194
Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic Analysis of Productive Efficiency and Adoption Robertson Richards Bisani Khataza MSc Development and Resource Economics, Norwegian University of Life Sciences (NMBU) BSc Agricultural Economics, University of Malawi (Bunda College) This thesis is presented for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy of The University of Western Australia UWA School of Agriculture and Environment: (Agricultural and Resource Economics) December 2017

Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic

Analysis of Productive Efficiency and Adoption

Robertson Richards Bisani Khataza

MSc Development and Resource Economics, Norwegian University of Life Sciences

(NMBU)

BSc Agricultural Economics, University of Malawi (Bunda College)

This thesis is presented for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy of

The University of Western Australia

UWA School of Agriculture and Environment:

(Agricultural and Resource Economics)

December 2017

Page 2: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

ii

THESIS DECLARATION

I, Robertson Khataza, certify that:

This thesis has been substantially accomplished during enrolment in the degree.

This thesis does not contain material which has been accepted for the award of any other

degree or diploma in my name, in any university or other tertiary institution.

No part of this work will, in the future, be used in a submission in my name, for any other

degree or diploma in any university or other tertiary institution without the prior approval

of The University of Western Australia and where applicable, any partner institution

responsible for the joint-award of this degree.

This thesis does not contain any material previously published or written by another

person, except where due reference has been made in the text.

The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark,

patent, or other rights whatsoever of any person.

The research involving human data reported in this thesis was assessed and approved

by The University of Western Australia Human Research Ethics Committee under

Approval reference number: RA/4/1/6929

This thesis contains published work and manuscripts prepared for publication, some of

which has been co-authored.

Signature:

Date: 05 December, 2017

Page 3: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

iii

Abstract

This thesis explored issues related to the economics of sustainable agricultural

intensification (SAI) in Malawi. Generally, SAI requires farms to produce in ways that

improve or maintain productivity, but with minimal impact on the environment so that

critical farm resources can endure. One of the most widely promoted components of SAI

technologies in Africa is legume-based conservation agriculture (CA). Given its

prevalence and importance to many farms across the continent, legume-based CA is the

core focus of this thesis. The value of this approach is assessed in a case study focused

on Malawi which, as one of the poorest nations on the globe, requires sustainable

agricultural practices to help ensure adequate nutrition for its population moving forward

into the future.

The main goal of the thesis is to examine the economic and social viability of SAI

technologies in Malawi, with the specific aim of providing insights on three research

questions as follows.

The first research question examines factors that could explain the heterogeneity in farm

efficiency observed among small scale farmers who have adopted legume-based SAI

technologies. This research question is addressed in chapters 2, 3 and 4, wherein technical

and cost efficiency are estimated for a sample of farmers engaged in sustainable

agricultural intensification management practices. Three analytical techniques were used

to model farm efficiency. First, a parametric Bayesian directional distance function was

implemented to account for the multifunctional nature of integrated production systems

where multiple-inputs are used to produce multiple outputs, including staple (maize) and

non-staple food crops. Second, a two-step non-linear optimisation model was used to

estimate a translog cost function and to impose regularity conditions implied by economic

theory. Third, a Bayesian stochastic frontier approach was implemented to ensure small-

sample precision of parameter estimates. Overall, the results reveal substantial resource-

use inefficiencies relating to the manner in which farmers in Malawi currently allocate

factors of production. The evidence makes a strong case for policies that can incentivise

farmers to operate reasonable farm sizes consistent with their household’s non-land

resource endowments.

Page 4: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

iv

The second research question addressed in Chapter 3 investigates whether legume-based

SAI technologies, as alternative forms of soil amendments, offer sufficient benefits over

chemical fertilisers. In addressing this question, marginal opportunity costs (shadow

prices) were estimated to reflect the trade-off between fertiliser-nitrogen and symbiotic-

nitrogen in the production of crop outputs. The estimation procedure used a directional

input distance function, which helps to set translation vectors to measure the extent to

which inputs (cost) can be reduced to achieve resource productivity with the same

technology. In addition, factor substitution was evaluated using Morishima elasticity

measures of substitution. The results suggest that complete factor substitution between

organic-based soil amendments (symbiotic nitrogen) and inorganic fertilisers can be

detrimental to farm productivity. The findings highlight the need to link sustainable

intensification with high-value markets if farmers are to be partially or fully protected

against potential welfare losses that could result from low productivity following the use

of resource-conserving practices.

The third research question addressed in Chapter 5 considers factors that determine

farmers’ propensity to adopt legume-based resource conserving technologies. To address

this research question, a discrete-time duration analysis model was employed to assess

factors that influence the timing of adoption of conservation agriculture technologies.

This method is suitable for modelling the occurrence of continuous-time events where

data have been recorded at discrete-time intervals, such as months or years. The results

show that farmers are reluctant to adopt new technologies unless the performance of such

technologies has already been ascertained by their peers or until adequate information

about the new technologies is available within the farming community. The findings

underscore the importance of information exchange and learning about the performance

of new technologies, which can encourage the timely adoption of these technologies.

Page 5: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

v

Table of contents

THESIS DECLARATION ............................................................................................................ ii

Abstract ........................................................................................................................................ iii

Acknowledgements .................................................................................................................... viii

Authorship declaration .................................................................................................................. x

CHAPTER 1 ................................................................................................................................. 1

1.0 Introduction and Background Information........................................................................ 1

1.1 Agricultural productivity and sustainability...................................................................... 1

1.2 Local context and problem statement ............................................................................... 6

1.3 Research Objectives .......................................................................................................... 9

1.4 Conceptual framework .................................................................................................... 10

1.5 Study location ................................................................................................................. 13

1.6 Contribution to scholarship and originality..................................................................... 16

1.7 Thesis organisation ......................................................................................................... 17

CHAPTER 2 ............................................................................................................................... 19

Examining the relationship between farm size and efficiency: a Bayesian directional distance

function approach ........................................................................................................................ 19

2.0 Abstract ........................................................................................................................... 19

2.1 Introduction ..................................................................................................................... 20

2.2 Analytical framework and empirical methods ................................................................ 25

2.2.1 Analytical framework ................................................................................................. 25

2.2.2 Empirical estimation ................................................................................................... 26

2.2.3 Data and variable description ...................................................................................... 30

2.3 Results and discussion .................................................................................................... 34

2.3.1 Technical efficiency estimates .................................................................................... 37

2.4 Conclusions and policy implications .............................................................................. 41

Appendix 2.0 ............................................................................................................................... 43

CHAPTER 3 ............................................................................................................................... 45

Estimating shadow price for symbiotic nitrogen and technical efficiency for legume-based

conservation agriculture in Malawi............................................................................................. 45

3.0 Abstract ........................................................................................................................... 45

3.1 Introduction ..................................................................................................................... 46

3.2 Theoretical model ........................................................................................................... 49

3.3 Empirical estimation ....................................................................................................... 52

3.4 Study area and data description ...................................................................................... 55

3.4.1 Study area .................................................................................................................... 55

3.4.2 Data description .......................................................................................................... 56

3.5 Results and discussion .................................................................................................... 60

3.5.1 Estimated measure of technical efficiency .................................................................. 60

Page 6: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

vi

3.5.2 Morishima elasticity of input substitution ................................................................... 61

3.5.3 Estimates of LBSF-N shadow prices ........................................................................... 63

3.6 Conclusions ..................................................................................................................... 67

Appendix 3.0 ............................................................................................................................... 70

Computation of symbiotic nitrogen using the harvest index approach ....................................... 70

CHAPTER 4 ................................................................................................................................ 77

Cost efficiency among smallholder maize producers in Malawi: to what extent can regularity

conditions reveal estimates biases? ............................................................................................. 77

4.0 Abstract............................................................................................................................ 77

4.1 Introduction ..................................................................................................................... 78

4.2 Methodology .................................................................................................................... 84

4.2.1 Theoretical model .................................................................................................... 84

4.2.2 Empirical estimation ................................................................................................ 85

4.2.3 Functional form ....................................................................................................... 86

4.2.4 Imposing regularity conditions ................................................................................ 89

4.3 Data description ............................................................................................................... 92

4.4 Results and discussion ..................................................................................................... 96

4.4.1 Cost efficiency prediction and sources of inefficiency ............................................ 99

4.4.2 Output and factor price elasticities ........................................................................ 103

4.5 Conclusions ................................................................................................................... 105

Appendix 4.0 ............................................................................................................................. 107

CHAPTER 5 .............................................................................................................................. 112

Information acquisition, learning and the adoption of conservation agriculture in Malawi: a

discrete-time duration analysis .................................................................................................. 112

5.0 Abstract.......................................................................................................................... 112

5.1 Introduction ................................................................................................................... 113

5.2 Theoretical framework .................................................................................................. 117

5.2.1 Discrete-time duration model of technology adoption .......................................... 119

5.2.2 Empirical discrete-duration model ........................................................................ 122

5.3. Study area, CA inception and variable description ....................................................... 124

5.3.1 Study area and the inception of CA practices ........................................................ 124

5.3.2 Data description ..................................................................................................... 128

5.3.2.1 Dependent variable ................................................................................................ 128

5.3.2.2 Explanatory variables and potential effects on adoption ....................................... 131

5.3.2.2a Information acquisition and learning ................................................................. 131

5.3.2.2b Farmer and household characteristics ................................................................ 132

5.3.2.2c Farm characteristics ........................................................................................... 134

5.4 Results and discussion ................................................................................................... 134

5.4.1 Non-parametric estimation results ......................................................................... 134

Page 7: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

vii

5.4.2 Semi-parametric and parametric analysis results .................................................. 137

5.4.3 Duration-dependence/the effect of time on adoption ............................................ 141

5.4.4 The effect of other covariates on adoption ............................................................ 141

5.5 Conclusions and policy implications ............................................................................ 143

Appendix 5.0 ............................................................................................................................. 145

CHAPTER 6 ............................................................................................................................. 147

Conclusions and Policy recommendations ............................................................................... 147

6.1 Summary ....................................................................................................................... 147

6.2 Policy implications ........................................................................................................ 153

6.3 Consideration for future research .................................................................................. 155

6.3.1 Use of biophysical data and data which have considerable variation in spatial and

temporal scale ........................................................................................................................... 155

6.3.2 Need for studies to examine the demand (consumer) side of sustainability ............. 157

References ................................................................................................................................. 159

Page 8: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

viii

Acknowledgements

This thesis is a product of determination, effort and motivation; the virtues which have been

nurtured through the guidance and strengths of several people who supported me in different

ways. I wish to thank all the people and institutions that have contributed to the successful

completion of this PhD dissertation. First, I would like to acknowledge financial support received

from the Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade through the Australia Awards Scholarship.

Second, I wish to profoundly thank my supervisors Associate Professor Atakelty Hailu, Senior

Lecturer Marit Kragt and Professor Graeme Doole for their immense technical support and

motivation for the entire study period. Dr Menale Kassie (formerly with CIMMYT) is

acknowledged for providing a letter of support required for University admission, but also for his

technical advice during the initial stages of PhD application and commencement.

I would also like to thank the entire management of the Lilongwe University of Agriculture and

Natural Resource (LUANAR) for granting me study leave. In addition, I thank IITA-Malawi for

granting permission to use the dataset studied within the thesis, which was generated under their

tropical legume project (TLII). Sincere thanks also go to farmers in Kasungu and Mzimba districts

for willingly and costlessly sharing information about their farming experiences, which has been

used in this thesis.

To my family members: Jane, Uweme, Talumba and Grace, thank you for your patience and

endurance over long-hours of my absence from your company. I am also grateful to the following

members of the UWA School of Agriculture and Environment (SAGE): Michael Burton, Amin

Mugera, Chunbo Ma, David Pannell and Ram Pandit for the solicited consultations and technical

support during my study period. Professor James Vercammen (University of British Columbia)

is appreciated for his insights about publishing. I also wish to acknowledge the tireless

administrative support provided by Deborah Swindells (SAGE), Celia Seah and Debra Basanovic

(International Sponsorship).

Special thanks go to Thayse Nery de Figueiredo for all the GIS help. Finally, to the following

SAGE PhD-student colleagues: Asha Gunawardena, Govinda Sharma, Luke Abatania, Rebecca

Owusu, Ari Rakatama , Phuc Ho, Alaya Spencer-Cotton, Tas Thamo, Ali Oumer, Masood Azeem,

Arif Watto, Giang Nguyen, Thi Chi Nguyen and Vandana Subroy, I say thank you all for the

corridor-whispers, lively discussions and moral support rendered during the depressing times of

the PhD period.

Page 9: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

ix

Page 10: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

x

Authorship declaration

This thesis contains work that has been published and material prepared for publication.

The bibliographical details of the published and unpublished material, their location in

the thesis, and the candidate’s contribution to the material relative to that of the co-authors

are as follows:

Chapter 2: Khataza, R.R.B., Hailu A., Doole G.J., Kragt M.E., Alene A.D. Examining

the relationship between farm size and efficiency: a Bayesian directional distance

function approach. In preparation for submission to Journal of Productivity Analysis or

Agricultural Economics.

Student’s contribution: 85% which includes conceptualisation, data analysis and writing

Chapter 3: Khataza, R.R.B, Hailu A., Kragt M.E., Doole G.J. (2017). Estimating

shadow price for symbiotic nitrogen and technical efficiency for legume-based

conservation agriculture in Malawi. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource

Economics 61, 462–480.

Student’s contribution: 85% which includes conceptualisation, data analysis and writing

Chapter 4: Khataza, R.R.B, Doole G.J., Kragt M.E., Hailu A. Cost efficiency among

smallholder maize producers in Malawi: to what extent can regularity conditions reveal

estimates biases? In preparation for submission to Agricultural Economics or Applied

Economics.

Student’s contribution: 90% which includes conceptualisation, data analysis and writing

Chapter 5: Khataza, R.R.B, Doole G.J., Kragt M.E., Hailu A. Information acquisition,

learning and the adoption of conservation agriculture in Malawi: a discrete-time duration

analysis. Submitted to Journal of Technological Forecasting and Social Change 26

March 2017

Student’s contribution: 85% which includes conceptualisation, data analysis and writing.

Student signature: ate: 05/12/2017

Page 11: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

xi

The undersigned supervisors certify that the student statements regarding his and the

co-authors’ contribution to each of the works listed above are correct.

Coordinating supervisor signature (Atakelty Hailu)

Date: 05/12/2017

Co-author’s signature (Marit E. Kragt): Date: 05 / 12 / 2017

Co-author’s signature (Graeme Doole): Date: 05/12//17

Page 12: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

0

Page 13: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

1

CHAPTER 1

1.0 Introduction and Background Information

1.1 Agricultural productivity and sustainability

In the recent years, there has been growing interest in sustainable agricultural

intensification (SAI) as a means of enhancing farm productivity and preserving the stock

of the natural environment (Lele 1991; Yunlong and Smit 1994; Pannell and Glenn 2000;

Rasul and Thapa 2004; Pretty et al. 2011; Garnett et al. 2013; Gunton et al. 2016). The

increasing interest in SAI technologies has emerged to address the adverse environmental

effects and social costs associated with intensive production strategies that characterised

the Green Revolution era (Yunlong and Smit 1994; Rasul and Thapa 2004; Lee 2005).

As a response to these concerns, global attention in the post-Green Revolution period is

on promoting agricultural production strategies that enhance agricultural sustainability.

These are approaches that require farms to produce in such ways that improve or maintain

current productivity with less damage on the environment, and attempt to avoid

compromising future productivity (Rasul and Thapa 2004; Lee 2005; Prettyet al. 2011;

Garnett et al. 2013; Gunton et al. 2016). In practice, agricultural sustainability

encompasses a diverse range of resource-conserving management practices and is thus

associated with a number of concepts. Other related concepts include integrated natural

resource management (INRM), integrated soil fertility management (ISFM), low input

sustainable agriculture (LISA), organic agriculture (OA), regenerative or ecological

agriculture (EA), soil and water conservation (SWC), precision or conservation

agriculture (CA), and climate-smart agriculture (CSA) (Reardon et al. 1999; Rasul and

Thapa 2004; Lee 2005; Pretty et al. 2011; Garnett et al. 2013; Latruffe and Nauges 2014;

Gunton et al. 2016). Since agricultural sustainability embraces a diverse range of

component technologies, the concept is difficult to study empirically. Nevertheless, an

Page 14: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

2

empirical assessment is important to show if pursuing sustainable production could lead

to substantial trade-offs between economic optimisation and ecological conservation.

Such trade-offs can negatively impact on farmers’ welfare, particularly those located in

low-income countries such as in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA).

Compared to other regions of the World, agricultural productivity in the SSA region is

generally low (Ehui and Pender 2005; Lee 2005; Pretty et al. 2011; Asafu-Adjaye 2014).

Low agricultural productivity in this region has been attributed to a number of factors,

including poor farm management practices, a degraded soil environment, and a lack of

farmers’ financial resources to purchase fertilisers and improved seeds (Bojö 1991; Ehui

and Pender 2005; Nkonya et al. 2008; Bationo et al. 2012). Land degradation and low

soil fertility are so widespread that 55% of soils in this region are now considered

unsuitable for cultivated agriculture at normal levels of investment (Henao and Baanante

2006; Bationo et al. 2012). In most SSA countries, net nutrient depletion from arable land

is in excess of 30 kg/ha nitrogen and 20 kg/ha of potassium per annum (Ehui and Pender

2005; Henao and Baanante 2006). Soil nutrient loss, particularly nitrogen, is responsible

for poor crop productivity in most of the cereal-based production systems in this region

(Bojö 1991; Ehui and Pender 2005; Nkonya et al. 2008). The depletion of the soil-

nitrogen stock and the consequential lowering of crop productivity increases the need for

external inputs, such as soil-fertility amendments.

In an effort to raise farm productivity, several SAI-related technologies are being

promoted in SSA. Of these, a number focus primarily on improving soil-nitrogen

reserves. The impact of these technologies has not been adequately researched and

documented, given that the implementation of certain SAI technologies requires that

farmers systematically follow expert recommendations (Giller et al. 2009; Thierfelder et

Page 15: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

3

al. 2013). In addition, the impact of SAI technologies are not well documented due to the

broad differences that are observed between the SAI technologies being promoted in each

of the SSA countries.

Notwithstanding the popularity of agricultural sustainability, there is no expert consensus

on what technologies are included and how success should be measured (Rasul and Thapa

2004; Garnett et al. 2013; Gunton et al. 2016). However, pioneering studies have

described agricultural sustainability as a collection of production approaches that harness

at least three interlinked dimensions (Barbier 1987; Daly 1990; Common and Perrings

1992; Harrington 1992; Yunlong and Smit 1994). The first is ecological soundness; i.e.

the sustainability principle that prioritises ecological/environmental carrying capacity,

ecosystem stability and resilience, and biodiversity conservation (Veeman 1989;

Common and Perrings 1992; Munn 1992; Norton and Toman 1997). Essentially, this

implies that a certain natural ecosystem can support a definite population of living

organisms, including humans and their economic activities. Thus, from an ecological

perspective, a natural ecosystem can survive extinction induced by economic or

environmental perturbation only if the existing population of the ecosystem’s essential

species is at least equal to its critical threshold or a safe minimum standard of conservation

(Veeman 1989; Foy 1990; Common and Perrings 1992; Norton and Toman 1997). The

second principle of agricultural sustainability is economic viability, which is concerned

with the technical and physical capacity of production systems to constantly meet the

increasing demand for agricultural commodities. Thus, the economic-sustainability

perspective focuses on productivity and technological change, economic growth and

capital investment (Hartwick 1977; Solow 1986; Veeman 1989; Gutés 1996; Neumayer

2010). Finally, the third component of sustainability is social acceptability, which

recognises poverty reduction, safeguarding food security and self-sufficiency, and

Page 16: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

4

heterogeneity in societal preferences (Smit and Brklacich 1989; Veeman 1989; Rasul and

Thapa 2004; Zilberman 2014). In all of the three sustainability principles, issues of rights

and justice/fairness are critical; hence, the need to consider temporal and spatial

distributions of resource availability and resource use throughout (Rasul and Thapa 2004;

Zilberman 2014).

The promotion of SAI technologies in the SSA region recognises the importance of these

three dimensions of sustainability. Thus, in a quest to maintain or raise farm productivity,

the complementarity between natural (ecological) and synthetic (manufactured or man-

made) capital is upheld (Daly 1990; Ekins et al. 2003; Neumayer 2010). This

complementarity is encapsulated in the concept of strong sustainability, which postulates

that critical ecological/natural resources and man-made capital are not perfectly

substitutable in production (Daly 1990; Stern 1997; Ekins et al. 2003; Neumayer 2010).

Thus, sustainable production entails judicious and efficient use of both natural capital and

synthetic capital. Conversely, unsustainable production could compromise the carrying

capacity of the agro-ecological system as a sink of pollutants or as a flow of ecological

functions that support agricultural production and provide amenity services. An

alternative to the notion of strong sustainability is the weak sustainability paradigm, as

advocated in general theories of economic growth and capital investment, such as the

Solow-Hartwick fair savings/investment policy (Hartwick 1977; Solow 1986; Gutés

1996; Neumayer 2010). The weak sustainability paradigm assumes that manufactured

and natural capital are near-perfect substitutes in production, and therefore, one form of

capital can offset the other factor that is limiting. However, the perfect-substitutability

assumption seems implausible in most agricultural production situations, given the

current level of degradation of the natural environment and the threat of ecosystem

collapse (as evidenced through adverse climate change effects and substantial decline of

Page 17: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

5

soil nutrients). This is the case because, among other reasons, effective agricultural

production is contingent upon the quantity and quality of both manufactured capital and

natural resources, such as land and water (Asafu-Adjaye 2014; Barbier 2016). In addition,

the production of manufactured capital (e.g. chemical fertiliser) could still require some

natural components (Daly 1990; Victor 1991; Barbier 2016). The long-standing evidence

that the SSA region is highly vulnerable to climate change emphasises the need for

farmers to adopt innovative production approaches, particularly those that use

technologies which embrace agricultural sustainability principles (Jones and Thornton

2003; Thornton et al. 2010; Arndt et al. 2014; Asafu-Adjaye 2014).

Previous studies evaluating sustainability have largely considered it as a macroeconomic

phenomenon and hence focused on indicators such as rates of growth of gross domestic

product (GDP), technological change, and capital investment (Solow 1986; Victor 1991;

Weitzman 1997; Hanley 2000; Böhringer and Jochem 2007; Neumayer 2010). While it

is important to treat sustainability as a global phenomenon, it is imperative for two reasons

to also consider it at lower levels of decision making, such as at the firm (farm) or

household unit. First, sustainable production of primary commodities and services—

particularly those derived from agriculture, forestry, fisheries, energy and water—is

important for supporting the livelihood of the resource-poor and natural-resource-

dependent households (Smit and Brklacich 1989; Pezzey 1992; Zilberman 2014; Smith

et al. 2016). Second, it is the collective economic performance of these sub-sectors that

determines the growth or decay of the macro-economy, as measured through indices such

as national GDP.

However, there have been few comprehensive analyses at the farm- or household-level

that assess the trade-offs between different sustainability dimensions (e.g. ecological

Page 18: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

6

diversity, economic viability or social acceptability), although a few notable empirical

applications exist (De Koeijer et al. 2002; Rasul and Thapa 2004; Gomes et al. 2009;

Solís et al. 2009). Therefore, in this thesis, a viable agricultural sustainability path is

analysed in the context of economic and social dimensions of sustainability. The thesis

evaluates the feasibility of sustainable agricultural-intensification technologies through

the following criteria: 1) economic performance, assessed as efficiency of agricultural

production systems; 2) social preferences, measured as farmer’s propensity to adopt

resource-conserving technologies which would allow for ecological diversity on a farm;

and 3) marginal opportunity cost, estimated as elasticities of factor substitution and

shadow prices. These three measures are both practical and useful to inform coherent

policies on agricultural sustainability.

1.2 Local context and problem statement

Malawi is a country in Southern Africa bordered by Zambia, Tanzania and Mozambique.

The country’s population is nearly 15 million and over 90% and 40% of its rural and

urban population, respectively, are engaged in agriculture (Jones et al. 2014). Based on

scale of operations, Malawi agriculture is classified into two subsectors; namely,

smallholder and estate production. The estate sector usually specialises in the production

of high value commercial crops such as tobacco, sugarcane, and tea. The smallholder

sector mainly produces subsistence food crops in the form of cereals (maize, rice,

sorghum and millet), roots and tubers (cassava, sweet potato and potato) and legumes

(beans, groundnuts, soybean, cowpea and bambara nuts). The smallholder farming system

is largely characterised by maize dominance, which occupies nearly 90% of total area

under cereal cultivation. Maize is the main staple followed by cassava, and the two staples

together provide more than 70% of calories in the diet (Rusike et al. 2010). All crops are

normally cultivated under rainfed conditions as irrigation development is still suboptimal.

Page 19: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

7

In previous decades, maize production was strongly supported through farm input

subsidies. However, this policy is now becoming financially unsustainable. As a result,

the combined effect of policy changes, rising population growth, and inadequate use of

soil fertility amendments has led to low crop productivity, and hence, the country is

experiencing unstable food supply and recurrent food insecurity (Figure 1.1).

Figure 1.1: Per capita food supply trends for Malawi, 1990-2016 (Data source:

FAOSTAT, 2016 available from http://www.fao.org/faostat/en/#data )

Following the recurrent food shortages, chemical fertilisers and organic intensification

have become important approaches to improve soil fertility and promote food production.

The sole use of chemical fertilisers as the first-best solution to raise farm productivity has

been tried, but the cost of inorganic fertilisers is often too high for an average farmer to

afford to apply them at recommended rates. Because of the high landing costs, Malawi’s

commercial fertiliser prices are among the highest market prices in the region. As a result,

the Malawian government has been relying on producer-subsidy programs to raise

agricultural productivity and ensure national food security. While the universal subsidy

program was terminated under the recommendation of the World Bank structural

adjustment program in the mid-1980s, new variants dubbed “smart subsidies” were

0.0

10.0

20.0

30.0

40.0

50.0

60.0

70.0

80.0

199

0

199

1

199

2

199

3

199

4

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

201

6

Per

cap

ita

foo

d s

up

ply

(kca

l/ca

pit

a/d

ay)

Page 20: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

8

introduced in 1998 under a targeted Farm Input Support Program (FISP). These new

programs recognise that increased use of chemical fertilisers masks major soil

micronutrient depletion and therefore provides a short term and unsustainable solution to

the problem of low farm productivity (Beedy et al. 2013). As a result, in its current state,

the smart subsidies under the FISP aim to increase farm productivity by combined use of

chemical fertilisers and biological soil amendments, such as the integration of legumes in

crop associations. Consequently, FISP provides vulnerable households with a package of

subsidised farm inputs consisting of nitrogen-phosphorus-potassium (NPK) fertilisers,

hybrid maize seed, and improved legume seeds as part of the integrated soil fertility

management strategies or SAI packages.

One of the most widely promoted components of the SAI technologies in Malawi, and

hence the focus of this research, is legume-based conservation agriculture (CA).

Conservation agriculture is based on three main principles: i.e. 1) minimum soil

disturbance, 2) permanent soil cover with live or dead plant material, and 3) crop

association or rotation with legumes (Giller et al. 2009; Thierfelder et al. 2013). Despite

the widespread promotion of resource conserving technologies, the viability of SAI

technologies has been contested for two reasons. First, some scholars doubt its adequacy

as the concept undermines/overshadows agricultural and rural development policies such

as food security, particularly in developing countries where poverty and hunger are

critical challenges (Lee 2005; Garnett et al. 2013; Gunton et al. 2016). Second,

agricultural sustainability is a broad concept such that it is not clear how it can be attained

or which technologies to deploy to reach this goal.

Clearly, the benefits of SAI or CA technologies will vary from one region to the other, in

part, due to the diversity of CA-related technologies being promoted, differences in the

Page 21: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

9

policy instruments used to incentivise the adoption of these practices and variations in the

diffusion of the available resource-conserving technologies (Giller et al. 2009; Andersson

and D'Souza 2014; Pannell et al. 2014). Therefore, clarifying such uncertainties requires

conducting location-specific research to devise local recommendations on how

agricultural sustainability can be best operationalised. In the context of Malawi, it is

important to examine factors that may affect adoption preferences and the magnitude of

efficiency associated with legume-based sustainable intensification practices, which are

alternative forms of preserving soil quality and enhancing crop productivity. It is against

this background that this study was conceptualised to evaluate the viability of agricultural

sustainability technologies in regards to economic performance (efficiency), marginal

opportunity cost (factor substitution), and farmers’ preferences for these technologies.

1.3 Research Objectives

The main goal of this study was to examine the economic viability of legume-based

sustainable agricultural intensification technologies and identify alternative pathways for

farmer’s welfare enhancement in Malawi. To achieve this goal, the study attempted to

provide insights by focussing on the following specific research questions:

1. What factors could explain the heterogeneity in farm efficiency observed among

small scale farmers that use legume-based sustainable agricultural intensification

production systems?

2. As alternative forms of soil amendments, do legume-based sustainable

agricultural intensification technologies offer sufficient benefits over chemical

fertilisers?

3. When farmers are cognisant of existing legume-based resource conserving

technologies, what factors determine their propensity to adopt such technologies?

Page 22: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

10

1.4 Conceptual framework

Figure 1.2 presents a conceptual framework that shows how the three research objectives

are linked. In summary, the figure shows two different pathways through which a farmer

can enhance resource productivity and realise welfare improvements; that is, aspects of

human welfare measured in terms of increased access to food, improved nutrition and

agriculture-derived household expenditure/income (von Braun 1995; Ravallion and

Lokshin 2002; Pinstrup-Andersen 2009). The first approach is by addressing production

inefficiencies (movement from A to B or A to C) and the alternative approach is through

the adoption of new technologies (a push to new production frontier depicted by a jump

from C to D). Collectively, the three research objectives investigate these two potential

pathways towards welfare improvement, i.e. improved resource-use efficiency and

adoption of new technologies.

Figure 1.2 Conceptual framework on farm efficiency and technological

change.

X

0

Page 23: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

11

Consider an agriculture-dependent household that produces a bundle of consumption

goods 1 2, ,..... M

mQ q q q , using a vector of farm resources ; { , }iX i Z E , where

1 2, ,..... J

jZ z z z represents land, labour and capital; and 1 2, ,..... K

kE e e e

represents the stock of environmental capital, such as farmland soil-quality attributes. In

line with economic theory, it is assumed that a farmer optimises welfare ( ) derived

from the aggregate value of agricultural output ( )Q defined as: ( | )f Q X .1 The state

of environment and how well it is maintained will determine the potential to achieve

sustainability outcomes, which can be considered in terms of future investment costs,

agricultural productivity and amenity services. Sustainability implies equality of

intertemporal welfare—or that the change in welfare is non-declining through time— i.e.

0t , where 1 0

( ) t

t t t and is the discount factor (Perman et al. 2003;

Barbier 2016). Evidently, resource use efficiency is a necessary condition for agricultural

sustainability because it could lead to prudent use of natural resources and external inputs,

such as chemical fertiliser (Tyteca 1998; Callens and Tyteca 1999; De Koeijer et al. 2002;

Kuosmanen and Kuosmanen 2009). In other words, resource productivity can contribute

positively towards both economic and ecological/environmental sustainability goals

(Gomes et al. 2009; Solís et al. 2009). For example, resource use efficiency helps a farmer

operating at point A in Figure 1.2 to realise improved economic and environmental

benefits in two ways. First, this farmer may achieve input or cost savings by using less

inputs to produce the same amount of output. This is shown in Figure 1.2 as a horizontal

movement from point A to B, where 1 2x x . Second, by removing inefficiencies, the

farmer could use the same quantity and quality of resources 2( )x but produce more

1 The assumption is consistent with smallholder subsistence-oriented production where farming households

largely consume own-produced food, although they may occasionally supplement their food supplies

through market access. The welfare function is assumed to be concave and well-behaved such that it is

increasing in output levels or 2 20; 0i iQ Q .

Page 24: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

12

outputs, which involves a vertical movement to reach the production frontier at point C.

Thus, if the economic performance of farms can be ranked based on a measure of

efficiency, then it is easy to suggest recommendations about the potential sources of

performance improvement for the least productive units. Consequently, the first two

research questions assess the extent to which firms in the sample deviate from the frontier

or technology boundary (i.e. estimate the magnitude of inefficiency as distances from A

to B or A to C) and explore possible policy options that could be implemented to enable

farmers to operate on, or closer to, the production frontier.

The second approach to achieving agricultural sustainability and productivity is through

the adoption of improved technologies (Solís et al. 2009; Mayen et al. 2010; Latruffe and

Nauges 2013; Villano et al. 2015). Alternative agricultural technologies are adopted to

replace or complement the existing technologies and management practices to effectively

improve farmer’s welfare ( ) . Thus, technology adoption helps farmers to achieve

efficiency and shift towards a new production frontier; this is represented as a shift from

C to D, which is on a higher production frontier in Figure 1.2. A switch from the

conventional to the new management practices will occur if the net benefit realised from

using the modern technology is positive and welfare-improving 3 2 1( ) , ceteris

paribus. This is outlined in the third research question, which explores factors that enable

farmers to adopt new technologies and, thus, improve their initial welfare or

0( | )f Q X to a new welfare level defined by 1( | )f Q X .

It is plausible that, given any two production technologies, farmers who have rationalised

their input use and have become efficient, will likely aspire to experience substantial

livelihood improvements and hence adopt new technologies—equivalent to shifting the

Page 25: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

13

production frontier outwards from 0( | )f Q X to 1( | )f Q X in Figure 1.2. A

number of localised research applications worldwide provide evidence highlighting

productivity benefits that are attributable to technology adoption, for example, use of

improved seeds and soil conservation techniques (Karagiannis et al. 2003; Solís et al.

2009; Mayen et al. 2010; Latruffe and Nauges 2013; Villano et al. 2015). It is worth

mentioning that, under certain environmental conditions, productivity gains associated

with SAI technologies may be minimal (Lankoski et al., 2006). Thus, if farmers can adopt

new technologies and effectively use them, then they are likely to improve their welfare.

1.5 Study location

The data used in this thesis comes from a survey collected from 341 households randomly

selected from Kasungu and Mzimba districts in Malawi (Figure 1.3).2 The survey was

conducted in the 2013/14 crop season. These districts are part of the medium-altitude

agro-ecological zone of the country. A subdivision of this agro-ecological zone is the

Kasungu–Lilongwe plain. This zone is one of the areas where legume-based sustainable

intensification technologies, which were a focus of this study, are most dominant among

smallholder maize and legume farmers in Malawi.

2 With the exception of the data used in Chapter 2, which is based on a survey conducted under the Tropical

Legume II project, which was jointly implemented by the International Crops Research Institute for the

Semi-Arid Tropics (ICRISAT), the International Center for Tropical Agriculture (CIAT) and the

International Institute of Tropical Agriculture (IITA.

Page 26: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

14

Figure 1.3 Map of Malawi showing study sites

The survey followed a three-stage random sampling approach. First, the study zones were

selected based on Ministry of Agriculture administrative demarcations, known as

extension planning areas (EPAs). The EPAs are district-level administrative units

established to coordinate and oversee the execution of extension services across the

country. With the help of Ministry of Agriculture officials, potential EPAs were identified

based on the dominance of legume-based CA activities in each of the two districts.

Afterwards, three and two EPAs were randomly chosen from Kasungu and Mzimba

districts, respectively. The second step involved random selection of EPA sections. An

EPA section is the lowest unit of administration in the Ministry of Agriculture hierarchy.

Subsequently, maize-legume producers were identified from each EPA section. This

procedure was done in order to establish a sampling frame. Third, after the selection of

Page 27: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

15

EPA sections and enumeration of maize-legume producers were completed, face-to-face

interviews were conducted with a set of randomly chosen respondents (household heads).

A total of 341 respondents, representing 33% of the total enumerated households, were

randomly selected for interviews. Table 1.1 shows the distribution of the respondents

across the five EPAs covered by the survey.

Table 1.1 Representation of the sample at district and EPA-level

District EPA Number of farmers Proportion of total

sample (%) Enumerated (N) Sampled (n)

Kasungu

Chamama 303 94 28

Chulu 240 50 15

Kaluluma 53 30 9

Sub-total 596 174 51

Mzimba Emfeni 207 71 21

Mbawa 246 96 28

Sub-total 453 167 49

Total 1049 341 100

Using a structured questionnaire, respondents were asked to provide information

regarding the adoption of SAI technologies, types and levels of inputs used in crop

production and amount of outputs realised, sources of information regarding new

technologies, as well as household and farm characteristics. In general, the survey focused

on three components of SAI technologies: 1) intercropping and crop rotation; 2) minimum

soil disturbance (minimum tillage); and 3) post-harvest retention of crop residues or

stubble (i.e. covering farm surface with maize stover and legume straw).

Page 28: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

16

1.6 Contribution to scholarship and originality

The importance of sustainability as a development goal is widely acknowledged; yet, how

to operationalise the concept has remained elusive across scientific disciplines, such as

agricultural and resource economics, ecological economics, and development economics

(Daly 1990; Rasul and Thapa 2004; Lee 2005; Barbier 2016). Accordingly, this thesis

makes academic contributions in two ways. First, the thesis applies the fundamentals of

production theory —i.e. principles of resource productivity (efficiency) and technology

adoption— to evaluate the viability of SAI technologies. In this way, the thesis contributes

to the literature by empirically demonstrating how analytical methods, which are applied

in the economics of technology adoption, and efficiency and productivity analysis, can

be used to derive practical indicators for evaluating the viability of SAI technologies.

Thus, the thesis highlights current methodological approaches with which to assess the

viability of SAI technologies in terms of social preference or adoption speed, performance

or productive efficiency, and independence or factor substitution possibilities.

Second, the thesis applies novel economic models to analyse the sustainability problem

and suggest salient policy solutions that can help incentivise farmers to adopt sustainable

agricultural intensification technologies. Thus, the study helps in interfacing resource

conservation with other important policy goals such as food security, agriculture-led

poverty reduction and rural development. This is important because promoting

agricultural sustainability at the expense of national goals, such as food security and the

realisation of farm income is counterintuitive.

Page 29: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

17

1.7 Thesis organisation

The thesis is organised into six chapters consisting of this introductory chapter, which is

followed by a series of papers that culminated from the study, and a general conclusion.

Chapters 2, 3, 4 and 5 present stand-alone research papers that examine the research

questions addressed in the thesis. Some unavoidable repetition is present therein due to

some procedural and methodological similarity between the applications. A preview of

the thesis chapters is as follows.

Chapter 2 uses a Bayesian directional distance function to test the so-called inverse-

productivity hypothesis on the relationship between farm size and productivity. Chapter

3 assesses the technical efficiency of legume-based conservation agriculture and

computes shadow prices or marginal opportunity cost of biological nitrogen, which

reflects the trade-off between chemical-nitrogen and symbiotic nitrogen required to

produce a given quantity of output. To achieve this, a directional input distance function

is employed. Chapter 4 compares parameter estimates from the restricted and unrestricted

models to demonstrate the importance of imposing regularity conditions on the translog

cost function. Two empirical procedures are used to impose regularity conditions: 1) a

two-step non-linear optimisation technique and 2) the Bayesian inference approach.

Chapter 5 uses a discrete-time duration model to investigate the factors that affect the

timing of adoption of conservation agriculture technologies. Finally, Chapter 6 presents

general conclusion to the thesis and provides policy recommendations. In addition, the

chapter describes study limitations and sets out new directions for further research.

Page 30: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

18

Page 31: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

19

CHAPTER 2

Examining the relationship between farm size and efficiency: a

Bayesian directional distance function approach

This paper is planned for submission as:

Khataza, R.R.B., Hailu A., Doole G.J., Kragt M.E., Alene A.D. Examining the

relationship between farm size and efficiency: a Bayesian directional distance function

approach. In preparation for submission to Journal of Productivity Analysis or

Agricultural Economics

2.0 Abstract

Achieving sustainable food security and increased farm income will depend on how

efficient production systems are in converting available inputs to produce outputs. Using

data from Malawi, we estimate a Bayesian directional distance function to examine the

relationship between farm-size and technical efficiency. Our results support the existence

of an inverse relationship between farm-size and efficiency, where small farms are more

efficient than large farms. On average, farms exhibit inefficiency levels of 69% or higher,

suggesting that productivity could be improved substantially. Improving productive

efficiency and food security will require farms to operate in ways where the size of

cultivated area is matched by non-land production inputs such as labour, fertiliser and

improved seeds. The results highlight the need for policies to incentivise farmers to

allocate excess land to alternative uses, such as sustainable land management activities

(e.g. conservation programs) and land-lease markets.

Key words: farm-size and productivity, technical efficiency, Africa, parametric distance

function

Page 32: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

20

2.1 Introduction

In a world that is facing increasing demand for food, it is imperative that cropping plans

are optimised, for example, by balancing operated farm-area and resource availability

(Erenstein 2006; Marongwe et al. 2011). Potentially, efficient land allocation could lead

to improved household food security and increased farm income, but could also help to

achieve sustainable land management objectives (Vanlauwe et al. 2014; Ortega et al.

2016). Recently, advocacy for sustainable agricultural intensification (SAI) is rising

across the globe (Pannell et al. 2014; Tittonell 2014; Vanlauwe et al. 2014). Sustainable

intensification, in part, includes the scaling down of land extensification, which involves

spatial land expansion for crop production. Arguably, food security achieved through land

extensification can often be unsustainable because the practice could lead to

environmental degradation (Jones et al. 2014). Unfortunately, there are still parts of Sub-

Saharan Africa (SSA) where land extensification is considered as a strategy for achieving

food security (Erenstein 2006; Marongwe et al. 2011; Vanlauwe et al. 2014)

Typically, land extensification increases the size of the total cultivated area or land

fragments. However, such extensification may not be supported by other essential inputs,

such as inorganic fertilisers. For example, studies evaluating the intensity of fertiliser use

in SSA show that fertiliser application rates are low and inconsistent with agronomic

recommendations (Jayne et al. 2003; Mafongoya et al. 2007; Vanlauwe et al. 2014). The

annual average intensity of fertiliser use is estimated to be only nine kg/ha in Africa,

compared to 86 kg/ha in Latin America or over 100 kg/ha in Asia (Crawford et al. 2006).

As a result of poor resource allocation, particularly chemical fertilisers, the problem of

low crop productivity in SSA remains a serious concern among farmers, researchers,

policy makers, and development agencies (Vanlauwe et al. 2014; Ortega et al. 2016).

Page 33: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

21

One could potentially improve crop productivity and food security through managing

more reasonable farm sizes. Since farmers can easily decide what size of land to operate

for a given level of non-land resources, it is important to examine the optimal farm-size

structure as a potential strategy towards achieving household food security.

Previous studies have investigated the farm size-efficiency relationship to justify land

reforms or to support other targeted public policies, such as provision of farm loans and

irrigation programs (Adesina and Djato 1996; Townsend et al. 1998; Barrett et al. 2010).

However, research evidence is still inconclusive about the presence or absence of an

inverse-relationship between farm-size and efficiency (Kalaitzandonakes et al. 1992;

Townsend et al. 1998; Dorward 1999; Hazarika and Alwang 2003; Helfand and Levine

2004; Barrett et al. 2010; Carletto et al. 2013). Inappropriate analytical methods and

measurement errors are partly responsible for the inconsistent results in the literature

(Kalaitzandonakes et al. 1992; Binswanger et al. 1995; van Zyl et al. 1995; Carletto et al.

2013). Previous research approaches test the inverse-relationship between farm-size and

efficiency using partial measures of productivity, usually regressing output per unit of

area (e.g. yield, revenue or profit per hectare) on the farm-size variable (Heltberg 1998;

Dorward 1999; Barrett et al. 2010; Carletto et al. 2013). For instance, Heltberg (1998)

and Dorward (1999) used a standard (non-frontier) ordinary least squares (OLS) model

to regress net value of output per hectare against land holding size. Using this approach,

Heltberg (1998) confirmed the existence of an inverse relationship for Pakistani farms,

but Dorward (1999) could not establish evidence for a similar relationship in the case of

Malawian farms. In a recent study, Carletto et al. (2013) applied a similar non-frontier

log-log model to data from Uganda. The findings from this study reinforced the inverse

size-productivity relationship.

Page 34: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

22

The conclusions drawn from previous non-frontier approaches may be confounded in two

important ways. First, the true or effective value of labour and land required for the

computation of net partial productivity measures may be distorted by missing factor

markets or other types of market imperfections prevalent in most developing countries

(Janvry et al. 1991; Heltberg 1998; Berkhout et al. 2010; Carletto et al. 2013). Second,

the estimation procedures that use standard production functions do not account for

inefficiencies inherent in most of the production units; yet, there is ample research

evidence that most agricultural production systems are not fully efficient (Bravo-Ureta

and Pinheiro 1993; Thiam et al. 2001; Karagiannis et al. 2003; Karagiannis and Sarris

2005; Bravo-Ureta et al. 2007).

An alternative to the classical approach is to use frontier-based methods that account for

productive inefficiencies. For example, Townsend et al. (1998) used data envelopment

analysis (DEA) to investigate the size-efficiency relationship among South African wine

producers. This study established a weak and inconsistent relationship between farm-size

and efficiency. In another study, Hazarika and Alwang (2003) estimated a Cobb-Douglas

stochastic cost function in their analysis of a sample of Malawian tobacco farms and

concluded that larger farms are more cost efficient than smaller ones. In a related study,

Helfand and Levine (2004) used the DEA approach to study the Brazilian agricultural

sector and reported an inverted-U relationship, suggesting that medium-sized farms are

the most productive. On the other hand, in their application of a stochastic frontier model

among a sample of Greek tobacco growers Karagiannis and Sarris (2005) could not

establish a concrete relationship between farm size and efficiency. These disparities on

the size-efficiency relationship are not surprising because different studies use different

approaches, target different commodities and focus on different regions.

Page 35: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

23

The objective of the present study is to examine the relationship between farm-size and

productive efficiency in the context of Malawian smallholder farmers. Malawi is an

interesting case study for a number of reasons. First, Malawi is one of the countries in

Africa where the majority of the population rely on agriculture for their livelihood.

Second, the country is characterised by rapid population growth and, as a result, it is

experiencing acute pressure for arable land, particularly in the Southern and Eastern

regions. Third, because of acute land pressure and low adoption of sustainable land

management practices, among other factors, crop productivity has been declining over

time. Accordingly, there is need for policy options to address low productivity and hence

achieve food security and dietary diversity. Empirically determining which farm-size

category is optimal to operate could better guide land-use decisions and policies regarding

effective acreage allocation among farmers. For example, if small farms are more

efficient, then low-resourced farmers who own excess land could be encouraged to

operate reasonable sizes. Where land markets exist, excess land could be leased-out at a

fee. Alternatively, excess and marginal land could be targeted for biodiversity

conservation schemes or sustainable intensification programs, where conservation

markets (green payment schemes) already exist or if they could emerge (Ferraro and Kiss

2002; Pascual and Perrings 2007; Sipiläinen and Huhtala 2013).

This paper makes two contributions to the literature. First, we demonstrate the application

of a Bayesian directional distance function to test the inverse-productivity relationship.

This approach is yet to be applied to examine the inverse-productivity hypothesis, yet the

method is convenient for at least two reasons. First, the Bayesian directional distance

function technique is an explicit representation of multiple-input and multiple-output

production technologies (Van den Broeck et al. 1994; Chambers et al. 1996; Färe and

Grosskopf 2000; O’Donnell and Coelli 2005). As a multiple output model, the distance

Page 36: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

24

function technique is an appropriate representation of non-specialised households which

simultaneously produce two or more crops (Coelli and Fleming 2004; Karagiannis et al.

2004; Rahman 2009). Second, the distance function technique is a primal approach that

neither requires price information on inputs and outputs, nor the postulation of any

behavioural assumption, such as cost minimisation and revenue/profit maximisation

(Grosskopf et al. 1995; Coelli and Fleming 2004; Rahman 2009; Feng and Serletis 2010).

Our second contribution is that we impose theoretical consistency within the Bayesian

estimation framework (Van den Broeck et al. 1994; O’Donnell and Coelli 2005), contrary

to most empirical studies that ignore or assume a priori that these conditions hold.

Clearly, empirical results obtained from a production technology that fails to satisfy the

regularity conditions, such as monotonicity and quasi-concavity, could lead to invalid

conclusions and biased policy recommendations (Sauer et al. 2006; Henningsen and

Henning 2009; Feng and Serletis 2010). Besides the ease of imposing regularity

conditions, the Bayesian approach offers a number of advantages over the classical

stochastic frontier technique, some of the notable ones being: 1) flexibility to explicitly

incorporate prior knowledge and non-sample information into the estimation process; 2)

ensuring precise small-sample inference on parameter estimates for most of the

estimation problems; and 3) quantifying parametric uncertainty by estimating probability

distributions for each of the parameters of interest.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows. In the next section, we provide the analytical

framework and steps followed in the empirical estimation of the Bayesian directional

distance function. This is followed by a brief description of the data and discussion of

empirical results. Finally, conclusions and policy implications are presented.

Page 37: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

25

2.2 Analytical framework and empirical methods

2.2.1 Analytical framework

The productive efficiency of a farm is determined by comparing its inputs and outputs

against the boundaries of the technology set or the best-practice frontier. Consider a farm

or decision making unit that uses a vector of inputs , to produce a vector of outputs

. Let the production technology set be defined in general terms as:

{( , ) : , ; } (1)N MT x y x y x can produce y

The directional technology distance function ( , ; , )T x yD x y g g , which is dual to the profit

function, is a complete representation of the production technology (Chambers et al.

1996; Färe and Grosskopf 2000; Färe and Grosskopf 2004). We assume that T is a

convex and closed set that satisfies free disposability of inputs and outputs (Chambers et

al. 1996; Färe and Grosskopf 2000; Fare and Primont 2006). Further properties of the

directional technology distance function are: 1) directional distance function is non-

decreasing in inputs and non-increasing in outputs; 2) it is concave in inputs and outputs,

and is of homogenous degree minus one in the translation vector g , where ,x yg g g

is the directional vector used to scale-down inputs and scale-up outputs; and 3) satisfies

the translation property. Given the directional vector ,x yg g g , then the directional

distance function is defined as:

( , ; , ) sup , (2)T x y x yD x y g g x g y g T

Equation (2) shows a directional distance function that simultaneously seeks to contract

inputs in the xg g direction and expand outputs in the yg g direction. Thus, the

directional distance function measures the amount that one can translate inputs

Nx

My

Page 38: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

26

(contraction) and outputs (expansion) to the technology frontier. In other words,

estimating the directional distance function helps to determine a firm’s potential for cost

(input) reduction and revenue (output) expansion, which is dual to profit maximisation

(Färe and Grosskopf 2004). Accordingly, the positive distance from any point below the

frontier gives the actual measure of inefficiency associated with a particular firm

producing at that point, and hence, the directional distance function measure of technical

inefficiency is given as: ( , ; , )T x yTI D x y g g .

2.2.2 Empirical estimation

There are two popular methods that have been used to estimate distance functions. The

first approach is a non-parametric or set representation called data envelopment analysis

(DEA). The main advantage of the DEA approach is that it does not impose a functional

form on the data. However, DEA is not differentiable and therefore it is difficult to derive

shadow prices from its estimates. In addition, DEA results are sensitive to data noise

(outliers), which may affect the accuracy of the estimates. The second technique is the

parametric approach, which can be estimated in two main ways: 1) as a deterministic

function and using mathematical programming techniques (e.g. Färe et al. 2006; Hailu

and Chambers 2012); and 2) as a stochastic function using either maximum likelihood

procedures (e.g. Coelli and Perelman 1999; 2000; Karagiannis et al. 2004; Rahman 2009)

or Bayesian inference (e.g. O’Donnell 2002; O’Donnell and Coelli 2005; Hailu and

Chambers 2012). We adopt the parametric approach because such methods allow for

statistical testing of hypotheses. In addition, this approach provides coefficient estimates

and elasticities, which can aid further economic interpretations and policy conclusions.

For example, by examining the estimated elasticity measures, one can explore the

possibility of resource substitution or complementarity for a given production system

(Khataza et al. 2017).

Page 39: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

27

Within the statistical methods available, the Bayesian method of inference is preferred

here because, with this method, it is easy to impose regularity conditions implied by

economic theory. Further, the Bayesian approach allows one to formally incorporate prior

non-sample information into the estimation process, and the approach yields precise

small-sample estimates.

The directional distance function in Equation (2) can be estimated using any suitable

functional form. However, according to Färe et al. (2010) and Färe and Vardanyan

(2016), the quadratic functional form is convenient because it is the only flexible form

that allows for the global imposition of the translation property. One of the criticisms of

using the directional distance function is the lack of clarity on the choice and the economic

interpretation of directional vectors, which are used to project the observed input-output

mix to the frontier (Sipiläinen and Huhtala 2013; Färe et al. 2017; Wang et al. 2017).

Accordingly, we use a unitary directional vector, with positive elements for outputs and

negative elements for inputs i.e. , ; 1,1x yg g g . Since the data are deflated by mean

values, the use of the unitary directional vector makes interpretation clearer in the sense

that efficiency measures can be directly interpreted as proportions of sample mean values

(Färe et al. 2001; Färe and Grosskopf 2004). The use of , ; 1,1x yg g g when the data

is mean-scaled is equivalent to using average values of inputs and outputs as directions

for the translation (Färe and Grosskopf 2004; Khataza et al. 2017). The quadratic

directional distance function is specified as follows:

Page 40: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

28

0

1 1 1 1

1 1 1 1

( , ; -1, 1) 0.5 .. (3)

0.5 . .

N M N N

T n n m m nn n n

n m n n

M M M N

mm m m mn m n

m m m n

D x y x y x x

y y y x v u

where my is the production output represented by aggregate value of gross energy and

gross protein; nx is a vector of inputs and is a vector of coefficient parameters of the

distance function and is assumed to be normally distributed. The nonnegative inefficiency

term (u) is assumed to be exponentially distributed, while the random error term (v) is

assumed to be normally distributed as 2~ (0, )i vv N .

Implementing Equation (3) in the Bayesian framework involves four steps (Judge et al.

1985; Griffiths 1988; O’Donnell 2002):

1) specification of prior probability density function, which quantifies the

uncertainty associated with values of the unknown parameters of the directional

distance function p , where ( , , )u v ;

2) construction of the likelihood function that summarises information about

parameters contained in the sample ( )L Y , where Y represents observed sample

information;

3) derivation of the joint posterior density function that combines prior information

and sample information through the Bayes’ Theorem

( ) ( )( ( ) ( ) ( )( ( )p Y p L Y p Y p L Y ; and

4) summarising marginal posterior density functions for the estimated parameters.

Page 41: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

29

We use uninformative priors so that the prior density function has little or no influence

on the shape of the posterior density function. Let the precision parameter h be

represented by a reciprocal of the prior variance given as 2 1( )h . The precision

parameter is assumed to be gamma distributed, with shape and scale parameters set such

that the prior is uninformative. Following Van den Broeck et al. (1994) and Hailu and

Chambers (2012), we assume that the inefficiency term ( u ) follows an exponential

distribution with a scale parameter . The exponential distribution is a common choice

among Bayesian efficiency studies, mainly because it is less sensitive to prior

assumptions (Van den Broeck et al. 1994; Kleit and Terrell 2001; Feng and Serletis 2010).

For firm-specific inefficiencies, we define exp( )u , where represents mean

inefficiency with a gamma distribution as follows: 1 1( | ) ( |1, )i G ip u f u .

Numerically, a gamma distribution with shape parameter one implies exponential

distribution.

Equation (3) is estimated in R using the BUGS program (Gilks et al. 1994; Spiegelhalter

et al. 1996) to undertake steps 2 to 4 in the Bayesian estimation, and the APEAR package

(Hailu 2013) was used to prepare data for the estimation and to retrieve and summarise

results. Regularity conditions are imposed such that the estimated parameters of the

directional distance function are theoretically consistent as follows: 1) representation,

which signifies the technical feasibility of the observed input-output mix and to show the

absence/presence of inefficiency or ( , ; , ) 0T y xD y x g g ; 2) monotonicity for outputs and

inputs or 0; 0T TD y D x ; symmetry or ij ji i j ; and 3) translation or

1; 0 ; 0 n m nn nm mn mm

n m n m

n m

. We set 50,000

iterations as a burn-in period and the posterior density simulations were monitored

Page 42: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

30

through two chains, each with a length of 200,000. Thinning was conducted at every 10th

random draw to reduce autocorrelation in the chains. Model convergence was checked

using the Gelman-Rubin diagnostic test and Monte Carlo error (Brooks and Gelman

1998).

2.2.3 Data and variable description

The data for our study comes from a household survey conducted under the Tropical

Legume II project (TLII) (Tsedeke 2009; Monyo and Laxmipathi 2014). The TLII project

was jointly implemented by the International Crops Research Institute for the Semi-Arid

Tropics (ICRISAT), the International Center for Tropical Agriculture (CIAT) and the

International Institute of Tropical Agriculture (IITA) in close collaboration with partners

in the National Agricultural Research Systems (Monyo and Laxmipathi 2014). In Malawi,

the TLII survey was conducted in two districts of Lilongwe and Dowa, which were

selected to provide baseline information for legume breeding activities. This survey

provides a rich data set consisting of more than ten food crops commonly cultivated in

Malawi. A total of 300 farming households were randomly selected to participate in the

survey. Our sample constitutes 278 households that produced a total of thirteen food crops

as follows: one cereal crop (maize); six legumes (bambara nuts, beans, cowpea,

groundnuts, soybean and pigeon pea); three root and tuber crops (cassava, potato and

sweet potato), and three other horticultural crops (tomato, onion and cabbage). These are

the major food crops commonly cultivated by most of the smallholder farmers in the study

area, and across the country. From a nutrition point of view, a more diversified

agricultural and food production system may help to improve dietary quality for the

producer-consumer households. This is especially true in Malawi and across Africa where

Page 43: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

31

smallholder farmers are subsistence oriented and thus, consume a substantial amount of

own-produced food (Berkhout et al. 2010; Jones et al. 2014; Koppmair et al. 2017).

Table 2.1 summarises the data. The data are disaggregated by farm-size classes based on

a criterion suggested by Dorward (1999). In this classification, farms are considered to be

small, medium and large if the operated area is under one hectare, between one and two

hectares, and over two hectares, respectively. Based on this classification, 49.3% of farms

are medium-sized, while the rest are large farms (26.3%) and small farms (24.5%). The

results show that the average supply of calorie-dense macro-nutrients was much higher

than the average value for the protein.

Page 44: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

32

Table 2.1 Variable description and summary statistics for inputs and outputs used in distance function estimation.

Variable Description

Small farms

(<1ha; n=68)

Medium-size farms

(1-2ha; n=137)

Large farms

(>2ha; n=73)

All farms (n=278)

Mean Range Mean Range Mean Range Mean Range

y1

Gross energy supply

(kilocalories)

25,874

(25,484)

0 – 136,805

39,020

(27,723)

0 – 186,543

62,834

(41,180)

0 –183,509

42,058

(34,027)

0 – 186,543

y2 Gross protein supply (grams)

1,033

(892)

0 – 4,488

1,552

(1,108)

0 – 6,675

2,421

(1,578)

0 – 6,586

1,653

(1,303)

0 – 6,675

x1

Cultivated area under food

crops (ha)

0.72

(0.27)

0.30 –1.90

1.29

(0.31)

0.50 – 2.20

2.18

(0.63)

0.70 – 3.86

1.38

(0.67)

0.30 – 3.86

x2 Fertiliser (kg)

60

(72)

0 – 453

71

(65)

0 – 400

96

(92)

0 – 400

75

(76)

0 – 453

x3 Labour (person-days)

136

(82)

28 – 510

208

(114)

42 – 636

285

(178)

62 – 1,167

210

(138)

28 – 1,167

x4

Other inputs (implicit quantity

index)

177

(327)

1 – 1,558

624

(1,024)

1 – 5,552

1,401

(2,423)

1 – 10,191

719

(1505)

1 – 10,191

Note: standard deviations in parentheses

Page 45: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

33

The analysis uses two outputs and four inputs. The two outputs are used to represent

potential food supply by aggregating macro nutrients derived from a total of thirteen food

crops produced by a household. Notwithstanding the limitation that different farms could

produce different crop varieties which may vary in terms of nutritional content3, our

aggregation procedure is theoretically consistent because it is based on a common metric,

which is represented by the nutrition value of food. The crop outputs are converted to

gross energy equivalent (kilocalories) and gross protein equivalent (grams) using nutrient

content of the thirteen food crops, as presented in Appendix (Table 2.A1). The

aggregation is done because the two macro-nutrients provide a convenient measure of

food supply and, thus, could be used to reveal food allocative efficiency (Berkhout et al.

2010). Evidently, nutrition is one of the criteria that producer-consumer (subsistence)

households seek to satisfy when choosing their crop-mix and the type of food they

consume (Huang 1996; Beatty 2007; Berkhout et al. 2010; Ortega et al. 2016). From a

statistical perspective, this aggregation procedure helps to reduce the dimensionality of

the multiple outputs; from 13 crops to two crop-derived outputs, which is computationally

a reasonable number to work with. Furthermore, the conversion helps to circumvent the

problem of zero output resulting from non-production or severe pre-harvest loss

experienced on certain farms.

Small-scale crop production in Malawi is not capital intensive because the majority of

smallholder farmers do not own or hire extensive physical capital (such as tractors) to

carry out farm operations. Typically, the inputs used in smallholder crop production are:

1) amount of cultivated area under food crops, measured in hectares; 2) fertiliser use in

kilograms; 3) amount of family labour expressed in person-days; and 4) other inputs

3 The limitation is that the conversion factors are only available for specific crops but these

factors do not distinguish the food content among crop varieties.

Page 46: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

34

represented by an aggregate implicit quantity comprising purchased seeds and non-

fertiliser chemicals (i.e. herbicides and pesticides). These four production inputs are

included in the estimation of the directional distance function. The implicit input-quantity

variable is constructed using a multilateral Tornqvist index, where each variable

contribution is deflated by a weighted price index of expenditure share and the

corresponding natural logarithm of inputs (Caves et al. 1982).4

2.3 Results and discussion

The coefficient estimates for the Bayesian direction distance function are presented in

Table 2.2. As expected, the estimates have positive first-order coefficients for inputs and

negative first-order coefficients for outputs, implying that monotonicity conditions are

satisfied (Hajargasht et al. 2008; Feng and Serletis 2010). The highest posterior density

intervals (HPDIs) for all first order coefficients are either on the left-side of zero (for

outputs) or on the right-side of zero (for inputs). Since our data was mean-scaled prior to

model estimation, these coefficients can be interpreted as elasticities evaluated at the

mean of the sample (Hajargasht et al. 2008; Khataza et al. 2017). For example, the mean

elasticities ( )T iD x , with respect to land, fertiliser and labour are 0.32, 0.20 and 0.18,

respectively. The productivity effect of material inputs (an index of seed and non-fertiliser

chemicals) was the lowest (0.05), relative to the other three inputs. The positive (negative)

input (output) elasticities in the directional distance function imply that technical

inefficiency increases with the level of input use (Hajargasht et al. 2008; Feng and Serletis

2010). That is, increasing the input bundle required to produce a fixed amount of crop

output could increase the distance to the frontier. Conversely, the negative output

4 The translog multilateral output (input) index for the kth farm is given by:

ln 0.5 ln lnk k

k i i i i

i

R R q q , where R represents revenue (expenditure) share for the ith

commodity (input) and q is the corresponding output (input) quantity.

Page 47: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

35

elasticities indicate that, given a set of inputs, producing more output reduces technical

inefficiency.

Table 2.2 Estimates of the Bayesian directional distance function

Parameter Notation Mean SD HPDI HPDI

2.5% 2.5%

Intercept 0 0.000 0.018 -0.039 0.032

1y 1 -0.113 0.030 -0.184 -0.067

2y 2 -0.148 0.033 -0.195 -0.067

1x 3 0.321 0.035 0.253 0.397

2x 4 0.199 0.016 0.163 0.226

3x 5 0.175 0.041 0.111 0.272

4x 6 0.045 0.010 0.028 0.068

2

1y 11 -1.1E-08 0.000 -9.2E-08 -1.2E-12

1y 2y 12 2.9E-07 0.000 -1.2E-05 1.6E-05

1y 1x 13 1.1E-06 0.000 -2.7E-05 4.2E-05

1y 2x 14 -6.8E-08 0.000 -2.6E-05 2.7E-05

1y 3x 15 -7.5E-07 0.000 -3.7E-05 2.8E-05

1y 4x 16 -2.5E-08 0.000 -4.8E-06 4.7E-06

2

2y 22 -0.001 0.003 -0.010 -9.1E-08

2y 1x 23 -0.002 0.005 -0.018 0.002

2y 2x 24 -1.2E-04 0.003 -0.008 0.007

2y 3x 25 4.2E-04 0.004 -0.006 0.012

2y 4x 26 1.0E-05 0.001 -0.002 0.002

2

1x 33 -0.011 0.021 -0.081 -1.4E-05

1x 2x 34 0.003 0.011 -0.015 0.037

1x 3x 35 0.006 0.013 -0.008 0.046

1x 4x 36 0.001 0.002 -0.003 0.007

2

2x 44 -0.029 0.007 -0.038 -0.010

2x 3x 45 0.027 0.011 -0.002 0.042

2x 4x 46 -0.001 0.003 -0.007 0.004

2

3x 55 -0.036 0.014 -0.069 -0.007

3x 4x 56 0.004 0.003 -0.004 0.010

Page 48: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

36

2

4x 66 -0.003 0.001 -0.005 -0.001

Gamma 2 2 2( )u u v 0.955 0.015 0.920 0.978

Note: HPDI =Highest posterior density interval

Page 49: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

37

2.3.1 Technical efficiency estimates

Table 2.3 presents a summary of the directional distance function measure of technical

inefficiency. The distance-estimate serves as a measure of firm-specific technical

inefficiency in the sample. The overall mean technical inefficiency (TI) is estimated at

0.69. Given that we used unit directional vectors ( , ; 1,1)x yg g g , the estimated

inefficiency score can be interpreted as a simultaneous potential decrease in inputs and

increase in outputs that can be achieved; all measured in terms of sample mean input and

output values. The estimated inefficiency score of 0.69 implies that, if all farms became

technically efficient, the average improvement would be equivalent to each farm

simultaneously achieving input reduction and output expansion equivalent to,

respectively, 69% of the sample mean input and output levels reported in Table 2.1. This

productivity gain could be achieved entirely through internal farm re-organisation or

improved management while using the same amounts and quality of resources. In terms

of scale efficiency, the estimates of the returns to scale (RTS) do not differ across the

three farm size categories. It is observed that all farm categories are scale inefficient

because they are operating at increasing rate of return (i.e. RTS>1).

Table 2.3 Estimated measures of technical inefficiency across farm size classes

Farm size category Mean TI TI Range RTS Gini index

Small (n = 68) 0.42 0 – 1.83 3.29 0.35

Medium (n = 137) 0.66 0.03 – 1.92 2.94 0.28

Large (n = 73) 0.99 0.04 – 2.97 3.55 0.30

Pooled (n = 278) 0.69 0 – 2.97 3.18 0.34

Note: TI = Technical inefficiency; RTS = Returns to scale

Page 50: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

38

Our findings are comparable to other studies analysing the performance of smallholder

agricultural production systems in Africa, although few studies have used directional

distance function and Bayesian approaches. For example, Khataza et al. (2017) used a

directional input distance function approach and reported mean technical inefficiency of

0.52 for a sample of the Malawian integrated maize-legume production system. For a

sample of vegetable growers in Benin, Singbo et al. (2014) applied a directional distance

function and reported marketing inefficiency of 0.25. Our inefficiency estimates, which

relate to macronutrient outputs and conventional inputs, are relatively close to the

Malawian study but are higher than the inefficiencies reported for Benin (Singbo et al.

2014). Given such levels of productive inefficiencies, it is clear from these studies that

expansion of food production is feasible in Malawi and other African states. Therefore,

maximising production efficiency is important to meet the demand for food in the region.

We now explore the relationship between farm-size and efficiency. The results presented

in Table 2.3 and Appendix 2.A1 show that, on average, small farms tend to be more

technically efficient (0.42) compared to medium farms (0.66) and large farms (0.99). Due

to productive inefficiencies, the observed input (output) mix for an average small farm is

42% higher (lower) than the most technically efficient quantities. Similarly, the

productivity gap for an average farm representing the large-sized category is 99% higher

than the optimal input use, while output is 99% lower than what could have been realised

if the firm operated efficiently. To examine whether the inter-class efficiency scores are

statistically different among the three farm-size classes, we use the nonparametric

Kruskal-Wallis test,5 as an alternative to the analysis of variance (ANOVA) test. The

5 The Kruskal-Wallis test was adopted after rejecting the null hypothesis that our efficiency-score variable

is normally distributed. Based on the test statistics for the Shapiro-Wilk test ( 2 52 ) and

Skewness/Kurtosis test ( 6.41z ), the normality assumption was rejected (p<0.001).

Page 51: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

39

ANOVA test is suitable for examining the equality of means for more than two groups.

This test, however, requires that the normality assumption on the dependent variable

(efficiency scores) is satisfied, which in our case is not met. Based on the Kruskal-Wallis

test results, we conclude that the level of efficiency tends to differ across these classes (

=59.69, p<0.001). These results support the existence of an inverse relationship

between farm-size and efficiency.

We also adopt the concepts of the Gini coefficient (concentration index) and Lorenz curve

to examine differences in the distribution of inefficiency across farm classes. This

approach has many benefits, including scale invariance. This property makes the Gini-

index suitable for measuring monetary and non-monetary inequalities, such as

inefficiency distributions (Allison 1978; Dervaux et al. 2004; Jacobson et al. 2005). The

Lorenz curve summarises inequality in such a way that the curve would lie along the 45o

diagonal line through the origin, if the estimated inefficiency measures were equal for all

farms in a given subclass; otherwise, the curve tilts outwards as the size of the individual

inefficiencies tend to be unequal. The Gini coefficient for a random inefficiency sample

( e ) of size n is calculated as 1

2ˆ 2 i ji j

G n e e e

(Allison 1978; Jacobson et al. 2005).

Typically, the index ranges between zero and one; where a value of zero indicates perfect

equality of observations, and the index approaches unity when observations differ

extremely. This information can be used to analyse the contribution of separate firms to

the total industry efficiency, given that efficiency scores derived from the directional

distance function can be consistently aggregated into a measure of industry efficiency

(Färe and Grosskopf 2004; Hailu and Chambers 2012). The Lorenz curves comparing the

level of efficiency among small, medium and large farms are presented in Figure 2.1.

2

Page 52: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

40

Figure 2.1 Lorenz curves showing inefficiency distributions across the three farm size categories

Since the three curves do not intersect, we can conclude that the Gini-index associated

with each curve gives unambiguous ranking of inequality among the three farm size

categories. As can be noted in Figure 2.1, the inefficiency measure appears to be

moderately concentrated in all the three farm classes. However, the intensity of dispersion

(spread) varies across these farm categories and is highest under small farms with a Gini

coefficient of 0.35, followed by large farms (0.30) and medium farms (0.28). From the

Lorenz curves, we note that the bottom 30%, middle 60% and top 10% of the small farms

account for 11%, 65% and 24% of the total within-group inefficiency, respectively. On

the other hand, the bottom 30% and the top 10% of the farms in the medium-sized group

account for 14% and 20% of the total within-group inefficiency, respectively. Similarly,

for large farms, the bottom 30% of the farms accounts for 12% of the total inefficiency,

whereas the middle 60% accounts for 67% of the total inefficiency. These results provide

0.1

.2.3

.4.5

.6.7

.8.9

1

Cum

ula

tive

pro

port

ion o

f in

effi

cien

cy

0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1

Cumulative population proportion

Small farms Medium farms Large farms

Page 53: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

41

further evidence that the majority of the large farms under-utilize available resources per

unit of realised output. It is likely that small farms carefully match available household

resources, such as labour and financial capital, with the size of the farms that they operate.

For example, farmers’ reliance on manpower and traditional farm equipment (such as

hand hoe or ox-drawn ploughs) for all critical farm operations could be a major source of

drudgery, as the size of the operated area increases considerably. In view of this,

landowners could improve their productive efficiency by operating reasonable farm-sizes

while renting out surplus land or enlisting excess land to conservation programs (green

payment schemes), where such markets exist.

2.4 Conclusions and policy implications

This paper examined the relationship between farm-size and efficiency in the context of

a developing country, where the challenges posed by declining soil fertility are

significant. A Bayesian directional distance function was used to investigate the size-

efficiency relationship in the context of Malawian production systems. The study

provides evidence of technical inefficiency and these inefficiencies are potentially

associated with farm management decisions such as the size of operated area, given as

the total area allocated to food crop cultivation in a season. Following the evidence that

smaller farms are more efficient than larger ones, it is important that resource-poor

farmers operate farm-sizes that better match the level of their resource endowment. The

majority of smallholder farmers depend on manpower and often do not have adequate

financial resources to purchase sufficient non-land inputs such as fertiliser and improved

seeds that are needed to support larger scale operations. Thus, extension advisors should

encourage farmers to operate reasonable farm-sizes which are consistent with available

complementary resources.

Page 54: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

42

Given that large farms are shown to be the most inefficient, these farmers may benefit

more if conservation and lease markets exist or could emerge. Where land markets are

functional, any excess or uncultivated land is likely to be exchanged at commercially

attractive rates. However, the current customary land rights common in SSA prevent

farmers from operating efficient farm size structures and limit long-term sustainable land-

care investments (Vanlauwe et al. 2014). A possible policy option would be to facilitate

land-lease markets, through instruments such as land certification (titling) and tenancy

contracts (Benin et al. 2005; Holden et al. 2009). Setting up more effective land lease

markets with clearly defined land-rights could provide a number of benefits such as

incentivising landholders to adopt sustainable land-care and land-intensification

strategies. Additionally, land markets could ensure that farmers have attractive land-

trading or land-leasing arrangements, and could thus, allocate surplus land to

conservation programs or other farmers, in cases where land is not utilised intensively.

Thus, the emergence of such market arrangements would incentivise farmers to operate

more efficient farm sizes.

Page 55: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

43

Appendix 2.0

Table 2.A1: Comparative energy and protein content of food crops produced by the

sample households (per 100 g)

Commodity Energy (kcal) Protein (g)

Cassava tapioca 360.00 0.60

Cereals general 331.00 11.90

Common beans 291.00 23.60

Fresh vegetables 19.00 1.90

Groundnuts 598.00 29.00

Maize 355.00 9.20

Millet 378.00 11.00

Peas 306.00 21.70

Pulses 314.00 23.40

Rice 332.00 6.70

Roots and tubers 104.00 1.30

Sorghum 339.00 11.30

Soybeans 416.00 36.50

Source: FAO 2001 Food balance sheets: A handbook. Food and Agriculture Organization of the

United Nations. http://www.fao.org/docrep/w0078e/w0078e06.htm

http://www.wfp.org/fais/nutritional-reporting/food-composition-table

Figure 2.A1. Relationship between technical inefficiency (TI) and farm-size

0.5

11.5

2

Tec

hnic

al i

nef

fici

ency

(T

I)

0 1 2 3 4

Size of area operated (ha)

Lower bound 95% HPDI Mean TI Upper bound 95% HPDI

Page 56: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

44

Page 57: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

45

CHAPTER 3

Estimating shadow price for symbiotic nitrogen and technical

efficiency for legume-based conservation agriculture in Malawi

This paper has been published as:

Khataza, R.R.B, Hailu A., Kragt M.E., Doole G.J. (2017). Estimating shadow price for symbiotic

nitrogen and technical efficiency for legume-based conservation agriculture in Malawi.

Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 61, 462–480.

3.0 Abstract

Determining the value of legumes as soil-fertility amendments can be challenging, yet

this information is required to guide public policy and to incentivise prescribed land-

management practices such as conservation agriculture. We use a directional input

distance function (DIDF) to estimate shadow prices for symbiotic nitrogen and the

technical efficiency for mixed maize-legume production systems in Malawi. The shadow

prices reflect the trade-off between fertiliser-nitrogen and symbiotic-nitrogen required to

achieve a given quantity of output. Our results reveal considerable technical inefficiency

in the production system. The estimated shadow prices vary across farms and are, on

average, higher than the reference price for commercial nitrogen. The results suggest that

it would be beneficial to redesign the current price-support programs that subsidise

chemical fertilisers and indirectly crowd-out organic soil amendments such as legumes.

Key words: Africa, biological nitrogen fixation, directional distance function, efficiency

and productivity, sustainable agricultural intensification

Page 58: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

46

3.1 Introduction

Legumes are an important component of smallholder farming systems in sub-Saharan

Africa (Sanginga, 2003; Giller et al. 2009). Besides crop outputs, legume-based cropping

systems (henceforth LBCS) supply a variety of indirect benefits that are essential for

sustainable agricultural intensification (Giller et al. 2009; Jensen et al. 2012; Preissel et

al. 2015). For example, LBCS can help to suppress parasitic weeds and pest/disease

incidence recurring from the use of monoculture. In addition to breaking the disease cycle

and controlling weeds, LBCS maintain soil fertility through nutrient recycling and

prevention of soil erosion (Giller et al. 2009; Preissel et al. 2015). Thus, the organic soil

amendments supplied through LBCS can reduce the need, at least partly, for commercial

fertiliser application and can hence lower farm investment costs (Pannell and Falconer,

1988; Sanginga, 2003; Mafongoya et al. 2007). Furthermore, as part of a soil-nitrogen

management plan, LBCS represent a cheap form of abatement to reduce nitrogen

leachates associated with excessive fertiliser use (Jensen et al. 2012). However, the values

of LBCS benefits, particularly the nutrient-recycling function, have not been adequately

studied. This is partly because the nitrogen derived from legume-association is an

intermediate resource which is neither directly observable nor traded in commodity

markets, and thus difficult to value through direct market prices. Instead, valuing

biological nitrogen derived from legume-based symbiotic fixation process (LBSF-N)

requires the application of indirect methods, such as shadow pricing (Piot-Lepetit and

Vermersch 1998; Reinhard et al. 1999; Färe et al. 2009).

Valuing soil-fertility benefits can help ascertain the economic importance of LBCS, and

justify the role of legumes in conservation agriculture and sustainable environmental

management. Currently, legume intensification is being promoted in sub-Saharan Africa

Page 59: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

47

as one of the strategies available under conservation agriculture (Giller et al. 2009;

Thierfelder et al. 2013). For example, in Malawi, the Government has included legume

seed as part of the targeted farm input support program. The farm-subsidy program

promotes both chemical and biological (legumes) fertilisers. Coincidentally, the impact

of conservation agriculture practices is not well researched in the case of Malawi and

other African countries (Giller et al. 2009; Thierfelder et al. 2013). Therefore, accurate

information on the economic benefits of LBSF-N will be useful for policy interventions

that promote conservation agriculture across Africa.

A few studies have attempted to value LBSF-N (Pannell and Falconer, 1988; Döbereiner,

1997; Smil, 1999; Herridge et al. 2008; Chianu et al. 2011). Apart from Pannell and

Falconer (1988) and Schilizzi and Pannell (2001) who use bio-economic modelling

approaches to value LBSF-N, previous studies have mainly applied the replacement-cost

method to estimate the value of LBSF-N (Smil, 1999; Herridge et al. 2008; Chianu et al.

2011). The replacement-cost method is based on an assumption that the two alternative

inputs being valued are perfectly substitutable; thus, the estimates arising from this

method do not capture changes in the degree of input substitutability. We address this

limitation by adopting an econometric approach, and use the ratio of marginal products

to determine the degree of substitutability between a pair of inputs. In our approach, we

apply the directional input distance function (DIDF) technique to estimate shadow prices

for LBSF-N. The estimated shadow price reflects the trade-off between nitrogen from

commercial fertilisers and LBSF-N, required to produce a given quantity of output.

Accordingly, this shadow price represents the benefit of using LBSF-N as a production

input.

Page 60: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

48

The paper makes a contribution to the literature in two ways. First, we demonstrate the

application of a DIDF to value the contribution of LBSF-N as a factor of production. To

the best of our knowledge, this is the first study to apply DIDF to value LBSF-N.

Although a non-frontier production function could be used to determine shadow prices,

as in Barbier (1994) and Magnan et al. (2012), such an approach does not account for

inefficiencies. Given the extent of inefficiency routinely reported in studies evaluating

the performance of smallholder agriculture, it is more appropriate to use more general

frameworks that allow for the estimation of both inefficiency and shadow prices.

Compared to other frontier-based approaches, the DIDF represents a flexible technique

that can derive an inefficiency measure that accounts for possible input reductions. With

the DIDF, it is possible to set a uniform translation vector that evaluates the extent to

which the technology can achieve input (cost) savings (Färe and Grosskopf 2004; Färe et

al. 2009; Hailu and Chambers, 2012). A key advantage of such an approach is that the set

of individual firm’s inefficiencies can be compared across farms and summed into an

aggregate measure of industry inefficiency (Färe and Grosskopf 2004; Färe et al. 2008;

Färe et al. 2009; Hailu and Chambers, 2012). An alternative distance function

specification is the radial approach, where the directional-vector for input contraction or

output expansion is data-driven (dictated by the input or output mix for each observation)

and therefore unknown to the analyst (Färe et al. 2008; Hailu and Chambers, 2012).

Radial input (output) distance function values reflect the highest (lowest) possible

proportionate reduction in inputs (outputs) and thus provide only relative measures of

inefficiency (Hailu and Veeman, 2000). Further, the DIDF, like its radial distance

function counterpart, can be used to represent multi-input, multi-output production

technologies (Hailu and Veeman, 2000). Our second contribution is on the application of

a bootstrapping technique, within the DIDF method, to test the robustness of the estimates

(Canty, 2002; Canty and Ripley, 2015). By using the bootstrapping technique, we are able

Page 61: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

49

to get a sense of the variability surrounding shadow price and technical efficiency

estimates.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows. In the next section we present a theoretical

representation of the DIDF, followed by empirical estimation procedures presented in

Section 3.3. We describe the study site and data in Section 3.4. Finally, empirical results

are discussed in Section 3.5 and conclusions are presented in Section 3.6.

3.2 Theoretical model

The productive efficiency of a firm is determined by comparing its inputs and outputs

against the boundaries of the best-practice frontier. A firm’s measure of inefficiency is

given by how far that firm is from the frontier boundary. Denote production inputs by

1 2, ,....., N

Nx x x x and outputs by 1 2, ,....., M

My y y y . Then a production

technology, which maps out all feasible input-output combinations, can be defined as an

input requirement set ( ) : L y x x can produce y .

Directional or radial input (or output) distance functions provide alternative avenues for

modelling the production technology. We adopt an input directional technology distance

function, which is dual to the cost function and, therefore, is convenient for modelling

input substitution possibilities. The directional input distance function

( , ; ) : ( , ) ( )sup xxDIDF x y g x g y L y

, represents the technology and helps to

measure a firm’s level of inefficiency. The vector, ( )N

xg g , is the translation metric

which maps the directions in which inputs are scaled. Thus, the translation vector seeks

Page 62: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

50

to achieve input contraction in the xg -direction. For any firm on the frontier boundary,

( , ; ) 0xDIDF x y g , indicating that it is technically infeasible to translate the input bundle

in any direction. Conversely, any firm below the technology frontier has a positive

distance value, ( , ; ) 0xDIDF x y g , such that the observed input bundle can be translated

in the direction given by ( )xg g .

The DIDF inherits the standard properties imposed on the production technology ( )L y

(Chambers et al. 1996; Färe et al. 2008). We assume that ( )L y is a closed, convex,

nonempty set with inputs and outputs freely disposable (Färe et al. 2008). Other important

properties of the DIDF technology include: 1) representation, which implies that all

technologically feasible input-output combinations have non-negative directional

distance function value, and vice-versa; 2) translation, which denotes that adding a

multiple of the direction vector to the input-output bundle reduces the distance function

by that multiple; 3) monotonicity, which indicates that the function is non-decreasing in

inputs and non-increasing in outputs; and 4) the function is concave in the input-output

vector (Chambers et al. 1996; Färe et al. 2008).

We derive shadow prices for LBSF-N by exploiting the duality relationship between the

DIDF and the cost function. Let 1 2, ,....., N

Nw w w w denote the vector of input

prices for which the shadow cost function is given by:

( , ) : ( ) (1)x

C y w i nf wx x L y

Page 63: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

51

Equation (1) gives the minimum cost that can be achieved, given input price ( w ) and

output vector My . It follows from the principle of cost minimisation that

( , ) ( )C y x wx x L y . That is, the minimum cost cannot exceed the actual cost of

producing My . Achieving input-efficiency implies that

( , : ). ( )x xx DIDF y x g g L y . Thus, for any production situation where technical

inefficiency can be reduced or eliminated, the minimum cost ought to be lower than the

actual costs as follows:

( , ) ( , : ). ( , : ) (2)x x x xC y x w x DIDF y x g g wx wg DIDF y x g

By rearranging Equation (2), the duality relationship between the cost function and the

DIDF can be expressed as (Chambers et al. 1996; Färe et al. 2009):

( , )( , : ) min (3)x

wx

wx C y xDIDF y x g

wg

Applying the envelope theorem to Equation (3) yields the following normalised input

price vector:

( , ; )1,2,....... (4)n x

n

DIDF x y gw wg n N

x

Provided that the DIDF is differentiable, one can estimate partial derivatives and use these

to derive shadow prices. For any two different inputs, n and n , it follows that their price

ratio equals the corresponding ratio of distance function derivatives. The ratio of distance

function derivatives indicates the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRS) expressed

by (Chambers et al. 1996):

Page 64: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

52

( , ; ) , (5)

( , ; ) n n

n x n nx x

n x n n

w DIDF x y g x MPxMRS n n

w DIDF x y g x MPx

where nw is the price for the thn production factor ( nx ), and xMP is the marginal product

derived with respect to factor x . Thus, the knowledge of one factor price ( nw ) can be

used to compute the price of the unknown inputs; in this case, LBSF-N.

In addition to the marginal products, one can also obtain technical (in)efficiency

measures, if a frontier-based technical relationship is specified. For a directional distance

measure of inefficiency, zero distance indicates that a firm is fully efficient, and a positive

distance-function value shows the level of inefficiency as follows:

( , ) ( , ; ) (6)xTI x y DIDF x y g

3.3 Empirical estimation

Both non-parametric approaches (e.g. data envelopment analysis (DEA)) and parametric

methods (e.g. stochastic frontier analysis) can be used to estimate the DIDF parameters.

We specify the DIDF as a parametric function, which is differentiable and thus it is easy

to recover shadow prices from it. Such a parametric specification can be estimated either

as a deterministic frontier or as a stochastic function. In our approach, we estimate the

DIDF as a deterministic frontier using mathematical-programming techniques to impose

representation, monotonicity and translation properties on the function easily (Färe and

Grosskopf 2004; Färe et al. 2009; Hailu and Chambers, 2012; Bostian and Herlihy, 2014).

The stochastic-frontier models could also be estimated using maximum-likelihood

methods (e.g. Coelli and Perelman, 2000) or using Bayesian methods (e.g. O’Donnell and

Coelli, 2005; Hailu and Chambers, 2012). Although one could impose monotonicity and

Page 65: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

53

other conditions using Bayesian methods, the choice of proper priors on the parameters

of frontier models is not straightforward; and the use of improper priors could affect the

accuracy of the posterior estimates (Fernández et al. 1997; Fernández et al. 2000).

Bayesian estimation is also computationally intensive and more difficult. Alternatively,

theoretical regularity restrictions can be imposed more easily using mathematical

programming techniques, as is the case in this study. This approach is straightforward,

given the central importance of constraints in defining the feasible space in constrained

optimisation problems.

The quadratic functional form is used because it is a flexible form that allows for the

global imposition of the translation property (Hailu and Chambers, 2012). We choose the

unit directional vectors, with negative elements for inputs and zero elements for output,

so that the projection to the frontier of an observed point seeks to contract inputs while

holding the output vector constant. Since the data are normalised by mean values, the use

of the unit vector for direction is equivalent to the use of the average sample direction for

the translation. By assigning the unit vectors, the directional input distance function gives

an estimate of the maximum unit reduction in inputs that is feasible for a given amount

of output (Färe and Grosskopf 2004; Hailu and Chambers, 2012). This approach is

valuable because it makes it easier to interpret the estimated measure of technical

inefficiency as proportions of the sample mean-values. Further, when a common

directional vector is chosen for all firms, the directional distance function measure of

inefficiency for an individual firm can be aggregated to a measure of industry inefficiency

(Färe and Grosskopf 2004; Färe et al. 2008; Fare et al 2009; Hailu and Chambers, 2012).

The quadratic DIDF is specified as follows:

Page 66: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

54

0

1 1 1 1

1 1 1 1

( , ; -1, 0) 0.5 .. (7)

0.5 . .

N M N N

n n m m nn n n

n m n n

M M M N

mm m m mn m n

m m m n

DIDF x y x y x x

y y y x u

where my represents the production output under consideration, nx is a vector of inputs,

and u represents the inefficiency term. Equation (7) is estimated in R, using APEAR

package (Hailu, 2013).

The underlying distance function and parameter values ( s and u) are based on a true, but

unobserved, technology frontier. Typically, the estimated frontier and parameters depend

on a sample of observations, usually believed to be representative of the true population.

Thus, one empirical challenge is to mitigate the potential bias that could result from small

samples and sampling variability. Therefore, we apply nonparametric bootstrapping

techniques to explore the variability of our sample estimates. Using the bootstrapping

procedure explained in Canty (2002) and Canty and Ripley (2015), the estimation of the

function in Equation (7) was bootstrapped a thousand times, whereby each pseudo

(bootstrap) sample was drawn with replacement from the original sample.

We start by assuming that a random sample, replicated r-times and where r is large

enough, can be used to construct the unknown population distribution from which the

original sample was drawn. Application of Equation (7) to the bootstrap sample gives

distance function parameters ̂ , and the distribution function F̂ , which are considered to

approximate the true population parameters, and F . A bootstrapping algorithm

generates r-pseudo samples which can yield consistent sample parameters *ˆr and F̂ . The

bootstrap sample-parameters are related to the true unobserved population parameters in

the following way:

Page 67: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

55

ˆˆ (8)f F f F

Equation (8) shows that given a representative sample, the estimated sample parameters

can be used to recover population parameters. Through resampling, an approximate

empirical distribution can be obtained for any statistics of interest, for example, the

variance and standard error. The statistics that are generated through bootstrapping in this

analysis are as follows:

* *

0.5

2 2* * * *

1 1

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ( ) ;

1 1ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ; (9)

1 1

r r

R R

r r r r

r r

bias E

ser r

where and se represent the variance and standard errors of individual parameters,

respectively. For a detailed description of this bootstrapping procedure, the reader is

referred to Canty (2002) and Canty and Ripley (2015).

3.4 Study area and data description

3.4.1 Study area

We use survey data collected from Kasungu and Mzimba districts in Malawi. The survey

was conducted in the 2013/14 crop season. These districts are part of the medium-altitude

agro-ecological zone of the country. A subdivision of this agro-ecological zone is the

Kasungu–Lilongwe plain. This zone is one of the areas where LBCS are most dominant

in Malawi.

The survey followed a three-stage random sampling approach. First, the study zones were

selected based on Ministry of Agriculture administrative demarcations, known as

Page 68: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

56

extension planning areas (EPAs). The EPAs are district-level administrative units

established to coordinate and oversee the execution of extension services across the

country. The second step involved the choice of an EPA section. An EPA section is the

lowest unit of administration in the Ministry of Agriculture hierarchy. Subsequently,

maize-legume producers were identified for each EPA section. This procedure was done

in order to establish a sampling frame. Third, after the selection of EPA sections and

enumeration of maize-legume producers were completed, face-to-face interviews were

conducted with a set of randomly chosen respondents (household heads).

3.4.2 Data description

The survey collected information on farm and household characteristics. We use primary

data from a sub-sample of 135 plots, representing the mixed maize-legume cropping

system. Fifty-five per cent of the sample (74 plots) was from Kasungu and the remainder

(45 per cent) came from Mzimba district (61 plots). We recorded one maize-legume

intercropped plot per producer hence the number of producers is the same as the number

of plots. The sample represents 13 per cent and 12 per cent of the total number of maize-

legume producers enumerated in Mzimba district (453) and Kasungu district (596),

respectively. Therefore, the number of farms sampled in the two districts are

proportionately represented. However, we realise that our sample size (135 out of 1049

farms) is relatively small; hence, we employ bootstrapping procedures to ameliorate some

potential problems associated with sampling variability. Typically, farmers intercropped

maize with common beans (Phaseolus vulgaris), groundnuts (Arachis hypogaea), or

soybean (Glycine max). Table 3.1 summarises the data.

Page 69: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

57

Table 3.1 Descriptive statistics for the variables used in the estimation (n = 135)

Variable name Unit 6 Mean SD Min. Max.

Output

Crop output (y) Output

index/acre 0.32 0.24 0.01 1.31

Inputs

Fertiliser nitrogen (x1) kg N /acre 27.33 19.78 0.00 109.00

Symbiotic nitrogen (x2) kg N/acre 0.74 1.13 0.00 11.06

Labour (x3) AEU/acre 1.88 1.28 0.18 8.05

Other variable inputs (x4) Input index/acre 1.74 1.15 0.23 8.94

Note AEU = Adult equivalent units (1 Male-adult = 1 AEU, 1 Female=0.8 AEU, 1 Child=0.5 AEU)

Total crop output is an implicit output-quantity index aggregated using a multilateral

Tornqvist approach, where the contribution of each commodity is weighted by its relative

share in total crop-value and the corresponding natural logarithm of outputs (Caveset al.

1982).7 Similarly, the aggregate value for other variable inputs represents an implicit

input-quantity index comprising purchased seeds, non-fertiliser chemicals and herbicides.

This implicit input-quantity variable is deflated by a weighted price index of expenditure

share and the corresponding natural logarithm of inputs. A total of four production inputs

are included in the estimation of the input distance function. These inputs are quantity of

commercial fertiliser, family labour, farm expenses, and symbiotic nitrogen. The quantity

of commercial fertiliser is expressed in kilograms of total nitrogen as the major active

ingredient contained in the fertilisers used in production. The main mineral fertilisers used

6 Following other previous studies (e.g. Seyoum et al. 1998; Mochebelele and Nelson 2000; Hazarika and

Alwang 2003), the analysis assumes that the underlying production technology is globally characterised by

constant returns to scale (CRS) such that each firm is automatically scale efficient. In a CRS economy with

perfect factor markets, there should be no observed differences in productivity across farm sizes (Coelli et

al. 2005; Kagin et al. 2016). However, this chapter does not test the effect of farm size on

efficiency/productivity, an objective which is reserved and explored in Chapter 2. Thus, the econometric

model estimated in this chapter does not include farm size as an explanatory variable.

7 We thank an anonymous reviewer for this suggestion. The translog multilateral output (input) index for

the kth farm is given by: ln 0.5 ln lnk k

k i i i i

i

R R q q , where R represents revenue

(expenditure) share for the ith commodity (input) and q is the corresponding output (input) quantity.

Page 70: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

58

in the maize-based production in Malawi are Urea, Calcium Ammonium Nitrate, and

23:21:0+4S. These three fertilisers, respectively, contain 46 per cent, 27 per cent, and 23

per cent nitrogen (N). Family labour is converted to adult-equivalent-units (AEU), which

represents farm labour supply measured in terms of full-time equivalent employees. The

computation of AEU is based on the conversion factors as follows: one adult male (15

years of age and over, working on a full day-basis) represents one AEU, whereas one

adult female working for a full day represents 0.8 AEU, and one child (5-14 years)

working for a full day represents 0.5 AEU (Deere and de Janvry 1981; Fletschner 2008;

Takane 2008). Overall, the data presented in Table 3.1 show wide variations in terms of

the input-output combinations, which reflects farm heterogeneity regarding resource

endowment and managerial ability, among other factors.

Symbiotic nitrogen (LBSF-N) is included as an additional source of nitrogen, which is

available to the component crops through intercropping and legume rotation. LBSF-N

values are not directly observable. However, the literature currently contains abundant

LBSF-N estimates that are obtained using reliable measurement methods, such as 15N-

based techniques (Peoples et al. 2009; Ronner and Franke, 2012). We use published

LBSF-N estimates to compute the amount of symbiotic N fixed on agricultural land. The

quantity of symbiotic nitrogen was computed based on the harvest-index method, which

relates plant biomass, nitrogen concentrations, and the proportion of atmospheric nitrogen

fixed (Høgh-Jensen et al. 2004; Herridge et al. 2008; Peoples et al. 2009). Alternatively,

one could use total area under leguminous crops to quantify the amount of farm-level

symbiotic nitrogen fixation. However, we prefer to use grain-weight because the quantity

and quality of grain harvested also reflects the growth conditions in which the crop

developed and matured (Stern, 1993). Thus, crop productivity (yield) is used as an

indirect measure of soil quality (fertility) and captures potential differences in soil quality

Page 71: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

59

across farms. Computation details for LBSF-N are provided in the appendix and

summarised in Table 3.A1.

LBSF-N was estimated for two cropping practices, namely, intercropping and crop

rotation. LBSF-N from intercropping was estimated using the harvest-index method (see

Table 3.A1), whereas that from crop rotation was estimated using coefficients obtained

from fitting a crop-response model (Stauber and Burt, 1973; Stauber et al. 1975; Frank et

al. 1990). The crop-response model was specified as a quadratic function to allow for

diminishing marginal productivity as follows:

2 2

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 1. (10)t t t t t t t t ty N x N x N x N

where ty is output in the current season t, tN is the quantity of nitrogen applied in the

current season, 1tN is the carry-over nitrogen from the previous season, x represents

other factors of production, and is the random error term. Table 3.A2 shows the results

of the crop-response model.

In our sample, crop rotations had been adopted on 61 farms (45 per cent). Out of these 61

farms, 72 per cent were legume-maize rotations and most of the remaining (23 per cent)

were tobacco-maize rotations. Further, 52 per cent of the sample (135 farms) practiced

in-situ crop residue retention, a practice aimed at enhancing soil productivity through

residue mineralisation. We used this plot-history data to test whether crop rotation has

significant effects on land productivity (i.e. crop yield) and the evidence suggests positive

incremental effects (Table 3.A2). The net residual nitrogen was then estimated implicitly

as a ratio of input elasticities for the intercropped LBSF-N and the rotation variables.

Page 72: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

60

3.5 Results and discussion

The coefficient estimates of the directional input distance function are reported in Table

3.A3. The estimated first-order coefficients have the expected signs: they are positive for

inputs and negative for output variables, with generally small standard errors.

3.5.1 Estimated measure of technical efficiency

Recall that technical inefficiency is given by the relative distance to the frontier and the

shorter the distance, the more efficient the production unit is. Table 3.2 presents the results

of the DIDF measure of technical inefficiency (TI). The DIDF estimates reveal a

considerable level of inefficiency for the sample farms. Only 31 farms (representing 23

per cent of the total sample) were operating at maximum efficiency. In the DIDF (Model

1) the mean TI obtained from the bootstrap model is 0.52, compared to 0.47 from the the

base model. As a robustness check, we included directional distance function model i.e.

[g(y, x; 1,-1)], which is dual to the profit function (Model 2). In this model, both input

and output directional vectors are used to simultaneously scale the data. In general, the

TI obtained using the base (non-bootstrap) model is significantly lower than that obtained

using the bootstrap model (p<0.1). Therefore, the base model underestimates technical

inefficiency. Generally, it is the bootstrap estimates that are considered plausible and

robust (Mugera and Ojede, 2014). Thus, the TI estimate of 0.52 implies that if the average

farmer operated efficiently, she or he could produce the same output with an input bundle

that is smaller by 52% of the mean input values reported in Table 3.1. For example, a

producer who used 27.33 kg per acre of nitrogen fertiliser could have used 13.12 kg per

acre of this input to produce the average output.

Page 73: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

61

Table 3.2 Estimated directional input distance function measure of technical

inefficiency (TI)

Model 1 [g(y, x; 0,-1)] Model 2 [g(y, x; 1,-1)]

Mean TI SE [95 % CI] Mean TI SE [95% CI]

Base model 0.47 0.03 0.41 – 0.53 0.33 0.02 0.29 – 0.37

Bootstrap model 0.52 0.06 0.40 – 0.64 0.36 0.04 0.28 – 0.44

Note: CI = confidence interval

Our findings are comparable with previous studies conducted in the region, although few

studies have applied directional distance functions on African agriculture. For example,

using a directional distance function, Singbo and Lansink (2010) reported mean

inefficiency of 0.20 for the Beninese rice and vegetable production system. In another

study, Singbo et al. (2014) evaluated the performance of vegetable-production in Benin

and reported TI of 0.14 and marketing inefficiency of 0.25. Mulwa and Emrouznejad

(2013) evaluated the performance of sugarcane production in Kenya and estimated TI to

be 0.14. Collectively, this evidence shows that there is substantial scope for improving

performance in the studied production systems and African agriculture in general.

3.5.2 Morishima elasticity of input substitution

The Morishima elasticity of substitution (MES) provides complete information about

input substitutability in cases where a production technology has more than two inputs

(Blackorby and Russell, 1989). The MES measures the degree of curvature of the isoquant

or the relative change in shadow prices associated with a unit change in the ratio of the

corresponding inputs (Grosskopf et al. 1995). We calculate the indirect Morishima

Page 74: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

62

elasticities to get a sense of the ease with which one input can be substituted for another

in the production process. Equation (11) shows the MES derived from the distance

function approach (Blackorby and Russell, 1989; Grosskopf et al. 1995):

* (11)nn n nnn n

n n

DIDF DIDFMES x

DIDF DIDF

where *

nx is the frontier value of input (input level adjusted for inefficiency), and nDIDF

and nnDIDF are the first-order and second-order derivatives of the directional input

distance function, respectively. The MES estimates are reported in Table 3.3.

Table 3.3 Estimates of the indirect Morishima elasticity of input substitution

f s l o

f -0.89 [-2.21 – 0.43] 1.11 [-0.23 – 2.45] 1.06 [-0.29 – 2.40] 1.76 [0.20 – 3.33]

s 0.26 [0.10 – 0.42] -0.13 [-0.20 – -0.07] 0.01 [0.01 – 0.02] 0.27 [0.14 – 0.39]

l 0.30 [0.23 – 0.36] 0.03 [0.02 – 0.04] -0.19 [-0.24 – -0.15] 0.70 [0.28 – 1.13]

o 3.79 [0.11 – 7.48] 2.08 [0.58 – 3.58] 2.10 [0.59 – 3.61] -3.70 [-7.33 – -0.08]

Note f = fertiliser nitrogen, s = symbiotic nitrogen, l = family labour; o = other input costs

The sign and size of the MES are important: the elasticity sign helps to classify inputs as

substitutes or complements, whereas the size of the elasticity indicates the degree of

substitutability or complementarity. Inputs n and n are considered to be Morishima

substitutes if 0nnMES , or complements if 0nnMES . High MES values show a low

degree of substitution while low values indicate relative ease of substitution (Grosskopf

et al. 1995). As shown in Table 3.3, the MES elasticities are generally asymmetric (

nn n nMES MES ). For example, the substitution of commercial fertiliser for symbiotic

Page 75: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

63

nitrogen gives an elasticity value of 1.11, whereas the reverse yields 0.26. The size and

sign of the elasticities suggest that the two inputs are partially substitutable; thus,

increasing fertiliser nitrogen to replace symbiotic nitrogen is relatively difficult, but the

reverse is relatively easy.

3.5.3 Estimates of LBSF-N shadow prices

We apply Equation (5) to obtain shadow prices for LBSF-N. Table 3.4 gives a summary

of shadow prices for the base and bootstrap models. The value of LBSF-N is estimated

as a fraction of the average market price for commercial nitrogen. The price of

commercial N is US$2.11/kg N, based on the 2013/14 crop-season price of fertiliser

nitrogen (Urea) which was selling at MWK17,000 per 50 kg bag (1 US$ = 350 MWK).

The shadow price values are positive and range from 1.01 to 22.23 US$/kg, when

evaluated using the 95 per cent confidence interval.8 The mean shadow price for LBSF-

N is estimated to be US$5.26/kg for the bootstrap model, and US$20.1/kg for the base

model. The difference between the two mean shadow prices is statistically significant

(p<0.01). We note that both the base and the bootstrap models yield average shadow

prices that are higher than the reference market price of US$2.11 /kg N. The estimated

shadow values can be interpreted as the opportunity cost of using LBSF-N in terms of

foregone commercial nitrogen, keeping output constant. The estimated shadow prices are

respectively, US$5.26/kg and US$2.61 for the bootstrapped input directional distance

function or Model 1 with directional vector [g(y, x; 0,-1)] and directional distance

8 The possibility that shadow prices could be sensitive to heterogeneities in soil quality has been pointed

out by an anonymous reviewer. However, in the absence of explicit soil quality data, we believe that crop

yield is a good proxy indicator to reflect potential differences in soil quality attributes across farms. In

addition, if farmers aim to optimise investment returns, then their input allocation decisions e.g. fertiliser

application will tend to approximate the prescribed agronomic recommendations which are based on soil

quality differences across the country (Benson, 1997). Since we only have input and output data, we

consider that using the ratio of marginal products (input substitution effects) is the most reasonable

approach that accounts for the differences in farm characteristics as well as farmer characteristics. As a

result, the estimated shadow prices correspondingly vary across farms.

Page 76: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

64

function or Model 2 with directional vector [g(y, x; 1,-1)]. An alternative interpretation

of shadow-price values is to regard them as surrogate or implicit prices for a non-market

good (LBSF-N).. In this regard, the commercial fertiliser market could serve as a proxy

market for LBSF-N. Thus, our estimated mean shadow price of US$2.61 or US$5.26/kg

could serve as an appropriate accounting value for fertiliser cost-savings, achieved as a

result of substituting LBSF-N for fertiliser N. This shadow price represents the per-unit

benefit that a producer would gain by using LBSF-N as a substitute for fertiliser nitrogen

(Bond and Farzin, 2007). For example, a farm operating without any unit of fertiliser N

would increase crop output-value by US$5.26 if an extra kilogram of LBSF-N were

available in the soil.

Table 3.4 Estimated shadow prices (SP) for symbiotic nitrogen (US$/kg N)

Model 1 [g(y, x; 0,-1)] Model 2 [g(y, x; 1,-1)]

Mean SP SE [95 % CI] Mean SP SE [95 % CI]

Base model 20.10 1.07 17.98 – 22.23 4.28 0.54 3.21 – 5.36

Bootstrap model 5.26 2.15 1.01 – 9.51 2.61 1.09 0.46 – 4.76

Note: CI = confidence interval

Because shadow prices for LBSF-N are not readily available in the literature, we compare

our estimates against somewhat related environmental services. Table 3.5 presents these

studies. The analysis of sustainable intensification or best management practice most

closely related to ours is an application by Bond and Farzin (2007), which deals with the

effect of low input production system using legume cover-crops, herbicides, and air

pollution in California, USA. Unfortunately, due to limitations in their soil quality data,

the study did not include shadow prices for non-marketable inputs (legume-fertiliser

effects). Other studies that have treated nitrogen leachate from agricultural sources as a

Page 77: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

65

bad output are Shaik et al. (2002), who studied the effect of organic and inorganic

fertilisers in the USA; Reinhard et al. (1999), who assessed the Dutch dairy industry; and

Piot-Lepetit and Vermersch (1998), who analysed the French pork sector. From these

studies, the estimated shadow prices for excess nitrogen are reported to be in the range of

US$2.00-4.77/kg for the US study, US$1.86/kg for The Netherlands, and US$0.14-

1.02/kg for the French pork sector. Recently, Hou et al. (2015) estimated the cost of soil

erosion and nitrogen loss in the Chinese Ansai region. From this study, the cost of soil

erosion and nitrogen loss are estimated to be US$0.02 per kg/ha and US$0.06 per kg/ha,

respectively. The reviewed studies show variations in the estimated shadow-price values.

The variation in the shadow-price estimates in the above studies is not surprising because

each study dealt with a different sub-sector that could differ in a number of ways,

including operational scale and local environmental conditions at the study locations.

Nevertheless, our results are close to the estimates for the US and the Netherlands

(Reinhard et al. 1999; Shaik et al. 2002).

Page 78: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

66

Table 3.5 Selected studies using the distance function approach to value environmental goods and services

Environmental

good/ service

Shadow price/ value Reference price/

market

Estimation

method

Efficiency score Study region Reference

Organic N (hog

slurry)

$0.14-1.02/kg Commercial fertiliser RDF/DEA 0.94-0.96 France Piot-Lepetit and Vermersch (1998)

Organic N (dairy

slurry)

$1.86/kg Dairy output SFA 0.89 Netherlands Reinhard et al. (1999)

Soil N (N pollution) $2.00-$4.77/kg Desirable output (crop

and livestock products)

RDF - Nebraska, USA Shaik et al. (2002)

Soil N (N pollution) $3.81-$4.30/kg Input cost (crop and

livestock production)

RDF - Nebraska, USA Shaik et al. (2002)

Fertiliser N $1.38E-3 -$2.17E-3 1 DEA

(bootstrap)

0.64-0.88

(0.31-0.78)

Benin Singbo et al. (2015)

Symbiotic N $20.10/kg Commercial fertiliser

price

DIDF 0.47 Malawi This study

Symbiotic N $5.26/kg Commercial fertiliser

price

DIDF

(bootstrap)

0.52 Malawi This study

Note: DIDF = directional input distance function; DEA = data envelopment analysis; RDF = radial distance function; SFA = stochastic frontier analysis

Page 79: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

67

3.6 Conclusions

The challenge of maintaining or improving agricultural productivity in sub-Saharan

Africa is enormous. As such, agricultural researchers and policy makers are constantly

looking for technologies that are economically attractive and environmentally sound. The

best strategy to improve productivity and maintain soil fertility in sub-Saharan Africa

should focus on a combination of both inorganic and organic fertilisers for maximum

complementary benefits (Mafongoya et al. 2007). However, research evidence shows low

adoption of integrated soil fertility management practices, which includes legume

cultivation (Giller et al. 2009). A better understanding of the value of these legume

systems is needed to develop more effective economic incentives that would facilitate the

adoption of best management practices and reward soil conservation efforts.

Using the directional input distance function approach (DIDF), this study appraised the

value of symbiotic nitrogen and estimated the technical efficiency of legume-based

cropping systems (LBCS) in Malawi. Our results reveal two major findings. First, the

results show that smallholder farmers exhibit substantial production inefficiency, with a

mean directional inefficiency value of 0.52. By addressing this production inefficiency,

an average farm could reduce each of the four inputs by 52 per cent while output remains

constant. Second, the average shadow price for symbiotic nitrogen (LBSF-N) is higher

than the observed market price for commercial nitrogen fertiliser. The shadow price

values of symbiotic nitrogen (and LBCS) reflect only productivity benefits achieved

without applying any unit of chemical fertilisers. The total value of LBCS could be greater

if other environmental services and socio-economic benefits, such as their value as a

disease break and for reducing soil erosion, are accounted for.

Page 80: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

68

In the interest of maintaining a productive stock of soil capital, market-based mechanisms

could be used to help enhance legume production and promotion of conservation

agriculture. However, given the prevailing market prices, our estimated elasticities of

input substitution demonstrate that a complete substitution to organic fertilisers can be

detrimental to farm productivity. This result infers that complete conversion to organic

production will require some compensation to farmers, for example through higher output

prices, for such a substitution to be profitable. Therefore, one of the possible policy

options to incentivise farmers’ investments in conservation agriculture is to facilitate

price premiums for commodities produced from sustainably-managed farms, such as

LBCS. For example, recent studies have shown that some farmers in other African

countries such as Ghana, Kenya, and Uganda are benefiting from price premiums

received as a result of participating in certification programs targeting low input

sustainable agricultural production systems (Bolwig et al. 2009; Kleemann and Abdulai

2013; Ayuya et al. 2015). Thus, price premiums can provide incentives to farmers to

invest in legume-based conservation agriculture as part of the integrated soil fertility

management strategies.

Organic soil amendments build long-term soil fertility benefits that are usually heavily

discounted by land users, who mostly seek to maximise their present farm benefits. As a

result, there is less investment in conservation practices by the land users, partly because

produce from such low input sustainable agricultural systems are considered as non-

differentiated products. Thus, the prevailing commodity prices fail to incentivise

conservation agriculture. We contend that price premiums could be a better alternative

and a more cost-effective policy instrument for promoting LBCS than the subsidies or

public-support programs that are currently being used to promote legume production in

Malawi and other African countries. We therefore recommend that future research should

Page 81: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

69

investigate the potential demand for produce from sustainably-managed farms, and also

mechanisms through which farmers can be integrated into existing or emerging regional

and export markets for such products. Specifically, policy makers could focus on creating

and promoting an enabling environment that allows the potential benefits of LBCS to be

fully exploited by: 1) promoting knowledge about soil and other benefits of the integrated

cropping systems; 2) supporting more sustainable production processes (e.g. through

certification and labelling requirements); and 3) channelling support from current input

subsidies to the support of extension and market development activities.

Page 82: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

70

Appendix 3.0

Computation of symbiotic nitrogen using the harvest index approach

The quantity of grain harvested reflects directly the total amount of crop N that the plant

fixes, and some of this nitrogen is assimilated in the grain and straw or biomass. The

quantities of biological nitrogen fixed ( FBNF ) and the resulting nitrogen transfer to

companion crop ( ccBNF ) are derived from above-ground and below-ground biomass as

follows (Høgh-Jensen et al., 2004; Herridge et al., 2008; Peoples et al., 2009):

; (A1)

(A 2)

1; (A3)

1 1(A 4)

1(A5)

F cn cn

s s

F

s s

g

s g

g s

F

g s s g

cc

s g

BNF N N Q

BNF Q

Q hh Q Q

Q Q h

h hBNF Q Q

h h

hBNF Q

h

where represents the proportion of crop N that is derived from the atmosphere (%Ndfa),

and s is the percent N-concentration available in the shoot dry matter. The parameter

is used to derive below-ground biomass-N equivalent of the shoot dry matter. Equation

(A1) shows that the amount of nitrogen fixed is given as a product of crop-N

concentration ( cnN ) and the capacity for that crop to transform atmospheric nitrogen ( )

into a form that is usable by plants. The ability to convert atmospheric-nitrogen into plant-

nitrogen is represented by the fractional N derived from atmosphere (%Ndfa) i.e. a

proportion of total crop N that is attributable to symbiotic nitrogen fixation. The crop

nitrogen concentration can be expressed as the amount of shoot dry matter at harvest ( sQ

) and the percent N-concentration ( s ) available in that component of plant biomass. The

Page 83: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

71

parameter is used to derive below-ground biomass-N equivalent of the shoot dry matter

(Equation A2).

In situations where biological yield is not reported as part of the normal crop statistics,

the quantity of dry matter can be estimated from the amount of grain harvested ( gQ ) using

the harvest index ( h ) as denoted in equation (A3). For grain crops, the harvest index is a

ratio of the economic yield (grain) and the above-ground biomass (i.e. shoot dry matter

inclusive of grain). In equations (A4)-(A5), grain weight and harvest index substitute for

the quantity of dry matter, sQ . Finally, the N transfer/credit available for the companion

crop ( ccBNF ) in equation (A5), allows for low crop density due to intercropping and

interference of fertiliser N (Stern, 1993; Smil, 1999; Herridge et al., 2008; Unkovich et

al., 2008). We use the adjustment coefficient, , to cater for the intercropping and

fertiliser suppression effects. Parameter values used to estimate equations (A1-A5) are

synthesised from various long-term agronomic experiments as reported in the original

publications (Table 3.A1). Alternatively, one could use total area under leguminous crops

to quantify farm-level symbiotic nitrogen. However, we prefer to use grain-weight,

because the quantity and quality of grain harvested also reflects the growth conditions in

which the crop developed and matured (Stern, 1993).

Page 84: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

72

Table 3.A1 Estimates of SNF for the sample grain-legume cropping systems

Parameter Notation Data

source‡

Mean

Beans Groundnuts Soybeans

Grain harvested

(kg/acre) gQ 1 49.03 96.41 67.01

Harvest index h 2 0.35 0.4 0.4

Dry matter yield

(kg/acre)

1s g

hQ Q

h

8 91.05 144.62 100.52

Dry matter N

concentration (%) s 2 2.0 2.3 3.0

Below-ground N

conversion factor 2 1.4 1.4 1.5

Average %Ndfa 3 44 51 40

Amount of N

fixed (kg/acre)

1F

s g

hBNF Q

h

8 1.12 2.37 2.31

N-credit transfer

factor (%) 4,5,6,7 40 40 20

Total N-transfer

to a non-legume

crop (kg/acre)

ccBNF 8 0.45 0.95 0.46

‡1: Own survey; 2: Herridge et al. (2008); 3: Ronner and Franke (2012); 4: Smil (1999), 5:

Sanginga et al. (2003), 6: Chianu et al. (2011), 7: Patra et al. (1986), 8: Own

computation

Page 85: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

73

Table 3.A2 Coefficient estimates for the quadratic crop-response model

Variable Variable unit Coefficient estimate Robust SE t-value

Fertiliser N kg N/acre 0.64*** 0.21 2.98

Symbiotic N kg N/acre 0.38*** 0.11 3.42

Labour AEU/acre 0.24 0.28 0.86

Other expenses Input quantity

index/acre -0.10 0.27 -0.38

(Fertiliser N)2 0.04 0.25 0.17

(Symbiotic N)2 0.00 0.03 0.04

(Labour)2 -0.24* 0.15 -1.66

(Other expenses)2 -0.09 0.34 -0.26

Fertiliser N x Symbiotic N -0.07 0.10 -0.76

Fertiliser N x Labour -0.10 0.15 -0.64

Fertiliser N x Other expenses -0.07 0.23 -0.31

Symbiotic N x Labour 0.08 0.09 0.91

Symbiotic N x Other expenses -0.02 0.09 -0.17

Labour x Other expenses 0.24 0.19 1.23

Legume break 2012/13 season

=1 if a legume

was the main

crop grown on

the plot one

year ago

0.34*** 0.12 2.92

Tobacco break 2012/13 season

=1 if tobacco

was the main

crop grown on

the plot one

year ago

0.23* 0.14 1.69

Monoculture 2012/13 season

=1 if maize was

the main crop

grown on the

plot one year

ago

0.18 0.08 2.29

Sowing time

Time of

planting

relative to first

rains (weeks

after first rains)

-0.08 0.06 -1.44

Page 86: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

74

Zone =1 if Kasungu;

=0 otherwise 0.01 0.09 0.14

Constant - -0.13 0.20 -0.65

R2 0.64

Note: The dependent variable is a Tornqvist multilateral output quantity index per acre;

SE=standard error; *p<0.10; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01; n=135

Page 87: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

75

Table 3.A3 Estimated parameters for the quadratic directional distance function

Variable Coefficient Estimate BC estimate SE.

Intercept 0 -0.043 -0.025 0.067

y1 1 -0.456 -0.495 0.146

x1 2 0.490 0.619 0.181

x2 3 0.120 0.019 0.128

x3 4 0.231 0.260 0.133

x4 5 0.158 0.103 0.156

y1.y1 11 0.038 0.104 0.148

y1.x1 12 -0.004 -0.023 0.102

y1.x2 13 0.031 0.072 0.060

y1.x3 14 0.023 0.001 0.080

y1.x4 15 -0.051 -0.049 0.052

x1.x1 22 -0.174 -0.205 0.051

x1.x2 23 0.053 0.092 0.041

x1.x3 24 0.086 0.106 0.063

x1.x4 25 0.034 0.007 0.053

x2.x2 33 -0.027 -0.025 0.033

x2.x3 34 -0.039 -0.071 0.035

x2.x4 35 0.013 0.004 0.028

x3.x3 44 -0.074 -0.062 0.054

x3.x4 45 0.027 0.027 0.040

x4.x4 55 -0.073 -0.038 0.084

Note: BC= bias corrected; SE = bootstrap standard error

Page 88: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

76

Page 89: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

77

CHAPTER 4

Cost efficiency among smallholder maize producers in Malawi: to what

extent can regularity conditions reveal estimates biases?

This paper is planned for submission as:

Khataza, R.R.B, Doole G.J., Kragt M.E., Hailu A. Cost efficiency among smallholder

maize producers in Malawi: to what extent can regularity conditions reveal estimates

biases? In preparation for submission to Agricultural Economics or Applied Economics

4.0 Abstract

The effectiveness of an empirical analysis that aims to inform and influence policy will

depend on how credible its estimates are as a basis for policy recommendations.

Obviously, policy recommendations based on theoretically inappropriate models are

likely to be inconsistent. However, most empirical studies in efficiency and productivity

analysis tend to assume that the estimated production technology is “well-behaved” or

theoretically consistent rather than checking if such conditions hold. Using a translog

stochastic cost frontier and data from Malawi, we show that imposing regularity

conditions provides efficiency and elasticity estimates that are empirically credible.

Page 90: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

78

4.1 Introduction

Poor performance of agricultural enterprises in developing countries, such as sub-Saharan

Africa (SSA), remains a serious concern among researchers, policy makers and

development partners (Alene, 2010; Headey et al., 2010; Mugera and Ojede, 2014;

Ogundari, 2014; Abdulai and Abdulai, 2016). The performance of the agriculture sector

is of primary relevance to a number of agricultural-led development policies, as the

majority of the population in SSA rely on this activity for their livelihood. As a result, the

analysis of efficiency and productivity of agriculture is an active area of research in this

region. Determining the level of efficiency and productivity, as well as examining factors

that affect these measures, has been a focus of numerous studies conducted across the

region. Some of the notable factors leading to poor efficiency and productivity among

smallholder farmers include environmental conditions (Sherlund et al., 2002; Alene,

2010; Abdulai and Abdulai, 2016), use of traditional technologies and farmers’ attitude

towards risk (Seyoum et al., 1998; Kassie et al., 2011), labour migration (Mochebelele

and Winter-Nelson, 2000; Wouterse, 2010), liquidity and credit constraints (Hazarika and

Alwang, 2003; Haji, 2007; Fletschner et al., 2010; Ali et al., 2014; Abdulai and Abdulai,

2016), and gender differentials in terms of resource access and control (Udry et al., 1995;

Quisumbing, 1996; Rahman, 2010; Kilic et al., 2015; Mutenje et al., 2016).

In general, there have been mixed results in terms of the range of cross-country efficiency

and productivity estimates identified in previous studies, as well as key factors driving

productivity change in the SSA region (Alene, 2010; Headey et al., 2010). The

inconsistency observed in results could partly be due to differences in the types of

analytical methods applied (e.g. programming versus econometric approaches) and/or a

lack of theoretical rigour in the applied methods (Sauer et al., 2006; Greene, 2008; Alene,

Page 91: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

79

2010; Headey et al., 2010; Henningsen, 2014). For example, in many empirical studies,

the theoretical regularity conditions are assumed to hold, but are rarely checked (Fox and

Kivanda, 1994; Koebel et al., 2003; Sauer et al., 2006; Henningsen and Henning, 2009).

One would expect that estimates, such as efficiency and slope parameters, derived from

any theoretically irregular or inconsistent models are likely to be flawed (Barnett and

Pasupathy, 2003; Sauer et al., 2006; Greene, 2008; Henningsen and Henning, 2009;

Serletis and Feng, 2015).

In parametric efficiency and productivity analysis, the majority of studies tend to use

flexible functional forms, particularly the translog function (Terrell, 1996; Sauer et al.,

2006; Henningsen and Henning, 2009; Färe and Vardanyan, 2016, ). The usefulness of a

flexible functional form depends on whether the model specification satisfies theoretical

regularity conditions of positivity, monotonicity, and curvature (Barnett and Pasupathy,

2003; Serletis and Feng, 2015). However, a number of empirical studies in the efficiency

and productivity literature tend to ignore these regularity conditions (Barnett and

Pasupathy, 2003; Sauer et al., 2006; Serletis and Feng, 2015; Sun, 2015). For example,

most of the studies included in a review by Sauer et al. (2006)9 did not satisfy the

regularity conditions, especially quasi-concavity. This is of significant concern because

ignoring regularity conditions could confound parameter estimates and lead to perverse

policy recommendations (Barnett and Pasupathy, 2003; Sauer et al., 2006; Henningsen

and Henning, 2009; Serletis and Feng, 2015).

9 Failure to satisfy regularity conditions in applied duality studies has not only been noted and discussed in

the stochastic frontier or efficiency literature but it has also been highlighted in the ordinary non-frontier

production economics literature (for example, see Fox and Kivanda 1994; Shumway 1995; Reziti and

Ozanne 1999; Barnett and Pasupathy, 2003)

Page 92: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

80

Typically, the empirical approach employed to check theoretical properties, particularly

for curvature and monotonicity, has been to evaluate these conditions locally, i.e. at the

mean of the data rather than for every data point or over a region of connected data points.

For example, using this approach, Solís et al. (2009) reported that their results—estimated

using an input distance function—satisfied regularity conditions for all output variables

and input variables (except for hired labour). In the same spirit, Rahman (2010) specified

a translog input distance function and concluded that their results satisfied regularity

conditions for all outputs and input variables 0; 0I ID x D y . In a related study,

Singbo and Larue (2016) assessed the scale and technical efficiency of the Canadian dairy

sector. Using a translog input distance function, this study reported 64% of monotonicity

violations for one of the capital variables. Similarly, Abdulai and Abdulai (2016)

estimated a translog cost function for a sample of Zambian maize farmers and concluded

that the estimated cost function was linearly non-decreasing in output and factor prices,

implying that monotonicity was satisfied. Admittedly, the local imposition of regularity

properties is easy to implement, but this approach disregards other data points where these

conditions may not hold (O'Donnell et al., 1999; Sun, 2015,).

As a result of the shortcomings of the local approach, Barnett and Pasupathy (2003)

recommend estimation procedures that permit flexible imposition of the regularity

conditions. As opposed to the local approach of imposing theoretical consistency, these

regularity properties can be regionally or globally imposed. However, global imposition

of curvature on the translog model can lead to severe violations of the regularity

conditions implied by economic theory (Diewert and Wales, 1987; Terrell, 1996;

Henningsen and Henning, 2009; Färe and Vardanyan, 2016). Accordingly, the regional

approach is typically more appropriate, as it maintains the flexibility of the functional

Page 93: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

81

form (Sauer et al., 2006; Henningsen and Henning, 2009; Wolff et al., 2010). In addition,

the regional approach ensures a better model fit to the sample data, relative to the global

approach (Wolff et al., 2010).

The present study aims to demonstrate the importance of estimating a production

technology that is theoretically consistent. This is done through an assessment of the

consequences of ignoring (imposing) regularity conditions by contrasting parameter

estimates obtained from constrained and unconstrained models. We use two approaches

to impose theoretical consistency over a range of data points in the sample. The first

method is a maximum likelihood approach proposed by Koebel et al. (2003) and

popularised by Henningsen and Henning (2009), which uses a second-stage quadratic

programming procedure to obtain parameter estimates that satisfy regularity conditions.

In the first step, unconstrained parameters are estimated. If monotonicity and curvature

conditions are not satisfied in the first step, a second step non-linear constrained

optimisation procedure is invoked to impose these regularity properties. The second

method uses Bayesian inference to impose regularity properties. The Bayesian approach,

which was introduced to the stochastic frontier analysis by van den Broeck et al. (1994),

has been widely used to impose economic regularity conditions such as monotonicity and

concavity (Terrell, 1996; Griffiths et al., 2000; Kleit and Terrell, 2001; O’Donnell and

Coelli, 2005; Griffin and Steel, 2007).

Besides the ease of imposing theoretical consistency, Bayesian estimation offers a

number of advantages over alternative methods, such as maximum likelihood estimation

procedures (Kleit and Terrell, 2001; Coelli et al., 2005; O’Donnell and Coelli, 2005).

First, the Bayesian technique provides a formal mechanism of incorporating prior

Page 94: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

82

knowledge and non-sample information into the estimation process. Second, the Bayesian

method provides precise small-sample inference on coefficients and efficiency estimates

for most of the estimation problems. Finally, the approach considers parameter

uncertainty by providing probability distribution for each of the estimated parameters of

interest, such as coefficient estimates and efficiency scores.

We note that regularity conditions can also be imposed using mathematical programming

methods, as pioneered by Aigner and Chu (1968) and later applied to input/output

distance functions by several analysts including (Färe et al., 1993; Hailu and Veeman,

2000; Färe and Vardanyan, 2016), and recently applied to directional distance functions

(Khataza et al., 2017). The downside of this approach is that it is deterministic in nature,

such that any deviation from the frontier is singularly attributed to inefficiency. It is

argued that the benefits of using mathematical programming approaches may not

outweigh the statistical advantages of estimating a stochastic frontier function (SFA) and

imposing the theoretical regularity conditions using either maximum likelihood or

Bayesian approaches. For example, among other advantages, the SFA approach enables

one to test statistical hypotheses and incorporate non-conventional inputs, such as farm

and farmer characteristics, to examine how such covariates tend to influence inefficiency

(Wang and Schmidt, 2002; Karagiannis et al. 2003; Karagiannis and Sarris 2005; Greene,

2008; Schmidt, 2011). Estimating a second stage regression to explain efficiency-

heterogeneity across farms, as is often done in applications adopting nonparametric

approaches such as data envelopment analysis (DEA), could potentially lead to

specification bias (Wang and Schmidt, 2002; Schmidt, 2011).

Page 95: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

83

We estimate a stochastic cost function, which is dual to the production function. Besides

technical and revenue measures of efficiency, cost-efficiency is a natural measure of farm

performance. The advantage of using a cost function in the estimation of farm efficiency

is to address endogeneity problems associated with input variables which are used as

regressors in primal production models; that is, models that specify technology using

production function and distance function techniques. Usually, the primal approaches are

used to model production technologies when price information is unavailable or when the

behavioural assumptions, such as cost minimisation, revenue and profit maximisation,

are inappropriate (Coelli and Fleming, 2004; O’Donnell and Coelli, 2005; Sun, 2015).

Key issues are identified in a case study applied to data from Malawi maize-based farm

systems. Analysis of cost efficiency in this context is useful for helping to design effective

policies aimed at supporting farmers; for example, by linking them to agricultural

sustainability programs, such as integrated maize-legume conservation agriculture.

Furthermore, Malawi is an interesting case study because the majority of the country’s

population depend on agriculture for livelihood and is characterised by the dominance of

mixed maize-legume farming systems. Under this production system, farmers

simultaneously grow more than one crop, usually cereals and legumes, on the same plot

of land. Recently, the practice of growing maize and legumes together has been adopted

as part of the integrated maize-legume conservation agriculture approach being promoted

in the country (Ngwira et al., 2012; Thierfelder et al., 2013).

The rest of the paper is organised into four sections. In the next section, we describe the

methodology of imposing regularity restrictions and the empirical model. This is followed

Page 96: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

84

by a description of the study area and data. In Section 4.4, we present and discuss the

results. Finally, the conclusion is presented in Section 4.5.

4.2 Methodology

4.2.1 Theoretical model

Consider a farmer who seeks to produce a vector of outputs My in a least-cost manner,

given a set of prevailing factor prices Nw . Let a production technology be represented

by an input requirement set ( )L y . Then, a cost frontier is defined by an isoquant that

maps out all possible combinations of minimum expenditure required to produce My

as follows:

0

( , ) inf | ( ) (1)x

C w y wx x L y

where 1,...., nx x x is a vector of production inputs, wx is the observed cost and ( , )C w y

is the optimal (minimum) cost. Some of the properties of the cost function are: 1)

positivity, which requires that the estimated cost is nonnegative for all data points; 2)

monotonicity in output and factor prices, which implies that the cost is non-decreasing in

output and factor prices or ( , ) 0; ( , ) 0C y w y C y w w ; 3) homogeneity, which

requires that a cost function be linearly homogenous in factor prices, such that the

production costs will vary in direct proportion to the change in factor prices; and 4)

concavity in factor prices, which imply that any input demand function derived from a

sensible cost function is downward sloping (Kleit and Terrell, 2001; Koebel et al., 2003;

Kumbhakar and Lovell, 2003; Coelli et al., 2005; Serletis and Feng, 2015 ).

Page 97: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

85

4.2.2 Empirical estimation

The cost function can be estimated using either nonparametric (programming)

approaches, involving data envelopment analysis (DEA), or parametric (econometric)

specification using stochastic frontier analysis (SFA), among others. Both approaches

have advantages and disadvantages. For example, the strength of DEA is that the method

does not require any assumptions about the functional form of the production technology.

However, the limitation of this approach is that the entire excess of the observed

expenditure over the optimal (minimum) cost is attributed to inefficiency, without

accounting for data noise. As a result, DEA methods can be sensitive to outliers because

they ignore data noise which could result from random factors such as measurement

errors, adverse weather conditions and pest/disease incursions. On the other hand, SFA

has been mainly criticised for its dependence on the distributional assumptions regarding

the technology (production, revenue, cost or profit function) and the difficulty associated

with handling multiple output production technologies using this technique (Karagiannis

et al. 2004). Fortunately, the problem of multiple outputs can be modelled using distance

functions and functional form limitations can be addressed by using flexible

specifications, such as the translog function (Coelli and Perelman, 2000; Kumbhakar and

Lovell, 2003; Karagiannis et al. 2004; O’Donnell and Coelli, 2005; Rahman 2009;

Headey et al., 2010). Furthermore, SFA offers some important advantages over

nonparametric methods. First, SFA accounts for firm’s inefficiency and data noise, both

of which are important in characterising the variance between the observed cost and the

optimal cost. Second, the method allows for statistical testing of hypotheses (Greene,

2008). Given the statistical advantages associated with the SFA approach, we represent

the production technology in Equation (1) using this method.

The empirical model for the stochastic variable-cost frontier can be expressed as follows:

Page 98: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

86

2

2

ln ( , ) (ln , ln | , )

~ (0, )(2)

~ (0, )

~ (0, )

i y w i i

v

u

C y w f y w v u

N

v N

u N

where C is the variable cost of the thi firm, y is a vector of outputs, w represents factor

prices, and is a vector of parameters to be estimated. The error structure of Equation

(2) is composed of two independently and identically distributed terms; that is, the

random error term denoted by v and the nonnegative inefficiency term (u ), which shows

excess expenditure relative to the best-performing farm(s).

4.2.3 Functional form

Estimation of Equation (2) in a SFA framework requires the choice of a functional form.

The Cobb-Douglas (CD) and translog forms are the most commonly used parametric

specifications in the efficiency literature (Coelli et al., 2005; Greene, 2008). The CD form

is parsimonious, but it can suitably represent production technologies that are typified by

constant returns to scale. In this regard, the CD specification is too restrictive to

accommodate situations where elasticities vary across farms (economies of scale). For

this reason, we prefer to estimate Equation (2) using a translog functional form, which is

the most widely applied flexible functional form (Coelli and Perelman, 2000; Coelli and

Fleming, 2004; O’Donnell and Coelli, 2005; Sauer et al., 2006; Rahman 2009; Färe and

Vardanyan, 2016). One limitation of the translog function is that the specification is

amenable to curvature violations. In our application, we are able to test and impose

regularity conditions on a range of data points. The translog cost function is expressed as

follows:

Page 99: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

87

2

0

1

ln ( ) ln ln( ) 0.5 ln ln

0.5 ln( ) ln( ) ln ln( ) (3)

i j m n n j mm

n m m

nn n j n j mn n j i i

n n

C w y w w y y

w w w w y w w v u

where y is the quantity of maize grain harvested, and nw represents factor prices for

fertiliser, hired labour, and maize seed. Since a sensible cost function satisfies

homogeneity of degree +1 in (positive) input prices, implying that a proportionate change

in input prices is likely to effect a change of similar magnitude in production costs, it was

appropriate to incorporate homogeneity into the estimation and not test for it. And

homogeneity is easily imposed for estimation as a condition on parameter values, unlike

monotonicity or concavity. Therefore, it is common to incorporate homogeneity from the

outset. In Equation (3), we follow previous studies (e.g. Farsi et al. 2005; Kumbhakar et

al. 2013; Abdulai and Abdulai 2016) and impose linear homogeneity restriction by

normalizing the logarithm of cost and factor prices with respect to the logarithm of one

of the factor prices (i.e. price of hired labour, ). Applying Shephard’s Lemma, the first

order conditions of the cost function with respect to factor prices would yield factor

demand functions for each input, represented by their respective expenditure share

equation as follows: ln ln ln lnn n n n n n m

n

C w w x C w y , where n n .

The measure of cost efficiency (CE), which represents both technical and allocative

efficiency, is given by the ratio of minimum cost to the observed expenditure (

*( , )C w y wx ). Essentially, CE is bounded between zero and unity, since the minimum

cost can be at least as large as the actual cost (Kumbhakar and Lovell, 2003). The CE

measure can be expressed in terms of a stochastic frontier framework as in Equation (4)

below:

jw

Page 100: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

88

*( , ).exp( )exp( ) (4)

( , ).exp( )

ˆz

C y w vCE u

C y w v u

u z

where z is a vector of non-traditional inputs (z-variables or observed heterogeneity)

believed to influence the observed level of cost efficiency. It is well established that cost

efficiency is affected by the environment in which a firm operates, hence the inclusion of

the environmental variables in the stochastic frontier model is appropriate (Greene, 2008;

Schmidt, 2011). Wang and Schmidt (2002) and Schmidt (2011) argue that the omission

of environmental variables that belong in the model (i.e. affect efficiency) is tantamount

to model misspecification.

The environmental variables can be included in the estimated model in two ways (Coelli

et al., 2005; Greene, 2008; Schmidt, 2011). The first approach involves the inclusion of

the non-traditional inputs in the deterministic component (cost, production, revenue or

profit function) and in the stochastic component (inefficiency term). Thus, this approach

assumes that the environmental variables have a direct impact on both the

technology/production structure and the efficiency component. The second approach

assumes that the non-conventional inputs do not directly influence the structure of

production, but rather only influence the efficiency estimates. As a result, the

environmental variables are appended to the inefficiency model. We adopt the second

approach and specify the model such that the z-variables are part of the inefficiency

component. This is due to the nature of the environmental variables in our data, which

are mainly management-related variables that are expected to influence inefficiency

rather than the production structure.

Page 101: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

89

4.2.4 Imposing regularity conditions

The parameters in Equations (3) and (4) are estimated jointly, first, using maximum

likelihood estimation technique and, second, using the Bayesian inference. In this section,

we describe the two approaches used to impose theoretical consistency on the estimated

model. One approach to imposing regularity conditions that we adopt is based on a two-

step procedure proposed by Koebel et al. (2003) and recently implemented by

Henningsen and Henning (2009). The first step involves estimation of an unrestricted cost

frontier model and extracting coefficient estimates (0̂ ) and covariance matrix ( ˆ

). In

the second step, the restricted parameters are obtained using a constrained quadratic

optimisation procedure (i.e. non-linear distance minimisation) that ensures positive

marginal products for all outputs and factor prices as follows:

0 0 1 0

0 0

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆˆarg min . .

(5)ˆ ˆ( , , ) ( , , )0; 0; , ,i i i i

s t

C y w C y wi y w

y w

The minimum distance optimisation approach yields precise restricted parameters (0̂ )

that are asymptotically equivalent to those obtained using a restricted one-step maximum

likelihood estimation procedure (Koebel et al., 2003; Henningsen and Henning, 2009).

Following the estimation of credible coefficients, the last step involves measurement of

efficiency scores and their determinants based on the theoretically consistent cost frontier.

On the other hand, estimating equation (2) under the Bayesian framework requires setting

priors for the estimable parameters. Priors summarise information about the parameters

of interest before such knowledge is updated using the observed data (Kleit and Terrell,

2001; Coelli et al., 2005). Hence, this step is important because information contained in

the priors will influence the quality of posterior inference. In particular, we are interested

Page 102: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

90

in estimating the posterior densities of coefficients , variance ( v ), and efficiencies

( u ), conditional on the sample data. We specify flat/diffuse or uninformative priors for

coefficients to express ignorance and allow information from the observed data to

dominate the posterior distribution.

For the parameterisation of the normal distribution, it is technically easier to work with

the precision parameter ( h ) rather than the variance (2

v ). Additionally, a gamma prior

distribution is a suitable choice for the inverse of the variance parameter ( h ) because it

provides for the estimation of proper posterior distributions (i.e. yields a density that

integrates to one and is therefore a correct density function) (Kleit and Terrell, 2001).

Thus, substituting the variance parameter for the precision term, the prior distribution is

expressed as follows: 1 2 1~ (0, ) ( )vv N h h . We assume ~ (0.001,0.001)h G where

0.001 represent the values assigned for the shape and scale parameters, which implies

assigning weak (diffuse) priors for the variance parameter (2

v ). Finally, we assume that

the non-negative inefficiency term follows a normal exponential-normal distribution with

mean 1 , such that ~ ( )u Exp . The exponential distribution is preferred over other

distributions because it is robust to prior assumptions about parameters (van den Broeck

et al., 1994; Kleit and Terrell, 2001). And the parameter of the inefficiency distribution

is assumed to be *~ ( ln( ))Exp r , where

* (0,1)r and *r represents median efficiency

of the sampled farms. We set *r equal to 0.7 based on cost efficiency estimates from

previous studies conducted in Malawi (Hazarika and Alwang, 2003; Maganga et al.,

2013) and in other regions (e.g. Haji, 2007; Thanh Nguyen et al., 2012; Abdulai and

Abdulai, 2016). We also experimented using a range of *r values (higher and lower than

0.7) but the results were robust to the choice of *r .

Page 103: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

91

The regularity conditions (monotonicity and curvature) are imposed over a region of

positive prices where inference is drawn, defined as a range of relative price ratios (Kleit

and Terrell, 2001). These regularity restrictions are imposed by constructing an indicator

function ( )I that equals one if these conditions are satisfied, or is zero otherwise

(Terrell, 1996; Kleit and Terrell, 2001; Coelli et al., 2005; Griffin and Steel, 2007). For

an empirical procedure, we use WinBUGS to employ the Markov chain Monte Carlo

(MCMC) sampling algorithm that generates the final posterior density through iterative

random sampling from the joint distribution of the model parameters (Spiegelhalter et al.,

2003; Griffin and Steel, 2007). A total of three chains were used and 200,000 iterations

were sufficient to achieve model convergence. In Bayesian analysis, it is standard practice

to discard the initial iterations because these iterations are strongly influenced by the

starting values (Terrell, 1996; Brooks and Gelman, 1998; Gelman and Shirley, 2011).

Therefore, a total of 20,000 iterations were discarded in an initial burn-in phase and the

remainder (180,000 iterations for each of the three parallel chains) were retained to

monitor posterior densities for the estimates.

Effective convergence of Markov chain simulation is achieved when posterior densities

for the parameters no longer depend on the starting values of the simulation (Brooks and

Gelman, 1998). For our Bayesian model (M2), we monitored, in two ways, if the model

had achieved reasonable convergence. First, we monitored the Monte Carlo error for the

parameters, which indicate the computational accuracy or how much of variations in the

posterior sample are attributable to the noise generated by the sampler (Spiegelhalter et

al., 2003; Ntzoufras, 2011). A rule of thumb is to increase the number of simulations until

the Monte Carlo error for each parameter of interest is less than about 5% of the sample

standard deviation (Spiegelhalter et al., 2003). Second, we monitored the Gelman-Rubin

convergence plots and trace plots. At convergence, multiple chains are expected to have

Page 104: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

92

fully mixed when these chains overlap one another and the Gelman-Rubin statistic ( ˆcR )

converges to its reference value of one (Brooks and Gelman, 1998; Spiegelhalter et al.,

2003; Gelman and Shirley, 2011; Ntzoufras, 2011).

4.3 Data description

We use survey data collected from 328 maize farmers randomly selected from Kasungu

and Mzimba districts in Malawi. The survey was conducted in the 2013/14 cropping

season. These districts are part of the medium-altitude agro-ecological zone of the

country. A subdivision of this agro-ecological zone is the Kasungu–Lilongwe plain. This

zone is one of the areas where legume-based conservation agriculture is most dominant

among smallholder maize and legume farmers in Malawi.

The survey followed a three-stage random sampling approach. First, the study zones were

selected based on Ministry of Agriculture administrative demarcations, known as

extension planning areas (EPAs). The EPAs are district-level administrative units

established to coordinate and oversee the execution of extension services across the

country. The second step involved the choice of an EPA section. An EPA section is the

lowest unit of administration in the Ministry of Agriculture hierarchy. Subsequently,

maize-legume producers were identified from each EPA section. This procedure was

done to establish a sampling frame. Third, after the selection of EPA sections and

enumeration of maize-legume producers were completed, face-to-face interviews were

conducted with a set of randomly chosen respondents (household heads). Using a

structured questionnaire, these respondents were asked to provide information regarding

the cost of maize production. The study also collected information regarding amount of

maize harvest and factor prices for the following commonly used inputs: fertiliser,

Page 105: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

93

purchased seed, and hired labour. These variables (output and factor prices) are standard

regressors included within a cost function. Other survey details and sample

representativeness are described in (Khataza et al., 2017).

Table 4.1 presents descriptive statistics for the data. The farms are categorised as small if

the size of the operated area equals or falls below the median area of 2 acres; otherwise,

the farms are classified as large. Although our data is cross-sectional, the major sources

of intra-season price variability can be attributed to differences in the geographical

location of markets and the timing of farm input purchases. For example, some farmers

purchase their farm inputs soon after the harvest period, while others wait for the

commencement of the cropping season. On average, it cost MWK 25000 or US$71 per

acre to produce maize, given the prevailing market prices for fertiliser, labour and maize

seed. Furthermore, small farms, on average, incurred higher production expenditure than

large farms.

Page 106: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

94

Table 4.1: Descriptive statistics for the sample data

Variable Notation

Pooled

(n = 328)

Small farms

(n = 203)

Large farms

(n = 125)

Mean SD. Mean SD. Mean SD.

Total variable cost

(MWK/acre) C 24,958 22,310 28,996 25,335 18,401 14,036

Maize grain

quantity (kg/acre) y 520 410 585 460 416 285

Fertiliser price

(MWK/kg) w1 222 138 219 150 228 116

Maize seed price

(MWK/kg) w2 209 292 201 324 223 231

Wage rate

(MWK/acre) w3 637 1647 552 1654 774 1634

Cultivated area

(acres) z1 2.23 1.52 1.38 0.52 3.61 1.60

Gender (=1 if male;

0 otherwise) z2 0.54 0.50 0.49 0.50 0.62 0.49

Farmer club (=1 if

member; 0

otherwise)

z3 0.70 0.46 0.69 0.46 0.71 0.45

Credit rationing z4 0.19 0.39 0.20 0.40 0.17 0.38

MWK = Malawi Kwacha; Exchange rate: 1 US$ = MWK350 at the time of the survey

We also seek to investigate factors that affect cost-efficiency heterogeneity among

smallholder maize farmers. The environmental variables considered are the size of the

cultivated area, gender of the household head, membership to farmer association and

loan-size rationing (credit-supply constraints). Credit rationing is a supply-side constraint

that occurs when lenders do not disburse loans according to the borrower’s demand

(Simtowe et al., 2008; Mason, 2014). To identify credit-rationed households, we use the

direct elicitation approach, where we ask each farmer a series of questions revealing their

credit demand and supply situation (Boucher et al., 2009; Fletschner et al., 2010; Mason,

Page 107: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

95

2014). First, each sampled farmer was asked if they experienced any liquidity constraints

or the need to seek farm credit in the 2013/14 crop season and, if they did, whether such

a farmer applied for a loan from formal lenders (i.e. expressing credit demand). Second,

applicants were asked how much credit was granted (measure of credit supply) whereas

non-applicants were considered as self-sufficient (if they did not need any credit) or as

discouraged potential borrowers who failed to meet the lender’s selection criteria e.g. due

to lack of collateral and high interest rates. We are concerned with credit rationing among

applicants as a reasonable indicator of supply-side credit constraints because failure to

apply for a loan could also imply lack of farmer’s confidence and capacity to repay the

loan. Failure to apply for a loan from formal lenders could also imply that such farmers

had already devised alternative plans either to intensively utilise non-market resources

(e.g. own-saved seeds and manure) or to seek loans from informal lenders and peers

within their social network. Using this information, we constructed a credit rationing

variable defined as a measure of unsatisfied demand or a shortfall between the amounts

of credit demanded ( )cD and supplied ( )cS as follows: ( )c c cCR D S D .

The intensity of credit rationing ranges between zero and one; a value of one indicates

that an applicant was totally rationed and a value of zero means that the farmer’s credit

demand was fully satisfied. Nearly 19% of the sample experienced loan-size rationing,

since these farmers were granted an amount of credit that was less than what they had

anticipated. Such an outcome could result from imperfections in the microfinance market

in two ways (Simtowe et al., 2008; Mason, 2014). First, credit rationing may signify a

lender’s perception that a borrower lacks capacity to repay the loan, revealing the lender’s

risk aversion regarding borrower’s credit worthiness. Second, credit rationing could also

imply a lenders’ lack of capacity to satisfy the borrower’s demand.

Page 108: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

96

4.4 Results and discussion

Table 4.2 presents the results of the maximum likelihood and Bayesian stochastic cost

functions. The table constitutes three main sections: the top part shows the stochastic cost

function estimates, the middle part shows the effects of z-variables on the levels of cost

efficiency, and the bottom part has the model diagnostic parameters. One of the key test

parameters is gamma (). The parameter gamma provides the justification for using the

stochastic frontier model, as opposed to the standard production function (Henningsen,

2014). Gamma is computed as the ratio of the inefficiency error variance and total error

variance 2 2( )u and lies between zero and one. A gamma value of zero signifies

an absence of inefficiency in the data and thus, whether the inclusion of the inefficiency

term is irrelevant (Karagiannis and Sarris 2005; Rahman 2009; Henningsen, 2014). Based

on our maximum likelihood results, the estimated value of gamma is greater than zero in

both the unrestricted (M0) and restricted (M1) models. The imposition of monotonicity

caused an increase in the value of gamma from 0.28 in M0 to 0.38 in M1. However,

having controlled for the factors that affect cost inefficiency, the estimated gamma values

for the restricted and unrestricted models are not statistically significant (p = 0.1).

Page 109: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

97

Table 4.2: Parameter estimates for the restricted and unrestricted translog cost function

Variable Unrestricted model (M0) Two-step nonlinear optimisation model (M1) Bayesian inference (M2)

Coef. Estimate z value Pr(>|z|) Min. dist. Coef Adj. coef Corrected coef z value Pr(>|z|) Coef. Estimate 95% CI

ln y 0.35*** (0.06) 5.52 0.00 0.32 0.27 0.43 (0.00) 0.30 - 0.56

1ln w 0.71*** (0.03) 22.63 0.00 0.65 0.60 0.73 (0.00) 0.66 - 0.80

2ln w 0.11*** (0.04) 3.08 0.00 0.19 0.14 0.11 (0.00) 0.03 - 0.18

11ln y 0.12*** (0.03) 4.20 0.00 0.05 0.00 0.12 (0.00) 0.06 - 0.18

1ln .lny w 0.07*** (0.02) 3.46 0.00 0.02 -0.03 0.05 (0.00) 0.01 - 0.09

2ln .lny w -0.06*** (0.02) -3.15 0.00 -0.03 -0.08 -0.06 (0.00) -0.10 - -0.01

11ln w 0.14*** (0.01) 10.68 0.00 0.08 0.03 0.13 (0.00) 0.10 - 0.15

12ln w -0.10*** (0.02) -6.59 0.00 -0.05 -0.10 -0.09 (0.00) -0.13 - -0.06

22ln w 0.11*** (0.02) 5.65 0.00 0.05 0.00 0.10 (0.00) 0.06 - 0.14

Intercept -0.43*** (0.12) -3.54 0.00 -0.29 -0.34 -0.05 (0.14) -0.36 0.72 -0.41 (0.00) -0.59 - -0.19

lcFitted 1.00*** (0.01) 101.90 0.00

Area -0.65*** (0.13) -4.97 0.00 -0.76*** (0.14) -5.39 0.00 0.50 (0.00) 0.20 - 0.83

Gender 0.15 (0.10) 1.51 0.13 0.09 (0.12) 0.71 0.48 0.61 (0.01) 0.19 - 1.59

Farmer club 0.01 (0.12) 0.11 0.91 -0.06 (0.14) -0.43 0.67 0.93 (0.01) 0.53 - 1.78

Credit constraint -0.47** (0.23) -2.01 0.04 -0.56** (0.27) -2.04 0.04 0.99 (0.02) 0.24 - 2.69

Sigma2 ( 2 ) 0.32*** (0.06) 5.56 0.00 0.39*** (0.10) 4.08 0.00 0.23 (0.00) 0.17 - 0.33

Gamma ( ) 0.28 (0.23) 1.25 0.21 0.38 (0.28) 1.37 0.17

AIC 543 561

DIC 567

Mean CE 0.725 0.706 0.706 0.734

Page 110: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

98

Our Bayesian model (M2) results show that convergence was successfully achieved; first,

because the Monte Carlo errors are quite small (below 1%) relative to the standard

deviations and therefore the posterior estimates obtained are precise and reliable. Second,

the Gelman-Rubin statistic stabilised around one as expected (denoted by red line in

Appendix 4.A1), as the number of iterations increased from 20,000 (burn-in length) to

180,000 iterations for each of the three parallel chains.

Overall, the maximum likelihood and Bayesian cost models show consistency in terms of

the sign of the estimated coefficients. There is also consistency for the magnitude of the

coefficients over many of the estimates. This result is not surprising, considering that we

used uninformative priors in the Bayesian estimation that allowed for sample data to

dominate the posterior estimates. The estimated coefficients have the expected signs for

all of the three models; that is, they have positive values for the first order derivatives for

the output variable and factor prices (Table 4.2 and Appendix 4.A2). This implies that the

monotonicity requirement is satisfied at the sample mean (for the unrestricted model) and

over a region of connected data points for the restricted models.10 The estimated

coefficients for the first order terms can be interpreted as cost elasticities evaluated at the

sample mean because our data was mean scaled prior to model estimation (Abdulai and

Abdulai, 2016; Singbo and Larue, 2016; Khataza et al., 2017). Based on the size of the

estimated coefficients, the largest proportion of the cost is attributable to fertiliser use.

For example, the results from Model 1 suggest that a 1% increase (decrease) in fertiliser

use would lead to a 0.6% increase (decrease) in the cost of maize production. In Malawi,

10 The initial model satisfied monotonicity in output and factor prices by 77%, and for each

specific variable as follows: 95%, 99% and 81% for maize output, fertiliser price and maize seed

price, respectively. However, the model satisfied curvature at only 35% of the data points. After

imposing restrictions, overall monotonicity and curvature improved up to 99% and 98%,

respectively. Furthermore, the new model achieved 0% monotonicity violations for each of the

variables.

Page 111: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

99

the cost of inorganic fertiliser constitutes the largest proportion of the total production

costs. This is the case because all the inorganic fertilisers used in crop production in

Malawi are imported and landing costs are relatively higher than what is incurred in the

coastal parts of the sub-Sahara Africa (Jayne et al., 2003; Kelly, 2006).

The coefficient for output represents a cost elasticity value of 0.43 in Model 2, implying

that a one percent increase in output quantity will increase production costs by 0.43%, all

things being equal. The corresponding elasticity of size (scale) is given as the reciprocal

of the cost elasticity i.e. 1

lnC y

and is estimated to be 2.3. This elasticity

measure means that if costs are increased by 1%, output quantity would increase by 2.3%

(Ferrier and Lovell, 1990; Henningsen, 2014). Since the estimated scale elasticity is

greater than one, the results suggest that the maize-based production system is

characterised by increasing returns to scale. In general, this shows that the scale of

operation is small and, as a result, farmers would increase their cost efficiency by

expanding the size of the operated area. The finding of increasing returns to scale is

consistent for all of the three models, where the estimated returns to scale range from

2.3% to 3.7%. Given that the size of the estimated returns to scale are greater than one, it

is justifiable to model this production system using a flexible functional form, as we have

done.

4.4.1 Cost efficiency prediction and sources of inefficiency

Table 3 presents cost efficiency (CE) scores obtained from the three models. Recall that

the cost inefficiency measure in Equation (4) represents combined resource use

inefficiencies arising from both technical and allocative errors. Therefore, it is not

possible to decompose the two inefficiency components with a single equation model and

Page 112: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

100

without the input and output quantities or cost share data (Kumbhakar and Lovell, 2003;

Kumbhakar et al., 2015). For this reason, we report cost inefficiency as a joint measure

of input-oriented technical inefficiency and allocative inefficiency. The cost efficiency

estimates are quite stable across the three methods and the estimated mean efficiency

score is 0.73 for each of the three models. This is the case because the quality of the

production data was not seriously irregular, indicating that small improvements were

achieved after imposing theoretical consistency restrictions. However, the overall

distribution of the efficiency estimates differ among the three models (Table 4.3; Figure

4.1). In other words, the three models produced efficiency ratings that differ in the range

and spread of the estimates. This difference arises from minor violations (or lack of

imposition) of the theoretical regularity conditions.

Table 4.3: Comparison of cost efficiency measures between restricted and unrestricted

models

Mean 95% CI H0 t-value WSR

score

K-S

score Decision

CE0 0.725 0.71- 0.74 CE0 - CE1 = 0 10.91 11.26 0.45 Reject H0 (p<0.001)

CE1 0.706 0.69- 0.72 CE0 - CE2 = 0 -1.77 -1.59 0.68 Reject H0 (p<0.01)

CE2 0.734 0.72- 0.75 CE1 - CE2 = 0 -6.38 -6.08 0.68 Reject H0 (p<0.001)

Note: CE0 denotes cost efficiency resulting from unrestricted model, whereas CE1 and CE2 denote cost

efficiencies obtained from the nonlinear optimisation method and the Bayesian inference approach,

respectively; WSR= Wilcoxon signed-rank test; K-S= Kolmogorov-Smirnov test; CI=confidence interval

We formally test the hypothesis that there is no difference between the cost efficiency

measures obtained from the restricted and unrestricted models (Table 4.3). To do this, we

compare a pair of matched cost efficiency scores using two nonparametric tests for

equality of distributions, the Kolmogorov-Smirnov (K-S) test and Wilcoxon signed-rank

(WSR) test to complement the t-test, which assumes normality of the distributions. The

Page 113: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

101

two nonparametric tests are suitable for testing the distribution assumption regarding

continuous variables from carefully matched samples (Rozek, 1988; Baumgartner et al.,

1998). This comparison shows that estimated efficiency scores are lowest for the two-

step nonlinear optimisation model and highest for the Bayesian inference approach, and

these efficiency estimates are statistically different among the three methods of analysis

(Table 4.3). However, we can suggest that the two-step nonlinear optimisation procedure

(M1) yielded reasonable estimates, given that the estimates from the Bayesian inference

approach (M2) were relatively close to those obtained from the unrestricted model (M0).

This is a result of using non-informative priors that allow sample data to dominate the

joint posterior densities of the parameters. In other words, the Bayesian estimates are

expected to coincide with the results obtained from the classical model, given that the

noninformative prior distribution was chosen. This could also be due to the exponential

distribution, which is considered to be less sensitive to the choice of priors (van den

Broeck et al., 1994; Kleit and Terrell, 2001).

Figure 4.1: Kernel density of efficiency measures for the restricted and unrestricted cost

functions

01

23

4

.2 .4 .6 .8 1

Cost efficiency (M0) Cost efficiency (M1) Cost efficiency (M2)

Page 114: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

102

To explain how different covariates affect cost efficiency, we consider the sign of the

estimated coefficients for the environmental variables included in the model. A positive

(negative) sign implies that a variable associated with such a coefficient increases

(reduces) inefficiency (Abdulai and Abdulai, 2016). Overall, farmers operating larger

farm sizes are relatively more cost efficient than their counterparts who operate small

farms. The results show that small farms are less efficient by a margin of 13-19% (Table

4.4).

Table 4.4: Comparison of cost efficiency measures between small and large farms

Small farms (n = 203) Large farms (n = 125) Diff. t-value Mean 95% CI Mean 95% CI

CE0 0.65 0.63 - 0.67 0.84 0.83 - 0.85 0.19 14.94

CE1 0.63 0.61 - 0.65 0.82 0.81 - 0.84 0.19 14.14

CE2 0.69 0.67 - 0.71 0.81 0.80 - 0.83 0.13 8.62

Overall 0.63 – 0.69 0.81 – 0.84 0.13 – 0.19

The finding that large farms are more cost efficient relative to small farms is consistent

with previous studies conducted in Malawi (e.g. Hazarika and Alwang, 2003). Further,

the results show that credit rationed households are more cost efficient. This finding is

intuitive in terms of the principle of allocative efficiency, such that those farmers who

were denied credit or were granted partial amounts had to spend less on purchased inputs,

and perhaps, compensated the input shortfall by utilising non-market resources, such as

organic fertilisers and recycled seed (Hazarika and Alwang, 2003). Another explanation

could relate to the fungibility nature of financial loans, which implies that some volume

of credit may easily be diverted to consumption activities (the disguised purpose of credit)

rather than being spent on production activities (the stated purpose of credit). Similarly,

Abdulai and Abdulai (2016), using a zero inefficiency stochastic frontier model (ZISF),

Page 115: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

103

found that a sample of Zambian maize farmers who experienced liquidity constraints and

sought credit were more cost inefficient than those who did not.

4.4.2 Output and factor price elasticities

We compare elasticities estimated from the models with and without imposing regularity

conditions, denoted as M1 and M0 respectively. The elasticity estimates for the restricted

and unrestricted models are presented in Table 4.5. The results show that mean elasticities

for output and fertilisier price are higher for the unrestricted model than those estimated

from the restricted model. Thus, the unrestricted model overestimates the cost

contribution of fertiliser and output. Intuitively, this shows that merely relying on the

unrestricted model could lead to less precise conclusions or recommendations drawn from

such elasticity measures. We note that the size of the estimated elasticities in the present

study are smaller than those obtained in a study conducted by Maganga et al. (2013)

which examined the potato sector in Malawi. However, our elasticity estimates are

comparable to previous studies conducted in the region (e.g. Obare et al., 2003; Adesina

and Djato, 1997).

Page 116: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

104

Table 4.5: Partial production elasticities of output and factor prices

Unrestricted model (M0) Restricted model (M1)

H0 t-value WSR score K-S score Decision Mean 95% CI Mean 95% CI

ye 0.320 0.303 — 0.337 0.290 0.283 — 0.297 0 1

y ye e 5.36 6.85 0.62 Reject H0 (p<0.001)

1we 0.845 0.817 — 0.873 0.780 0.761 — 0.799 0 1

1 1w we e 11.71 10.66 0.59 Reject H0 (p<0.001)

2we 0.152 0.132 — 0.172 0.209 0.200 — 0.219 0 1

2 2w we e -11.04 -10.23 0.63 Reject H0 (p<0.001)

3we 0.003 -0.014 — 0.0.21 0.010 -0.005 — 0.026 0 1

3 3w we e -5.76 -5.80 0.72 Reject H0 (p<0.001)

Page 117: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

105

4.5 Conclusions

Most of the parametric applications in the efficiency literature tend to use flexible

functional forms, particularly the translog specification. Unfortunately, the majority of

previous studies have tended to ignore checking the regularity properties (i.e. positivity,

monotonicity and curvature) and, therefore, have explicitly or implicitly assumed that the

estimated production technology is well-behaved. For those studies that have considered

checking if these properties hold, most of them have confined their efforts to local

inspection; that is, testing for the regularity conditions at the mean of the sample data.

This local approach to checking theoretical consistency is not sufficient for sample data

with heterogeneous features. In this paper, we assess the consequences of ignoring these

properties, in terms of efficiency estimates, slope parameters and elasticities. We employ

a two-step nonlinear optimisation procedure and the Bayesian inference to impose these

regularity conditions, when they are violated.

Our results show that imposing regularity conditions yields credible estimates and these

estimates are statistically different from those obtained when the regularity conditions are

violated (less precise estimates). Overall, curvature improved by 53%; up from 35% to

98%, whereas monotonicity improved by 22%; up from 77% to 99%. Similarly, imposing

regularity conditions made reasonable improvements in the efficiency and elasticity

estimates.

Furthermore, the results show that the size of the operated area and credit rationing are

the critical factors that affect the level of cost inefficiency among maize producers. We

find evidence that farmers who operate small farms are less cost efficient than those

operating relatively large farms. Thus, farmers operating relatively large farms potentially

Page 118: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

106

experience benefits arising from economies of scale. In addition, households with binding

borrowing constraints tend to be more cost efficient. This result highlights the fungibility

nature of financial loans, which implies that loans that are disbursed in-cash can easily be

diverted to unintended and non-productive activities such as payment for medical bills or

the purchase of food and other consumption goods. Thus, there is a need to disburse

material (in-kind) loans such as farm inputs whenever the risk of loan diversion is

substantially high. In addition, incidences of credit diversion could be reduced if the poor

and vulnerable households can be targeted as beneficiaries of safety-net programs, where

such programs are available. Overall, the results underscore the need to heed regularity

conditions that are implied by economic theory for any empirical analysis to deliver

precise and consistent policy recommendations.

Page 119: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

107

Appendix 4.0

alpha chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.01

.0

beta[1] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.00

.51

.0

beta[2] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.01

.0

beta[3] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.01

.0

beta[4] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.00

.51

.0

beta[5] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.01

.0

beta[6] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.01

.0

beta[7] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.01

.0

beta[8] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.01

.0

beta[9] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.01

.0

gamma[1] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.00

.51

.0

gamma[2] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.01

.0

Page 120: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

108

Figure 4.A1: Gelman-Rubin convergence diagnostic plots for the coefficient estimates

gamma[3] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.01

.0

gamma[4] chains 1 : 3

start-iteration

20900 50000 75000 100000bg

r d

iag

no

sti

c0

.00

.51

.0

Page 121: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

109

alpha sample: 540003

alpha

-1.0 -0.75 -0.5 -0.25 0.0

P(a

lph

a)

0.0

4.0

beta[1] sample: 540003

beta[1]

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8

P(b

eta

[1])

0.0

4.0

8.0

beta[2] sample: 540003

beta[2]

0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

P(b

eta

[2])

0.0

10

.0beta[3] sample: 540003

beta[3]

-0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3

P(b

eta

[3])

0.0

10

.0

beta[4] sample: 540003

beta[4]

-0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3

P(b

eta

[4])

0.0

10

.0

beta[5] sample: 540003

beta[5]

-0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2P

(be

ta[5

])0

.01

0.02

0.0

beta[6] sample: 540003

beta[6]

-0.2 -0.1 0.0 0.1

P(b

eta

[6])

0.01

0.02

0.0

beta[7] sample: 540003

beta[7]

0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2

P(b

eta

[7])

0.0

20

.0

beta[8] sample: 540003

beta[8]

-0.2 -0.15 -0.1 -0.05

P(b

eta

[8])

0.0

20

.0

beta[9] sample: 540003

beta[9]

0.0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2

P(b

eta

[9])

0.01

0.02

0.0

gamma[1] sample: 540003

gamma[1]

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0P(g

am

ma

[1])

0.0

2.0

gamma[2] sample: 540003

gamma[2]

-2.0 0.0 2.0 4.0P(g

am

ma

[2])

0.0

1.0

2.0

Page 122: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

110

Figure 4.A2: Density plots of the parameter estimates

gamma[3] sample: 540003

gamma[3]

0.0 2.0 4.0 6.0P(g

am

ma

[3])

0.0

1.0

2.0

gamma[4] sample: 540003

gamma[4]

0.0 5.0 10.0P(g

am

ma

[4])

0.0

1.0

Page 123: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

111

Page 124: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

112

CHAPTER 5

Information acquisition, learning and the adoption of conservation

agriculture in Malawi: a discrete-time duration analysis11

This paper has been submitted for peer review as:

Khataza, R.R.B, Doole G.J., Kragt M.E., Hailu A. Information acquisition, learning and

the adoption of conservation agriculture in Malawi: a discrete-time duration analysis.

Submitted to Journal of Technological Forecasting and Social Change 26 March 2017

5.0 Abstract

Understanding factors that influence the adoption of agricultural innovations is

imperative to stakeholders promoting such technologies as well as farmers who are the

potential users of the same. Using a discrete-time duration model, this study identifies

factors that determine the timing of adoption of conservation agriculture in Malawi. We

establish that social learning through a network of peers, and access to extension advisors

facilitate quick adoption of conservation agriculture technologies. Further, our results

show that farmers who became aware of the existence of conservation agriculture during

years of drought-hazards were highly likely to adopt these practices. The results highlight

the need for strengthening and targeting social networks as conduits for information about

new technologies. (JEL-codes C41, O33, Q12, Q24)

Key words: Africa, adoption and diffusion, survival analysis, social learning,

sustainable agricultural intensification

11 An initial version of this paper benefited from constructive comments given by Professor James

Vercammen of The University of British Columbia.

Page 125: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

113

5.1 Introduction

Recent efforts to improve agricultural productivity in Africa have focused on the

promotion of low-cost sustainable land-care strategies such as conservation agriculture

or CA (Giller et al., 2009; Teklewold et al., 2013; Andersson and D'Souza, 2014; Manda

et al., 2016). Despite the widespread promotion of CA technologies, the adoption of these

practices has been slow and modest in Africa and elsewhere (Giller et al., 2009;

Teklewold et al., 2013; Andersson and D'Souza, 2014; Pannell et al., 2014; Manda et al.,

2016). The low rate of adoption for these technologies is a result of a diverse range of

factors. Notable factors include: 1) farmer’s behaviour and attitude towards risk (Ghadim

et al., 2005); 2) limited availability of key farm resources such as land and labour, and

competing uses of crop residues (Pannell et al., 2014); 3) imperfections in the capital

markets and liquidity constraints, especially when herbicides are part of the CA package

(Teklewold et al., 2013; Pannell et al., 2014; Parks et al., 2015); 4) weak property rights

to land and tenure insecurity (Teklewold et al., 2013; Parks et al., 2015) and 5) imperfect

information and uncertainty regarding CA’s benefits (Giller et al., 2009; Pannell et al.,

2014).

Farmers’ lack of information related to the performance of CA technologies is one of the

key reasons responsible for their slow adoption in different geographic regions

(Andersson and D'Souza, 2014; Pannell et al., 2014; Parks et al., 2015). As a result, the

role of information acquisition on adoption decisions has been frequently studied, albeit

using static binary-choice models such as logit or probit specifications (D'Emden et al.,

2006; Teklewold et al., 2013). These dichotomous-choice models evaluate adoption as a

one-shot decision occurring at some date. Yet, such an approach conceals important

policy information regarding the timing and speed of technology adoption (Besley and

Page 126: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

114

Case, 1993; Sunding and Zilberman, 2001; Abdulai and Huffman, 2005; Moser and

Barrett, 2006; Foster and Rosenzweig, 2010).

Investigating the timing of technology adoption provides insights in two ways. First,

earliness of adoption partly reflects a farmer’s level of innovativeness or receptiveness to

new technologies (Rogers, 1995; 2002). Second, rapid adoption of a new technology

implies that the technology is perceived to possess inherently-beneficial features that

could potentially address the challenges experienced by its intended users (Rogers, 1995;

2002). Therefore, an analysis of the time-to-adoption for a technology or technologies

can contribute to a clearer understanding of the factors that influence their diffusion, and

thus guide policy interventions that promote these practices. As an alternative to fertiliser-

based soil amendments, CA practices play an important role in terms of harnessing

economic benefits (e.g. labour savings and productivity improvements) and

environmental services, such as erosion control and carbon sequestration (Knowler and

Bradshaw, 2007; Giller et al., 2009; Manda et al., 2016).

The objective of the present study is to investigate the role of information acquisition on

the timing of technology adoption, using minimum tillage and crop residue-retention as

examples of CA practices. Unlike crop association or rotation that farmers widely

perceive as part of the typical integrated maize-legume farming system, these two CA

principles are regarded as relatively new management practices in the study area (Mloza-

Banda, 2003; Ito et al., 2007; Andersson and D'Souza, 2014; Ngwira et al., 2014). Thus,

the two practices are ideal for an adoption study. We hypothesise that delayed investment

or under-investment in CA technologies could arise from insufficient information for two

reasons:

Page 127: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

115

1. Even if farmers are aware about the existence of a new technology, they could

still be uncertain about how best to use such a technology from a technical

perspective (Foster and Rosenzweig, 2010; Genius et al., 2013).

2. New technologies can be perceived as riskier than conventional ones given that

uncertainty exists with respect to their performance across both space and time

(Rogers, 1995; Foster and Rosenzweig, 2010; Pannell et al., 2014).

Imperfect information and uncertainty regarding CA’s benefits will then delay its

adoption. Where farmers do not have access to researcher-coordinated experiments,

social learning through peers (homophily exchange) becomes a vital source of

information about new technologies (Rogers, 1995; Foster and Rosenzweig, 2010; Genius

et al., 2013; Krishnan and Patnam, 2014). For example, farmers can learn about CA’s

performance by observing the plots of early adopters or through interaction with their

acquaintances who are familiar with such technologies (Moser and Barrett, 2006;

Maertens and Barrett, 2013; Krishnan and Patnam, 2014).

We contribute to the literature by providing empirical evidence on the determinants of

time-to-adoption for sustainable land-care technologies, using a discrete-time duration

analysis framework (DT-DA). To the best of our knowledge, this is the first application

of the DT-DA approach to assess the timing of adoption of these sustainable land-care

technologies. With some exceptions (e.g. Porterfield, 2001; Burton et al., 2003;

Goncharova et al., 2008; Tiller et al., 2010; An and Butler, 2012; Bontemps et al., 2012),

the DT-DA approach has been less widely applied in the agricultural and resource

economics literature, yet this method has considerable theoretical and empirical

convenience (Singer and Willett, 1993; Jenkins, 1995; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal,

Page 128: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

116

2012). The DT-DA framework is suitable for modelling the occurrence of continuous-

time events where data have been recorded at discrete-time intervals (Jenkins, 1995; Box-

Steffensmeier and Jones, 2004; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012). In practice, it is fairly

common to record continuous-time adoption data as grouped or interval data. For

example, due to the unavailability of reliable panel data, the majority of micro-level

studies examining the timing of adoption of agricultural technologies tend to rely on recall

data (Besley and Case, 1993; Fuglie and Kascak, 2001; Burton et al., 2003; Moser and

Barrett, 2006; An and Butler, 2012). Such retrospective data are usually reported on

interval-censored scales, such as months or years (Burton et al., 2003; Jenkins, 2005; An

and Butler, 2012). Thus, it is reasonable to use discrete-time duration models rather than

the continuous-time specifications that have been extensively applied in previous studies

investigating the timing of adoption of resource-conserving technologies (eg Fuglie and

Kascak, 2001; D'Emden et al., 2006; Genius et al., 2013). Besides their suitability to

handle interval-censored data, DT-DA models can also accommodate other forms of data

censoring, which include left-censoring and right-censoring. Given that some households

will not have adopted the technology by the end of the study period, right censoring is

inevitable. On the other hand, left-censoring is applicable where some farmers may report

having adopted agricultural technologies earlier than the anticipated entry date. A naïve

approach could involve deleting right-censored observations from the sample. However,

such an approach leads to sample-selection bias, which could yield inefficient parameter

estimates (Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012). Furthermore, exclusion of censored data

involves discarding useful information that can help explain the phenomenon under study

(Singer and Willett, 1993; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012). Fortunately, discrete-

duration analysis can easily handle all of the three forms of data censoring described

above (Porterfield, 2001; Burton et al., 2003; Jenkins, 2005; Bontemps et al., 2012; Rabe-

Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012).

Page 129: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

117

The rest of the paper is organised as follows. In the next section, we present a theoretical

framework underlying optimal learning and the timing of adoption decisions. This is

followed by an empirical model for our analysis. In Section 5.3 we give a brief description

of the study area and data. Empirical results are presented and discussed in Section 5.4.

Finally, Section 5.5 presents the study conclusions.

5.2 Theoretical framework

Consider a farmer who, in the present cropping season 0( )s , has the technology choice

set consisting of two mutually exclusive land-care alternatives represented by

( , )jL CA CT , where CA is a green technology and CT is a conventional (brown)

technology. By adopting one or both of the two land-care technologies, a farmer derives

some economic and environmental benefits denoted by

0( ); ( ) 0,1,2,..........,j t ts s s t t T .12 Accordingly, the expected net present value

(NPV) of a stream of discounted benefits for the thi farmer is given by

( ), ( )i CA t CT tV s s .

There is an incentive for the farmer to adopt the green technology if its benefits are greater

than those derived from the conventional technology. Thus, the farmer’s propensity to

invest in any CA technology follows the standard NPV criterion given as

12 0s denotes the inception period for the new technology, i.e. the time when farmers start learning

about the existence of the new technology within their proximity, whereas t and T represent the

adoption date and end of the study period, respectively. It is likely that some farmers will not have

adopted the new technology up to time T , hence such farmers are liable to right-censoring. In

retrospective data, adoption time t is recorded discretely, usually in years.

Page 130: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

118

* ( ) ( ) 0CA CA t CT CT tV V s V s (Sunding and Zilberman, 2001; Abdulai and

Huffman, 2005; Goncharova et al., 2008; Song et al., 2011; Genius et al., 2013). We

assume, as in real option theory, that investments are uncertain and irreversible. The

irreversibility characteristic implies the importance of sunk costs, such that it is costly for

a farmer to recover investments already committed in a cropping season13 (Dixit and

Pindyck, 1994; Song et al., 2011; Genius et al., 2013). Therefore, the farmer’s problem

concerns whether to adopt and, if so, when to adopt the available CA technology and

optimise the investment benefits *( )V associated with this decision. There are two options

to consider: adopt CA in the current season 1( )s , if the technology is worthwhile, or wait

for more information and adopt it in the future, 1( ) 2,3,..........,ts s t t T , after

validating its prospects.

A farmer reduces the uncertainty about the technology by gathering more information

from at least three channels: extension agents, early adopters (peers or social network

members) and self-learning or learning-by-doing (Rogers, 1995; Ghadim et al., 2005;

Genius et al., 2013). In each subsequent cropping season(s), potential adopters update

their expectation about the prospects of the new technology *( )V , given the information

gathered up to that time. The optimal time of terminating this information-search

coincides with the time when a farmer builds a favourable perception of the new

technology, hence the farmer adopts the technology at this point. Otherwise, the adoption

13 In real option theory, the irreversibility of a technology is explained by the presence of sunk costs that

are incurred, in this case, at the beginning of the cropping season. Once these costs have been committed,

it is costly to reverse. For annual crops and CA technologies, the decision whether or not to continue with

the present technology is revised at the end of each harvest period i.e. the end of investment horizon.

Page 131: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

119

decision is postponed while the farmer continues to look for extra information in favour

of this technology (Sunding and Zilberman, 2001; Genius et al., 2013).

Since sustainable land-care technologies supply multiple benefits, including non-

marketable services that may be difficult to value (e.g. carbon sequestration, soil organic

matter content, and water infiltration capabilities), the complete benefit function,

* (.)V , is considered as a latent function. Thus, the *V which the landowner aspires

to optimise is obscure to the analyst. However, the occurrence of an adoption decision

within the study time ( 1,2,..., )t T acts as a proxy indicator revealing the optimal length

of learning or information acquisition, as well as the likelihood that the new technology

is perceived to be beneficial to the land-owner i.e. * 0V . We therefore observe the

farmer’s technology adoption decision as follows:

*

*| 1,2,..,

1 (.) (.) 0(1)

0 (.) (.) 0t

CA CTt T

s t TCA CTt T

if V VAdopt

if V V

V

V

This binary characterisation of the adoption decision mimics that used in earlier work

(e.g. Teklewold et al., 2013). However, our work deviates from this established literature

through modelling the dynamic adoption decision using a discrete-time duration or hazard

function, which gives the probability that a farmer who has not adopted CA technologies

in crop season ts will adopt in the subsequent season 1ts (Abdulai and Huffman, 2005;

Goncharova et al., 2008; Tiller et al., 2010; Genius et al., 2013).

5.2.1 Discrete-time duration model of technology adoption

In the formulation of a discrete-time duration model, we are interested in the length of

time that elapses between a farmer’s time of exposure to CA practices and the actual

Page 132: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

120

adoption year. Let the discrete adoption time, in years, be represented by a random

variable 0T . Therefore, the frequency distribution of time-realisation t, which denotes

technology adoption, can be represented by the probability density function ( )f t .

Furthermore, let ( )S t define the survival function, which gives the probability that

technology adoption will not be realised before t i.e. ( ) Pr( )S t T t .

One of the fundamental parameters in the analysis of duration data is the hazard rate. In

the context of adoption, the hazard function ( )h t assesses whether and, if so, when the

adoption of a given technology is likely to take place. The hazard function specifies the

probability of event failure ( )f t conditional on survival ( )S t , as follows (Box-

Steffensmeier and Jones, 2004; Jenkins, 2005; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012):

( )Pr( | ) ( ) (2)

( )

f tT t T t h t

S t

The conditional probability of survival is alternatively expressed in terms of the hazard

function as Pr( | ) 1 ( )T t T t h t . The estimation of the hazard rate proceeds via

maximum likelihood such that both completed spells (i.e. individuals with definite

adoption time) and censored spells (i.e. individuals whose adoption time is undefined at

the end of the study) are included in the likelihood function. The sample likelihood

function is the product of these two sets of independent adoption-spells (Singer and

Willett, 1993; Jenkins, 1995; Box-Steffensmeier and Jones, 2004; Rabe-Hesketh and

Skrondal, 2012). The likelihood contribution for a censored household corresponds to the

survival function ( )S t , and is defined as the probability that an individual does not adopt

within the entire study period (Singer and Willett, 1993; Box-Steffensmeier and Jones,

2004; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012):

Page 133: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

121

1

Pr( ) ( ) (1 ) (3)t

i i i is

s

L T t S t h

where 1,2,.........,s t T is the period in which individual i adopts CA or is censored

at the end of the study period T . The likelihood contribution from the completed spell

within the study period ( )t T , corresponds to the probability of adoption in period t .

This likelihood contribution is given as in Equation 4 (Singer and Willett, 1993; Box-

Steffensmeier and Jones, 2004; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012):

1

1

Pr( ) ( ) (1 ) (4)t

i t i it is

s

L T t f t h h

Given ic as the censoring indicator defined such that 0ic if adoption occurs

(uncensored observation), otherwise 1ic if an observation is right-censored. The

likelihood for the whole sample is given by combining the independent likelihoods

expressed in Equations (3) and (4) (Singer and Willett, 1993; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal,

2012):

1

11

1 1 1

Pr( ) Pr( ) (1 ) (1 ) (5)

i i

i i

c cn t t

c c

i i i i i it is is

i s s

L T t T t h h h

where n is the sample size.

Equation (5) is operationalised by replacing ic with iy , which depicts the farmer’s

adoption status. For each individual in the sample, we construct a binary dependent

variable, 0

1it

i cy

if adoption occurred in any period t T and

10

iti c

y if adoption

Page 134: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

122

never occurred until timeT . Thus, the whole-sample likelihood function is modified as

follows (Singer and Willett, 1993; Box-Steffensmeier and Jones, 2004):

1 1

1 1 1

(1 ) ( ) ( ) (6)i

it it i

tn ny y y y

i is is

i s i

L h h f t S t

5.2.2 Empirical discrete-duration model

Typically, a full empirical model augments the effects of elapsed time and other

covariates on the timing of adoption. Let X represent a vector of both time-variant

variables (e.g. age, experience and environmental conditions) and time-invariant

covariates (e.g. gender and location). A common approach to incorporate the effects of

both the baseline hazard and covariates on a hazard function is through the use of a

proportional hazard (PH) specification. The generalised formulation of the PH models, as

in the Cox PH model, is expressed as follows (Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012):

0( , ) ( ).exp( ) (7)i ih t x h t x

where is a vector of unknown parameters, and 0 ( )h t represents a constant baseline

hazard function which is common to all farmers within a sample. The baseline hazard

function reflects the adoption path that a technology could follow if the effects of all

covariates were zero (i.e. time dependence). In contrast, the relative hazard (defined as

exp( )x ) is conditional on covariates and thus varies for each farmer. We adopt the

exponential specification of the hazard function as denoted in Equation (7) for two

reasons. First, the exponential form ensures that the hazard function is automatically non-

negative, as required by definition, without imposing restrictions on coefficients

(Kiefer, 1988; Burton et al., 2003). Second, the interpretation of the results from this

formulation is straightforward, such that the estimated coefficients indicate the

direction and magnitude of influence that any covariate exerts on the hazard rate. Thus, a

Page 135: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

123

value of one implies no impact of a particular covariate on the hazard rate, whereas a

value greater than one indicates a positive influence on the likelihood of event occurrence

and vice versa (Kiefer, 1988; Fuglie and Kascak, 2001; Burton et al., 2003).

To estimate Equation (7) using the DT-DA approach, we need to choose a functional form

for the hazard rate. Any of the binary-dependent variable models, such as logit and probit

formulations, could be used to examine the factors that affect time-to-adoption, once the

data have been re-organised into a person-time format (Jenkins, 1995; Porterfield, 2001;

Tiller et al., 2010; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012). This format enables one person to

have multiple records from entry time up to the year when adoption occurs ( )it T or

the censoring time at the end of the study period ( )it T . We parameterise the hazard

function (Equation 7) using a complementary log-log specification (clog-log) because it

is the discrete-time equivalent of the continuous-time PH model (Jenkins, 1995;

Bontemps et al., 2012; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012). The clog-log functional form

is specified as follows:

0log log ( , ) ln{ ln(1 )} ( )exp[ ( ) ] (8 )

ln{ ln(1 )} ( ) (8 )

i i it i i

it it it i

c h t X e h h t X t e a

h D t X e b

where X is a vector of covariates; D is a time-variable capturing the effect of duration

dependence (baseline hazard); and are estimable parameters; 2~ (0, )ie N is a

random error term representing unobserved individual specific characteristics. The

random error term is assumed to be uncorrelated with X . The presence of unobserved

heterogeneity could result from a number of factors including functional-form

misspecification and omission (inclusion) of important (irrelevant) variables (Kiefer,

1988; Abdulai and Huffman, 2005). Failure to control for unobserved heterogeneity, if

Page 136: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

124

present, can confound coefficient estimates and inferences about duration dependence

(Abdulai and Huffman, 2005; Beyene and Kassie, 2015). To deal with unobserved

heterogeneity, we incorporate the error term (Equation 8) that is assumed to follow a

normal distribution with mean zero and finite variance equal to 2 (Jenkins, 1995; Rabe-

Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012).

5.3. Study area, CA inception and variable description

5.3.1 Study area and the inception of CA practices

We use survey data collected from a total of 311 households randomly selected from

Kasungu and Mzimba districts in Malawi. The survey was conducted in the 2013/14 crop

season. These districts are part of the medium-altitude agro-ecological zone of the

country. A subdivision of this agro-ecological zone is the Kasungu–Lilongwe plain. This

zone is one of the areas where CA practices are most dominant among smallholder maize

and legume farmers in Malawi.

The survey followed a three-stage random sampling approach. First, the study zones were

selected based on Ministry of Agriculture administrative demarcations, known as

extension planning areas (EPAs). The EPAs are district-level administrative units

established to coordinate and oversee the execution of extension services across the

country. The second step involved the choice of an EPA section. An EPA section is the

lowest unit of administration in the Ministry of Agriculture hierarchy. Subsequently,

maize-legume producers were identified from each EPA section. This procedure was

done in order to establish a sampling frame. Third, after the selection of EPA sections and

enumeration of maize-legume producers were completed, face-to-face interviews were

conducted with a set of randomly chosen respondents (household heads). A total of 341

respondents were randomly selected for interviews, but the analysis in this chapter uses a

Page 137: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

125

sub-sample of 311 households. Using a structured questionnaire, these respondents were

asked to provide information regarding CA technologies existent in the area, the year

when a farmer became aware of the existence of these technologies, if and when, the

farmer adopted any of the available CA technologies. We focus on only two CA principles

which are relatively new in the study area. The two CA principles are minimum soil

disturbance (minimum tillage) and post-harvest retention of crop residues (i.e. covering

farm surface with maize stover and legume straw).

Despite a long history of promoting sustainable land-care technologies in Malawi, great

interest in CA technologies was revitalised in the 1990s after not receiving much attention

throughout the 1980s (Mloza-Banda, 2003; Ito et al., 2007; Ngwira et al., 2014). The

rekindled interest in CA technologies followed the need to address numerous production

and socio-economic challenges facing the country, which include land degradation,

down-sizing of fertiliser-subsidy programs and recurrent food shortages experienced

from the 1990s onwards (Devereux, 2007; Ito et al., 2007; Harrigan, 2008; Andersson

and D'Souza, 2014). As a result, a number of CA programs were promoted as part of the

integrated soil-improvement strategies proposed by both state and non-state agencies.

These programs incorporated various CA add-ons, such as improved maize and legume

seeds, crop diversification, agroforestry technologies and other soil and water

conservation practices (Ito et al., 2007; Andersson and D'Souza, 2014). In our analysis,

we consider this period of enormous investment in CA programs (1990) as the inception

time for minimum tillage and residue retention. Defining the inception period in this way

helps us to correctly deal with left-censoring or delayed entry. Figure 5.1 shows the trend

of CA awareness and adoption over the study period (1990-2014). The diffusion pattern

exhibited in this figure shows that few farmers in the sample were aware of the existence

Page 138: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

126

of CA technologies in the early 1990s. Instead, the popularity of these technologies started

rising from the early 2000s.

Page 139: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

127

Figure 5.1. CA awareness and adoption trends among smallholder maize-legume producers, 1990-2014

Page 140: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

128

5.3.2 Data description

5.3.2.1 Dependent variable

We are interested in the factors that explain the speed of transition from non-adoption to

adoption of CA technologies. Therefore, our dependent variable measures time until

adoption, expressed as the number of years that elapsed between the time when a farmer

became aware of the existence of specific CA practices, and the time when that farmer

adopted any of the two CA components. This dependent variable is constructed using

recall data, an approach which has been widely applied in adoption studies when panel

data is not readily available (Fuglie and Kascak, 2001; Burton et al., 2003; Moser and

Barrett, 2006; An and Butler, 2012). The recall approach creates a quasi-panel data which

may provide a better understanding on factors that influence adoption patterns over time,

as depicted in Figure 5.1.

Within the survey period (1990-2014), three different time spells can be distinguished

based on a farmer’s length of time-to-adoption: 1) a complete spell, representing any

farmer who had adopted CA within the study period; 2) a right-censored spell associated

with any farmer who had not yet adopted CA by end of the survey period (2014); and 3)

a left-truncated spell or delayed entry, which corresponds to a farmer whose awareness

date occurred prior to 1990, and therefore, this farmer may have adopted CA technologies

or was yet to adopt by 2014. We deal with left-truncation by deleting observations prior

to the start date (1990), such that the correct likelihood contribution is restricted to only

those observations that fall within the survey period (Jenkins, 2005; Bontemps et al.,

2012; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012). Only 3 and 2 farmers in the sample indicated

that they knew about the existence of residue retention and minimum tillage prior to 1990,

respectively (Figure 5.1). Table 5.1 describes and summarises the data. The differences

Page 141: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

129

in the number of observations between continuous-time models and discrete-time models

is a result of data transformation from single-case format into person-time format where

an individual has multiple records from entry time up to the year when adoption occurs.

The mean adoption time is estimated at five and six years for minimum tillage and residue

retention, respectively.

Page 142: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

130

Table 5.1 Variable description and summary statistics for the sample households

Variable name

Variable description

Minimum tillage

Residue retention

Adopters

(n=301)

Non-

adopters

(n=39)

Adopters

(n=311) Non-adopters (n=29)

Mean Mean Mean Mean

Adoption time Time until adoption (elapsed years from awareness to

adoption) 4.76 (3.67) - 6.22 (5.00) -

Own ruminants 1 if the household owns any ruminants; =0 otherwise 0.55 (0.50) 0.46 (0.51) 0.54 (0.50) 0.55 (0.51)

Age Age of household head (years) 44.56

(13.63)

44.62

(15.71) 43.95

(13.38) 51.21 (17.15)

Gender 1 if the household head is male; =0 otherwise 0.57 (0.50) 0.33 (0.48) 0.54 (0.50) 0.55 (0.51)

Education Education of the household head (years) 6.82 (3.21) 6.53 (3.55) 6.86 (3.19) 5.96 (3.82)

Dependency ratio Ratio of economically inactive members to total household

size 1.41 (1.26) 1.33 (1.12) 1.40 (1.17) 1.49 (1.90)

Land holding size Total land owned (acres) 6.82 (3.54) 5.68 (3.37) 6.79 (3.50) 5.59 (3.75)

Member of social network 1 if the household head is a member of a farmer association 0.72 (0.45) 0.54 (0.51) 0.70 (0.46) 0.62 (0.49)

Learning through peers 1 if peers were the main information-source about CA

technologies 0.23 (0.42) 0.00 (0.00) 0.20 (0.40) 0.00 (0.00)

Learning through advisors 1 if extension advisors were the main information-source

about CA 0.47 (0.50) 0.00 (0.00) 0.56 (0.50) 0.00 (0.00)

Radio communication 1 if radio was the main information-source about CA

technologies 0.26 (0.44) 0.00 (0.00) 0.21 (0.40) 0.00 (0.00)

Livestock holding index Aggregate of tropical livestock units (TLU) 1.33 (2.67) 0.70 (1.21) 1.16 (2.34) 2.28 (4.10)

Soil fertility 1 if farmer rates soil fertility of their farm as poor; =0

otherwise 0.51 (0.51) 0.35 (0.35) 0.50 (0.51) 0.38 (0.37)

Distance to farm Distance from homestead to the farm in hours of walking time 0.22 (0.42) 0.15 (0.37) 0.23 (0.42) 0.07 (0.26)

District 1 if household is in Kasungu district; =0 if located in Mzimba 0.54 (0.50) 0.28 (0.46) 0.53 (0.50) 0.31 (0.47)

Aware during the 2000s 1 if farmer became aware of CA during the 2000s drought

episodes 0.09 (0.29) 0.00 (0.00) 0.13 (0.34) 0.00 (0.00)

Aware during 2012 1 if farmer became aware of CA during the drought episode of

2012 0.20 (0.40) 0.00 (0.00) 0.17 (0.38) 0.00 (0.00)

Note: standard deviations in parentheses; Tropical livestock units (TLU) conversion factors across different livestock classes are as follows: cattle = 1.0; chicken=0.01;

donkey=0.8; duck/guinea fowl/turkey=0.03; goat/sheep = 0.2; oxen = 1.2; pig =0.3; rabbit = 0.01 (Source: Bundervoet 2010; Njuki et al. 2011)

Page 143: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

131

5.3.2.2 Explanatory variables and potential effects on adoption

Previous studies provide some guidance regarding factors that may explain the timing of

adoption for new technologies (Burton et al., 2003; D'Emden et al., 2006; Beyene and

Kassie, 2015; Mutenje et al., 2016). Based on these studies and adoption theory (e.g.

Rogers, 1995; Pannell et al., 2014), we identify explanatory variables which include

sources of technology information, farm characteristics and farmer or household

characteristics. The summary statistics for these variables are presented in Table 5.1. In

what follows we describe variable measurement and posit their possible influence on the

timing of CA adoption.

5.3.2.2a Information acquisition and learning

Knowledge and experience boosts a farmer’s confidence on how to use the technology

independently and could increase adoption speed. For example, Knowler and Bradshaw

(2007) provide evidence that availability of information has a positive impact on the early

adoption of CA technologies. We identify five variables that relate to information

acquisition and the building of a stock of knowledge regarding new technologies. The

first set of information variables are membership in a farmer organisation and farmer-to-

farmer exchange of information. Together, this set of variables is used to denote the level

of social learning that is undertaken. Social interaction through direct contact with leading

farmers or via a network of peers (e.g. within a farmer association) is a cost-effective way

of transmitting knowledge about new technologies (Maertens and Barrett, 2013; Manda

et al., 2016). We note that membership in a farmer association may not be an explicit

measure of social learning as argued by Maertens and Barrett (2013), but such a variable

still provides relevant information that can improve our understanding about the timing

of CA adoption (Moser and Barrett, 2006; Knowler and Bradshaw, 2007; Teklewold et

Page 144: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

132

al., 2013; Beyene and Kassie, 2015; Manda et al., 2016). The other three information

variables included in the analysis are access to extension agents, radio communication,

and self-learning or experience, represented by the age of the farmer. Fifty per cent of the

farmers learnt about the existence of CA technologies through extension advisors,

followed by mass media (radio programs) and peer exchange of information (Table 5.1)

5.3.2.2b Farmer and household characteristics

Farmer characteristics such as gender, education, and household assets may affect the

adoption of agricultural technologies. For example, male farmers tend to have a higher

propensity to adopt agricultural innovations than their female counterparts (Knowler and

Bradshaw, 2007; Marenya and Barrett, 2007). This is the case because, compared to

female farmers, male farmers usually have better access to financial capital, which could

be used to purchase complementary farm inputs (Marenya and Barrett, 2007; Mutenje et

al., 2016). It may also reflect the traditional dominance of household decision making by

a given gender, in certain cultures (Parks et al., 2015; Mutenje et al., 2016). Besides the

gender of the farmer, education levels of the decision maker, could facilitate CA adoption.

Higher education levels are associated with innovation-seeking behaviour, improved

information-processing capabilities and better farm management skills that could

facilitate the timely adoption of CA technologies (Rogers, 1995).

The availability of family labour is another factor that could increase CA adoption speed.

The supply of adequate labour is necessary because certain components of CA

technologies, such as crop residue-retention, could be labour-intensive. Generally,

residue-retention has two peak labour requirements. The first labour peak is prior to

planting season when crop residues are spread in the field, and the second peak is at the

Page 145: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

133

time of weeding. Farmers have to cope with increased weeding intensities, especially

when herbicide use is not part of the conservation package (Giller et al., 2009; Andersson

and D'Souza, 2014). Coincidentally, smallholder farmers in Malawi find herbicides not

only expensive, but also perceive their use as a threat to plant biodiversity and future

productivity. Additionally, we use age structure of a household to reflect the quantity and

quality of family labour endowment. This age structure is given by the household’s

dependency ratio, which is expressed as a proportion of economically inactive family

members (those aged over 65 years and children aged between 1 and 15 years) to the total

number of household members.

Livestock ownership tends to influence CA adoption both in negative and positive ways,

depending on the type of crop-livestock synergy being exploited. For example, ownership

of ruminants could reduce the likelihood of CA adoption because animals could graze

crop residues, removing the opportunity to use them as a green manure (Pannell et al.,

2014). Most parts of Malawi experience a unimodal rainfall pattern; thus, most of the

grazing areas become dry during and after the harvest season. During this period, the

scarcity of quality feed is remarkably high and therefore deciding on whether to use crop

residues as soil amendments or feed is a difficult choice for a farmer. On the other hand,

livestock provide manure that, if used together with crop-residues, can enrich the quality

of organic soil amendments and enhance crop productivity. Thus, the effect of livestock

holding on CA adoption is ambiguous. We adopt the tropical livestock unit (TLU) as an

aggregate measure of livestock holdings to account for heterogeneity across livestock

classes (Bundervoet, 2010; Njuki et al., 2011). The total livestock holding size is

computed as .i liTLU m where li is the TLU for the thl livestock class owned by

Page 146: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

134

farmer i , and m is the total number of livestock in that particular class. The higher the

value of the TLU index, the larger the livestock holding size for the household.

5.3.2.2c Farm characteristics

Farm characteristics such as size and soil fertility status have the potential to influence

both the scope and scale of CA technologies being adopted. As a result of the

heterogeneity in soil types and distance to farm, farmers could selectively adopt certain

components of CA technologies rather than adopting the complete package (Pannell et

al., 2014). Furthermore, farm remoteness makes transporting complementary resources

(e.g. manure and labour) from homestead to the farm more complex, and this could

constrain CA adoption. The variable that we use to assess land quality is based on a

farmer’s assessment of soil fertility status, given their experience regarding the

productivity of the farm. In terms of farm size, farmers with large farms could choose to

implement CA on some plots and retain conventional practices on other parts of their

farm. Thus, we expect farm size to be positively correlated with CA adoption.

5.4 Results and discussion

5.4.1 Non-parametric estimation results

We use the Kaplan-Meier’s graphical approach to explore the probability of survival

(non-adoption) beyond time t , or conversely, the probability of event failure (adoption)

after time t . This approach can give insights on the speed of adoption over the study

period. The results of this non-parametric analysis are presented in Figure 5.2. The plots

show that the survivor probability is falling and hence, the number of CA adopters is

increasing over time. The advantage of using the Kaplan-Meier approach is that this

method does not make any assumption about the functional form of the survivor function.

However, this approach cannot explicitly model the effects of covariates. As a result, this

Page 147: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

135

study uses both non-parametric and parametric approaches. In the next section, we present

results estimated from the parametric models.

Page 148: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

136

Figure 5.2 Kaplan-Meier survival estimates of the time-to-adoption of CA technologies in Malawi

Page 149: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

137

5.4.2 Semi-parametric and parametric analysis results

5.4.2.1 Model diagnostic tests

Table 5.2 presents the results from three sets of models estimated for each of the two CA

technologies as follows: 1) the baseline hazard model in which the hazard rate is regressed

on adoption-time as the only covariate, assuming that the effect of other covariates is

inconsequential; 2) the semiparametric Cox PH model, which is estimated assuming that

time-to-adoption is recorded on a relatively fine time interval; and 3) the complete model

defined using a discrete-time PH specification, accounting for the effects of both

adoption-time and other covariates. Similar discrete-time PH models were estimated

assuming a logit and probit functional form, but the results from these models were almost

identical to the clog-log model. We therefore report only the results of the clog-log model,

given that it is the counterpart of the continuous-time PH model.

Further analysis was conducted to test the effects of unobserved heterogeneity. The

estimated variance parameter ( 2 ) from the models, controlling for unobserved

heterogeneity, was nearly equal to zero (Appendix 5.A1). Thus, the null hypothesis that

unobserved heterogeneity is not present ( 2 0 ) could not be rejected, suggesting that

the effects of unobserved heterogeneity in the estimated models were less severe.

Accordingly, the coefficient estimates presented in Table 5.2 are based on models

excluding unobserved heterogeneity.

A comparison of the continuous-time and discrete-time PH models shows stability in

terms of the sign of the estimated coefficients (effects of covariates). However, there are

slight differences in terms of the magnitude of the estimated coefficients. Overall, the

AIC, BIC and log-likelihood statistics show that the discrete-time models (clog-log PH

Page 150: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

138

model) fitted our data better than the alternative Cox PH model. Therefore, in the next

section, our discussion is centred on the discrete-time PH models.

Page 151: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

139

Table 5.2 Coefficient estimates for the Cox PH and discrete-time duration models of CA adoption time

Minimum tillage

Crop-residue retention

Baseline PH

model

Cox PH model DT PH model Baseline PH

model

Cox PH model DT PH model

HR z-

value

HR z-

value

HR z-

value

HR z-

value

HR z-

value

HR z-

value

Own ruminants

0.88

(0.26)

-0.42

0.92

(0.27)

-0.29

1.18

(0.35)

0.56

1.26

(0.39)

0.73

Age

1.10

(0.07)

1.52

1.09

(0.07)

1.45

0.96

(0.04)

-1.02

0.96

(0.04)

-0.93

(Age)2

1.00

(0.00)

-1.40

1.00

(0.00)

-1.36

1.00

(0.00)

0.64

1.00

(0.00)

0.55

Gender

0.46***

(0.12)

-3.09

0.48***

(0.12)

-3.02

0.90

(0.22)

-0.41

0.92

(0.24)

-0.31

Education

1.07

(0.13)

0.51

1.10

(0.13)

0.81

1.42***

(0.15)

3.32

1.42***

(0.15)

3.29

(Education)2

1.00

(0.01)

-0.43

0.99

(0.01)

-0.63

0.98***

(0.01)

-3.08

0.98***

(0.01)

-3.03

Dependency ratio

1.01

(0.09)

0.08

1.00

(0.10)

0.00

1.02

(0.08)

0.26

1.04

(0.08)

0.45

Total area

1.00

(0.04)

-0.04

1.01

(0.04)

0.20

1.03

(0.03)

1.05

1.03

(0.03)

1.00

Member of a social

network

1.60

(0.48)

1.58

1.64

(0.51)

1.59

1.46**

(0.28)

1.99

1.44*

(0.28)

1.82

Learning through peers

6.59***

(3.30)

3.77

6.72***

(3.50)

3.66

3.20***

(1.02)

3.66

3.24***

(1.06)

3.58

Learning through

extension advisors

4.72***

(1.85)

3.97

5.40***

(2.30)

3.97

3.39***

(0.93)

4.44

3.51***

(0.99)

4.46

Livestock index

1.11*

(0.06)

1.84

1.11*

(0.06)

1.82

1.04

(0.04)

0.94

1.04

(0.04)

0.91

Distance to farm

1.19

(0.32)

0.65

1.16

(0.33)

0.52

1.01

(0.20)

0.04

1.00

(0.20)

0.00

Page 152: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

140

Table 5.2 (continued)

Minimum tillage Crop-residue retention

Baseline PH model Cox PH model DT PH model Baseline PH model Cox PH model DT PH model

HR z-

value

HR z-

value

HR z-

value

HR z-

value

HR z-

value

HR z-

value

Poor soil fertility 1.70**

(0.45)

2.02 1.80**

(0.49)

2.19 1.36

(0.26)

1.62 1.37*

(0.26)

1.66

District fixed

effects

3.33***

(1.12)

3.57

3.38***

(1.12)

3.66

1.02

(0.24)

0.09

1.02

(0.25)

0.10

Aware during

2000-05

0.31***

(0.10)

-3.72

0.25***

(0.09)

-3.79

0.74

(0.20)

-1.09

0.68

(0.20)

-1.32

Aware during

2012

3.40***

(1.15)

3.63

2.67***

(0.80)

3.28

4.77***

(1.68)

4.42

4.51***

(1.36)

4.99

Duration

dependence

D1 (1 5)t 0.05***

(0.01)

-

23.71

1.28

(0.86)

0.37

0.05***

(0.01)

-

24.37

0.37***

(0.13)

-2.75

D2

(6 10)t

0.05***

(0.01)

-

13.40

3.65**

(2.44)

1.93

0.07***

(0.01)

-

16.17

0.91

(0.32)

-0.25

D3

(11 15)t

0.05***

(0.01)

-

11.14

3.75***

(1.98)

2.50

0.06***

(0.01)

-

12.65

0.98

(0.37)

-0.04

D4

(16 25)t

0.01***

(0.00)

-8.53

0.04***

(0.01)

-

12.72

Constant

0.00***

(0.00)

-4.98

0.02***

(0.02)

-3.57

LLR -400

-362

-296

-538

-573

-453

AIC 807

759

634

1084

1180

947

BIC 830

823

754

1108

1243

1069

n 2408

311

2200

2660

311

2433

Note: PH= proportional hazard; HR= hazard ratio; DT= discrete-time; LLR= Log likelihood ratio; AIC= Akaike's information criterion; BIC= Bayesian

information criterion; standard errors in parentheses; cluster-robust standard errors are reported in the Cox PH and complete DT PH models; *p<0.10; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.

Page 153: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

141

5.4.3 Duration-dependence/the effect of time on adoption

In this subsection, we examine the effect of time (duration dependence), assuming that

the effect of other covariates on the speed of adoption is zero. This (baseline) model

provides the answer to the question regarding the time when adoption is likely to occur.

We model the baseline hazard as a step function by including dummy variables to

represent a period in which adoption had occurred (D1-4 in Table 5.2, columns 2 and 8).

This approach leads to a flexible baseline hazard model, which if augmented with the

effects of other covariates yields a semiparametric full discrete-time PH model (columns

6 and 12 in Table 5.2). Our results show that the magnitude of the estimated coefficients

for the variables representing elapsed time are stable in the initial periods (D1-3) but fall

in the latter periods (D4). Overall, these results indicate that the probability of

procrastinating the adoption decision is highest in the initial periods. In other words, there

is negative duration-dependence, especially for minimum tillage. Thus, many farmers

become more willing to adopt CA technologies with the passage of time. The surging

adoption rates in the latter years could be due to various factors including increased

confidence due to greater knowledge regarding the value proposition of technologies,

increased awareness, changes in the natural environment (e.g. adverse effects of climate

change) and the lower incidence of farmer-support agricultural policies, such as the farm

input subsidy programs (Devereux, 2007; Harrigan, 2008; Andersson and D'Souza,

2014).

5.4.4 The effect of other covariates on adoption

The effects of covariates of interest on farmers’ propensity to adopt CA technologies are

examined using the continuous-time Cox PH model and the discrete-time PH model. The

advantage of the Cox model is that it is semi-parametric and does not impose any

Page 154: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

142

functional form on the baseline hazard, 0 ( )h t . The results of these models are presented

in Table 5.2. For easy comparison of the results, all coefficient estimates are reported in

terms of hazard ratio (HR), such that a value of one implies no impact of a particular

covariate on the hazard rate, whereas a value greater (less) than one indicates positive

(negative) influence on the likelihood of CA adoption (Burton et al., 2003; D'Emden et

al., 2006; An and Butler, 2012; Beyene and Kassie, 2015). Since there could be some

correlation among farmers within the same location such as village, we use cluster-robust

standard errors and thereby allow for random errors to be correlated within a village but

not across villages (Cameron and Miller, 2015). A total of 64 spatial clusters (villages)

were used to adjust the standard errors.

The coefficients for the information variables (i.e. peer knowledge-transfer, membership

in a farmer association, and access to extension services) are positive (greater than one)

and significant. This provides evidence on the importance of information acquisition and

learning in terms of accelerating CA adoption. The results are consistent with previous

studies focussing on CA adoption (Knowler and Bradshaw, 2007; Manda et al., 2016;

Mutenje et al., 2016). When producers are uncertain or have imperfect information about

the profitability of a new technology, they tend to postpone the adoption decision until

sufficient information becomes available (Ghadim et al., 2005; Genius et al., 2013). The

importance of information is to dispel misconceptions that farmers might have, as well as

build their expertise in terms of technical recommendations that could have been

unfamiliar to new users of the technology. For example, farmers in the study area express

reservations over minimum tillage as it is perceived to proliferate rapid weed growth

during the onset of the rainy season. In this case, minimum tillage is believed to increase

weeding intervals, and is therefore deemed labour-intensive. Farmers also believe that

Page 155: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

143

minimum tillage creates a hard soil-pan that hinders seed germination or reduces seedling

vigour. The observation that CA induces higher weed pressure and increases peak labour

demand has been observed by other researchers (Giller et al., 2009; Andersson and

D'Souza, 2014; Parks et al., 2015). This is particularly so when herbicides are not part of

the adopted CA package. Therefore, as more information about the technology attributes

become available, farmers are more able to evaluate the technology objectively.

In addition to this information, we find evidence that low soil fertility increases chances

of CA adoption. Further, farmers who became aware of the existence of CA technologies

during the years of severe drought (e.g. in 2012) were likely to adopt CA as part of their

climate-change adaptation strategy. The popularity of CA technologies has been

increasing in the recent past; at least partly, because of an increasing incidence of food

insecurity resulting from erratic rainfall (Devereux, 2007; Harrigan, 2008; Andersson and

D'Souza, 2014).

5.5 Conclusions and policy implications

Malawi and the rest of Sub-Saharan Africa faces serious agricultural-productivity

challenges that have direct consequences for the sustenance of food security and

environmental quality. Consequently, researchers and policy makers are constantly

searching for cost-effective strategies to address these challenges. Recently, sustainable

land-care strategies such as conservation agriculture (CA) have been proposed as a

solution, and are being promoted in the region (Giller et al., 2009; Andersson and

D'Souza, 2014; Manda et al., 2016; Mutenje et al., 2016).

Page 156: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

144

Using a discrete-time duration model, this study examined factors that affect time-to-

adoption of conservation practices among smallholder farmers in Malawi. We find that

the most critical factors driving the adoption decision of CA practices are access to

information, low soil fertility and changes in the natural environment. Uncertainty and

imperfect information regarding the benefits and costs of CA practices could delay the

adoption of such technologies. Accordingly, peer knowledge-transfer and access to

extension advisors stimulates the adoption of these practices. These findings suggest the

need for localised adaptive research to generate objective and policy-oriented information

about CA benefits. Indeed, research partnerships between farmers and scientists or

technology dissemination agents need to be established or strengthened where they

already exist. The more time that leading farmers invest in participating in these

partnerships and learning about CA principles, the higher the chances that the practices

could be accepted. As the research evidence suggests, potential adopters may

subsequently learn from a social network of innovators or from their acquaintances who

have developed a better understanding of how CA principles are implemented.

Accordingly, peer networks are found to act as technology-incubation hubs, where new

farmers can learn about the value of agricultural innovations and how best to tailor them

to suit their individual situations.

Page 157: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

145

Appendix 5.0

Appendix 5.A1: Coefficient estimates for the discrete-time duration models with frailty

Minimum tillage Crop-residue retention

HR z-value HR z-value

Own ruminants 1.09 (0.32) 0.31 1.30 (0.42) 0.82

Age 1.06 (0.06) 1.00 0.97 (0.04) -0.62

(Age)2 1.00 (0.00) -1.01 1.00 (0.00) 0.26

Gender 0.49*** (0.12) -2.91 1.00 (0.26) 0.00

Education 1.02 (0.12) 0.19 1.41*** (0.15) 3.28

(Education)2 1.00 (0.01) 0.05 0.98*** (0.01) -2.97

Dependency ratio 0.98 (0.10) -0.21 1.07 (0.08) 0.99

Total area 0.99 (0.03) -0.18 1.02 (0.03) 0.74

Member of a social network 1.40 (0.41) 1.16 1.60** (0.33) 2.30

Learning through peers 6.95*** (3.45) 3.91 2.91*** (1.01) 3.09

Learning through extension

advisors 5.74*** (2.53) 3.97 3.75*** (1.04) 4.75

Livestock index 1.10** (0.06) 1.87 1.04 (0.04) 1.22

Distance to farm 1.25 (0.32) 0.84 0.96 (0.20) -0.21

Poor soil fertility 1.59* (0.43) 1.72 1.28 (0.25) 1.28

District fixed effects 3.52*** (1.15) 3.87 1.08 (0.26) 0.32

Aware during 2000-05 0.27*** (0.10) -3.63 0.66 (0.19) -1.41

Aware during 2012 2.25*** (0.67) 2.73 4.75*** (1.45) 5.10

Duration dependence

D1 (1 5)t 1.37 (0.91) 0.47 0.37*** (0.13) -2.81

D2 (6 10)t 3.51*** (2.40) 1.84 0.94 (0.32) -0.18

D3 (11 15)t 4.37*** (2.32) 2.77 1.05 (0.39) 0.13

Constant 0.00*** (0.00) -4.84 0.01*** (0.01) -3.95 2 0.00 (25.48) 0.00 (11.47)

LLR -347 -485

AIC 738 1015

BIC 865 1143

n 2339 2594

Page 158: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

146

Page 159: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

147

CHAPTER 6

Conclusions and Policy recommendations

6.1 Summary

The concept of sustainable agricultural intensification (SAI) is receiving increased

attention among researchers and development practitioners across the globe. This is

mainly due to concerns about acute degradation of the environment (both on- and off-

farm), low agricultural productivity, and increased human-health risks associated with

food-borne illnesses. The concept of agricultural sustainability implies a shift towards

practices that can achieve current and future gains in agricultural productivity with less

adverse impact on the environment.

Recognizing that the challenges, opportunities and preferences that underpin the success

of SAI will vary from one region to the other, it is imperative to develop approaches to

support agricultural sustainability under local contexts, accounting for the needs and

conditions of farmer populations. Therefore, the main goal of the thesis was to examine

the viability of SAI technologies. The feasibility of adopting sustainable agricultural

practices was analysed in the context of smallholder farmers in Malawi, a small African

nation in which sustainable intensification has become one of the prominent strategies to

achieve agricultural productivity and thus, improve farmers’ welfare through increased

food supply and farm incomes. Traditionally, restoration of soil fertility was achieved

naturally, through long fallow periods and crop rotations. However, due to growing

population pressure and expansion of farm sizes, the long fallow periods no longer exist

and maize-dominated monoculture and mono-cropping practices are now more common

among smallholder farmers.

Page 160: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

148

This thesis addressed the economic and social feasibility of SAI technologies by

estimating their speed of adoption and the level of productive efficiency. In this way, the

thesis has contributed to the literature by providing practical approaches and indicators

that can be used to evaluate the viability of SAI technologies.

Overall, the study reveals substantial resource-use inefficiencies relating to the way that

farmers currently allocate their factors of production. While small farms are found to be

technically more efficient than large ones (Chapter 2), these farms (small farms) are

relatively more cost inefficient than their larger counterparts (Chapter 4). The difference

could be due to errors in optimisation which show up as higher costs, representing both

technical and allocative inefficiencies as modelled in Chapter 4. It is likely that small

farmers fail to optimise their input choices, given the prevailing market prices.

Furthermore, the study has provided evidence supporting the following conclusions: 1)

independence or complete factor substitution between organic-based soil amendments

(e.g. symbiotic nitrogen) and inorganic fertilisers can be detrimental to farm productivity;

and 2) farmers are reluctant to adopt new technologies unless the performance of such

technologies has already been ascertained by their peers (homophily effect) or until

adequate information about the new technologies is available within the farming

community. The following subsections highlight the specific research objectives

addressed in each of the thesis chapters, empirical methods employed, key findings and

policy implications.

Page 161: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

149

6.1.1 Examining the relationship between farm size and efficiency: a Bayesian

directional distance function approach (Chapter 2)

In this chapter, a Bayesian directional distance function was used to estimate and compare

efficiency scores across three farm classes: small, medium and large farms. The objective

of this chapter was to empirically test the existence/absence of an inverse-productivity

relationship. In the past, non-frontier regression analysis and partial factor productivity

measures have tended to dominate the conclusions drawn on the relationship between

farm size and efficiency. In this study, a Bayesian directional distance function approach

was applied to explicitly model multiple input and multiple output production structure

associated with non-specialised subsistence households, experiencing non-separable

production and consumption decisions. Two macro nutrients (gross energy and protein)

were used as production outputs, representing household potential food supply. The

directional distance function helps to estimate potential reduction (addition) to inputs

(outputs) that is feasible, while using the same technology. The empirical results revealed

that small farms are more efficient than large farms (i.e. evidence supporting the presence

of an inverse productivity relationship). Hence, it is important that resource-poor farmers

operate reasonable farm-sizes that better match the level of their resource endowment. By

implication, farmers may benefit more where conservation and lease markets are well-

functioning. Thus, setting up more effective land lease markets with clearly defined land-

rights could provide a number of benefits such as incentivising landholders to adopt

sustainable land management strategies.

Page 162: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

150

6.1.2 Estimating shadow price for symbiotic nitrogen and technical efficiency for

legume-based conservation agriculture in Malawi (Chapter 3)

This chapter applied a bootstrapped directional input distance function (DIDF) to: 1)

assess the level of technical efficiency associated with the integrated maize-legume

production systems in Malawi; and 2) estimate the shadow price for legume-based

symbiotic nitrogen. A comparison of the estimated technical efficiency for bootstrapped

and non-bootstrapped (base model) directional input distance function showed that the

base model under-estimated technical inefficiency by 10%. Overall, the technical

efficiency results have shown that there is scope to increase food production by

addressing the observed inefficiencies. The shadow pricing approach implemented in this

chapter demonstrated an empirical application founded on production theory—utilizing

the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRS) and the duality between input distance

function and cost function—to value non-marketable goods and services. Using this

approach, shadow prices for symbiotic-nitrogen were estimated, which reflect the trade-

off between fertiliser-nitrogen and symbiotic-nitrogen required to achieve a given

quantity of output. Thus, the shadow price value represents the benefit of using symbiotic

nitrogen as a production input. The estimated shadow prices showed wide variations

across farms and were, on average, higher than the reference price for commercial

nitrogen. In addition, factor substitution between fertiliser-nitrogen and symbiotic-

nitrogen was explored using Morishima elasticity of substitution (MES). The MES

measure showed limited scope of substitution between the two factors. This means that

farmers who wish to completely substitute synthetic fertilizer for symbiotic nitrogen (as

a more sustainable approach to production) may have lower revenues. Thus we need

policy measures to stimulate the use of symbiotic nitrogen such as mechanisms for linking

farmers to high-value markets to earn price premiums for commodities produced from

more sustainably-managed farms.

Page 163: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

151

6.1.3 Cost efficiency among smallholder maize producers in Malawi: to what extent

can regularity conditions reveal estimates biases? (Chapter 4)

This chapter examined the importance of imposing regularity restrictions implied by

economic theory. Theoretical consistency, in terms of monotonicity and concavity

restrictions, were imposed on a translog cost function and data from a sample of

smallholder maize producers in Malawi. The advantage of using a cost function in

assessing farm performance (productive or economic efficiency) is to address

endogeneity problems associated with input variables which are used as regressors in

primal estimation models using production function or distance functions. Two methods

were employed to impose regularity conditions: 1) a two-step nonlinear (quadratic)

optimisation procedure; and 2) the Bayesian approach to constrained parameter

estimation. The estimation results showed that imposing regularity conditions yielded

credible estimates and these estimates were statistically different from those obtained

when the regularity conditions were violated. Thus, imposing regularity conditions

substantially improved monotonicity and curvature as well as efficiency and elasticity

estimates. Furthermore, the results indicate that farmers who operated small farms were

less cost efficient than those operating relatively large farms. In this analysis, cost

efficiency represents both technical and allocative measures of farm performance or

resource-use productivity. The results also show that households with binding borrowing

constraints tended to be more cost efficient.

Page 164: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

152

6.1.4 Information acquisition, learning and the adoption of conservation agriculture

in Malawi: a discrete-time duration analysis (Chapter 5)

In this chapter, factors affecting the speed of adoption of conservation agriculture

technologies were examined using a discrete-time duration (survival) analysis model.

This method is suitable for modelling the occurrence of continuous-time events where

data have been recorded at discrete-time intervals, such as months or years. Such timing

is common for adoption studies targeting agricultural technologies. It was hypothesised

that lack of information related to the performance of conservation agriculture

technologies is the single most important element driving their slow adoption.

Accordingly, the chapter investigated how information exchange and learning could

affect the timing of adoption of conservation agriculture in Malawi, using minimum

tillage and crop residue-retention as examples. Our research finds that social learning

through a network of peers and access to extension advisors facilitated quick adoption of

conservation agriculture technologies. Further, the results showed that farmers who

became aware of the existence of conservation agriculture during years of drought-

hazards were highly likely to adopt these practices. The results have highlighted the need

for strengthening and targeting social networks as conduits for information about new

technologies.

Page 165: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

153

6.2 Policy implications

In most developing countries, the transition from the current state of agricultural

intensification (which is capital intensive and potentially unsustainable) to an alternative

one, which is low-input and sustainable, is restrained by several challenges. For example,

developing countries face acute poverty and unemployment, high levels of population

growth and malnutrition as well as market imperfections. These challenges need to be

overcome through appropriate policy instruments, if agricultural sustainability is to be

realistic and transformative. Thus, policy makers need to devise strategies and incentives

for smallholder farmers to use natural resources judiciously. Accordingly, some of the

policy instruments that could facilitate agricultural sustainability have been highlighted

in the thesis chapters and are summarised in Table 6.1. These policies would enhance

agricultural sustainability through improved efficiency and the adoption of resource-

conserving technologies. For example, the establishment of land rights could facilitate

formal tenancy agreement and land transactions. Farmers need confidence that their land

rights are secure and investments in sustainable management strategies would continue

to yield private returns in the future (see Chapter 2). In addition, linking sustainable

production with high-value markets could facilitate adoption of improved landcare

strategies because farmers are hedged against potential welfare loss that could result from

low productivity associated with resource conserving practices (Chapter 3). Another

policy option to improve efficiency is by linking vulnerable farmers to off-farm

opportunities. This would better position farmers to direct farm resources towards

productivity-enhancing activities and ecosystem-improving practices rather than

diverting farm resources towards non-productive and consumption related activities (see

Chapter 4). Finally, availability of information regarding the performance of new

technologies is vital for hastening the adoption of these technologies. Therefore,

establishing or strengthening effective information exchange among researchers,

Page 166: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

154

extension advisors and farmers could facilitate technology adoption (see Chapter 5). For

effective results, a package of these policies should be implemented concurrently.

Table 6.1: Summary of policies towards achieving agricultural sustainability

Policy goal (intent) Policy strategy

Encourage investment in long-term land-care

technologies

Grant farmers property rights

Introduction of conservation (green) payment

schemes or subsidies

Improve communication and learning Promote farmer-to-farmer learning and

information exchange

Improve delivery of extension services

Protect and secure farmers’ income Provide/link smart subsidies to low-input

sustainable production

Link farmers to high-value markets (e.g.

contract farming) that offer price premiums

for sustainably managed farm produce

Facilitate registration, certification and brand

labelling of sustainably managed (green)

products

Demonstrate the benefits and limitations of

agricultural innovations being developed and

promoted

Develop and promote farmer-researcher

partnerships

Conduct targeted participatory agricultural

research and innovation platforms for farmers

to experience the performance of new

technologies under local environment

Reduce pressure (overexploitation of) on

critical natural resources

Creating off-farm opportunities

Targeting poor and vulnerable households in

safety-nets and public works programs

Page 167: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

155

6.3 Consideration for future research

In this thesis, the economic performance and social acceptability of SAI management

practices has been evaluated. The study focuses on the production-related aspects of these

technologies and—by nature of a PhD study—faced some data limitations. Most

importantly, the available data lacked spatial and temporal variability. Another

opportunity for further data collection is to extend the analysis to other dimensions of

sustainability within the food-supply chain. While the present analysis mainly focussed

on the supply-side of sustainable agricultural production, conducting further analysis on

the demand aspects of SAI technologies could complement the supply-side efforts. The

details and recommendations for future research are described in the next sub-sections.

6.3.1 Use of biophysical data and data which have considerable

variation in spatial and temporal scale

The data used in the analysis was limited to survey data collected in one agro-ecological

zone and at one point in time. This means that the study lacks information pertaining to

spatial and intertemporal variations for both inputs and outputs. In particular, soil quality

indicators were not available for inclusion in the analysis. The realisation of crop yield

and environmental services will depend on the interaction of soil properties (i.e. chemical,

physical and biological properties), which are expected to vary across both spatial and

time scales (Parr et al. 1992; Doran and Parkin 1994; Carter et al. 1997; Smith et al.

2000). Topsoil depth, organic carbon content, soil pH and water retention abilities are

examples of soil attributes that determine the capacity of an agroecosystem to provide

various ecosystem services, such as food provisioning and regulatory functions (Smith et

al. 2000). Therefore, there is a possibility that the estimated measures of farm

performance and shadow prices could be sensitive to heterogeneities in soil quality across

Page 168: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

156

the country. Unfortunately, explicit soil quality data were not available for this study. As

a result, the analysis relied on crop yield as the sole indicator of soil-quality. Generally,

the empirical methods and precision of the estimates could have benefited from other soil-

quality indicators. In addition, the estimated sustainability indicators (i.e. efficiency and

shadow prices) are based on a relatively limited spatial scale (2 out of 28 districts in the

country) and are cross-sectional, which does not account for time. It would be interesting

to capture countrywide and year-to-year variability thereby accounting for diverse

changes in environmental conditions. A dynamic economic model would be ideal to

assess substitution possibilities within and across soil attributes and management

variables (Scoones and Toulmin 1998; Smith et al. 2000).

Furthermore, there is a need for an extended analysis of soil nutrient dynamics, preferably

by adopting a nutrient balance approach across various farming systems (Scoones and

Toulmin 1998; Henao and Baanante 1999; Sheldrick et al. 2002; Cobo et al. 2010). This

approach could establish the status of nutrient mining/depletion or accumulation by

comparing the amount of nutrients exported through crop and livestock uptake against

the amount of nutrients applied to the soil for different spatial scales and farming systems.

Soil-nutrient audits/budget have to account for losses (mainly through crop/livestock

uptake, leaching, erosion and volatilisation) and gains arising from fertiliser application

(both chemical and organic fertilisers) and other sources of nutrient deposits, which

include symbiotic nitrogen fixation and root sloughing (Sheldrick et al. 2002; Herridge

et al. 2008). There have been mixed findings in terms of both positive and negative

nutrient balances having been reported for major staple crops cultivated in Malawi and

across Africa (Scoones and Toulmin 1998; Mafongoya et al. 2006; Adu-Gyamfi et al.

2007; Yusuf et al. 2009; Cobo et al. 2010). Evidently, the methods demonstrated in this

thesis can be extended to compute shadow prices for multiple nutrients (nitrogen,

Page 169: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

157

phosphorous and potassium) and thus determine the total cost of nutrient mining or

restitution associated with specific land uses and farming systems.

6.3.2 Need for studies to examine the demand (consumer) side of

sustainability

This study was conceptualised to examine the supply-side of sustainability and,

consequently, it did not evaluate the demand factors that could impact agricultural

sustainability, such as consumers’ willingness to pay for agricultural commodities

produced from sustainably managed (i.e. low external input) farms. Future research could

establish the demand and market opportunities for organic produce. It is the demand for

such commodities that will generate compensatory benefits and therefore drive the

profitability and expansion/scaling-up of agricultural sustainability (Tittonell 2014).

However, as indicated above, this study did not collect or source data on the performance

of the other sub-sectors along the food supply chain. Besides the supply side constraints,

such as soil degradation, farmers face a number of post-harvest constraints that lead to

substantial post-harvest food losses. For example, the extent of post-harvest losses is

reported to be in the range of 20-40% for cereals in Africa (Zorya et al. 2011; Tefera

2012; Abass et al. 2014; Affognon et al. 2015) and between 10% and 50% for different

food commodities across the globe (Boxall 2001; Parfitt et al. 2010; Gustavsson et al.

2011). Thus, efficiency gains achieved through sustainable production ought to be

maintained throughout the food value chain; otherwise, the bottlenecks experienced in

the post-production sectors could limit the efforts and tenets of sustainable food supply.

For example, post-harvest losses need to be reduced (e.g. through food-processing and

preservation) to optimise the efficiency gains achieved in food production. New research

could consider this avenue and investigate the synergies between sustainable food supply

Page 170: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

158

and sustainable food utilisation. Such studies could complement the production-side

analysis undertaken in this thesis.

Page 171: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

159

References

Abass, A.B., Ndunguru, G., Mamiro, P., Alenkhe, B., Mlingi, N. and Bekunda, M. 2014.

Post-harvest food losses in a maize-based farming system of semi-arid savannah

area of Tanzania, Journal of Stored Products Research 57, 49-57.

Abdulai, A., Huffman, W.E., 2005. The diffusion of new agricultural technologies: The

case of crossbred-cow technology in Tanzania. American Journal of Agricultural

Economics 87, 645-659.

Abdulai, A.N. and Abdulai, A. 2016. Allocative and scale efficiency among maize

farmers in Zambia: a zero efficiency stochastic frontier approach, Applied

Economics 48, 5364-5378.

Adesina, A.A. and Djato, K.K. 1996. Farm size, relative efficiency and agrarian policy in

Cote d'Ivoire: profit function analysis of rice farms Agricultural Economics 14,

93-102.

Adesina, A. A. and Djato, K. K. 1997. Relative efficiency of women as farm managers:

Profit function analysis in Côte d'Ivoire. Agricultural Economics, 16, 47-53.

Adu-Gyamfi, J.J., Myaka, F.A., Sakala, W.D., Odgaard, R., Vesterager, J.M. and Høgh-

Jensen, H. 2007. Biological nitrogen fixation and nitrogen and phosphorus

budgets in farmer-managed intercrops of maize–pigeonpea in semi-arid southern

and eastern Africa, Plant and Soil 295, 127-136.

Affognon, H., Mutungi, C., Sanginga, P. and Borgemeister, C. 2015. Unpacking

postharvest losses in sub-Saharan Africa: A meta-analysis, World development

66, 49-68.

Aigner, D.J. and Chu, S.F. 1968. On estimating the industry production function, The

American Economic Review 58, 826-839.

Alene, A.D. 2010. Productivity growth and the effects of R&D in African agriculture,

Agricultural Economics 41, 223-238.

Ali, D.A., Deininger, K. and Duponchel, M. 2014. Credit constraints and agricultural

productivity: evidence from rural Rwanda, Journal of Development Studies 50,

649-665.

Allison, P.D. 1978. Measures of inequality, American sociological review865-880.

An, H., Butler, L.J., 2012. A Discrete‐Time Duration Analysis of Technology

Disadoption: The Case of rbST in California. Canadian Journal of Agricultural

Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie 60, 495-515.

Page 172: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

160

Andersson, J.A., D'Souza, S., 2014. From adoption claims to understanding farmers and

contexts: A literature review of Conservation Agriculture (CA) adoption among

smallholder farmers in southern Africa. Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment

187, 116-132.

Arndt, C., Schlosser, A., Strzepek, K. and Thurlow, J. 2014. Climate change and

economic growth prospects for Malawi: An uncertainty approach, Journal of

African Economies 23, ii83-ii107.

Asafu-Adjaye, J. 2014. The economic impacts of climate change on agriculture in Africa,

Journal of African Economies 23, ii17-ii49.

Ayuya, O.I., Gido, E.O., Bett, H.K., Lagat, J.K., Kahi, A.K. and Bauer, S., 2015. Effect

of certified organic production systems on poverty among smallholder farmers:

Empirical evidence from Kenya. World Development, 67, pp.27-37.

Barbier, E. B. 1994. Valuing environmental functions: tropical wetlands. Land

economics: 155-73.

Barbier, E.B. 1987. The concept of sustainable economic development, Environmental

conservation 14, 101-110.

Barbier, E.B. 2016. Sustainability and development, Annual Review of Resource

Economics 8, 261-280.

Barnett, W.A. and Pasupathy, M. 2003. Regularity of the generalized quadratic

production model: A counterexample, Econometric Reviews 22, 135-154.

Barrett, C.B., Bellemare, M.F. and Hou, J.Y. 2010. Reconsidering Conventional

Explanations of the Inverse Productivity–Size Relationship, World Development

38, 88-97.

Bationo, A., Hartemink, A., Lungu, O., Naimi, M., Okoth, P., Smaling, E., Thiombiano,

L. and Waswa, B. 2012. Knowing the African soils to improve fertiliser

recommendations, Improving soil fertility recommendations in Africa using the

decision support system for agrotechnology transfer (DSSAT). Springer, pp 19-

42.

Baumgartner, W., Weiß, P. and Schindler, H. 1998. A nonparametric test for the general

two-sample problem, Biometrics1129-1135.

Beatty, T.K.M. 2007. Recovering the shadow value of nutrients, American Journal of

Agricultural Economics 89, 52-62.

Beedy, T.L., Ajayi, O.C., Sileshi, G.W., Kundhlande, G., Chiundu, G. and Simons, A.J.

2013. Scaling up agroforestry to achieve food security and environmental

Page 173: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

161

protection among smallholder farmers in Malawi, Field Actions Science Reports.

The journal of field actions.

Benin, S., Ahmed, M., Pender, J. and Ehui, S. 2005. Development of Land Rental Markets

and Agricultural Productivity Growth: The Case of Northern Ethiopia, Journal of

African Economies 14, 21-54.

Benson, T. 1997. Area-specific fertilizer recommendations for hybrid maize grown by

Malawian smallholders: a manual for agricultural extension personnel.

Department of Agricultural Research and Technical Services, Ministry of

Agriculture and Irrigation, Lilongwe, Malawi.

Berkhout, E.D., Schipper, R.A., Kuyvenhoven, A. and Coulibaly, O. 2010. Does

heterogeneity in goals and preferences affect efficiency? A case study of farm

households in northern Nigeria, Agricultural Economics 41, 265-273.

Besley, T., Case, A.C.F.p.d.M., 1993. Modeling Technology Adoption in Developing

Countries. The American Economic Review 83, 396-402.

Beyene, A.D., Kassie, M., 2015. Speed of adoption of improved maize varieties in

Tanzania: An application of duration analysis. Technological Forecasting and

Social Change.

Binswanger, H.P., Deininger, K. and Feder, G. 1995. Chapter 42 Power, distortions,

revolt and reform in agricultural land relations. in Jere, B. and Srinivasan, T.N.

(eds.), Handbook of Development Economics. Elsevier, pp 2659-2772.

Blackorby, C. and Russell, R. 1989. Will the Real Elasticity of Substitution Please Stand

Up?, American Economic Review 79, 882-888.

Böhringer, C. and Jochem, P.E.P. 2007. Measuring the immeasurable—A survey of

sustainability indices, Ecological economics 63, 1-8.

Bojö, J.P. 1991. Economics and land degradation, Ambio75-79.

Bolwig, S., Gibbon, P. and Jones, S., 2009. The economics of smallholder organic

contract farming in tropical Africa. World Development, 37(6), pp.1094-1104.

Bond, C.A. and Farzin, Y.H. 2007. Estimating Agricultural Pollution Abatement Costs at

the Plot Level Using Experimental Data: A Maximum Entropy Approach, Journal

of Agricultural and Resource Economics 32, 273-290.

Bontemps, C., Bouamra-Mechemache, Z., Simioni, M., 2012. Quality labels and firm

survival: some first empirical evidence. European Review of Agricultural

Economics.

Page 174: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

162

Bostian, M.B. and Herlihy, A.T. 2014. Valuing tradeoffs between agricultural production

and wetland condition in the U.S. Mid-Atlantic region, Ecological Economics

105, 284-291.

Boucher, S.R., Guirkinger, C. and Trivelli, C. 2009. Direct elicitation of credit

constraints: Conceptual and practical issues with an application to Peruvian

agriculture, Economic Development and Cultural Change 57, 609-640.

Boxall, R.A. 2001. Post-harvest losses to insects—a world overview, International

Biodeterioration & Biodegradation 48, 137-152.

Box-Steffensmeier, J.M., Jones, B.S., 2004. Event history modeling: A guide for social

scientists. Cambridge University Press.

Bravo-Ureta, B., Solís, D., Moreira López, V., Maripani, J., Thiam, A. and Rivas, T. 2007.

Technical efficiency in farming: a meta-regression analysis, Journal of

Productivity Analysis 27, 57-72.

Bravo-Ureta, B.E. and Pinheiro, A.E. 1993. Efficiency Analysis of Developing Country

Agriculture: A Review of the Frontier Function Literature, ARER88-101.

Brooks, S.P. and Gelman, A. 1998. General methods for monitoring convergence of

iterative simulations, Journal of computational and graphical statistics 7, 434-

455.

Bundervoet, T., 2010. Assets, activity choices, and civil war: evidence from Burundi.

World Development 38, 955-965.

Burton, M., Rigby, D., Young, T., 2003. Modelling the adoption of organic horticultural

technology in the UK using Duration Analysis. Australian Journal of Agricultural

and Resource Economics 47, 29-54.

Callens, I. and Tyteca, D. 1999. Towards indicators of sustainable development for firms:

a productive efficiency perspective, Ecological economics 28, 41-53.

Cameron, A.C., Miller, D.L., 2015. A practitioner’s guide to cluster-robust inference.

Journal of Human Resources 50, 317-372.

Canty A., and Ripley, B. 2015. boot: Bootstrap R (S-Plus) Functions. R package version

1.3-13.

Canty, A.J. 2002. Resampling methods in R: the boot package, R News 2, 2-7.

Carletto, C., Savastano, S. and Zezza, A. 2013. Fact or artifact: The impact of

measurement errors on the farm size–productivity relationship, Journal of

Development Economics 103, 254-261.

Page 175: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

163

Carter, M.R., Gregorich, E.G., Anderson, D.W., Doran, J.W., Janzen, H.H. and Pierce,

F.J. 1997. Chapter 1 Concepts of soil quality and their significance, Developments

in Soil Science 25, 1-19.

Caves, D. W., Christensen, L. R. and Diewert, W. E. 1982. Multilateral comparisons of

output, input, and productivity using superlative index numbers. The economic

journal, 92, 73-86.

Chambers, R. G., Chung, Y., and Färe, R. 1996. Benefit and distance functions. Journal

of economic theory, 70(2): 407-19.

Chianu, J., Huising, J., Danso, S., Okoth, P.F. and Sanginga, N. 2011. Economic

Evaluation of the Contribution of Below-Ground Biodiversity: Case Study of

Biological Nitrogen Fixation by Rhizobia. in Bationo, A., Waswa, B., Okeyo,

J.M., Maina, F. and Kihara, J.M. (eds.), Innovations as Key to the Green

Revolution in Africa. Springer Netherlands, pp 1043-1053.

Cobo, J.G., Dercon, G. and Cadisch, G. 2010. Nutrient balances in African land use

systems across different spatial scales: a review of approaches, challenges and

progress, Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment 136, 1-15.

Coelli, T. and Fleming, E. 2004. Diversification economies and specialisation efficiencies

in a mixed food and coffee smallholder farming system in Papua New Guinea,

Agricultural Economics 31, 229-239.

Coelli, T. and Perelman, S. 2000. Technical efficiency of European railways: a distance

function approach, Applied Economics 32, 1967-1976.

Coelli, T. and Perelman, S. 1999. A comparison of parametric and non-parametric

distance functions: With application to European railways, European Journal of

Operational Research 117, 326-339.

Coelli, T.J., Rao, D.S.P., O'Donnell, C.J. and Battese, G.E. 2005. An introduction to

efficiency and productivity analysis. Springer Science & Business Media.

Common, M. and Perrings, C. 1992. Towards an ecological economics of sustainability,

Ecological economics 6, 7-34.

Crawford, E.W., Jayne, T.S. and Kelly, V.A. 2006. Alternative approaches for promoting

fertilizer use in Africa. The World Bank, Washington DC.

Daly, H.E. 1990. Sustainable development: from concept and theory to operational

principles, Population and development review 16, 25-43.

De Koeijer, T.J., Wossink, G.A.A., Struik, P.C. and Renkema, J.A. 2002. Measuring

agricultural sustainability in terms of efficiency: the case of Dutch sugar beet

growers, Journal of environmental management 66, 9-17.

Page 176: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

164

Deere, C.D. and de Janvry, A. 1981. Demographic and social differentiation among

Northern Peruvian peasants, The Journal of Peasant Studies 8, 335-366.

D'Emden, F.H., Llewellyn, R.S., Burton, M.P., 2006. Adoption of conservation tillage in

Australian cropping regions: an application of duration analysis. Technological

Forecasting and Social Change 73, 630-647.

Dervaux, B., Ferrier, G.D., Leleu, H. and Valdmanis, V. 2004. Comparing French and

US hospital technologies: a directional input distance function approach, Applied

Economics 36, 1065-1081.

Devereux, S., 2007. The impact of droughts and floods on food security and policy

options to alleviate negative effects. Agricultural Economics 37, 47-58.

Di Falco, S., Veronesi, M. and Yesuf, M. 2011. Does adaptation to climate change

provide food security? A micro-perspective from Ethiopia, American Journal of

Agricultural Economics 93, 825-842.

Diewert, W.E. and Wales, T.J. 1987. Flexible Functional Forms and Global Curvature

Conditions, Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society43-68.

Dixit, A.K., Pindyck, R.S., 1994. Investment under uncertainty. Princeton university

press.

Döbereiner, J. 1997. Biological nitrogen fixation in the tropics: Social and economic

contributions, Soil Biology and Biochemistry 29, 771-774.

Doran, J.W. and Parkin, T.B. 1994. Defining and Assessing Soil Quality. in Doran, J.W.,

Coleman, D.C., Bezdicek, D.F. and Stewart, B.A. (eds.), Defining Soil Quality for

a Sustainable Environment. Soil Science Society of America and American

Society of Agronomy, Madison, WI, pp 1-21.

Dorward, A. 1999. Farm size and productivity in Malawian smallholder agriculture, The

Journal of Development Studies 35, 141-161.

Ehui, S. and Pender, J. 2005. Resource degradation, low agricultural productivity, and

poverty in sub‐Saharan Africa: pathways out of the spiral, Agricultural Economics

32, 225-242.

Ekins, P., Simon, S., Deutsch, L., Folke, C. and De Groot, R. 2003. A framework for the

practical application of the concepts of critical natural capital and strong

sustainability, Ecological economics 44, 165-185.

Erenstein, O. 2006. Intensification or extensification? Factors affecting technology use in

peri-urban lowlands along an agro-ecological gradient in West Africa,

Agricultural Systems 90, 132-158.

Page 177: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

165

FAO 2001. Food balance sheets: A handbook. Food and Agriculture Organization of the

United Nations Rome.

FAO 2017. Nutritive factors. Food and Agricultural Organization, Rome.

Farsi, M., Filippini, M. and Kuenzle, M. 2005. Unobserved heterogeneity in stochastic

cost frontier models: an application to Swiss nursing homes. Applied Economics,

37, 2127-2141.

Färe, R. and Grosskopf, S. 2000. Theory and application of directional distance functions,

Journal of Productivity Analysis 13, 93-103.

Färe, R. and Grosskopf, S. 2004. New directions: efficiency and productivity. Springer

Science & Business Media.

Fare, R. and Primont, D. 2006. Directional duality theory Directional duality theory,

Economic Theory 29, 239-247.

Färe, R. and Vardanyan, M. 2016. A note on parameterizing input distance functions:

does the choice of a functional form matter?, Journal of Productivity Analysis 45,

121-130.

Färe, R., Grosskopf, S. and Margaritis, D. 2008. Efficiency and Productivity: Malmquist

and More. in Fried, H.O., Knox Lovell, C.A. and Schmidt, S.S. (eds.), The

Measurement of Productive Efficiency and Productivity Change Oxford

University Press, pp 522-623.

Färe, R., Grosskopf, S. and Weber, W.L. 2001. Shadow Prices of Missouri Public

Conservation Land, Public Finance Review 29, 444-460.

Färe, R., Grosskopf, S. and Weber, W.L. 2006. Shadow prices and pollution costs in US

agriculture, Ecological Economics 56, 89-103.

Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., Lovell, C.A.K. and Yaisawarng, S. 1993. Derivation of shadow

prices for undesirable outputs: a distance function approach, The review of

economics and statistics374-380.

Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., Roland, B.E. and Weber, W.L. 2009. License fees: The case of

Norwegian salmon farming, Aquaculture Economics & Management 13, 1-21.

Färe, R., Martins-Filho, C. and Vardanyan, M. 2010. On functional form representation

of multi-output production technologies, Journal of Productivity Analysis 33, 81-

96.

Färe, R., Pasurka, C. and Vardanyan, M. 2017. On endogenizing direction vectors in

parametric directional distance function-based models, European Journal of

Operational Research 262, 361-369.

Farooq, M. and Siddique, K.H.M. 2015. Conservation agriculture. Springer.

Page 178: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

166

Feng, G. and Serletis, A. 2010. Efficiency, technical change, and returns to scale in large

US banks: Panel data evidence from an output distance function satisfying

theoretical regularity, Journal of Banking & Finance 34, 127-138.

Fernández, C., Koop, G. and Steel, M. 2000. A Bayesian analysis of multiple-output

production frontiers, Journal of Econometrics 98, 47-79.

Fernández, C., Osiewalski, J. and Steel, M.F.J. 1997. On the use of panel data in stochastic

frontier models with improper priors, Journal of Econometrics 79, 169-193.

Ferraro, P.J. and Kiss, A. 2002. Direct payments to conserve biodiversity, Science 298,

1718-1719.

Ferrier, G.D. and Lovell, C.K. 1990 Measuring cost efficiency in banking: econometric

and linear programming evidence, Journal of Econometrics 46, 229-245.

Fletschner, D. 2008. Women's access to credit: does it matter for household efficiency?,

American Journal of Agricultural Economics 90, 669-683.

Fletschner, D., Guirkinger, C. and Boucher, S. 2010. Risk, credit constraints and financial

efficiency in Peruvian agriculture, The Journal of Development Studies 46, 981-

1002.

Foster, A.D., Rosenzweig, M.R., 2010. Microeconomics of technology adoption. Annual

Review of Economics 2, 395-424.

Fox, G. and Kivanda, L. 1994. Popper or production. Canadian Journal of Agricultural

Economics 42(1):1-13

Foy, G. 1990. Economic sustainability and the preservation of environmental assets,

Environmental Management 14, 771-778.

Frank, M.D., Beattie, B.R. and Embleton, M.E. 1990. A Comparison of Alternative Crop

Response Models, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72, 597-603.

Fuglie, K.O., Kascak, C.A., 2001. Adoption and diffusion of natural-resource-conserving

agricultural technology. Review of Agricultural Economics 23, 386-403.

Garnett, T., Appleby, M.C., Balmford, A., Bateman, I.J., Benton, T.G., Bloomer, P.,

Burlingame, B., Dawkins, M., Dolan, L. and Fraser, D. 2013. Sustainable

intensification in agriculture: premises and policies, Science 341, 33-34.

Gelman, A. and Shirley, K. 2011. Inference from simulations and monitoring

convergence, Handbook of markov chain monte carlo163-174.

Genius, M., Koundouri, P., Nauges, C., Tzouvelekas, V., 2014. Information transmission

in irrigation technology adoption and diffusion: social learning, extension services,

and spatial effects. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 96 (1): 328-344.

Page 179: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

167

Ghadim, A.K.A., Pannell, D.J., Burton, M.P., 2005. Risk, uncertainty, and learning in

adoption of a crop innovation. Agricultural Economics 33, 1-9.

Gilks, W.R., Thomas, A. and Spiegelhalter, D.J. 1994. A language and program for

complex Bayesian modelling, The Statistician169-177.

Giller, K.E., Witter, E., Corbeels, M. and Tittonell, P. 2009. Conservation agriculture and

smallholder farming in Africa: the heretics’ view, Field crops research 114, 23-

34.

Gomes, E.G., e Souza, G.d.S., Meza, L.A. and de Carvalho Mangabeira, J.A. 2009.

Efficiency and sustainability assessment for a group of farmers in the Brazilian

Amazon, Annals of Operations Research 169, 167.

Goncharova, N., Oskam, A., Oude Lansink, A., Van Der Vlist, A., Verstegen, J., 2008.

Investment spikes in Dutch greenhouse horticulture. Journal of Agricultural

Economics 59, 516-536.

Greene, W.H. 2008. The econometric approach to efficiency analysis. in Fried, H.O.,

Knox Lovell, C.A. and Schmidt, S.S. (eds.), The Measurement of Productive

Efficiency and Productivity Change Oxford University Press, pp 92-250.

Griffin, J.E. and Steel, M.F. 2007. Bayesian stochastic frontier analysis using WinBUGS,

Journal of Productivity Analysis 27, 163-176.

Griffiths, W.E. 1988. Bayesian econometrics and how to get rid of those wrong signs,

Review of Marketing and Agricultural Economics 56, 36-56.

Griffiths, W.E., O’Donnell, C.J. and Cruz, A.T. 2000. Imposing regularity conditions on

a system of cost and factor share equations, Australian Journal of Agricultural

and Resource Economics 44, 107-127.

Grosskopf, S., Hayes, K. and Hirschberg, J. 1995. Fiscal stress and the production of

public safety: a distance function approach, Journal of Public Economics 57, 277-

296.

Gunton, R.M., Firbank, L.G., Inman, A. and Winter, D.M. 2016. How scalable is

sustainable intensification?, Nature plants 2, 16065.

Gustavsson, J., Cederberg, C., Sonesson, U., Van Otterdijk, R. and Meybeck, A. 2011.

Global food losses and food waste, Food and Agriculture Organization of the

United Nations, Rome, (Serial online). Available from URL:

http://www.fao.org/docrep/014/mb060e/mb060e00.pdf [accessed 01/05/2017].

Gutés, M.C. 1996. The concept of weak sustainability, Ecological economics 17, 147-

156.

Page 180: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

168

Hailu, A. 2013. A package for productivity and efficiency analysis in R (apear).

http://ahailu.are.uwa.edu.au.

Hailu, A. and Chambers, R. 2012. A Luenberger soil-quality indicator, Journal of

Productivity Analysis 38, 145-154.

Hailu, A. and Veeman, T.S. 2000. Environmentally Sensitive Productivity Analysis of

the Canadian Pulp and Paper Industry, 1959-1994: An Input Distance Function

Approach, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 40, 251-274.

Hajargasht, G., Coelli, T. and Rao, D.S.P. 2008. A dual measure of economies of scope,

Economics Letters 100, 185-188.

Haji, J. 2007. Production efficiency of smallholders' vegetable-dominated mixed farming

system in eastern Ethiopia: A non-parametric approach, Journal of African

Economies 16, 1-27.

Hanley, N. 2000. Macroeconomic measures of ‘sustainability’, Journal of economic

surveys 14, 1-30.

Harrigan, J., 2008. Food insecurity, poverty and the Malawian Starter Pack: Fresh start

or false start? Food Policy 33, 237-249.

Harrington, L.W. 1992. Measuring sustainability: issues and alternatives. Journal for

Farming Systems Research Extension, 3 (1): 1-20

Hartwick, J.M. 1977. Intergenerational equity and the investing of rents from exhaustible

resources, The american economic review 67, 972-974.

Hazarika, G. and Alwang, J. 2003. Access to credit, plot size and cost inefficiency among

smallholder tobacco cultivators in Malawi, Agricultural Economics 29, 99-109.

Headey, D., Alauddin, M. and Rao, D. 2010. Explaining agricultural productivity growth:

an international perspective, Agricultural Economics 41, 1-14.

Helfand, S.M. and Levine, E.S. 2004. Farm size and the determinants of productive

efficiency in the Brazilian Center-West, Agricultural Economics 31, 241-249.

Heltberg, R. 1998. Rural market imperfections and the farm size— productivity

relationship: Evidence from Pakistan, World Development 26, 1807-1826.

Henao, J. and Baanante, C. 2006. Agricultural production and soil nutrient mining in

Africa: implications for resource conservation and policy development. IFDC-An

International Center for Soil Fertility and Agricultural Development.

Henao, J. and Baanante, C.A. 1999. Estimating rates of nutrient depletion in soils of

agricultural lands of Africa. International Fertiliser Development Centre (IFDC)

Technical Bulletin T48. Muscle Shoals, Alabama, USA.

Page 181: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

169

Henningsen, A. 2014. Introduction to econometric production analysis with R (Draft

Version), Date accessed: December 15, 2014.

Henningsen, A. and Henning, C.H. 2009. Imposing regional monotonicity on translog

stochastic production frontiers with a simple three-step procedure, Journal of

Productivity Analysis 32, 217.

Herridge, D., Peoples, M. and Boddey, R. 2008. Global inputs of biological nitrogen

fixation in agricultural systems, Plant and Soil 311, 1-18.

Høgh-Jensen, H., Loges, R., Jørgensen, F.V., Vinther, F.P. and Jensen, E.S. 2004. An

empirical model for quantification of symbiotic nitrogen fixation in grass-clover

mixtures, Agricultural Systems 82, 181-194.

Holden, S.T., Deininger, K. and Ghebru, H. 2009. Impacts of Low-Cost Land

Certification on Investment and Productivity, American Journal of Agricultural

Economics 91, 359-373.

Hou, L., Hoag, D.L.K. and Keske, C.M.H. 2015. Abatement costs of soil conservation in

China's Loess Plateau: Balancing income with conservation in an agricultural

system, Journal of Environmental Management 149, 1-8.

Huang, K.S. 1996. Nutrient elasticities in a complete food demand system, American

Journal of Agricultural Economics 78, 21-29.

Huang, K.S. 1996. Nutrient elasticities in a complete food demand system, American

Journal of Agricultural Economics 78, 21-29.

Ito, M., Matsumoto, T., Quinones, M.A., 2007. Conservation tillage practice in sub-

Saharan Africa: The experience of Sasakawa Global 2000. Crop Protection 26, 417-

423.

Jacobson, A., Milman, A.D. and Kammen, D.M. 2005. Letting the (energy) Gini out of

the bottle: Lorenz curves of cumulative electricity consumption and Gini

coefficients as metrics of energy distribution and equity, Energy Policy 33, 1825-

1832.

Janvry, A.d., Fafchamps, M. and Sadoulet, E. 1991. Peasant Household Behaviour with

Missing Markets: Some Paradoxes Explained, The Economic Journal 101, 1400-

1417.

Jayne, T.S., Govereh, J., Wanzala, M. and Demeke, M. 2003. Fertilizer market

development: a comparative analysis of Ethiopia, Kenya, and Zambia, Food

Policy 28, 293-316.

Jenkins, S.P., 1995. Easy estimation methods for discrete‐time duration models. Oxford

bulletin of economics and statistics 57, 129-136.

Page 182: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

170

Jenkins, S.P., 2005. Survival analysis. Unpublished manuscript, Institute for Social and

Economic Research, University of Essex, Colchester, UK.

Jensen, E., Peoples, M., Boddey, R., Gresshoff, P., Hauggaard-Nielsen, H., J.R. Alves,

B. and Morrison, M. 2012. Legumes for mitigation of climate change and the

provision of feedstock for biofuels and biorefineries. A review, Agronomy for

Sustainable Development 32, 329-364.

Jones, A.D., Shrinivas, A. and Bezner-Kerr, R. 2014. Farm production diversity is

associated with greater household dietary diversity in Malawi: findings from

nationally representative data, Food Policy 46, 1-12.

Jones, P.G. and Thornton, P.K. 2003. The potential impacts of climate change on maize

production in Africa and Latin America in 2055, Global environmental change

13, 51-59.

Judge, G.G., Griffiths, W.E., Hill, R.C., Lütkepohl, H. and Lee, T.C. 1985. The Theory

and Practice of Econometrics, 2E. New York, NY: John Wiley and Sons.

Kagin, J., Taylor J.E. and Yúnez-Naude, A. 2016. Inverse Productivity or Inverse

Efficiency? Evidence from Mexico. The Journal of Development Studies 52:3,

396-411.

Kalaitzandonakes, N.G., Wu, S. and Ma, J.C. 1992. The Relationship between Techinical

Efficiency and Firm Size Revisited, Canadian Journal of Agricultural

Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie 40, 427-442.

Karagiannis, G., Midmore, P. and Tzouvelekas, V. 2004. Parametric decomposition of

output growth using a stochastic input distance function, American Journal of

Agricultural Economics 86, 1044-1057.

Karagiannis, G. and Sarris, A. 2005. Measuring and explaining scale efficiency with the

parametric approach: the case of Greek tobacco growers, Agricultural Economics

33, 441-451.

Karagiannis, G., Tzouvelekas, V. and Xepapadeas, A. 2003. Measuring Irrigation Water

Efficiency with a Stochastic Production Frontier, Environmental and Resource

Economics 26, 57-72.

Kassie, M., Shiferaw, B. and Muricho, G. 2011. Agricultural technology, crop income,

and poverty alleviation in Uganda, World Development 39, 1784-1795.

Kelly, V.A. 2006. Factors affecting demand for fertilizer in Sub-Saharan Africa,

Agriculture and rural development discussion paper, (Serial online),

23(Available from URL.

Page 183: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

171

Khataza, R.R.B., Hailu, A., Kragt, M.E. and Doole, G.J. 2017. Estimating shadow price

for symbiotic nitrogen and technical efficiency for legume-based conservation

agriculture in Malawi, Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource

Economics 61, 462-480.

Kiefer, N.M., 1988. Economic duration data and hazard functions. Journal of economic

literature, 646-679.

Kilic, T., Palacios-Lopez, A. and Goldstein, M. 2015. Caught in a productivity trap: a

distributional perspective on gender differences in Malawian agriculture, World

Development 70, 416-463.

Kleemann, L. and Abdulai, A., 2013. Organic certification, agro-ecological practices and

return on investment: Evidence from pineapple producers in Ghana. Ecological

Economics, 93, pp.330-341.

Kleit, A.N. and Terrell, D. 2001. Measuring potential efficiency gains from deregulation

of electricity generation: a Bayesian approach, Review of Economics and Statistics

83, 523-530.

Knowler, D., Bradshaw, B., 2007. Farmers’ adoption of conservation agriculture: A

review and synthesis of recent research. Food policy 32, 25-48.

Koebel, B., Falk, M. and Laisney, F. 2003. Imposing and testing curvature conditions on

a Box–Cox cost function, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 21, 319-335.

Koppmair, S., Kassie, M. and Qaim, M. 2017. Farm production, market access and dietary

diversity in Malawi, Public Health Nutrition 20, 325-335.

Krishnan, P., Patnam, M., 2014. Neighbors and extension agents in Ethiopia: Who

matters more for technology adoption? American Journal of Agricultural

Economics 96, 308-327.

Kumbhakar, S.C. and Lovell, C.A.K. 2003. Stochastic frontier analysis. Cambridge

university press.

Kumbhakar, S.C., Wang, H. and Horncastle, A.P. 2015. A practitioner's guide to

stochastic frontier analysis using Stata. Cambridge University Press.

Kuosmanen, T. and Kuosmanen, N. 2009. How not to measure sustainable value (and

how one might), Ecological economics 69, 235-243.

Lankoski, J., Ollikainen, M., and Uusitalo, P. 2006. “No-till technology: benefits to farmers and

the environment? Theoretical analysis and application to Finnish agriculture.” European

Review of Agricultural Economics 33(2): 193-221.

Page 184: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

172

Latruffe, L. and Nauges, C. 2014. Technical efficiency and conversion to organic

farming: the case of France, European Review of Agricultural Economics, 41(2):

227-253.

Lee, D.R. 2005. Agricultural sustainability and technology adoption: Issues and policies

for developing countries, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 87, 1325-

1334.

Lele, S.M. 1991. Sustainable development: a critical review, World development 19, 607-

621.

Luedeling, E., Sileshi, G., Beedy, T. and Dietz, J. 2011. Carbon sequestration potential

of agroforestry systems in Africa, Carbon Sequestration Potential of Agroforestry

Systems. Springer, pp 61-83.

Maertens, A., Barrett, C.B., 2013. Measuring Social Networks' Effects on Agricultural

Technology Adoption. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 95, 353-359.

Mafongoya, P.L., Bationo, A., Kihara, J. and Waswa, B.S. 2007. Appropriate

technologies to replenish soil fertility in southern Africa. in Bationo, A., Waswa,

B., Kihara, J. and Kimetu, J. (eds.), Advances in Integrated Soil Fertility

Management in sub-Saharan Africa: Challenges and Opportunities. Springer

Netherlands, pp 29-43.

Maganga, A.M., Abdi-Khalil, E. and Matchaya, G.C. 2013. Cost efficiency, Morishima,

Allen-Uzawa and cross-price elasticities among Irish potato farmers in Dedza

District, Malawi.

Magnan, N., Larson, D.M. and Taylor, J.E. 2012. Stuck on Stubble? The Non-market

Value of Agricultural Byproducts for Diversified Farmers in Morocco, American

Journal of Agricultural Economics, 94(5): 1055-1069

Manda, J., Alene, A.D., Gardebroek, C., Kassie, M., Tembo, G., 2016. Adoption and

Impacts of Sustainable Agricultural Practices on Maize Yields and Incomes:

Evidence from Rural Zambia. Journal of Agricultural Economics 67, 130-153.

Marenya, P.P., Barrett, C.B., 2007. Household-level determinants of adoption of

improved natural resources management practices among smallholder farmers in

western Kenya. Food Policy 32, 515-536.

Marongwe, L.S., Kwazira, K., Jenrich, M., Thierfelder, C., Kassam, A. and Friedrich, T.

2011. An African success: the case of conservation agriculture in Zimbabwe,

International Journal of Agricultural Sustainability 9, 153-161.

Page 185: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

173

Mason, D.R. 2014. Who gets what? Determinants of loan size and credit rationing among

microcredit borrowers: evidence from Nicaragua, Journal of International

Development 26, 77-90.

Mayen, C.D., Balagtas, J.V. and Alexander, C.E. 2010. Technology adoption and

technical efficiency: organic and conventional dairy farms in the United States,

American Journal of Agricultural Economics 92, 181-195.

Mloza-Banda, H.R., 2003. Development and application of conservation agriculture in

Malawi’s smallholder subsistence and commercial farming systems. Proceedings

of Workshop on Conservation Farming for Sustainable Agriculture: 20-24 October

2002.

Mochebelele, M.T. and Winter-Nelson, A. 2000. Migrant labor and farm technical

efficiency in Lesotho, World Development 28, 143-153.

Monyo, E.S. and Laxmipathi, G.C. 2014. Grain Legumes Strategies and Seed Roadmaps

for Select Countries in Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia. International Crops

Research Institute for the Semi-Arid Tropics (ICRISAT), Andhra Pradesh, India.

Moser, C.M., Barrett, C.B., 2006. The complex dynamics of smallholder technology

adoption: the case of SRI in Madagascar. Agricultural Economics 35, 373-388.

Mugera, A. and Ojede, A. 2014. Technical efficiency in african agriculture: is it catching

up or lagging behind?, Journal of International Development 26, 779-795.

Mulwa, R. and Emrouznejad, A. 2013. Measuring productive efficiency using Nerlovian

profit efficiency indicator and metafrontier analysis, Operational Research 13,

271-287.

Munn, R.E. 1992. Towards sustainable development, Atmospheric Environment. Part A.

General Topics 26, 2725-2731.

Mutenje, M., Kankwamba, H., Mangisonib, J., Kassie, M., 2016. Agricultural innovations

and food security in Malawi: Gender dynamics, institutions and market

implications. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 103, 240-248.

Neumayer, E. 2010. Weak Versus Strong Sustainability: Exploring the Limits of Two

Opposing Paradigms. Edward Elgar Publishing.

Ngwira, A., Johnsen, F.H., Aune, J.B., Mekuria, M., Thierfelder, C., 2014. Adoption and

extent of conservation agriculture practices among smallholder farmers in Malawi.

Journal of Soil and Water Conservation 69, 107-119.

Ngwira, A.R., Aune, J.B. and Mkwinda, S. 2012. On-farm evaluation of yield and

economic benefit of short term maize legume intercropping systems under

conservation agriculture in Malawi, Field Crops Research 132, 149-157.

Page 186: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

174

Njuki, J., Poole, J., Johnson, N., Baltenweck, I., Pali, P., Lokman, Z., Mburu, S., 2011.

Gender, livestock and livelihood indicators. Version 2, International Livestock

Research Institute, Nairobi.

Nkonya, E., Pender, J., Kaizzi, K.C., Kato, E., Mugarura, S., Ssali, H. and Muwonge, J.

2008. Linkages between land management, land degradation, and poverty in Sub-

Saharan Africa: The case of Uganda. Intl Food Policy Res Inst.

Norton, B.G. and Toman, M.A. 1997. Sustainability: ecological and economic

perspectives, Land Economics553-568.

Ntzoufras, I. 2011. Bayesian modeling using WinBUGS. John Wiley & Sons.

Obare, G. A., Omamo, S. W. and Williams, J. C. 2003. Smallholder production structure

and rural roads in Africa: the case of Nakuru District, Kenya. Agricultural

Economics, 28, 245-254.

O’Donnell, C.J. 2002. Parametric estimation of technical and allocative efficiency in US

agriculture. in Ball V. Elton and George, N.W. (eds.), Agricultural Productivity:

Measurement and Sources of Growth. Springer, New York pp 137-166.

O’Donnell, C.J. and Coelli, T.J. 2005. A Bayesian approach to imposing curvature on

distance functions, Journal of Econometrics 126, 493-523.

O'Donnell, C.J., Shumway, C.R. and Ball, V.E. 1999. Input demands and inefficiency in

US agriculture, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 81, 865-880.

Ogundari, K. 2014. The paradigm of agricultural efficiency and its implication on food

security in Africa: what does meta-analysis reveal?, World Development 64, 690-

702.

Ortega, D.L., Waldman, K.B., Richardson, R.B., Clay, D.C. and Snapp, S. 2016.

Sustainable Intensification and Farmer Preferences for Crop System Attributes:

Evidence from Malawi’s Central and Southern Regions, World Development 87,

139-151.

Pannell, D.J. and Falconer, D.A. 1988. The relative contributions to profit of fixed and

applied nitrogen in a crop-livestock farm systems, Agricultural Systems 26, 1-17.

Pannell, D.J. and Glenn, N.A. 2000. A framework for the economic evaluation and

selection of sustainability indicators in agriculture, Ecological economics 33, 135-

149.

Pannell, D.J., Llewellyn, R.S. and Corbeels, M. 2014. The farm-level economics of

conservation agriculture for resource-poor farmers, Agriculture, Ecosystems &

Environment 187, 52-64.

Page 187: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

175

Parfitt, J., Barthel, M. and Macnaughton, S. 2010. Food waste within food supply chains:

quantification and potential for change to 2050, Philosophical Transactions of the

Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 365, 3065-3081.

Parks, M.H., Christie, M.E., Bagares, I., 2015. Gender and conservation agriculture:

constraints and opportunities in the Philippines. GeoJournal 80, 61-77.

Parr, J.F., Papendick, R.I., Hornick, S.B. and Meyer, R.E. 1992. Soil quality: attributes

and relationship to alternative and sustainable agriculture, American Journal of

Alternative Agriculture 7, 5-11.

Pascual, U. and Perrings, C. 2007. Developing incentives and economic mechanisms for

in situ biodiversity conservation in agricultural landscapes, Agriculture,

Ecosystems & Environment 121, 256-268.

Patra, D.D., Sachdev, M.S. and Subbiah, B.V. 1986. 15N studies on the transfer of

legume-fixed nitrogen to associated cereals in intercropping systems, Biology and

Fertility of Soils 2, 165-171.

Peoples, M.B., Brockwell, J., Herridge, D.F., Rochester, I.J., Alves, B.J.R., Urquiaga, S.,

Boddey, R.M., Dakora, F.D., Bhattarai, S., Maskey, S.L., Sampet, C., Rerkasem,

B., Khan, D.F., Hauggaard-Nielsen, H. and Jensen, E.S. 2009. The contributions

of nitrogen-fixing crop legumes to the productivity of agricultural systems,

Symbiosis 48, 1-17.

Perman, R., Ma, Y., McGilvray, J. and Common, M. 2003. Natural resource and

environmental economics. Pearson Education Limited, Edinburgh Gate, Harlow

Essex CM20 2JE, United Kingdom

Petersen, B. and Snapp, S. 2015. What is sustainable intensification? Views from experts,

Land Use Policy 46, 1-10.

Pezzey, J. 1992. Sustainability: an interdisciplinary guide, Environmental values, 321-

362.

Pinstrup-Andersen, P. 2009. Food security: definition and measurement. Food Security,

1, 5-7.

Piot-Lepetit, I. and Vermersch, D. 1998. Pricing Organic Nitrogen Under The Weak

Disposability Assumption: An Application to the French Pig Sector, Journal of

Agricultural Economics 49, 85-99.

Porterfield, S.L., 2001. Economic vulnerability among rural single-mother families.

American Journal of Agricultural Economics 83, 1302-1311.

Page 188: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

176

Preissel, S., Reckling, M., Schläfke, N. and Zander, P. 2015. Magnitude and farm-

economic value of grain legume pre-crop benefits in Europe: A review, Field

Crops Research 175, 64-79.

Pretty, J., Toulmin, C. and Williams, S. 2011. Sustainable intensification in African

agriculture, International journal of agricultural sustainability 9, 5-24.

Quisumbing, A.R. 1996. Male-female differences in agricultural productivity:

Methodological issues and empirical evidence, World Development 24, 1579-

1595.

Rabe-Hesketh, S., Skrondal, A., 2012. Multilevel and Longitudinal Modeling Using

Stata. Stata Press books.

Rahman, S. 2009. Whether crop diversification is a desired strategy for agricultural

growth in Bangladesh?, Food Policy 34, 340-349.

Rahman, S. 2010. Women’s labour contribution to productivity and efficiency in

agriculture: empirical evidence from Bangladesh, Journal of Agricultural

Economics 61, 318-342.

Rasul, G. and Thapa, G.B. 2004. Sustainability of ecological and conventional

agricultural systems in Bangladesh: an assessment based on environmental,

economic and social perspectives, Agricultural systems 79, 327-351.

Ravallion, M. and Lokshin, M. 2002. Self-rated economic welfare in Russia. European

Economic Review, 46(8), 1453-1473.

Reardon, T., Barrett, C., Kelly, V. and Savadogo, K. 1999. Policy reforms and sustainable

agricultural intensification in Africa, Development policy review 17, 375-395.

Reinhard, S., Lovell, C.A.K. and Thijssen, G. 1999. Econometric Estimation of Technical

and Environmental Efficiency: An Application to Dutch Dairy Farms, American

Journal of Agricultural Economics 81, 44-60.

Reziti, I. and Ozanne, A. 1999. Testing regularity properties in static and dynamic duality

models: the case of Greek agriculture. European Review of Agricultural

Economics, 26, 461-477.

Rogers, E.M., 1995. Diffusion of Innovations. Free Press, New York.

Rogers, E.M., 2002. Diffusion of preventive innovations. Addictive Behaviors 27, 989-

993.

Ronner, E. and Franke, A.C. 2012. Quantifying the impact of the N2Africa project on

Biological Nitrogen Fixation, (Serial online). Available from URL:

www.N2Africa.org [accessed 10-02-2015].

Page 189: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

177

Rozek, R.P. 1988. A nonparametric test for economies of scope, Applied Economics 20,

653-663.

Rusike, J., Mahungu, N.M., Jumbo, S., Sandifolo, V.S. and Malindi, G. 2010. Estimating

impact of cassava research for development approach on productivity, uptake and

food security in Malawi, Food Policy 35, 98-111.

Sanginga, N. 2003. Role of biological nitrogen fixation in legume based cropping

systems; a case study of West Africa farming systems, Plant and Soil 252, 25-39.

Sauer, J., Frohberg, K. and Hockmann, H. 2006. Stochastic efficiency measurement: the

curse of theoretical consistency, Journal of Applied Economics 9, 139.

Schilizzi, S. and Pannell, D. 2001. The economics of nitrogen fixation. Agronomie, 21(6-

7): 527-37.

Schmidt, P. 2011. One-step and two-step estimation in SFA models, Journal of

Productivity Analysis 36, 201-203.

Scoones, I. and Toulmin, C. 1998. Soil nutrient balances: what use for policy?,

Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment 71, 255-267.

Serletis, A. and Feng, G. 2015. Imposing theoretical regularity on flexible functional

forms, Econometric Reviews 34, 198-227.

Seyoum, E.T., Battese, G.E. and Fleming, E.M. 1998. Technical efficiency and

productivity of maize producers in eastern Ethiopia: a study of farmers within and

outside the Sasakawa-Global 2000 project, Agricultural Economics 19, 341-348.

Shaik, S., Helmers, G.A. and Langemeier, M.R. 2002. Direct and Indirect Shadow Price

and Cost Estimates of Nitrogen Pollution Abatement, Journal of Agricultural and

Resource Economics 27, 420-432.

Sheldrick, W.F., Syers, J.K. and Lingard, J. 2002. A conceptual model for conducting

nutrient audits at national, regional, and global scales, Nutrient Cycling in

Agroecosystems 62, 61-72.

Sherlund, S.M., Barrett, C.B. and Adesina, A.A. 2002. Smallholder technical efficiency

controlling for environmental production conditions, Journal of development

economics 69, 85-101.

Shumway, C. R. 1995. Recent Duality Contributions in Production Economics. Journal

of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 20, 178-194.

Simtowe, F., Diagne, A. and Zeller, M. 2008. Who is credit constrained? Evidence from

rural Malawi, Agricultural Finance Review 68, 255-272.

Page 190: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

178

Singbo, A. and Lansink, A. 2010. Lowland farming system inefficiency in Benin (West

Africa): directional distance function and truncated bootstrap approach, Food

Security 2, 367-382.

Singbo, A. and Larue, B. 2016. Scale Economies, Technical Efficiency, and the Sources

of Total Factor Productivity Growth of Quebec Dairy Farms, Canadian Journal

of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie 64, 339-363.

Singbo, A., Oude Lansink, A. and Emvalomatis, G. 2014. Estimating farmers’ productive

and marketing inefficiency: an application to vegetable producers in Benin,

Journal of Productivity Analysis 42, 157-169.

Singbo, A.G., Lansink, A.O. and Emvalomatis, G. 2015. Estimating shadow prices and

efficiency analysis of productive inputs and pesticide use of vegetable production,

European Journal of Operational Research 245, 265-272.

Singer, J.D., Willett, J.B., 1993. It's about Time: Using Discrete-Time Survival Analysis

to Study Duration and the Timing of Events. Journal of Educational Statistics, 155-

195.

Sipiläinen, T. and Huhtala, A. 2013. Opportunity costs of providing crop diversity in

organic and conventional farming: would targeted environmental policies make

economic sense?, European Review of Agricultural Economics, 40 (3): 441-462.

Smil, V. 1999. Nitrogen in crop production: An account of global flows, Global

Biogeochemical Cycles 13, 647-662.

Smit, B. and Brklacich, M. 1989. Sustainable development and the analysis of rural

systems, Journal of Rural Studies 5, 405-414.

Smith, A., Snapp, S., Chikowo, R., Thorne, P., Bekunda, M. and Glover, J. 2016.

Measuring sustainable intensification in smallholder agroecosystems: A review,

Global Food Security.

Smith, E.G., Lerohl, M., Messele, T. and Janzen, H.H. 2000. Soil quality attribute time

paths: Optimal levels and values, Journal of Agricultural and Resource

Economics, 307-324.

Solís, D., Bravo‐Ureta, B.E. and Quiroga, R.E. 2009. Technical efficiency among peasant

farmers participating in natural resource management programmes in Central

America, Journal of Agricultural Economics 60, 202-219.

Solow, R.M. 1986. On the intergenerational allocation of natural resources, The

Scandinavian Journal of Economics141-149.

Page 191: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

179

Song, F., Zhao, J., Swinton, S.M., 2011. Switching to perennial energy crops under

uncertainty and costly reversibility. American Journal of Agricultural Economics

93, 764-779.

Spiegelhalter, D., Thomas, A., Best, N. and Lunn, D. 2003. WinBUGS user manual.

version.

Spiegelhalter, D., Thomas, A., Best, N. and Gilks, W. 1996. BUGS 0.5: Bayesian

inference using Gibbs sampling manual (version ii), Institute of Public Health.

University of Cambridge, MRC Biostatistics Unit, Cambridge, UK, pp 1-59.

Stauber, M.S. and Burt, O.R. 1973. Implicit Estimate of Residual Nitrogen Under

Fertilized Range Conditions in the Northern Great Plains, Agronomy Journal 65,

897-901.

Stauber, M.S., Burt, O.R. and Linse, F. 1975. An Economic Evaluation of Nitrogen

Fertilization of Grasses When Carry-over is Significant, American Journal of

Agricultural Economics 57, 463-471.

Stern, D.I. 1997. Limits to substitution and irreversibility in production and consumption:

a neoclassical interpretation of ecological economics, Ecological economics 21,

197-215.

Stern, W.R. 1993. Nitrogen fixation and transfer in intercrop systems, Field Crops

Research 34, 335-356.

Sun, K. 2015. Constrained nonparametric estimation of input distance function, Journal

of Productivity Analysis 43, 85-97.

Sunding, D., Zilberman, D., 2001. The agricultural innovation process: research and

technology adoption in a changing agricultural sector. Handbook of agricultural

economics 1, 207-261.

Takane, T. 2008. Labor use in smallholder agriculture in Malawi: six village case studies,

African Study Monographs 29, 183-200.

Tefera, T. 2012. Post-harvest losses in African maize in the face of increasing food

shortage, Food security 4, 267-277.

Teklewold, H., Kassie, M., Shiferaw, B., 2013. Adoption of multiple sustainable

agricultural practices in rural Ethiopia. Journal of agricultural economics 64, 597-

623.

Terrell, D. 1996. Incorporating monotonicity and concavity conditions in flexible

functional forms, Journal of Applied Econometrics179-194.

Thanh Nguyen, T., Hoang, V.N. and Seo, B. 2012. Cost and environmental efficiency of

rice farms in South Korea, Agricultural Economics 43, 369-378.

Page 192: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

180

Thiam, A., Bravo-Ureta, B.E. and Rivas, T.E. 2001. Technical efficiency in developing

country agriculture: a meta-analysis, Agricultural Economics 25, 235-243.

Thierfelder, C., Chisui, J.L., Gama, M., Cheesman, S., Jere, Z.D., Bunderson, W.T., Eash,

N.S. and Rusinamhodzi, L. 2013. Maize-based conservation agriculture systems

in Malawi: long-term trends in productivity, Field Crops Research 142, 47-57.

Thornton, P.K., Jones, P.G., Alagarswamy, G., Andresen, J. and Herrero, M. 2010.

Adapting to climate change: agricultural system and household impacts in East

Africa, Agricultural systems 103, 73-82.

Tiller, K.J., Feleke, S.T., Starnes, J.H., 2010. A discrete‐time hazard analysis of the exit

of burley tobacco growers in Tennessee, North Carolina, and Virginia. Agricultural

Economics 41, 397-408.

Tittonell, P. 2014. Ecological intensification of agriculture—sustainable by nature,

Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability 8, 53-61.

Tsedeke, A. 2009. Tropical legumes II. Second Annual Review and Planning Meeting,

Proceedings of the Second Annual Review and Planning Meeting; 16–20

November 2009 2009 Bamako, Mali. ICRISAT-Nairobi.

Townsend, R.F., Kirsten, J. and Vink, N. 1998. Farm size, productivity and returns to

scale in agriculture revisited: a case study of wine producers in South Africa,

Agricultural Economics 19, 175-180.

Tyteca, D. 1998. Sustainability indicators at the firm level, Journal of Industrial Ecology

2, 61-77.

Udry, C., Hoddinott, J., Alderman, H. and Haddad, L. 1995. Gender differentials in farm

productivity: implications for household efficiency and agricultural policy, Food

policy 20, 407-423.

Unkovich, M., Herridge, D., Peoples, M., Cadisch, G., Boddey, R., Giller, K., Alves,

B.J.R. and Chalk, P. 2008. Measuring plant-associated nitrogen fixation in

agricultural systems, (Serial online), ACIAR Monograph No. 136. URL:

http://aciar.gov.au/files/node/10169/mn136_measuring_plant_associated_nitrog

en_fixation_19979.pdf (accessed 25-03-2014].

Valbuena, D., Erenstein, O., Tui, S.H.K., Abdoulaye, T., Claessens, L., Duncan, A.J.,

Gérard, B., Rufino, M.C., Teufel, N. and van Rooyen, A. 2012. Conservation

Agriculture in mixed crop–livestock systems: Scoping crop residue trade-offs in

Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia, Field Crops Research 132, 175-184.

Page 193: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

181

Van den Broeck, J., Koop, G., Osiewalski, J. and Steel, M.F.J. 1994. Stochastic frontier

models: A Bayesian perspective, Journal of Econometrics 61, 273-303.

van Zyl, J., Binswanger, H. and Thirtle, C. 1995. The relationship between farm size and

efficiency in South African agriculture, Policy and Research Working Paper

1548, (Serial online). Available from URL.

Vanlauwe, B., Coyne, D., Gockowski, J., Hauser, S., Huising, J., Masso, C., Nziguheba,

G., Schut, M. and Van Asten, P. 2014. Sustainable intensification and the African

smallholder farmer, Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability 8, 15-22.

Veeman, T.S. 1989. Sustainable development: Its economic meaning and policy

implications, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne

d'agroeconomie 37, 875-886.

Victor, P.A. 1991. Indicators of sustainable development: some lessons from capital

theory, Ecological economics 4, 191-213.

Villano, R., Bravo‐Ureta, B., Solís, D. and Fleming, E. 2015. Modern rice technologies

and productivity in The Philippines: disentangling technology from managerial

gaps, Journal of Agricultural Economics 66, 129-154.

von Braun, J. 1995. Agricultural commercialization: impacts on income and nutrition and

implications for policy. Food Policy, 20, 187-202.

Wang, H.-J. and Schmidt, P. 2002. One-step and two-step estimation of the effects of

exogenous variables on technical efficiency levels, Journal of Productivity

Analysis 18, 129-144.

Wang, K., Xian, Y., Lee, C.-Y., Wei, Y.-M. and Huang, Z. 2017. On selecting directions

for directional distance functions in a non-parametric framework: a review,

Annals of Operations Research1-34.

Weitzman, M.L. 1997. Sustainability and technical progress, The Scandinavian Journal

of Economics 99, 1-13.

Wolff, H., Heckelei, T. and Mittelhammer, R.C. 2010. Imposing curvature and

monotonicity on flexible functional forms: an efficient regional approach,

Computational Economics 36, 309-339.

Wouterse, F. 2010. Migration and technical efficiency in cereal production: evidence

from Burkina Faso, Agricultural Economics 41, 385-395.

Yunlong, C. and Smit, B. 1994. Sustainability in agriculture: a general review,

Agriculture, ecosystems & environment 49, 299-307.

Page 194: Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Malawi: An Economic … · The work(s) are not in any way a violation or infringement of any copyright, trademark, patent, or other rights

The Economics of SAI Technologies in Malawi

182

Yusuf, A.A., Iwuafor, E.N.O., Abaidoo, R.C., Olufajo, O.O. and Sanginga, N. 2009.

Grain legume rotation benefits to maize in the northern Guinea savanna of

Nigeria: fixed-nitrogen versus other rotation effects, Nutrient Cycling in

Agroecosystems 84, 129-139.

Zilberman, D. 2014. The economics of sustainable development, American Journal of

Agricultural Economics 96, 385-396.

Zorya, S., Morgan, N., Diaz Rios, L., Hodges, R., Bennett, B., Stathers, T., Mwebaze, P.

and Lamb, J. 2011. Missing food: the case of postharvest grain losses in sub-

Saharan Africa, Economic and Sector Work Report No. 60371-AFR, (Serial

online). Available from URL:

https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/2824 [accessed

01/05/2017].