14
Valuation of Intangibles

Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Valuation of Intangibles

Page 2: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Measuring the value of outcomes(or social surplus)

• Two basic methods– Revealed preference (observing what people actually do in

the market when price, quality and other attributes change)– Stated choice (asking what people would do in the market

under different prices, qualities and other attributes change).

• Social surplus = #’s affected x marginal social benefit (cost) of one unit

• Under perfect competition, P = MSC• The intersection of marginal social benefit and marginal

social cost is the shadow price of the outcome

Page 3: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Market analogies

• Use the private sector price as if it were the proxy for the price under perfect competition.

• This can be used as the shadow price for the publicly provided good if the private price is what the users of the publicly provided good would be willing to pay (if they could afford it).

• Targeting is an issue. If the publicly provided good (housing) is provided to middle income residents, they would actually be prepared to pay more and the estimated benefits of public housing would increase

Page 4: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Trade-off

• Opportunity costs reflects trade-off inherent in choice.• EG. Use of wages as a proxy for the value of time

– Wages do not include actual and psychic benefits of working

– Taxes distort wages– Some down time (travel) can be productive– Travel time may have values– Value of time depends on what else could be done– Wages depend on institutional constraints – hours of work

are flexible– Wages can reflect monopoly power

Page 5: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Value of statistical life

• Foregone earnings – Courts often use discounted present value of

lifetime earnings to estimate values of limbs lost and compensation for life.

– This assumes full-employment and that wage = marginal social product. Those who are paid are valued more than those who volunteer.

• Options include– Purchase test (insurance)– Wage premium accept increased risk of death

Page 6: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

The prices and uptake in a comparable community is used as the basis for estimating a freely provided service in the subject community.

The CS for the free pool is the area under the demand curve

The revenue from the paid attendance pool underestimates the consumer surplus by a wide margin.

Page 7: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

(p+w) ((life) - $300 = pV(life)(p+w) ((life) - pV(life) = - $300wV(life) = $300V(life) = $300/w

W=1/10,000 - likelihood of death from no airbags implies that the value of a statistical life is $3 million

Page 8: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Problems with simple consumer purchase and wage risk models

• Do workers have full information• Adrenalin junkies may obtain non-wage

benefits (risk averse people may avoid dangerous professions) – self-selection results in a lower premium for dangerous work

• Risk of death data may not be complete• Diminishing marginal utility for safety• Assumption of market efficiency

Page 9: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Intermediate (secondary) market good

• Useful for training/education programs– Compare incomes for those with and without training (training premium)– Assumes that incomes accurately measure the benefits of training– Some credentials may be overvalued (Harvard MBA?)

• Double counting (if the value is measured by reduced unemployment, measuring increased earnings and combining the two double counts, unless one measures the increased employment and increased wages as an estimate of increased GDP – you cannot include both increased wages and increased GDP or increased hours and increased GDP.

• The example the benefits of irrigation as the increase in area under the demand curve for water and also measure increased revenues by farmers is double counting.

• One advantage of having clients pay a portion of the costs for a social program is that one more directly measures demand, which leads to direct measures of consumer surplus.

Page 10: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Asset Valuation

• Use the discounted or capitalized value of capital assets to track impacts

• This tracks valuations in secondary markets (land) as a reflection of primary markets (transportation)

• Natural experiments and using cross-sectional studies to show asset price variation as a function of a project/amenity are common.

• Land is the most common asset to use as meaSure of the intangible

Page 11: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Hedonic pricing• Two step process to control for omitted variable and then to control for self-

selection.• Require that the capital value of asset reflects changes in the attribute (e.g. travel

time to work is the attribute and the value of the house is the capital asset.• Step 1 – estimate the value of the house as a function of attributes

P = f(travel time, view, age, size, …..) ……… 1 this is the hedonic price function ……….2P = B0travel timeB1viewB2ageB3sizeB4 ……....3

ln= lnB0 +B1ln*time+B2ln*view+B3ln*age*B4ln*size… ……….4

B1,B2,B3, B4 are elasticities that show how a change in an attribute affects price• The hedonic price of an attribute is the change in price for a one unit change in

that attribute…

rv = B2 P/view

Page 12: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Hedonic Pricing – cont’dStep 2 – we measure rv as a function of the attribute of interest

rv = A0 + A1View + A2 Age + A3 income

Notice that rv varies with scenic view level (this is the non-linear form of step 1).

Technically, rv should be a straight line in the second graph according to the equation above.

Page 13: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Value of statistical life - hedonicsln (wage) = B0 + B1ln(fatality risk) + B2ln injury risk + b3ln(job tenure)… 1

rf = B1 wage/fatality risk

rf = A0 + A1(fatality risk) + A2(age) + A3(education) ……………………………….2

• Problems– People must understand the attribute in question(view, travel time, risk…)– The measurement of the variables (view, risk …) is important– The functional form is critical– Variation must exist in housing location, jobs …. to ensure proper statistical fit– Econometric issues in the data– Assumption of efficient markets

Page 14: Valuation of Intangibles. Measuring the value of outcomes (or social surplus) Two basic methods – Revealed preference (observing what people actually

Travel cost method(recreation - parks)

• Assume that remote sites cost time and money to visit• Willingness to incur these costs provide an estimate of

value• Demand

q = f(price, prices, Y, Z)

Where q = number of trips to the park, price is the total cost, prices is the price of substitutes, Y is income and Z is tastes.

• Key idea is that price varies depends on travel cost (time) which varies for each individual)

• Often the model surveys visitors and uses zones (FSA) to estimate costs