2
EQUIPMENT Urine specimen container, sterile  Washclo ths, cotton balls, or softnets Antiseptic solution or soap Sterile water Bedpan or urinal if child on bedrest Gloves, nonsterile GENERAL GUIDELINES FOR SPECIMEN COLLECTION 1. Check ph ysicia n’ s order . Ensures appropriate specimen obtained from the correct child. 2. Check ch ild for alle rgies to any ma terial s used, e.g ., povidone-iodine. 3. Prepa re chil d and f amily . Enhances cooperation/pa rtici-  pation; reduces anxiety/fear.  NOTE: Have an assistant hold/comfort the child as nec- essary and in accordance with agency policy. 4. Gat her eq uip men t. Promotes organization and effi- ciency. 5. Wash h ands. Don g loves . Reduces transmission of  microorganisms. PROCEDURE 1. Steps 1 –5 of Ge neral Guide lines . 2. Moiste n half of washclot hs, cotton ba lls, or softnets wit h soap solution and half with water. 3. Put o n non steril e glo ves. Protects from contact with  body fluids. 4. Cleanse area. a. Male. 1. Wipe tip of penis in cir cular motion down ward toward shaft. Wipe only once with each cloth or cotton ball. Repeat until comes away clean. If uncircumcised, retract foreskin before cleansing. Retract only if it retracts easily and replace fore- skin after cleansing. Maintains asepsis by cleaning  from least to most contaminated area. 2. Repeat process u sing w ater t o rinse away all so ap. Removes soap or antiseptic solution, which could contaminate the specimen. b. Fe ma le. 1. Sprea d the labia major with o ne ha nd an d wip e from front to back once with each cloth or cotton ball. Repeat until comes away clean. Maintains asepsis by cleaning from least contaminated to  most contaminated area. 2. Repe at pro cess w ith wa ter to rinse away all soa p. Removes soap or antiseptic solution, which could contaminate the specimen.  NOTE: Older children can clean themselves. They  should be instructed to wash their hands and then clean in manner as described above. 5. Have child start to void into a receptacle ( e.g., bedpan, hat); after a few drops, stop flow , then urinate into ster- ile container. Collect enough urine for a specimen, approximately 30–50 cc. 6. Allow ch ild to finis h voidin g in recept acle. 7. Labe l specime n and place in appro priate ba g or con- tainer along with laboratory requisition slip. Ensures  specimen is properly identified and correct test is per-  formed. 8. Remov e glov es. W ash ha nds. Reduces transmission of  microorganisms. 9. Sen d spec ime n to lab . DOCUMENTATION FOR SPECIMEN COLLECTION 1. Time sp ecime n col lecte d. 2. Amoun t of urine colle cted. 3. Col or of u rine. 4. T ype of test to b e perf ormed . 5. Condi tion of skin of perin eal are a. OBTAINING A CATHETERIZED URINE SPECIMEN See Skill 29, Urinary Catheterization. 37 Copyright © 2007 by Thomson Delmar Learning, a division of Thomson Learning, Inc. All rights reserved. SKILL 13 SKILL 13 Collectio n of a Mids tr eam, Clean Catch Urine Specimen on Older Child

TN5 Futures Risk Premium

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: TN5 Futures Risk Premium

8/14/2019 TN5 Futures Risk Premium

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/tn5-futures-risk-premium 1/11

Document Date: November 2, 2006

 An Introduction To Derivatives And Risk Management , 7th

Edition

Don Chance and Robert Brooks

Technical Note: Futures Risk Premiums, Ch. 9, p. 309

This technical note supports the material in the Asset Risk Premium Hypothesis

section of Chapter 9 Principles of Pricing Forwards, Futures, and Options on Futures.

We explore here the relationship between futures prices and expected spot prices under 

various assumptions about market microstructure. Insights are supported with

observations from the gold, copper and natural gas futures markets.

Futures prices and expected spot prices

We explore the relationship between spot asset prices and futures or forward

contracts when arbitrage is and is not possible. We do not distinguish between forwardor futures markets here.

 Asset Price in Secondary Market 

The price of the spot asset ( ) could be represented as the present value of the

expected future asset value (

0S

( )T0 SE ) adjusted for any holding costs (future value of 

storage, insurance and such), any benefits (convenience yield, dividends, and such) (all

carry costs are denoted ), and a spot asset risk premium (θ ( )T0,S Sφ ), expressed as:

( ) ( )T0,ST00 SSES φ−θ−=  

Using a standard supply and demand graph, we illustrate this result in Figure 1.

Page 2: TN5 Futures Risk Premium

8/14/2019 TN5 Futures Risk Premium

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/tn5-futures-risk-premium 2/11

Figure 1. Asset Supply and Demand Curves

Price

Asset Supply

Asset Demand

 

E0[PA]

PA 

QA Quantity

Insights:

• The clearing price and quantity are determined by asset supply and demand in the

secondary asset market

• The asset price is the present value of expected future cash flows, discounted at a

risk adjusted discount rate

 Net Hedging: A Digression

It is reasonable to assume that hedgers are willing to pay a futures risk premium

to reduce their risk. Figure 2 illustrates the net hedging theory when net hedgers are long.

The phrase net hedger is used because in any futures market there are typically hedgers

on both the long and short side of the market. One can add up all the hedgers that are long

and all the hedgers that are short. Subtracting these two totals, one can determine whether 

a particular futures contract has net long or net short hedgers. These net hedgers are long

the futures contracts and are willing to contract at futures prices above the expected

future spot price. Net speculators provide the hedging protection for a futures risk 

  premium above the expected future spot price. This market is said to be in normal

IDRM7e, © Don M. Chance and Robert-Brooks Futures Risk Premiums2

Page 3: TN5 Futures Risk Premium

8/14/2019 TN5 Futures Risk Premium

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/tn5-futures-risk-premium 3/11

contango as the futures price is above the unobservable expected future spot price. The

figure below illustrates the case where net hedgers are long and speculators demand a risk 

 premium.

Figure 2. Net Positions of Hedgers and Speculators when Net Hedgers are long:

Normal Contango

0,f φ

Equilibrium Futures Price

 Net Hedgers

 Net Speculators

Expected Future Spot Price

Futures Price

Short Contracts Long Contracts

Recall that hedgers are willing to pay a premium to reduce their risk. If net

hedgers are short the futures contract they are willing to hedge at futures prices below the

expected future spot price. Net speculators will provide the hedging protection for a

futures risk premium below the expected future spot price. This market is said to be in

normal backwardation as the futures price is below the unobservable expected future spot

 price, illustrated in Figure 3.

IDRM7e, © Don M. Chance and Robert-Brooks Futures Risk Premiums3

Page 4: TN5 Futures Risk Premium

8/14/2019 TN5 Futures Risk Premium

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/tn5-futures-risk-premium 4/11

Figure 3. Net Positions of Hedgers and Speculators when Net Hedgers are short:

Normal Backwardation

Futures Price

0,f φ

Equilibrium Futures Price

  Net Hedgers Net Speculators

Expected Future

S ot Price

Short Contracts Long Contracts

 Futures Price in Unarbitraged Derivatives Market 

The price of the futures contract on the spot asset could be represented as the

expected future asset value adjusted for any holding costs (margin, impact of marking-to-

market and such), any benefits (embedded options and such), and a futures risk premium

(which could be positive or negative depending on net hedging demand):

( ) ( ) ( )T0,f T00 SSETf  φ−θ−=  

Assuming no holding costs or benefits from having a position in the futures market,

( ) ( ) ( )T0,f T00 SSETf  φ−=  

Thus, in an unarbitraged market we expect to find that the futures price is a function of 

the expected future spot asset value adjusted for perhaps a significant futures risk 

  premium. Figure 4 depicts equilibrium in a futures markets where arbitrage is not

feasible.

IDRM7e, © Don M. Chance and Robert-Brooks Futures Risk Premiums4

Page 5: TN5 Futures Risk Premium

8/14/2019 TN5 Futures Risk Premium

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/tn5-futures-risk-premium 5/11

Figure 4. Equilibrium in Unarbitraged Futures Market

Insights:

• Speculators must earn a positive risk premium to be induced to participate

• Hedgers are assumed to be net long

• The difference between the futures price and the expected future asset price is the

compensation to the speculator (futures risk premium)

• Greater hedging demand results in higher compensation to speculators

• The difference between expected the future spot asset price and today’s asset

 price depends on both the risk-free rate and any asset risk premiums

 Futures Price in Fully-Arbitraged Derivatives Market 

Recall that only when the futures market is fully arbitraged, we have

( ) θ+= 00 STf .

Solving for the future value of costs and benefits and substituting this result into the spot

 price equation, we have:

( ) ( )T0,ST00 SSES φ−θ−= .

Hedger Demand – Net Long

Speculator Supply – Net ShortPrice

PF,UA  E0[PA]

PA 

QF,UA QA Quantity

IDRM7e, © Don M. Chance and Robert-Brooks Futures Risk Premiums5

Page 6: TN5 Futures Risk Premium

8/14/2019 TN5 Futures Risk Premium

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/tn5-futures-risk-premium 6/11

Thus substituting S0,

( ) ( ) ( )T0,ST00 SSETf  φ−= .

Thus, the futures price does not equal the expected future asset price. This equation is a

direct outcome, however, of assuming the market is arbitrage-free and there are no

market imperfections. Every derivatives market has some imperfections and hence this

result is not exactly correct. Figure 5 illustrates both the unarbitraged case and the fully

arbitraged case.

Figure 5. Equilibrium in Unarbitraged and Arbitraged Futures Market

Insights:

• A fully arbitraged futures market implies that the futures price is equal to the

future value of the asset price, adjusted for the marginal dealer’s cost of funds

(“risk-free” interest rate).

• The difference between the current futures price and the expected future asset

 price is the asset’s risk premium.

• The difference between the quantity of long futures positions in a fully-arbitraged

market and the quantity of long futures positions in an unarbitraged market

represents the net additional supply of short contracts provided by arbitragers

Hedger Demand – Net Long

PF,A = FV[PA]

E0[PA]

Speculator Supply – Net ShortPrice

PF,UA 

PA 

QF,UA QA QF,FA Quantity

IDRM7e, © Don M. Chance and Robert-Brooks Futures Risk Premiums6

Page 7: TN5 Futures Risk Premium

8/14/2019 TN5 Futures Risk Premium

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/tn5-futures-risk-premium 7/11

• Arbitrageurs, however, are net short futures contracts and will hence buy the same

amount of the underlying asset, driving the asset price up, resulting in less

demand by arbitrageurs.

• Assuming the asset market price does not materially change, the difference

 between the quantity of long futures positions in a fully-arbitraged market and the

quantity of long futures positions in an unarbitraged market represents the net

societal benefit from satisfying greater hedging demand.

• There is no futures risk premium in fully arbitraged futures markets.

• The futures price reflects the asset risk premium (the difference between the

expected future asset price and current futures price).

Based on the analysis above, futures markets can be classified into three types, fully-

arbitraged, quasi-arbitraged, and un-arbitraged. In a futures market that is fully-

arbitraged, both carry arbitrage and reverse-carry arbitrage can be conducted by a wide

array of market participants. In a futures market that is quasi-arbitraged, either carry

arbitrage or reverse-carry arbitrage can be conducted by a wide array of market

 participants, but not both. In a futures market that is un-arbitraged, neither carry arbitrage

nor reverse-carry arbitrage can be conducted by market participants.

 Market Classification Illustrated 

 Fully-Arbitraged Market 

One characteristic of a fully arbitraged market is the stochastic nature of futures

contracts that differ only by maturity. Assuming the carry model, the percentage

difference in futures prices of different maturities is: (denoted %TP for percentage term

 premium)

( ) ( )( )

( )

1

S

SS

Tf 

Tf Tf TP%

T

T

T0

T0T0

0

00

−θ

θ=

θ+

θ+−θ+=

−τ+=

τ+

τ+

.

  Notice that the difference in futures prices depends solely on the difference in the

maturity and the carry costs. We assume the longer time to maturity, the higher the carry

IDRM7e, © Don M. Chance and Robert-Brooks Futures Risk Premiums7

Page 8: TN5 Futures Risk Premium

8/14/2019 TN5 Futures Risk Premium

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/tn5-futures-risk-premium 8/11

costs. Hence, one would expect that at a point in time, the percentage difference in

futures prices would be slightly positive and stable. Figure 6 illustrates gold futures

contracts. Since 1985 gold futures contracts exhibit the characteristics common for fully-

arbitraged markets. In the late 1970s and early 1980s there appeared some evidence that

gold futures were not fully arbitraged. For example, at the end of 1979 and in early 1980,

there were periods of time when the percentage term premium was large and both

 positive and negative.

A large positive term premium implies a profitable arbitrage trade: enter a long

 position in the distant contract and a short position in the near contract. When the near 

contract expires, buy the underlying asset with borrowed money and deliver it when the

distant contract expires.

A large negative term premium implies a profitable arbitrage trade: enter a short

 position in the distant contract and a long position in the near contract. When the near 

contract expires, short sell the underlying asset and lend money and cover the short

 position when the distant contract expires.

Figure 6. Term Premium for Gold Futures

-20.00%

-15.00%

-10.00%

-5.00%

0.00%

5.00%

10.00%

15.00%

20.00%

Jan-75 Jan-77 Jan-79 Dec-80 Dec-82 Dec-84 Dec-86 Dec-88 Dec-90 Dec-92 Dec-94 Dec-96 Dec-98 Dec-00

Calendar Time

   P  e  r  c  e  n   t  a  g  e   P  r  e  m   i  u  m

 

IDRM7e, © Don M. Chance and Robert-Brooks Futures Risk Premiums8

Page 9: TN5 Futures Risk Premium

8/14/2019 TN5 Futures Risk Premium

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/tn5-futures-risk-premium 9/11

Quasi-Arbitraged Market 

A quasi-arbitrage market is rare to find. One side of the carry arbitrage must be

feasible, whereas the other is not. The copper futures market during the late 1980s and

mid-1990s fit this classification scheme. Figure 7 illustrates the copper futures market.

  Notice that apparent ceiling in the percentage term premium. There are large negative

term premiums but not large positive term premiums.

In the copper market, by the late 1980s traders apparently had entered the copper 

arbitrage business. Recall, a large positive term premium implies a profitable arbitrage

trade: enter a long position in the distant contract and a short position in the near contract.

When the near contract expires, buy the underlying asset with borrowed money and

deliver it when the distant contract expires. The only requirement is to be able to store

copper cheaply, not a difficult task.

Short-selling copper, however, is more difficult. By 1997, firms with an inventory

of copper apparently entered the reverse carry arbitrage business. Recall a large negative

term premium implies a profitable arbitrage trade: enter a short position in the distant

contract and a long position in the near contract. When the near contract expires, short

sell (or sell out of inventory) the underlying asset and lend money and cover the short

 position when the distant contract expires. Apparently, by 1997 both sides of the carry

arbitrage were feasible, and hence copper graduated to a fully-arbitraged futures market.

IDRM7e, © Don M. Chance and Robert-Brooks Futures Risk Premiums9

Page 10: TN5 Futures Risk Premium

8/14/2019 TN5 Futures Risk Premium

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/tn5-futures-risk-premium 10/11

Figure 7. Term Premium for Copper Futures

-20.00%

-15.00%

-10.00%

-5.00%

0.00%

5.00%

10.00%

15.00%

20.00%

Jan-75 Jan-77 Jan-79 Dec-80 Dec-82 Dec-84 Dec-86 Dec-88 Dec-90 Dec-92 Dec-94 Dec-96 Dec-98 Dec-00

Calendar Time

   P  e  r  c  e  n   t  a  g  e   P  r  e  m   i  u  m

 

Un-Arbitraged Market 

This type of market is easy to find. Neither side of the carry arbitrage is feasible.

The natural gas futures market fits this classification scheme at this time, as illustrated in

Figure 8. Notice that the percentage term premium can vary dramatically.

IDRM7e, © Don M. Chance and Robert-Brooks Futures Risk Premiums10

Page 11: TN5 Futures Risk Premium

8/14/2019 TN5 Futures Risk Premium

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/tn5-futures-risk-premium 11/11

Figure 8. Term Premium for Natural Gas Futures

-20.00%

-15.00%

-10.00%

-5.00%

0.00%

5.00%

10.00%

15.00%

20.00%

Jun-93 Jun-94 Jun-95 May-96 May-97 May-98 May-99 May-00 May-01 May-02 May-03

Calendar Time

   P  e  r  c  e  n   t  a  g  e   P  r  e  m   i  u  m

 

Valuation models need to be tailored to the category of futures market. A fully-

arbitraged market would apply a carry model for valuation purposes. The carry model is

solely dependent on the cost of carrying the underlying asset through time and the

appropriate discount rate. The quasi-arbitrage market would apply the carry model for 

valuation purposes at some times and not at others. The un-arbitraged market requires an

entirely different approach to valuation.

References 

Black, F. “The Pricing of Commodity Contracts.”   Journal of Financial 

 Economics 3 (1976), 167-179.

French, K. R. “Detecting Spot Price Forecasts in Futures Prices.” The Journal of 

 Business 59 (1983), S39-S54.

IDRM7e, © Don M. Chance and Robert-Brooks Futures Risk Premiums11