26
The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development Shanna Ratner February 2000 Contractor Paper 00-03 About the Authors Shanna Ratner is President of Yellow Wood Associates located in St. Albans, Vermont. Contractor papers are distributed by TVA Rural Studies as part of its effort to improve the information available to rural decision makers. Each contractor paper reflects the research and opinions of the authors. Research papers are published without going through a formal review process and TVA Rural Studies neither endorses nor disavows any opinions in these papers. All staff and contractor papers are working papers and can be found on the TVA Rural Studies website http://www.rural.org/publications/reports.html.

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in RuralCommunity Economic Development

Shanna Ratner

February 2000Contractor Paper 00-03

About the Authors

Shanna Ratner is President of Yellow Wood Associates located in St. Albans, Vermont.

Contractor papers are distributed by TVA Rural Studies as part of its effort to improve the informationavailable to rural decision makers. Each contractor paper reflects the research and opinions of the

authors. Research papers are published without going through a formal review process and TVA RuralStudies neither endorses nor disavows any opinions in these papers.

All staff and contractor papers are working papers and can be found on the TVA Rural Studies websitehttp://www.rural.org/publications/reports.html.

Page 2: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development
Page 3: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 20001

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

IntroductionThis paper is about broadening our

concept, as rural development practitioners andpolicy makers, of what the rural economy is andhow people survive in it. It examines how whatwe do as rural development practitioners andpolicy makers to improve the quality of life ofthose in need might be different if we look firstbeyond the formal economy to the informaleconomy, and finally to the rural economy as awhole. This exploration is an attempt to think“out-of-the-box” and thus generate new, morepowerful, solutions to persistentunderdevelopment in rural communities.

What is the Difference Between theFormal and the Informal Economy?

The formal economy, or simply “theeconomy” as most of us refer to it, is that portionof natural, human, manufactured, andentrepreneurial capital used to meet our wantsthat we actually count. Measures like the rate ofunemployment, the Gross National Product, therate of inflation, the Producer Price Index, therate of housing starts, etc. help us keep track ofwhat is happening in the formal economy.

There is, of course, much economic activitywe do not count.1 The majority of this activity isconsidered to be informal and/or criminal innature. This paper addresses the full range ofnon-criminal economic activity that we do notcount, which includes self-provisioning, caringwork, barter, unreported business transactions,sharing, and volunteer activity. The informaleconomy is often thought of as a kind of “safetynet” for people who do not find a place forthemselves in the formal economy. Researchfindings summarized in this paper dispute thatcharacterization and raise deeper questions abouthow economic benefits are distributed.2

What Is the Informal Economy?The informal economy, known variously as

invisible, shadow, secondary, underground,clandestine, undeclared, unreported, black,irregular, submerged, subterranean, etc. includeseverything from household production andconsumption (sometimes called self-provisioning) of goods and services (paid andunpaid) to interhousehold barter, sharing,

volunteer work, subsistence production, unpaidlabor and labor exchanges, unreported businesstransactions, and care giving to young and old.The informal economy is a part of everyday lifeand household survival strategies in rural (andurban) America, yet its contribution to well-being remains poorly understood and largelyignored by both practitioners and policy makers.

What is and is not part of the informaleconomy changes, depending on location, timeframe, and social context.

Informality...is not an inherent property ofspecific activities (e.g. homeworking,window cleaning). Instead, whether anactivity is informal or not is a socialconstruction (Portes 1994) and all goodsand services can be produced anddistributed either formally or informally(Williams and Windebank 1998).

Increasingly, social scientists recognizeformal and informal economies as comple-mentary parts of a single system.

Within any given location, time period, andsocial context, any “economic activity which isnot recorded in official statistics and whichoperates in the absence of administrativemonitoring and control” (Leonard 1998) shall,for the purposes of this paper, be consideredinformal. It is important to note some portions ofthe informal economy are illegal by virtue ofbeing unreported, while others are inherentlycriminal (e.g. drug dealing, money laundering,etc). This paper does not address the criminaleconomy, but limits itself to those activitieswhich would otherwise be legal except for thefact that they are undeclared or unreported aswell as all perfectly legal but informal economicactivities.

Why Does the Informal Economy Matter?

It’s Big and We Couldn’t Sustain the FormalEconomy Without It

While estimates of the size of the informaleconomy vary depending on how it is definedand how it is measured, they range from 28% ofGross National Product (Feige 1979), to 37-51%of the market economy (Murphy 1982), to

Page 4: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 20002

between $500 billion and $1 trillion in 1993(Feige 1997).3 Bureau of Economic Analysisfigures that include transfer payments, in-kindcontributions, and noncash income, typicallyreport personal incomes ranging from 10 to 25percent higher than census data (Speer 1995).One researcher reported $90 billion inunreported taxable income from legal small scaleenterprises and $10 billion from largecorporations in 1981 (Witte 1981). Anotherreported household labor to be valued at onethird of Gross National Product and one half oftotal disposable income (Burns 1977). A thirdresearcher found that Americans failed to report$630 billion in adjusted gross income in 1995which is 13.1 percent of total adjusted grossincome, an increase of two percent since 1988.(Bartlett, 1998).

In many ways, the formal economy that wemeasure, see, and attempt to manipulate, is justthe tip of the economic iceberg.

Money and money-equivalents, ‘in-kind’values, cannot accurately measure wealthor income in a money-poor but barter-and-borrow rich environment. Until amethod is devised that can rendersubsistence-barter-and-borrow systemsquantitatively comparable to the moneysystem, there is little ability to estimate thereal income or wealth of a state like WestVirginia, even at the present day(Salstrom 1997).

There is no question, however, that theinformal economy is large and that itforms an important piece of what keepsfamilies alive and thriving and capable ofparticipating in the formal economy as theneed and opportunity arise (Nelson andSmith 1999).

So, if we want to take all our resources intoaccount and look anew at all our developmentoptions, we need to broaden our perspective toinclude the informal economy.4

Our Formal Economy Numbers Don’t Tell UsEverything We Need to Know

One of the trends of the last two-thirds ofthe twentieth century has been a growing relianceon economic statistics to define our collectivesense of well-being. When the gross national

product is rising at a reasonable rate, theunemployment rate is down, the rate of inflationis steady, productivity is up, we tell ourselves all iswell. When any or all of these statistics turn sour,we become collectively uneasy. We’ve also cometo believe that we can, in part, control oureconomic environment through policies aimed ataffecting these numbers. Inflation too high?Raise interest rates. Unemployment too high?Lower interest rates. Without addressing themyriad complexities of macroeconomic decision-making, suffice it to say that the entire discipline,and the actions that stem from it, rely oncollection and interpretation of economic data.The data we collect has come to define theeconomy for us and the economy, in turn, isdefined by the data we collect.

The goals of the economy we have createdin this way have been full employment, lowinflation, and continuous growth measuredthrough an ever increasing Gross NationalProduct. Achievement of these goals has beenlargely equated with well-being and progress.We, particularly those of us in industrializedcountries, have believed (more or less) in theachievability of these goals. Within the lasttwenty years or so, however, some have begun toquestion both the goals themselves and the extentto which they may ever be achieved, eitherdomestically or worldwide.

It has often been pointed out, for example,that our measure of Gross National Productincludes both “goods” and “bads”—production ofgoods and services that improve our quality of life(education, preventive health care, housingrehabilitation), and production of goods andservices that arguably do not (prisons, locks,housing construction that produces sprawl,health care for environmentally caused illnesses).Failure to distinguish the “goods” from the“bads” leaves us vulnerable to poor decision-making when it comes to maximizing well-beingthrough economic interventions.5

The importance of environmental valuesand externalities that exist outside the formaleconomy have become increasingly clear.Environmental values are the non-monetizedgoods and services we receive from nature thatallow us to breathe, eat, recycle waste, and sustainlife on this planet. Many of these goods andservices are irreplaceable at any price, while weare just beginning to measure the value of thosewe believe we could replace if we had to. RobertCostanza and a number of colleagues estimated

Page 5: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 20003

the value of the entire biosphere (most of whichis outside the market) at US $16-54 trillion peryear with an average of US $33 trillion per year.Global gross national product is around US $18trillion a year.6

Externalities are the costs and benefitsderived from economic production andconsumption that are not captured in marketprices. For example, if a company produceshazardous waste as a byproduct of itsmanufacturing process and that waste is disposedof at little or no cost to the company, the cost ofthe impacts of the waste on society (ground watercontamination, health problems, etc.) are notfactored into the cost of the product. Theartificially low product price induces excessivedemand which, in turn, leads to furtherenvironmental degradation that remainsunaccounted for. Lack of complete informationresults in poor decision-making that underminescollective well-being. Recognition of bothenvironmental values and externalities is slowlybut inexorably leading us to redefine our notionsof economy.7

When we cease to use money as our onlyruler, we begin to realize that we live in aworld of two economies, not just one. Oneis the formal marketplace measured by—and consisting mainly of—monetarytransactions. This is the realm ofsupermarkets and shopping centers, officesand factories that the media calls theeconomy. The other economy is theinformal networks of helping in families,neighborhoods, volunteer groups, and thelike. What we call growth is often merelythe transfer of a function from theinformal to the formal economy, from aninvisible pocket to a visible one. There isno net gain in output and often there is aloss in social cohesion and well-being(Cahn and Rowe 1996).

For example, in writing about theprofessionalization of caring, Deborah Stoneobserves:

When care is recast as an economic andbureaucratic good, deep norms aboutaltruism, generosity, and cooperation arereshaped as well...When people care in apublic context as employees of an agencyand, in effect, as agents of insurance

companies or Medicare and Medicaid,they are made to feel that their personalrelationships with clients areillegitimate—something to be hidden,kept in check, restrained, best leftunspoken...They talk about caring andtheir care giving work almost as if theywere engaging in civil disobedience(Stone 1999).

The importance of social factors andrelations on individuals’ economic behaviorhas been traditionally ignored inconventional economics. The relationshipsbetween community members engaged inthese (informal) exchanges are qualitativelydifferent from the relationships betweenlabourers and employers/customers. Thisapplies even when money forms the basisof the exchange (Leonard, 1998).

The Formal Economy Alone Can’t Meet AllOur Needs

The tunnel vision that has resulted fromour romance with economic statistics appliesequally to the informal economy. Over the pasttwenty years or so, researchers have increasinglybegun to question the assumptions of the formaleconomy and to inquire as to what role theinformal economy may play in our present andfuture collective well-being. In part, thisquestioning began with a realization that theunderlying assumptions of the formaleconomy—i.e. it is the only economy thatmatters and progress will result fromincorporation of all resources into the formaleconomic structure—did not accord with reality.Contrary to the beliefs of formal economists, theworld has not evolved in a straight line from aninformal, exchange-based economy to a formal,market-based economy, nor is it at all apparent itwill do so in the future. The informal economy isalive and well even in advanced industrialcountries such as the United States, GreatBritain, Germany, Canada, etc. (Sassen-Koob1989, Standing 1989, Offe and Heinze 1992,Fortin et al. 1996, and others). Furthermore, theformal economy, by failing to achieve and sustaineither full employment or comprehensive welfareprovisions, has not lived up to our collectiveexpectations for increased well-being.

Page 6: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 20004

For many years informal employment,although its existence was not denied, wasassumed to be in decline and/or of littlerelevance for understanding andinterpreting advanced economies and theirprospects. Instead, an assumptionprevailed that informal employment was amere leftover from a previous era ofproduction. Work and welfare wouldbecome increasingly formalized and resultin an end-state of full-employment andcomprehensive and universal formalwelfare provision. However, the history ofthe past twenty years in advancedeconomies and beyond has taught us thatsuch an assumption can no longer beaccepted. Rather, a far-reachingrestructuring of work and welfare hasbrought starkly into question theinevitability of continuing formalizationand thus that full employment coupledwith comprehensive welfare provision isthe natural end-state of our developmentpathway (Williams and Windebank1998 p.5).

The mass entry of married women into theformal labour market, growing levels ofunemployment and theinternationalization of the division oflabour have created major difficulties forthe welfare state programmes developed bymany western industrialized countries. Inattempting to deal with these crises, stateshave tried to dismantle, reduce or declineto implement welfare strategies and in theprocess opened up opportunities forinformal economic activities. The crisis inwelfare state policy and provision hascoincided with a crisis in mass production.The long-term trend towardscentralization has been stopped in itstracks by a newly emerging trend in theopposite direction. It is within this countertrend toward decentralization andflexibility that informal economic activityemerges as a central feature of theeconomic structures of most industrialsocieties as they approach the newmillennium (Leonard 1998 ).

Attempting to make a hard and fastdistinction between formal and informalemployment risks distorting the accuracy of ourview of the economy still further.

The formal/informal distinction was avaluable but somewhat crude first step inthe attempt to come to grips with what isbasically a form of individual adaptation toconstrictions in economic life and well-being brought about by global and nationaleconomic forces and institutions. To speakof ‘informal personnel’ is to obscure theexistence and activities of the ‘moonlighter’or ‘Sunday person’ who is formallyemployed during normal business hours,throughout some, if not all, of the regularwork week. And to speak of ‘informalactivities’ denies the fact that virtuallyidentical products may be sold or servicesperformed by both formal and informalenterprises (Smith 1990).

To define informal employment solely as amarginal activity of the poor and excludedwould be to do an injustice to the largenumber of informal workers who earnabout the average formal wage and for theconsiderable number of formal employeeswho earn less than the average informalwage (Williams and Windebank 1998).

Economic activity should be defined inrelation to its contribution to theproduction of goods and services for thesatisfaction of human needs regardless ofwhether this production is channeledthrough the market or through thehousehold. By treating household workand wage labour as separate issues, the fullrange of household economic strategies hasbeen blurred and the continuedimportance of work which takes placeoutside formal employment has beenundermined (Leonard 1998).

We have begun to recognize that theformal economy does not hold all the answers tosustainable well-being. At the same time, wehave begun to understand something of thecomplex interplay between formal and informaleconomic activity which suggests that theinformal economy will always be with us.

Page 7: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 20005

...The informal economy is an integralfeature of the formal economy. As a vitalcomponent of the formal economy, thenature of informal economic activitychanges and responds to transformationsin the formal economy (Leonard 1998).

The Difference Between Growth andDevelopment

The difference between growth anddevelopment has also been widely recognized.Growth implies a trajectory that will yield moreof what you started with over time. Developmentimplies a complex process through which thequality of life improves as judged by those wholive it. Growth can be measured in a centralizeddata collection system—development, since it isin the eye of the participant, cannot. Increasingly,we are coming to realize that what our formaleconomy counts may not be all that “counts” forus. The goal of rural development is notnecessarily growth, but rather what RobertChambers, international rural developmentexpert, refers to as “sustainable livelihoodsecurity.” He elaborates:

The many priorities and criteria of well-being of poor people vary from person toperson, from place to place, and from timeto time. Health is often, if not always, one.In addition, a common and almostuniversal priority expressed is an adequate,secure, and decent livelihood. Livelihoodhere can be defined to include a level ofwealth and of stocks and flow of food andcash which provide for physical and socialwell-being. This includes security againstsickness, against early death, and againstbecoming poorer. It includes, thus, securecommand over assets as well as income,and good chances of survival...A phrase tosummarize all this is sustainable livelihoodsecurity (Chambers 1994).

What Role Has the Informal Economy inSustainable Livelihood Security?

The following section summarizes what weknow of the informal economy based on the lastseveral decades of research. We examine whoparticipates, how the informal economy isaccessed, barriers to participation, and theinterrelationship of the formal and informal

economy from both a structural and experientialperspective.

Who participates?Many of us falsely assume the informal

economy is peopled by those who lack access tothe formal economy. This is not the case.

There is a general consensus amongresearchers into informal economic activityin most European countries and NorthAmerican states that the unemployed areunlikely to participate in the informaleconomy. This is because of a variety offactors including the level of opportunitiesavailable, the extent to which informalemployment is monitored by the state andother official agencies, the penalties forengaging in informal employment whileofficially classified as unemployed and thelevel and extent of welfare provision indifferent countries....The generalconcurrence among these studies is thatthe unemployed are less likely than theemployed to engage in informalemployment due to lack of skills, transportand capital and lack of opportunities dueto the probability of living in poorlocalities where employment opportunitieseither formal or informal are likely to beminimal (Leonard 1998).

In fact, participation in the informaleconomy cuts across all income levels (Jensen,Cornwell, Findeis, 1995), and individualsfrequently work both formally and informally(Williams and Windebank, 1998). For example,

Eyler (1989) found that in an era ofcorporate downsizing and transnationalcapital flight, some white collar andmanagement workers in the US turn tomoonlighting as a way of experimentingwith second careers or acquiring new skillsand contacts in case these were needed dueto the possibility of losing their full-timejobs (Leonard 1998).

What are the benefits?The informal economy provides

participants with a variety of benefits, which mayinclude monetary income, goods and services,social satisfaction, and cultural connection. In

Page 8: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 20006

addition, the informal economy acts as analternative distribution network in which thosewho do not have money to buy goods andservices nevertheless are able to access at leastsome of what they need for both production andconsumption.

The benefits of the informal economy are,like the economy itself, defined by context. Forexample, Kathleen McInnis-Dittrich studied 23low income Appalachian women to determinetheir patterns of participation in the informaleconomy. All the women had participated in theinformal economy both 12 months before thestudy and during it. The women earned abouthalf their income from otherwise legal butunregulated activities such as housework, child orelder care, yard sales, recycling, or work in thetobacco fields. On average they earned $168 amonth for 90 hours of work or $1.87 an hour.This money was essential to the survival of thesewomen and their families. Opportunities forhigher paying off-the-books work at sawmills,farms, etc. went to men.

The other half of the total income earnedby these women was generated by fewer than25% of them through illegal activities includingprostitution, bootlegging, growing and sellingmarijuana, or selling stolen property. Womenwho earned money illegally rarely saw the moneythey earned (McInnis-Dittrich, 1995).

In contrast, when analyzing a mixedincome sample of households, the MassachusettsCooperative Extension Service estimated theaverage annual economic value of household-produced goods and services, including suchthings as food and meal preparation, laundry,home repairs and maintenance, child care,sewing, transporting, etc., at $22,776 per familyper year. (University of Massachusetts 1984).

Other researchers have emphasized thenon-material benefits of the informal economy.

Participation in the subsistence lifestylehas payoffs beyond the physical needs itsatisfies. In addition to serving criticalroles in both supplementing income andproviding a source of support duringperiods when monetary income becomesscarce or nonexistent, subsistence activitiescontribute to overall social well-beingthrough a variety of social, cultural, andpsychological functions (Glass, Muth,Flewelling 1989).

If the formal economy confers status andwages, the informal economy confers livelihoodsecurity and a community-based identity.Describing the informal economy in centralAppalachia, Joseph Matvey notes:

The continuance of domestic productionconstitutes one alternative in that suchpractices enable families to close the gapbetween wages and human needs andwants...The retention of home productionpractices is not merely a tradition but aninnovative ethic of a people who confrontdaily the force of structural currentsimpacting upon their region inunderdevelopment...They are not purelyeconomic functions nor are they alwaysperceived as such, but material practiceswhich act as a vehicle for social expression,cultural identity, heritage and thereaffirmation of community...Festivals area crucial expression of sociality and socialreinforcement—a reinforcement whichcenters itself around domestic production(Matvey 1991).

The distributional benefits and function ofthe informal economy are also significant.

Using household survey data from Detroit,Michigan, the authors argue that althoughindividual exchanges may be small, takenas a whole, the social and irregulareconomy provide goods and services oftenunavailable or difficult to obtain in theregular economy. The irregular and socialeconomies also distribute goods producedin the regular economy to local or marginalmarkets as well as consumes, distributes,and maintains products made in theregular economy (Ferman and Berndt1981 as summarized in Feldman andFerretti, 1998).

One of the most influential studies of howsocial relationships and networks operateto meet economic needs was carried out byCarol Stack (1974). Her research waslocated in a community experiencingsevere economic depression. The economicinsecurity experienced by residents waslessened through their extensive kinshipand friendship networks which lessened

Page 9: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 20007

their dependence on formal sources tomeet their daily needs. The most widelypracticed strategies involved swapping,trading, and borrowing from onehousehold to another. In this way, thescarce range of goods available in thecommunity could be redistributedthroughout a number of households.Services were also ‘swapped.’ Henceresidents could trade their limited skillswith the limited skills of other communitymembers and in the process gain access toa wider range of services than their internalresources could cover (Leonard, 1998).

Appalachia’s main economic anomaly wasthat distributive relations remained lessmonetized there; they remained composedmore of bartering and borrowing(Salstrom 1997).

Who gains access and how?Research consistently emphasizes the role

of social networks in gaining access to theinformal economy. In some instances, thesenetworks are primarily kinship-based. Forexample:

Morris and Irwin (1992) focused on thelevels of support among four types ofhouseholds: couples in which the man wassecurely employed, couples in which theman was recently recruited to employment,couples in which the man was long-termunemployed, and couples in which theman was out of the labour force...Theyfound the density of support (the numberof exchanges) was highest among the long-term unemployed. Much of the supportavailable however depended on kinshiprather than friendship ties (Leonard 1998).

Networks are also established amongfriends and neighbors. In a study of 400households in deprived neighborhoods ofSouthampton and Sheffield, England, ColinWilliams and Jan Windebank found that,

Everyday life in deprived neighborhoods ischaracterized by an inability of householdsto get completed a large number of basictasks that are necessary to maintain areasonable quality of life. When

households do manage to get these tasksaccomplished, some 84.8% are conductedusing primarily their own labour or that offriends, neighbors, and relatives, and82.0% of household would like to engagein more activities for themselves andothers (Williams and Windebank 1999).

Networks may also be a byproduct ofinvolvement in the formal economy.

Because the members of good work8

households were enmeshed in broadnetworks of social support, they were wellpositioned to locate good jobs (should theyfind themselves ‘downsized’) and to carryout self-provisioning and entrepreneurialmoonlighting projects (Nelson and Smith1999).

For example, someone who sews on theside but has a formal job as a dental technician, isable to meet people on a regular basis who maybecome informal customers. People withoutformal employment have more limitedopportunities to meet potential customers.

By virtue of their location within good jobhouseholds, they also have access tonetworks of colleagues and friends whocan help them locate other good jobs(Nelson and Smith, 1999).

Once a person becomes established in theformal economy, the likelihood of maintainingaccess increases by virtue of social networks.

In the informal economy, more so than inthe formal economy, the utility of networks to anindividual or household hoping for accessdepends, in large measure, on their capacity toengage in reciprocal exchange relationships.

Lowenthal examines how people withinadequate incomes meet their needs andsurvive in the context of diminishingresources and declining real wages.Although health care and housing mayremain unmet, other needs are met bypeoples participation in social networksand mutual aid systems...Economictransactions are embedded in personalnetworks which structure arrangements forthe provision of goods and services. Thesearrangements operate in a social economy

Page 10: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 20008

through principles of reciprocity andadequacy of response (Lowenthal, 1981).

Writing about Appalachia’s informaleconomy and the transition to capitalism, PaulSalstrom notes:

Within Appalachia, like elsewhere in theUnited States, almost all goods andservices which were delivered beyond thoseintimate spheres carried an expectationthat the receiver would feel obligated tosooner or later deliver something orequivalent value to the giver. Beyond theboundaries of “family groups” and ofcharity, in other words, almost no able-bodied people received favors except thepeople who also rendered them (Salstrom1997).

The preconditions to establishing reciprocalexchange relationships include control over one’stime, the capacity to plan, and access to assetssuch as skills and equipment. In a study of ruralhouseholds in Vermont, Nelson and Smith ask:

What is it about households with a leastone good job that enables them to engagein these activities (self-provisioning andnonmonetary household exchange)? Theanswer is as self-evident as it isparadoxical: Self-provisioning consumesenormous resources before it can evenbegin to justify its expense (Nelson andSmith 1999).

Similarly, in rural New York, Cornellresearchers find,

The rural households with low and modestincomes that we studied all had access toresources they could use for commercialends, household provisioning, andrecreational purposes. None of them canbe accounted among the moredisadvantaged rural poor (Gillespie,Lyson, Harper 1994).

[In rural Vermont] A set of conditions(e.g. having a second car, being close tograndmother or neighbor who could watchthe children for less than market costs,work schedules that permit coordination,and being able to sustain geographical

stability) stood behind the capacity of badjob households to allow at least one workerin a dual-earner bad job household tomoonlight. The same set of preconditionsunderlies the propensity of bad jobhouseholds to maintain a second earnerand simultaneously to sustain high rates ofself-provisioning (Nelson and Smith1999).

McInnis-Dittrich identified four patternsof participation in the informal economy amonga sample of low income women in Appalachia:the anticipatory pattern, the chronicallydisorganized pattern, the familial pattern, and theentrepreneurial pattern. Women who fell into theanticipatory pattern were “good turn women”who were respected, well-liked, and consideredgood people. They would anticipate the need formoney by the end of the month and seek work inthe informal economy to meet the need. Theyworked at legal activities and were able to dolong-range planning for their limited resources,use a bank, and follow a budget. Thirty percentof the sample fell into this category. Women whowere chronically disorganized were persistentlyunable to plan beyond the moment. They couldnever commit to a regular source of informalincome, such as child care, because they mightnot be trusted to remember. These womensought income from the informal economy onlyin reaction to an impending financial disaster.Thirty percent fell into this category. Womenliving the familial pattern relied on intra-familytransfers of money to survive. These women weregenerally young, passive, and dependent onothers including men and family. Seventeenpercent fit this pattern. Finally, theentrepreneurial women obtained most of theirincome from illegal activities. They had learnedthat, despite the impoverished environment inwhich they lived, there was money to be made inillegal activities, and they were proactive inpursuing these opportunities. They were youngerand more aggressive than many of the otherwomen in the sample and had little interest inlegal activities. Most had police records, and allhad lifetime experiences of sexual and physicalabuse. Twenty-two percent of the sample fellinto this category. (McInnis-Dittrich 1995).

McInnis-Dittrich’s work reveals the socio-structural underpinnings of participation in theinformal economy. These underpinnings appearto be a composite of family patterns, early

Page 11: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 20009

experiences, personality type, and psychologicalprofile. The degree of variation is notable,especially as it was found within a chronicallydepressed area in which, at a superficial level, allparticipants faced similar economic constraints.

Networks can also be established andmaintained through structures such as periodicmarket systems and/or intermediaries betweeninformal and formal markets such asstorekeepers.

Drawing from ethnographic fieldwork inKentucky, Halperin ... (finds) carefullycultivated kin and friendship networksprovide access to goods and servicesoutside the formal market. Regional andperiodic marketplace systems also play akey role as alternative economicinstitutions for generating neededhousehold cash from the sale of family-produced goods (Halperin 1990 assummarized in Feldman and Ferretti1998).

Farmers’ markets, community celebrations,antique fairs, roadside stands, swap shops, etc. allprovide vehicles for informal exchange, and, assuch, are an important part of the economicecology of community life. These types of venuesmay be crucial to the livelihood security ofparticipants. Lack of such venues, or over-formalization, may create barriers to participationin the informal economy.

In rural Appalachia, as reported by Hicks(1973):

[S]torekeepers...are the intermediariesbetween the subsistence and the casheconomy. They control the flow of goodsand cash both into and out of the ruralcommunity. Storekeepers also competewith one another for clientele. Forexample, galax, a fern gathered by men,women, and children alike, and used asbackground greenery in flowerarrangements, is sold to florists outside thecommunity for cash. Storekeepersdistribute galax to the outside by obtaininggalax from clients and converting it intocredit against a person’s account (Smith1990).

In many rural communities, brokers whopurchase green lumber from part-time sawmillersplay a similar role. These intermediaries, withtheir greater knowledge of and exposure to theformal marketplace, while they do provide accessto the informal economy by bridging with theformal economy, are often also in a position toexploit their suppliers.

What are the barriers to entry?Although it may seem counterintuitive, the

barriers to entry into the formal economy are inmany ways mirrored with respect to the informaleconomy.

One cannot simply view informalemployment as a refuge for marginalizedpopulations...Instead, there appears to be aheterogeneous informal labour marketwith a hierarchy of its own. This hierarchy,moreover, seems to reproduce, rather thanmitigate, the socio-spatial inequalitiesprevalent in the formal labour market(Williams and Windebank 1998).

Communities with weak or weakeningformal economies tend to have weak orweakening informal economies as well.

The general consensus among thesestudies is that the unemployed are lesslikely than the employed the engage ininformal employment due to lack of skills,transport, and capital and lack ofopportunities due to the probability ofliving in poor localities where employmentopportunities, either formal or informal,are likely to be minimal (Leonard 1998).

Barrier to entry and participation in theinformal economy include lack of assets, money,time, and networks, and, an often misplaced fearof government intervention.

Jobless households are less able thanemployed households to get workcompleted and to improve their situationby helping themselves and others...Thebarriers preventing them from gettingwork done and from helping themselvesand others are their lack of money,equipment, time, skills, confidence,physical abilities and social networks, as

Page 12: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200010

well as their perception of theneighbourhood and fear of beingmistakenly reported to the authorities(Williams and Windebank 1999).

Ironically, the nature of the barriers toparticipating in the informal economy mitigateagainst participation by the poorest of the poor.Informal work within the household needs morethan time. It demands skills and money to buythe articles necessary to convert materials intofinal products. Household income obviouslyinfluences the ability of households to purchaseformal goods and services. If households caneasily afford the purchase of formal goods andservices then it seems reasonable that they willhave little incentive to engage in self-provisioning. Yet, the studies outlined above(Glatzer and Berger 1988, Smith 1986, Pahl1984, Offe and Heinz 1992, Sassen 1996,Mingione 1988) indicate that high incomehouseholds are those most likely to engage inself-provisioning. To some extent this is tied upwith home ownership. High income householdstend to own their own homes and thus engage ina wide range of DIY (do-it-yourself) housemaintenance and improvement measures...Poorer households face a constant contradictionbetween the rationality of increased self-provisioning and a structurally limited capacity tomake use of it. (Leonard 1998).

The inability to reciprocate also poses asignificant barrier to participation in the informaleconomy.

Both groups (bad job and good jobhouseholds) understand that reciprocityshould be a norm in informal exchanges,that reduced rates should be paid withgratitude, and that fairness should prevailin barter. Because the individuals in badjob households face more urgent needs,however, they cannot always abide bythose rules. Bad job households with lowincomes receive less assistance from othersthan do bad job households with highincomes...Social relationships that aresecured through exchange among good jobhouseholds are jeopardized among thosehouseholds that might need theserelationships the most (Nelson and Smith1999).

Intra-household co-operation was oftenbased on the principle of reciprocity.Hence the needs of those unable toreciprocate were left unmet (Leonard1998).

Finally, the capacity to form networks at allhinges on a certain amount of geographicstability:

It is said that the decay of traditionalpatterns of living in industrial societies isbound up with increased social mobility.But by the same token it is connected withan increase of regional mobility. Whentraditional links become more tenuous,time has to be spent on forming contactnetworks that are sought because of theirpotential for increasing well-being—andthis need increases pari passu with regionalmobility. Where contact cannot be madewith such networks or where they remainineffective on account of fluctuatingmembership, the individual then has tosatisfy any requirements he may havethrough the market. So the less contactthere is, on account of mobility, with suchgroups, the more dependent areindividuals on having money of their ownto make purchases (Offe and Heinze1992).

The interrelationship of formal and informaleconomies

At the macro level, the stronger the formaleconomy, the stronger the informal economy.

The size of the hidden economy ispositively related to the size of themeasured economy and to inflation, whileunemployment is shown to have no cleareffect...Structural rather than cyclicalphenomena explain the growth of thehidden economy (O’Higgins 1985).

At the micro level, a household’srelationship to the formal economy shapes theirpotential and actual involvement in the informaleconomy:

Page 13: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200011

The household activities of bad jobhouseholds were tied to the kind ofemployment that characterizes thehousehold, but because bad work stood atthe center of the household economy, boththe direct and indirect links had differentconsequences. Perhaps most significantly,bad work undermined the capacity of thehousehold to maintain the dual earnerstrategy as an ongoing achievement,especially when there were young childrenwithin the household. This was so becausethe instability of bad jobs constantlydisrupted employment patterns, becausethe lack of paid time off meant thatfamilies could not respond to criseswithout jeopardizing employment, andbecause the wages paid were insufficient tocover the costs of employment...Contraryto the contemporary claim that householdshave lost their economic rationale, the waypeople sustain themselves goes far beyondthe individual wage and requires a set ofstrategies based on familial relationships.The survival strategies of householdsemerge from and are grounded in theconnections they have with waged labor(Nelson and Smith 1999).

Participation in the informal economyoften requires goods that must be acquiredformally. Glass, Muth and Flewelling (1989)describe adaptations in the informal economy inAlaska:

Most of the traditional subsistence gearhas been replaced by modern equipmentsuch as metal and fiberglass boats,outboard motors, or even large watercraft,sonar devices, guns, ammunition, steeltraps, and the like. Food preservation haslargely changed from the use of traditionalsmoking and drying processes to homecanning and freezing. While all of thesetechnological advances have addedefficiency in harvesting and preserving,they have made the residents of ruralcommunities more and more intertwinedwith the other sectors of theeconomy...Because the monetary incomeoriginates in the public and market sectors,contemporary rural communities insoutheastern Alaska have developed truly

integrated three-sector economies (Glass,Muth and Flewelling 1989).

Reliance on more modern equipment is notlimited to Alaska. In rural New York,participation in self-provisioning often hinges onownership of, or access to, a chain saw and arototiller (Ratner 1984) and in rural Vermont,Nelson and Smith (1999) find, “One obvious link(between formal and informal economies) is thatthese so-called informal activities rely on theproducts of formally organized markets.”

Often the goods produced in informalmarkets are distributed and sold through formalmarkets. Examples include clothing made ininformal sweat shops and non-timber forestproducts harvested informally and sold to brokerswho resell to export markets. Goods producedinformally may cross over into the formal sectoror may form the basis for continuing informaltransactions. Sometimes informal production isan attempt to bypass expensive regulatoryrequirements and leads to exploitation of labor.While instances of exploitation can be found inboth the formal and informal economies, therehas been no research that suggests it is any morewidespread in one than the other.

It is only by recognizing thecommonalities between the positions ofcertain groups within the formal andinformal economy that the forces whichgive rise to exploitative forms of labour canbe more fully understood and challenged(Leonard 1998).

Several authors have emphasized the role ofthe informal economy in, in effect, subsidizingthe formal economy, both historically andcurrently.

Local ‘subsistence-barter-and-borrow’systems, based mostly on voluntaryreciprocity, were brought to West Virginiaby its earliest white settlers. When heavyindustrialization began in West Virginia(about one hundred years ago), thesetraditional economic systems did not ceaseto function. Their continuation subsidizedthe state’s industrialization (Salstrom1997).

In many areas today the informal economyis providing the goods and services that allow low

Page 14: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200012

wage workers in the formal economy to survive.In Eastern Kentucky, Smith (1990) studiedperiodic marketplaces, one of which was locatedadjacent to a large shopping mall which soldmany identical items for as much as ten times theprice. She says,

It could be argued that the existence ofsuch an alternative system of distribution iswhat makes it possible for the largenumbers of working class people to live atthe rural/urban interface. These workersprovide the temporary labor for thegrowing numbers of (light industry)factories. Alternative sources fordistribution of goods are essential in thiscontext, otherwise people would have toeither retreat back to the deep rural areasor move to the cities and become totallydependent upon cash from low level jobsor welfare. The fact that the interfaceprovides so many livelihood alternatives,and that people utilize multiple strategies,is an indicator of pluralism that appears onthe increase, and for the near future, likelyto remain (Smith,1990).

Nelson and Smith (1999) found the type offormal employment critical to the capacity ofhousehold members to engage in informalactivities. One of the most important factors iscontrol of time.

Ironically, substantial self-provisioning(like engagement in an on-the-sideentrepreneurial activity) not only dependson additional formal labor market activitybut also requires having time that can bebracketed and defined as discretionary...Itis the ability to control time which is soimportant in extensive self-provisioning.This is a privilege reserved to those whohave at least some good employment and,as a consequence, do not have to resort towaged moonlighting or staggered workschedules (Nelson and Smith 1999).

In this way, low-wage jobs that demandflexibility of their workers and do not providereliable scheduling have a doublely damagingimpact on households. Not only do they fail toprovide a living wage, but, by introducinguncertainty over one’s schedule, they prevent

people from participating effectively in theinformal economy.

The quality of a household’s connection tothe formal economy influences its informalopportunities in other ways as well.

A worker with a bad job in a grocery storecan use the garbage thrown out at the endof the day to feed a pig being raised by afriend for half the profits. Or someoneworking at a car repair place can use theshop’s equipment on their own car...Themore jobs in the family, the higher theprobability that these necessary perks willbe available...Self-provisioning builds onemployment and the more employmentthe better...Bad jobs limit self-provisioning, and without the ability toengage in that activity, bad workhouseholds with but a single earner areeven poorer than wage levels wouldsuggest (Nelson and Smith 1999).

Even a bad job provides more opportunitythan no job at all. Yet achieving livelihoodsecurity requires more than a formal job.

The more insecure and unrewarding theformal economic environment, the more likelyare households to turn to the informal economyfor support.

Expanding low income populationsencourages the growth of informaleconomic activities by enhancing demandfor low cost goods and services... Hencethe parallel development of a market forhigh priced and low priced goods andservices facilitates the trend towardinformalization (Leonard 1990).

However, since the formal and informaleconomies parallel each other, as the formaleconomy deteriorates and job quality falls, theinformal economy is also weakened.

Households become self-provisioningunits, drawing on the informal laboursupply of family members, and thecommunities in which households arelocated become locations for thedevelopment of reciprocal economictransactions as households attempt to

Page 15: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200013

maintain some form of economic securityin an increasingly insecure and changingeconomic environment (Leonard 1998).

“Attempt” is perhaps the most importantword in the preceding sentence. Households thatare better connected, more settled, and moreprosperous, that have developed a variety ofreciprocal exchange relationships over time, arefar more likely to benefit from self-provisioningand exchange than the households that have thegreatest need. As economic developmentpractitioners, the challenge we face is how toshape a whole economy, inclusive of formal andinformal arrangements, to provide livelihoodsecurity for all.

Implications for Policy and Practice

Unless we understand how informal sectorworkers and formal sector enterprisesparticipate within a single economicsystem, policy recommendations will offeronly speculative solutions tounemployment (Lozano, 1983).

From a macroeconomic policy standpoint,much of the concern about the informal economystems from its negative impact on tax collections.Proposed policy “solutions” are weighted towardincreasing formalization by controlling informalactivities. Attempts to control informal economicactivities tend to result in the exclusion ofparticipants most dependent on the activities tobegin with. For example, the Maxwell Streetmarket in Chicago, one of the longest runningand largest open-air markets in the country, hadmore than 800 vendors, low vendor fees, andattracted crowds of more than 20,000 before itwas formalized by the City of Chicago in 1994.Now participation requires licences and permits,higher fees and increased controls. Less than halfthe vendors have made the transition to the newmarket (Martel 1996). This is not an isolatedinstance.

Many commentators (e.g. Lautier 1994)are now arguing that attempts to formalizeinformal employment have foundered inalmost all cases where this has beenattempted (e.g. Burkino Faso, Brazil, IvoryCoast, Columbia) and thus, paid informalactivities cannot be formalized for

developmental purposes (Williams andWindebank 1998).

Given that, from a developmentperspective, experiments in formalizing theinformal sector have not been successful, wheredo we go from here? If one accepts the notionthat formal and informal activities arecomplementary, that the boundaries betweenthem are fluid rather than fixed, and that the bestchoice at any given time and place is that whichmost effectively provides livelihood security, thena key question becomes: How do we activateavailable resources to meet human needsregardless of formality or informality?

Approaches that recognize the importanceof the informal economy to our individual andcollective well-being and deliberately seek toprotect and expand opportunities for reciprocalexchange include (but are not necessarily limitedto) Time Dollars, co-management of naturalresources, and Local Exchange and TradingSystems.

Time DollarsEdgar Cahn and Jonathan Rowe have

developed a system called Time Dollars that isbeing used to recapture time as a valuableresource. Time Dollars programs offerparticipants service credits based on time spenthelping others.

They do for the informal economy ofhelping what money did for thecommercial economy of barter; they free itfrom the tandems of you-and-merelationships and enable this timeexchange to grow into a community ofgood works. They become a kind ofscaffolding on which to rebuild theinformal, household economy (Cahn andRowe 1996).

Time Dollars programs encouragerelationship building, reciprocity, and exchange.They appeal to both men and women and tomany who are not otherwise engaged asvolunteers. Time Dollars programs also appeal torecipients of services since they know they aren’taccepting charity or welfare, but rather allowingtheir helper to gain credits he or she can use.Time Dollars programs appear to “tap a differentspectrum of motivation and concern—the desire

Page 16: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200014

to help and be needed—that market wages eitherignore or repulse” (Cahn and Rowe 1996).

Several states, including Missouri andMichigan, have enacted legislation in support ofTime Dollars programs. Michigan’s bill focusedon people who provide care for frail seniors intheir homes and created a state bank to track thecredits earned by service providers. Missourioffered a guarantee for the Time Dollars earnedin the respite program. If the people who earnedcredits through the program can’t find anothervolunteer to help them when they need it, thestate will pay for that help instead. The programhas been successful.

Elderplan, an HMO in Brooklyn, NewYork, adopted the Time Dollars program in themid 1980s. Time Dollars allowed members ofthe HMO to earn service credits by caring forother members. Elderplan allows members to useTime Dollars to pay for part of their HMO feebecause active members who feel needed byothers are less prone to disease, so they requireless care from the HMO.

Time Dollars is one example of anapproach that helps people meet very real needs,increases connections, and activates time as anunderutilized resource.

Williams and Windebank argue foradoption of an Active Citizens’ Credit schemefor Great Britain modeled after Time Dollarsand suggest as a more comprehensive option aminimum guaranteed income for activecitizenship paid via a tax credit system (Williamsand Windebank 1999).

Co-management of Natural ResourcesAs the informal use of natural resources

gains legitimacy, experiments have emerged inco-management whereby governmental bodieswork with indigenous or simply localcommunities to help maintain informaleconomies as a part of a larger conservationstrategy. These efforts tend to fall into threecategories:

• Confronting external threats to the resourcesof community subsistence economies fromcompeting demands and values. This requirespolitical engagement, education, andsometimes mediation to achieve sharedunderstandings of economic values andchoices.

• Creating new and appropriate economicopportunities built around informal resourceuse strategies such as harvesting non-timberforest products and assisting in researchrelated to resource depletion andmanagement.

• Redirecting the flow of benefits from naturalresources to communities such thatcommunities can benefit directly from theresources they help to steward by developinginfrastructure such as bed and breakfasts,outfitters, educational programs, etc. thatgenerate economic returns to localcommunities.9

These strategies engage local communitiesin defining traditional and evolving resource usepatterns that are part of the informal economy,finding ways to support these uses while at thesame time, improving resource conservationpractices.

Establishing partnerships betweengovernment agencies and communitieshelps to build mutual awareness and betterworking relationships for dealing withcomplex modern day problems. Moreimportantly, co-managementarrangements offer another venue forachieving sustainable and self-definedapproaches to progress (Kofinas 1993).

Local Exchange and Trading System (LETS)LETS, founded by Michael Linton in

Canada in the early 1990s, is a barter-basedsystem that uses centralized credit accounting. Itis designed to enable people to trade goods andservices with each other where the nationalcurrency is in short supply, by providing a localunit of currency in which the value of trades isrecorded. Members pay a small registration feeand then list the goods and services which theywish to offer and receive in a directory. Thoseseeking to trade come to mutual agreement onthe value of the trade and then notify the centralaccounting system. Members receive a regularstatement of the balance in their accounts. As ofthe mid-1990s, there were 164 systems inAustralia, 350 in the United Kingdom, and about20 in North America.

In a detailed study of LETS in Australia,Colin Williams found the level of trade permember drops slightly when there are more than

Page 17: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200015

200 members and where the LETS covers a largegeographical area. Distance inhibits membersfrom providing services to one another. Initially,LETS members were predominantly people whofavored alternative and/or green lifestyles, butnewer LETS have been shown to have a farbroader and more mixed base of participants.(Gran 1998). Coordinators estimated thatapproximately 1/3 of their members are notemployed. As LETS have grown and the statehas become active in their promotion, through,for example, giving out information on LETSwhen a person applies for unemploymentcompensation, unemployed who would otherwisebecome isolated from social networks have heardabout them and joined. This suggests that LETSare able to meet needs that unemployed peoplecannot meet in either the formal or informal casheconomy (Williams, 1997).

Time Dollars, co-management of naturalresources, and LETS are described as a startingpoint for creative thinking about how we mightintegrate the informal economy more deliberatelyinto our programmatic rural development efforts.Clearly, any of these will have to be tailored tothe needs and possibilities of each place and/ororganization into which they are introduced.None are simply bandaids. All require significantinvestments in time, energy, and patience tonurture and build the relationships upon whichsuccess depends.

Building the Principle of Connectivityinto Our Work

Persistent underdevelopment, at its core,bespeaks a lack of relationship. People who arepoor in America are people who are isolated.Isolated people lack choices. Isolated people lacklivelihood security. Isolated people never developthe skills to enter into reciprocal exchangerelationships. Socially isolated individuals are attwo to three times the risk of dying prematurelycompared to socially well-connected individuals(Kawachi 1999). Isolated people are no morelikely to succeed in the informal economy than inthe formal economy.

Research into levels of self-provisioning inWest Germany found that householdcomposition was the most significantfactor in accounting for variations in self-provisioning among households and thisremained the case when other variablessuch as income and class were taken into

account. The lowest degree of self-supportwas found in one person households.While often these households lackedsufficient resources to purchase goods andservices from the formal market,nonetheless they did not possess sufficientlabour power to rely on self-production(Leonard, 1998).

Part of the appeal of programs like TimeDollars is that by “countering the isolatingpathologies of money, [they] tend to restore theconditions of neighborly doing and therefore ofhealth” (Cahn and Rowe 1996).

If we accept the profound relationshipbetween poverty and isolation from both formaland informal economic opportunity, and the keyrole of connectivity and social networks inaccessing and participating effectively in economyin any form, then how does this change theemphasis in our work as developmentpractitioners?

Many economic development practitionersframe their goal in terms of the number of jobsthat they can claim to have created. Someeconomic development practitioners have gonebeyond asking how many jobs a particularbusiness will create in their community to askingabout the quality of those jobs. Ourunderstanding of the relationship between theformal and informal economies suggests thatquality is not only a matter of wage rates. Otherquality-related questions we need to ask include:

• Will employees be able to control their ownhours?

• Will the hours of employment, even if lessthan full-time, be stable and predictable?

• Will the employer assist in any way withchild care?

• What type(s) of health care benefits will beprovided?

• Will employees have access to tools,equipment, “waste” products, or other assetsof the business for non-business use?

• Will employees develop skills useful in eitherthe formal or the informal economy?

• Does the business encourage participation insocial/professional networks?

Page 18: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200016

The answers to these questions have adirect bearing on the total economic involvementof households and their capacities to createlivelihood security for themselves. The morethese questions are answered in the affirmative,the greater the likelihood that households will beable to mesh formal and informal economicparticipation effectively, and therefore gain netbenefits from formal employment. The morethey are answered negatively, the greater thelikelihood that those who take the jobs will findit increasingly difficult to supplement theirearnings through involvement in the informaleconomy, thus becoming twice poor.

Some economic development practitionershave also begun to ask, “Jobs for whom?” Is itgood development policy to create more jobsthan the local labor force can fill and therebyinduce in-migration? Is it good policy to createjobs requiring skills the local labor force doesn’thave and is unlikely to have the opportunity toacquire? How do you create a mix of jobs in acommunity that provides for entry and growth?For the needs of full-time formal workers, andpart-time workers, blue-collar and white-collar,home-based producers and factories, recognizingthat it’s the richness of the mix that creates thebest environment for meeting the full range ofhuman needs?

To really answer the question, “Jobs forwhom?” we need to know who lives in ourcommunities, and how they are currently meetingand not meeting their economic needs. We needto recognize and accept that jobs, whether formalor informal, are not, by themselves, enough toinduce improvements in well-being for thosewho are socially, economically, culturally, and,above all, personally isolated.

Isolation is the number one barrier tolivelihood security. Isolation is, in part, astructural problem, particularly in rural areas. Forexample:

Although the most prevalent mode oftransportation in rural areas is theautomobile, one of every 14 households inrural America has no vehicle. Thepercentage of rural elderly and poorwithout vehicles rises to 45 percent and 57percent respectively. And 38 percent of thenation’s rural residents live in areaswithout any public transit service...Therural poor are one of the least connectedsectors: only 74.4 percent of rural

households with annual incomes less than$5,000 have phones (EconomicDevelopment Digest, April 1999).

Alongside the absence of structuralconnection through transportation,telecommunications, and now the internetamong rural and urban disadvantaged people, wemust recognize the often profound lack of socialskills based on a lack of experience and models.People who do not know how to connect withone another have excruciatingly limitedopportunities to engage in our economy in anyform. Outreach, mentoring, social work, homevisits, and similar deliberate efforts to createconnection are essential in addressing the roots ofpersistent poverty. This quote, from a womanwho grew up in poverty in the mountains inAppalachia, explains the importance of one-on-one contacts:

To me what brings you out of poverty isnot anything that the school system does.It’s not anything that bureaucracy does. Ithas more to do with a mentor. You have tohave somebody there. I don’t think that aperson necessarily knows they’re a mentorat the time. But there has to be somethingintroduced to that person’s life before theycan see there’s a different world...A lot ofthese people that live in poverty withnothing think that’s normal, that’sexpected—because that’s all they’ve everknown. If that’s all you’ve ever known allof your life, how can you know there’sanything different? (Duncan 1999).

Development practitioners need to formalliances with social workers, communityorganizers and informal networks of caring, tolearn together how best to find and includeisolated people in the web of relationships thatcreate livelihood security. We must recognize andaddress the social skill prerequisite required forconnectivity and the experiences one must haveto develop social skills, and provide venues inwhich these can be developed. These venuesmust not be segregated by class or experience.

The more practitioners can support thosewho assist individuals in creating networks thatbridge class, neighborhood, race, community, thericher the opportunities for economic

Page 19: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200017

participation. Exchange networks, whetherbarter-based or time-based, must bridge,

[B]oth the social divide between peoplewho have ‘a lot of time and little money’and those for whom the reverse holds true,as well as between the potential suppliersand takers of different categories ofservices, as well as spanning the temporaldivide between different age groups (Offeand Heinz 1992).

Development practitioners mustacknowledge the central role of facilitatingconnectivity in our work. The work of ensuringsustainable livelihoods for all cannot succeed insegregated pockets with programs targeted toonly those we perceive as disadvantaged.Programs must provide the opportunity to linkacross class, race, gender, place of origin, etc. tofoster opportunities for personal developmentand exchange that will, with encouragement, leadto opportunities for economic exchange andparticipation.

And, finally, we must treat informaleconomic activity as valid and valuable in its ownright, and not exclusively as a stepping stone toformal employment. Many practitioners inmicro-enterprise development, particularly innatural resource areas, are struggling with this asthey discover the extent of informal economicactivity and both the perceived and real barriersto formality. For example, one practitionerworking to organize a cooperative of rabbitgrowers found potential participants fearful of“the system.” Because they were afraid, theydidn’t want anyone to know what they weredoing. Many of the assumptions they weremaking about their own vulnerability toregulations and taxation were wrong, but fear of“the system” made them unwilling to askquestions. The development practitioner, whoserole was to formalize the group into acooperative, began to realize this would not be aproductive approach. First, it was necessary tobuild trust, then to help the group test theirassumptions, and finally, to work with them toweigh carefully the pros and cons of formalizingversus remaining informal.

Other research has shown that,

[W]omen perceive their income fromhousehold production as necessary...andview child care needs and policyregulations as constraints to enterprisedevelopment (Shifflett and Hoskins 1985).

As practitioners, we should welcome theopportunity to assist those we work with inunderstanding the reality of formal economicrequirements and in making informed choicesregarding their approaches to livelihood security.This task should be approached with an openmind and not with an agenda of formalization. Insome instances, formalization will make sense; inothers it will not. By ignoring the significance ofinformal activities to livelihood security, we riskdestabilizing the security of those we areattempting to help. There are many instances inwhich informal economic activity may provideflexibility, social insurance, and a sense ofbelonging, as well as material benefits that areunavailable to participants in the formaleconomy.

Opportunities for informal and formaleconomic involvement may look very differentfrom one community to the next, as the nature ofwhat is available and the rules governing behaviorand possibility vary. To ignore informalopportunities and benefits and to insteadprivilege formal opportunities, howeverinadequate, may be to undermine both sectors ofthe economy and further impoverish people. Onthe other hand, recognizing the role of informaleconomic activity in the lives of individuals andhouseholds, provides a base around which formalemployment may be usefully structured.Practitioners who are willing to recognize andaccept the legitimacy of informal livelihoodsecurity may find opportunities to assist inovercoming barriers to formality whereappropriate and to build a more robust informalsector where formality is not appropriate.

Page 20: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200018

Endnotes

1 This includes a shadow economy created by the public sector through off-budget spending estimated at$32.2 billion in 1981 (Bennett and DiLorenzo 1982).

2 Another aspect of the economy that we typically do not count is the value of services provided by thenatural environment. Environmental services are, in some real sense, the basis of all economic activity, aswithout them the basis for life as we know it would disappear.

3 For an excellent discussion of the range of methodologies used to study the informal economy and theirrelative strengths and weaknesses, the author recommends Informal Employment in the Advanced Economiesby Williams and Windebank.

4 Several authors have explored the notion of the “whole economy” using heuristic devices such as totempoles and layer cakes (New Internationalist Issue 278; Henderson 1981). These constructions show natureas the base upon which the social (non-market) economy, the underground (market) economy, the publicsector and finally the official private sector market economy are built. They reinforce the fact that withoutthe personal, neighborly, and familial activities of the informal economy, we would be hard put to producequalified laborers for the formal economy.

5 There has been a great deal of discussion, going back at least 30 years, on the need to adjust our measuresof the economy to reflect “bads” and quality of life issues. Readers are directed to If the GDP is Up, Why isAmerica Down? by Cobb, Halstead, and Rowe, Atlantic Monthly Magazine, October 1995 for a sample.There is also a considerable literature on alternative measures, including the Genuine Progress Indicator(GPI) and the Measurement of Economic Welfare (MEW).

6 Costanza et al., The Value of the World’s Ecosystem Services and Natural Capital, Nature Magazine, 1998.

7 See, for example, recent work by Paul Hawken, William McDonnough, and others on natural capitalism.

8 An individual who holds a waged job that is defined as year round, full time, and “regular” is provisionallyclassified as having good employment. Good jobs include stability, benefits and an arm’s lengthrelationship with the employer. "Bad jobs” are part-time, seasonal, or specifically designated “temporary”.Bad jobs are unstable, and lack benefits.

9 Typology from Kofinas 1993.

Page 21: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200019

Bibliography

Abel, Allen. “Subterranean Harvest.” http://www.cangeo.ca/So98/worms.html. December 3, 1998.

Ackerman, Frank. “Understanding the Nature of Work.”http://www.islandpress.org/ecocompass/changingatow/changing1.html. December 31, 1998.

Ahmed, Norman. “Informal Economy is Spreading out its Wings.”http://www.dawn.com/daily/19980720/ebr8.htm. December 21, 1998.

Balkin, Steve, John C. Cross, and Alfonso Morales. “Street Sales: Commerce in the Post-Modern World.”http://www.openair.org/research/street.html. April 1997.

Bennett, James T. and Thomas J. DiLorenzo. “The Underground Federal Government: Bane of theBalanced Budget?” Policy Analysis No. 19. http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa019es.html. October 1982.

Benton, Lauren A., Manuel Castells, and Alejandro Portes. The Informal Economy: Studies in Advanced andLess Developed Countries. The Johns Hopkins University Press. 1989.

Berry, Wendell. “17 Steps to a Sustainable, Local Community: A Few Practical Guidelines on How toSustain a Place-Based Community.” Sustainable Development, Aspen REPP. March 1995.

Berry, Wendell. “Back to the Land: The Radical Case for Local Economy.” The Amicus Journal. Winter1999. Pages 37-40.

Bischak, Greg. “Socioeconomic Trends in the Appalachian Region.” Excerpted from a Summary Reportto the Appalachian Regional Commission. Mountain Promise. Volume 10, No. 1. Summer 1999.

Brandt, Barbara. Whole Life Economics: Revaluing Daily Life. New Society Publishers. Gabriola Island,British Columbia. 1995.

Brownlee, Derek. “Inventing a Win-Win World.”http://www3.pair.com/genesis/journ...lalexandria/neweconomy/winwin.html. February 1996.

Bryant, Clifton D. et. al. The Rural Workforce: Non-Agricultural Occupations in America. Bergin and GarveyPublishers Inc. Massachusetts. 1985.

Cahn, Edgar S. “Rebuilding Community: The Co-Production Imperative.” Time Dollar Institute.http://www.timedollar.org/essay.htm. January 12, 1999.

Cahn, Edgar S. “Thinking Outside the Box: Redefining Work to Redefine Welfare.” Time DollarInstitute. http://www.timedollar.org/welfarefinal.htm. January 12, 1999.

Cahn, Edgar S. “Time Dollars: Creating New Currency to Build a Community.” Family ResourceCoalition of America. http://www.frca.org/timedollars.htm. January 12, 1999.

Cahn, Edgar S. and Jonathon Rowe. Time Dollars: The New Currency That Enables Americans to Turn TheirHidden Resource—Time—Into Personal Security & Community Renewal. Published by Family ResourceCoalition of America in 1998.

Cartwright, John M. “Calculation of County Economic Levels for FY 1999.” Appalachian RegionalCommission. Washington DC. May 1998.

Page 22: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200020

Caryl, Christian. “Only a Fool Pays Taxes in Capitalist Russia, a Shadow Economy Keeps the CountryGoing.” U.S. News and World Report.http://www.usnews.com/usnews/issue/980330/30russ.htm. March 30, 1998.

Center for International Private Enterprise. “Informal Sector Newsletter.”http://www/usis.usemb.se/ERT/e02/5INFSEC.HTML. December 9, 1998.

Center for International Private Enterprise. “News and Views.” http://www.cipe.org/ce/96_2ce4.htmlNovember 25, 1998.

Charmes, Jacques. “The Informal Sector, Public Intervention and Social Protection in a Changing LaborMarket.” Economic Research Forum. http://www.erf.org.eg/nletter/Jul95-03.asp November 25, 1998.

Chow, Gina. “Bartering Fuels Underground Economy.” The Detroit News.http://www.detnews.com/1997/nation/9711/03/11030074.htm. November 3, 1997

Clague, Michael. The Household Economy: A Workbook for Families, Friends, and Neighbors. CommunityInitiatives Publications. Vancouver, British Columbia. June 1985.

Cross, John C. “Developing the ‘Informal Economy’: Micro Business and Macro Dollars.”http://acs.aucegypt.edu/www/cross/smlegypt.html. 1997.

Cross, John C. “The State and Informal Economic Actors.”http://auc-acs.eun.eg/www/cross/subecon4.html. January 1994.

Cross, John C. “The Informal Sector.”http://auc-acs.eun.eg/www/cross/infdef2.html. 1998.

Cross, John C. “Formalizing the Informal Economy: The Case of Street Vendors in Mexico City.”http://auc-acs.eun.eg/www/cross/vendnow2.html. January 1995.

Cross, John C. “Entrepreneurship & Exploitation: Measuring Independence in the Informal Economy.”http://auc-acs.eun.eg/www/cross/infentr.html. August 1995.

Cross, John C. “Informal Leverage.” http://auc-acs.eun.eg/www/cross/esmat.html. 1998.

De Soto, Hernando. The Other Path, The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. Harper and Row. NewYork. 1989.

Doda, Ida. “The Informal Economy and Depressed Areas Define a New Map of Marginality.”http://www.xcom.it/icef/abstracts/doda.html. January 6, 1999.

Duncan, Cynthia M. Worlds Apart: Why Poverty Persists in Rural America. Yale University. 1999.

Egeberg, Olaf. “Non-Money: That ‘Other Money’ You Didn’t Know You Had.”http://www.bendigo.latrobe.edu.au/arts/ijccr/volume1.1bb.htm. A Book Review by Barbara Brandt. 1997.

Eisler, Riane. “Changing the Rules of the Game: Work, Values, and Our Future.”http://www.great-ideas.org/work.htm. December 9, 1998.

Esbenshade, Jill. “Immigrants and the Informal Economy.”http://www.igc.apc.org/nnirr/network_news/win98/immig_info_econ.html October 4, 1998.

Page 23: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200021

Feldman, Shelley and Eveline Ferretti. Informal Work and Social Change. A Bibliographic Survey. CornellUniversity Press. 1998.

Fetterman E. and R. Simon. “Economic Worth of Household-Produced Goods and Services.” Universityof Massachusetts, Cooperative Extension Service. March 1984.

Francisconi, Michael. Kinship, Capitalism, Change: The Informal Economy of the Navajo, 1868-1995.Garland Publishing, Inc. New York, New York. 1998.

GKE Economic Research Co. “The Hidden Economy in Hungary.” http://www.cipe.org/cee/epr2.html.December 21, 1998.

Glass R., R. Muth and R. Flewellin. “Subsistance as a Component of the Mixed Economic Base in aModernizing Community.” Northeast Forest Experiment Station. Radnor, Pennsylvania. July 1989.

“Glossary of Terms used in the Volunteer Economy.” December 1998.http://www.northlink.com/~derekb/glossary.htm.

Gillepsie G., T. Lyson, and D. Harper. “Diversified Rural Livelihood Strategies Among Low-IncomeFarm Families in the Northeast.” Final Report. The Rural Economic Policy Program. April 1994.

Grabowski, Maciej. “The Informal Sector in Poland: An Assessment and Policy Implications.” GdanskInstitute for Market Economics (GIME). http://www.cipe.org/efn/gime2.htmlNovember 25, 1998.

Gran, Even. “Green Domination In Norwegian Letsystems: Catalyst For Growth or Constraint OnDevelopment?” http://www.bendigo.latrobe.edu.au/arts/ijccr/volume2/2eg.htm. July 1999.

Greenfield, Harry. Invisible, Outlawed, and Untaxed: America’s Underground Economy. Praeger. Westport,Connecticut. 1993.

Greenwald M. and S. Schmidt. “Home Enterprise in Minnesota: Minnesota’s Role in the Growth andDevelopment of Home Based and Cottage Industries.” The Minnesota Project. October 1984.

Off, Claus and Rolf G. Heinze. Beyond Employment: Time, Work and the Informal Economy. TempleUniversity Press, Philadelphia. 1992.

Ingleby, Julie. “Local Economic Trading Systems: Potentials for New Communities of Meaning: A BriefExploration of Eight LETSystems, With a Focus on Decision Making.” CMB Yuendumu via AliceSprings, NY 0872 Australia. http://www.bendigo.latrobe.edu.au/arts/ijccr/volume2/2ji.htm.

Kaufman, Maynard. “The Need for a Third Way in Economics.”http://www.traverse.net/NonProf/Center/synapse40/maynard.html. December 9, 1998.

Kawachi, Ichiro. “Measurement of Social Capital in Public Health.” Memorandum given out at theSaguaro Seminar. Harvard School of Public Health. October 1999.

Kofinas, Gary. “Subsistence Hunting in a Global Economy: Contributions of Northern Wildlife Co-Management Community Economic Development.”http://arcticcircle.uconn.edu/NatResources/subsistglobal.html December 7, 1998.

Kunsman, Dan. “Thomas Amends Spending Bill to Prevent Government Competition with PrivateSector.” http://www.senate.gov/~thomas/pr55.html. July 1997.

Page 24: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200022

Leonard, Madeleine. Invisible Work, Invisible Workers: The Informal Economy in Europe and the U.S.St. Martin’s Press, Inc. New York, New York. 1998.

Lerner, Sally. “The Future of Work in North America: Good Jobs, Bad Jobs, Beyond Jobs.” University ofWaterloo. Waterloo, Ontario.http://cs-www.uchicago.edu/discussions/cpsr/jobtech/future-of-work.html October 22, 1998.

M2 Communications. “UN: Informal Economy, Ageing of Society Among Issues Discussed by SocialDevelopment Commission.” http://library.northernlight.com/

Martel, Elise. “From Market to Market: The Restructuring of Chicago’s Maxwell Street Market.”http://www.openair.org/research/emartel.html. January 5, 1999.

Mason, Debra A. “Vermont’s Other Economy: The Economic and Socio-Cultural Values of Hunting,Fishing, and Trapping for Rural Households.” Masters Thesis Presentation, University of Vermont. 1990.

Matvey, Joseph J. “Subsistence in Central Appalachia: Some Structural and Cultural Currents.”http://www.etext.org/Politics/Prog...sistence_in_Central_Appalchis.1991January 19, 1999.

McInnis-Dittrich, Kathleen. “Women of the Shadows: Appalachian Women’s Participation in theInformal Economy.” AFFILIA: Journal of Women and Social Work. Vol. 10, No.4, Winter 1995 398-412.Sage Publications.

Muth, Robert M. “Community Stability as Social Structure: The Role of Subsistence Uses of NaturalResources in Southeast Alaska.” (Draft) USDA Forest Service. Juneau, Alaska. 1986.

Muth R., D. Ruppert , and R. Glass. “Subsistence Use of Fisheries Resources in Alaska: Implications forGreat Lake Fisheries Management.”

National Center for Policy Analysis. “The Growing Underground Economy (Summary).”http://www.ncpa.org/pi/taxes/july98b.html. July 1998.

The NADO Research Foundation. “Focus on Rural America.” Economic Development Digest. April 1999.

National Center for Policy Analysis. “The Underground Economy.” http://www.ncpa.org/ba/ba273.htmlNovember 21, 1998.

The Natural Resources Defense Council. The Amicus Journal. The Argus Press. Albany, New York. Fall1986.

Nelson, M. and J. Smith. Working Hard and Making Do: Surviving in Small Town America. University ofCalifornia Press. Berkeley, CA. 1999.

The New Internationalist. “The Economic Totem Pole.” http://oneworld.org/ni/issue278/totem.htmlDecember 3, 1998.

Newton, R. and M. Moss. “The Subsistence Lifeway of the Tlingit People: Excerpts of Oral Interviews.”USDA Forest Service, Alaska Region. Juneau, Alaska. July 1984.

Ninez, Vera K. “Household Gardens: Theoretical Consideration on an old Survival Strategy.” Training andCommunications Department. International Potato Center. Lima, Peru. March 1985.

Page 25: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200023

Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development. Framework for the Measurement of UnrecordedEconomic Activities in Transition Economies. Head of Publications Service, OECD. Paris, France. 1997.

Pacione, Michael. “Local Exchange Trading Systems as a Response to the Globalization of Capitalism.”http://library.northernlight.com. December 9, 1998.

Raphael, Dennis, C. Psych. “From Increasing Poverty to Societal Disintergration: Economic Inequalityand the Future Health of Canada.” Department of Public Health Sciences, University of Toronto.http://www.interlog.com/~cjazz/bnews2.htm.

Raspberry, William. “Time Dollars: A Concept for Caring.” http://www.timedollar.org/about.htmJanuary 12, 1999.

Ratner, Shanna. Emerging Issues in Learning Communities. Yellow Wood Associates. 1997

Rowe, Jonathon and Judith Silverstein. “The GDP Myth: Why ‘Growth’ Isn’t Always a Good Thing.” http://cool.impresso.com:80/cgi-bin/nph-cnctcgi?K=1288016409&T=VR01LhqS&template=1.As published in the Washington Monthly.

Rural Policy Research Institute. “Rural America and Welfare Reform: An Overview Assessment.”http://www.rupri.org/pubs/archive/old/welfare/p99-3/index.html. February 10, 1999.

Revenue Canada’s Underground Economy Initiative (Fact Sheet).http://www.rc.gc.ca/E/pub/xr/980225et/980225e.txt.html December 3, 1998.

Salant, Priscilla and Anita J. Waller. Guide to Rural Data. Island Press. 1995.

Salstrom, Paul. “Appalachia’s Informal Economy and the Transition to Capitalism.” Journal of AppalachianStudies. Volume 2 Number 2.

Salstrom, Paul. “Subsistence-Barter-and-Borrow Systems: An Approach to West Virginia’s EconomicHistory.” http://www.wvlc.wvnet.edu/history/journal_wch/wch51-4.html. December 21, 1998.

Smith D., C. Starrs and G. Stewart. “The Whole Economy: A Concept Paper.”http://magi.com/~jrennie/gail.html. December 1, 1998.

Smith, Estellie M. Perspectives on the Informal Economy (Monographs in Economic Anthropology, No. 8).University Press of America. May 1991.

Smith, Joan and Margaret K. Nelson. “ ‘Patching it Together’: The Economy of Rural Households andthe Nature of Rural Poverty.” Final Report. Ford Foundation Project Number 925-0188.

Soza, Shari. “Local Government Should FACILITATE THE UNDERGROUND ECONOMY AS ABACKUP ECONOMIC SYSTEM For Times When Cashflow is Stagnating.”http://www.snowcrest.net/soza/jobs/nugrund.htm. January 1996.

Speer, Tibbett L. “Digging Into the Underground Economy.”http:www.demographics.com/publications/ad/95_ad/9502ab04.htm. November 21, 1998.

Spracklin, Kathryn. “Unpaid Work: A Measure of Women’s Equality.” The Kitchen Table Revolution.http://www.cyberus.ca/~maw/ktr.htm#KTRContents. December 4, 1998.

Page 26: The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

The Informal Economy in Rural Community Economic Development

TVA Rural Studies Program / Contractor Paper 00-03 Shanna Ratner, February 200024

Stone, Deborah. “Care and Trembling.” The American Prospect. March-April 1999. pp. 61-67.

Usher, Peter J. Property Rights: The Basis of Wildlife Management. P.J. Usher Consulting Services. Ottawa,Ontario. 1984.

Weld, Madeline. “Human Population Growth.” A paper delivered to the Canadian Association for theClub of Rome. May 1997.

Whole A., C. Williams, and J. Windebank. “Social Polarization of Households in Contemporary Britain:A ‘Whole Economy’ Perspective.” http://library.northernlight.com/ December 9, 1998.

Wilde, Keith. “Reaction to ‘The Whole Economy: A Concept Paper’.” Proceedings. Series 1 Number 23September 1997.

Williams, Colin C. “A Helping Hand: Harnessing Self-Help to Combat Social Exclusion.” University ofLeicester, Department of Geography, UK. July 1999.

Williams, Colin C. “Local Exchange and Trading Systems (LETS) in Australia: A New Tool forCommunity Development?” http://www.bendigo.latrobe.edu.au/arts/ijccr/volume1/1ccw.htm. July 1999.

Williams C. and J. Windebank. “What is to be Done About the Paid Informal Sector in the EuropeanUnion? A Review of Some Policy Options.” International Planning Studies.http://library.northernlight.com/ December 9, 1998.

Williams, Colin C. and Jan Windebank. Informal Employment in the Advanced Economies, Implications forWork and Welfare. Routledge. 1998.