25
7KH 5ROH RI 0HUFKDQW :KROHVDOHUV LQ ,QGXVWULDO $JJORPHUDWLRQ )RUPDWLRQ $XWKRUV $P\ *ODVPHLHU 6RXUFH $QQDOV RI WKH $VVRFLDWLRQ RI $PHULFDQ *HRJUDSKHUV 9RO 1R 6HS SS 3XEOLVKHG E\ 7D\ORU )UDQFLV /WG RQ EHKDOI RI WKH $VVRFLDWLRQ RI $PHULFDQ *HRJUDSKHUV 6WDEOH 85/ http://www.jstor.org/stable/2563620 $FFHVVHG Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=taylorfrancis. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Association of American Geographers and Taylor & Francis, Ltd. are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Annals of the Association of American Geographers. http://www.jstor.org

The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

http://www.jstor.org/stable/2563620

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available athttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unlessyou have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and youmay use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained athttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=taylorfrancis.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printedpage of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range ofcontent in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new formsof scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

Association of American Geographers and Taylor & Francis, Ltd. are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize,preserve and extend access to Annals of the Association of American Geographers.

http://www.jstor.org

Page 2: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration Formation

Amy Glasmeier

Graduate Program in Community and Regional Planning, University of Texas at Austin, Austin, TX 78712

Abstract. This paper explores the impor- tance of merchant wholesalers in the early for- mation of industrial agglomerations. Mer- chant wholesalers reduce the size constraint of local markets by extending an entrepre- neur's market reach. The merchant wholesale function also facilitates the formation of the division of labor by allowing greater local spe- cialization. Merchant wholesalers are hypoth- esized to be part of the complex formation process. In the early stage of a complex's de- velopment, these intermediaries trade-in from outside as local demand warrants. Over time, local wholesale functions unfold. As a com- plex grows, these wholesalers specialize, cre- ating a range of wholesale operations. The process of merchant wholesaler formation is thought to be dialectical; prior generations of technology lay the basis of subsequent mer- chant wholesale specializations. A model of wholesale evolution is presented and tested, based on a case study of firms in Austin, Texas.

Key Words: agglomeration, complex, distribu- tion, wholesaling, high-tech, linkages.

I J HHE emergence of new innovative in- dustry complexes has resulted in a growing body of research exploring their

causes and consequences. Three strands of theorizing stand out in the literature. At the interregional level, the seedbed shift hypoth- esis suggests that product cycle forces and di- minished seedbed capacity resulted in a cu- mulative shift of innovative industries toward the U.S. Sunbelt. Initial branch plant relocation was followed by a process of "in-filling" which Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 80(3), 1990, pp. 394-417 ? Copyright 1990 by Association of American Geographers

resulted in the creation of new centers of in- novation (Norton and Rees 1979).

At the metropolitan level, case studies of in- novative regions cite place-specific character- istics as the genesis of new complexes. These factors include personal location decisions (Saxenian 1985; Rogers and Larsen 1984), selec- tive and unduly concentrated levels of federal research and development expenditures (Mar- kusen et al. 1990), and synergism among various local factors which resulted in a new territorial innovation complex (Stohr 1986). Using a con- ceptual framework based on product-process characteristics, I have previously argued that local transactions are regulated by ownership imperatives and corporate customs that inhibit or encourage linkage and spinoff formation (Glasmeier 1988). Scott and Storper (1987) con- tend that occasionally "windows of opportu- nity" are opened by an initial spark of indus- trialization. As news of an innovation spreads, competition evolves between locations until finally a new and dominant agglomeration emerges (Storper and Walker 1989).

At the intrametropolitan scale, Scott asserts a production-based explanation for the inter- nal integration of cities (1988). The divisibility of certain labor processes makes possible ver- tical disintegration of production. These trans- actions are either undertaken through internal production or obtained through market ex- change. As firms contract out for the separable activities which are more costly if executed within the company, and market transactions replace internal production, geographic "in- filling" occurs.

This body of literature operates at three geo- graphic levels in suggesting why industries lo- cate proximately and in exploring the impor- tant determinants of expansion in favored locations. The viewpoints are welcome addi-

Page 3: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 395

tions to our knowledge about agglomeration formation. But with one exception, each ac- count treats the process of city formation in isolation (Glasmeier 1988). Thus the evolution of a new complex has been discussed inde- pendently of other cities, and only now are we invited to look within as opposed to outside complexes for factors that precipitate the ex- pansion of new agglomerations. Theoretical treatments do not identify the locational and organizational conditions that nurture the in- fancy of a new formation.

In this article, I argue that new complex for- mation must be analyzed and considered from a perspective which, rather than treating in- dividual cities discretely or in isolation, encom- passes what I will call the city system. Regardless of the original stimuli for a complex's forma- tion, it is the interaction between it and other cities that leads to growth and development over time (Pred 1977). Time and place con- straints that regulate the material transforma- tion and transportation of stock represent flows in the system of goods and ultimately result in the evolution of another participant in this city system. Reliance on endogenous development forces (embedded in the vertical disintegration paradigm) ignores relationships between dis- tant markets and newly forming agglomera- tions, particularly in a complex's formative stages. Frontier locations emerge and ultimate- ly flourish through the intermetropolitan trans- mission of growth, assisted by intermediaries linking preexisting complexes to newly form- ing ones.

This paper addresses a number of issues that have been only weakly conceptualized or largely ignored in the contemporary literature on in- dustrial agglomeration formation. The first concern revolves around a region's ability to specialize (thus innovate and grow) and its de- pendence on trade. In the early stage of a com- plex's development, external trade allows firms to specialize beyond what local demand sup- ports. The flow of goods and services is accom- plished primarily through direct sales by pro- ducing firms and the use of indirect market channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels are the more efficient mechanism to secure needed inputs. Therefore I explore the role of market intermediaries (emphasizing merchant wholesalers) in the expansion of trade among regions and sketch out their locational

implications. I then turn to a model of regional formation which is based on the concept of stock control, viz., one expression of how fron- tier locations are incorporated into a national system of cities (Meyer 1980). By reasserting trade agent control over stock, the geographic evolution of wholesaling within a city system and a newly emerging agglomeration can be outlined.

A realistic appraisal of how stock flows across space and through time requires that we un- derstand the motives behind firms' choices of distribution channels. With the rise of the ver- tically integrated corporation, the functions of distribution and material acquisition are inter- nalized within the firm. As later sections will elaborate, vertical integration best describes industries in which there are few large sellers and market share is maintained by superficial product differentiation and extensive market- ing and sales functions. As the specific concern is with centers of new industrial innovation where complexes expand through a process of new product development, I abandon the overly deterministic framework originally de- tailed by Chandler (1966; see Porter and Livesay 1971).

By linking firm distribution strategies with the geography of metropolitan development, an evolutionary model of agglomeration forma- tion can be articulated which incorporates wholesale trade. The formative stages of an ag- glomeration rely upon new product develop- ment and entrepreneurial initiative. Over time as the complex achieves some success, nonlocal wholesalers trade-in to satisfy periodic and in- creasingly specialized wants. As an agglomer- ation grows in size and complexity, specialized wholesalers establish a geographic presence. While local production may be sufficient to sat- isfy basic material input needs, wholesaling re- mains strong, particularly for specialized goods. Even with the introduction of large multilo- cational firms, specific immediate needs are often satisfied through distribution channels. This model is elaborated by examining the evo- lution of a new high-tech industrial complex, Austin, Texas, first through a historical exami- nation of merchant wholesale evolution in the electronics industry and then via a firm survey which identifies the extent that firms currently use distributors. I conclude with comments on the importance of interregional trade in new agglomeration formation.

Page 4: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

396 Glasmeier

The Role of Wholesalers and Firm Marketing Strategies Definition of Wholesalers

Before proceeding, it is necessary to define wholesaling. Elsewhere I have shown that the wholesaling function can be broken down by scale, industry, and type of transaction (Glas- meier 1989). Borrowing from Vance, wholesal- ing is usually defined as "the sale of goods in large lots." The wholesale function denotes transactions by individuals in pursuit of a trade, "rather than simply to satisfy a personal or fam- ily need." Further clarification indicates that wholesaling involves "the sales of one entre- preneur to another, intended for resale by the second." Vance concludes, "the purpose rath- er than the scale is the determinant in these instances" (1970).

This study focuses on full-function merchant wholesalers who take title of goods and accept all ownership risks. They typically buy in large quantities, break bulk, assemble, sort, sell, and deliver. Merchant wholesalers are also sector- ally specialized, and they undertake various forms of product adjustment as goods move between the manufacturer and the final cus- tomer. These enhanced distributor functions have many names, including kitting (the assem- bly and pretesting of complex parts), assembly, and value-added distribution. Such services continue to evolve as firms attempt to meet manufacturers' )IT (Just in Time) inventory re- quirements. In finishing, testing, making man- ufacturing adjustments, and packaging, distrib- utors virtually eliminate the receiving firm's need for preassembly inspection. Inputs are scheduled to arrive at the factory in time for immediate insertion on the assembly line (Johnston and Lawrence 1988; Graves 1989).

Distributor Usage in Manufacturing

While this article highlights high-tech indus- tries (considered footloose and therefore most likely to use the services of market interme- diaries), wholesale distribution channels are commonly used in all manufacturing industry. Industrial distributors comprise approximately 30 percent of the nation's 338,000 merchant wholesalers. In a survey of industrial manufac-

turing firms (ordered by broad SIC [Standard Industrial Classification] categories), 54 percent reported they used a combination of marketing channels which included both their own sales forces and distributors to sell their products and services ("Industry Markets through ... 1985). Instrument manufacturers have the highest percentage of direct sales to industry (final market) (39 percent), while in electrical and electronics equipment industries, only 13 percent used factory-direct sales (Fig. 1). Of firms which used only one channel, 24 percent in- dicated they bought factory-direct; 23 percent used distributors. Thus, on a purely numerical basis, it is clear that firms use a variety of chan- nels to distribute their goods and to acquire material inputs. Given costs, time, and service requirements, the use of intermediaries is ex- pected to increase in the 1990s (Crespedes 1 988a).

The key to distribution is the provision of place and time utility. Place utility refers to the satisfaction of demand in its immediate loca- tion. Time utility measures the satisfaction of wants immediately. Distributors move goods from locations of surplus to areas with deficits. By either anticipating demand and maintaining stock to satisfy immediate unscheduled wants, or by estimating an apparent demand and mak- ing provisions to fulfill it, the merchant whole- saler ensures both place and time utility.

Modern Channel Strategies

In the business literature the selection of a marketing strategy is termed "channeling." Most marketing literature approaches channel selection from the standpoint of how a firm can best distribute its products. For our pur- poses, this approach is turned slightly on end to be viewed through the lens of geography and regional development concerns. Thus we are able to answer questions about when and under what circumstances firms use market in- termediaries to distribute goods and, by im- plication, determine what kinds of goods and inputs firms purchase through distributors.

Reasons for Using Indirect Channels

It has often been said that firms can eliminate the middleman, but not the functions per-

Page 5: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 397

33.8%|

Chemical & Allied Products 10.8% 55.4%

Stone, Clay & Glass Products 38.9%

a_15.0% Primary Metal Industries 5%

80.0%

_10.6%

Fabricated Metal Products ~~~~~~~~~~~~50.0%

Machinery, except Electrical 48 55.9%

Electrical & Electronic Equipment 23.8 63.4%

-_ ~~~~~~~31.8% Transportation Equipment 13.6%

54.5%

_ _-_-_ _ ~~~~~~~38.8% Instruments & Related Products

_ ~~~~~40.0%

_ ~~~~~~~29.6% Misc. Manufacturing Industries 18.5%

51.9%

Direct to Industry Through Distributors, Agents, or Dealers Through Both

Figure 1. Percentage of manufacturers using various channels of distribution.

formed (Drucker 1962). Thus while a firm may choose to distribute its own goods and circum- vent the need for indirect channels, it must still break bulk, sort, transport, finance, service, and market its products (Cox 1965; Bowersox et al. 1968).

Companies use distributors in lieu of direct sales for many reasons. These include the cost of otherwise maintaining an internal sales force (Crespedes 1988b); the role of adjustment and market access required to implement JIT (Giu- nipero and O'Neal 1987; Socolovsky 1985); the increasing use of computerized links between manufacturers, wholesalers, and final cus- tomers (Kastiel 1987; Russell 1985); the increas- ing segmentation of markets which span nu- merous geographic locations (Rayner 1986); the effect of foreign competition invading domes- tic markets (Kerr 1987); and the need for prod- uct-related adjustments to satisfy customer needs (Bertrand 1986; Temin 1985). In addition

to the established role of wholesalers, these entities are increasingly considered the most efficient and profitable means by which spe- cialized producers can gain access to growing markets.

Channel Strategy Depends on Product

Transaction cost analysis is important in de- scribing the use of vertically integrated versus intermediary marketing channels (Williamson 1981a, b). In this instance, the key is "asset spec- ificity" which describes the specialized knowl- edge built up by agents distributing a product and the type of service provided by market intermediaries who distribute goods. The choice of channel strategy is a critical decision usually based on the total cost of executing a transaction and the competitive conditions in the market (Magrath and Hardy 1987).

Page 6: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

398 Glasmeier

Channel strategy has traditionally depended on the type of product-specialized versus mass-produced (Crespedes 1988a). Intensive distribution (product placed in as many loca- tions as possible) usually occurs with consumer goods. Selective channels cover the goods cus- tomers actively seek for specific purposes (e.g., electronic products). Exclusive distribution oc- curs when a good is in short supply or requires high levels of service and is marketed from a single location. A firm adopts a sales strategy when a good is new and has few readily iden- tifiable customers. As a product matures and users increase, channel adjustments, although costly, are made (Magrath and Hardy 1987). The choice to alter or augment distribution chan- nels depends on the extensiveness of users, the prospect for future market segmentation, in- creasing market competition, expanding geo- graphic dispersion, and the prerequisite ser- vices needed to support a sale.

Channel strategy for new products depends on certain imperatives associated with the spe- cific good. The entrepreneur most familiar with the good often markets it to firms which have some likelihood of needing the innovation (Abratt 1986). Later, periodic adjustments in channel strategy are tied to market success. If the market expands rapidly or if many com- petitors arise, the producer must seek avenues of distribution beyond the capacity of a single salesperson (Butaney and Wortzel 1988; Vance 1970; Lamont 1972). The most convenient, least costly, and most immediately realized means to market a product is through the use of man- ufacturers' representatives, viz., an external sales force distributing the good along with a num- ber of complementary product lines (Lamont 1972). Alternatively, the entrepreneur may choose to establish an internal sales force by absorbing the costs of developing specialized knowledge of existing markets and competi- tors.

Channel strategies require continual adjust- ment as markets expand geographically, and large single-customer sales become significant. A critical juncture is reached when firms must decide whether to maintain an in-house sales force or to expand market-reach through in- termediaries. This choice usually depends on a firm's cash position (its ability to employ and reasons for employing its own sales force), the product (need for special service), and the ex- tent that the market is growing geographically

(Crespedes 1988b). This is particularly true when the cost of maintaining an internal sales force is weighed against other pressing demands on capital such as research and development. Firms often adopt a mixed channel strategy, handling large and steady customers with an internal sales force while less explicit, more variable, and small markets are turned over to distributors.

Geography plays a critical role in channel de- cisions. When markets are expanding geo- graphically (given the preexistence of estab- lished wholesale networks), producers place a portion of their output with market interme- diaries to meet the needs of newly emerging centers of demand (Davis 1989). Because inter- mediaries have asset-specific knowledge of in- dividual geographic and sectoral markets, they are the most effective means of addressing the needs of new users and distant markets. Per- sistence of wholesale links derives not only from product characteristics but also from the com- bined benefits of future sales of new product introductions. Having outlined aspects of firm marketing strategies, I now discuss the role of market intermediaries in the development of regions.

Mercantilism as a Model of Regional Development

There is limited geographic literature on the role of wholesaling in the formation of indus- trial agglomerations (see Vance 1970; Muller 1977; Fredriksson and Lindmark 1979; Meyer 1980; and Lord 1984 for exceptions). Sparse mention stems from two views of industrial complex organization. The first evolves from a historic model of industrialization which pre- sumed that because transportation and com- munication costs inhibited long distance link- ages, producers found jointly in space exchanged goods among themselves (Marshall 1898).1 The second view focuses on vertically integrated corporations' effect on the distri- bution of material goods. This institutional and organizational development overshadowed in- terest in the process of material exchange as a separate subject of study; it was simply sub- sumed within the vertically integrated corpo- ration. Additional geographic inquiries focused on transportation costs and agglomeration economies as explanations for spatial cluster-

Page 7: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 399

ing. But the former sidestepped the precise transactional nature of the acquisition process, and the latter assumed exchange was between two producers (Weber 1929; Hoover 1948). Be- cause much of geographic inquiry over the last twenty years has been oriented toward under- standing the behavior of large multilocational corporations, it is important that we examine how wholesalers fit into this greater organiza- tional development (Collins and Walker 1974).

The Rise of the Managerial Corporation

Elsewhere I have written of the historic role of merchants as traders, producers, and con- veyors of goods (Glasmeier 1989).2 While once dominant in goods production and distribu- tion, the wholesalers' role became more cir- cumscribed as new institutions absorbed many of the merchant's traditional functions (Porter and Livesay 1971).

The diminished importance of wholesaling is frequently tied to the emergence of the ver- tically integrated corporation and mass mar- kets. With advancements in communications and transportation, corporations could profit- ably internalize the full range of functions, in- cluding distribution. Firms systematized both the acquisition of needed inputs and the dis- tribution of final product. Product and market factors led to a contraction in wholesaler func- tions (Chandler 1962; 1966). Wholesalers were bypassed when they were unable to distribute the volume of goods produced by manufac- turers, they could not move goods swiftly enough from producer to final market, or they were unable to provide product advertising. Neither were wholesalers used when special- ized handling or services were required or when a product's distribution necessitated specific capital investments to ensure quality at the point of consumption. Finally, wholesalers were often less important in instances when the final prod- uct required demonstrable technical knowl- edge and support both during and after the sales transaction (Porter and Livesay 1971).

Chandler's analysis emphasized both supply and demand conditions which encouraged manufacturers to internalize distribution. He noted that internalization was most prevalent in oligopolistic and concentrated industries. In this instance producers were price setters, and

barriers to entry were high. Therefore market shares were relatively stable. But Chandler's model of firm evolution has been overgener- alized which led to the assumption that all firms grow large and vertically integrate. Also as used, the model is inflexible and ultimately static, un- able to account for the mixed distribution strat- egies of many firms. Most importantly, it rules out new industry and firm creation. Chandler correctly described the rise of oligopolistic corporations, but his analysis overlooked the emergence of new industries and centers of innovation (Jorde and Teece 1989).

If the role of mass producers had eclipsed the need for wholesalers, then their numbers would have surely dwindled. But during the twentieth century, as the national economy has become more specialized, wholesaling units have grown more rapidly than manufacturing establishments (Vance 1970; U.S. Department of Commerce 1982).3 Even industries most em- blematic of mass production and distribution often maintain two sales networks: one to sat- isfy preexisting concentrations of demand and another to deal with newly emerging markets (Chandler 1966). Finally, in high-tech industries, distributors routinely account for half of all sales ("Does the Country Really Need . . ." 1985).

Mercantilism as a Counterpoint to Central Place Theory

The dominance of central place theory as a model of urban settlement overpowered early geographic contributions on the subject of wholesaling.4 A noted exception is Vance's monograph on the merchant in U.S. regional development (1970). His mercantile model was a critique of central place theory's reliance on endogenous change leading to higher levels of regional specialization. Central place theory could not account for instances where local production was insufficient to satisfy local de- mand. Nor could it contend with the implica- tions of local specialization and production vol- umes exceeding local markets. As soon as self- sufficiency was exceeded, labor specialization expanded, leading to growth of trading areas. Industrial specialization was dependent upon trade. By extending demand through geo- graphic expansion, specialization could occur, thus verifying Adam Smith's seminal dictum.

Page 8: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

400 Glasmeier

Time and the Impulse to Trade

Ignoring the constraints of time and place in modeling demand and immediate fulfillment through supply, a mercantile model of regional development makes explicit the notion of time of demand fulfillment. The wholesaler is re- sponsible for moving goods from a location of abundance to one of scarcity. Thus once trade is established, demand may accumulate while an agent gauges its periodicity and matches this with supply from a variety of sources. The geo- graphic extent of wholesaling depends on the composition of demand which varies by sector, time, and place. A wholesaler can satisfy wants in a small locality by generalizing the goods traded or by specializing in traded goods and expanding his/her market area. Unlike central place theory, which argues that the range of geographic distribution of a good is a function of its local population, wholesaling dramatically increases a product's range by delivering a good to the customer. In concentrating on service quality, wholesalers benefit customers by spe- cializing in products and satisfying demand on a more infrequent basis. Therefore, trade oc- curs across long distances when a customer is willing to satisfy need periodically.

The impulse to trade regulates the geograph- ic extent of wholesalers. A strong impulse re- sults in either long-distance trade or frequent transactions; a weak impulse is characterized either by short linkages or infrequent trade in- tervals. This matrix of possibilities knits togeth- er place and time utility and suggests why and for what types of goods firms use wholesalers (Vance 1970).

Internalization

The evolution of the space economy based on trade is a steady process of internalization. As regions and cities expand, wholesalers com- pete based on market access and service deliv- ery. At a certain point it becomes necessary for wholesalers to extend their geographic pres- ence into growing markets or risk losing market share to competitors with better service. While original wholesale centers persist, new loca- tions emerge as density of demand warrants. At first the wholesaler may simply establish a sales office to respond to firms' information needs. But eventually if demand expands ap-

preciably, firms establish a stocking location to service critical and/or large customers, to ac- commodate immediate demand fulfillment, and to make final adjustments in products.

Wholesalers specialize to establish and main- tain high levels of market control. This is an interactive process between the evolution of the complex and the variety of goods available. As a complex strengthens its dominance in a single sector, specialized wholesalers are at- tracted. In very small cities, there is also oc- casion for local wholesale stocking to occur. This type of trade is usually more industry spe- cific and transcends issues of scale. Even the sum of many very small transactions may war- rant general stocking of goods.

Vance's mercantile model draws consider- able validation from historical literature on the settlement of the United States. By rejecting central place theory as rigid, scale-dependent, and economically deterministic, Vance sug- gests that intermetropolitan trade is a necessary prerequisite for regional specialization. But his model is sketched broadly and does not suffi- ciently elaborate the ways in which frontier lo- cations are integrated into a system of cities.

Frontier City Integration

Using a framework that focuses on control of exchange and physical distribution, Meyer makes explicit frontier city integration into a national system of cities (1980). Control of ex- change is presumed to have three properties. First, per-unit costs to exert control are modest beyond a certain distance. Second, because an entrepreneur can accumulate demand and pe- riodically fill it, considerable economies of scale exist in the purchase of material goods. To se- cure continued patronage, savings are passed on to customers. Finally, as the space economy evolves, entrepreneurs must either specialize further and extend their geographic trade area or carry a broader range of goods and operate within the same territory. Based on control of exchange, Meyer suggests that trading into frontier locations (as opposed to relocation of the entrepreneur to a region) occurs until "sav- ings in transaction cost/unit gained by prox- imity exceeds the higher cost/unit of local stocking/production" (1980, 123). Thus, ini- tially, entrepreneurs operate from outside a

Page 9: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 401

frontier location, only relocating when local demand warrants a stocking location.5

Control of stock originates in the metropol- itan agglomeration closest to the frontier and operates over a large area.6 As demand at the frontier location grows, local generalized stocking (by an outside distributor or a local entrepreneur-distributor) occurs. Meyer notes, "more specialized entrepreneurs of the origi- nal stocking location will maintain control of the frontier at a higher level of specialization" (1980, 125). As entrepreneurs seek control over stocking in specific geographic areas, the goods traded must become more generalized and ap- peal to a broad set of markets. In this instance, stocking of general purpose items may be done by a local wholesaler, and more specialized goods may be stocked outside and sold into the region by a specialized wholesaler.

Meyer retreats from the mercantile model because of its dependence on wholesalers as the agents of trade. Merchants' control over many traditional functions associated with trade (finance, insurance, and transportation) dimin- ished as they evolved either as separate spe- cializations or were absorbed within vertically integrated manufacturing firms. Using the less specific term, "entrepreneur," Meyer gener- alizes the process of integration. In this article, I wish to reassert the importance of wholesalers in the specific context of an expanding space economy within which the number of cus- tomers is increasing rapidly, and the level of complex specialization is high.

Wholesaler's Contribution to New Industrial Complex Formation

To articulate the role of wholesalers in new agglomeration formation, we must consider the opposite side of marketing's traditional em- phasis on sales. I start by making a series of assumptions which begin with the very earliest stages of new agglomeration, viz., when an en- trepreneur invents a product which satisfies an unfulfilled need. Demand is nonlocal, and the new product is specialized; few material inputs are purchased (the majority are manufactured in-house). Outside inputs are generally avail- able, and demand can be satisfied by existing wholesalers who carry a broad range of goods and/or can acquire more complex goods by periodically filling demand.7 Over time other

sources of demand develop, including new en- trepreneurs and branch plants. Developments in new technologies force changes in the com- position of goods offered by wholesalers, and information about available new inputs ex- pands local opportunities, thereby increasing the potential for local specialization.

Modern complexes rarely expand through entrepreneurial growth alone. Branch plants went to Silicon Valley once the region became known for specialized high-tech goods. Simi- larly, branch plants were formed as locally owned firms became acquisition targets of firms headquartered outside the region. Branch plant material acquisition channels depend on the historic purchasing patterns of parent firms, in- tracorporate purchasing policies, and levels of place and time utility. While these establish- ments may conduct purchasing through in- house intermediaries, satisfaction of immediate needs and the extent of specialization of goods demanded eventually call forth the use of dis- tributors, particularly when a product incor- porates new innovations or is a new innovation itself.

In the following two sections the evolution- ary model of industrial complex formation through a case study of Austin, Texas is elab- orated. I begin by establishing the historical ba- sis of the industrial complex and the role of wholesalers in the provision of electronic sup- plies and equipment during a forty-year peri- od. Thus we explore the contemporary im- portance of wholesalers in the expanding regional economy.

Austin, Texas-A Model of Industrial Complex Formation

In the mid-1970s high-tech industries be- came the engine of growth for many southern and western U.S. cities. Colorado Springs, Col- orado; Austin, Texas; Raleigh-Durham, North Carolina; Boca Raton, Florida; and Phoenix, Ar- izona are all identified with the 1980s high-tech boom. Austin stands out among similar size cit- ies as having grown rapidly in both population and manufacturing jobs during the last two de- cades. As branch plants, high-tech consortia, and local start-ups greatly expanded the city's manufacturing base, Austin received national (and eventually international) acclaim as the successor to Silicon Valley.

Page 10: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

402 Glasmeier

Austin, the capital of Texas and home of the University of Texas, is located in the south-cen- tral part of the state in the Hill Country. State government offices and affiliated agencies clus- ter in the city, forming the economic base. Many state-sponsored public institutions such as schools for the learning-impaired are also lo- cated in Austin; there is also a large Air Force base approximately 15 miles south of the met- ropolitan area.

In 1989 Austin had approximately 720,000 residents. The 1986 Census ranked the city as the 58th largest in the nation (U.S. Department of Commerce 1986). Like its regional neighbors, Albuquerque, Phoenix, and Colorado Springs, Austin's recent growth experience has been spectacular. The city's population increased 141 percent between 1960 and 1984. Between 1980 and 1984, Austin was ranked the tenth fastest growing metropolitan area in the country and at one point in the 1980s was dubbed the na- tion's fastest growing city.

Austin's economy is primarily government- and service-based. These two sectors consti- tute 49 percent of all non-agricultural employ- ment. Retail and wholesale trade make up another 22 percent, and of all jobs, manufac- turing employment constitutes only 12 per- cent. While it is correct that the city's economy is not manufacturing-based, between 1980 and 1988, manufacturing job growth was third be- hind services and trade. Most significantly, dur- ing the 1970s and into the early 1980s Austin experienced an annual manufacturing growth rate of 8.3 percent (compared with the nation's meager 1 to 2 percent). Between 1977 and 1982, manufacturing job growth increased 63 per- cent, second only to Colorado Springs which, with a much smaller base, increased by 86 per- cent.

Throughout the last twenty years, high-tech manufacturing has led Austin's economic ex- pansion, while the city's economy is based on government and services, its most dynamic component has recently been manufacturing. High-tech industries comprise approximately 71 percent of all manufacturing jobs. In the 1980s, the largest high-tech manufacturing em- ployers in the city added more than 20,000 jobs ("Texas in The 1980s" 1989). Compared with other cities noted for rapid high-tech growth between 1975 and 1985, Austin had the largest high-tech base (more than 40,000 jobs) and grew among the fastest.

With the addition of numerous branch plants in conjunction with the creation of locally owned firms, Austin has become one of the largest centers for the manufacture of semi- conductor devices outside of Silicon Valley. Al- most 15 percent of Motorola Inc.'s domestic semiconductor employment is now located in Austin. Advanced Micro Devices (AMD) locat- ed its largest production facility outside Silicon Valley in the city. Cypress Semiconductor has both a production and a design center within the metropolitan area. As high-tech industries were squeezed out of their original locations in the northeastern and western U.S., Austin became the recognized leader in attracting this new employment.

History of High-Tech Manufacturing in Austin

The origin of the Austin high-tech complex dates to the late 1930s when two University of Texas physics professors, Lucien LaCoste and Arnold Romberg, developed a gravity meter for measuring the depth of oil wells in offshore drilling operations (Susbauer 1972). The U.T. Physics Department was an early incubator of numerous small instrumentation firms. Pre- vious researchers have speculated that the in- dustry's connection with physics, as opposed to engineering, partially explains why instru- ments formed the base of Austin's nascent high- tech economy (Fig. 2).

Similar to a number of other high-tech lo- cations, defense-related research provided another early source of support for Austin's high-tech industry growth. The Tracor Cor- poration, Austin's only home-grown Fortune 500 company, began in 1954 as a consulting firm which merged with another local firm to be- come a defense-related high-tech manufac- turing corporation. Mapping new firm forma- tions in early Austin underscores the ties among companies thought to have spun off from Tra- cor (Fig. 3).

The base of the early Austin technology com- plex relied on small firms. Almost twenty years passed before a branch plant of a large national corporation located in the city (Susbauer 1972). The first major branch plant siting of a large national firm (IBM) occurred in 1968. IBM's jus- tification for locating a typewriter manufactur- ing plant in Austin was to facilitate access to the growing southwestern market. From the

Page 11: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 403

03C C coCu00~ 0

0 6

Cu oC jU) 0Cu

(-C V(0 c

-0) - ~~~~~~~~~~~~~Lt~~~~~ .~~0 a- u

Ci) o~~~~~D 0) ~~~O) ~~~~~~~~~E L.~~~~~~~~C Ei . CZ~~~~O U) CzuO CC coCC C: U) 0 to Cu

>)~~fl~~ Cu) co a) 0~ a) >,Lo co0 CnV C. 20 C: C

a =3 CZ w 4X)~0 CZuECC (D,-) CO:u0 < ,z co aC)~ ,-

CC: W(u (D >~ Ek E C

U) C.) CD D,~Cu C.) 0 CY) (D) CoO in 00~ 0 <

C:CM (n C.) Cu Cd CO Dc .4 g Cm 1 = a) Ea) a) C. C 0a) < 0 C13 - :3~~~~~~u ~ 0 ~ o Cn Cn a Y. :0) CY) > Cn)

0 :3~~, Q) uu u LO) - x 0 Z .cu0u' Cu ( C CC:u\

co co Cn gz Zo \I C u'D u mn (D cr =3 (D~~~~~~~~~I~~uO

Cu ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~0 co Cn C-

0D -. J

C.0 00

0 CA~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ t L'5~~~~~~~~

a)~~~~ Q, co - +-I~~~~~~~~Cu Cu

CCu C C o >)CnV

LIII O C Cu ,5 CC =

Cu>~~~~~~~~~3 0Cu Cu~~~~~~~~~~~~X a) co0

CuV ~~~~~~~(,-Cun u

(Ue1Jud0SLO Ld E z CuC> <

Page 12: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

404 Glasmeier

3M PC's Limited

Continuum (from 1969)

Carbomedics TRACOR BDM

(Associated bb L Consultants and Abbott Labs

Engineers -> Texas Research Houston Control Eaton AMD Lockheed

Associates) Instruments IBM Data Corp. Motorola Data General W.L. Gore

1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 ' 1985

Johnson Austron Texas Radian Espey Eagle Signal Neil MCC Controls Instruments Huston Tektronix Products Martin Decker

Burroughs

Tandem Cypress Semiconductors

Schlumberger

bold type indicates "Home-grown" companies ROLM Fisher Controls

Figure 3. Development of Tracor and its spin-outs, 1947-84.

beginning this plant was vertically integrated. Almost all material inputs were either made in the plant or received through intracorporate purchasing agreements. Austin's second major branch plant siting occurred a year later when Texas Instruments Corporation built a plant to manufacture office products and desktop com- puter equipment. Four years passed before a third national corporation, Motorola, opened its semiconductor wafer fabrication facility on the east side of the city. The Ed Bluestein plant is Motorola's most highly integrated fabrication location, employing device R&D, advanced en- gineering, and prototype capacity.

Between 1974 and 1984, Austin received another twelve branch plants of firms head- quartered in other high-technology complexes (Fig. 4). In the early 1980s, Motorola set up a second plant in Austin for its microprocessor group. During the same period, Lockheed es- tablished a major defense research and devel- opment facility. Other major Austin branch plant locations include Advanced Micro De- vices, which set up another wafer fabrication plant. In 1985 Tandem Corporation moved a design, engineering, and manufacturing plant to Austin. Finally, in 1986, the 3M Corporation opened a research facility, the first outside its Minneapolis corporate headquarters area.

By the early 1980s, Austin was perceived as a newly emerging high-tech center. The city

boasted a considerable stable of both manu- facturing branch plants and locally grown firms. In 1983, with the announcement that the Mi- croelectronics and Computer Corporation (MCC) had selected Austin as its headquarters, both the city and the state's aspirations as cen- ters of high-tech industry seemed assured. A multifirm consortium, MCC is conducting col- laborative research on computer, software, and manufacturing process design and develop- ments. Twelve firms working as a team created the research facility, the first to pursue com- mon research goals in combating international computer and microelectronics competition. Today seventeen firms participate in the con- sortium.

Austin Today

The heady days of successive branch plant announcements have passed. From 1985-90, Austin's electronics and computer industry ex- perienced a slump. Although occasional whis- pers of possible new plant sitings are still ov- erheard, the last announcement occurred in 1986. Growth moderated considerably during this period; in 1988 Austin added a meager 600 manufacturing jobs.

Yet the aura of the complex has been sus- tained. With the 1988 announcement that Aus-

Page 13: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 405

Espey-Huston

Tanga, Inc.

AMI Associated Texas Guerrero's DAC Consultants TRACOR Computer Photographic International

and (merged Corp. Group Engineers withI

Textran) Pinson Spenco Texas Key Associates, Systems Telesystems Concepts

Texas | Inc.Syste ns Texas Continuum Inc. College of Research Tracoustics Research Co.

Engineering Associates Austron Unitech Institute Weed 7 X | i Radian _ _ |SGE Inc. Instruments

, 4 / Z $~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~, -~D% a,o @NsD -Qasi &n,&> @>> 9 -,e 'IQ 'IQZ Se

Research Lab

1945

Figure 4. Major company relocation or founding in Austin, 1955-86. Source: Smilor et al. 1988.

tin was selected as the site for the Sematech consortium, the city once again became a newsmaker. The semiconductor industry's an- swer to declining competitiveness in manufac- turing, research at the Sematech facility is geared toward improving the nation's manufacturing capability while providing incentives and de- sign opportunities for firms that produce man- ufacturing equipment for the semiconductor industry.

The Early Ingredients

How did the Austin complex evolve? What determined its industrial composition? An- swers to these questions must necessarily consider the original base of instruments man- ufacturing. Instruments are tailored, often one- of-a-kind (sometimes batch- but almost never mass-produced) products with very specific markets. Products are knowledge-intensive and rely on a few specific parts usually made in- house. This type of manufacturing necessarily limited the formation of local linkages (Glas- meier 1988). Items that were off-the-shelf or could not be produced in-house were easily purchased either through distributors or fac- tory-direct, again further reducing the need for local manufacturing.

In the early days of LaCoste and Romberg's innovation, knowledge of material sources came in part from the U.T. Physics Department's pur-

chasing office. The gravity meter was the first of its kind. Thus it enjoyed high demand by oil exploration companies, and buyers came from all over the world to purchase it. Although the vast majority of product was sold directly from producer to final market, eventually LaCoste and Romberg did use sales representatives for distribution.

For a number of years (from the late 1930s to the early 1950s), additions to Austin's manufac- turing base consisted mainly of instrument manufacturers. Material inputs entered the complex via various channels. Connection with outside suppliers through traditional catalog sales and manufacturers' representatives made local manufacturing possible without the for- mation of an elaborate local parts and equip- ment fabricating capacity.

The economic mix of the University, small instrument firms, state government, and the military combined to support a modest elec- tronic component demand. Component needs were serviced by full-line wholesalers and not until the mid-1950s did a noninstrument man- ufacturing firm emerge. But at least five years earlier the city generated a local electronics wholesaler.

Verifying the model of early complex for- mation previously laid out, it is apparent that manufacturing is possible despite the absence of a detailed parts-producing complex. Fur- thermore, rather than vertical disintegration being the primary basis of complex expansion

Page 14: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

406 Glasmeier

and diversification, it is evident that firms op- erate autonomously with the assistance of in- formation flows in the form of catalog sales, manufacturers representatives, and merchant wholesalers which bring information into a na- scent complex and spread the word of local firm offerings outside the immediate market area.

The Spatial Evolution of Wholesaling: An Empirical Example

This section explores the validity of a mer- cantile model of regional formation through an analysis of the history of wholesale electronic development within the city of Austin. A re- statement of the theory suggests that whole- saling begins as a service providing generalized inputs, sustained through sales responding to a variety of markets. Over time, as the level of local materials demand increases and the com- plex evolves, wholesale specialization occurs. Eventually wholesalers from the closest ag- glomeration sell into the complex. Simulta- neously, in response to this encroachment from outside, original wholesalers broaden their product line and serve a more general clien- tele. Thus a pattern unfolds in which whole- saling begins with local firms, followed by regionally and eventually nationally headquar- tered wholesalers. In the long run, local mer- chant wholesalers may simply disappear as they prove unable to match the service capabilities of larger, nonlocal establishments.

The Evolution of Wholesaling in Austin

While the evolution of high-tech industry in Austin is relatively well recorded, there is no documented history of wholesaling in the city. Nonetheless, interviews with wholesalers who have operated in Austin since the early 1960s and analysis of phonebook entries dating back to the late 1940s and early 1950s provide an- ecdotal documentation to trace the evolution of this activity within the metropolitan area. Electronics wholesaling in Austin gradually evolved from the sale of electrical parts for the repair and maintenance of commercial and do- mestic equipment to trade in electronics goods.

Prior to the early 1940s, sales of parts for elec- trical goods were accomplished primarily through firms which performed sales and ser- vice. For example, Sears, Roebuck stocked spare parts inventory in their retail outlets as well as offering parts for home and commercial ap- pliance repair in their mail order catalogs.

The early formation of electronics wholesal- ing occurred in response to the need for radio and television repair parts. This type of general line distributor carried a small supply of a wide array of standard parts for hobbyists, tinkerers, and repairpersons. The first phone listing of an electronics wholesale firm dates to 1950. The company provided a broad range of general parts used for equipment sales, repair, and maintenance. By the mid-1950s, the city had five wholesalers (Table 1). One firm, White In- struments, wholesaled parts for other instru- ment manufacturers as well as for its own use. And in 1957 the Motorola Corporation opened an electronics parts and service office provid- ing equipment and parts for television and ra- dio electronics applications.

Prior to the 1960s electronics wholesaling was quite general, providing parts and accessories for equipment repair to a wide variety of in- dustries. For example, Wholesale Electronics, which opened in 1961, stocked small quantities of a broad variety of parts used in maintenance, repair, and testing for commercial equipment companies, the university, state government, computer firms, and the entertainment indus- try. In these early days local wholesalers kept pace with changes in industry by broadening their product lines rather than further special- izing in specific sub-industries.

By the early 1960s wholesale operations be- gan to specialize with separate operations for radio and television repair, electronic parts dis- tribution, and maintenance and repair opera- tions for commercial firms. Improvements in air conditioning, complex building systems, and the needs of the city, university and state gov- ernment resulted in a small proliferation of maintenance and repair distributors.

In the mid-1960s the ratio of manufacturers to wholesalers was about four to one. As the complex evolved, various wholesale submar- kets emerged and attracted wholesalers head- quartered outside the region (Table 2, Fig. 5). In 1963 the first nonlocal firms listed exchange numbers (the precursors to 1-800 toll-free numbers) to sell wholesale electronic parts. One

Page 15: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 407

Table 1. Number of Electronics Wholesalers, 1950-87

Nonlocal Nonlocal distrib- phone National

Total utors numbers firms 1950 1 1955 5 1960 6 1965 15 6 5 la

1971 13 6 6 3a 1975 19 13 10 1, 2a 1980 40 15 11 5 1985 52 20 10 9 1988 50 18 12 7

Source: Southwestern Bell, Austin telephone directory, se- lected years 1950-88.

aindicates national firm with toll-free number.

regional firm headquartered in Dallas listed two offices (one in Houston and one in Garland), while another listed a San Antonio address. Parts purchased from these nonlocal distributors were commonly shipped on Greyhound buses, an early form of overnight delivery. In 1964 Hall-Mark Electronics Corporation, a large na- tional distributor headquartered in Dallas, opened an operation in Austin (Table 3; Fig. 6).

Through the late 1960s, the city continued to add wholesalers, both nonlocal distributors and local firms with warehouses in Austin. There was also considerable merger activity as non- local wholesalers bought up Austin companies. As the large firms began to dominate wholesale trade, it became increasingly difficult for small- er, local firms to survive. About this time elec- tronics manufacturing firms headquartered outside the local area in Dallas, Houston, Cal- ifornia, and Oregon (e.g., Hewlett-Packard and Textronix) also began advertising in the yellow pages. Many out-of-town and out-of-state firms operated sales offices rather than manufactur- ing products in Austin. A second top-twenty national distributor also opened a warehouse in 1969.

Additional locally owned distributors formed through the mid-1970s. Nonetheless, the city's wholesale base was dominated by nonlocal firms, some of whom established local ware- houses while others simply listed toll-free num- bers in the telephone book. In the late 1970s, the city added two national chains, and local wholesalers once again comprised more than half of all distributors (16 of 27). By the end of

Table 2. Location of Out-of-town Distributors Listing Toll-free Numbers in

Austin, 1965-88

1965 1971 San Antonio Dallas (2) Houston (2) Piano, TX Dallas (2) Houston

Hauppauge, NY Philadelphia

1975 1980 Piano, TX Piano, TX Houston (3) Dallas (2) Hauppauge, NY Addison, TX Dallas (2) Shreveport, LA Van Nuys, CA Houston (2) Stafford, TX Dayton, OH Fort Worth Van Nuys, CA

Fort Worth New York

1985 1988 Piano, TX (3) Piano, TX (6) Brownsville, TX Dallas (2) Dallas Stafford, TX Channel View, TX San Antonio Dayton, OH Van Nuys, CA Van Nuys, CA Fort Worth Fort Worth (2)

Source: Southwestern Bell, Austin telephone directory, se- lected years 1965-1988.

the decade, seven national wholesalers had es- tablished either a sales office or a warehouse in Austin. Of 42 electronic wholesalers, more than half were single location operations.

The city's base of high-tech manufacturers and wholesalers grew in lock-step through the 1980s. The presence of wholesale firms head- quartered outside the city remains strong de- spite corporate and territorial reorganizations which have led to the closings of warehouses and the consolidation of stock in a few regional facilities.

An Empirical Example of Contemporary Distribution Relationships

Based on circumstantial evidence, I have sug- gested the importance of wholesalers in the early formation of the Austin complex. The

Page 16: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

408 Glasmeier

Table 3. Regional and National Wholesale Firms with Local Branches and Parts Producers with Sales Officesa

1964 1977 1981

Hall-mark Electronics Sterling Electronics Arrow Electronics Hdq., Dallas Hdq., Houston Hdq., Melville, NY

Kent Electronics 1969 1978 Hdq., Dallas

Newark Electronics Hamilton-Avnet Corp. Hdq., New York 1982

Hdq., Chicago Kierulff Electronics 1979 Owned by Ducommun

1974 Southwest Electronics Hdq., Cypress, CA Schweber Electronics Hdq., San Antonio

Inc. 1984-85 Owned by Lex Elec- 1980 a NEC Electronics

Hdqrondon Altair Co. Hdq. Londons Hdq., Richardson, TX 1988

1976 Pioneer Electronics Wyle Laboratories Hdq., Cleveland Hdq., Irvine, CA

Berg Electronics Div. a Fairchild Semi- Time Electronics of Dupont conductors Hdq., New York

Hdq., Delaware a GTE Micro Circuits Norvell Electronics Hdq., Dallas

Source: Southwestern Bell, Austin telephone directory, selected years 1964-88. a Sales offices of national and multinational manufacturers.

evolution of the complex has been traced by examining, over a concurrent period, changes in wholesaling and increases in high-tech man- ufacturing (Tables 1 and 4). The complex's initial requirements for electronic inputs were prob- ably satisfied by local wholesalers catering to a broad base of input needs. Over time this was followed by increasing wholesale specialization as the economy developed. Some wholesalers evolved in place, others established presence via long distance toll-free numbers. This last section explores the importance of wholesaling in the contemporary period. Based on a survey of firms, the importance of distributors in the contemporary functioning of the Austin high- tech economy is evident.

Generalizations can be made about the prob- ability of distributor usage based on industrial linkage theory, but results presented earlier in- dicated that the majority of firms, regardless of industry, used a mixed channel strategy to dis- tribute their products. Referring to Figure 1, it is also obvious that firms in the electronics in- dustry used outside distribution agents with great frequency. Examination of the distribu- tion trade literature and interviews with whole-

sale distributors further indicate that distribu- tor usage is rising. The advancing speed of product life cycles, heightening international competition, expanding geographic markets, and growing importance of small firms all im- prove the probability that firms will use dis- tributors in lieu of direct sales forces. Given that the concern here is with the nascent stages of complex formation, high levels of distributor usage would be expected (because local de- mand remains insufficient to warrant local pro- duction). Furthermore, it has been established by others that high-tech product markets are almost exclusively nonlocal. Therefore I antic- ipate that most manufactured goods are not destined for consumption within the complex. Accordingly, the following research results are an initial attempt to identify the contemporary importance of wholesalers in a newly forming complex. In more mature complexes, the fre- quency and scale of demand have presumably precipitated the development of local manu- facturing capacity of some material inputs. Nevertheless, anecdotal evidence from nation- al distributors indicates that even in mature complexes, distributor usage is high.

Page 17: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 409

Austin ouston

.'n A h n i San Ant 10 S taff.od

Figure 5. The locti f w ln Fiue .Th oato o uto-ow isrbuoslitngtllfe nmer nAustin,16-8

Sample Description

The sample of firms interviewed in this study was drawn from the 1986-87 State Survey of Manufacturers (published annually in the state since the late 1950s). In addition to this refer- ence, I cross-classified the original list of firms with those advertising in yellow pages of the municipal telephone directory. The use of the phone book improved the completeness of the

local sample by adding firms which had not participated in the state survey.

Sample Construction

This study focuses on high-tech products in the electronics, communications, aerospace, computers, instruments, and medical equip- ment industries. A total of 126 firms were iden- tified for interview. Seventeen were eliminated

Page 18: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

410 Glasmeier

1960 - 1969

Dallas

Austin

1970 -1979

NYo

Londri Dal as

Austin San Antonio Houston

1980 -1988

K~Melvl wYork

San Js

Cypr Irvine Richardson

Japan alls

Ausi

Figure 6. Regional and national firms that estab- lished local branches and parts producers that opened sales off ices.

because they did not manufacture a product with an SIC code corresponding to a 3-digit industry category listed in Table 5 and another six were excluded because their major product was a service. Of the manufacturing firms ex- cluded, more than half were chemical com- panies. The remainder comprised a broad group of general manufacturing inputs such as plastic parts, rubber molding, and miscellaneous metal parts.

Table 4. Number of High-Tech Manufacturers, 1950-87

Year Firms Year Firms 1950 1 1969 30 1952 2 1973 37 1954 1 1976 53 1956 2 1978 52 1958 5 1979 61 1960 10 1981 82 1962 1982 110 1964 1983 77 1966 21 1986 110

Source: This table combines the firms listed in the local telephone directory with those listed in the Texas Manufac- turers Guide, Bureau of Economic Research, University of Texas, Austin, 1986.

The universe of firms was reduced to 103. Of these, 62 companies completed face-to-face interviews. Of those which did not respond, 22 were unable to complete the questionnaire either because the appropriate respondent was unavailable, the information was proprietary, or there was some other extenuating circum- stance. Nine firms refused to be interviewed. Five companies were no longer in business, and an additional six were misclassified; they did not fall into the prespecified industry cate- gories.

Examination of the firms that did not answer the survey reveals that they were on average smaller than those that did respond.8 The di- vergence is explained by a higher response rate with the largest firms in the city. Overall, the study consisted of 68 percent small firms with fewer than 100 employees; these small firms constituted 77 percent of the total number of firms in the population. Based on a second measure, the percentage of firms locally owned versus branch plants of nonlocal corporations, there was no significant ownership bias in the firms that failed to respond.

General Characteristics of Firms in the Study

The group of firms studied is dominated by small, locally owned firms at least five years old. Companies are concentrated in three sectors: electronics, scientific instruments, and com- puters. Overall the firms are R&D intensive; 76 percent indicated they spent 3 percent or more of after-sales revenues on research. Austin firms also employ a significant number of technical

Page 19: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 411

Table 5. Industrial Classification of Firms Interviewed and the General Population (%)

Sample Population SIC28 5 4 SIC 35 13 9 SIC 36 39 53 SIC 37 1 1.6 SIC 38 32 31

Source: Texas Manufacturers Guide, Bureau of Economic Research, University of Texas, Austin, TX, 1986.

employees. Sixty-four percent indicated that 10 percent or more of their workforce was comprised of engineers and technicians.

As found in studies of other high-tech in- dustry concentrations, the market for Austin firms' goods is decidedly nonlocal (Oakey 1984; Goldstein and Malizia 1985; Hagey and Malecki 1986; Gordon et al. 1988; Porterfield 1988). For- ty percent indicated their markets were locat- ed entirely outside the local area. Another 45 percent sold less than 15 percent of their out- put to local firms.

As part of this study I questioned the origins of different types of inputs used by local firms. Borrowing and modifying Hagey and Malecki's research design, I grouped inputs into five cat- egories: unfinished materials (such as sheet steel, aluminum, glass); low-tech inputs which were either off-the-shelf or were routinely (without special processing) produced (such as greases, boxes, batteries); high-tech inputs (goods in short supply which required special process- ing, were especially pure, or required sophis- ticated production technology, such as quartz crystals, precision lenses, ASICs-application specific integrated circuits); high-tech services (software, engineering, consulting, etc.); and production equipment (lathes, bonders, mill- ing machines). Each respondent was prompted about distinctions between high and low-tech inputs and each gave an example of what con- stituted high and low-tech inputs to his/her firm. While not clear-cut in every instance, the majority of firms agreed that the distinction was important in their material input purchasing decisions.

As part of the study, local linkage purchases were identified (Table 6). In general, firms pur- chased little in the way of material inputs from local manufacturers. The majority of firms (56 percent) satisfied less than 20 percent of their needs through purchases from firms manufac- turing high-tech inputs locally. Low-tech in-

Table 6. Percentage of Inputs Purchased from Local Manufacturing Firms

Percent- age Satisfied

Input of firms locally Raw materials 70 <20 High-tech inputs 56 <20 Low-tech inputs 50 <20 High-tech services 56 <20 Production equipment 67 <20

puts were bought with slightly higher frequen- cy (50 percent of local firms purchased less than 20 percent of their low-tech inputs from local manufacturers). This may reflect the ubiquitous nature of such goods, their tendency to be standardized, and their availability from a va- riety of vendors. Only 44 percent purchased substantial amounts of high-tech services such as computer programming and management consulting locally, and 67 percent purchased 20 percent or less of their production equip- ment from local manufacturers.

These results are quite similar to a study of high-tech manufacturing conducted in Florida (Hagey and Malecki 1986). Low levels of link- ages reveal there are alternative solutions for acquiring inputs. As markets become more ex- tensive and corporations develop increasingly complex divisions of labor, market intermedi- aries gain importance. Beyond acquisition of inputs and reduction of transaction costs, firms use them for strategic reasons. Thus pertinent considerations include: how do distributors operate in a local economy? what types of in- puts do they provide? and how does knowl- edge of distribution theory enhance our un- derstanding of interfirm transactions?

Distributor Use for Material Input Acquisitions

To determine and explore their uses of dis- tributors, firms were asked whether and for what inputs they used distribution channels. Specifically we questioned whether they pur- chased their inputs from a distributor or by ordering factory-direct (defined as transactions with the original equipment manufacturer as opposed to with a market intermediary). As it was difficult to standardize for the year of pur- chase, survey questions pertaining to the ac- quisition of capital equipment were eliminated.

Page 20: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

412 Glasmeier

Table 7. Acquisition of High-Tech Inputs

Number Distributor 35 Factory direct 9 Total 44

By location of headquarters Nonlocal Local Total

Distributor 7 (63.6%) 28 (84.8%) 35 Factory direct 4 (36.4%) 5 (15.2%) 9

Column 11 33 44 Chi-Square 2.28148 Significance 0.1309

By size of firm Small Large

(1-100) (101+) Total Distributor 24 (80.0%) 11 (78.6%) 35 Factory direct 6 (20.0%) 3 (21.4%) 9

Column 30 14 44 Chi-Square 0.01197 Significance 0.9129

By age of firm in years 1-5 6-20 21-33 Total

Distrib- utor 11 (84.6%) 17 (70.8%) 7 (100.0%) 35

Factory- direct 2 (15.4%) 7 (29.2%) 9 Column 13 24 7 44 Chi-Square 3.12495 Significance 0.2096

Office supplies and equipment are purchased much more regularly, so we substituted ques- tions about these inputs. In general, firms used distributors for unfinished materials, high-tech inputs, office supplies, and (to a lesser extent) low-tech inputs.

The majority of firms purchasing unfinished materials used distributors (76 percent). There was no significant difference based on firm size or age, but a larger portion of locally head- quartered and nonsubsidiary firms used dis- tributors than did their nonlocal brethren.

Although the percentages differed signifi- cantly, the majority of firms, regardless of char- acteristics such as size, age, or location, used distributors to secure both high and low-tech inputs (80 and 64 percent respectively). Dis- tributors were used to purchase high and low- tech inputs for both small and large firms (Tables 7 and 8). Although both locally and non- locally headquartered firms purchased from distributors, the locally headquartered com- panies were more likely to use distributors for

Table 8. Acquisition of Low-Tech Inputs

Number Distributor 23 Factory direct 13 Total 36

By location of headquarters Nonlocal Local Total

Distributor 4 (57.1%) 19 (65.5%) 23 Factory direct 3 (42.9%) 10 (34.5%) 13

Column 7 29 36 Chi-Square 0.17141 Significance 0.6789

By size of firm Small Large

(1-100) (101+) Total Distributor 16 (72.7%) 7 (50.0%) 23 Factory direct 6 (27.3%) 7 (50.0%) 13

Column 22 14 36 Chi-Square 0.91548 Significance 0.1664

By age of firm in years 1-5 6-20 21-33 Total

Distrib- utor 6 (75.00%) 12 (57.10%) 5 (71.40%) 23

Factory direct 2 (25.0%) 9 (42.9%) 2 (28.6%) 13 Column 8 21 7 36 Chi-Square 1.01481 Significance 0.6021

both types of inputs than their nonlocal coun- terparts. Also there was a suggestion of some discrepancy accountable for by age (older and younger firms used distributors more often). These results, however, were not statistically significant.

I also examined the use of distributors for the purchase of high-tech versus low-tech inputs (regardless of firm characteristics). Cross tabu- lation of this relationship indicates there is a statistically significant difference between firm use of distributors for each type. This confirms an earlier implied hypothesis that firms will purchase low-tech goods locally and factory- direct with greater frequency than they do high- tech inputs. We also tested for differences in the percentage of high and low-tech goods manufactured locally. As anticipated given the nonlocal nature of high-tech markets, there was a statistically significant difference between the percentages of high and low-tech goods man- ufactured locally. Respondents indicated that the low-tech goods they purchased were man-

Page 21: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 413

ufactured locally more often than were high- tech inputs.

Certain inputs, such as office supplies and equipment, were overwhelmingly acquired through distributors (more than 95 percent). This finding may reflect that office supplies consist of hundreds of discrete but standard items (pens, pencils, paper) bought in relatively small lots. Given the broad range of products, no single producer is likely to manufacture them all. Moreover, the vast number of markets (often small in size) inhibit the efficient use of strictly factory-direct sales. Instead producers rely on distributors to reach wide-ranging markets. In contrast, office equipment is produced by rel- atively few large firms. Factory-direct pur- chases are no doubt made by large corpora- tions with national accounts, but the broad range of this market also necessitates the use of distributors.

These results contrast with general findings about the spatial location of industrial linkages. Previous studies verifying the importance of local proximity in the purchase of high-tech inputs may erroneously equate local purchase via distributors with local production. Clearly these results suggest greater precision is nec- essary to establish distinctions between goods produced locally and those purchased through intermediaries.

I originally anticipated that the use of dis- tributors would vary based on the type of prod- uct and the age, ownership, and size of estab- lishment. But firms used distributors mostly regardless of these classifying characteristics. Further examination of the data to determine whether increases in local purchases resulted in more factory-direct purchasing indicated that regardless of the share of purchases made lo- cally, firms used distributors for the acquisition of inputs.

A shortcoming of this analysis is that we did not determine the dollar value of all inputs pur- chased through distributors. While a great vol- ume of material may be purchased through these intermediaries, it is still possible that crit- ical (high-value) inputs are purchased factory- direct. Respondents were asked what per- centage of their input purchases consisted of goods manufactured locally. For the residual input, we asked what percentage was pur- chased factory-direct and what percentage was acquired through a distributor. On the basis of the original study, we cannot definitively in-

dicate the quantitative importance of distrib- utor linkages.

A follow-up study currently underway will determine what percentage of inputs (by value) are purchased through distributors. Quantita- tive information about the percentages of in- puts purchased locally versus factory-direct or through distributors is being collected. In this second study, additional distinctions are being made concerning the types of inputs pur- chased through distributors and the use of dis- tributors with stocking locations in Austin. Pre- liminary results support the assertions of the implied importance of distributors examined here. As this second study is incomplete, I can- not make quantitative generalizations about the results, nor can I discern purchases made be- tween local and nonlocal distributors. None- theless, survey results are important first indi- cators of the use of distributors. Future findings will help substantiate the importance of this relationship in industrial complex formation.

Conclusions The evolution of wholesaling in central Texas

illustrates the importance of interregional trade in new industrial complex formation. This re- lationship should not be surprising. Results only confirm the suggestions of Pred, Vance, and Meyer that complex formation rarely results solely from endogenous forces and is instead importantly facilitated by trade agents origi- nating outside a region. Because the existing literature is dominated by the vertically inte- grated firm presumed to internalize distribu- tion functions (obviating the importance of ex- ternal distribution channels), trade agents have gone largely unnoticed. But the development of new industries, expansion of sectoral and geographic markets, and the growing impor- tance of entrepreneurial firms all establish the need to consider distribution channel structure when analyzing industrial linkage formation.

Of equal importance is the geographic ex- pansion of the wholesale function. These re- sults validate insights found in both Vance's and Meyer's early treatments of wholesaling and regional development. In particular, the evo- lution of wholesaling in Austin closely follows Vance's original notion of "internalization." As the city's economic base specialized more and more in high-tech manufacturing, Austin be-

Page 22: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

414 Glasmeier

came a profitable location for national whole- salers. Eventually, by offering superior service and variety, national and regional wholesale firms came to dominate the area's high-tech wholesale market. Local firms retreated to very general and mostly nontechnical product lines.

This study also confirms Meyer's original hy- pothesis about the progression of wholesaling developing across regions. (Initially a whole- saler's reach stretches from an agglomeration to a frontier location, in this case from San An- tonio to Austin). His model did not adequately address the power of national firms and their ability to penetrate a frontier location, eroding any geographic advantage associated with ini- tial proximity.

A mixed channel strategy is the dominant sales structure of manufacturing firms. Few en- joy the luxury of dealing directly with original equipment manufacturers (OEMs). Both time and place constraints often prohibit factory- direct transactions. While we might correctly assume that large incorporated firms pursue a rational material acquisition strategy, purchas- ing policies of small firms and newly established enterprises often border on chaos and exhibit limited premeditation. More importantly, small firm order size is simply too small and therefore costly for OEMs to service. Consequently there is no alternative to using distributors.

A growing body of current research focuses on production-based explanations for indus- trial complex development. Examination of wholesale distributors questions this singular explanation of complex formation and linkage establishment. As Vance and Meyer noted, the growth of regions is governed by a process of internalization. Primary stages of development are facilitated by firms that trade-in from the outside. After some point, local consumption may precipitate local production for goods which require tailoring or are standard and therefore face far-reaching local demand. Scott rightly identifies activities such as mold making, metal fabricating, etc. as following the pattern (1988). This analysis does not deny the impor- tance of existing theoretical insight. Rather I simply state that the evolution of such activity alone does not make an industrial complex. In particular, time and place constraints often preclude a local production-based solution to even the most basic material acquisition prob- lem. The interplay of demand for goods man- ufactured outside and those traded-in facili-

tates the demand for local production of standardized goods. The transactions cannot be viewed in isolation. They must be consid- ered jointly to explain the diversity of produc- tion experiences found in different locations.

The persistent importance of wholesalers in the local economy simply underscores the point that firms use mixed channels to distribute their goods and by implication buy material inputs from both internal and external agents. Future linkage studies must therefore go beyond ask- ing whether a good is purchased locally. As this analysis has attempted to demonstrate, the an- swer to this question is just as likely to lead to the warehouse of a distributor as to the loading dock of a manufacturer. We must acknowledge that new production mandates call for increas- ing use of distributors (as firms attempt to im- plement JIT inventory practices).

It is also critical to understand the choices of distribution channels selected by firms over the lives of both the product and the firm. We must delve further into the workings of firms to dis- cover how they select and then carry out their marketing strategies. Here I have suggested dis- tributors' importance in the early formation of a complex. I have stressed the fact that as some form of industrialization takes hold in a local economy, wholesalers are attracted to service new specialized needs. Still unexplored is the role of distributors in the evolution and even- tual integration of complexes over time. For example, are wholesalers only important in the absence of prior industrialization? Anecdotal evidence from Pittsburgh, a former industrial city which aspires to become a high-tech cen- ter, suggests initial aspirations are not being met with the formation of local manufacturing link- ages. Instead the city is the recipient of sales offices and wholesale distributors of high-tech manufactured goods. On the basis of the results reported here, the first stages of industrial de- velopment may quite regularly consist only of trading agents who would eventually be ac- companied by local production as the complex takes root. Thus there is a need to examine the transformation of complexes as they grow, change and mature, and intraregional produc- tion relations unfold.

New industrial complex formation is expe- dited by the activities of market intermediaries. While it might be appropriate to view major complexes and longstanding agglomerations as self-contained systems, some of their suste-

Page 23: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 415

nance is clearly determined by firms' abilities to reach out to new economic centers. Through examination of the complex interplay between existing and newly forming agglomerations, we can enhance our understanding of the evolu- tion of the space economy.

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank the University Pol- icy and Research Institutes of the University of Texas at Austin for support of this research. Students in the regional research seminar of the Graduate Program of Community and Regional Planning participated in the design, development, and implementation of the survey. Their assistance was essential to the comple- tion of this project. The author wishes to thank Amy K. Teran for substantive discussions and editorial as- sistance during the various phases of the manuscript's life. The author would also like to thank the reviewers who provided invaluable criticism of earlier drafts, and whose comments greatly strengthened the the- oretical argument. Finally, special thanks to Bennett Harrison, Flavia Martinelli, Erica Schoenberger, Mor- gan Thomas, William Beyers, Mary Beth Pudup, and Barney Warf for comments on earlier versions of this paper. As always, any and all omissions are attribut- able to the author.

Notes

1. But as Hoare (1985) notes, these historic studies (i.e., Wise's examination of the Birmingham gun and jewelry industries) were based only on visual observation, not surveys of firms' material input requirements or markets. When scholars have studied quintessential industrial quarters (e.g., London), they have found that less than half of all firms had any local linkages whatsoever.

2. Wholesale establishments increased 43 percent between 1972 and 1982, the last year for which data were collected by the U.S. Department of Commerce. Over the same time, the percentage of manufacturing declined nationally.

3. For example, David Harvey notes the historic im- portance of merchants in the spatial organization of production in Paris (1985). Intrametropolitan clusters of households producing highly divisible goods, such as silk flowers, came together in space for the convenience of the merchant. Harvey ar- gues that the merchant created the division of labor and producers clustered near merchants to gain access to markets and material inputs.

4. By analogy, the same can be said about local pro- duction; as long as local consumption is less than sufficient to support local production, then ex- change with producers from outside is efficient.

5. The degree of specialization may be determined by demand at the origin of the wholesaler and not at the frontier location.

6. The extent that a firm relies on internal manufac- turing versus off-the-shelf parts buying depends fundamentally on product type. If the product is an assembly of off-the-shelf components such as a computer, then a firm will buy the parts needed and assemble the good. But if the product is highly tailored for a specific end-user and requires the manufacture of unique parts, then the firm is likely to fabricate the inputs within the firm.

7. Developing a sample framework for conducting a local survey of firms is a difficult endeavor. No single source of data provides a comprehensive list. Unlike the federal government, which draws names and addresses from the Internal Revenue Service and Social Security systems, except for tax purposes, no local or state government organi- zation has power to enforce a firm's response to inquiries. Thus, there is no effective mechanism for developing a complete directory of firms. Often local and state guidebooks are based on imprecise collection methods which resort to such sources as word-of-mouth or new firm announcements in the media.

The use of the phone book (while adding to the potential capture rate of interview subjects) has additional limitations. Firms pay a fee for listing their businesses in the telephone directory yellow pages. This means that some small establishments that may not be able to afford the costs of adver- tising or that may not have a local market either cannot or will not purchase a directory listing. Also firms classify themselves. Advertisers decide the industrial categories within which they wish to be listed. Therefore some companies could be er- roneously classified as manufacturers when they are in fact manufacturers' representatives, distrib- utors, or consultants. As partial compensation for this potential bias, firms which do advertise in the phonebook are more likely to sell their goods lo- cally or at least want to have a visible local pres- ence.

Another problem with local data sources is dif- ficulty in maintaining the currency of firm lists. Updating the database when firms are no longer in business, have changed their form of business, or have merged is particularly problematic, es- pecially when trying to establish a measure of the universe of firms.

8. Contact the author for further details about the sample characteristics.

References

Abratt, R. 1986. Industrial buying in high tech mar- kets. Industrial Marketing Management 15:293-98.

Bertrand, K. 1986. Changing channels in the mi- crocomputer market. Business Marketing Sep- tember: 88-94.

Bowersox, D.; Smykay, E.; and LaLonde, B. 1968. Physical distribution management. London: Mac- millan.

Butaney, G., and Wortzel, L. 1988. Distributor

Page 24: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

416 Glasmeier

power versus manufacturer power. The custom- er role. Journal of Marketing 52:52-63.

Chandler, A. 1962. Strategy and structure: Chapters in the history of the industrial enterprise. Cam- bridge, MA: M.I.T. Press.

1966. The visible hand: The managerial rev- olution in American business. Cambridge, MA: M.I.T. Press.

Collins, L., and Walker, D., eds. 1974. Locational dynamics of manufacturing activity. London: Wi- ley.

Cox, R. 1965. Distribution in a high-level economy. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

Crespedes, F. 1988a. Channel management is gen- eral management. California Management Review 31:1.

1988b. Control vs. resources in channel de- sign: Distribution differences in one industry. In- dustrial Marketing Management 17:215-27.

Davis, 1. 1989. Western U.S. Regional sales man- ager, Hamilton Avnet. Personal interview, April.

Does the country really need another stocking branch? 1985. Purchasing 68:25-29.

Drucker, P. 1962. The economy's dark continent. Fortune 103:265-70.

Fredriksson, C., and Lindmark, L. 1979. From firms to systems of firms: A study of inter-regional de- pendence in a dynamic system. In Spatial analysis, industry and the industrial environment, 1-indus- trial systems, ed. F. E. I. Hamilton and G. R. Linge, pp. 155-86. Chichester, UK: Wiley.

Giunipero, L., and O'Neal, C. 1987. Obstacles to )IT procurement. Industrial Marketing Manage- ment 16:1-7.

Glasmeier, A. 1988. Factors governing the devel- opment of high tech industry agglomerations: A tale of three cities. Regional Studies 22:4, 287- 301.

1989. The missing link: The role of merchant wholesalers in regional development. No. 1, Com- munity and Regional Planning Working Paper Series, University of Texas at Austin.

Goldstein, H., and Malizia, E. 1985. Microelec- tronics and economic development in North Carolina. In High hopes for high tech: Microelec- tronics policy in North Carolina, ed. Dale Whit- tington, pp. 255-56. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press.

Gordon, R.; Dilts, A; and Kimball, L. 1988. High technology innovation and the global milieu: Small and medium sized enterprises in Silicon Valley. Pa- per prepared for the Colloque GREMI II, Ascona, Switzerland, April 14-17.

Graves, P. 1989. Sales Manager, Pioneer Electron- ics, personal interview, March.

Hagey, M., and Malecki, E. 1986. Linkages in high tech industry: A Florida case study. Environment and Planning A 18:1477-98.

Harvey, D. 1985. Consciousness and the urban ex-

perience: Studies in the history and theory of cap- italist urbanization. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Hoare, A. 1985. Industrial linkage studies. In Pro- gress in Industrial Geography, ed. Michael Pa- cione, pp. 40-80. London: Croom Helm.

Hoover, E. 1948. The location of economic activity. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Industry markets through dual channels says Mc- Graw-Hill Study. 1985. Industrial Distribution, April, 15.

Johnston, R., and Lawrence, P. 1988. Beyond ver- tical integration-the rise of the value-adding partnership. Harvard Business Review, July-Au- gust, 94-101.

Jorde, T., and Teece, D. 1989. Competition and cooperation: Striking the right balance. California Management Review 31:3.

Kastiel, D. 1987. Electronic communications avoid short circuits to distributors. Business Marketing, July, 70-75.

Kerr, 1. 1987. Seoul sourcing: Nationals demur as regionals jump in. Electronic Business, June 1, 30- 32.

Lamont, L. 1972. The role of marketing in technical entrepreneurship. In Technical entrepreneurship: A symposium, pp. 150-65. Milwaukee, WI: Cen- ter for Venture Management.

Lord, D. 1984. Shifts in the wholesale trade status of U.S. metropolitan areas. The Professional Geog- rapher 36:51-63.

Magrath, A., and Hardy, K. 1987. Avoiding the pitfalls in managing distribution channels. Busi- ness Horizons, September-October, 29-33.

Markusen, A.; Hall, P.; Campbell, S.; and Detrick, S. 1990. The rise of the American gunbelt. New York: Oxford University Press, forthcoming.

Marshall, A. 1898. Elements of the economics of industry. London: Macmillan.

Meyer, D. 1980. A dynamic model of integration of frontier urban places into the United States system of cities. Economic Geography 56:120-40.

Muller, E. 1977. Regional urbanization and the se- lective growth of towns in North American re- gions. Journal of Historical Geography 3:21-39.

Norton, R., and Rees, 1. 1979. The product cycle and the spatial decentralization of American manufacturing. Regional Studies 13:141-51.

Oakey, R. 1984. High technology small firms: Re- gional development in Britain and the United States. New York: St. Martins Press.

Porter, G., and Livesay, C. 1971. Merchants and manufacturers: Studies of changing structuring of nineteenth-century marketing. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Porterfield, S. 1988. Potentially exportable services in regional economic development: An empirical comparison of survey data from manufacturing and service-producing firms. Dissertation, Depart-

Page 25: The Role of Merchant Wholesalers in Industrial Agglomeration … · 2016-01-12 · channels. Because of the tenuous nature of new complexes and limited local demand, indirect channels

Merchant Wholesalers 417

ment of Agricultural Economics, University of Wisconsin, Madison.

Pred, A. 1977. City systems in advanced economies. New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Rayner, B. 1986. National strategies for regional distributors. Electronic Business, October 15, 75- 77.

Rogers, E., and Larsen, 1. 1984. Silicon Valley fever. New York: Basic Books.

Russell, 1. 1985. Why not walk down to your dis- tributor's office? ... just down the hall. Pur- chasing, March 14, 29-37.

Saxenian, A. 1985. The genesis of silicon valley. In Silicon Landscapes, ed. Peter Hall and Ann Mar- kusen, pp. 20-35. Boston: Allen and Unwin.

Scott, A., and Storper, M. 1987. High technology industry and regional development: A theoret- ical critique and reconstruction. International So- cial Science Journal 112:215-32.

1988. Metropolis: From the division of labor to urban form. Berkeley: University of California Press.

Smilor, R.; Kozmetsky, G.; and Gibson, D. 1988. The Austin/San Antonio corridor: The dynamics of a developing technopolis. In Creating the tech- nopolis: Linking technology, commercialization and economic development, pp. 145-84. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

Socolovsky, A. 1985. JIT jitters. Electronic business. State survey of manufacturers. Various years. Uni-

versity of Texas at Austin, Austin TX.

Stohr, W. 1986. Territorial innovation complexes. In Milieux innovateurs en Europe, ed. Philippe Ay- dalot, pp. 29-56. Paris: GREMI.

Storper, M., and Walker, R. 1989. The capitalist imperative: Territory, technology, and industrial growth. New York: Basil Blackwell.

Susbauer, 1. 1972. The technical entrepreneurship process in Austin, Texas. In Technical entrepre- neurship: A symposium, pp. 28-47. Milwaukee, WI: Center for Venture Management.

Temin, T. 1985. Distributors more cautious now about semicustom ICs. Purchasing, March 14:39- 41.

Texas in the 1980s. Austin American-Statesman, De- cember 25, 1989.

U.S. Department of Commerce. 1982. Economic census. Washington: Government Printing Of- fice.

. 1986. State and metropolitan data book. Washington: Government Printing Office.

Vance, 1. 1970. The merchant's world: The geography of wholesaling. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

Weber, A. 1929. Theory of the location of industries, transi. Carl Loachim Friedrich. Chicago: Univer- sity of Chicago.

Williamson, 0. 1981a. The economics of organi- zation: The transactions cost approach. American Journal of Sociology 87:548-77.

. 1981b. The modern corporation: Origins, evolution, attributes. Journal of Economic Litera- ture 19:1537-68.