The History of Indian Economic History

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    1/20

    The History of Indian Economic History

    Prasannan Parthasarathi

    May 2012

    Introduction

    While there is a long tradition of both historical and economic thinking in the Indian

    subcontinent, modern economic history may be dated from the late nineteenth century. From the

    early pioneers of economic history, including Mahadev Govind Ranade and Romesh Chander

    Dutt, the field reached a high level in India, giving rise to a stellar set of practitioners and an

    impressive body of scholarship, ranging from Irfan Habibs studies of the Mughal empire to

    Amiya Bagchis analyses of the colonial economy.

    In the last century and a half, three main lines of thinking may be identified in Indian economic

    history. The first is the early nationalist school inaugurated by Ranade and Dutt. The turn to

    history for these thinkers was part of an agenda to develop an Indian economics, which was

    attuned to the peculiarities of India. A historical approach was essential to this intellectual

    project. The search for an Indian economics went largely into decline from the 1930s and in

    faculties of economics the study and teaching of economic history was of secondary importance

    for several decades. The second line of economic history may be dated from the 1950s and

    emerges from a growing influence of Marxism, whose enormous impact was felt by both

    economists and historians. The final line emerged in the 1960s at the great powerhouse of both

    economics and economic history in recent decades, the Delhi School of Economics. This

    represented to some extent a revival of economic history within the ranks of economists.

    The flourishing state of economic history in India in the 1960s and 1970s represented a

    confluence of different forces. Similarly, the decline of economic history from its highpoint of

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    2/20

    those years is due to multiple factors as well as broad changes in both historical practice and

    economic thinking.

    The focus of this essay is on the evolution of economic history within India itself. Important

    contributions to Indian economic history have come from scholars located outside the country,

    but that work is for the most part not taken up in this essay, although references to some of these

    contributions is inevitable, especially those that shaped economic history writing in India itself.

    Nonetheless, the purpose of the essay is to chart the development of this branch of history in

    modern India.

    Nationalism and Economic History

    Mahadev Govind Ranade is widely acknowledged to be the father of Indian nationalist

    economics, or Indian political economy. He was born in western India in 1842 and was in

    instructor in economics at Elphinstone College for a decade and a half where he taught Adam

    Smith and John Stuart Mill, who was the main figure on the syllabus, but to give his students a

    wider perspective of political economy, he studied Malthus, Bastiat, Ramsay, McCulloch and

    Senior.1

    Indian nationalist economics had two goals. The first was the well known critique of the

    economic impact of British rule in India. The second goal, although less recognized but no less

    important, was to reject the universalism of economic theory and to construct a framework which

    captured the unique features of the Indian economy. As Ranade put it in his seminal essay,

    Indian Political Economy, delivered as a lecture at the Deccan College in Pune in 1892, The

    same teachers and statesmen, who warn us against certain tendencies in our political aspirations .

    1B. N. Ganguli, Indian Economic Thought: Nineteenth Century Perspectives (New Delhi, 1977), p. 164.

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    3/20

    . . seem to hold that the truths of economic science, as they have been expounded in our most

    popular English text-books, are absolutely and demonstrably true, and must be accepted as

    guides of conduct for all time and place whatever may be the stage of national advance. Ethnical,

    social, juristic, ethical, or economical differences in the environments are not regarded as having

    any influence in modifying the practical application of these truths.2

    Indian political economy was an economics rooted in the social, cultural and political conditions

    of India. One inspiration for it was John Stuart Mill, who rejected the universal claims of

    political economy. Mill wrote in his autobiography that his teachers tried to construct a

    permanentfabric out of transitory materials; that they took for granted the immutability of

    arrangements of society, many of which are in their naturefluctuating or progressive; and

    enunciate, with as little qualification as if they were universal and absolute truths.3

    Such

    statements found an appreciative audience among Indians of the late nineteenth century.

    The more important inspiration, however, was the German historical school, which gave Indian

    economics a firm rooting in the study of the past. (Ranade wrote, The German school regards

    that universalism and perpetualism in economic doctrine are both unscientific and untrue.4)

    Between these two influences, B. N. Ganguli gives primacy to the German historical school and

    he reconciles them in the following terms: Parts of the British economic theory, which had

    assimilated some of the contentions of the continental thinkers, were readily acclaimed by

    2Mahadev Govind Ranade, C.I.E., Indian Political Economy, in his Essays on Indian Economics: A Collection of

    Essays and Speeches, 3rd edn. (Madras, 1920), p. 2.3

    Cited in Ganguli, Indian Economic Thought, p. 69.4Ranade, Indian Political Economy, p. 20.

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    4/20

    Indians. But where assimilation was doubtful and the resulting compromise or rather balance,

    uncertain, there was preference for the conclusions of the Historical School.5

    Among the German economists, Friedrich List was to be the most influential. According to

    Ranade, It was the writings of List, which gave the fullest expression to the rebellion against the

    orthodox creed . . . The function of the state is to help those influences which tend to secure

    national progress through the several states of growth and adopt free trade or protection, as

    circumstances may require.6

    List was representative of a larger historical method in economic

    analysis. Again, to quote Ranade, The method to be followed is not the deductive but the

    historical method, which takes account of the past in its forecast of the future; and relativity, and

    not absoluteness, characterizes the conclusions of economical science.7

    Romesh Chander Dutts two volumeEconomic History of India was the most important

    historical work produced in this nationalist historical tradition. Dutt was a polymath, one of the

    first Indian entrants into the Indian Civil Service, the elite administrative cadre that governed

    British India. He resigned from the government after twenty-six years and devoted himself to

    politics and writing. He was active in the Indian National Congress and he produced novels,

    several historical works, translations from the Sanskrit, as well as important political tracts. His

    two-volume study of the Indian economy under British rule established the contours of a

    nationalist economic history which endures even in our times.8

    (One commentator writes of the

    5Ganguli, Indian Economic Thought, p. 76.

    6Cited in Ganguli, Indian Economic Thought, pp. 78-9.

    7Ranade, Indian Political Economy, pp. 20-1.

    8Romesh Dutt, The Economic History of India, 2 vols. (London, 1902-4)

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    5/20

    first volume, In several respects this book would rank as the most valuable of books on India

    under the British rule.9)

    Agriculture is given pride of place in both volumes, perhaps not surprising given the importance

    of the land revenue for the British Indian state. Much attention is given to the formation of the

    land revenue systems in the different provinces of British India and their revisions. Industry,

    internal and external trade, finance, and railways and irrigation are all explored as well, however.

    The Listian influence is also made explicit. After quoting a long passage from The National

    System of of Political Economy in which List discussed the economic relationship between

    Britain and India, Dutt concludes, While British Political Economists professed the principles of

    free trade from the latter end of the eighteenth century, the British Nation declined to adopt them

    till they had crushed the Manufacturing Power of India . . . [I]n India the Manufacturing Power

    of the people was stamped out by protection against her industries, and then free trade was

    forced on her so as to prevent a revival.10

    The commitment to a distinct Indian political economy continued into the early decades of the

    twentieth century, as did a commitment to a historical approach. As late as 1957 the economics

    department at the University of Madras was still called the Department of Indian Economics.

    In the early twentieth century a number of the leading economists combined research in

    historical topics along with studies of contemporary Indian problems. P. J. Thomas, who became

    Professor of Economics at Madras University in 1927, wrote his Oxford doctoral thesis on

    British trade with India in the late seventeenth and eighteenth century, the now classic

    9P. K. Gopalakrishnan, Development of Economic Ideas in India (1880-1950) (New Delhi, 1959), p. 147-8.

    10Romesh Dutt, The Economic History of India, vol. 1, Under Early British Rule (Delhi, 1960), pp. 215-6.

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    6/20

    Mercantilism and the East India Trade.11

    He also produced, along with B. Nataraja Pillai, a

    seminal study of the depression of the 1820s-1840s in South India.12

    The rest of his oeuvre,

    however, was devoted to analyses of the Indian economy of the 1930s and 1940s and he served

    on the Provincial Banking Enquiry Committee, the Agricultural Economic Council, the among

    other government bodies. Thomas took leave from the university in 1943 to take up a position in

    the Government of India, eventually resigning from his professorship three years later.13

    Similarly, the publications of Radhakamal Mukerjee, who began his career as a lecturer in the

    department of economics at the University of Calcutta and then served as professor and head of

    the department of economics and sociology at Lucknow University, ranged from economic

    history to contemporary village studies. He published his The Economic History of India: 1600-

    1800 in 1939.14

    Earlier in his career he was part of a sociological investigation in the Madras

    Presidency of Dravidian village communities, published several works on the foundations and

    postulates of Indian economics, housing and slums in urban India, comparative economics and

    demography.15

    Mukerjee is best remembered today as a founder of the Lucknow School of

    Sociology.16

    He was committed to both history and serious field work, however. In his

    autobiography, he wrote, In the early years of my own teaching I deeply felt the necessity of

    11 P. J. Thomas, Mercantilism and the East India Trade (London, 1926).12

    P. J. Thomas and B. Nataraja Pillai, Economic Depression in the Madras Presidency (1820-1854) (Madras, 1933).13

    History of Higher Education in South India, vol. 1, University of Madras 1857-1957(Madras, 1957), pp. 161-3.14

    Radhakamal Mukerjee, The Economic History of India: 1600-1800 (London, 1939).15

    Post-Graduate Teaching in the University of Calcutta 1919-1920 (Calcutta, no date of publication), pp. 65-6;

    Satish Chandra Ghosh, The Economic and Commercial Publications of the Post-Graduate Teachers of Calcutta

    University(Calcutta, 1948), pp. 44-5.16

    P. C. Joshi, Founders of the Lucknow School and their Legacy Radhakamal Mukerjee and D. P. Mukerji: Some

    Reflections, Economic and Political Weekly, 21 (1986), pp. 1455-69.

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    7/20

    relating economic theories and doctrines not only to economic history but also to the concrete

    social and economic environment.17

    Most famous of all is D. R. Gadgil, who was a major figure in Indian economics from the 1920s

    to the 1970s. His first book, The Industrial Evolution of India in Recent Times, was submitted as

    a MLitt thesis at Cambridge University. Ostensibly, it was a study of industry from 1860 to 1914

    (subsequent editions brought the story forward into the 1920s and 1930s), but it was in reality a

    broad economic history of the period.18

    The work was a critique of British rule and in the later

    editions this critique, particularly of British laissez faire, was made more explicit.19

    (Gadgil

    provided an introduction to a Government of India reprint of Romesh DuttsEconomic History

    of India.) Gadgil later undertook important investigations on the impact of World War II on the

    Indian economy, industrial labor and wages, the urban economy of western India, and planning

    and development in post-Independence India. Gadgil was also a staunch proponent of

    cooperatives for development and this, along with other positions sympathetic to the plight of

    labors and peasants, led S. A. Dange, Chairman of the Communist Party of India, to produce a

    pamphlet in appreciation of Gadgil after the economists death in 1971.20

    The economic histories of India produced by Indian nationalism did not go unchallenged by the

    defenders of British rule. Among the most enduring are the writings of W. H. Moreland, the

    former civil servant turned historian, who concentrated his energies on the economics of the

    Mughal Empire.21

    In Morelands interpretation of Mughal rule and its economic impact, the

    problems of British India, including low standards of living and widespread poverty, were

    17Radhakamal Mukerjee, India: The Dawn of New Era (An Autobiography) (New Delhi, 1997), p. 119.

    18D. R. Gadgil, The Industrial Evolution of India in Recent Times (London, 1924).

    19Bhabatosh Datta, Indian Economic Thought: Twentieth Century Perspectives 1900-1950 (New Delhi, 1978), p. 51.

    20S.A. Dange, Gadgil and the Economics of Indian Democracy(New Delhi, 1971). For Gadgils writings on

    cooperatives see his Writings and Speeches of D. R. Gadgil on Cooperation (Poona, 1975).21

    W. H. Moreland, India at the Death of Akbar(London, 1920) and From Akbar to Aurangzeb (London, 1923).

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    8/20

    portrayed as long-standing features of the Indian political economy. Others defended British rule

    along similar lines and attributed Indian economic problems to the deficiencies of culture and

    society, the most prominent being Vera Anstey, who was located not in India but at the London

    School of Economics.

    From the 1930s the historical bent in Indian economics went into decline and a new generation

    of economists focused on the contemporary problems of India with little appeal to history and

    little interest in the past. The independence of India from British rule in 1947 reinforced these

    choices and the finest economic thinkers in the country turned their minds to the problems of

    development and planning, which preoccupied both academic and government experts in the

    1950s. Perhaps no figure better symbolizes the new practices of Indian economists than V. K. R.

    V. Rao. Rao was born in South India in 1908 and he was only seven years younger than D. R.

    Gadgil, but of a different generation in several important respects. He, as did Gadgil, studied

    economics at Cambridge where he was a student of John Maynard Keynes. Raos early work was

    on the national income India in the 1920s and 1930s. His subsequent research focused on

    macroeconomics, public finance, education, and development planning, as well as a variety of

    other topics. Unlike his predecessors, however, Rao did not venture into economic history.22

    Why the turn from history, which had been a hallmark of Indian political economy since the late

    nineteenth century? In his Rise and Decline of Development Economics Albert Hirschman

    credits the Keynesian Revolution for creating the intellectual space to make development

    economics possible. He wrote, Development economics took advantage of the unprecedented

    discredit orthodox economics had fallen into as a result of the depression of the thirties and of

    the equally unprecedented success of an attack on orthodoxy from within the economics

    22For more on his life, see S. L. Rao (ed.), The Partial Memoirs of V. K. R. V. Rao (Delhi, 2002).

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    9/20

    establishment. I am talking of course about the Keynesian Revolution of the thirties . . . The

    Keynesian step from one to two economics was crucial: the ice of monoeconomics had been

    broken and the idea that there might be yet another economics had instant credibility.23

    Just as the Keynesian Revolution made possible an economics of development, it created the

    economic justification to develop an approach to the Indian economy, an Indian economics,

    which did not need recourse to history. On theoretical grounds alone, as Keynes showed, there

    are compelling arguments for multiple approaches to the study of economics. It was this door,

    which Keynes created, that Rao and his successors entered, leaving history behind. It would not

    be till the 1960s that Indian economists would seriously reckon with economic history.

    Marxism

    While economists, especially those of a more mainstream persuasion, abandoned economic

    history in the 1940s and 1950s, the growing influence of Marxism, most strikingly among

    historians, infused economic history with new life and energy. Even in the early decades of the

    twentieth century historians of India had dealt with economic questions, such as A. Appadorais

    monumental two-volume study of economic conditions in medieval South India.24

    In the 1950s

    there were figures such as N. K. Sinha in Bengal, who wrote a path-breaking three volume

    economic history of Bengal from the mid-eighteenth to the mid-nineteenth century.25

    However,

    the bulk of historical research focused on political history and the state.

    A Marxian interpretation of the Indian past emerged after Indian independence in 1947,

    displacing the high politics that had reigned supreme for several decades. According to Sumit

    23Albert O. Hirschman, The Rise and Decline of Development Economics, in his Essays in Trespassing: Economics

    to Politics and Beyond(Cambridge, 1981), p. 6.24

    A. Appadorai, Economic Conditions in Southern India (1000-1500 A.D.), 2 vols. (Madras, 1936).25

    N. K. Sinha, The Economic History of Bengal, 3 vols. (Calcutta, 1956-70).

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    10/20

    Sarkar, the change in historical sensibilities emerged from the conjuncture of the 1950s and

    1960s, marked by a strong and apparently growing Left presence in Indian political and

    intellectual life . . . It was not mainstream British or American historiography, not even writings

    on South Asian themes, but a journal likePast and Present, the transition debate, and the work

    of historians like Hill, Hobsbawm and Thompson . . . that appeared most stimulating to Indian

    scholars exploring new ways of looking at history.26

    The injection of Marxism into history writing in India opened up whole new worlds of

    possibilities. One of these was economic history, which flourished in major history departments

    of India from the 1960s. Many of the contributions to Indian economic history made in those

    decades were closely connected to research in social history, which too was energized by the

    Marxian turn.

    The impact of Marxism and its contribution to a deeper engagement with economic life was felt

    across the long span of the Indian past. The study of ancient India was reinvigorated under the

    influence of D. D. Kosambi and his highly original use of Marxism as a starting point for

    historical inquiry. As Romila Thapar writes, The outstanding exponent of the Marxist

    interpretation of Indian history in all its complexity and the one, who ushered in a paradigm shift

    in the study of ancient Indian history, was D D Kosambi. The paradigm shift was the move away

    from colonial and nationalist frameworks and the centrality of dynastic history to a new

    framework integrating social and economic history and relating the cultural dimensions of the

    past to these investigations . . . For him history was the presentation in chronological order of

    successive developments in the means and relations of production.27

    26Sumit Sarkar, The Many Worlds of Indian History, in his Writing Social History(Delhi, 1997), p. 37.

    27Romila Thapar, Early Indian History and the Legacy of DD Kosmabi, Resonance, June 2011, p. 553-4.

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    11/20

    Kosambi also influenced scholarship in medieval history with his arguments for the utility of the

    concept of feudalism in the study of India, in the usage of Kosambi from the classical to the

    medieval period.28

    R. S. Sharma developed these ideas further.29

    The debate on Indian feudalism

    sparked a major comparative exchange in theJournal of Peasant Studies on the appropriateness

    of the category for understanding societies outside Europe. Harbans Mukhia initiated the

    exchange with his essay, Was There Feudalism in Indian History?30

    The influence of Marxism was felt elsewhere in the study of medieval India, perhaps most

    strikingly in studies of the Mughal Empire where the focus shifted from the personalities of the

    ruling emperors to material conditions. Investigations were undertaken on the agrarian order,

    technology, commerce, banking, feudalism, and the potentialities of capitalism. Irfan Habib was

    the giant who loomed over the field of Mughal studies and his great work, theAgrarian System

    of Mughal India, was published in 1963. His structuralist interpretation of the empire and his

    articulation of lines of class conflict to explain the crisis of the empire and its decline took

    Mughal history by storm.31

    Modern history as well came under the Marxian rethink. While the study of the nationalist

    movement continued to be of great importance for historians of modern India, the rise of social

    history led to a greater emphasis on material conditions and, therefore, economic life. Sumit

    Sarkar sees the development of economic history one of the major areas of advance in the study

    of modern India, which was also furthered by the fuller development of the nationalist paradigm

    enriched through more sophisticated tools and empirical detail the basic critique of colonial

    28D. D. Kosambi, Stages of Indian History, in his Combined Methods in Indology and Other Writings (Delhi, 2002),

    pp. 57-72.29

    R. S. Sharma, Indian Feudalism (Calcutta, 1965).30

    T. J. Byres and Harbans Mukhia (eds.), Feudalism and Non-European Societies (London, 1985).31

    This is how several years ago Harbans Mukhia described the impact of the book to me.

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    12/20

    policies and structures that had been initiated by the first generation of nationalist economists

    and developed by Marxists like R. P. Dutt.32

    Modern economic and social historians tackled a broad range of issues, including demography,

    external as well as internal trade, finance, banking and currency questions, and national income

    estimation. However, the economic and social history of modern Indian has centered on

    agriculture and industry, which is not surprising given that these sector loomed large in policy

    discussions on economic development after independence. Nevertheless, it is somewhat

    surprising that important issues such as Indias place in the global order, which had been a

    longstanding concern for nationalist economic historians of the late nineteenth and early

    twentieth century, received so little attention from historians. Dadhabai Naoroji, Romesh

    Chander Dutt and others were deeply concerned with the drain of wealth from India to Britain,

    which they saw as operating through the international payments and settlements system. G.

    Balachandran sees the neglect of this topic as due to the canonical status of the nationalist

    economists who wrote on the subject . . . the tightening of Indias external economic controls

    since the 1950s; and the complicit evolution of disciplinary regimes in both mainstream

    economics and history.33

    The last point, on the divergent paths of history and economics, is one

    that this essay will return to.

    While the study of Indias place in the world economy has been neglected for the modern period,

    it has flourished with respect to the period between 1500 and 1800. These centuries were

    traditionally considered to form part of the medieval history of India, but they are now

    increasingly considered to mark the flowering of an early modernity, manifest in economic, as

    32Sarkar, The Many Worlds of Indian History, p. 39.

    33G. Balachandran, Introduction, in G. Balachandran (ed.), India and the World Economy 1850-1950 (Delhi,

    2003), p. 1.

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    13/20

    well as political, social and cultural life. In the 1960s and 1970s Indian economic historians,

    most notably, Ashin Das Gupta, produced major studies of subcontinents maritime connections

    and lay the foundation for the new field of Indian Ocean studies.

    Despite these exciting developments in pre-colonial trade history, when it came to the colonial

    period, agriculture and industry ruled the day. The agrarian turn waspart of a larger return of

    the peasant to South Asian history, in Eric Stokes evocative language and from the 1960s

    enormous numbers of regional and local histories of agriculture were produced. These ranged

    from investigations of the British revenue settlements, a well-worn path of research, to the land

    market in colonial India, class relations in the countryside, to studies of famine. The richness of

    this scholarship defies easy summary and the continued value of many of these studies cannot be

    overstated.34

    The most important Marxian debate in the agrarian history of India has come to be known as the

    mode of production debate and it took place in the 1960s and 1970s with many of the major

    contributions published in theEconomic and Political Weekly.35

    The essence of the debate was

    empirical and theoretical disagreements on how to categorize the mode of production in

    agriculture in India. The exchange began in the early 1960s within economists who were

    attempting to understand the nature of capitalist relations of production in contemporary Indian

    agriculture. The debate broadened quickly, however, to ask if the contemporary agrarian order

    could be even labeled capitalist, with feudalism and semi-feudalism proposed as alternatives.

    The debate also broadened its temporal focus to include commercial relations in the countryside

    34For a sense of the richness and range of agrarian history in recent decades see Binay Bhushan Chaudhuri,

    Peasant History of Late Pre-Colonial and Colonial India (New Delhi, 2008).35

    For a selection of key contributions to the debate see Utsa Patnaik (ed.),Agrarian Relations and Accumulation:

    The Mode of Production Debate in India (Delhi, 1990).

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    14/20

    during the period of British rule and the extent to which the coming of independence represented

    a break in the development of agriculture. In terms of the historical dimension of the debate, the

    contributions of Jairus Banaji, especially his Capitalist Domination and the Small Peasantry:

    Deccan Districts in the Late Nineteenth Century, were to be of the greatest importance.

    Although the debate was at times highly technical, and occasionally appeared to be overly

    concerned with semantics, its impact was felt widely in the writing of Indian agrarian history.

    The bulk of the participants in the mode of production debate focused on contemporary India,

    which reflected the larger disconnecteven within Marxian economicsbetween economics

    and history, which as we have seen emerged in the 1930s. Nevertheless, the vigor with which

    economists embraced the historical dimensions is reminiscent of Indian economic thinking in the

    early decades of the twentieth century, at the time when the discipline was searching for an

    Indian political economy. This may be attributed to the historicism of Marxism, but as we shall

    see, in the 1960s there was to some extent a rediscovery of history by Indian economists.

    Industrialization and deindustrialization was the second major area of research within an

    economic and social history inspired by the Marxian turn. The deindustrialization of nineteenth-

    century Indian regions was a key plank of the nationalist critique of British rule and figured in

    Romesh Chander Dutts economic history of India. Amiya Bagchis study of manufacturing

    employment in nineteenth-century Bihar may be the most important modern study of

    deindustrialization and sparked a renewed discussion and debate which drew participants from

    India as well as around the world.

    Bagchi is also the author of what may be the most important study of industrialization in

    twentieth-century India,Private Investment of India. While the work is influenced by Keynesian

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    15/20

    macroeconomics, with its emphasis on demand as a crucial limit on private investment in the

    early decades of the twentieth century, its larger thesis is that before the First World it was the

    governmental policy of free trade, and after the war it was the general depression in the capitalist

    system combined with the halting and piecemeal policy of tariff protection adopted b y the

    Government of India, that limited the rate of investment in modern industry.36

    With this

    argument Bagchi took on a long line of thinkers who had argued that the problem of slow Indian

    growth and development was due to supply side factors such as lack of capital, entrepreneurship

    or Indian values.

    Bagchi combined his historical interests with research on contemporary themes. Both interests

    were brought together in hisPolitical Economy of Underdevelopment, which ranged beyond

    India to include discussions of Latin America, Indonesia and China, as well as the analysis of

    several problems in economic development, including land reform, labour, capital and the state,

    population growth, and planning.37

    Bagchis work then has investigated some of the classic

    themes in Indian economic history as inaugurated by the nationalists of the late nineteenth and

    early twentieth century, including deindustrialization, the constrained industrialization of British

    India, the extraction of resources through agricultural taxation and the drain. (Bagchi has also

    produced seminal works on the financial history of British India.38

    )

    The continuity between nationalist economic history and Marxian economic history illustrates

    what Sumit Sarkar has called a Left nationalist-Marxist consensus. He wrote, As the example

    of economic history indicates, there was considerable scope in modern Indian history for a kind

    36Amiya Kumar Bagchi, Private Investment in India 1900-1939 (Cambridge, 1972), p. 19.

    37Amiya Kumar Bagchi, The Political Economy of Underdevelopment(Cambridge, 1982).

    38See his The Presidency Banks and the Indian Economy, 1876-1914 (Calcutta, 1989) and his multi-volume history

    of the State Bank of India, The Evolution of the State Bank of India.

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    16/20

    of Left nationalist-Marxist consensus, a rough counterpart perhaps in historiography to the

    Nehruvian consensus which, at least in retrospect, seems to have characterized middle-class

    Indian intellectual life during those decades.39

    This consensus, along with an admixture of social and economic history, dominated major

    history departments in India from the 1960s. Even as late as 1997, a volume celebrating the

    seventy-fifth anniversary of Delhi University, which was founded in 1922, described the history

    department, one of the leading in India, in the following terms: Almost every member of the

    present Faculty has been constantly working on various aspects of socio-economic history

    cutting across chronological frontiers of Indian history . . . The Department has, over the years,

    set to achieve itsobjectives, viz. lhistorire (sic) integrale: the study of total history over the

    long (sic) duree.40

    Economists Re-Engage with the Past

    While Marxism was reshaping the writing of history from the 1950s, economists at what

    had become the preeminent center for research and teaching of the discipline, the Delhi School

    of Economics, began to re-engage with the study of the past. In the closing years of the decade

    V. K. R. V. Rao, who established the Delhi School in 1949 and later became the Vice-Chancellor

    of Delhi University, invited Tapan Raychaudhuri to join the economics department, which he did

    in February 1959.41

    In the early 1950s Raychaudhuri received a PhD in History from Calcutta

    University with a dissertation on the social history of Bengal in the Mughal period, after which

    he embarked upon a teaching career in Calcutta. Several years later he completed a DPhil in

    History at Oxford on the trade of the Dutch East India Company in South India. Upon returning

    39Sarkar, The Many Worlds of Indian History, p. 39.

    40R. B. Jain (ed.), The University of Delhi: Faculties and Departments, A Profile (Delhi, 2000), p. 165.

    41Tapan Raychaudhuri, The World in Our Time: A Memoir(Noida, 2011), p. 274.

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    17/20

    to India he took up a post as the Deputy Director and Acting Director of the National Archives of

    India.

    It is not clear why Rao, who as previously noted showed little inclination towards

    economic history in his own career as an economist, asked a historian to join the economics

    department. It is clearer, however, why Rao had to turn to someone trained as a historian and not

    as an economist: the decline of economic history within economics had meant that very fewif

    anyIndian economists had been trained in that field in recent decades. Raychaudhuri describes

    feeling lost in the midst of very high-powered theoretical economics. This period was perhaps

    the heyday of the Delhi School as it boasted on its economics faculty K. N. Raj, Amartya Sen,

    Sukhamoy Chakravarty and Jagdish Bhagwati. Raychaudhuri writes in his memoir that he

    realized that he had made a mistake in coming. At the same time, the colleagues were

    extremely accommodating. In 1964 a chair in economic history was created, to which he was

    appointed, and the department took a decision to specialize in economic history and economic

    development. This allowed for the addition of a reader in economic history, to which post

    Dharma Kumar was appointed, and the establishment of a visiting professorship in economic

    history, which drew top economic historians from the United Kingdom, including M. M. Postan,

    John Habakkuk and Peter Mathias, the United States, Japan and the USSR. According to

    Raychaudhuri, My colleagues were aware of my predicament, the professional isolation from

    which I suffered, and did their best to make me feel at home.42

    With the growing presence of

    economic history at the school other members of the faculty were encouraged to venture into the

    42Raychaudhuri, The World in Our Time, pp. 278-9.

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    18/20

    field. Amartya Sen, for example, undertook studies of industrialization in India in the second half

    of the nineteenth century.43

    In 1963 Tapan Raychaudhuri and Dharma Kumar launched theIndian Economic and

    Social History Review, which remains the leading journal of Indian economic history. The initial

    editorial committee included R. S. Sharma, Nurul Hasan, Ranajit Guha, K. N. Raj, M. N.

    Srinivas, Amarty Sen, Irfan Habib and Dharma Kumar with Tapan Raychaudhuri as the

    Managing Editor. The journal, as suggested by the name and this group, had an interest in

    economic questions but broadly defined to include the social and political dimensions. (Over

    time cultural questions came increasingly under the purview of the journal as well.) This broad

    approach characterized the articles as well. The first issue of the journal contained essays on the

    nature of land rights in Mughal India, the pattern of public investment in early twentieth-century

    India, and two pieces on the nationalist movement and the agrarian economy.

    Dharma Kumar and Tapan Raychaudhuri teamed up again to produce the Cambridge

    Economic of History. The former (with the assistance of Meghnad Desai on the statistical parts),

    edited the second volume, which covered the period from the mid-eighteenth century to the

    present. The latter, along with Irfan Habib, edited the first volume, which ranged from 1200 to

    1750.44

    It was an unlikely editorial team. Tapan Raychaudhuri was a staunch nationalist, who

    had been jailed in 1942 during the Quit India movement and Habib was a leading Marxist

    historian. Dharma Kumar, in the meantime, had made her name with an important critique of the

    nationalist narrative, arguing in herLand and Caste in South India that landless labor in South

    43The Commodity Pattern of British Enterprise in Early Indian Industrialization 1854-1914, in the Proceedings of

    the Second International Conference of Economic History(Paris,1965); The Pattern of British Enterprise in India

    1854-1914: A Causal Analysis, in B. Singh andV. B. Singh, eds., Social and Economic Change (Bombay: Allied

    Publishers, 1967).44

    Raychaudhuri, The World in Our Time, p. 280.

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    19/20

    India was not a creation of British rule but predated it.45

    The second volume of the Cambridge

    EconomicHistory did not subscribe to the nationalist line and was criticized widely for this.46

    In the 1970s economic history (along with econometrics) flourished at the Delhi

    School.47

    Economic history benefitted from the fact that it made sense for students to remain at

    the school to pursue doctorates in it, as opposed to going to the UK or the USA.48

    From the

    1960s the Delhi School produced a number of very fine economic historians, including Om

    Prakash, Omkar Goswami and Sanjay Subrahmanyam. Much of this work was not narrowly

    economic in its focus and included the social and political domains, as did the articles in the

    Indian Economic and Social History Review, and the interests and methods of the economic

    historians at the Delhi School shared much with historians in Delhi and elsewhere in India.

    While fine quantitative work emerged from the Delhi School, such as that of S.

    Sivasubramaniam on national income, cliometrics did not find a home, perhaps not least because

    of the poor quality of much Indian data.49

    Conclusion

    In retrospect, the two-volume Cambridge Economic History of India marked the end of

    the heyday of economic history in India. While excellent work continued even after its

    publication in 1982, economic history slowly lost much of its glamour. The Delhi School of

    Economics has no faculty in economic history. The leading history departments in India have

    shifted from social and economic history to social and cultural history. From the history

    45Dharma Kumar, Land and Caste in South India (Cambridge, 1965).

    46Irfan Habib, Studying a Colonial Economy without Perceiving Colonialism, Modern Asian Studies, 19 (1985), pp.

    355-81.47

    Interview with Dilip Mookherjee, May 9, 2012.48

    Dharma Kumar and Dilip Mookherjee (eds.), The D. School: Reflections on the Delhi School of Economics (Delhi,

    1995).49

    S. Sivasubramaniam, The National Income of India in the Twentieth Century(Delhi, 2000).

  • 7/28/2019 The History of Indian Economic History

    20/20

    recounted in this paper, the decline of economic history may be seen as the outcome of two

    developments.

    The first is the decline of Marxism, which had been the source of the economic turn in

    history departments from the 1950s. Of course, historians were not narrow economic historians

    and placed economic life in a broader context, but the economic came to be less central with the

    dwindling appeal of Marxism. For some, the shift from the economic was a reaction to crude

    reductionism, but for many it was a slow evolution as new concerns came to the fore. The career

    of Harbans Mukhia may be illustrative in which a shift from Marxism came from a deepening

    engagement with the Annales and the total history of that approach. 50 (This tension has already

    been seen in the Delhi University history departments commitment to social and economic

    history as well as total history.)

    The second is the rise of a universal economics, or monoeconomics, within departments

    of economics. The search for an alternate paradigm drove the turn to history in Indian economics

    in the late nineteenth century. In the 1960s economic history appears to have flourished in

    tandem with development economics as they both sought to construct a framework that could

    help untangle the problems of the Indian economy. The growing influence of neoclassical

    economics and its universalization has eliminated the need for a historical approach in

    contemporary Indian economics.

    50See the intellectual biography of Mukhia by Rajat Datta in Rajat Datta (ed.), Rethinking a Millenium: Perspectives

    on Indian History from the Eighth to the Eighteenth Century, Essays for Harbans Mukhia (Delhi, 2008).