Stocks and the Petersburg Paradox,” Journal of Finance 12, 348-363.

Fama, E., 1977. “Risk-Adjusted Discount Rates and Capital Budgeting Under Uncertainty,”

Journal of Financial Economics, 5 (August): 3-24.

Fama, E., and K. French, 2000, “Forecasting Profitability And Earnings,” Journal of Business 73,

161-175.

Friedman, M. and L. J. Savage, 1948, “The Utility Analysis of Choices Involving Risk,” Journal

of Political Economy 56, 279-304.

Gordon, M. (1962), The Investment, Financing, and Valuation of the Corporation. Homewood,

Ill.: Irwin.

Lintner, J., 1965, “The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock

Portfolios and Capital Budgets,” Review of Economics and Statistics 47, 1337-1355.

Pastor, L., and P. Veronesi, 2003, “Stock valuation and learning about profitability,” Journal of

Finance 58, 1749–1789.

Pratt, J., 1964, “Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large,” Econometrica 32, 122-136.

Rubinstein M., 1976, Valuation of Uncertain Income Streams and the Pricing of Options. Bell

Journal of Economics (Autumn), 407-425.

Senetti J. T., 1976, “On Bernoulli, Sharpe, Financial Risk, and the St. Petersburg Paradox.”

Journal of Finance 31, 960-962.

Sz´ekely, G. J., and Richards, D. St. P. (2004), “The St. Petersburg Paradox and the Crash of High-

Tech Stocks in 2000,” The American Statistician, 58, 225-231.

Page 21: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

20

Sharpe, W. F., 1964, “Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of

Risk,” Journal of Finance 19, 425-442.

Weirich, P., 1984, “The St. Petersburg Gamble and Risk,” Theory and Decision 17, 193-202.

Page 22: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

21

Figure 1. Upper bound on long run dividend growth rate

The three sloping lines represent the upper bound on the long run dividend growth rate, computed

from Equation (10), as a function of the degree of mean reversion (φ ), for three levels of gβ . The

model parameters are: 037.0=fR , market risk premium 0804.0)( =− fm RRE , and 2εσ = 0.01.

The horizontal line, set at 037.0=fR , represents the upper bound on the constant (deterministic)

growth rate in the Gordon model.

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.00 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60

Up

pe

r b

ou

nd

Phi

Rf

Beta g = 0.5

Beta g = 1.0

Beta g = 1.5

Page 23: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

22

Appendix: Proof of Equations (8) and (9)

Without loss of generality, we set time t at 0, and define the sequence of future growth rates as a

row vector ),,( 1'

τggG K≡ . We then use the following system of equations to describe potential

sample paths from time periods 1 thru τ:

+

+

=

ττ ε

εεφ

φ

φφ

φ

φφ

.

.

0

.

.

0

)1(

.

.

)1(

)1(

.

.

10..0

...

0.010

0..01

0..001

2

1

2

1 tg

g

g

g

g

g

g

(1)

A compact representation for this system is Ε++−=Φ 0)1( Gig G φ , where i is a column vector

of 1s, 0G is a column vector with 0gφ in the first row and 0 in the remaining rows, and

),,,( 21'

τεεε K E ≡ is the vector of random innovation terms. This set implies that the cumulative

growth rate ∑ =τ

1j jg has conditional mean 01'1')1( Giiig −− Φ+Φ−φ and conditional variance

ii '11'2 )( −− ΦΦεσ . Using a result from time series analysis (Ali, 1977), we show next that these

moments may be computed without inverting the Φ matrix. Define the vector

1'11

' ),,,( −− Φ=≡ izz zZ TT K and note that each element may be computed recursively from the

previous one: 11 += −jj z z φ for j=1, 2, … , τ, and starting value z0=0. Hence, each future expected

dividend is given by:

∑++∑−===

τετ

ττ σφφ

1

220

100 )2/()1(exp

jj

jj zgzzgD DE , and Equation (9)

follows immediately.

Next, we derive the present value of each future dividend τD starting from τ=1, 2, and so

on. Let 10

1 −=V

D R be the rate of return on a claim that pays off a single cash flow $ 1D at τ=1, and

Page 24: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

23

sells for 0V . Plug this return into the security market line (Equation 7) to show that the present

value is given by the expected dividend multiplied by a discount factor

( )

+

−−=

f

mmtfm

R

RDEDCovRERDE V

1

/)),/(()(1 2110

100

σ. Using Stein’s lemma it follows that:

( )11110

1 ,, mm RCovRDE

DCov ε=

. Define the growth rate beta ( ) 2

11 /, εσεβ mg RCov= .

Therefore, the present value of the first dividend is given by Equation (8) with τ=1.

Next, let V1 be the time-1 value of a single cash flow $D2 expected one period later. Again,

let 10

1 −=V

V R be the rate of return (from 0 to 1) from holding the claim on $D2. The security

market line (Equation 7) implies that ( )

+

−−=

f

mmfm

R

RVEVCovRERVE V

1

/)),/(()(1 21101

100

σ.

Using a similar argument as in Fama (1977), we can show that ( )

+

−−=

f

gfm

R

zRERDE VE

1

)(1 1

2010

β

. Moreover, the ratio of V1 to its conditional expectation one period prior, E0V1, equals the ratio of

cash flow expectations: DE

DE

VE

V

20

21

10

1 = . Then, from Stein’s lemma we have

1,

10

1 , mRVE

VCov

( )1,2112 , mRzzCov εε += = ( )1,12 , mRCovz ε . Therefore, the present value of the second dividend is

given by Equation (8) with τ=2.

Proceeding in this fashion one may show that for any Dτ , the present value is:

( ) [ ]

( )τ

τ

τ β

f

j

gjfm

R

zRERDE

V+

−−

=∏=

1

)(11

0

0 . Thus, Equation (8) holds by the principle of value

additivity. ■

Page 25: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

24

Proof of Equations (15 and 16)

Consider the sequence of future growth rates ),,( 1'

Ttt ggG ++≡ K may be described as a

multivariate system ΘΕ++−−=Φ 021 )1( Gig G φφ , where

−−

−−

1..0

...

0.01

0..01

0..001

12

12

1

φφ

φφφ

,

θθ

0..0

...

0.010

0..01

0..001

,,, igG and Ε were defined in the previous proof, while the initial conditions vector 0G consists

of ttt gg εθφφ −+ −121 in the first row, tg2φ in the second row, and 0s in the τ-3 remaining rows.

The first two moments of cumulative growth are: 01'1'' )1( Giiig G iEt

−− Φ+Φ−= φ and

( )( )'1'1'2' ΘΦΘΦ= −− ii G iVt εσ . Again, define 1'

11' ),,,( −

− Φ=≡ izz zZ TT K so that each element

may be computed recursively from the previous one: 12211 ++= −− jjj zz z φφ , and starting value

of z0 = 0. Define also the vector Θ=≡ −'

11' ),,,( Zw wwW TT K to aggregate serial correlation

induced by the moving average component of growth. Each element may be computed recursively

as: 11 −−= jjj zz w θ for j=1, 2, … , τ. Given these transformation, the conditional expected future

cash flow has a closed form solution given by

∑+−++∑−−==

−=

+T

jjtTtTtT

T

jjtTtt zzgzgzzgD DE

1

22121

121 )2/()1(exp εσεθφφφφ . We note that

this expectation is conditional on the time t shock to the current growth rate. This shock is

unobservable, therefore we use a property of normal random variables to obtain the unconditional

value. To obtain this result, observe that the expectation of ]|[ tTtt DE ε+ is analogous to the

Page 26: St Petersburg Paradox and Asset Pricing AoFSince the paradox was presented by Daniel Bernoulli in 1738, it ... The conclusion is in section 7. 2. ... (‘ducats’ in the . 3 original

25

moment generating function of tε evaluated at the point θTz . Then, Equation (16) follows

immediately.

The rest of the proof is by induction on t. From the proof of (8) above, we know that at τ-1 the

dividend discounted value is given by:

+

−−= −−

f

gfm

R

RERDE V

1

)(111

βτττ . Thus, (15) holds as of

τ-1 because the first value of w is 1. Assume the result holds for time period t = τ+1. From Stein’s

lemma we have

+

+=∑ 1,

1

, ττ

τ m

T

s

s RgCov = ( )1,' , +ττ mREWCov = ( )1,1, ++− ττττ ε mT RCovw . Using

the same logic as in Proposition 1, as we move back one time period from τ+1 to τ, the discount

factor is

+

−−

f

fm

R

wRER

1

)(1 ετ β. Thus, the time t=T-τ price is given by:

( ) [ ]

( )τ

τ

τ β

f

j

gjfmTT

TtR

wRERDE

V+

−−

=

∏=

1

)(1

1,

This last step shows that the proposition holds for time period t = T-τ, and all other times t. ■