17
EL FUTURO DE LA ALIMENTACIÓN Y RETOS DE LA AGRICULTURA PARA EL SIGLO XXI: Debates sobre quién, cómo y con qué implicaciones sociales, económicas y ecológicas alimentará el mundo. THE FUTURE OF FOOD AND CHALLENGES FOR AGRICULTURE IN THE 21st CENTURY: Debates about who, how and with what social, economic and ecological implications we will feed the world. ELIKADURAREN ETORKIZUNA ETA NEKAZARITZAREN ERRONKAK XXI. MENDERAKO: Mundua nork, nola eta zer-nolako inplikazio sozial, ekonomiko eta ekologikorekin elikatuko duen izango da eztabaidagaia Taking the part of peasants’: Hits and Misses Henry Bernstein Paper # 1 Apirila – Abril – April 24, 25, 26 2017

Taking the part of peasants’: Hits and Misseselikadura21.eus/wp-content/uploads/2017/04/1-Bernstein.pdf · 2017. 4. 19. · Debates sobre quién, cómo y con qué implicaciones

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    5

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • www.elikadura21.eus

    ELFUTURODELAALIMENTACIÓNYRETOSDELAAGRICULTURAPARAELSIGLOXXI:Debatessobrequién,cómoyconquéimplicacionessociales,económicasyecológicasalimentaráelmundo.

    THEFUTUREOFFOODANDCHALLENGESFOR

    AGRICULTUREINTHE21stCENTURY:Debatesaboutwho,howandwithwhatsocial,economicandecological

    implicationswewillfeedtheworld.ELIKADURARENETORKIZUNAETANEKAZARITZARENERRONKAKXXI.MENDERAKO:Munduanork,nolaetazer-nolakoinplikaziosozial,ekonomikoetaekologikorekinelikatukoduenizangodaeztabaidagaia

    Takingthepartofpeasants’:

    HitsandMissesHenryBernstein

    Paper#1

    Apirila–Abril–April24,25,262017

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    1

    Takingthepartofpeasants’:HitsandMisses

    “...populist practice is concerned with two things: personal survival andimprovedagriculture.”(Narkiewicz1976,271)

    “It is up to the agriculturalists of the whole world, once they haveunderstood their significance and value and their common destiny, touniteforthesakeofthewelfareofthepeople–todefendsociety,toassisttheStateonitswaytopeace,andtoupholdagriculture;thatistosay,bygrowing food and by the character of their own existence, to fulfil theprincipal agrarian idea in giving thepeople, the States and thenations afirmfoundationforalifeofmaterialandmoralwell-being.”(CentralOfficeof the International Agrarian Bureau, Prague, 1922, quoted by Mitrany1961,143)

    Introduction

    This is a preliminary sketch of parts of a larger paper in progress which willconsider how convincingly ‘AgrarianMarxism’ andAgrarian Populism- as (socio-)economic theory, ideologyandpoliticalproject -meet thechallengesofhittingtheir targets, aswell as their direct confrontations and contestationswith eachother. Themost celebrated, and intriguing,historical lociof such confrontationsand contestations remain Russia from the 1880s into the 1920s, and south-easternEuropefromthelatenineteenthcentury,andespeciallytheendofWorldWar I, until World War II. Those instances, and their contemporary andsubsequentdebates, informmuchof this paper, andareused tohelp structureexposition. I also aim to restrict references although, aswill be evident, I havebenefittedgreatlyfromre-readingtwobooksinparticular:DavidMitrany’sclassic,if somewhat eccentric, populist work Marx against the peasant (1961, firstpublished 1951), and Gavin Kitching’s remarkable little critique of ‘populistdevelopment theory’, Development and underdevelopment in historicalperspective. Populism, nationalism and industrialization (revised edition, 1989,firstpublished1982).

    ‘Hitsandmisses’ inthetitlereferstothemain‘targets’associatedwithAgrarianPopulism (‘Taking the part of peasants’) towhich this paper limits itself. This isimposedbyconstraintsoftimeandspace,butalsoseemsappropriatetothisICASmeetingwhichappearsfirmlyweddedto‘Peasantism’,asMitrany(1961)termsit.At the same time, it is worthwhile to ask how much agrarian populism todaydepartsfromthehistoricalconditionsandpreoccupationsofthe‘classic’debatesandconfrontationsindicated-andtheircomplexities.

    Ofcourse,theframingby(socio-)economictheory,ideologyandpoliticalprojectisheuristic and in practice it can be difficult (impossible?) to maintain secureboundaries between its three components. Both analytically and empirically(which includes historically) it is useful to distinguish between the ‘economicsociology’ofagrarianchange,complexenoughinitsdiversityanddeterminations,andits‘politicalsociology’whichaddsfurtherdeterminations,hencecomplexities(Bernstein2010).

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    2

    1. (Socio-)economictheory

    I begin with some familiar themes from political economy applied to explorehighly varied trajectories of the development of capitalism, a centralpreoccupation in both Marxism and classic (Russian and eastern European)populismandonwhichtheyclashed:analyticallyonthe ‘necessity’orotherwiseofcapitalistdevelopment,aboveallindustrialization;empiricallyonitsactuality-howfarcapitalismhadproceededinthecountriesconcerned;andprescriptivelyon its desirability or otherwise, as establishing conditions of possibility of‘alternative’paths,by-passingortranscendingfull-blowncapitalism.

    Centralelementshereincludeissuesofthedevelopmentoftheproductiveforcesin farming and agriculturemore widely; economic scale; relationships betweenagricultureand industry/industrialization;accumulation;property;markets; classrelationsanddynamics (exploitationandoppression);and indeedtoday ‘feedingtheworld’.Herearesomeunavoidablybriefcommentsoneach.

    The development of the productive forces in farming, and in agriculture morewidely, was, of course, a central concern of classical political economy and itsmodels of accumulation. To criticize simplistic and reified notions of thedevelopment of the productive forces in farming, and in agriculture, that linksthemunconditionally toeconomiesof scale, to technical change (mechanizationand‘chemicalization’),andhencetoacontinuouslygrowingproductivityoflabour– characteristic of ‘mechanical’ Marxism – is relatively straightforward andnecessary.Atthesametime,thereareissueslurkingherethatagrarianpopulismignorestoitscost.Forexample,therearemany(‘capitalized’)‘familyfarmers’(inboth North and South) who rely on mechanical and chemical technologies topursuetheiractivitiesandtoreproducethemselves.

    More generally, the productivity of labour remains a central issue and can, orshould, not be sidestepped with reference to inherited (‘traditional’) ways offarming, let alone celebration of its long hours and often backbreaking labour(‘drudgery’ inChayanov’sterm),nortomodesof ‘agro-ecological’farmingwhichareacclaimedfor their labour intensity.Thewider implications includenot leastthe returns to farmers and farming households, signalled by ‘models of pricing’and ‘producers’ salaries’ noted in themotivation for this conference. And theyalsoconnectwithhowproductivitiesoflabourinfarmingbearonthefeasibilityof‘familyfarmers’feedingthe(restofthe)world.

    Indeed, theneed to improve the technicalquality, henceoutput (andmarketedoutput) of household farmingwas a constant theme in the deliberations of theclassic (Russian and eastern European) populists, often tied to issues of scale,whichIcommentonnext.

    The agrarian populists of Russia and eastern Europeanweremostly clear abouttheseverelimitationsof‘backward’peasantfarming,justastheywerechampionsofthemoralqualitiesofpeasantwaysoflife.Theysaw’backwardness’asderivedfromtinyscalesoffarmingandthe‘primitive’instrumentsoflabouremployed(aswellaslowlevelsoftechnicalcultureandeducation).Economicallyunviablefarmsizecouldbehighlightedbydemographicpressure.Mitrany(1961,129)remarksthatthe‘ironyoftheeasternrevolutionwasthatthebreak-upofthelargeestates

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    3

    into millions of peasant holdings [after WWI, HB] was presided over not byPopulists but by those who stood for the industrial solution’, with landredistributionfollowedbyruralpopulationincreaseofnearly30percentbetweenthe wars in south-eastern Europe (ibid, 120), and with almost no growth inmarketed production (ibid, 117) – itself a problem for wider economicdevelopment.

    WithlandreformafterWWIinsouth-easternEurope,the‘farmerwastobemadesecure in his tenure, but the secure tenantwas expected to be a good farmer’(Mitrany 1961, 110). In the populist vision of the time, the solution was tocombine individual household farming, equippedwith sufficient land and othermeans, with economies of scale both upstream and downstream of farmingachieved through effective co-operation (though some populists hoped formovement towards collective production in farming). In short, more ‘scientific’populism (in Mitrany’s term; or ‘neo-populism’ in Kitching, 1989, for whomChayanovwas the keypioneer) advocatedbothmuch improved andproductiveindividual family farming, linked with the wider economy through supportivenetworksofruralco-operationmanagedbyfarmersthemselves.

    Russian populism in the nineteenth century (until the 1880s) was infused withhostility to industrialization on the model of ‘western’ (European) capitalistdevelopment, and the threat it posed to an often-idealized peasant existence.Latermore ‘scientific’ populism (or neo-populism) in south-eastern Europewasmorereceptiveto formsof industrializationthatcouldsupportpeasant farming,that is, industry that was smaller-scale, decentralized, used local materials,centred on the production of means of production and consumption for thecountryside, and was able to provide employment for peasants according toagriculturalseasons.The lastwasexplicitlyargued intermsofdealingwithrural‘surplus labour’, and more specifically supplementing incomes derived fromhouseholdfarming.

    Evidently, one of the principal differences between conditions then and nowconcerns the trajectories, extent, forms and effects of capitalist development.Russia and south-eastern Europe in the periods noted were predominantly‘peasantsocieties’ofakindwhichnolongerexistsinthetwenty-firstcentury.Itisnot surprising, then, that their intellectuals were preoccupied with paths ofdevelopmentpreferabletothatof‘thewest’,alsoacentralmotifindebatesaboutdevelopment inAsiaandAfricaafter independence fromcolonial rule. (This isaprincipal themeof Kitching 1989; and is elaborated in the caseof Russia at theturn of the twentieth century by Shanin 1985). Today, alongside the strong(sometimesapparentlydefinitive)veinofagro-ecologyinpopulisttheory,isthereanysystematicthoughtonindustryandindustrializationotherthanageneralizedantipathy on one hand, and, on the other, specific critiques of ‘industrialized’agriculturalproductionmethods?Onewondersabouttheplaceofindustry,whattypesof industry and their linkages to agriculture, andurban ‘classesof labour’(andindeedruralproletarians),inthecontemporarypopulistimaginary.

    At the same time, an enduring continuity between earlier and contemporarypopulistsistheiroppositiontoagriculture,anditsfarmers,servingasakeysourceof(‘primitive’)accumulationfor industrialization,whetherframedwithinnotionsof ‘national’ development (Kitching 1989) or now increasingly ‘globalized’, aconcern brought up-to-date with reference to David Harvey’s ‘accumulation

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    4

    through dispossession’ (2003) and its often promiscuous invocations (althoughbuildinga ‘national’ industrial accumulation fund isno longeraprincipalgoal inthiseraofneo-liberalism).

    Another key socio-economic theme centres on property, above all peasantproprietorship of land. This is manifested in movements for land reform (andaccess to ‘commons’), of course, then and now, in a wide range of historicalconditions: anti-‘feudal’ movements, anti-capitalist movements, and whetherpeasants’property rights in landarearguedon thebasisof individual tenureorsome or other form of ‘community’ ownership. A potent thread in populistthought is the unity assigned to ownership of land and the ‘family’ labour thatworksit:the‘familylabourfarm’theorizedbyChayanov.ThisisacentralbeliefofMitrany(amongmanyothers),whosuggestssomewhatproblematicallythat‘theclaimtoindividualownershipmaybelogicallyrootedinthenatureofagriculturalproductionitself’(1961,125),andmoregenerallySchumacher(1973)thatthereis‘something natural and healthy about...the private property of the workingproprietor’(citedbyKitching1989,96).

    Thisraisesvariousissuesespeciallyoncetheassumptionisdroppedthatfamily(orpatriarchal) individual ownership of land is reproduced seamlessly acrosssuccessivegenerationsofthesamefamiliesoffarmers–moreplausibleperhapsin the time of Chayanov, his predecessors and contemporaries, than today,precisely because of theways inwhich capitalism has spread since then. If theassumptionisrelaxed,orformulatedasamatterforinvestigation(ratherthanana priori), then other possibilities arise, notably the outright or implicitcommodificationof land: theemergenceof ‘formal’ (de jure)or ‘vernacular’ (defacto)commodityexchangesoflandandallthatcanentail.

    Thisthenbringsus,inhaste,toanothermuch-contestedarea,thatofmarketsin‘peasant’ reproduction. The basic model of Chayanov is one of simplereproductionof the ‘family labour farm’.Once this is separated fromnotionsof‘subsistence’asexclusivelyorprimarilyself-provisioning,thenitpointstoissuesofsimplereproductionsecuredatleastpartlyandoftenlargelythroughinvolvementinmarkets:toobtaininstrumentsofproduction(andalsoland,above)andcredit(indebtedness isoneof themostwidespreadandcontinuousburdenson familyfarmers in the different times and places of modern history), and to sell farmproducts.Chayanovwaswellawareofthis;hismodelisnotoneof‘subsistence’inany narrow sense. The big question then became, and remains, even more, aconcern today: how do different forms of (necessary) peasant involvement inmarkets help or hinder their reproduction? How might it generate differencesbetweenpeasants?

    Thereis,ofcourse,avastliteratureonsuchquestions,field-basedandempiricalaswellasmanifestedintheoreticalcontention.KitchingfollowsMarx’sresponsetovisionsofsocialismasakindofsmallproducers’(peasantsandartisans)marketutopia,citingMarx’sconclusiononProudhonandothersthat

    Theyallwantcompetitionwithoutthelethaleffectsofcompetition.Theyall want the impossible, namely the conditions of bourgeois existencewithout thenecessary consequencesof those conditions. (Kitching1989,32,seealso136)

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    5

    Kitching’sfifthchapteron‘Neo-populisminmoderndevelopmenttheory’focuseson four emblematic sets of texts: those of Julius Nyerere, the ILO’s WorldEmploymentProgrammepapersofthe1970s,MichaelLipton’sWhypoorpeoplestaypoor(1977),andSchumacher’sSmallisbeautiful(1973).HisdiscussionoftheILO and Lipton shows, implicitly, that their versions of what might be called‘appliedpopulistdevelopmenttheory’–appliedtoemploymentgenerationbytheILO,and to small farmerdevelopmentbyLipton– followa logicofneo-classicaleconomics.Whatholdsbackadvance inthetwoareastheyaddress is, ineffect,political ‘interference’ withmarkets, attributed to ‘big leap’ import-substitutingindustrializationinthefirstcase,and‘urbanbias’inthesecond.Pro-employmentandpro-smallfarmerpoliciestohelperadicatepovertythusamounttothe‘right’politicalinterventionstorepairmarket‘distortions’thatarisefromthewrongsortof political interventions, thereby restoring market ‘efficiency’. (Schumacherunusuallyarguedexplicitlyforreducinglabourproductivity,alsoimplicitintheILOanalysis,andhadastrongecologicaldimension.)

    This is cited not to suggest that there is any single correct theorization, andpractice,adequatetopeasantprogress throughmarket integration,but that the‘market question’ continues to generate tensions and ambiguities in agrarianpopulismtoday.

    I now arrive at the theme where so much of the above and its contestationsconverge, namely class relations and their dynamics of exploitation andoppression, including,of course,patriarchy, andethnic and religiousdifferencesanddivisions,oftenstronglyassociatedwithcolonialand imperial legacies (as inpartsofTsaristRussiaandsouth-easternEurope).

    Atitsbroadest,agrarianpopulismviewsallfarmersdeemedtobe‘familyfarmers’as belonging to a single class, or at least a distinctive social formation withcommon interests: ‘peopleof the land’.This raises thequestionof ‘whoarethefarmers?’ in social terms (Bernstein2014),especiallywhenaunitary (orat leastunified) quality (‘essence’?) is applied across the extremely diverse range offarmers in the world today, from, say, hoe-farmers in sub-Saharan Africa to(capitalized) family farmers inNorthAmerica. ‘Family’ farmers inNorthAmericaandwesternEuropemaybeheartenedby thebelief that theypursue the same(benign)‘logic’ashoe-farmersinsub-SaharanAfrica,thelatterlessso:whythenaretheyrichandwearepoor?WhattheyhaveincommonmightbetheorizedinChayanovianterms,the(simple)reproductionoffarminghouseholds,informedbytheir striving for autonomy, at itsmost extremepostulated as a trans-historical(which is to say, ahistorical) universal. Or theymight share oppression by, andresistanceto,thepressuresexertedonthembylarge-scalecapitalupstreamanddownstream of farming, associated with contemporary conditions of giantagribusiness (and finance capital too). Thus ‘farmer’ vs capital, with ‘classes oflabour’(wageworkers)tendingtodisappearfromthepictureofclassrelationsincapitalism.

    As class is a relation, any claims for class or class-like social qualities entailmutuallyconstitutiverelationsbetweenclasses,whichchange,especiallyintheirforms, indifferenthistoricalconditions.ForRussianandsouth-easternEuropeanradical intellectuals, bothpopulists andMarxists,manypeasants (themajority?)theyaddressedthroughtheagrarianquestionsoftheirtimeswerestillexploitedand oppressed largely through ‘semi-feudal’ or ‘neo-feudal’ exactions of landed

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    6

    property(andstates),aconditionhighlightedbythelimitedgains(ifany)formostpeasantsoftheformalabolitionofserfdom(‘emancipation’)inRussiain1861andsubsequently elsewhere in the east, and which fed into their politics. TeodorShanin 1986, among others, argues that the dramatic uprisings of Russianpeasantsinthe1905-7revolutionledLenintoafundamentalreappraisaloftheirpoliticalrole.

    Nonetheless,andas iswell-known,Lenin (1964/1899)hadearlierpioneered theinvestigationofclassdifferentiationamongRussianpeasantsaspartofthewidedevelopmentofcapitalismthere. Whetherhisaccountwasempiricallyaccuratehas been questioned by some formidable scholarship, suggesting a salutarywarningabout leaping froma shakyeconomic sociology toanevenmore shakypoliticalsociology. However,Lenin’sanalyticcontinuestobetestedandappliedinmuchmaterialist work on agrarian change, and indeed in ways that tend toabolish the application of inherited notions of ‘peasant’ farming, economy,society, and the like, to today’s conditions of global capitalism. One approach,developed inmyownwork, is toseethosedesignatedas ‘family’ farmers intheworld today as mostly either petty commodity producers, constituted as acontradictory combination of capital and labour, or rurally based ‘classes oflabour’ whose reproduction is necessarily secured through wage labour, evenwhencombinedwithadegreeof‘ownaccount’farming(Bernstein2010).

    Why,andhow,classdifferentiationoffarmers isproblematicfortoday’scallstoagrarianmovementsheldtorepresentall(‘family’)farmers,‘peopleoftheland’,isconsideredfurtherbelow.However,itcanbenotedherethatissuesconcerningpropertyinland,andreproductionthroughintegrationinmarketsandcommodityrelations, however briefly stated above, at least raise some complications foragrarian populism. This is nicely illustrated by an incident reported in Venturi’sencyclopaedicaccountofRussianpopulismandsocialismfrom1825to1881.Atameetingconvenedbynarodnikswho‘wenttothepeople’inthe1870s,andwhotoldassembledvillagersofapost-revolutionidyllwhentheywouldownland,oneresponsewas‘Oh,howwonderfulwhenweshallredistributeland!Ishallhiretwoworkers and live like a lord!’ (Venturi 1966, 505). There is no reason to believethat peasant was typical but he was certainly familiar with the notion, and nodoubtthepractice,ofindividuallyownedprivatelandworkedwithwagelabour.

    2. Ideology

    Thesketchsofaralreadypointstoelementsofideology,whichincludestrugglesforsocialandenvironmental justice;otherphilosophicalandcultural issues;andthe matter of whose interests ‘alternatives’ (to capitalism) are imagined orconstructedtoserve.

    Socialandenvironmentaljustice

    The declaration from the Central Office of the International Agrarian Bureau,basedinPrague,in1922,quotedattheheadofthispaper,servesaswellasany,as a brief statement of a global ideological vision Indeed, it could serve as thecharterofLaVíaCampesina today,apart fromsome traces characteristicof itshistoricalmoment,notably itsreferenceto ‘theState’and ‘States’,andwiththetopicladditionof thevirtuesofagro-ecologypracticedbyat leastavanguardof‘peasant’farmers.

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    7

    Otherphilosophicalandculturalissues

    This is unfortunately expressed here as a kind of residual and cannot be takenfurther in this paper. Rather its serves to signal the many, rich and eclecticphilosophicalandculturalideasinwhichpopulismaboundsthroughoutitsvariedhistories,sometimesattheexpenseofanyplausible(socio-)economictheory,asVenturi(1966)arguesformuchRussianpopulisminthenineteenthcentury(andKitching1989doesfor‘populistdevelopmenttheory’generally).Thatwaslargelya product of the intelligentsia, both resident (often in prison and internal exile)and emigré. Venturi traces the ideas of, and contestations between, thoseinfluencedatdifferent timesbyGermanromanticism, theworkofProudhon,byother socialist currents and increasinglyover timebyMarx, byMarx’s anarchistopponents, of whom Bakunin and Kropotkin were leading figures, and so on.Moreover, there were influences of Slavophil historians on notions of peasanttradition in Russia that bore on heated disputes concerning the obschina orRussianpeasantcommune,itsfortunesinthefaceofcapitalistdevelopment,andits prospects for the future. Arcane as some of these debatesmay seem, theyprovide linkswith some persistent tropes of populist discourse today, not leastclaimsoverlandandwaysoflifeofindigeneity(includingintheBasquecountry?),and issues of ‘community’ as an organizing principle of farming and social life(below).

    Inwhoseinterests?

    The declaration from 1922 quoted above is striking in its belief that‘agriculturalistsofthewholeworld’arethepotentialsavioursofhumanity.Thisisechoedinsomepopulistbeliefstodaythatagro-ecologicalfarming,togetherwith‘foodsovereignty’andthelike, istheprimarykeytosavingtheplanetandall itspeople from the social injustices and ecological destructions of capitalism. Eventhough ‘people of the land’ are no longer amajority of theworld’s population,unlikewhatpopulistscouldargueacenturyorsoago (Mitrany1961,148), theycarrythepromiseofa ‘world-historicalsubject’ forourtimes. Ineffect,theyarepromotedtothestatusoftheuniversal‘class’oncebestowedontheproletariatinMarxian socialism. This moves from the plane of the ideological to my thirdcomponent,agrarianpopulismasapoliticalproject.

    3. Politicalproject

    In many ways, this can be regarded as the crux of the matter, and a centralconcern of themotivation of this conference, at which I expect to learn aboutcurrent formsof thinkingandactivism inthepursuitof thatproject fromotherswhoknowfarmoreaboutthemthanIdo.InviewofthatIlimitmyobservationsinthissection.

    Politicalproject(s) includethefamiliar issuesofthekeyclasses/groups‘targeted’for mobilization; ‘community’ as a basis for solidarity and action; politicalalliances; strategies and tactics. It is the terrain on which Marxist agrarianprogrammes have at best a varied historical record. Has agrarian populism abetterrecord,and(or)doesitpromisemoreintoday’sconditions?

    Constituencies

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    8

    In principle, ‘people of the land’ - producers of food - is the encompassingconstituency of contemporary agrarian populism, as remarked above. As allpeople are also consumers of food (albeit divided by class and culturaldifferences), they have, or can and should have, an interest in the food that isavailable to them:how it is produced,where it comes from, its variety, quality,cost,andsoon-keyconcernsoftheprojectof‘foodsovereignty’.

    A central feature of this project is (and should be) the recognition that not allfarmers are committed to the practice of agro-ecological and autonomousactivity,and indeednotall ‘family’ farmers.Leavingasidecapitalist farmers,and‘family’farmerswhopursuespecializedcommodityproductionandaccumulation(forwhomitmightpromiseameasureof‘autonomy’),thosecommittedtoagro-ecologyarelikelytobea‘vanguard’inthevastlydifferentplacesandconditionsof‘family’farming–indeedforsomepopuliststhisisamatterof‘choice’byfarmers(and thosewhowould support them). Thepurposeof theproject, indeedwhatmakes it a project, is to demonstrate to ‘family’ farmers the virtues of agro-ecological production, and to enlist them in themovement. If the ‘art of (agro-ecological) farming’ is used to construct apolitical (rather than socio-economic)definition of ‘peasants’ as those committed to it, then they constitute thespearhead(‘vanguard’?)oftheprojectwhichdrawsinmoreandmore‘peasants’,old and ‘new’, as it advances: a valid characterisation of the project of La VìaCampesina?Thematter remains,ofcourse,ofhowtobasetheproject insocio-economicconditionsandtheiranalysis,necessarytoassessingitsfeasibility.

    This perspective may be conceptualized, and classified, in terms of a series ofwidening concentric circles, from working with small groups of farmers inparticular locales, with all their ecological and social (including market)specificities, to regionaland ‘national’organizations,programmesanddemands,to the formation and activities of a strategically ambitious transnational socialmovementlikeLaVíaCampesina.

    Community

    ‘Community’ is oneof themostpromiscuouslyused terms in social scienceandindeedpublicdiscourse,hencealwaysneedstobeinterrogated.Ittypicallymeanscommunity of identity, sometimes described as ‘community of fate’, orcommunity of interest, or, ideally for certain purposes, not least in agrarianpopulism,aunityofthetwo

    ‘Community’ isawidespread tropeofagrarianpopulismtoday,and isespeciallysignificant as it seems to point a way beyond working with (socio-economic)modelsofindividualhouseholdfarming(whichisthecoreofChayanoviantheory).Invocationsof‘community’signifytheclaim,orhope,thattherearesolidaritiesofruralgroups,sufficientlyhomogenousandequal intheir internalsocialrelations,thatcanbedrawnontofacilitatetheagrarianpopulistprojectatlocallevels–orthatcanbeconstructedforthatpurpose.Theformerrestsonnotionsofpre-given(‘traditional’)qualitiesandcapacitiesofruralcommunity(typicallyembeddedinaculturalfoundation)asabasisofco-operation,and,asnotedabove,receiveditsmostintenseattention,andcontestation,inthecaseoftheRussianobschina(ormir).Thiswasacorporateentity responsible forallocating land fromacommonstocktoitsmemberhouseholds,ideallyaccordingtotheirneeds,notleastfamilysize and location in the cycle of household reproduction, highlighted in the

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    9

    Chayanovian notion of demographic differentiation (as opposed to classdifferentiation). The obschina also exercised other functions of village self-government,andwasresponsibletothestatefortaxesandotherobligations.Itisworth noting here the interest in the obschinaof the lateMarx, as part of hismoregeneralconcernwith‘primitive’communityanditsplaceinsocialevolution.(seeShanin1983forthevariousdraftsofMarx’scorrespondencewiththeRussianrevolutionarypopulistVeraZasulich,andanumberofcommentaries).

    However,thesecondkindofuseindicatedabovemaynotneedtoclaimsomeorotherpre-givenqualityasabasisofpeasanteconomicorganization(co-operation,mobilization)butfocusesratheronhow‘community’canbeconstructedaspartof the political project, by farmer activists, outside sympathizers, or somecombination of the two. This then entails some conscious effort to overcomedivisions internal toparticular ‘communities’ –of class, gender, generation, andotherdifferentiation–toachievethegreatergood.Thisisanareaofwhichthereare ‘emblematic instances’, as I called them elsewhere (Bernstein 2014), in theliteratures of La Vìa Campesina and ‘food sovereignty’ and no doubt moreexampleswillbepresentedatthisconference.

    Politicalalliances

    Beyond alliances between farmers constructed through the diffusion of andeducation in agro-ecological farming, and of the means to establish it, andthrough activism and organizing within and between ‘communities’, there areissuesofconnectingwithnon-farmers:‘classesoflabour’inbothcountrysideandtown. Some scholar-activists are more sensitive to class differences in thecountryside(forexample,EdelmanandBorras,2016),buthaveyettoformulateapoliticsofdealingwithit?Thisappliessimilarlytoconnectingwithurban‘classesof labour’,whosefrequentconditionsof immizerationandinsecuritymeansthattheyaredriventoobtainfoodatthelowestpossibleprices(andlowestqualities).There are many instances in the histories of agrarian populism when it waspresented, across a wide ideological spectrum, as the alternative to bothcapitalism and socialism, and to political formations based on the interests ofcapitalandlabour.Arethereexamplesofthistoday?

    More directly (and pragmatically?) there is the pursuit of alliances withenvironmentalmovements,insomecaseswithpoliticalpartiesandgovernments,and lobbyingactivity indifferent typesof internationalarenas,plusadistinctiveprocessoftryingtogetadeclarationof‘Peasants’Rights’adoptedbytheUN.Thisconnectsthenwithissuesofstrategiesandtactics.

    Strategiesandtactics

    While aware of strategic positions and tactical practices in agrarian populismtoday,Iprefertoleavetheirdiscussionatthisconferencetothosewhoarebetterinformed about them than I am, and indeedwho are committed to developingand advancing strategy and tactics of greater and lesser scope and ambition(across the concentric circles noted above). Much of this political work isnecessarily pragmatic much of the time – what works? what works better? inwhatconditions?–andpresentsamovingtarget,ofcourse.

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    10

    4. Agrarianpopulism:hitsandmisses

    Agrarianpopulismthenandnow

    Theconditions,formsandtrajectoriesofagrarianchangeintheworldsoftoday’scapitalismdifferagreatdeal fromthose thatpreoccupiedearliergenerationsofpopulistthinkersandactivists,notleastinnineteenthandearlytwentiethcenturyRussiaandfurtherafieldineasternandsouth-easternEurope.Akeybaselineforinvestigatingandunderstandingdifferencesbetween(‘family’)farmersacrosstheworld today ishowtheyare incorporated in–and ‘resist’ - theongoingunevendevelopmentofcapitalismanditsalwayscontradictorydynamics. Itstrajectoriesare highly diverse, of course, with deep historical roots, although the commonthread – the general theme from which different histories weave complexvariations (to paraphraseGilsenan1982) – is the commodification of productionandreproduction(elaboratedinBernstein2010).

    Today commodification has proceeded, however unevenly, at every site fromvillages to the global capitalist economy. ‘Peasant societies’ of the nineteenthcentury, and well into the twentieth century in some zones of the world, andwhichhadstartedtobindpeasantsintocommodityrelationswithincontinuing(ifchanging) forms of ‘semi-feudalism’ and ‘neo-serfdom’ – of endogenous andcolonial provenance – no longer exist. Perhaps the most common, and leastimplausible,applicationof‘peasantsociety’todayistothevillageorrurallocality,and (moreof a stretch, analytically) inChayanoviannotionsofwhat constitutespeasant‘behaviour’(and‘choice’?).Itisnowimpossibletodesignateas‘peasantsocieties’ national entities shaped only marginally by industrial production andurban concentrations, and by other (non-agrarian) classes, whether stronglyevidentwithincountriesand/or for thepoorestcountrieseffectedthroughtheirintegrationininternationaleconomy.

    Populist rediscoveries and reconstructions of the ‘family’ farmer thus have toplace her and him in the diverse and mutating conditions of contemporarycapitalism.Moreover (asabove) ‘family’ farmersareno longeramajorityof theworld’s population, and even less so if (i) many so designated are betterunderstoodasrurallybased‘classesoflabour’,(ii)onlyaminority(the‘vanguard’)exemplify agro-ecological farming with family labour (and are surplus foodproducers?).

    Therearesomeothermorespecificdifferencesbetweenagrarianpopulismthenandnow.Perhapsthemostsignificantisthestrong,almostdefinitive,framingofagrarianpopulismtodaybyitsecologicalconcerns.Interestingly,this isbuilt intotheappealofLaVíaCampesinatosomefarmersintheNorthaswellasSouth(adivision that, in any case, the notion of ‘new peasantries’, argued from aChayanovian perspective, would transcend). This certainly marks a break from‘classic’ populism; despite the appeal to a globalmovement of ‘agriculturalists’quotedabove,the‘Peasantleaders[ofsouth-easternEurope,HB]neverassumedthat that theirviewshadanyvalidity for industrializedcountries’ (Mitrany1961,156).

    Finally, there are, of course, vastly different circumstances of political context.Thenthereweremoreandlessintensestrugglesbetweencontendingideas,andthe political forces organized around them - agrarian populist and (Marxian)socialist – in conditions of Tsarist autocracy and the incomplete and extremely

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    11

    fragile new ‘democracies’ of eastern and south-eastern Europe afterWWI. Thecourseof such struggles, as always, tookmany twists and turns, unexpectedbythetheoriesandstrategies,practicesandtactics,ofthoseengagedinthem.NowthereislittleinthewayofseriousMarxianpoliticalorganizationandactivismonlarger scales, but a variety of ‘anti-capitalisms’ including agrarian populism andradicalenvironmentalisms.

    Tosummarize,thereareseveralstrategicdifferencesbetweenagrarianpopulismthenandnow.Oneistoday’secologicalframingwhichfocusesattentiononfarmproductionandhowitisdone(adeparturefromtheprimacyofdistributionoverproduction, argued to be characteristic of populism by Kitching 1989, amongothers). Another, somewhat counter-intuitively, is relatively less emphasis onproperty rights in land, despite its centrality to some topical concerns, notably‘land-grabbing’ which is a major theme in agrarian populism, and despite theongoing commodification of land and its effects for ‘peasant’ reproduction anddifferentiation,whichisnot.AthirdisthatLaVíaCampesinaisnotpreoccupiedinthesamewayswithachievinggovernment,letalonestate,power,howevermuchitmightstrivetoinfluencepolicyandhowitisconducted.

    Socio-economicrealities

    On one hand, the major ‘hit’ of agrarian populism today is its critique ofcontemporary capitalist farming and agriculture (comprising all the linkagesupstream and downstream of farming, dominated by agribusiness andincreasinglyfinancecapital), inwhich itoverlapswith(some)materialistanalysis(e.g.Araghi2009,Empson2014,Moore2014).Ontheotherhand,its‘miss’isthatthisisprobablystrongeronecologicalgroundsthanintermsofsocialrelations,totheextentthatthelatterareframedtheoreticallyaroundChayanoviannotionsofthe individual ‘family’ farm and its internal ‘logic’, or politically by appeals to apotentialunited‘peopleoftheland’.

    Someofthereasonsformyscepticismaboutboththese‘framings’wereindicatedabove, and have been elaborated elsewhere (Bernstein 2014, 2016). Central tothis are the various, and admittedly complicated, issues concerning theformations, andmutations, of class relations in the countryside, ofwhich someagrarianpopulistsareawarebuttendtoavoidconfrontingevenwhentheysignalthem. This no doubt stems from agrarian populism as a political projectcommitted to constructing a unity of (most) farmers, transcending whateverdifferences might exist between them, requiring then an awareness of classalliances and their challenges. One major challenge is that the potentialconstituenciesofagrarianpopulismarelocateddifferentlywithincapitalism,withdifferentstrainsontheirreproduction.Thisis,insignificantpart,amatterofclassdifferences between farmers, whether at local levels or far apart (mediatedthroughthefunctioningoftheinternationaleconomy),whichcanberegardedasubiquitous,ifvaryingwidelyintheirmechanisms,forms,degreesandeffects.

    Togiveonetypeof illustration:therearerelatively few, ifany,ruralhouseholdstoday that are able (or wish?) to reproduce themselves wholly through theirfarmingactivity.Thishaslongbeenaconcern,includingamongagrarianpopulists,as shown above: the issue of rural ‘surplus labour’ as well as earnings fromfarming inadequate for reproduction. The celebration of ‘part-time’ farmers(engaged in ‘pluriactivity’), deemed to be otherwise (or because) committed to

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    12

    ‘the peasant way’, is not convincing as an overarching generalization (ordeductionfromfirstprinciples). (As Ihave longarguedinconversationswithJanDouwevanderPloeg, thismaybe thecase for some farmers in someplacesatsometimes,butnotformanyothers–inshort,itisanempiricalquestion).Atthevery least, the prospects of success of ‘part-time’ farmers rest on theopportunitiesofandreturnstoworkoutsideoftheirownfarming,hencetothewiderconditionsofeconomicgrowth,andspecifically labourmarkets,especially‘informal’ labour markets, and above all for ‘footloose’ labour from thecountryside(inJanBreman’spotentterm).

    Afurtherfactorhereisthedemographic.InotedearlierMitrany’sconcernabouttheeffectsof ruralpopulationgrowth insouth-easternEurope in the1920sand1930s following land redistribution but without marked improvement inproductivity, marketed product, and rural seasonal (non-agricultural)employment.Theremaywellbeviablefuturesforsome‘family’farmers(aspettycommodity producers) but hardly for all currently engaged in some or other(small)scaleoffarming,letalonetheirchildren.Indeed,itseemstomethatmanyof themore positive ‘emblematic instances’ of small-scale farming provided byagrarianpopulismtodaynecessarilyentailconditionsthatapplytoonlyaminorityof ‘peasants’ –whetherdeploying agro-ecological ‘alternative’methods; able toexploitorconstructnicheactivitiesand‘nested’markets;toeconomizeoncertain‘inputs’;todiversify(eco-tourismandgastronomy),andthelike–howevermuchenergy and ingenuity they devote to them.What works for some according tolocationandactivityinwidersocio-economiccontextswillnotworkforall.

    Ideological

    ThisislistedforthesakeofcompletenessalbeitIhavelittletoaddheretowhatI’ve sketched already, including the lacuna (‘miss’) of agrarian populism in notconfronting capital-labour relations in today’s capitalism,with all their variationacrosstheglobaleconomy.‘Classesoflabour’arehardlyrestrictedtothe‘classic’industrial proletariat but encompass all engaged in the pursuit oflivelihood/reproduction throughwage employment across different sites of thesocialdivisionoflabour,traversingcountrysideandtown,andsooftencombiningwageworkandpettyproduction.

    Politicalproject

    A final illustration fromMitrany’saccountof south-easternEuropebetween thewars concerns his explanation for the defeat there of agrarian populismwhichgeneratedsomemajorpoliticalpartiesandledorparticipatedingovernmentforshort periods. Apart from the rivalry with socialist currents and parties (whoseagrarianprogrammeswereoftenverysimilar,Mitrany1961,171,173)hepointsto a kindof ‘premature’ formationofpolitical parties - ‘theeasternpeasantriesfound themselves called upon to act as parties before they had been educatedpoliticallyandphilosophicallyasamovement’(ibid,142);totheferociouspowerof reactionwhichcrushed theaspirationsandgainsof thepeasantparties;and,interestingly, to a kindof anticipationof ‘weaponsof theweak’: ‘Thepeasant’spower lies not in action but in resistance; that is why he so often proves anendlesspuzzletorevolutionariesandreactionariesalike.’(ibid,155)

    Itisnotformetopronounceonthepoliticalproject(s)ofagrarianpopulismtoday,especiallytheirpoliticalrecordof‘success’and‘failure’(‘hitsandmisses’)onthe

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    13

    differentscales/arenaswhichagrarianpopulism‘targets’andinwhichitoperates.I can only note that unavoidably the actions of agrarian populism vary in theirradicalism, their scale, and their feasibility, and itwould bemost interesting tolearnhowsuchdifferencesareexpressedwithinagrarianpopulismandenter itsdebatesaboutstrategyandtactics.Further,thearenasinwhichsuccessesmaybeclaimed, from local experiments and networks in agro-ecological farming and‘alternative’marketstoinfluencinginternationalarenasandorganizations,saytheFAO,varygreatly,asnotedearlier.Thisisinparttheproblemofthe‘emblematicinstance’:successinonesmall-scaleprojectinagivenplaceatagiventimeshouldnotbeexaggeratedassignifying thesuccessofwhathappenselsewhere,norofthelargerproject.

    Itisnothelpfultocountertendenciestotriumphalisminthestancesandrhetoricof contemporary agrarian populism with a dismissive stance—there are only‘misses’-butitisalwaysnecessarytoaskabout,andinvestigate,theclassbasesofparticularfarmers’movements,theirdynamicsandtheirpractices.

    References

    Araghi,F.,2009.‘Accumulationbydisplacement,globalenclosures,foodcrisis,andtheecologicalcontradictionsofcapitalism’.Review,32(1):113-146.

    Bernstein,H.,2010.ClassDynamicsofAgrarianChange.HalifaxNS:Fernwood.

    Bernstein,H.,2014.‘Foodsovereigntyviathe“peasantpath”.Ascepticalview’.JournalofPeasantStudies,41(6):1031-1063.

    Bernstein,H.,2016‘Agrarianpoliticaleconomyandmodernworldcapitalism:thecontributionsoffoodregimeanalysis’,JournalofPeasantStudies,43(3),onlineDOI:10.1080/03066150.2015.1101456.

    Edelman,M.andS.M.BorrasJr,2016.PoliticalDynamicsofTransnationalAgrarianMovements.HalifaxNS:Fernwood.

    Empson,M.,2014.LandandLabour.Marxism,EcologyandHumanHistory.London:Bookmarks.

    Gilsenan,M.,1982.RecognizingIslam.London:CroomHelm.

    Harvey,D.,2003.TheNewImperialism.Oxford:OxfordUniversityPress.

    Kitching,G.,1989.DevelopmentandUnderdevelopmentinHistoricalPerspective.Populism,NationalismandIndustrialization.London:Routledge(firstpublished1982).

    Lenin,V.I.,1964.TheDevelopmentofCapitalisminRussia.TheProcessoftheFormationofaHomeMarketforLarge-ScaleIndustry.InCollectedWorksVolume3,Moscow:ProgressPublishers(firstpublished1899).

    Mitrany,D.,1961.MarxAgainstThePeasant.AStudyinSocialDogmatism.NY:CollierBooks(firstpublished1951).

    Moore,J.W.,2015.CapitalismintheWebofLife.EcologyandtheAccumulationofCapital,LondonandNewYork:Verso.

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    14

    Narkiewicz,O.A.,1976.TheGreenFlag.PolishPopulistPolitics1867-1970.London:CroomHelm.

    Schumacher,E.F.,1973.SmallIsBeautiful.EconomicsasifPeopleMattered.NY:Harper&Row.

    Shanin,T.ed,1983.LateMarxandtheRussianRoad.Marxandthe‘PeripheriesofCapitalism’.London:Routledge&KeganPaul.

    Shanin,T.1985.Russiaasa‘Developing’Society.Vol1ofTheRootsofOtherness:Russia’sTurnofCentury.London:Macmillan.

    Shanin,T.1986.Russia1905-7.RevolutionasaMomentofTruth.Vol2ofTheRootsofOtherness:Russia’sTurnofCentury.London:Macmillan.

    Venturi,F.1966.RootsofRevolution.AHistoryofthePopulistandSocialistMovementsinNineteenthCenturyRussia.NewYork:Grosset&Dunlap.

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    15

    NazioartekoHizketaldiaELIKADURARENETORKIZUNAETANEKAZARITZARENERRONKAKXXI.MENDERAKO:

    Munduanork,nolaetazer-nolakoinplikaziosozial,ekonomikoetaekologikorekinelikatukoduenizangodaeztabaidagaia

    InternationalColloquiumTHEFUTUREOFFOODANDCHALLENGESFORAGRICULTUREINTHE21stCENTURY:

    Debatesaboutwho,howandwithwhatsocial,economicandecologicalimplicationswewillfeedtheworld.

    April24th-26th.EuropaCongressPalace.VitoriaGasteiz.Álava.BasqueCountry/Europe

    ColoquioInternacionalELFUTURODELAALIMENTACIÓNYRETOSDELAAGRICULTURAPARAELSIGLOXXI:

    Debatessobrequién,cómoyconquéimplicacionessociales,económicasyecológicasalimentaráelmundo.

    !"/#$deAbril,#-./.PalaciodeCongresosEuropa.Vitoria-Gasteiz.Álava.PaísVasco.Europa.

    GUNTZAILEAK/COLABORAN/COLLABORATINGORGANIZATIONS

    2017koapirilaren24/26.EuropaBiltzarJauregia.Vitoria-Gasteiz.Araba.EuskalHerria.Europa.

  • Elfu

    turodelaalim

    entación

    ylaAgriculturaenelSigloXXI.

    16

    LAGUNTZAEKONOMIKOA/APOYAN/WITHSUPPORTFROM