36
1 The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva 1 August 2017 ABSTRACT This work examines how the tax composition - income taxes on individuals, corporate tax and taxes on consumption and property - affects income inequality and economic growth. Using a panel of 25 developed countries over the last three decades we estimate the relationship between the tax composition and two variables: the Gini index and per capita GDP growth. Potential endogeneity is addressed by creating a time-gap between the independent and the dependent variables. We find that income taxes on individuals and non-recurrent property taxes are negatively correlated with inequality and economic growth; corporate tax impedes economic growth and has no clear impact on inequality; taxes on consumption increase both inequality and growth. Municipal taxes neither support growth nor reduce inequality. We construct two country specific measures for the extent the tax composition supports (or discourages) equality and economic growth. These indicators are used to design a feasible efficiency frontier that represents the tradeoff between economic growth and equality. We show that some countries (Germany, Sweden and Finland) are close to the frontier, while others have ample room for improving at least one policy objective through efficiency gains. Key Words: Taxation Policy, Inequality, Economic Growth, Panel Estimation Categories JEL: E63, H21, D63 1 We wish to thank our colleagues in the Chief Economist's Department for their helpful comments. We are also grateful to Lihi Shafran, Ido Hanegbi, Katya Mazirova and Sari Band for their help in the writing of the research. This work reflects only the views of its authors.

The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    5

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

1

The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth

Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1

August 2017

ABSTRACT

This work examines how the tax composition - income taxes on individuals, corporate tax and

taxes on consumption and property - affects income inequality and economic growth. Using a

panel of 25 developed countries over the last three decades we estimate the relationship

between the tax composition and two variables: the Gini index and per capita GDP growth.

Potential endogeneity is addressed by creating a time-gap between the independent and the

dependent variables. We find that income taxes on individuals and non-recurrent property

taxes are negatively correlated with inequality and economic growth; corporate tax impedes

economic growth and has no clear impact on inequality; taxes on consumption increase both

inequality and growth. Municipal taxes neither support growth nor reduce inequality. We

construct two country specific measures for the extent the tax composition supports (or

discourages) equality and economic growth. These indicators are used to design a feasible

efficiency frontier that represents the tradeoff between economic growth and equality. We

show that some countries (Germany, Sweden and Finland) are close to the frontier, while

others have ample room for improving at least one policy objective through efficiency gains.

Key Words: Taxation Policy, Inequality, Economic Growth, Panel Estimation

Categories JEL: E63, H21, D63

1 We wish to thank our colleagues in the Chief Economist's Department for their helpful comments. We

are also grateful to Lihi Shafran, Ido Hanegbi, Katya Mazirova and Sari Band for their help in the

writing of the research. This work reflects only the views of its authors.

Page 2: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

2

Section 1 – Introduction

In recent decades, inequality has grown in most OECD countries - Brys et al. (2016).

Frequently mentioned drivers of this trend are: (1) an increase in the wage gap in favor of the

highly educated as a result of technological changes; (2) changes in employment patterns

which have led to an increase in the share of part-time jobs and low-paying jobs; (3)

demographic changes; (4) a decrease in the contribution of the tax system and of transfer

payments to the reduction of inequality OECD (2011, 2015).

The tax composition affects net inequality in two ways: first, taxes have a different degree of

progressiveness, and therefore the mixture of taxes is responsible for part of the difference

between market inequality (prior to governmental intervention, refer to Appendix A.1) and

net inequality. Second, the tax composition affects economic incentives (e.g., labor market

incentives), and thus indirectly affects net inequality. In addition, the tax composition has

various channels of impact on economic growth. Tax policy affects economic incentives

related both to investment and labor decisions, more specifically, it influences the financial

profitability of investments and it changes the amount of effort workers choose to invest, and

skills they choose to acquire.

This work examines how the tax composition – i.e., the division of tax revenue to income

taxes on individuals, corporate taxes, taxes on consumption and property taxes - affects net

inequality and economic growth. Our analysis is based on a panel of OECD countries in the

years 1970 – 2012. This paper is part of a relatively new and growing literature which deals

with the effect of the tax composition on macro-economic variables (Arnold, 2008, Arnold et

al., 2011; Ormachea and Yoo, 2012) and on the factors of production (Heckman et al. 1998;

Gould and Moav, 2007; Gentry and Hubbard, 2000). This paper contributes to the existing

literature in three main ways: first, the analysis takes into account behavioral changes that

arise in response to tax policy; second, the analysis distinguishes between the impact of a

specific tax and the impact derived from changes in the overall tax burden; finally, it presents

the efficiency frontier of equality and growth tradeoff with respect to the tax composition.

We find that income taxes on individuals and non-periodic property taxes reduce inequality

and growth; corporate taxes were found to have no significant effect on inequality and a

negative effect on growth, and that an increase of the share of consumption taxes increases

both inequality and growth. These results highlight the existing tradeoff between the degree to

which the tax composition supports growth and its ability to increase equality. However, most

countries are far from the efficient equality/growth frontier and thus have ample room for

gains on both the equality and growth aspects via the tax system by improving the efficiency

Page 3: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

3

of the tax composition. Moreover, we show that the distance to the efficiency frontier has

increased in the last three decades.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 presents the main trends in

inequality, growth and tax systems in OECD countries; Section 3 reviews the relevant

literature; Section 4 describes the data used for this study; Section 5 outlines our

methodology; Section 6 presents the main results; Section 7 discusses the policy implications

for tax policy, equality and growth; Section 8 summarizes.

Section 2 – Trends in Inequality, Economic Growth and Tax Composition

2.1 Trends in inequality

In most OECD countries income inequality has increased over the past few decades. This

trend persists despite efforts to reduce inequality by increasing the tax burden. The few

OECD countries in which income inequality has decreased are those who had high levels of

inequality at the initial period of the sample (e.g., Turkey and Mexico).

Chart 1 - The Gini Index of Inequality in 1980 and 2011

(Change between 1980 to 2011 in percentage points)

Market Inequality - Pre-taxes and Transfer Payments.

Por

tuga

l Ir

elan

dB

rita

inG

reec

eS

pain

Isra

elU

SA

Ger

man

yF

ranc

eIt

aly

Aus

tral

iaH

unga

ryS

wed

en

New

Zea

land D

enm

ark

Fin

land

C

anad

aP

olan

dL

uxem

bour

gB

elgi

um

Nor

way

S

wit

zerl

and

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

Chi

le

Mex

ico

Hol

land

Tur

key

Est

onia

Aus

tria

Cze

ch R

epub

lic

Slo

vaki

aS

love

nia

Icel

and

Japa

n

Increase in

Inequality Decrease in

Inequality

Partial Data

1980 2011

Page 4: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

4

Net Inequality - After Taxes and Transfer Payments

2.2 Trends in economic growth

During the last few decades GDP growth among OECD countries has been characterized by a

10 years business cycles (Chart 2). These business cycles are highly correlated with those of

US2, a fact that emphasizes the interdependence between advanced economies.

The average GDP growth rates (Chart 3) illustrate a beta-convergence where countries with

lower GDP per capita (e.g. Mexico, Chile, Korea and Israel) grow faster than countries with

higher initial GDP per capita. This rationale is based on the law of diminishing return to

capital. According to this notion one should expect countries like Greece and Italy to

demonstrate higher rates of averaged growth than those shown. However, these two belong to

a group of economies which suffered severely from both the global financial crisis and the

Eurozone crisis which uncovered structural problems which has impeded recovery.

2 http://www.nber.org/cycles.html

Isra

elU

SA

Bri

tain

Sp

ain

Po

rtu

gal

New

Zea

lan

dA

ust

rali

aIt

aly

Can

ada

Po

lan

dF

ran

ceG

erm

any

Hu

ng

ary

Lu

xem

bo

urg

Fin

land

Ho

llan

dD

enm

ark

Bel

giu

mN

orw

ayS

wed

en

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

Ch

ile

Mex

ico

Tu

rkey

Gre

ece

Sw

itze

rlan

dIr

elan

d

Est

on

iaA

ust

ria

Slo

vak

iaS

lov

enia

Cze

ch R

epu

bli

cIc

elan

dJa

pan

1980 2011

Page 5: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

5

-4.0

-3.0

-2.0

-1.0

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

5.0

6.0

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

OECD Average Growth

Chart 3 – GDP per capita (1980), Average Growth (1980-2015)

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

12000

14000

16000

18000

20000

Ko

rea

Ch

ile

Po

rtu

gal

Me

xico

Gre

ece

Isra

el

Spai

n

Ire

lan

d

New

Zea

lan

d

Ital

y

Jap

an

OEC

D a

vrag

e

Fin

lan

d

Un

ite

d K

ingd

om

Au

stri

a

Au

stra

lia

Ger

man

y

Can

ada

Un

ite

d S

tate

s

Be

lgiu

m

Fran

ce

Net

her

lan

ds

De

nm

ark

No

rway

Swed

en

Swit

zerl

and

GDP per capita Growth

Page 6: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

6

Chart 4 – GDP per capita (1980, 2015)

2.3 Trends in the Tax Burden

Over the last three decades, on average, OECD countries have increased their tax

burden(Chart 5). The tax burden increased significantly during 1980-2000 whereas the years

of 2000-2011 were characterized by a stable tax burden, amounting to approximately 35% of

GDP, on average. When observing the changes in each country separately (Chart 6), one

notices that there were countries in which the tax burden increased substantially (Italy,

Finland, Turkey, Greece) while in others the tax burden decreased (Israel, Hungary, Canada).

In other countries, no substantial changes occurred (Britain, Sweden, USA).

Greece

Italy

Denmark

Germany

France

Switzerland

Belgium

Austria

Japan

FinlandNetherlandsUK

Portugal

Spain

Sweden

Canada

Norway

OECD averageNew Zealand

USA

Mexico

Australia

Israel

Chile

Ireland

Korea

0

10,000

20,000

30,000

40,000

50,000

60,000

70,000

80,000

0 3,000 6,000 9,000 12,000 15,000 18,000

2015

1980

Page 7: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

7

Average Percentage Point Range 25 – 75

Net

herl

ands

Hun

gary

Isra

el

Pol

and

Est

onia

Slo

vak

Rep

ubli

c

Irel

and

Fra

nce

Ital

y

Aus

tria

Ger

man

y

Icel

and

Por

tuga

l

Gre

ece

Spa

in

Japa

n

Sw

itze

rlan

d

Tur

key

Mex

ico

Den

mar

k

Fin

land

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%Increase in the Tax

Burden

(1980-2011)

Decrease in the Tax

Burden

(1995-2011)

Chart 5 - Tax Burden, 1980 - 2011 (% of GDP, OECD Countries)

Chart 6 - Tax Burden in Selected Years

(% of GDP, Selected Countries*, From the Highest in 2011 to the Lowest)

*Countries in which the tax burden either increased or decreased by more than 3% during the relevant

period.

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

1980 1990 2000 2010

Page 8: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

8

The Tax Composition

Chart 7 shows the tax composition in 2013, by country. Income taxes on individuals

constitute the main revenue source in many countries (such as the USA). The second largest

revenue source is consumption taxes. This revenue source is particularly high in countries in

which income taxation of individuals is relatively low (Chile, for example). The shares of

corporate and property taxes in the total revenues are relatively smaller.

Chart 7 - Tax Composition in OECD Countries, 2013

(In Percentages of Total Collection, Sorted According to the Share of Direct Taxes)

0 20 40 60 80 100

Australia

Denmark

USA

Canada

Switzerland

Norway

New Zealand

Sweden

Japan

Austria

Luxembourg

Germany

Ireland

Belgium

OECD

Netherlands

United Kingdom

Portugal

Israel

Finland

Korea

Italy

Hungary

Slovenia

Greece

Chile

France

Poland

Spain

Turkey

Czech Republic

Direct on Individuals Corporations Consumption Property Others

Page 9: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

9

8%

11%

14%

17%

20%

1980 1990 2000 2010

Direct Taxes on Individuals

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

1980 1990 2000 2010

Income Tax on Companies

6%

9%

12%

15%

1980 1990 2000 2010

Tax on Consumption

0%

1%

2%

3%

1980 1990 2000 2010

Taxes on real estate

The relative importance of the various tax categories as a source of revenue for OECD

countries has not changed substantially during the last three decades (Chart 8): income tax on

individuals constitutes the principal source of revenue, 12% - 14% of GDP on average; taxes

on consumption contribute about 10% - 12%; corporation income taxes have a much lower

share of 2.5% - 4% and taxes on real estate contribute less than 2%. During the reviewed

period, the share of corporate income tax and consumption taxes has increased at the expense

of income tax on individuals. The share of real estate taxes has not changed significantly.

Chart 8 - Trends in the Composition of Taxes, 1980 - 2010 (% of GDP, OECD Countries)

Section 3 - Literature review

Tax composition and inequality

In most studies, the effect of specific taxes on inequality is examined by using microdata

simulations based on household surveys (e.g., Immervoll et al., 2005). These simulations

suffer from two main methodologic flaws. First, they only examine the direct effect of

changes in a specific tax on inequality (Appendix A.1, Arrow A) and do not take into account

Average Percentage Point Range 25 – 75

Page 10: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

10

the indirect effect stemming from behavioral changes (Arrow B) or from political reasons

(Arrow C). Second, these calculations do not take into account that a change in a specific tax

brings about changes in the total tax burden or in the collection of other taxes. For example, if

the VAT rate is raised, it raises the tax burden or alternatively allows for a reduction of other

taxes (while keeping the tax burden constant). In light of these shortcomings we examine the

effect of the tax composition on inequality by using an econometric estimation model, based

on a macro level panel dataset. This approach enables us to estimate the overall effect - both

income and consumption - of changes in the tax composition on inequality. Furthermore, it

allows us to analyze the impact of corporate and property taxes whose effect on inequality3 is

difficult to estimate using static simulations which rely on household level data.

A few studies use a macro-level econometric approach to estimate the effect of the tax

composition on inequality. Duncan and Sabirianova (2012) examined the effect of

progressivity on different measures of inequality and found that progressivity influences

observed inequality more than it affects actual inequality4. They deal with the issue of

endogeneity, originated from both the omission of relevant variables and simultaneity, by

utilizing a 2SLS estimation. Changes in the tax regimes of neighboring countries are used as

an instrumental variable. While this approach does offer some measure of treatment to the

endogeneity issue, it fails to deal with regionally or globally correlated business cycles.

Furthermore, the authors do not control for the aggregate debt burden, and thus their results

do not reflect a full equilibrium. As noted before, a change in the tax system could lead to a

change in public expenditure, which in turn affects inequality. Liu and Martinez‐Vazquez

(2015) employ a similar methodology to examine the impact of tax composition on inequality

and growth. With respect to income taxes, their results reveal some tradeoff in the way in

which these taxes affect inequality and growth. No clear tradeoff was found regarding the

influence of excise taxes.

According to the literature, there are a few common variables which affect inequality. In our

estimation we include variables suggested by Williamson and Higgins (2002), which

generally relate to the following three factors:

1. Economic development: According to Kuznets (1955), the effect of GDP per capita

on inequality is not linear. The structural and technological process that accompanies

economic development tends to increase inequality at the early stages of development

3 The Gini Index for inequality, which we have used in this research, is based on incomes and does not relate to the

wealth distribution, due to data constraints. The effect of property taxes, and corporate taxes reflects the correlation

with the income Gini Index only and is not indicative of these taxes effect on wealth inequality. 4 The authors use consumption based Gini as a proxy for actual inequality.

Page 11: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

11

(due to increasing demand for capital and for skilled workers) and to lower inequality

at a later stage, as the rate of growth slows down.

2. Demographics: A particularly large cohort (e.g. the "baby boom" generation in the

USA) decreases average wages due to the influx of workers. Accordingly, when this

cohort is at the peak of its earnings inequality is reduced; and when it reaches

retirement, inequality is increased. The demographic structure also influences

inequality because a high proportion of children or the elderly with lower income

potential increases inequality.

3. Openness to foreign trade: Williamson and Higgins (2002) suggest that openness to

foreign trade increases inequality in developed countries and reduces it in developing

countries. They find a negative connection between openness and inequality in

general. However, no empiric support for the claim regarding the differences between

developed countries to developing ones was found.

Tax composition and growth

Previous literature has focused mainly on how the tax burden affects factors of production

and technology level, whereas recently more attention has been given to the effect of the tax

composition itself rather than the overall burden.

Hall and Jorgenson (1967) find that reducing taxation on physical capital increases the

incentive for short term investments. Heckman et al., (1998) and Moav and Gould (2007)

examine how human capital decisions are affected by taxes and the phenomenon of "brain

drain", respectively. They find that a progressive tax system with respect to income taxes

discourages accumulation of human capital, and that highly educated people are more likely

to migrate than less educated people, with income playing a significant role in the decision

making process. The impact of taxes on the labor supply in the short term is not straight-

forward. However, evidence suggests that a higher tax burden reduces labor supply regardless

of the elasticity level. For further discussion see Brender and Gallo (2009), Brender and

Strawczynski (2006).

Taxation also affects the number of active entrepreneurs and the channels firms use to finance

their activities. Thus, taxation affects technological advancement. Gentry and Hubbard (2000)

claim that progressivity creates asymmetry according to which in case of successes, the

entrepreneurs pay relatively higher taxes rather than the taxes they save in case of failure.

Page 12: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

12

Devereux et al., (2008) find that in order to attract multinational companies, OECD countries

compete with each other on the level of corporate and capital taxes. Multinational firms were

also found to contribute to higher levels of investment and productivity (Balsvik, 2011).

Kneller et al. (1999) studied the effect of the tax composition on growth in 22 OECD

countries for the years 1970-1995. They divide taxes into two categories – distorting and non-

distorting taxes and find the first group to have a negative effect on economic growth while

the latter has no significant link with economic growth. Arnold (2008) and Arnold et al.

(2011) estimate the impact of tax composition on economic growth in 21 OECD countries for

the years 1970-2004. Arnold et al. (2011) conclude that corporate and individuals' income

taxes reduce GDP growth whereas consumption and property taxes support it. Ormaechea and

Yoo (2012) replicate Arnold's papers while expanding the sample and find similar results with

respect to the negative effect of the tax imposed on individuals. Switching to consumption

and property taxes in expense of income tax in Ireland, was found to be beneficial for both

GDP growth and the employment rate in a study conduct by O'Connor (2013). Canavire-

Bacarreza et al. (2013) consider a sample of Latin American countries. Unlike most research,

their paper indicates no negative impact of personal income taxes and corporate income taxes

on growth for nearly all countries in the sample. With respect to general taxes on goods and

services they come to a similar conclusion as others, suggesting that these taxes promote

economic growth.

Section 4 – Data

The analysis is based on annual data for 1975-2011 focusing on 25 OECD countries for which

available data exists (see Appendix 2 for the country list). In order to maintain uniformity, we

omitted data regarding Germany prior to 1991, Portugal prior to 1994 and Israel prior to 1995.

Data regarding the collection of taxes, public debt, population and employment, is taken from

the OECD database; GDP data and its components are taken from the Penn World Tables;

real exchange rate data is issued by The World Bank; inequality data is taken from the

Standardized World Income Inequality Database (5.0 SWIII, Solt, 2014). To the best of our

knowledge, this database offers the best harmonized inequality data by unifying the data from

various surveys into one dataset taking into account the varying quality of the data. The

inequality index based upon the income ratio of the top ten percent and the bottom ten percent

(the 90/10 Incomes Ratio Index) is calculated based on OECD data.

Page 13: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

13

4.1 Definition of Tax Collection Aggregates

1. Individual income taxes: personal income tax, taxation of profits and capital gains of

individuals, social security contributions and other taxes on employment for which employers

are liable.5

- Taxes on employment of individuals: taxes on income from employment and

employees' national insurance payments.

2. Corporate taxation: taxation of revenues, profits and capital gains of companies.

3. Taxes on consumption: taxes on goods and services and other taxes.

- VAT, GST (Sales Tax) and other general taxes on goods and services.

- Excise taxes: taxation of selected items such as cars, fuels and tobacco.

4. Capital Taxation: recurrent taxation of real estate, recurrent taxation of other

property, inheritance and gifts tax, taxation of capital movements and other taxes on assets.

- Recurrent property taxation: recurrent taxation of real estate, and other recurrent

taxes.

- Non- recurrent property taxation: inheritance tax, estate and gifts tax, and other non-

recurrent taxes.

4.2 Descriptive Statistics

Descriptive statistics for the main variables are shown in Table 1. According to our

methodology, the variables refer to a five year period (a detailed explanation is given in

Section 5). Keeping that in mind, the following statistics relate to the five year period

beginning in the years 1970, 1975, 1980, 1985, 1990, 1995, 2000 and 20056. Table 8 in the

appendix outlines data availability for specific countries.

5 All definitions are based on OECD classification, which can be viewed in detail at:

http://www.oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/tax-database.htm 6 Unlike the rest of the variables, Average growth of GDP per capita relates to the entire sample.

Page 14: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

14

Table 1 – Descriptive Statistics

N Average Min Max SD

Macro variables

Gini Index (5 years average)7 179 30.4 19.4 52.1 7.0

Average GDP per capita growth 189 2.4 -1.5 11.4 1.9

GDP per capita (thousand US Dollar) 189 22.3 2.6 58.9 9.2

Tax burden (as a percentage of GDP) 178 33.1 14.8 51.4 8.9

Unemployment rate 166 5.8 0.0 18.7 3.4

Inflation 187 11.9 -0.7 374.7 36.5

Abs. inflation (>4%) 102 19.3 4.1 374.4 47.4

Openness to foreign trade (as a percentage of

GDP) 185 62.7 10.7 181.7 29.9

Share of the population aged under 15 188 22.8 13.8 46.8 6.4

Share of the population aged 40-59 189 23.1 11.6 30.1 3.7

Tax composition (as a percentage of tax collection)

The share of income taxes on individuals 171 37.5 8.6 61.6 10.3

The share of corporate taxes 173 8.9 1.6 27.0 4.8

The share of taxes on consumption 178 32.7 14.0 65.2 10.5

Of which : VAT and GST 178 16.4 0.0 41.8 6.5

Of which : Excise Taxes 178 9.2 2.2 35.7 4.4

The share of taxes on property 178 6.2 0.5 15.0 3.5

Section 5- Specification

This Section presents the methodology for measuring the effect of the tax composition on net

inequality and economic growth. We estimate the impact of the total tax burden and of

different types of taxes on inequality and growth indices. For the estimation of the effect on

inequality, a set of covariates is added based on Williamson and Higgins (2002), who

provided a review of factors that influenced inequality in 80 countries during 1960-1990. As

previously mentioned, the authors found that inequality is influenced by demography,

7 The Gini index is calculated on disposable income, based on all financial revenues excluding asset

revaluation. We present the index ranging from 0 to 100. Thus, an increase of 0.15 in the Gini Index

refers to an increase of 0.15 hundreds of a point, or an increase of 0.0015 points in the more common

method of presenting the Gini Index.

Page 15: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

15

economic development (depicted as the level of GDP per capita) and by openness to foreign

trade. For the economic growth estimation we add a set of covariates based on Barro (1991,

1996) who found that the per capita growth rate is affected by the initial level of GDP per

capita, inflation, institutions quality, government consumption and by openness to foreign

trade.

The main econometric challenge in estimating the above relations is due to potential

endogeneity and, more specifically, reverse causality. Taxes affect the level of inequality and

the growth rate of the economy but at the same time it is reasonable to assume the opposite

("the Richard and Meltzer Effect"). Both the level of inequality and the pace of economic

growth can influence the tax composition through the tax base and the tax rate. It is common

to address this issue by creating a time-gap between the independent and the dependent

variables. We estimate how an independent variable in a base year (1975, 1980, 1985, 1990,

1995, 2000, and 2005) explains the averaged dependent variable (inequality or economic

growth) during the ensuing 5 year. This methodology was outlined inter alia, by Devarajan

(1996) and Ostry et al. (2014). In order to eliminate further endogeneity that might arise

despite the time gaps, a 2SLS specification is employed (see Section 6 for more details). The

estimated regression equations are as follows:

𝐺𝐼𝑁𝐼𝑖,𝑡+1→𝑡+5 = 𝛽1′ 𝑋𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽2

′ 𝑇𝑆𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽3′ 𝑍𝑖 + 𝛽4

′ 𝑊𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡

∆lny𝑖,𝑡+1→𝑡+5 = 𝛼1′ 𝑋𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼2

′ 𝑇𝑆𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼3′ 𝑍𝑖 + 𝛼4

′ 𝑊𝑡 + 𝑢𝑖,𝑡

Where 𝐺𝐼𝑁𝐼𝑖,𝑡+1→𝑡+5 represents the average net inequality during the subsequent 5 years (t

indicates the base year); ∆lny𝑖,𝑡+1→𝑡+5 symbolizes the average per capita GDP growth during

the 5 following years; X is a design matrix (tax burden, per capita GDP, openness to foreign

trade, inflation, demography and education) that includes appropriate adjustments for each

estimation; TS expresses the share of - income taxation on the earnings of individuals,

corporate tax, taxes on consumption, VAT, purchase taxes, recurrent property taxation, non-

recurrent property taxation – in total tax revenues; Z is a dummy variable for geographic

regions8 and W is a dummy variable for different periods.

Some limitations arise from the definitions of the variables. While the net GINI index reflects

household income inequality (taking into account taxes and transfer payments) it contains

only partial information regarding capital income and does not incorporate consumption and

property. As a result one should bear in mind that the estimated impact of corporate,

8 The results of a robustness test with Fixed Effects regression are given in the Appendix.

Page 16: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

16

consumption and property taxes on inequality might not tell the whole story. An

internationally comparable "consumption GINI index" will allow an extension of the analysis

conducted in this paper.

Section 6 – Estimation Results

6.1 Tax composition and inequality

As mentioned above, the effect of the tax composition on inequality is estimated using

specifications which include factors that were reported to affect inequality in the literature;

the list contains the following variables: GDP per capita, the tax burden, openness to trade

and demographic structure. The estimation results regarding the effect of these variables on

inequality are presented in Table 2 (see Appendix A.2).

We find that higher GDP per capita in the base year reduces Gini values in the ensuing years.

This outcome fits the classic Kuznets model (1955), which predicts a negative relationship

between the level of GDP per capita and inequality in developed economies. The tax burden

was found to have a negative effect on inequality as well. This result is explained by two

main factors: First, most tax systems are progressive with a large share of the revenue derived

from the middle-upper class segments of the population. Second, countries with a higher tax

burden tend to provide larger transfer payments in absolute terms and also as a percentage of

GDP (see Appendix A.3). Openness to foreign trade contributes to a reduction in inequality,

contrary to the theoretical model of Williamson and Higgins (2002), although as mentioned

above, they found on empiric collaboration to this theoretic result. Finally, we find that the

demographic composition has a significant impact on the income gaps, as a greater share of

the population in peak employment and at earnings capacity ages (40-59), reduces the level of

inequality.

Specification (4) in Table 2 was selected as the baseline for the estimation of the impact of tax

composition. Controlling for the total tax burden enables us to examine the effect of

composition changes in the tax system on inequality9. Later in this Section, we report the

cases under which the main specification coefficients differ significantly from those derived

from the alternative estimations. In addition, we have found no evidence of a non-linear

relationship between tax composition and the Gini index.

Table 3 reports the results of estimating the effect of income taxes on inequality. We find that

an increase of the share of income tax on individuals (keeping the tax burden constant)

9 In addition to the tax variables mentioned above each model includes an additional revenues variable

capturing revenues that do not fall under any examined category.

Page 17: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

17

reduces inequality. According to specification (1) an increase of a percentage point in the

share of income tax on individuals (as a share of total revenues) reduces the average Gini by a

cumulative 0.15 points10 during the next 5 years. Specification (2) differentiates between the

effect of income taxes on labor income and the effect of taxation on capital gains of

individuals. The findings indicate that while the taxes on labor income reduce inequality,

taxation of individuals' capital gains positively affects the Gini index. The latter result can

reflect the mismeasurement in calculation of the Gini index, which frequently lacks reliable

information on capital held by individuals.

Specifications (3) - (5) evaluate the effect of corporate taxes on inequality. Specification (3)

reports no impact of corporate taxes on inequality. However, the lack of significance might be

a consequence of a time lag – sometimes there is a substantial lag until the proceeds have

been received (due to appeals or litigation). To deal with this potential endogeneity, we add

specifications (4) and (5) which include an instrumental variable.11 The results obtained are

similar to those obtained by Model (3).

Table 3 - The effect of income taxes on inequality

10 The Gini index is measured on a 0-100 scale. 11 We use an instrumental variable - corporate tax share lagged by 5 years (for example the corporate

tax share in the year 2000 constitutes an instrumental variable for the corporate tax share in 2005). The

selected instrumental variable meets the two required criteria for the exclusion restriction: it is closely

linked with the current corporate tax share and it has no direct effect on inequality.

Dependent Variable: Average Gini index in the five years following the base year

(5)

2SLS

(4)

2SLS

(3)

OLS

(2)

OLS

(1)

OLS

1.750−

(2.031)

−4.025**

(1.641)

−5.336***

(1.241)

−5.491***

(1.018)

−4.639***

(1.031)

Logarithm of per capita

GDP

−0.280***

(0.040)

−0.298***

(0.040)

−0.337***

(0.038)

−0.229***

(0.039)

−0.303***

(0.037) Tax Burden

−2.203**

(0.903)

−2.563***

(0.892)

−0.2832***

(0.913)

−2.752***

(0.827)

−2.733***

(0.859)

Openness to foreign trade

(% of GDP)

0.206−

(0.183)

−0.513***

(0.154)

−0.519***

(0.139)

−0.267**

(0.135)

−0.343**

(0.137)

Share of the population

aged 40-59

−0.222***

(0.078)

−0.195***

(0.034)

−0.146***

(0.034)

Share of income taxes on

individuals

1.237***

(0.302)

- Share of individual's

capital gains taxation

0.261−

(0.181)

0.027

(0.111)

0.051

(0.067) Share of corporate taxes

Page 18: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

18

Standard deviations in parentheses. All specifications include period effects, dummies for geographical regions

and the share of revenue not associated with any of the tax categories. *p<0.10, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01.

The effect of consumption and property taxes on inequality is shown in Table 4. Model (1)

shows that taxes on consumption tend to increase inequality. According to Model (2) both

general consumption taxes (such as VAT and GST) and excise taxes contribute to an increase

in inequality. In an alternative estimation in which the dependent variable is the 90/10 ratio,

the only significant results are with regard to the excise taxes. A possible explanation would

be that the Gini index is much more influenced by the middle of the distribution, and the

90/10 ration is affected by the edges of the distribution. Consumption is much less affected by

the tax policy on the edges of the distribution because demand is very robust (at the bottom)

or because budget constraints are loose (at the top).

The results indicate a substantial difference between non-recurrent property taxes (taxation of

real estate transactions, inheritance tax) and recurrent property taxes (municipal taxes) in

terms of the impact on inequality. Model (4) shows that non-recurrent property taxes reduce

income inequality. However, recurrent property taxes were found to positively affect the Gini

index. Therefore, the positive effect of the overall property tax observed in column 4 is a

result of a larger share of the recurrent property taxes (mostly municipal).

Table 4 - The effect of consumption taxes on inequality

Dependent Variable: Average Gini index in the five years following the base year

(4) (3) (2) (1)

−4.152***

(1.011)

−4.439***

(1.070)

−3.514***

(1.163)

−3.937***

(1.121)

Logarithm of per capita

GDP

−0.310***

(0.036)

−0.285***

(0.040)

−0.325***

(0.0395)

−0.334***

(0.0373) Tax Burden

0.578−

(0.928)

−2.266**

(0.900)

−3.006***

(0.893)

−2.879***

(0.890)

Openness to foreign trade

(as a % of GDP)

−0.347***

(0.131)

−0.531***

(0.133)

−0.405***

(0.141)

−0.437***

(0.139)

Share of the population

aged 40-59

0.109***

(0.039) Share of consumption taxes

0.109**

(0.053)

– VAT and GST

121 121 163 156 163 Observations

0.779 0.776 0.813 0.756 0.834 Adjusted R2

Page 19: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

19

0.178**

(0.075)

– Excise taxes

0.259***

(0.083)

Property tax

0.604***

(0.111)

- Recurrent property

taxes

−1.356***

(0.504)

- Other property

taxes

163 163 163 163 Observations

0.844 0.824 0.822 0.822 Adjusted R2

Standard deviations in parentheses. All specifications include period effects, dummies for geographical regions

and the share of revenue not associated with any of the tax categories. *p<0.10, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01.

6.2 Tax composition and economic growth

In this section, we estimate the impact of the tax composition on growth. The estimation

methodology is similar to the one presented in the previous section. We start by estimating

the impact of various macroeconomic variables on economic growth. Appendix A.4 outlines

the results: Lagged growth rate, unemployment rate (which is used as a proxy for position

within business cycle), high inflation, the share of population under the age of 15 and

openness to foreign trade are positively correlated with current growth. Lower inflation was

found to be negatively correlated with economic growth.

Based on Table 6 we find that increasing income taxes on individuals or corporate taxes have

a negative impact on growth. For example, according to model (1), increasing the share of

income taxes on individuals by one percentage point will reduce the average growth per year

in the five years following base year by 0.078%, with cumulative negative effect on GDP per

capita of 0.39%. Therefore, the elasticity of growth in relation to the income tax burden for

OECD countries in 2013 is estimated at -1.1512. The impact of income taxes on individuals

remains negative when controlling for the corporate tax share (Table 6, model 5).

Table 6. The effect of income taxes on GDP growth

Dependent Variable: Average rate of per capita growth in the five years following the base

year

OLS

(1)

OLS

(2)

2SLS

(3)

2SLS

(4)

OLS

(5)

Lagged growth rate of

per capita GDP 0.081 0.230*** 0.231*** 0.134* 0.084

(0.073) (0.074) (0.074) (0.071) (0.073)

12 In a similar way, one can quantify the impact of the overall tax burden on growth. The average

impact of the tax burden on growth (averaged on all models) is -0.061. The negative effect of

increasing the tax burden by one GDP percentage point is 0.303% of GDP (cumulatively over 5 years).

Page 20: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

20

Unemployment rate 0.087** 0.132*** 0.150*** 0.095*** 0.077**

(0.038) (0.041) (0.029) (0.031) (0.039)

Inflation 0.208** 0.248** 0.145 0.110 0.192*

(0.099) (0.108) (0.095) (0.089) (0.099)

Abs. inflation (>4%) -0.206** -0.264*** -0.229*** -0.185** -0.199**

(0.086) (0.093) (0.081) (0.077) (0.086)

Share of the population

aged under 15 -0.017 0.034 0.073* 0.029 -0.019

(0.042) (0.044) (0.037) (0.036) (0.041)

Openness to foreign

trade (% of GDP) 1.939*** 1.902*** 1.211*** 1.224*** 1.867***

(0.407) (0.450) (0.366) (0.343) (0.408)

Tax burden -0.053*** -0.079*** -0.067*** -0.046*** -0.058***

(0.017) (0.018) (0.018) (0.017) (0.017)

Share of income taxes

on individuals. -0.078***

-0.062*** -0.083***

(0.015)

(0.014) (0.016)

Corporate tax share

-0.002 -0.114*** -0.122*** -0.038

(0.029) (0.040) (0.038) (0.027)

Observations 142 142 139 139 142

Adjusted R-squared 0.556 0.465 0.449 0.511 0.560

Standard deviations in parentheses. All specifications include period effects, dummies for geographical regions

and the share of revenue not associated with any of the tax categories. *p<0.10, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01. The

instrumental variable in the model (5) is corporate tax share lagged by 5 years.

Models (2) and (5) in table 6 measure the effect of corporate taxation on growth. As

previously mentioned, corporate tax revenues are sometimes received with a significant lag.

In addition, there might be a reverse causality between taxes and growth. When policymakers

observe a slowdown in growth they might reduce corporate taxation in order to support

economic activity. The endogeneity arising can distort the results. We use an instrumental

variable approach to solve this problem13. Model (2) does not identify a significant correlation

between the corporate tax share and GDP growth. However, Models (3) and (4), which are

estimated using 2SLS (where corporate tax share lagged by five years serves as an

instrumental variable for current corporate tax share), reveal a significant and negative effect

of corporate taxation on GDP growth. We estimated Model (2) using the exact same sample

as the one used in Models (3) and (4) to assure the difference in the results does not originate

in the differences among the two samples. These results are similar to those reported by

Arnold et al. (2008, 2011), and partly similar to those of Ormaechea et al. (2012) which found

no negative correlation between corporate taxation and economic growth.

13 We use an instrumental variable - corporate tax share lagged by 5 years (for example the corporate

tax share in the year 2000 constitutes an instrumental variable for the corporate tax share in 2005). The

selected instrumental variable meets the two required criteria: it is closely linked with the current

corporate tax share and it has no direct effect on economic growth.

Page 21: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

21

Table 7 presents the effect of consumption and property taxes on growth. Model (1) shows

that on average, increasing the share of consumption taxes has a positive effect on the GDP

growth rate. The results reported in Model (2) show that both the general consumption taxes

(such as VAT and GST) and the excise taxes have a positive effect on GDP growth. The

positive effect of excise taxes (which include taxes designed to capture negative externalities)

is significantly larger.

We find that property taxes have a negative effect on growth (Models (3) and (4)). In

particular, we observe that the negative effect of non-recurrent property taxes is relatively

higher compared with the negative effect of recurrent property taxes (mostly municipal). The

specifications in Table 7 were re-estimated using 2SLS14, to address the potential endogeneity

between the tax composition and GDP growth. The results were similar to those reported in

Table 7.

Some of the results presented in Table 7 are different from those reported by Arnold et al.

(2008, 2011) and Ormaechea et al. (2012). In particular, our finding regarding the negative

effect of property taxation on growth differs from the results of Arnold (2008, 2011) but is

similar to Ormaechea et al (2012). The negative impact of property taxes on growth was also

found in other studies (for instance Kneller, 1999). Regarding consumption taxes, our

findings are compatible with the findings of Arnold (2008, 2011) and other studies; while

Ormaechea et al. (2012) reports that the effect of consumption taxes on growth is not

statistically significant.15

Table 7. The effect of consumption and property taxes on GDP growth

Dependent Variable: Average rate of growth in the five years following the base year

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Lagged growth rate of

per capita GDP 0.096 0.135* 0.113 0.069

(0.070) (0.073) (0.075) (0.075)

Unemployment rate 0.085** 0.101** 0.159*** 0.157***

(0.037) (0.039) (0.038) (0.037)

Inflation 0.173* 0.186* 0.251** 0.236**

(0.098) (0.103) (0.101) (0.098)

Abs. inflation (>4%) -0.189** -0.211** -0.238*** -0.218**

(0.085) (0.089) (0.087) (0.085)

Share of the population

aged under 15 -0.022 0.043 0.037 0.039

14 The selected IV variable is the lagged share of relevant tax. 15 In Ormaechea et al., (2012) some consumption taxes were found to have a positive impact on growth

rate, but as stated, the aggregate effect of all consumption taxes was not significant.

Page 22: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

22

(0.041) (0.045) (0.042) (0.040)

Openness to foreign

trade (% of GDP) 1.634*** 1.469*** 1.868*** 1.790***

(0.403) (0.435) (0.428) (0.446)

Tax burden -0.088*** -0.077*** -0.069*** -0.064***

(0.016) (0.019) (0.019) (0.018)

Consumption share tax. 0.081***

(0.015)

VAT and GST

0.044*

(0.024)

Excise tax

0.150***

(0.044)

Property tax

-0.119**

(0.047)

Recurring

property tax -0.119**

(0.059)

Other property

taxes -0.637**

(0.307)

Observations 142 142 142 142

Adjusted R-squared 0.570 0.525 0.528 0.555 Standard deviations in parentheses. All specifications include period effects, dummies for geographical regions

and the share of revenue not associated with any of the tax categories. *p<0.10, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01.

Section 7 – Discussion and policy implications

The complex relationships existing between the tax composition, equality and growth

reported in the previous section have far-reaching policy implications for tax system design.

In order to support policy formulation we construct two measures for aggregate impact of the

tax composition on equality and growth – Equality Effect of the Tax Composition (EETC)

and Growth Effect of the Tax Composition (GETC). We calculate these measures based on

the estimation results shown in the previous section. The index defined in equation (1)

examines the extent to which the tax composition supports a reduction in inequality16 while

Index (2) measures the impact of the tax composition on economic growth. These indices

reflect the effect of the tax composition, after controlling for the impact of the total tax

burden.

(1) 𝐸𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦 𝐸𝑓𝑓𝑒𝑐𝑡 𝑜𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐶𝑜𝑚𝑝𝑜𝑠𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 (𝐸𝐸𝑇𝐶)𝑖,𝑡 = (−1) ⋅ ∑ 𝑤𝑗,𝑖,𝑡 ⋅ 𝛽𝑗

𝑛

𝑗=1

16 We use (-1) multiplication in order to measure equality. In other words, higher values of the EETC

index suggest that tax composition contributes more to equality.

Page 23: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

23

(2) 𝐺𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑡ℎ 𝐸𝑓𝑓𝑒𝑐𝑡 𝑜𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐶𝑜𝑚𝑝𝑜𝑠𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 (𝐺𝐸𝑇𝐶)𝑖,𝑡 = ∑ 𝑤𝑗,𝑖,𝑡 ⋅ 𝛼𝑗

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝒘𝒋,𝒊,𝒕 - represents the share of a specific tax j in year t for country i;

𝜷𝒋 - represents the estimated impact of tax j on the Gini Index (hence the index values are

in Gini points)

𝜶𝒋 - represents the estimated impact of tax j on per capita GDP growth (hence the index

value is in percent of GDP).

Appendices A.6, A.7 provide the calculated values of the EETC and GETC indices for the

countries in the sample17. Chart 13 displays the dispersion of EETC and GETC across

countries. OECD countries with larger shares of income taxes (e.g., Belgium, Austria,

Denmark and Germany) have higher values of EETC which indicate that their tax

compositions support income equality. The large share of corporate tax in total tax revenues

and the small shares of consumption taxes for countries such as Australia, Canada and the

U.S. hampers economic growth.

The OECD average divides chart 13 into four quarters. Countries in the upper right quarter

have a tax composition that contributes to both growth and equality more than the OECD

average. The immediate conclusion from this chart is that most countries can make Pareto

efficient changes to their tax composition in which they will improves at least one of the two

policy variables without having to sacrifice the other.

Page 24: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

24

Chart 13 – EETC and GETC Values, 2013-2014 average

*Japan and Spain are omitted for clarity of presentation purposes (overlapping). Data for Mexico is unavailable for

the relevant period.

Furthermore, the EETC and GETC indices enable us to chart a feasible efficiency frontier for

the tax composition. The first step in the construction of the efficiency frontier is to rank the

relevant taxes by β and α (i.e. the effect of each tax on equality and economic growth). Next,

the marginal rate of substitution between growth and equality (MRS) is calculated for each

tax category. The MRS measures how much equality is gained for each percent of GDP

growth that is lost for changes in a share of given tax type18. We continue with establishing

the largest positive contribution to economic growth (the x-axes). This is done by

constructing a tax composition using ranked order of growth friendly taxes. To ensure a

feasible frontier we restrict each tax share to the maximum tax share observed in the sample

(e.g. the maximum share of individual income tax for 1980-1985 is 22.7% and it relates to

Denmark in 1985).

This maximum feasible value for GETC serves as the starting point for the drafting of the

efficiency frontier. It is important to mention that the corresponding EETC value could be

negative, as is the case in the Appendix A.8. The rest of the frontier was drawn by a step-by-

18 In some cases the ratio is zero or positive. For example municipal taxes have negative impact both on

growth and equality.

AustraliaAustralia

AustriaAustriaBelgiumBelgium

CanadaCanada

ChileChile

DenmarkDenmark

FinlandFinland

FranceFrance

GermanyGermany

GreeceGreece

IrelandIreland

IsraelIsrael

ItalyItalyKoreaKorea

NetherlandsNetherlands

New ZealandNew Zealand

NorwayNorway

PortugalPortugal

SwedenSwedenSwitzerlandSwitzerland

United KingdomUnited Kingdom

United StatesUnited States

Growth-, Equality-

Growth-, Equality+

Growth+, Equality-

Growth+, Equality+

OECD

-5-3

-11

35

79

Equ

alit

y E

ffe

ct T

ax C

om

po

sitio

n (

EE

TC

)

-27 -22 -17 -12 -7 -2Growth Effect Tax Composition (GETC)

-14.8

1.8

Page 25: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

25

step change in the tax composition according to the MRSs of each tax. Chart 14 presents the

efficiency frontier for the years 1980-1985 combined with the distribution of countries in the

relevant years. Some of the countries, such as Sweden, were close to the frontier, while others

(Japan, Canada and UK) had ample space to improve both the growth friendliness and the

redistributive effect of the tax system.

Chart 14. Tax composition policy efficient frontier 1980-1985

AustraliaAustria

Belgium

Canada

Switzerland

Spain Finland

France

Greece

United Kingdom

Ireland

Italy

Japan

Korea

Norway

Sweden

United States

-50

510

15

20

EE

TC

(D

iffe

ren

ces in

te

rms o

f G

INI, p

ct. p

oin

ts)

-40 -20 0 20GETC (Differences in terms of GDP, pct.)

Page 26: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

26

Chart 15. Tax Composition Policy Efficient Frontier 2013-2014

Changes in the tax shares along the years have caused some alteration in the frontier itself and

in the position of the countries, as shown in charts 14 and 15. Due to the growing share of

inefficient taxes (corporate and recurrent property taxes) the efficiency frontier is pushed

inside causing the maximum feasible EETC and GETC in 2013-14 to be lower than those in

1980-85. Moreover, the average distance to the frontier increased relative to the 1980s. A

partial explanation for this movement stems from the political role which tax systems play in

recent years. Since in many cases it is easier to change the tax system than the expenditure

outlay and the cost of these changes is hard to measure, and since these changes are often

outside of the budget framework, taxes have become a popular policy tools.

Chart 16 presents the evolution of the impact of the tax composition for the OECD countries.

On average, the tax systems across OECD countries put more emphasis on reducing

inequality during the 70's and the 80's. During the 90's and the 00's, there was a large shift

towards a more growth friendly tax composition, followed by a partial reversal after the 2007-

2008 crisis.

Australia

AustriaBelgium

Canada

Switzerland

Chile

GermanyDenmark

Finland

France

GreeceUnited Kingdom

Ireland

Israel

Norway

New Zealand

Portugal

United States

-50

510

15

20

EE

TC

(D

iffe

ren

ces in

te

rms o

f G

INI, p

ct. p

oin

ts)

-40 -20 0 20GETC (Differences in terms of GDP, pct.)

Page 27: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

27

Chart 16. Trends in tax composition across OECD countries 1970-2014

Our results suggest that there is ample room for improving both policy objectives through

efficiency gains. Relatively small changes in the shares of corporate and excise taxes could

have a large and positive impact on growth with no significant adverse effect on equality. The

best recipe for improved equality is to increase taxation on individuals while reducing the

share of inefficient taxes (e.g. recurrent property taxes).The following illustration shows how

changes in the tax composition could benefit both equality and growth.

Table 8: Current and proposed OECD tax composition (% GDP)

1970-1974

1975-1979

1980-1982

1983-1990

1991-2001

2002-20080.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

-32 -30 -28 -26 -24 -22 -20 -18

EETC

GETC

2009-2014

Individuals

income

Corporate VAT

and GST

Excise Recurrent

property

Other

property

GETC EETC

OECD

Average

12.9% 3.2% 6.6% 2.3% 1.5% 0.2% -33.09 2.45

Proposed

composition

14.1% 1.6% 6.6% 3.4% 0.8% 0.2% -19.21 4.23

∆= +1.78 ∆= +13.88

Page 28: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

28

Section 8 – Summary

This work examines how the tax composition - in terms of a division into income taxes on

individuals, corporate tax and taxes on consumption and property - affects income inequality

and economic growth. Using a panel of 25 OECD countries over the last three decades, we

estimate the relationship between the tax composition and two variables: the Gini index and

GDP growth per capita. Potential endogeneity is addressed by creating a time-gap between

the independent and the dependent variables. We find that income taxes on individuals and

non-recurrent property taxes are negatively correlated with inequality and economic growth;

corporate taxes impede economic growth and have no clear impact on inequality; taxes on

consumption contribute to both inequality and growth. We also find that municipal taxes

neither support growth nor reduce inequality.

These results allow us to construct two country specific measures for the extent the tax

composition supports (or discourages) equality and economic growth. These indicators are

used to design a feasible efficiency frontier that represents the all Pareto efficient tradeoffs

between economic growth and equality. We show that some countries (Germany, Sweden and

Finland) are close to the frontier, while others have ample room for improving at least one

policy objective through efficiency gains. For most OECD countries, proposed changes in the

tax composition can reduce income inequality and enhance economic growth. This is an

important finding since previous papers on the effect of the tax composition reported tradeoffs

between GDP growth and equality with regards to tax composition. Furthermore, our paper

contributes to the existing literature by considering behavioral changes emerging from tax

policy and providing framework for joint analysis of the impact on inequality and growth. We

believe it has far-reaching implications on optimal tax policy design.

Page 29: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

29

References

Acosta Ormaechea, S., & Yoo, J. (2012). "Tax Composition and Growth: A Broad

Cross-Country Perspective." IMF Working Paper 12/257.

Arnold, J. M. (2008). "Do Tax Structures Affect Aggregate Economic Growth?

Empirical Evidence from a Panel of OECD Countries." OECD Economics

Department Working Papers, No. 643.

Arnold, J. M., Brys, B., Heady, C., Johansson, Å., Schwellnus, C., & Vartia, L.

(2011). "Tax Policy for Economic Recovery and Growth." The Economic

Journal, 121(550), F59-F80.

Balsvik, R. (2011). "Is labor mobility a channel for spillovers from multinationals?

Evidence from Norwegian manufacturing". The Review of Economics and Statistics,

93.1, 285-297.

Barro, R. J. (1991). "Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries". The

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 407-443.

Barro, R. J. (1996). "Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross Country Empirical

Study." NBER Working Paper, No. 5698.

Brender, A., & Gallo, L. (2009). "The Response of Voluntary and Involuntary Female

Part-Time Workers to Changes in Labor-Market Conditions." Israel Economic

Review.

Brender, A., & Strawczynski, M. (2006). "Earned Income Tax Credit in Israel:

Designing the System to Reflect the Characteristics of Labor Supply and Poverty."

Israel Economic Review 4.1, 27-58.

Brys, B., Perret S., Thomas A., & O’Reilly P. (2016). "Tax Design for Inclusive

Economic Growth." OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 26.

Canavire-Bacarreza, G., Martinez-Vazquez, J. & Vulovic, V. (2013). "Taxation and

Economic Growth in Latin America." Inter-American Development Bank (IDB).

Dackehag, M. & Hansson, A. (2015). "Taxation of Dividend Income and Economic

Growth: The Case of Europe." IFN Working Paper, No. 1081.

Devarajan, S., Swaroop, V., & Zou, H. F. (1996). "The Composition of Public

Expenditure and Economic Growth." Journal of monetary economics, 37(2), 313-344.

Devereux, M. P., Lockwood, B., & Redoano, M. (2008). "Do Countries Compete

Over Corporate Tax Rates?" Journal of Public Economics, 92, No. 5, 1210-1235.

Duncan, D., Sabirianova, K. P. (2012). "Unequal Inequalities: Do Progressive Taxes

Reduce Income Inequality?" IZA Discussion Paper, No. 6910.

Page 30: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

30

Feenstra, R. C., Robert, I., & Marcel P. T. (2015), "The Next Generation of the Penn

World Table" Forthcoming American Economic Review.

Gentry, W. M., & Hubbard, R. G. (2000). "Tax policy and entrepreneurial

entry." American Economic Review, 283-287.

Gould, E. D., & Moav, O. (2007). "Israel's brain drain." Israel Economic

Review, 5(1), 1-22.

Hall, R. E., & Dale, W. J. (1967). "Tax Policy and Investment Behavior." The

American Economic Review, 391-414.

Heckman, J. J., Lochner, L., & Taber, C. (1998). "Tax Policy and Human Capital

Formation." NBER Working Paper, No. 6462.

Higgins, M., & Williamson, J. (2002). "Explaining Inequality the World Round:

Cohort Size, Kuznets Curves and Openness." Southeast Asian Studies, Vol. 40.

Immervoll, H., Levy, H., Lietz, C., Mantovani, D., O'donoghue, C., Sutherland, H., &

Verbist, G. (2005). "Household Incomes and Redistribution in the European Union:

Quantifying the Equalizing Properties of Taxes and Benefits."

Kneller, R., Bleaney, M. F., & Gemmel, N. (1999). "Fiscal Policy and Growth:

Evidence from OECD Countries." Journal of Public Economics, 74, No.2, 171-190.

Kotlan, I. and Machova, Z. (2013). "World Tax Index: New Methodology for OECD

Countries, 2000-2010." DANUBE: Law and Economics Review, European

Association Comenius - EACO, Issue 2, 165-179.

Kuznets, S. (1955). "Economic Growth and Income Inequality." The American

Economic Review, 1-28.

Liu, Y., & Martinez-Vazquez, J. (2015) "Growth–Inequality Tradeoff in the Design of

Tax Structure: Evidence from a Large Panel of Countries." Pacific Economic Review,

Vol.20 (2), 323-345.

Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). "A Rational Theory of the Size of

Government." The Journal of Political Economy, 914-927.

O'Connor, B. (2013). "The structure of Ireland's tax system and options for growth

enhancing reform." The economic and social review, Vol. 44(4).

OECD. (2010). "Tax Policy Reform and Economic Growth." OECD Tax Policy

Studies, No. 20, 38-33.

OECD. (2011). "Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising." OECD

Publishing.

OECD. (2015). "In it Together: Why Less Inequality Benefits All." OECD

Publishing.

Page 31: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

31

OECD/Korea Institute of Public Finance. (2014). "The Distributional Effects of

Consumption Taxes in OECD Countries." OECD Tax Policy Studies, No. 22.

Ostry, M. J. D., Berg, M. A., & Tsangarides, M. C. G. (2014). "Redistribution,

inequality, and growth." International Monetary Fund.

Solt, F. (2014). "The Standardized World Income Inequality Database." Working

paper. SWIID Version 5.0.

Stravchinsky, M. (2015) "The Taxation Policy in Israel in the Coming Years from the

Viewpoint of Growth and Inequality", Aaron Institute, Policy Papers.

Page 32: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

32

C (Political Influence) Net Inequality

Tax Composition

Direct Effect

B1

A

B2

Indirect Effect

Market Inequality

Appendix A.1 - The Direct and Indirect Effect of the Tax composition on Net Inequality

Appendix A.2 – Factors affecting inequality (excluding tax composition)

Standard deviations in parentheses. All specifications include period effects and dummies for geographical areas. *p<0.10, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01.

Dependent Variable: Average Gini index in the five years following the base year

(4) (3) (2) (1)

−4.546***

(1.094)

−5.278***

(1.123)

−5.138***

(1.127)

−3.468***

(1.399)

Logarithm of per capita

GDP

−0.353***

(0.037)

−0.377***

(0.038)

−0.379***

(0.0381) Tax Burden

−2.313***

(0.877)

−1.511***

(0.888)

Openness to foreign trade

(% of GDP)

−0.525***

(0.138)

Share of the population

aged 40-59

170 170 170 179 Observations

0.854 0.841 0.839 0.793 Adjusted R2

Page 33: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

33

Appendix A.3 - Transfer payments and the tax burden in OECD countries, 1970-2011

Appendix A.4 - Factors affecting economic growth (excluding tax composition)

(1) (2) (3)

Lagged growth rate of per capita

GDP 0.368*** 0.348*** 0.314***

(0.063) (0.063) (0.063)

Unemployment rate 0.155*** 0.141*** 0.116***

(0.039) (0.039) (0.040)

Inflation 0.333*** 0.257** 0.215*

(0.107) (0.112) (0.111)

Abs. inflation (>4%) -0.336*** -0.300*** -0.261***

(0.097) (0.098) (0.097)

Share of the population aged

under 15 0.077** 0.082**

(0.035) (0.035)

Openness to foreign trade (% of

GDP) 1.059**

(0.432)

Observations 147 146 146

Adjusted R-squared 0.322 0.339 0.363

Standard errors in parentheses * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01

Page 34: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

34

Appendix A.5 –EETC and GETC Tradeoff

Appendix A.6 - The impact of tax composition on income equality (EECT)

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

EETC

Page 35: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

35

-25

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

Un

ited

Sta

tes

Jap

an

Can

ada

Au

stra

lia

Sw

itze

rlan

d

Bel

giu

m

No

rway

Den

mar

k

OE

CD

Un

ited

Kin

gd

om

Fra

nce

Ko

rea

Irel

and

New

Zea

lan

d

Sw

eden

Ger

man

y

Au

stri

a

Isra

el

Sp

ain

Net

her

lan

ds

Fin

lan

d

Ital

y

Po

rtu

gal

Gre

ece

Chil

e

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

22.60-28.51-34.52-42.81

EETC

GETC

Appendix A.7 – The impact of tax composition on economic growth (GETC)

Appendix A.8 – Efficiency Frontier 1980-1985

Page 36: The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and ... · The Impact of Tax Composition on Income Inequality and Economic Growth Lev Drucker, Ze'ev Krill and Assaf Geva1 August

36

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

1.89-37.17

EETC

GETC

Appendix A.9 – Efficiency Frontier 2013-2014

Appendix A.10 – Distance to the frontier, change between 1980-1985 and 2013-2014

13.5

-5.3

-10.0

-5.0

0.0

5.0

10.0

15.0