33
Bachelor Thesis Organization & Strategy 2010 The determinants of partner selection for the performance of strategic alliances Written by: Konstantin Petrov ANR: 103709 Study Program: International Business Supervisor: Dean Hennessy Word count: 7923 10.06.2010

The determinants of partner selection for the performance

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

Bachelor Thesis Organization & Strategy 2010

The determinants of partner selection for the performance of strategic alliances Written by: Konstantin Petrov ANR: 103709 Study Program: International Business

Supervisor: Dean Hennessy

Word count: 7923

10.06.2010

Page 2: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

2

Management summary

Despite the obvious advantages that strategic alliances can offer, they appear to be very fragile

organizational form, which very often fail to bring expected value to their participants. In order for

alliances to be successful, various factors should be considered by managers. Some of the factors should

be taken into account after the actual formation of an alliance, some factors are beyond managerial

control, and others should be carefully considered before the actual formation of strategic alliances.

Current paper focuses on the factors that are particularly important for the performance of strategic

alliances during the phase of partner selection. The two crucial factors for the selection of compatible

partners being studied are complementary resources and interorganizational trust. It is indicated that in

general, higher degree of complementarity of partners’ resources and high degree of interorganizational

trust have positive effects on the performance of strategic alliances. Moreover, it is found out, that

apart from direct influence interorganizational trust and complementary resources have on alliances’

performance, they are also interdependent factors. After all, it is concluded that in order for strategic

alliances to be successful, it is important to choose partners with a high degree of complementary

resources to the resources already obtained by an organization, and partners with whom high degree of

interorganizational trust can be maintained.

Page 3: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

3

Table of contents

Management summary …………………………………………………………………………………. 2 Chapter 1 – Introduction………………………………………………………………………………… 4

1.1 Problem indication…………………………………………………………………………………………………. 4 1.2 Problem statement………………………………………………………………………………………………… 4 1.3 Research questions………………………………………………………………………………………………… 5 1.4 Research relevance……………………………………………………………………………………………….. 5 1.5 Research design and data collection........................................................................... 6 1.6 Structure of the thesis……………………………………………………………………………………………. 6

Chapter 2 – Strategic alliance and performance measurement ………………………. 9 2.1 Competition versus cooperation……………………………………………………………………………. 9 2.2 From cooperation to strategic alliances……………………………………………………………….. 10 2.3 Strategic alliances do fail……………………………………………………………………………………… 11 2.4 Performance variable…………………………………………………………………………………………… 12

Chapter 3 – Complementary and idiosyncratic resources………………………………. 14 3.1 Resource-based view……………………………………………………………………………………………. 14 3.2 Resource requirements………………………………………………………………………………………… 14

3.2.1 Rareness……………………………………………………………………………………………………………. 15 3.2.2 Inimitability……………………………………………………………………………………………………….. 15

3.2.2.1 Historical conditions…………………………………..…………………………………………………… 15 3.2.2.2 Causal Ambiguity……………………………………………………..…………………………………….. 16 3.2.2.3 Social complexity…………………………………………………………………..……………………….. 16

3.2.3 Non-substitutability…………………………………………………………………………………………… 16

3.3 Market imperfections in obtaining valuable resources…………………………………………. 17 3.4 Complementary resources and performance of an alliance…………………………………. 17

3.4.1 Complementary resources……………………………………………………………………………….. 17 3.4.2 Idiosyncratic resources……………………………………………………………………………………... 18

Chapter 4 – Interorganizational trust……………………………………………………………. 19 4.1 Transaction cost theory………………………………………………………………………………………… 19

4.1.1 Opportunism…………………………………………………………………………………………………….. 19 4.1.2 Bounded rationality…………………………………………………………………………………………… 20

4.2 Concept of interorganizational trust……………………………………………………………………. 20 4.3 Relationship between trust and performance of strategic alliance…………………….. 21

4.3.1 Trust as a deterrent of opportunistic behavior………………………………………………… 21 4.3.2 Trust as a tool to economize on bounded rationality……………………………………….. 21 4.3.3 Trust as reducing costs of negotiating………………………………………………………………. 21 4.3.4 Trust as a tool for reducing conflicts…………………………………………………………………. 22 4.3.5 Other ways through which trust can stimulate performance of strategic alliance 23

4.4 Trust and its effect on idiosyncratic resources creation………………………………………. 23

Chapter 5 – Conclusions and recommendations……………………………………………. 25 5.1 Conclusions…………………………………………………………………………………………………………… 25 5.2 Limitations and practical recommendations………………………………………………………… 26

List of references………………………………………………………………………………………….. 28

Page 4: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

4

Chapter 1 – Introduction

1.1 Problem indication

Recently, it became more common to use different forms of cooperation across all types of firms

competing in various industries (Lei, Slocum, Pitts, 1997). To give an example of growing popularity of

various forms of cooperation, the number of joint ventures in the U.S. grew by 423% over the period

1986-1995 (Hitt, Ireland & Hoskisson, 1997) and keeps on rising. Various forms of cooperation between

organizations exist, and one of such forms– is strategic alliance.

Lately, however, many strategic alliances failed to be successful and were not bringing value to their

participants. Thus, results of research by Das and Teng (2000) show that alliances have failure rates of

70%. Existing literature (Dacin, Hitt & Levitas, 1997; Lambe et al., 2002; Kogut, 1989) emphasizes

incompatibility of partners as one of the most important reasons for that. Therefore, there is a growing

need for a careful research on the aspects of choosing compatible partner, which will lead to higher

alliance performance and bring satisfaction to all the parties involved in it.

There exist many factors, which should be considered while selecting a compatible partner. However, in

the following research the influence of two factors, namely complementary resources and

interorganizational trust on the performance of strategic alliance will be analyzed. The selection for

those factors was done in accordance with existing literature, which points out interorganizational trust

(Zaheer et al., 1998; Elmuti, Kathawala, (2001) and partners’ complementary resources (Das & Teng,

2000; Lambe et al., 2002) as the most important aspects of compatible partner selection for the future

alliance performance.

1.2 Problem statement

The following research will be aimed at analyzing the influence of partners’ compatibility on the

performance of strategic alliance. It will investigate the factors which contribute the most to the

performance of strategic alliances during the phase of partner selection. Since partners’ compatibility is

pretty broad concept, it had to be operationalized before it could be studied. Complementary resources

and interorganizational trust are going to be considered as the main components of partners’

compatibility in the current paper. The question to be answered in the following thesis is: “How do

partner’s complementary resources and interorganizational trust influence the performance of strategic

alliance?”

Page 5: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

5

In the following research, performance of strategic alliances is going to be a dependent variable.

Interorganizational trust and complementary resources of each individual partner are going to be

considered as independent variables. However, unlike various existing literature, only indirect effects of

complementary resources and interorganizational trust will be supposed in the following paper. The

effect of complementary resources is going to be mediated by idiosyncratic resources. The effect of

interorganizational trust on the performance of strategic alliances will be mediated by the degree of

transaction cost. Moreover, the moderating effect of interorganizational trust is going to be considered

in relation to complementary resources input and idiosyncratic resources creation.

1.3 Research questions

After the problem statement and the relationship between variables had been formulated, the research

questions can be stated. The following questions are going to be answered throughout the research:

1. To what extent can degree of complementary resources of each partner influence the degree of

idiosyncratic resources creation?

2. What is the relationship between the degree of idiosyncratic resources and performance of

strategic alliances?

3. What is the influence of interorganizational trust between partners on the transaction costs?

4. What is the relationship between transaction costs and performance of strategic alliances

5. To what extent can interorganizational trust influence relationship between complementary

resources of each partner and the degree of idiosyncratic resources creations?

1.4 Research relevance

The following research is expected to be highly relevant from both: academic and managerial

perspectives. Previously, various researches were aimed at studying the relevance of different factors in

explaining variance of strategic alliance performance. The following paper will concentrate on the

factors which are crucially important at the stage of partner selection. It will give complete emphasis

particularly to two very influential factors, namely complementary resources and interorganizational

trust. Unlike many researches, the effects of complementary resources and interorganizational trust are

not going to be direct, but rather mediated through idiosyncratic resources and transaction costs

respectively. Moreover, contrasting to the researchers which were studying effects of

interorganizational trust and complementary resources independently of each other, the

interdependency between these factors will be considered in the following paper.

Page 6: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

6

From the managerial perspective following thesis will be very important, since it is going to point out

factors influencing selection of compatible partners, which is vital for the future performance of

strategic alliances. Knowing factors influencing performance of future strategic decisions (e.g. selection

of compatible partner) can be highly important for the success in the short and/or long runs.

1.5 Research design and data collection

The following research is going to be mainly descriptive. The main tool to tackle the problem previously

indicated will be the literature review. Moreover, real life examples might be used when needed. The

independent variables together with mediating and moderating variables are going to be carefully

analyzed in order to fulfill the demands of research objective.

The secondary sources are going to be used to gain access to the necessary data. This method is chosen

to be the most reliable in the current settings for various reasons. First of all, it is going to be possible to

save time by referring to already existing information. Second of all, this method of collecting data is

going to be cost efficient. The only drawback of that method is the possibility of existing information to

become obsolete up to the current moment. The website of the library of Tilburg University is going to

be used as the main source of journals, books and articles, as it offers several reliable databases, each

containing various data. In order to avoid referencing low quality papers, the “Journal Citation Reports”

tool will be implemented. That tool will help to distinguish between low and high quality papers.

1.6 Structure of the thesis

In the remaining chapters all the variables are going to be discussed separately. The main part of the

thesis is going to be divided into chapters in order to discuss each variable in turn. First, the dependent

variable will be described. Then, remaining variables and their influence on dependent variable will be

analyzed. The graphical representation of the relationships among the variables can be represented in

the following diagram:

Page 7: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

7

+

+

_

+

_

In the second chapter notion of organizational cooperation will be introduced. Reasons for increased

organizational cooperation will be discussed. Later, the transition from organizational cooperation to

strategic alliances will be done in order to bring in the idea of strategic alliances gradually. First of all,

the increased growth of strategic alliances will be illustrated. Then, several advantages of strategic

alliances will be discussed briefly. Afterwards, it will be shown, that despite obvious advantages of

strategic alliances, the failure rate still remains high – calling for careful research on the determinants of

alliance performance. The performance variable will be discussed in the end of the chapter.

In the third chapter the concept of resource-based view of strategic alliance creation will be introduced.

Then, the relationship between complementary resources of partners and the performance of strategic

alliance is going to be discussed. Such an effect is going to be mediated through the idiosyncratic

resources of strategic alliance. It is going to be analyzed why is it so important for partners to have high

degree of complementary resources in order to increase performance of the strategic alliances.

In the fourth chapter, the relationship between the second independent variable (interorganizational

trust between partners) and dependent variable will be analyzed. For that the transaction cost theory

and its main assumptions will be introduced. Then, the concept of interorganizational trust will be

discussed. In the end, several ways through which interorganizational trust can influence performance

of strategic alliances are going to be analyzed. It will be shown that relationship between trust and

performance of strategic alliances is mediated by transaction costs. Finally, the moderating effect of

interorganizational trust will be considered. Interorganizational trust is going to moderate the

Performance of strategic

alliance

(dependent variable)

Complementary

resources of individual

partners

(independent variable)

Interorganizational trust

(independent variable +

moderating variable)

Idiosyncratic

resources of

strategic alliance

(mediating

variable)

Transaction costs

(mediating variable)

Page 8: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

8

relationship between complementary resources of each individual partner and degree of idiosyncratic

resources creation within strategic alliances.

In the last chapter results from all the preceding chapters of the research will be summed up. Various

conclusions for managers with regard to choosing compatible partners will be provided. Moreover, the

limitations of the following paper and practical recommendations will be discussed.

Page 9: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

9

Chapter 2 – Strategic alliance and performance

measurement

2.1 Competition versus cooperation

Through time, there was a growing interest in the intensity of competition in organizing economic

activities (Williamson, 1975) and making strategic decisions (Porter, 1980). Competition was considered

to be a driving vehicle in creating new products, services, technologies, which would differentiate one

firm from others, give it competitive advantage, and help to provide consumers with better selection of

products. The definition given to a competitive firm by Richardson (1972): “island in a sea of market

relations”, represents fully the leading paradigm at that time. Firms were considered as alien entities

competing harshly in the market for the customers, sales, and profits. Any form of cooperation was

unthought-of at that time, putting all the emphasis on competition.

However, recently researches paid increased attention to the disadvantages of competition. Traditional

view on organizing economic activities and making strategic decisions through competition became less

useful in the presence of highly turbulent environment (Zineldin, 2004). The more effective approach of

maintaining relationships through cooperation has been developed. Thus, Emery (1967) suggests that

cooperation is of vital importance as organizations are encountering challenges of unstable

environment. Under a new paradigm firms are seen as interdependent agents pursuing common

interests and deriving mutual benefits (Contractor & Lorange, 1988). Firms are no longer expected to

fiercely compete over all areas of their business. On the contrary, increased cooperation over various

dimensions is expected to be present.

One doesn’t need to search a lot for the instances of cooperative behaviors. For example, one can think

of a recent alliance between KLM and Air France, or cooperation between Peugeot and Toyota in 2005

on shared components for a new city car. According to Dagnino & Padula (2002): “the market is not

(any more) an atomistic structure based on instant exchange, but it becomes a system of interactive and

continuous relationships in which the firms progressively strengthen their reciprocal commitments and

realize a process of mutual adaptation and joint value creation.” The growing importance of

globalization, competition on international markets, turbulent competitive environment, and complex

technologies developments strengthened the view on inter-firm cooperation, as a tool through which

mutual benefits can be gained and firms’ performances can be stimulated (Dyer & Singh, 1998;

Lorenzoni & Lipparini, 1999).

Page 10: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

10

2.2 From cooperation to strategic alliances

One of such forms of cooperation – is strategic alliance, and recently it became one of the most

important organizational forms which is growing in popularity dramatically in recent years (Kale & Singh,

2007). Mowery et al. (1998) presents the following graph in his research, emphasizing rapid growth of

strategic alliances in the period of 1975-1989:

McCarter and Northcraft (2007) define strategic alliances as a specific form of voluntary tie between

businesses, organized in order to handle the uncertainty caused by environmental forces which cannot

be controlled by the organizations. Additionally, Kale et al. (2000) define strategic alliances as purposive

strategic relationships between separate organizations that “share compatible goals, strive for mutual

benefits, and acknowledge a high level of mutual dependence” (Mohr and Spekman, 1994).

There are several potential advantages of strategic alliances which assist organizations in maintaining

superior competitive positions. Bierly and Gallagher (2007) emphasize three advantages of strategic

alliances. First of all, alliances allow firms to focus on their own core competences and rely on their

partners in other areas outside of scope of their core competencies. Second of all, increase in firm’s

strategic flexibility by sharing costs and resources over range of technologies and activities can be

considered as another advantage. Finally, they propose, that through strategic alliances firms can gain

access to new competitive advantages by getting access to complementary technologies and new

markets. However, despite already mentioned, several other advantages of strategic alliances exist.

Sinha (2001) argues that strategic alliances can assist organizations in avoiding threat of expropriation

by the host country. Moreover, existing literature emphasizes economies of scale, shared risks and R&D

costs, reduction in competition (Nielsen, 2003), uncertainty management, and facilitation of tacit

Page 11: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

11

collusion (Barney & Hesterly, 2008) as motives for strategic alliance creation. The summary of the

potential benefits of strategic alliances can be found in the Table 1 below.

Potential benefit Author

Focus on one’s own competencies Bierly and Gallagher (2007)

Increase in one’s strategic flexibility Bierly and Gallagher (2007)

New competitive advantage development Bierly and Gallagher (2007)

Avoid threat of host government

expropriation

Sinha (2001)

Economies of scale Nielsen (2003)

Shared risks Nielsen (2003)

Shared R&D costs Nielsen (2003)

Reduction in competition Nielsen (2003)

Uncertainty management Barney & Hesterly (2008)

Facilitation of tacit collusion Barney & Hesterly (2008)

Table 1. Potential benefits of strategic alliances

2.3 Strategic alliances do fail

Even though, scientific literature predicts lots of potential advantages for strategic alliance membership,

the reality shows the true complexity of such form of cooperation. There are drawbacks to the

successful implementation of cooperation through alliances, which might lead to unexpected outcomes,

including total failures (e.g. bankruptcy). In order to avoid such unpleasant outcomes, aspects of

strategic alliances have to be researched carefully, defining determinants of high performance. Existing

literature points out, that most of the failures in alliances occurred due to a partners’ incompatibility

(Dacin, Hitt & Levitas, 1997).The results of a survey conducted by Technology Associates and Alliances

(Elmuti, Kathawala, 2001) in order to reveal most important factors for the success of alliances

emphasize the importance of careful partner selection, in order to avoid potential incompatibilities,

which might detriment the alliance performance. The results of the survey presented in Table 2 reveal

that almost 70% of all managers, who took part in the survey, indicated ‘partner selection’ as the most

important factor influencing the success of alliances.

Page 12: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

12

Table 2.

Therefore, it is of crucial importance to know which factors are essentially important on the phase of

partner selection for the performance of strategic alliances. In the proceeding chapters, the

independent variables such as complementary resources and interorganizational trust will be discussed

with regard to their influence on the performance of strategic alliances. Moreover, the research will be

added with the moderating effect of interorganizational trust and mediating variables (idiosyncratic

resources and transaction costs), in order to increase reliability and have more robust results.

Conclusions, limitations and recommendations for further research will be provided in the end of the

research.

2.4 Performance variable

Before the research is conducted further, it is important to operationalize the performance variable.

Various researchers were using such measures of alliance performance as financial survival (Killing,

1983), ownership instability (Gomes-Casseres, 1987), and duration (Kogut, 1988). Others were using

financial measures, such as profitability and sales growth (Mohr & Spekman, 1994). However, there is

obvious lack of agreement among researchers over the most reliable and effective measure.

According to Das and Teng (2003), performance measures can be directed towards two distinct loci:

alliance itself or each individual partner. “The former represents how the alliance as an entity performs.

The latter addresses the benefits to the partners - individually or collectively - from the alliance” (Olk,

2002). Das and Teng (2003) propose that measures focusing on each individual partner are more

advantageous since it is hard to evaluate alliance performance independently of interests of each

partner forming it. However, interests of each partner may not be always compatible and therefore it

Page 13: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

13

creates problems in evaluating performance correctly. For instance, satisfaction of one partner with the

goal achievement may be simultaneous with dissatisfaction of another partner (Das & Teng, 2003). For

that reason, performance measure proposed by Beamish (1987) and Harrigan (1988) is going to be used

in the following research. They proposed that alliance performance has to be measured with regard to

mutual satisfaction of partners from achievement of strategic objectives. If one partner gains

satisfaction on the expense of others, performance of such alliance cannot be considered as successful

Das and Teng (2003).

Page 14: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

14

Chapter 3 – Complementary and idiosyncratic resources

3.1 Resource-based view

Resource-based view (RBV) was extensively researched in various existing literature (Penrose, 1959;

Teece, 1988; Barney, 1986) as another approach of competitive advantage achievement, in contrast to

Porter’s (1980) competitive forces framework. While in a competitive forces framework organizational

success depends on external to the organization factors, RBV indicates the importance of internal

organizational factors. According to Mowery et al. (1998) organization in a RBV is best characterized as a

“collection of sticky and difficult-to-imitate resources and capabilities” which provide organizations with

unique competitive advantages. Mowery et al. (1998) proposes several categories of organizational

resources which might contribute to the development of organizational competitive advantage:

physical, such as technology; intangible, such as brand awareness or loyalty; knowledge, idiosyncratic

routines, and complex networks, aimed at product distribution and marketing.

Existing literature (Grant, 1991; Barney, 1991; Hoffer and Schendel, 1978) provides several resource

classifications; yet most of them lack sufficient theoretical underpinnings (Das & Teng, 2000). Miller and

Shamsie (1996) suggest that such a drawback of firm-specific resources classification can be avoided, in

case of identifying them in two broad categories on the basis of barriers to imitability, namely property-

based resources and knowledge-based resources. Property-based resources are legal properties of a

firm, which cannot be easily copied by the competitors due to legal protection imposed on them

through property rights (Miller & Shamsie, 1996). Such resources might include financial capital, physical

resources and/or human resources (Das & Teng, 2000). Knowledge-based resources are intangible

know-how and skills, which can hardly be copied by the competitors due to their vagueness and

ambiguousness (Das & Teng, 2000). Such resources consist of tacit know-how, skills, and technical and

managerial systems of a firm, which are not legally protected (Hall, 1992).

3.2 Resource requirements

Various researchers (Barney, 1991; Peteraf, 1993) studying RBV mention that not every resource in

organization can generate competitive advantage. Barney (1991) proposes that in order for a resource

to be realized in a competitive advantage it has to be valuable. He identifies valuable resources, as those

which contribute organizations to the development of strategies, improving their efficiencies or

effectiveness. Accordingly, Fahy and Smithee (1999) state that efficiency and effectiveness of an

organization can be ameliorated in case of bringing value to the customer through differentiated

products or lowest costs. Valuable resources help organization to grasp the opportunities and avoid

Page 15: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

15

threats, which influences competitive advantage creation (Barney, 1991). RBV suggests typical features

of resources, which can be called valuable, namely rareness, inimitability, and non-substitutability.

3.2.1 Rareness

Barney (1991) suggests that competitive advantage cannot be sustained or even achieved in case that

valuable resource is in hands of large number of competitors. Barney (1991) provides an explanation for

that by emphasizing an importance of value-creating strategies in the creation of competitive

advantage. He mentions that competitive advantage can be achieved through implementing value-

creating strategies by exploiting firm’s resources. If that resource can be exploited by many firms

identically and simultaneously, then each firm will have similar strategy, which will not result in

competitive advantage for anyone. In general, Barney (2001) suggests that rareness of a resource is

achieved in case it is possessed uniquely by one or small number of firms, which allows them to achieve

competitive advantage through improved efficiency and effectiveness, which is not obtainable to other

firms.

3.2.2 Inimitability

Barney (1991) proposes that rareness of resources will not be a key factor in sustaining competitive

advantage for a long time, in case competitors can easily obtain such resources by imitating them.

Sustainability of competitive advantage can be obtained by firms only in case their resources are not

easily imitable. Lippman and Rumelt (1982) also call such characteristic of a resource as “imperfect

imitability”. Existing literature (Barney, 1991; Dierickx & Cool, 1989) identifies three sources through

which (or through combination of which) resources can be protected from imitation, namely unique

historical conditions, causal ambiguity, and social complexity.

3.2.2.1 Historical conditions

First source of resource inimitability can originate from historical conditions. Before the creation of

resource-based view, various researchers (Porter, 1980, Scherer, 1980) claimed that performance of the

firm can be analyzed despite historical differences of organizations. Thus, Porter (1980) claims that

firms’ histories are irrelevant in the analysis of their performance and therefore can be neglected. On

the contrary, Barney (1991) opposes, by saying that the RBV stresses the importance of history in the

abilities of firms to acquire and exploit specific resources. As he puts it in his research: “once this

particular unique time in history passes, firms that do not have space- and time-dependent resources

cannot obtain them, and thus these resources are imperfectly imitable”. According to Peteraf (1993),

resources are history dependent, meaning that they are influenced by the previous learning levels,

degrees and sources of investments and development activities. For instance, previous decision to

Page 16: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

16

locate a firm on a more valuable land can be considered as an imperfectly imitable physical capital

resource (Hirshleifer, 1980).

3.2.2.2 Causal Ambiguity

Secondly, causal ambiguity can be a descendent of resource imperfect imitability. Causal ambiguity can

serve as a source of resource inimitability by other organizations, if other organizations are not able to

understand the relationship between firm’s resources and sustained competitive advantage (Barney,

1991). Barney (1991) suggests that such an effect is reached, simply, because other organizations are

unsure of which resources they should imitate in order to duplicate successful value-creating strategies.

Counter-intuitively, Lippman and Rumelt (1982) develop that subject even further by suggesting that

perfect causal ambiguity is reached, if none of the firms understands the relationship between

resources and sustained competitive advantage, including firm possessing such an advantage. They

suggest that once the firm with a competitive advantage understands the relationship between its

resources and sustained competitive advantage, other firms can learn about, for example by hiring that

firm’s managerial staff. For as long as none of the parties can understand such a relationship, the

resources cannot be easily imitated which will allow competitive advantage to be sustained through

time.

3.2.2.3 Social complexity

Finally, resource inimitability can occur as a result of social complexity. In that case, ability of other firms

to imitate such resources is restrained by resources’ foundation in complex social phenomena, which

cannot be manageable or influenced (Barney, 1991). Various researchers provide instances of socially

complex resources. Examples include managerial interpersonal relationships (Hambrick, 1987), firm’s

reputation in the eyes of their suppliers (Porter, 1980), and customers (Klein & Lefler, 1981). Moreover,

social complexity of organizational resources can be a result of asset stocks interconnectedness (Diericks

and Cool, 1989), and co-specialized assets (Teece, 1986). In such cases, other firms are capable in

understanding the relationship between firm’s resources and sustained competitive advantage, but

aren’t capable of social engineering to imitate such resources (Barney, 1991).

3.2.3 Non-substitutability

Furthermore, Barney (1991) suggest, that it is important for a resource to have no equivalent substitutes

to be valuable. He defines equivalent resources as those, which might be realized in similar value-

creating strategies. In that case none of the firms is expected to sustain competitive advantage, due to

perceived ease with which they can be replicated.

Page 17: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

17

3.3 Market imperfections in obtaining valuable resources

After all, such characteristics of organizational resources allow firms to achieve sustainable advantage

due to possibility of providing customers with products of higher value or lower costs, than competitors

can offer. However, as Das and Teng (2000) propose, it is not always possible to accumulate such

resources internally. In case of perfectly efficient markets for resources, cooperation of firms would be

minimized, and firms would prefer to do business on their own, obtaining valuable resources through

market exchanges (Eisenhardt & Schoonhoven, 1996). However, in reality, most of the resources are

hardly tradable due to their embeddedness in organizations (Chi, 1994). Therefore, Das and Teng (2000)

claim that strategic alliances is a way of organizations to overcome problem of imperfect markets for

resources and capabilities, and obtain resources of partner firms, in order to get access to new

competitive advantages, which would be impossible to obtain under other circumstances.

3.4 Complementary resources and performance of an alliance

In the following research, resource complementarity is conceptualized in accordance with a research by

Sarkar et al. (2001), as “extent to which each partner brings in unique strengths and resources of value to

the collaboration.” The effect of complementary resources on the performance of an alliance is studied

in two steps. First, the effect of complementary resources of each separate partner on the idiosyncratic

resources of alliance has to be identified. Later, the relationship between idiosyncratic resources and

performance of the alliance can be emphasized. The difference between those types of resources was

described in research of Hunt (2000), who proposed that complementary resources are considered as

firm-specific, which are brought by individual partners to the alliance and later developed into

idiosyncratic resources of alliance. In turn, these are the idiosyncratic resources which might be

considered as valuable for the alliances, and therefore, can create competitive advantage.

3.4.1 Complementary resources

As was already stated, one of the motives of organizations to cooperate with each other in a strategic

alliance - is lack of resources, needed to develop a competitive advantage. By forming strategic

alliances, organizations can get access to resources of their partners and gain resource advantages over

their competitors via formation of new resources through combination of individual resources (Hunt,

1997). However, only the resources, which are complementary to the resources already obtained by one

of the partners, can lead to successful achievement of resources combinations. As proposed by Lambe

et al. (2002), in that case complementary resources of partners, merged together, reduce deficiencies in

each other resource portfolio. The combination of complementary resources into unique system, which

is unavailable to competitors leads to creation of competitive advantage (Hunt, 1997). Such combination

of complementary resources is very often referred to as idiosyncratic resources. Jap (1999) suggests

Page 18: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

18

direct relationship between complementary resources of each partner and idiosyncratic resources of

alliance. According to his research, higher complementarity of partners’ individual resources causes

more intensive development of idiosyncratic resources. Such an effect is reached due to a higher chance

of idiosyncratic resources of an alliance to result in unique competitive advantage, which wouldn’t be

achieved otherwise through competition (Jap, 1999).

3.4.2 Idiosyncratic resources

Now after the relationship between complementary and idiosyncratic resources is identified, the

mediating effect of idiosyncratic resources on the performance of an alliance can be analyzed. Lambe et

al. (2002) provides well-elaborated definition of idiosyncratic resources. According to his research,

idiosyncratic resources are unique resources, developed during an alliance existence via combination of

firm-specific complementary resources. Hunt (2000) suggests that idiosyncratic resources can be

tangible, such as joint facility, and intangible, such as new process creation. After all, idiosyncratic

resources suppose to allow alliances to “extract the competitive advantage potential from the

combination of the partner firms’ respective resources” (Lambe et al., 2002). From a RBV perspective,

unique idiosyncratic resources should allow alliances to sustain resource advantage over their

competitors for a longer time due to their non-durability and non-imitability (Dyer and Singh, 1998; Jap,

1999). Day (1995) suggests that such an effect will be achieved because competitors will not be able to

replicate the same idiosyncratic resources easily and in a timely and cost efficient manner.

Unique idiosyncratic resources can be considered as collective strengths, which wouldn’t be accessible

to the competitors (Das & Teng, 2003). Beamish (1987) found out that the higher the degree of

collective strength (e.g. idiosyncratic resources) accumulated by an alliance, the higher the performance

impact. Various researchers (Sarkar, et al, 2001; Lambe et al., 2002) confirmed those findings,

suggesting that competitive advantages gained through the combination of firms individual resources

via idiosyncratic resources will in turn be one of the main determinants of strategic alliances’

performance. According to them, higher degree of idiosyncratic resources in an alliance will improve the

performance of alliance.

Page 19: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

19

Chapter 4 – Interorganizational trust

After the influence of complementary resources on the performance of strategic alliance had been

discussed, interorganizational trust is going to be considered as another independent variable. Smith

and his colleagues (1995) emphasize in their research the importance of trust for cooperative

relationships by saying: "the study of trust and its impact on cooperative relationships at all levels may

be a particularly fruitful area of future research". As was noted by Gulati (1995), trust plays essential role

in strategic alliances and is one of the major determinants of alliance performance (Madhok, 1995).

However, before the relationship between interorganizational trust and performance of strategic

alliance is researched, the concept of interorganizational trust and the transaction cost theory have to

be explained.

4.1 Transaction cost theory

Transaction cost theory (TCT) plays crucial role in understanding of the relationship between trust and

performance of strategic alliances. Overall, TCT is focused on the minimization of transaction costs in

the organization of firm’s activities (Williamson, 1991). According to Robbins (1987) transaction costs

can be defined as those that are associated with economic exchanges and differ independent of the

competitive market price of goods being exchanged. Examples of transaction costs may include

negotiation costs with a partner (Agarwal and Ramaswami, 1992) or monitoring costs of the partner

(Makino & Neupert, 2000). Williamson (1975) suggests that transaction costs reduction is one of the

goals that partner firms may pursue by forming cooperation, which has to gain considerable attention.

To understand the transaction cost theory completely and its relation to the interorganizational trust, it

is important to state two assumptions on which this theory is based.

4.1.1 Opportunism

First assumption of TCT is opportunism. Aubert and Weber (2001) suggest that opportunism is a

phenomenon which arises when human-beings act in their own self interest. In other words, humans

might sacrifice common goals in order to receive individual benefits. Therefore, there is a high

probability that partners can pursue short term individual goals and objectives rather than work for an

increase in overall long term performance of their partnership. Williamson (1985) defines opportunism

as a threat to every organization and consequently determines it as a transaction cost. The higher the

opportunistic behavior of partners, the higher the transaction costs involved (Williamson and Masten,

1995).

Page 20: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

20

4.1.2 Bounded rationality

Bounded rationality is the second assumption of TCT. The theory of bounded rationality states, that

“human behavior is intendedly rational, but only limitedly so" (Simon, 1961). According to the theory of

bounded rationality, humans lack the wits necessary to think of all the possible contingencies and state

them in the contracts (Chiles & McMackin, 1996). Therefore, according to Chiles and McMackin (1996),

contracts turn out to be incomplete, which increases the behavioral uncertainty of partners, increases

possibility to behave opportunistically, decreases the ability for contract enforcement, and that in turn

leads to higher transaction costs involved.

4.2 Concept of interorganizational trust

After the basics of TCT have been explained, the concept of interorganizational trust can be elaborated.

Overall, trust can be defined as the partner’s willingness to believe in the other partner in a context of

co-dependent actions (Doney et al., 1998). Even though, trust exists between individuals, the notion of

trust is extendable to the level of interorganizational exchanges, since individuals in each organization

are responsible for managing interorganizational relationships (Bradach and Eccles, 1989). As defined by

Zaheer et al. (1998) the term interorganizational trust means “the extent of trust placed in the partner

organization by the members of a focal organization”. As suggested by Aulakh et al. (1996),

interorganizational trust consists of a set of expectations for each partner regarding each other's

behavior and each partner's fulfillment of its obligations with regard to such anticipation. The more

elaborated definition of interorganizational trust by Zaheer et al. (1998) implies that partners will have

commitment to their obligations, behave in a predictable manner and act and negotiate fairly even in

case of a possibility to behave opportunistically.

Existing literature points out two components of partners’ trust: structural and behavioral (Hosmer

1995; Madhok 1995). But, whereas, the structural component of trust may be essential for the

formation of the relationship, it is behavioral component of trust which is responsible for its

continuation and evolution (Madhok, 1995). According to Aulakh et al. (1996) behavioral dimension of

trust refers to the confidence aspect in exchange relationships. Anderson and Narus (1990) define such

confidence aspect as "firm's belief that another company will perform actions that will result in positive

outcomes for the firm as well as not take unexpected actions that result in negative outcomes."

Behavioral component of interorganizational trust is essentially useful in the continuation of ongoing

relationships, and, that is why it should be considered carefully before forming a strategic alliance. In

further sections of that chapter behavioral component of trust is going to be assumed without explicitly

mentioning it.

Page 21: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

21

4.3 Relationship between trust and performance of strategic alliance

Existing literature points out several ways through which interorganizational trust can influence

performance of alliances. Mainly, all of them increase performance of strategic alliance through a

reduction in transaction costs involved into the activities of strategic alliances.

4.3.1 Trust as a deterrent of opportunistic behavior

First of all, as it was proposed by Bradach and Eccles (1989), trust in interorganizational exchanges

serves as a tool to reduce opportunistic behavior. When high degree of trust exists in strategic alliances,

there is a strong propensity that short term individual goals will be passed in favor of long term common

benefits, which will decrease transaction costs and increase alliance overall performance (Banks, 1987).

The reasoning for that is provided by Hill (1990), who claims that motivation for engagement in

opportunistic behavior is reduced substantially in trust-based interorganizational exchanges, since

“behavioral repertoires are biased toward cooperation, rather than opportunism”.

4.3.2 Trust as a tool to economize on bounded rationality

Second of all, it is possible to analyze the effect of trust on performance of strategic alliances through

the concept of bounded rationality. Zand (1972) in his research proposes a framework which leads to

the conclusion that higher levels of trust will reduce behavioral uncertainty and lead to ‘economization

on bounded rationality’. In particular, higher levels of trust will cause more accurate, comprehensive and

timely information exchange, better receptivity to other partners’ influence, and lower levels of needed

controls for the behavior of other partners. Consequently, it leads to the greater certainty of partners

over each other’s behavior which reduces behavioral uncertainty, and lowers transaction costs. As a

result, partners are able to increase performance of alliance. Later, the results of a research of Zand

(1972) were confirmed by Lincoln (1990) and Powell (1990). For instance, Powel (1990) suggests that

"trust reduces complex realities far more quickly and economically than prediction, authority, or

bargaining"

4.3.3 Trust as reducing costs of negotiating

Third of all, trust may greatly reduce the costs of negotiating between partners. The negotiating costs

can be defined as costs (e.g. time and effort) which arise in the process of reaching mutually satisfying

agreements, determining efficient courses of action, and settling on divisions of costs and benefits

(Milgrom and Roberts, 1992). It is possible to come to the conclusion regarding mutually satisfying

agreements much faster and with lower efforts in case of high interorganizational trust. It becomes

possible due to an elimination of such drawbacks of negotiations as imperfect communications,

misrepresented information, private information and verification difficulties, which make information

Page 22: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

22

sharing more honest and open, allowing for development of common understanding over arising issues

(Zaheer et al., 1998). In other words, trust reduces costs of negotiations and makes them faster and

easier by providing each partner with an opportunity to be more flexible in reaching agreements and

sharing sensitive information, due to mutual expectations that the other partner will reciprocate in

future as well (Dore, 1983). Negotiations between partners with low level of trust are more likely to be

extensive in time and difficult in terms of efforts involved (Williamson, 1975). According to Williamson

(1975, 1985), such an effect will arise due to two reasons. First of all, partners will have to discuss all

contingencies because of partners’ possible ex ante and ex post opportunism will be present. Second of

all, partners will have to negotiate over contractual and structural safeguards in order to protect

investments in the relationship.

The performance of an exchange relationship is highly dependent on parties’ ability to limit the

contracting costs, which arise at the moment of negotiations and renegotiations (Zaheer et al., 1998).

Obviously, the negotiation costs are lowering overall performance of strategic alliance. It happens

because the time and efforts spend on negotiations in pursuit of influencing the terms of the deal can be

considered as waste (Milgrom and Roberts, 1992). In other words, as Zaheer et al. (1998) proposes, the

performance is influenced by those unnecessary costs, which distract partners from their business.

Trust-based relationships will be aimed at reaching mutually beneficial agreements and solutions, even

in case of arise of contingencies not explicitly covered by the contract (Zaheer et al., 1998).

4.3.4 Trust as a tool for reducing conflicts

Fourth of all, trust may assist partners in avoiding conflicting situations. It is not uncommon for partners

to experience various conflicts, which arise very often due to disagreements of partners over crucial

aspects. Those disagreements might be provoked by divergent goals that firms pursue in their exchange

relationships and unforeseen contingencies in their relationships (Zaheer et al., 1998). In case of trust-

based relationship, conflicts can be solved much easier in order to sustain stable relationship through

common range of norms and social processes (Macneil, 1980).

Reduction in conflict situations will also result in the increase in performance of alliance. As it was

proposed by Narus (1990), disagreements in interorganizational exchanges may result in conflicts

destroying the relationship. The overburdens of relationship with conflicts will most likely result in

dysfunctional outcomes, such as additional time and effort spent on conflicts resolution (Zaheer et al.,

1998). As was already said, those time and effort, which could very much be avoided in case of trust-

based relationship, can be considered as waste. Therefore, direction of time and effort in activities

which are not creating additional values for the relationship will result in lowering the performance of

Page 23: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

23

alliances. Madhok (1995) states that trust between partners helps to prevent many conflict situations

from happening by “reducing friction”, which allows partners to avoid waste of time and efforts on non-

value creating activities, and stimulates the performance of alliances. Such an effect is realized through

the presence of greater tolerance towards conflicts and presence of partners’ motivation to develop

relationship despite unforeseen circumstances (Gomes-Casseres, 1987; Kogut, 1989).

4.3.5 Other ways through which trust can stimulate performance of strategic alliance

Furthermore, as proposed in a research by McEvily et.al (2003) trust can result in increased performance

of the relationship by improving the scale and the scope of communication between partners.

Accordingly, Dyer and Chu (2003) state that partner’s trustworthiness influences the degree of

information exchange. Particularly, they state that higher levels of perceived partner’s trustworthiness

are more likely to cause more extensive information sharing between partners. Likewise, Creed and

Miles (1996) point out that trust facilitates more open communication and information sharing.

Finally, in order to realize another influence of trust on performance of an alliance, it has to be studied

together with control over the alliance. Various researchers, studying the effect of control emphasized

its importance on performance of strategic alliances. Ouchi (1979) observes that in the organizational

context “people must either be able to trust each other or closely monitor each other.” Therefore,

there is a negative correlation between the level of trust and amount of control over the alliance.

Sprenger (2004) explains such relationship by stating that control can be reduced due to expectations

about competence and goodwill in acts of a partner. Therefore, higher level of interorganizational trust

between partners leads to a reduction of control imposed over strategic alliance. Consequently, efforts

and costs which were spent on control now can be spent on value-creating activities.

4.4 Trust and its effect on idiosyncratic resources creation

Interorganizational trust is essential for strategic alliances not only because it has direct influence on

their performance, but also due to its influence on the idiosyncratic resources creation within strategic

alliance. As was concluded in the third chapter, idiosyncratic resources of strategic alliance arise as a

combination of complementary resources of each individual partner. Greater input of complementary

resources will result in accumulation of larger degree of idiosyncratic resources. However, the degree of

resource input might depend on the degree of interorganizational trust between partners. Thus, as was

proposed in a paper by Hennessy (2002), “resource commitments of each partner in the form of inputs…

are a function of trust between partners at any given time.”

Page 24: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

24

Absence of trust might create confusion whether to treat partner as an enemy or an ally, creating

difficulties for a resource exchange (Powell et al. 1996). The resource exchange might be limited as a

result of lack of trust in the strategic alliance. Conversely, in case of strategic alliances based on trust,

resource exchange might receive additional boost. For instance, according to Blau (1964) trust-based

relationship stimulates free exchange of knowledge, since partners do not feel a need for protecting

themselves from opportunistic behavior. Tsai and Ghoshal (1998) confirm these results by stating that

the resource exchange appears to be easier between partners who have high level of trust, since they

are not afraid to be taken advantage of. They state, that partner with a higher level of

interorganizational trust is more likely to interact in higher degree of resource exchange. Therefore,

firms are willing to share more resource with partners whom they see as more trustworthy.

Page 25: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

25

Chapter 5 – Conclusions and recommendations

5.1 Conclusions

From the following paper several important conclusions regarding the strategic alliances and their

performance can be made. Despite all the potential benefits that strategic alliances can have for the

individual firms, they remain very fragile constructions, which often fail to bring any value to the

partners. The following paper emphasizes the importance of careful partner selection, which happens

before the actual strategic alliance formation. Two factors influencing the future performance of

strategic alliances, namely complementary resources of individual partners and interorganizational trust

between partners, were identified as having potentially positive effects. However, unlike many papers

individually discussing direct effects of each of these variables, the current paper emphasizes the

importance of considering those factors as interdependent. For the sake of ease of understanding of

those relationships, two theories, namely resource-based view and transaction cost theory were used.

Through the RBV current paper explains the underlying reasoning for the strategic alliances creation,

and the relationship between complementary resources of each individual partner and performance of

strategic alliance. It was found out that having high degree of complementary resources by individual

partners is vital for the performance of their alliance, due to possibility of realization of unique

competitive advantages. However, it is also concluded, that simply obtaining complementary resources

is not enough for creating unique competitive advantages within strategic alliances. It is a requirement

that complementary resources of each individual partner are combined together. Such combination of

resources is called ‘idiosyncratic resources’ and it mediates the relationship between complementary

resources and alliances performance. Higher complementarity of resources causes higher degree of

idiosyncratic resources. Consequently, higher degree of idiosyncratic resources, which play a role of a

mediating variable, will lead to increased performance of an alliance through creation of unique

competitive advantage.

With the help of transaction cost theory the relationship between interorganizational trust and

performance of strategic alliances was explained. It was concluded that interorganizational trust can be

used within an alliance to increase its performance, by minimizing various costs connected to

transactions and directing them into value creating activities. Several ways, through which such effect

takes place, were outlined. First of all, interorganizational trust can be served in order to minimize the

causes of transaction costs emergence by deterring opportunistic behavior and economizing on the

bounded rationality. Second of all, interorganizational trust can be used to minimize transaction costs by

Page 26: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

26

minimizing costs of negotiating, reducing conflicts, improving scale and scope of communication

between partners, and reducing control and monitoring costs. Therefore, high level of trust between

potential partners is crucial in order to keep transaction costs on minimum and enhance the

performance of their strategic alliance. Lower levels of trust will inevitably lead to increase in

transaction costs which, in turn, will decrease performance of strategic alliance.

Moreover, current paper went beyond the scope of most of the papers, describing only the direct effect

of interorganizational trust on the performance of the strategic alliances. It is shown that

interorganizational trust has an important moderating effect for the relationship between

complementary and idiosyncratic resources. As it was investigated, simply obtaining high degree of

complementary resources is not enough for combining them into idiosyncratic resources. Partners

should be willing to share their resources to a high extent. Higher interorganizational trust enhances the

willingness of partners to contribute their resources to the creation of new competitive advantage by

combining them into idiosyncratic resources, since they are less afraid to be taken advantage of. As it

can be concluded, higher degree of trust will stimulate partners to input more complementary resources

in their partnership, which will create an opportunity for creation of higher degree of idiosyncratic

resources. In case that relationship is not based on trust, partners might not input resources into

partnership that easily, which will create a barrier for idiosyncratic resources creation, which in turn will

affect the performance of strategic alliance.

The main conclusion, which can be derived from the following paper, can be particularly important for

the managers. There are various factors which contribute to the development of alliances’ success and

high performance. Despite various causes which might influence the performance of alliance already

after their formation, current paper concentrates on several important factors, which should be

carefully considered before the actual formation of the strategic alliances during the phase of partner

selection. Those factors are complementary resources and interorganizational trust. In choosing the

compatible partner, it is very important for managers to select those, who are in possession of high

degree of complementary resources to the resources already obtained by their organization. Moreover,

managers should choose only those organizations to have strategic alliances with, which they consider

as trustworthy enough. Managers should make a selection in favor of such partners with whom they are

maintaining high degree of interorganizational trust. By satisfying these two conditions on the phase of

partner selection, firms are able to form strategic alliance which has a high chance to be highly

successful and realize the goals of individual partners to a high extent.

5.2 Limitations and practical recommendations

Page 27: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

27

Current paper is concentrated on the factors crucial for the performance of the strategic alliances, which

partners should take into the account on the phase of partner selection before the actual alliance

formation. Interorganizational trust and complementary resources of each partner were considered to

be the most important factors to take into the account by the managers while choosing the appropriate

partner. However, several other factors might also be important for managerial consideration while

choosing a partner for alliance formation, which were not explicitly covered in the current paper. Such

factors could be managerial capabilities for alliance management, alliance experience of the partner,

size of the partner, cultural-fit, or strategic fit. Due to the limits imposed on the size of the current

paper, only two factors were selected for further elaboration. However, for the robustness of the

results, more factors crucially important for the partner selection should be included in the future

researches.

What's more, careful selection of partners itself doesn’t guarantee the successful implementation of

strategic alliances. The performance of strategic alliances can be very much affected by the

implementation factors and environmental factors beyond partners’ control, which were not considered

in the current paper. Such factors could be frequent performance feedback, information system

integration, dynamics of competition, technological shifts, government regulations, or natural disasters.

These factors could not be included in the paper due to size restrictions as well. The future researchers

studying the performance of strategic alliances should go beyond the partner selection factors, and

include implementation and environmental factors in their researches.

Furthermore, due to the choice of literature review, as a type or research, none of the empirical or

statistical analyses were conducted. The reasons for choosing literature review were discussed in the

introduction chapter of the current paper. However, literature review is not always appropriate type of

research, since the knowledge might have became obsolete already or be highly criticized. For instance,

the resource based view, which is a cornerstone for understanding the relationship between

complementary resources and performance of strategic alliances has substantial weaknesses, among

which the most important are paradoxical, tautological, and infinite regress (Lado et al., 2006). For these

reasons, the next research should be conducted together with empirical and statistical analyses, which

will help to shed the light upon truth, despite the knowledge obsoleteness, which could have became an

issue since the previous researches.

Page 28: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

28

List of references

Agarwal, S., & Ramaswami, S. N. (1992). Choice of foreign market entry mode: impact of ownership, location

and internalization factors. Journal of International Business Studies, 23, 1-27.

Anderson, J. C., & Narus, J. A. (1990). A Model of Distributor Firm and Manufacturer Firm Working Partnerships.

The Journal of Marketing, 54 (1), 42-58.

Aubert, B. A., & Weber, R. (2001, 1 May). Transaction cost theory, the resource-based view, and information

technology sourcing decisions: a re-examination of Lacity et al.’s findings. Paper presented at the Cahiers du

GRES.

Aulakh, P. S., Kotabe, M., & Sahay, A. (1996). Trust and Performance in Cross-Border Marketing Partnerships: A

Behavioral Approach, Journal of International Business Studies, 27 (5), 1005-1032.

Banks, J. C. (1987). Equity joint ventures and the theory of the multinational enterprise. Journal of International

Business Studies, 18(2), 1-16.

Barney, J. B. (1986). Strategic factor markets: expectations, luck, and business strategy. Management Science, 32

(10), 1231–1241.

Barney, J. B. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17, 99–120.

Barney, J. B. (2001). Is the resource-based “view” a useful perspective for strategic management research? Yes.

Academy of Management Review, 26, 41-56.

Barney, J. B., Hesterly, W. S., (2008). Strategic management and Competitive Advantage. Pearson Prentice Hall,

second edition.

Beamish, P. W. (1987). Joint ventures in LDCs: Partner selection and performance. Management International

Review, 27, 23–37.

Bierly, P.E., & Gallagher, S. (2007). Explaining Alliance Partner Selection: Fit, Trust and Strategic Expediency.

Long Range Planning, 40, 134-153.

Blau, P. M. (1964). Exchange and Power in Social Life. Wiley, New York.

Bradach, J. L., & Eccles, R. G. (1989). Price, authority, and trust: From ideal types to plural forms. American

Review of Sociology, 15, 97-118.

Chi, T. (1994). Trading in strategic resources: Necessary conditions, transaction cost problems, and choice of

exchange structure. Strategic Management Journal, 15, 271–290.

Page 29: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

29

Chiles, T. H., & McMackin, J. F. (1996). Integrating variable risk preferences, trust, and transaction cost

economics. Academy of Management Review, 21 (1), 73-99.

Contractor, F.J. & Lorange, P. (1988). Cooperative strategies in international business. Boston: Lexington Books.

Creed, W. E. D., & Miles, R. E. (1996). Trust in Organizations: A Conceptual Framework Linking Organizational

Forms, Managerial Philosophies, and the Opportunity Costs of Control, in Kramer, R. M., & Tyler, T. R. Trust in

Organizations: Frontiers of Theory and Research. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE Publications.

Dacin, M.T., Hitt, M.A., &Levitas, E. (1997). Selecting partners for successful international alliances: Examination

of U.S. and Korean firms. Journal of World Business, 32 (1), 3-16.

Dagnino, G.B., & Padula, G. (2002, 9 May). A new kind of inter-firm dynamics for value creation. Paper presented

at the Second Annual Conference - “Innovative Research in Management”, Stockholm.

Das, T. K., Teng, B. S. (2000). A resource-based theory of strategic alliances. Journal of Management, 26, 31– 61.

Das, T. K., Teng, B. S. (2000). Instabilities of strategic alliances: an internal tension perspective. Organizational

Science, 11 (1), 77–103.

Das, T. K., Teng, B. S. (2003). Partner analysis and alliance performance. Scandinavian Journal of Management,

19, 279–308.

Day, G. S. (1995). Advantageous Alliances? Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 23 (4), 297-300.

Dierickx, I., & Cool, K. (1989). Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage.

Management Science, 35 (12), 1504- 1511.

Doney, P.M., Cannon, J.P., & Mullen, M.R. (1998). Understanding the influence of national culture on the

development of trust. Academy of Management Review, 23 (3), 601–620.

Dore, R. (1983). Goodwill and the Spirit of Market Capitalism. British Journal of Sociology, 34, 459-482.

Dyer, J. H., & Chu, W. (2003). The role of trustworthiness in reducing transaction costs and improving

performance: Empirical evidence from the United Stated, Japan, and Korea. Organization Science, 14 (1), 57-68.

Dyer, J. H., & Singh, H. (1998). The Relational View: Cooperative Strategy and Sources of Interorganizational

Competitive Advantage. Academy of Management Review, 23 (4), 660-679.

Eisenhardt, K. M., & Schoonhoven, C. B. (1996). Resource-based view of strategic alliance formation: Strategic

and social effects of entrepreneurial firms. Organization Science, 7, 136–150.

Elmuti, D., Kathawala, Y. (2001). An overview of strategic alliances. Management Decision, 39 (3), 205-217.

Emery, F. (1967). The Next Thirty Years: Concepts, Methods and Applications. Human Relations, 30, 199-237.

Page 30: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

30

Fahy, J. and Smithee, A. (1999). Strategic marketing and the resource based view of the firm. Academy of

Marketing Science Review, 10, 1-20.

Gomes-Casseres, B. (1987). Joint venture instability: Is it a problem? Columbia Journal of World Business, 22 (2),

97−102.

Grant, R. M. (1991). The resource-based theory of competitive advantage: Implications for strategy formulation.

California Management Review, 33 (3), 114–135.

Gulati, R. (1995). Does Familiarity Breed Trust? The Implications of Repeated Ties for Contractual Choice in

Alliances. Academy of Management Journal, 38, 85-112.

Hall, R. (1992). The strategic analysis of intangible resources. Strategic Management Journal, 13, 135–144.

Hambrick, D. (1987). Top management teams: Key to strategic success. California Management Review, 30, 88-

108.

Harrigan, K. R. (1988). Joint ventures and competitive strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 9, 141–158.

Harrison, J. S., Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. E., & Ireland, R. D. (1991). Synergies and post- acquisition performance:

Differences versus similarities in resource allocations. Journal of Management, 17, 173-190.

Hennessy, D. (2002). Give and Take: The Dynamics of Trust and Learning in Strategic Alliances. Presented at

ASAC 2002 Conference, Winnipeg, Manitoba.

Hill, C. W. L. (1990). Cooperation, opportunism, and the invisible hand: Implications for transaction cost theory.

Academy of Management Review, 15, 500-513.

Hirshleifer, J. (1980). Price theory and applications (2nd edition). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

Hofer, C. W., & Schendel, D. (1978). Strategy formulation: Analytical concepts. St. Paul, MN: West.

Hosmer, L. T. (1995). Trust: The connecting link between organizational theory and philosophical ethics.

Academy of Management Review, 20 (2), 379-403.

Hunt, S. D. (1997). Competing Through Relationships: Grounding Relationship Marketing in Resource Advantage

Theory? Journal of Marketing Management, 13, 1-15.

Hunt, S. D. (2000). A General Theory of Competition. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

Jap, S. D. (1999). Pie-Expansion Efforts: Collaboration Processes in Buyer-Seller Relationships. Journal of

Marketing Research, 36 (4), 461-475.

Kale, P., & Singh, H. (2007). Building firm capabilities through learning: The role of the alliance learning process

in alliance capability and firm-level alliance success. Strategic management journal, 28, 981-1000.

Page 31: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

31

Kale, P., Singh, H., & Perlmutter, H. (2000). Learning and protection of proprietary assets in strategic alliances:

building relational capital. Strategic Management Journal, 21(3), 217-237.

Klein, B., & Leffler, K. (1981). The role of price in guaranteeing quality. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 615-644.

Kogut, B. (1988). Joint Ventures: Theoretical and Empirical Perspectives. Strategic Management Journal , 9 (2),

319-332.

Kogut, B. (1989). The stability of joint ventures: Reciprocity and competitive rivalry. Journal of Industrial

Economics, 38 (2), 183−198.

Lado, A.A, Boyd, N.G., Wright, P., & Kroll, M. (2006). Paradox and theorizing within the resource-based view.

Academy of Management Review, 31, 115-131.

Lambe, C.J., Spekman, R.E., and Hunt, S.D. (2002). Alliance competence, resources, and alliance success:

conceptualization, measurement, and initial test. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 30 (2), 141–158.

Lei, D., Slocum, J. W. Jr., and Pitts, R. A. (1997). Building cooperative advantage: Managing strategic alliances to

promote organizational learning. Journal of World Business, 32 (3), 203-223.

Lincoln, J. R. (1990). Japanese organization and organization theory, in Staw, B. M. & Cummings L. L. Research in

organizational behavior. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

Lippman, S. A., & Rumelt, R. P. (1982). Uncertain Imitability: An Analysis of Interfirm Differences in Efficiency

under Competition. The Bell Journal of Economics, 13 (2), 418-438.

Lorenzoni, G., & Lipparini, A. (1999). The Leveraging of Interfirm Relationships as a Distinctive Organizational

Capability: A Longitudinal Study. Strategic Management Journal, 20 (4) (Apr., 1999), pp. 317-338

Macneil, I. R. (1980). The New Social Contract. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

Madhok, A. (1995). Revisiting Multinational Firms’ Tolerance for Joint Ventures: A Trust-Based Approach.

Journal of International Business Studies, 26 (1), 117-137.

Makino, S., & Neupert, K. E. (2000). National culture, transaction costs, and the choice between joint venture

and wholly owned subsidiary. Journal of International Business Studies, 31, 705-713.

McCarter, M.W., & Northcraft, G. B. (2007). Happy together?: Insights and implications of viewing managed

supply chains as a social dilemma. Journal of Operations Management, 25 (2), 498-511.

McEvily, B., Perrone, V., & Zaheer, A. (2003). Trust as an Organizing Principle. Organization Science, 14 (1), 91-

103.

Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1992). Economics, Organization and Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

Page 32: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

32

Miller, D., & Shamsie, J. (1996). The resource-based view of the firm in two environments: The Hollywood film

studios from 1936 to 1965. Academy of Management Journal, 39, 519–543.

Mohr, J., & Spekman, R. (1994). Characteristics of partnership success: Partnership attributes, communication

behavior, and conflict resolution techniques. Strategic Management Journal, 15, 135–152.

Mowery, D. C., Oxley, J. E., & Silverman, B. S. (1998). Technological overlap and interfirm cooperation:

Implications for the resource-based view of the firm. Research Policy, 27, 507–523.

Nielsen, B.B. (2003). An Empirical Investigation of the Drivers of International Strategic Alliance Formation.

European Management Journal, 21 (3), 301-322.

Olk, P. (2002). Evaluating Strategic Alliance Performance, in F. Contractor and P. Lorange. Cooperative strategies

in international business, Lexington Books, Lexington, MA

Ouchi, W. G. (1979). A conceptual framework for the design of organizational control mechanisms.

Management Science, 25, 833-848.

Penrose, E.T. (1959). The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. Wiley, New York.

Peteraf, M. A. (1993). The cornerstones of competitive advantage: A resource-based view. Strategic

Management Journal, 14, 179–191.

Porter, M.E. (1980). Competitive Strategy: Techniques for analyzing industries and competitors. New York: Free

Press.

Powell, W. W. (1990). Neither market nor hierarchy: Network forms of organization, in Staw, B. M. & Cummings

L. L. Research in organizational behavior. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

Powell, W.W., Koput, K.W., & Smith-Doerr, L. (1996). Interorganizational Collaboration and the Locus of

Innovation: Networks of Learning in Biotechnology. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41 (1), 116-145.

Richardson, G.B. (1972). The organization of industry. Economic Journal, 82: 883-896.

Robbins, J. (1987). Organizational economics: Notes on the use of transaction cost theory in the study of

organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly, 32, 68-86.

Sarkar, M.B., Echambadi, R., Cavusgil, S.T., & Aulakh, P.S. (2001). The influence of complementarity,

compatibility, and relationship capital on alliance performance. Academy of Marketing Science Journal, 29, 358-

373.

Scherer, E. M. (1980). Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance (2nd Edition). Boston: Houghton-

Mifflin.

Simon, H. A. (1961). Administrative behavior (2nd ed.). New York: Macmillan.

Page 33: The determinants of partner selection for the performance

33

Sinha, U. B. (2001). International Joint Venture, Licensing and Buy-out under Asymmetric Information. Journal of

Development Economics, 66, 127-151.

Smith, K. G., Carroll, S. J., & Ashford S. J. (1995). Intra- and Inter- organizational Cooperation: Toward a Research

Agenda. Academy of Management Journal, 38, 7-23.

Sprenger, R. K. (2004). Trust: The best way to manage. Frankfurt/Main: Campus Verlag.

Teece, D.J. (1986). Firm boundaries, technological innovation and strategic management, in Thomas, L.G. The

economics of strategic planning. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.

Teece, D.J. (1988). Technological change and the nature of the firm, in Dosi, G., Freeman, C., Nelson, R.,

Silverberg, G., Soete, L. Technical Change and Economic Theory. Frances Pinter, London.

Tsai, W., & Ghoshal, S. (1998). Social Capital and Value Creation: The Role of Intrafirm Networks. The Academy

of Management Journal, 41 (4), 464-476.

Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: The Free Press.

Williamson, O. E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: The Free Press.

Williamson, O. E. (1991). Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives.

Administrative Science Quarterly, 36, 269-296.

Williamson, O. E., & Masten, S. E. (1995). Transaction cost economics. Aldershot: Elgar.

Zaheer, A., Mcevily, B., Perrone, V. (1998). Does trust matter? Exploring the effects of interorganizational and

interpersonal trust on performance. Organization Science, 9 (2), 141–159.

Zand, D. E. (1972). Trust and managerial problem solving. Administrative Science Quarterly, 17(2), 229-239.

Zineldin, M. (2004). Co-opetition: the organization of the future. Marketing Intelligence & Planning, 22 (7), 780-

790.