46
The Solow Growth Model with Human Capital Lecture 6

The Solow Growth Model with Human Capital · 2017. 2. 15. · Descendents of Solow Model • There are number of descendents of the Solow model. (Chap. 3 ) • A key descendent is

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • The Solow Growth Model with

    Human Capital

    Lecture 6

  • Descendents of Solow Model

    • There are number of descendents of

    the Solow model. (Chap. 3 )

    • A key descendent is that the extention

    incorporates human capital.

    • Mankiw, G., Romer, D. And Weil, D.

    (1992) ‘A Contribution to the Empirics

    of Economic Growth’.

    • Included human capital

  • Including human capital

    • They recognised that labour in different

    economies may possess different levels of

    education and different skills.

    • Extending the Solow model to include

    human capital or skilled labour is relatively

    straightforward.

    • New production funtion

  • New production funtion

    • Constant returns to scale

    • Y = Ka (AH)1-a (1)

    Where

    Y is Output,

    K Physical capital

    A is Labour augmenting technology

    H ; Skilled labour

  • Details....

    • A represents labour augmenting technology that

    grows exogenously at rate g.

    • Individuals in this economy accumulate human

    capital by spending time learning new skills

    instead of working.

    • Let U denote the fraction of an individual’s time

    spent learning skills, and let L denote the total

    amount of (row) labour used in production in the

    economy.

  • Total amount of labour in the

    economy

    • The total amount of (row)labour input in

    the economy is given by;

    • L = (1- U ) P

    • Where L is row labour, U is the fraction of

    an individual’s time spent learning skills, P

    is population.

    • Make the following functional assumption

    about skilled labour generation

  • Skilled labour

    • We assume unskilled labour learnings skills for

    time U generates skilled labour H according to:

    • H = euψ L (2)

    • Where ψ positive constant.

    • Notice that if U = 0, then H = L, all labour is

    unskilled.

    • By increasing U, a unit of unskilled labour

    increases the effective units of skilled labour H.

    To see how;

  • Effect of increase of U on H• To see by how much, take logs and derivatives

    of equation (2) w.r.t. U.;

    • (dlog H)/((dU) = Ψ (3)

    • Exp. : effect of time spent on learning on wages.

    • This equation states that a small increase in U increases H by the percentage Ψ (or more correctly, (Ψ X 100)

    • The fact that the effects are proportional is driven by the somewhat odd presence of the exponential e in the question.

    • This formulation is intended to match a large literature in labour economics that finds that an additional year of schooling increases the wages earned by an individual by something like 10%.

  • Physical capital

    • Physical capital is accumulated by investing

    some output instead of consuming it:

    • ΔK = sY –δK (4)

    • Where Sk is the investment rate of physical

    capital and δ is the constant depreciation rate.

    • We solve this model using the same techniques

    employed earlier: Intensive form

  • Intensive form

    • Let lower case letters denote variables divided by the stock of unskilled labour, L, and rewrite the production function in terms of output per worker

    • y = ka (Ah)1-a (5)

    • Notice that h = euψ.

    • How do agents decide how much time to spend accumulating skills instead of working?

    • Just as we assume that individuals save and invest a constant fraction of their income, we will assume that U is constant and given exogenously.

  • Constant h

    • The fact that h is constant means that the production function in equation (5) is very similar to that used earlier in the Solow model.

    • In particular along a balanced growth paths, y and k will grow at the constant rate g, the rate of technological progress.

    • As in the earlier Solow model, the model is solved by considering ‘state variables’ that are constant along a balanced growth path. There, recall that the state variables were terms such as y/A . Here, since h is constant, we can define the state variables by dividing by Ah.

    • Denoting these state variables with a tilde, equation (5) implies that

    • ỹ =ќa which is same as the earlier prod. function

  • New capital accumulation eq.

    • Thus the capital accumulation equation

    can be written in terms of the state

    variables as;

    • Δќ = s ỹ - (n+g+δ) ќ (7)

    • Adding human capital does not change the

    basics of the model.

  • The new steady state values

    • The steady state values of ќ and ỹ are

    found by setting Δќ = 0, which yields;

    • (ќ) / (ỹ) = (s) / (n+g+ δ)

    • Substituting this condition into the

    production function in equation (6) we find

    the steady-state values of the output-

    technology ratio ỹ:

    • ỹ* = ((s)/(n+g+ δ))a/1-a

  • Why some countries are rich in

    extended Solow model

    • Rewriting this in terms of output per worker, we

    get;

    • ỹ*(t) = ((s)/(n+g+ δ))a/1-a h A(t) (8)

    • Where we have explicitly included t to remind us

    which variables are grıwing over time.

    • This last equation summarizes the explanation

    provided by the extended Solow model for why

    some countries are rich and the others are poor.

  • Countries are rich because...

    • They have high investment rates in physical capital, spend a large fraction of time accumulating skills (h = euψ), have low population growth rates, and have high levels of technology.

    • Furthermore, in the steady state, per capita output grows at the same rate of technological progress, g, just as in the original Solow model.

  • How well does this model perform

    empirically..

    • How well does this model perform

    empirically in terms of explaining why

    some countries are richer than others?

    • Solow model with human capital has

    strong empirical support. İ.e. Countries

    that invest a large fraction of their

    resources in physical capital and in the

    accumulation of skills are rich.

  • THE ECONOMICS OF IDEAS

    Lecture 6

  • Capital based or otherwise...

    • The neoclassical models we have studied

    so far are in many ways capital based

    theories of economic growth.

    • These theories focus on modeling the

    accumulation of physical and human

    capital.

    • In another sence, however, the theories

    emphasized the importance of technology.

  • Technology or otherwise...

    • The models do not generate economic growth in the absence of technological progress and productivity differences help to explain why some countries are rich and others are poor.

    • In this way, neoclassical growth theory highlights its own shortcomings, although technology is a central component of neoclassical theory, it is left unmodeled.

    • Technological improvements arrive exogenously at a constant rate, g, and differences in technology across economies are unexplained. In this lecture we will explore the broad issues associated with creating an economic model of technology and technological improvement.

  • What is technology?

    • In the economics of growth and development, the term technology has a very specific meaning.

    • Technology; is the way inputs to the production process are transformed in to output.

    • For example, if we have a general production function Y = F(K,L) , then the technology of production is given by the function F(.); this production function explains how inputs are transformed into output.

  • Cobb-Douglas prod. technology

    • Cobb-Douglas production function of

    earlier discussions,

    • Y = Ka (AL)1-a

    • A is a index of technology.

  • Ideas and technology

    • Ideas improve the technology of production.

    • A new idea allows a given bundle of inputs to produce more or better output.

    • Example from Romer (1990); Early age humans used iron oxide as a pigment to create drawings on the walls of caves. Now we ‘paint’ iron oxide onto magnetic tape to produce VCR recordings.

  • Ideas• The ‘idea’ behind the VCR allows us to use a

    given bundle of inputs to produce output that generates a higher level of utility.

    • In the context of the production function above, a new idea generates an increase in the technology index, A.

    • Examples of ideas and technological improvements: In 1800,light was provided by candles and oil lamps, whereas today we have very efficient fluorescent bulbs.

    • Nordhous (1994) has calculated that the quality adjusted price of light has fallen by a factor of 4000 since the year 1800.

  • Ideas

    • Ideas are by no means limited to fields of

    engineering.

    • The multiplex theatre and diet_soft drinks are

    innovations that allowed firms to combine inputs

    in new ways that consumers, according to

    revealed preference, have found very valuable.

    • The assembly lines and mass production

    techniques that allowed car production company

    to produce in every 24 minutes

  • The Economics of Ideas

    • Beginning in the mid-1980’s, paul Romer

    formalized the relationship between the

    economics of ideas and economic growth.

    • This relationship can be thought of in the

    following way;

    Ideas Nonrivalry Increasing

    Returns

    Imperfect

    Competition

  • Ideas are nonrivalry because

    • Once idea is invented, it can be used by one person or by one thousand people at no additional cost.

    • Nonrivalry implies the presence of increasing returns to scale.

    • To model these increasing returns in a competitive environment with international research necessarily requires imperfect competition.

  • Ideas as an economic good

    • A crucial observation emphasized by Romer(1990) is that ideas are very different from most other economic goods.

    • Most goods, such as DVD players or lawyer services are rivalrous; That is, my use of a DVD player excludes your use of the same DVD player, or my seing a particular lawyer today from 1:00 pm to 2:00 pm precludes your seing the same attorney at the same time.

    • Most economic goods share this property: the use of the good by one person precludes its use by another.

  • Nonrivalrous Ideas

    • In contrast, ideas are nonrivalrous.

    • The fact that Toyoto takes advantage of

    just-in-time inventory methods does not

    preclude GM from taking advantage of the

    same technique.

    • Once an idea has been created, anyone

    with knowledge of the idea can take

    advantage of it.

  • Ideas Excludable

    • Another important characteristics of ideas,

    one that ideas share with most economic

    goods: they are, at least partially

    excludable; The degree to which a good is

    excludable is the degree to which the

    owner of the good can change a free for

    its use.

  • Excludable ideas

    • The firm that invents the design for the next computer chip can presumably lock the plans in a safe and restricted access to the design, at least for some period of time.

    • Alternatively, copyright and patent system grant inventors who receive copyrights or patents the right to charge for the use of their ideas.

  • Examples

    Degree of

    excludability

    Rivalrous goods Nonrivalrous

    goods

    High

    Low

    Lawyer services

    CD player

    Flopy disk

    Fish in the sea

    Encoded Satellite

    TV transmission.

    Computer code

    for a software

    application.

    National Defence

    Basic R&D

    Calculus

  • The tragedy of the commons

    • Goods that suffer from the ‘tragedy of the commons’ problem are rivalrous but have low degree of excludability.(ower fishing of international water-over grazing of land)

    • The cost of one peasent choosing to graze an additional cow on the commons is shared by all of the presents, but the benefit is captured solely by one peasent.

    • The result is an inefficiently high level of grazing that can potentially destroy the commons.

  • Degree of excludability

    • Ideas are nonrivalrous goods, but they

    vary substantially in their degree of

    excludability.

    • Encoded satellite TV transmissions are

    highly excludable, while computer

    software is less excludable.

    • Software piroting is another example.

  • Public good

    • Nonrivalrous goods that are essentially

    unexcludable are often called public

    goods; A traditional example is a national

    defence.

  • Externalities

    • Goods that are excludable allow their producers to capture the benefits they produce goods thaqt are not excludable involve substantial ‘spillovers’ of benefits that are not captured by producers.

    • Such spillovers are called externalities.

    • Goods with positive spillovers tend to be underproduced by markets, providing a classic opportunity for government intervention to improve welfare. İ.e. Basic R&D and national defence are financed by primarily government.

    • Goods with negative spillovers may be overproduced by markets, and government regulation may be needed if property rights can not well defined.

  • Rival-non rival

    • Goods that are rivalrous must be produced each

    time they are sold; goods that are non-rivalrous

    need to be produced only once.

    • That is nonrivalrous goods such as ideas involve

    a fixed cost of production and zero marginal

    cost.

    • İ.E. First production of latest word processor or

    Edison lamb. Fixed cost high but marginal cost

    is very low.

  • Increasing return and imperfect

    competition

    • The only reason for a nonzero marginal cost is that the non-rivalrous good-the idea- is embodied in arivalrous good- the flopy disk or the materials of the light bulb.

    • This reasoning leads to a simple but powerful insight: the economics of ‘ideas’ is intimately tied to the presence of increasing returns to scale and imperfect competition.

    • The link to increasing returns is almost immediate once we grant that ideas are associated with fixed costs.

  • Costs

    • Once the product is developed, each additional unit is produced with constant returns to scale: doubling the number of floppy disks,instruction manuals and labour to put everything together will double production.

    • In other words this process can be viewed as production with a fixed cost and a constant marginal cost.

    • Prod. Function : y=f(x)=100*(X-F) that exibits a fixed cost F and a constant marginal cost of production.

  • Fixed cost and increasing returns

  • Cost

    • Think of y as copies of the next generation of word-processing software with ‘voice recognition’ lets call it ‘word talk’, and think of X as the amount of labour input required to produce Word Talk.

    • (This statement is aproximately rigt, the true version is F+(1/100) units of labour required to produce first copy)

    • Thus, F is the research cost, which is likely to be a very large number.

    • If X is measured as hours of labour input, we might assume that F=10000: it takes 10000 hours to produce the first copy of Word Talk.

    • After the first copy is created, additional copies can be produced very cheaply.(In this example 100 hour labour can produce 100 copies)

  • Increasing returns and MC

    • Recall that a production function exibits incresing returns to scale if f(ax) a f(x) where a is some number greater than one for example, doubling the inputs more than doubles output.

    • Q. If the marginal cost of production is very small why is it that the product costs so much? Doesn’t this imply an inefficiency in the market?

  • Why not MC=P

    • The answer is that yes, there is an inefficiency because price should be equal in MC for efficient level of production.

    • However, the inefficiency in many ways a necessary one.

    • Hihg level of fixed cost or more generally presence of incresing returns, implies that setting price equal to MC will result in negative profit..

  • Fixed cost and incresing return

  • Fixed cost and incresing return

    • The figure shows the costs of production as a function of the number of units produced.

    • The marginal cost of production is constant e.g. İt costs 10 TL to produce each additional unit of software.

    • But the average cost is declining.

    • The first unit costs F to produce because of the fixed cost of the idea, which is also the average cost of the first unit.

    • A higher levels of production, this fixed cost is spread over more and more units so that the average cost declines with scale.

  • If P = MC

    • Assume that AC>MC If MC=P .

    • With increasing returns to scale average cost is always greater than marginal cost and therefore marginal cost pricing result in negative profits.

    • In another words, no firm would enter this marketand pay the fixed cost F to develop the computer software if it could not set the price above the marginal cost of producing additional unit.

    • Firms will enter only if they can charge a price higher than marginal cost that allows them to recoup the fixed cost of creating the good in the first place.

    • It is essential to be away from perfect competition.

  • Conclusion

    • Questions

    • Discussions