4
THE ECONOMIC WEEKLY ANNUAL January, 1960 Teaching Economics Joan Robinson For many years I have been employed as a teacher of theoretical economics; I would like to be- lieve that I earn my living honestly, but I often have doubts. I am concerned particularly for India and other developing countries whose economic doctrines come to them mainly from England and in English, Is what we are giving them helpful to their development? IN Cambridge, one or two of our best men, in most years, come from the sub-continent. This is not at all surprising. If talent is fairly evenly distributed in various popu- lations, there must be eight poten- tially first-class men there for every one bred in Britain and where eco- nomic problems are of great im- portance and the natural sciences not very well endowed, a larger pro- portion of talent is attracted to the subject than with us. (In the Thirties, when unemployment was an urgent problem and the discovery of remedies intellectually exciting, economies attracted more talent in England than it docs now.) A small proportion come to English Universities, but a small proportion of a large total comes to quite an appreciable number. These good men who come to us to be taught (and the not-so good ones also) go home often to teach in their turn, and their pupils, too, become teachers and influence thought through other channels. Moreover, the books and the sub- jects chosen for examinations bear the stamp of English teaching. We have a great responsibility on our shoulders. Are we doing more harm or good? In a gloomy mood, I think of the harm. Most students, of course, approach their studies merely with tile aim of passing an examination and acquiring a degree. (This is not a matter of natural talent, but of character and circumstance. Some who are naturally brilliant may set themselves this limited aim. Some less clever may be more seri- ous.) The exam-passers learn the trick of saying what is expected; of not asking themselves what is meant by what they are saying (for that is disturbing and dangerous and may lead to losing marks), of repeating the particular formula which sounds as though it was relevant to each particular question. In India, espe- cially, where the ancient belief in the power of words as such is still strong, this comes quite naturally. The exam-passer who does well be- comes in due course an examiner and by then he has quite lost any doubts he may once have had to stifle. He has come to believe that this kind of thing really is education. And so the system feeds on itself. What about the few who are serious, who really want to learn something? What do we do for them? The serious student is often attracted to economics by humani- tarian feeling and patriotism—he wants to learn how to choose eco- nomic policies that will increase human welfare. Orthodox teaching dellccts these feelings into the dreary desert of so-called Welfare Econo- mics, a system of ideas based on a mechanistic psychology of a com- pletely individualistic pursuit of pleasure and avoidance of pain, which no one believes to be a cor- rect account of human nature, dish- ed up in algebraical formulae which do not even pretend to be applicable to actual data. As he goes deeper into the matter, he reads some bril- liant and subtle authors who debunk the whole subject and show conclu- sively that its methodology was in- admissible. For most, this is too bitter a pill to swallow and they desperately cling to some scraps of what they have learned because no other way has been offered of for- mulating the vague benevolent feel- ings with which they began. The serious student was hoping, also, to learn something that would help him to make up his mind on the great question that lies open be- fore all the developing countries. How far can private-enterprise capi talism l*e made to serve national ends? Why is it that the Socialist countries appear to develop faster than the democracies? Is the cost that they exact from their people necessary, or could the job be done with less pain? Must he make an all-or-none choice or is there a mid- dle way? 3 He soon begins to notice that, without any overt discussion of the question, he is being indoctrinated with notions soaked in a prejudice for laisser-faire. This is partly the result of a mere time-lag. Nine- teenth Century economic teaching was built .up round the conception of the merits of the free market, and in particular, of free trade (which at that time favoured Brit- ish national interests, though it was damaging to India); the modern text-books are still much influenced by the masters of that period. It is partly the result of the choice of curriculum. A large proportion of his time is taken up by the theory of relative prices. The question of the distribution of given resources amongst alternative ends, subject to the condition that there is an equit- able (and not very unequal) distri- bution of purchasing power among the families concerned, lends itself to exhibiting a free market in a favourable light; the student is re- quired to work out exercises devised to show how, in these conditions, interference with the free play of the forces of supply and demand causes harm to the individuals who make up the market. All this is very complicated, and when modi- fied by modern embellishments such as the theory of oligopoly and im- periect competition, may well occu- py a year of lectures and reading. If the serious student has the hardi- hood to ask: but are resources given, and is income distributed equitably? he is made to feel fool- ish. Do you not understand that these are necessary simplifying as- sumptions for the analysis of prices? You cannot expect to do everything at once. It is true that we cannot, in the time available, leach everything that we would like. But why do we pick out for treatment just that selection of topics that is least likely to raise any questions of fundamental im- portance? 173

Teaching Economics - epw.in

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    5

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Teaching Economics - epw.in

T H E E C O N O M I C W E E K L Y A N N U A L January, 1960

T e a c h i n g Economics Joan Robinson

For many years I have been employed as a teacher of theoretical economics; I would like to be­lieve that I earn my living honestly, but I often have doubts.

I am concerned particularly for India and other developing countries whose economic doctrines come to them mainly from England and in English,

Is what we are giving them helpful to their development?

I N Cambridge, one o r two o f our best men, in most years, come

f rom the sub-continent. This is not a t all su rpr i s ing . I f talent is f a i r l y evenly d is t r ibuted in various popu­lations, there must be eight poten­t i a l l y first-class men there for every one bred in B r i t a i n and where eco­nomic problems are of great i m ­portance and the natura l sciences not very wel l endowed, a larger pro­po r t i on of talent is attracted to the subject than w i t h us. ( I n the Thi r t i es , when unemployment was an urgent p rob lem and the discovery of remedies intel lectual ly exc i t ing , economies attracted more talent in England than it docs now.) A small p ropo r t i on come to Engl ish Universi t ies , but a small p r o p o r t i o n of a large total comes to qui te an appreciable number.

These good men who come to us to be taught (and the not-so good ones also) go home often to teach in their t u rn , and their pup i l s , too, become teachers and influence thought th rough other channels. Moreover, the books and the sub­jects chosen for examinations bear the stamp of Engl i sh teaching. We have a great responsibi l i ty on our shoulders. Are we do ing more ha rm or good?

In a gloomy mood, I t h ink of the h a r m . Most students, of course, approach their studies merely w i t h t i le a i m of passing an examinat ion and acqu i r ing a degree. (Th is is not a matter of na tura l talent, but of character and circumstance. Some who are na tura l ly b r i l l i a n t may set themselves this l im i t ed a i m . Some less clever may be more seri­ous.) The exam-passers learn the t r i c k of saying what is expected; of not asking themselves what is meant by what they are saying ( f o r that is d i s t u rb ing and dangerous and may lead to losing m a r k s ) , of repeating the par t i cu la r formula w h i c h sounds as though it was relevant to each par t icu la r question. In I n d i a , espe­c ia l ly , where the ancient belief in the power of words as such is s t i l l

strong, this comes qui te na tura l ly . The exam-passer who does wel l be­comes in due course an examiner and by then he has quite lost any doubts he may once have had to stifle. He has come to believe that this k i n d of th ing really is education. A n d so the system feeds on itself.

What about the few who are serious, who really want to learn something? W h a t do we do fo r them? The serious student is of ten attracted to economics by humani -ta r ian feeling and pa t r io t i sm—he wants to learn how to choose eco­nomic policies that w i l l increase human welfare. Or thodox teaching dellccts these feelings in to the dreary desert of so-called Wel fa re Econo­mics, a system of ideas based on a mechanistic psychology of a com­pletely i nd iv idua l i s t i c pursu i t of pleasure and avoidance of p a i n , w h i c h no one believes to be a cor­rect account of human nature, dish­ed up in algebraical formulae w h i c h do not even pretend to be applicable to actual data. As he goes deeper in to the matter, he reads some b r i l ­l iant and subtle authors who debunk the whole subject and show conclu­sively that its methodology was i n ­admissible. For most, this is too bi t ter a p i l l to swallow and they desperately c l ing to some scraps of what they have learned because no other way has been offered of for­mu la t i ng the vague benevolent feel­ings w i t h wh ich they began.

The serious student was hop ing , also, to learn something that would help h i m to make up his m i n d on the great question that lies open be­fore all the developing countries. How far can private-enterprise capi talism l*e made to serve national ends? W h y is i t that the Socialist countries appear to develop faster than the democracies? Is the cost that they exact f rom their people necessary, or could the j o b be done w i t h less pa in? Must he make an all-or-none choice or is there a m i d ­dle way? 3

He soon begins to notice that, wi thout any overt discussion of the question, he is being indoctr inated w i t h notions soaked in a pre judice for laisser-faire. Th i s is pa r t l y the result of a mere t ime-lag. Nine­teenth Century economic teaching was bu i l t .up round the conception of the meri ts of the free market , and in par t icu lar , of free trade ( w h i c h at that t ime favoured Br i t ­ish nat ional interests, though it was damag ing to I n d i a ) ; the modern text-books are s t i l l much influenced by the masters of that per iod . I t is p a r t l y the result of the choice of c u r r i c u l u m . A large p r o p o r t i o n of his t ime is taken up by the theory of relat ive prices. The question of the d i s t r i bu t ion of given resources amongst alternative ends, subject to the condi t ion that there is an equit­able (and not very unequal) d i s t r i ­bu t ion of purchasing power among the famil ies concerned, lends itself to e x h i b i t i n g a free market in a favourable l i g h t ; the student is re-qu i r ed to work out exercises devised to show how, in these conditions, interference w i t h the free play of the forces of supply and demand causes ha rm to the ind iv idua l s who make up the market. A l l this is very complicated, and when modi­fied by modern embellishments such as the theory of ol igopoly and i m -periect competi t ion, may well occu­py a year of lectures and reading. If the serious student has the ha rd i ­hood to ask: but are resources given, and is income d i s t r ibu ted equi tably? he is made to feel fool­ish. Do you not understand that these are necessary s i m p l i f y i n g as­sumptions for the analysis of prices? Y o u cannot expect to do everything at once.

It is t rue that we cannot, in the t ime avai lable , leach everything that we would l ike . But why do we pick out fo r treatment just that selection of topics that is least l ikely to raise any questions of fundamental im­

p o r t a n c e ?

173

Page 2: Teaching Economics - epw.in

January, 1960 THE ECONOMIC WEEKLY ANNUAL

174

Page 3: Teaching Economics - epw.in

THE ECONOMIC WEEKLY January, 1960

A R I D LANDS

T r u d g i n g th rough these a r i d lands, the serious student s t i l l hopes to l ea rn something about develop­ment, p l a n n i n g , inf la t ion and al l that concerns the b u r n i n g questions of Ind ia today. Here the mere p a s -sure of events has forced some new questions into the c u r r i c u l u m and a new theoretical apparatus of c a p i t a l / output ratios and g rowth rates has been hastily botched up to meet the need. Systematic teaching, however, for the most par t s t i l l rests at the stage of the o ld e q u i l i b r i u m theory. Take, for example, the question of choosing the c a p i t a l / o u t p u t rat io in f r a m i n g the plans for industrial isa­t i on . The text-book theory says, no more than that, i f we compare two economies, each already in e q u i l i ­b r i u m , w i t h the same total value of capital already in existence in each, the one w i t h the lower level of real wages w i l l have (on certain stated assumptions about compet i t ion etc) a h igher level of employment . That is where the argument is left . If the student falls in to the t rap of concluding that cu t t ing wages would cause employment to increase, very l i k e l y no one w i l l go out of their way to expla in w h y this is a non-sequitur.

The prestige of the teachers and the books bears down on the serious student w i t h a heavy weight . l i e learns to distrust his native common sense and to curb his generous im­pulses, He submits himself to a course of miseducation and comes out, not " b y the same door wherein he went''- but by another door, in the wrong street.

So in my gloomy mood. But even at the gloomiest, I do not th ink of g i v i n g up. The subject does exist. For better or worse it has become the basis of a flourishing profession. There is no s topping i t now. We must keep on pegging away and t r y to make the best of i t .

BEGIN WITH ECONOMIC SYSTEMS

H o w wou ld I l ike to sec teaching reformed? First , do not let us bother about the exam-passers. Whatever we teach they s t i l l reduce to slogans, and new slogans cannot be more mis-educating than the o ld ones. If the new ones are less easy to detach f r o m real i ty , they migh t even be a shade less mis educating.

For the serious students, I w o u l d take the b u l l by the horns and start f r o m the beg inn ing to discuss various types of economic system. Every

society (except Robinson Crusoe) has to have some rules of the game for organis ing p roduc t ion and the d i s t r ibu t ion of the produc t . Laisser faire capi ta l ism is on ly one of the possible sets of rules, and one in fact which is unemployable in a pure f o r m . It always has to be mixed w i t h some measures of col­lective cont ro l . The I n d i a n scene provides examples of pre-capitalist, capitalist and socialist games being played side by side. Students ac­quainted w i t h the old fast-vanishing w o r l d can help in t r y i n g to puzzle out the economic analysis of i ts func­t ion ing and to test out the meaning of concepts such as wages and capi­ta l in non-capitalist contexts.

A d a m Smi th , Ricardo, M a r x , Mar-shall and Keynes would be treated in terms of the model of an economic system that they each had in m i n d and of the actual problems that each sought to solve.

DISPLACE THEORY OF RELATIVE PRICES

I should displace the theory of the relative prices of commodit ies f rom the centre of the p ic ture and make the m a i n topic product ion , accumu­lat ion and d i s t r ibu t ion looked at f rom the po in t of view of an economy taken as a whole. Keynes's General Theory then falls in to place as the short-period section of a t ru ly gene­ral theory. Here pr ice theory comes in as an element in the theory of d i s t r ibu t ion , for the relat ion of prices to money-wage rates in the indust r ia l sector of an economy is one of the determinants of the dis­t r i b u t i o n of proceeds between work­ers and capital ists or the state, and the relat ion of agr icu l tu ra l to manu­fac tur ing prices is a ma in determi­nant of d i s t r ibu t ion between sectors of the economy.

Markets and the laws of supply and demand I should treat not only in terms of an ideal e u i l i b r i u m already achieved but also in terms of actual dealings in commodities, w i t h their tendency to develop cob­web cycles, and the violent shocks that arc given f r o m t ime to t ime to the communit ies dependent on them.

Welfare I should treat in human terms and teach the students to look, not for "preference surfaces", but for objective tests of standards of n u t r i t i o n and health.

In all this I should emphasise that economic theory, in itself, preaches no doctrines and cannot establish any universally v a l i d laws. It is a

175

method of o rder ing ideas and fo rm­ula t ing questions. For this reason, I should pay a good deal of atten­t ion to method. I should insist upon the d is t inc t ion between an account­ing ident i ty , a statement of equi l i ­b r i u m conditions and a summary of econometric facts. Y = C + S, (where Y is net value of national income of a per iod , C is the value of purchases of consumable goods and S, net saving,) is an ident i ty . The word 'net ' covers a balancing factor (amort isa t ion of pre-existing capital) wh ich makes the two sides equal by def in i t ion . S = sY (where s is the p ropor t ion of national in­come normally saved) is a statement of conditions of e q u i l i b r i u m ; its whole significance lies in the sense given to normally. A table of figures g i v i n g estimates of S and Y over some past per iod is a statement, ex post, of supposed facts; its signi­ficance depends largely on the rel i­ab i l i t y of the estimates. None of these tells us anyth ing about causa­t ion and models b u i l t w i t h these bricks w i l l never stand up. To f ind causal relations wc want to know how individuals behave and bow the behaviour of various groups reacts on each other. I should t ry to break down the awe that students feel for formulae, not so as to induce a sceptical d r i f t into intellectual n ih i ­lism but so as to fo rm the habit of p i ck ing them to pieces and put t ing them together again, w i t h the ambi-g u i t i e s cleaned o i l , and keeping them f i r m l y in their place as useful adjuncts to common sense, not as substitutes for i t .

A l l this sounds dry and fo rma l i s t s but, i l lustrated first w i th precise imaginary simple examples, and then w i t h rough and inexact actual examples, leading up to questions of real importance, it can be made in -leresting and educational for the serious students. The exam-passers wi l l not be any the worse for i t .

A generation well educated, re-sistent to fudging , imbued w i t h the h u m i l i t y and the p r ide of genuine scientists, could make contribution? both to knowledge and to the con-duct of affairs that no one need be ashamed of.

Re tu rn ing f r o m this happy day dream, my gloom is a l l the deeper. To w r i t e down what I want to see emphasises how unl ike ly i t is that I ever, shall . But, courage! We must t r y as best we may to do a l i t t l e good here and there to set in the scales against all the ha rm.

Page 4: Teaching Economics - epw.in