Wealth Creation and Managerial Pay, MVA and EVA as Determinants of Executive Compensation

  • Upload
    so-lok

  • View
    7

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • D 2003 Elsevier Science Inc. All rights reserved.

    Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179JEL classification: J33; G3

    Keywords: Compensation; Pay for performance; Economic value added; Market value added

    1. Introduction

    Previous studies have proposed that optimal executive compensation contracts perfectly

    align the interests of the executives with those of the firms shareholders (Grossman &

    Hart, 1983; Harris & Raviv, 1979). In theory, such contracts act as incentive mechanisms

    for executives to engage in behaviors that maximize the firms value and rewardWealth creation and managerial pay: MVA and EVA

    as determinants of executive compensation

    Ali Fatemia, Anand S. Desaib, Jeffrey P. Katzb,*

    aDePaul University, Chicago, IL, USAbKansas State University, Manhattan, KS, USA

    Received 1 June 2001; received in revised form 1 October 2002; accepted 1 October 2002

    Abstract

    Designing effective compensation contracts has become increasingly complex due to the

    globalization of the executive work force and the multitude of incentive schemes. We examine the

    relationships between managerial pay and firm performance among domestic and global firms using

    economic value added (EVA) and market value added (MVA) to assess wealth creation. Our work

    suggests that top managers in domestic- and globally focused firms are not only incented to increase

    EVA, but also rewarded for past additions to MVA. The results of our research suggest that managers

    of highly globalized firms tend to be paid at higher levels, reflecting the increased complexity of

    managing global firms.executives for such behavior (Fama, 1980; Jensen & Meckling, 1976). Whether executive

    compensation contracts meet this test of optimality, ex ante or ex post, is an empirical

    question subject to ongoing investigation (Tosi, Werner, Katz, & Gomez-Mejia, 2000).

    1044-0283/03/$ - see front matter D 2003 Elsevier Science Inc. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/S1044-0283(03)00010-3

    * Corresponding author. Tel.: +1-785-532-7451; fax: +1-785-532-7024.

    E-mail address: [email protected] (J.P. Katz).

  • A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179160Several studies have examined the relationships between measures of firm performance

    and top manager pay. For example, Murphy (1985) found a statistically significant

    relationship between the level of pay and performance, while Mehran (1995) found firm

    performance is positively related to managements ownership stake and to the percentage

    of its equity-based compensation. However, Jensen and Murphy (1990) did not find a

    significant relationship between changes in firm value and changes in executive compen-

    sation. Miller (1995) showed no support for a linear relationship between pay and

    performance, but found strong support for a convex relationship. Hadlock and Lumer

    (1997) found that payperformance sensitivities have significantly increased over time for

    small firms, but not for large firms.

    More recently, in a study examining the role of boards in setting managerial pay, Porac,

    Wade, and Pollock (1999) found evidence that boards make comparisons within and

    between industries in which the firm competes to support their top management

    compensation decisions. The authors conclude that boards of directors tend to anchor

    their comparability judgments by examining other firms performance. This suggests that

    top manager performance is assessed based on relative measures and with an eye toward

    the industry environment affecting the firm.

    Unfortunately, most of the studies exploring the nature of the relationship between

    managerial pay and performance have used accounting-based measures of performance

    (such as return on equity [ROE] or return on assets [ROA]). Such measures may bear little

    resemblance with the economic return earned by the firm since accounting-based measures

    do not account for the risk incurred by the firms managers in their search for growth and

    profitability (Shiely, 1996). For example, earnings growth which may follow a decision to

    increase the size of the firm does not automatically lead to a per-share growth in firm value

    because the former may be achieved at excessive capital costs (Copeland, Koller, &

    Murrin, 1995). In addition, even studies using measures of performance based on market

    returns fail to adjust returns for the level of risk exposure (Harris & Raviv, 1979). Thus,

    the exact relationship between pay and performance can be somewhat different than what

    the empirical results suggest because the impact of risk is not adequately accounted for in

    commonly employed measures of performance (Lehn & Makhija, 1996; Stewart, 1991).

    Our study is designed to further clarify the nature of the payperformance relationship

    by adding risk to the equation. Specifically, we seek to investigate the relationship between

    top management compensation and two measures of risk-adjusted firm performance:

    economic value added (EVA) and market value added (MVA). EVA and MVA are

    measures developed and trademarked by the Stern Stewart and Co. First suggested by

    Stewart (1991), EVA can be thought of as a proxy for the measurement of economic

    returns. It is the firms residual profitability in excess of capital costs. A firms EVA is

    positive when after-tax operating profits exceed the dollar cost of capital (COC). MVA is a

    closely related measure in that it is the present value of all expected future EVA and can be

    thought of as the net present value of the firm.

    Variations of these measures have been proposed, and used, by others (Copeland et al.,

    1995; Rappaport, 1986). However, EVA and MVA have received wider attention both in

    the corporate world and in scholarly research (see for example, Hodak, 1994; Lehn &

    Makhija, 1996; Spinner, 1995; Tully, 1993; Uyemura, Kantor, & Pettit, 1996). Includedamong these are studies that have attempted to document the presence (or lack thereof) of

  • A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179 161a relationship between EVA and measures of stock price performance. Dodd and Chen

    (1996), for example, report that EVA explains only slightly more than one fifth (20.2%) of

    the variation in stock returns for a sample of 566 firms, comparing unfavorably with

    ROA, which explains almost a fourth (24.5%) of the variation. Further, Dodd and Johns

    (1999) found some differences in performance between the adopters and nonadopters of

    EVA. However, as documented by Weaver (2001), there are significant differences in how

    firms measure EVA. Examining a set of 29 EVA adopters who participated in his survey,

    he found that none of the respondents measured the EVA the same way. Directly relevant

    to our purpose is Weavers finding that the adopters top reasons for implementation of

    EVA are to enhance financial management and to enhance compensation metrics.

    Also of direct interest to this work is Kramer and Peters (2001) finding that, as a proxy

    for MVA, EVA does not suffer from any industry-specific bias. However, they also

    conclude that EVA is consistently outperformed by the net operating profit after tax

    measure.

    We believe EVA and MVA are reasonable proxies for the measurement of owner wealth

    maximization while taking into account the relative risk-based costs of doing so (Hodak,

    1994; Shiely, 1996). However, the relationships between executive compensation and

    these measures of firm performance have not yet been explored empirically. In this study,

    we seek to examine these relationships. Under the pay-for-performance hypothesis, we

    expect a positive relationship between executive compensation and firm performance. In

    this study, firm performance is measured in the context of value creation for the owners of

    the firm using MVA and EVA. We also examine the contribution of these measures in

    explaining the cross-sectional variation in executive compensation relative to the account-

    ing-based measure of ROA.

    Executive compensation generally consists of several components such as salary,

    bonus, stock options, and long-term incentive payments. It is plausible that certain

    components, such as bonuses, are used as a reward for past performance, while other

    components related to firm value are designed to provide the correct incentive for future

    performance (Murphy, 1985). The complex design of the total compensation package

    requires that we separately examine the relationship between firm performance and each of

    these components.

    Recently, there has been an increase in the body of research pointing to the global

    managerial labor market as the basis for better understanding differences in levels of pay,

    as well as the mix of incentive plan components. That is, there is increasing evidence that

    top managers in highly global firms have higher proportions of performance-based pay in

    their total compensation contract (Carpenter, Sanders, & Gregersen, 2001). In addition,

    Richard (2000) suggests that pay policies that include equity participation practices

    pioneered in the United States are becoming common throughout the global business

    community. We hope to assess whether there are differences in the relationships between

    pay and performance based on the level of international impact of the firm.

    We also seek to examine the causal order of the relationshipthat is, whether

    compensation serves as a reward for past performance, or as an incentive for enhanced

    future performance. Given shareholder wealth maximization as the goal of the firm, is the

    executive compensation scheme used by the firm incentive-compatible? To answer thisquestion, we use leading and lagged values of firm performance. If compensation is an

  • Firm performance measures are obtained from two sources. EVA and MVA are

    obtained from the Performance 1000 database. ROE and ROA are obtained from the

    A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179162Compustat database.

    Economic theory, human capital theory, and agency theory suggest that top manager

    pay will be positively related to firm size (Agarwal, 1981; Becker, 1964; Deckop, 1988;

    Jensen & Meckling, 1976). That is, economic theory of marginal revenue products

    predicts greater pay in firms of greater size (Gomez-Mejia et al., 1987). Additionally, if

    an effective CEO can create greater profits for large firms than for small ones, then it is

    likely that the marginal productivity of the CEO would vary directly with size. Further,

    human capital theory predicts greater pay in firms of greater size (Becker, 1964). The

    prediction follows from the observation that the top position in a larger firm requiresincentive for top managers to perform in certain ways, then we would expect top manager

    pay to be unrelated to past performance, but instead would observe a positive relationship

    between current compensation and future performance. On the other hand, if compensa-

    tion is a reward for superior performance, we would expect top manager pay to be

    positively related to past performance, but not to future performance (Gomez-Mejia, Tosi,

    & Hinkin, 1987; Tosi et al., 2000).

    The rest of our paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we describe our data.

    We present and discuss our results in Section 3 and our conclusions and implications for

    further research are presented in the last section.

    2. Data

    Executive compensation and firm performance measures used in this study are obtained

    from three sources: the Standard and Poors ExecuComp database, Stern Stewart and Co.s

    Performance 1000 database, and Standard and Poors Compustat database.

    We define top managers as individuals with the title of Chairman, CEO, President and

    senior-level Vice President. Compensation data are obtained from the ExecuComp data-

    base. In our study, we use three measures of compensation: salary, bonus, and total direct

    compensation (TDC). TDC is defined as the sum of salary, bonus, value of restricted stock

    granted, value of stock options granted, and other annual items, which include perquisites,

    payments to cover executives taxes, preferential earnings payable but deferred at

    executives election, and preferential discounts of stock purchases. Data requirements

    for the incentive/reward hypothesis require us to use annual compensation in the 4-year

    period from 1992 to 1995.

    The number of executives varies across the firms in our sample, ranging from 1 to 12.

    Larger firms tend to have a greater number of executives. Since we are interested in the

    total executive compensation package of the firm, for each firm (and for each year) in the

    sample period, we aggregate the compensation component for all executives of this firm

    listed in the ExecuComp database. Implicit in this aggregation is the assumption that the

    firms compensation policy applies uniformly to top executives of different ranks. Prior

    research has shown that this hierarchical assumption is reasonable (Demski & Sappington,

    1989; Werner & Tosi, 1995).greater human capital because a larger firm is more complex, more difficult to manage,

  • A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179 163and demands more responsibility than in a smaller firm. To control for firm-size effects,

    we standardize our variables using the total capital employed by the firm, as explained

    below. Total capital (CAPITAL) is obtained from the Performance 1000 database.

    Jensen and Meckling (1976) propose that executive compensation is related to the

    firms risk. The higher the risk borne by the firm, and thus, the greater the likelihood of

    performance variance, the greater the compensation risks. In an efficient managerial labor

    market, executives will demand, and receive, compensation for bearing risk, thus leading

    to a positive relationship between compensation and the risk borne by the firm (Fama,

    1980; Harris & Raviv, 1979; Winn & Shoenhair, 1988).

    More recently, it has been suggested that top manager pay, in part, reflects risks borne

    by the firm (Hadlock & Lumer, 1997; Hall & Liebman, 1998; Kroll, Simmons, & Wright,

    1990). To facilitate the efficient measurement of risk, the firms COC is used as a proxy for

    risk. Managers choosing competitive strategies exposing the firm to greater risk will be

    charged higher costs by investors for the risk through higher capital costs. It is not

    surprising that all asset-pricing models predict an upward-sloping relationship between the

    level of risk borne by the firm and its COC (Lehn & Makhija, 1996; Uyemura et al., 1996).

    In our cross-sectional tests, we control for firm risk differences using the COC as a proxy

    for risk. While equity beta coefficients are often used as a measure of risk, they only

    measure the risk borne by the shareholders. Since we are concerned with the overall risk of

    the firm, we need to incorporate the risk borne by other security holders in the firm as well.

    The weighted-average COC can therefore serve as a reasonable proxy for the firms risk.

    We obtain COC estimates from the Performance 1000 database.

    The extent of a firms global presence is measured by overseas (foreign) sales, as a

    proportion of the firms total sales, and is denoted by FSALES. Both total and overseas

    sales are obtained from the Compustat database.

    In combining the samples of firms obtained from the compensation and the

    performance databases, we require that data be available for all variables to be used

    in tests of our hypothesis. This results in a final sample size of 1965 observations,

    where each observation is a firm-year. The numbers of firms in each year from 1992 to

    1995 are 432, 550, 502, and 481, respectively. Overseas sales were only available for

    119 firms, and only for the 1995 year. Hence, our tests of the pay-for-performance

    hypotheses that account for the global nature of the firms operations are limited to this

    subsample.

    Since EVA, MVA, and compensation measures are measured in dollars and therefore

    related to firm size, we control for firm-size differences in our cross-sectional tests. Firm

    size is measured by the capital employed at the beginning of the year (BOYCAP),

    obtained from the Performance 1000 database. Using this measure of firm size, salary is

    redefined as salary/BOYCAP. Other compensation measures are adjusted for firm size

    similarly. We also define the firm-size standardized EVA (denoted as SEVA) as EVA/

    BOYCAP. Since MVA is the total market value added to the stock of capital, it is a

    cumulative measure. The incremental market value added during year t, after adjustment

    for differences in firm sizes, is defined as:

    DMVAt MVAt MVAt1 1

    BOYCAPt

  • Table 1 provides descriptive statistics for all variables used in our cross-sectional tests.

    On average, salary constitutes about 46% of TDC, and bonus constitutes about 22% of

    TDC. Further, the usual accounting measures of performance (ROA and ROE) are positive

    on average. The average EVA is, however, $95.74 million, while the average DMVA isabout $3.6 billion. Since EVA is defined as the product of the capital employed and

    difference between the return on capital and the COC, a negative EVA implies that the

    return on capital is less than the COC on average. In our sample, the average return on

    capital, obtained from the Performance 1000 database, is 10.95%. This is less than the

    average COC of 11.68%.

    It is tempting to conclude, on the basis of the negative average EVA, that our sample

    firms have been engaged in suboptimal decision-making with respect to resource

    allocation. However, the positive incremental market value added (DMVA) suggests adifferent implication. For strategic reasons, firms may commit resources to investments

    with expected payoffs in the distant future. Investments in these real options are

    valuable, and their value is reflected in a higher market value of the firm. Thus, even

    though the EVA is negative, the market views these investments favorably and

    consequently revalues the firm upwards. Of the 1965 observations in our sample,

    1247 (63.5%) had a negative EVA. However, 60.5% of these negative EVA firms had

    positive increments to their market value. Interestingly, this proportion of positive

    DMVA firms is comparable to the proportion of positive DMVA firms in the totalsample (60.7%).

    A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179164In Table 2, we provide simple correlation coefficients between the variables used in this

    study. Panel A reports correlation coefficients between our measure of firm size

    Table 1

    Descriptive statistics on measures of compensation, risk, and firm performance for the sample of 1965

    observations between 1992 and 1995a

    Variable Mean Standard deviation

    Salaryb 409.39 216.46

    Bonusb 272.48 333.47

    TDCb 1609.38 3311.88

    (Salary/TDC)c 46.35 24.31

    (Bonus/TDC)c 22.22 16.01

    CAPITALd 4736.95 10 323.29

    COCc 11.68 2.33

    ROEc 12.77 86.12

    ROAc 5.13 7.48

    EVAd 95.74 652.40MVAd 3599.90 9028.39

    SEVAc 0.65 9.20DMVAc 29.77 162.47FSALESc 14.05 13.35

    a Statistics for FSALES are based on a sample of 119 firms for 1995.b In thousands of dollars.c In percent.d In millions of dollars.

  • ROA 0.132*** 0.258*** 0.156***

    ROE 0.012 0.030 0.015

    A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179 165(CAPITAL) and the three compensation measures (unadjusted for firm-size differences).

    All correlation coefficients are positive and significantly different from zero, indicating

    that executives of large firms receive greater compensation than do executives of smaller

    firms.

    Panel B shows the correlation coefficients between the size-adjusted compensation

    measures and the risk of the firm as measured by the COC. All correlation coefficients are

    positive and significant at the 1% level. These coefficients indicate a strong positive

    relationship between firm risk and executive compensation. In subsequent tests of the

    payperformance relationship, we control for both firm size (by normalizing all dollar-

    denominated measures using firm size) and for risk (by including our proxy for risk as an

    SEVA 0.118 0.193*** 0.101***

    DMVA 0.235*** 0.228*** 0.300***

    ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.a Compensation variables used to compute the correlation coefficients with Capital are not adjusted for

    differences in firm size. In all other computations in the table, compensation variables are scaled by the capital

    employed at the beginning of the year.Table 2

    Correlation coefficients between selected measures of compensation and firm size, risk, and performance for the

    sample of 1965 observations between 1992 and 1995a

    Salary Bonus TDC

    Panel A

    CAPITAL 0.436*** 0.252*** 0.295***

    Panel B

    COC 0.211*** 0.250*** 0.224***explanatory variable).

    In Panel B, we also report the correlation coefficients between measures of performance

    and the size-adjusted compensation components. Generally, there is a strong indication of

    a positive relation between firm performance and compensation. While compensation is

    not correlated with ROE, the strong positive correlation between compensation and ROA

    may suggest that compensation policy is more a function of enterprise performance

    rather than simple return to equity holders.

    3. Results

    We investigate the relationship between executive compensation and firm perform-

    ance using cross-sectional regression analysis. The dependent variables in all our

    cross-sectional regressions are the three components of compensation (salary, bonus

    and TDC) adjusted for firm size. For brevity, we refer to compensation components

    generically as COMP. In all regressions, the t statistics are based on Whites (1980)

    heteroskedasticity-consistent estimators of the standard errors of the models parame-

    ters.

  • 3.1. Determinants of executive compensation

    Our first test examines the relationship between the components of compensation and

    each of the four measures of firm performance (ROE, ROA, SEVA, and DMVA) in turn,while simultaneously controlling for firm risk. Thus, we estimate the following model:

    COMPi a0 a1PERFi a2COCi ei 2where the performance variable (PERF) is ROE, ROA, SEVA or DMVA. Estimates of thismodels parameters are reported in Table 3.

    Regardless of the compensation measure and performance measure used in the models

    estimation, the estimates of a2 are all positive and statistically significant at the 1% level.This positive relationship between compensation and firm risk is consistent with the

    arguments presented by Fama (1980), Harris and Raviv (1979), and Winn and Shoenhair

    (1988) that, in an efficient managerial labor market, executives demand and receive

    compensation for bearing risk.

    After we control for firm size and risk, we find a statistically significant relationship

    between all three measures of executive compensation and the change in the market value

    (DMVA) and ROA. The estimates of a1 are positive and statistically significant in all of

    Table 3

    OLS estimates of the relation between compensation and firm performance after controlling for risk, for the

    sample of 1965 observations between 1992 and 1995a

    Compensation

    measure

    a0 a1 a2 F statistic( P value)

    Adjusted

    R2

    A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179166Panel A: COMPi = a0 + a1DMVAi + a2COCi + eiSalary 0.397*** ( 4.73) 0.110*** (3.71) 6.652*** (8.65) 97.15 ( < .01) .09Bonus 0.467*** ( 6.83) 0.077*** (3.03) 5.986*** (9.24) 112.86 ( < .01) .11TDC 6.201*** ( 5.94) 1.217*** (3.48) 66.470*** (6.87) 150.92 ( < .01) .13

    Panel B: COMPi = a0 + a1SEVAi + a2COCi + eiSalary 0.491*** ( 3.33) 0.275 ( 0.26) 7.720*** (5.76) 46.52 ( < .01) .04Bonus 0.407*** ( 4.71) 0.954* (1.77) 5.715*** (7.23) 87.60 ( < .01) .08TDC 5.511*** ( 5.46) 12.678** (2.14) 64.374*** (6.64) 90.14 ( < .01) .08

    Panel C: COMPi = a0 + a1ROEi + a2COCi + eiSalary 0.461*** ( 5.27) 0.001 (0.24) 7.474*** (9.02) 45.57 ( < .01) .04Bonus 0.511*** ( 7.18) 0.013 (1.35) 6.538*** (9.52) 65.75 ( < .01) .06TDC 6.904*** ( 5.71) 0.055 (1.12) 75.527*** (6.58) 62.10 ( < .01) .06

    Panel D: COMPi = a0 + a1ROAi + a2COCi + eiSalary 0.400*** ( 4.28) 0.582*** (2.72) 6.692*** (7.34) 48.02 ( < .01) .05Bonus 0.351*** ( 4.77) 1.518*** (4.38) 4.515*** (6.17) 97.93 ( < .01) .09TDC 5.553*** ( 5.39) 12.757*** (3.80) 58.427*** (6.21) 78.17 ( < .01) .07***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

    a COMPi is the measure of executive compensation, TDC is total direct compensation, COCi is the cost of

    capital, DMVAi is the change in market value added, SEVAi is the standardized economic value added, ROEi isthe return on equity, and ROAi is the return on assets for firm i. t statistics are in parenthesis.

  • A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179 167these cases. However, we find no evidence of a relationship between compensation and

    ROE, indicating that executive compensation is more a function of enterprise performance

    than the return to equity holders. Further, we find only a weak relationship between

    compensation and economic value added (SEVA). While bonus and TDC are related to

    SEVA at the 10% and 5% levels, respectively, the relationship between salary and SEVA is

    not significant.

    Taken together, the results presented in Table 3 indicate that there is a positive

    relationship between executive compensation and broad measures of firm performance

    (ROA and MVA), after controlling for differences in firm size and risk. However, it can be

    argued that a firms competitive position, and hence, its performance, may be a function of

    the extent of its global operations. In a recent survey of U.S. multinational companies only

    6% of the firms did not provide some type of long-term incentive plan (Freedman, 2000).

    However, with higher levels of performance-based pay reportedly being awarded to global

    managers, it is unclear whether differences in performance of global firms will result in

    disparate changes in the pay of global versus domestic managers (Platt, 2002). Clearly, the

    level of international sales has been suggested to have an effect on the components of

    executive compensation.

    To examine the effect of the firms global nature on the pay-for-performance relation-

    ship, we estimate the following model on the subsample of 119 firms for which we were

    able to obtain the ratio of overseas sales to total sales:

    COMPi a0 a1PERFi a2COCi a3FSALESi ei 3where FSALES is the ratio of overseas sales to total sales. Estimates of this models

    parameters are presented in Table 4.

    From Table 4, we find that even after controlling for the extent of the firms global

    nature, there is a significant positive relationship between executive compensation and

    firm performance. Our estimates of the coefficient on performance (a1) are all positive andsignificant except in the case where ROE measures firm performance. Only bonus is

    positively related to ROE in Table 4, whereas salary and TDC are not. We also find that all

    measures of compensation are significantly positively related to EVA for these 119 firms,

    indicating that EVA is an important determinant of compensation for global firms.

    The model in Eq. (3) also allows us to address the issue of whether executive

    compensation is related to the extent of the firms global nature. From Table 4, the

    coefficients on FSALES are significantly different from zero when ROE measures

    performance. Further, when performance is measured by DMVA or ROA, there is asignificant positive relationship only between TDC and FSALES. When performance is

    measured by SEVA, the positive relationship is observed for salary and bonus, but not

    TDC. These results suggest that TDC is higher for executives of firms with a greater global

    presence, but that this relationship is also dependent on how firm performance is

    measured.

    A number of previous studies have discussed the relationship between executive

    compensation and ROA (see for example, Agarwal, 1981; Deckop, 1988; Kroll et al.,

    1990; Leonard, 1990; Pavlik & Belkaoui, 1991; Winn & Shoenhair, 1988). Although EVA

    and MVA are measures of performance more indicative of contribution to shareholderwealth, it is not clear whether these broader measures are better predictors of the cross-

  • A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179168Table 4

    OLS estimates of the relation between compensation and firm performance after controlling for risk, for the

    sample of 119 observations in 1995a

    Compensation

    measure

    a0 a1 a2 a3 F statistic( P value)

    Adjusted

    R2

    Panel A: COMPi = a0 + a1DMVAi + a2COCi + a3FSALESi + eiSalary 0.045

    ( 0.42)0.051**

    (2.30)

    2.042**

    (2.04)

    0.298

    (1.19)

    13.16

    ( < .01)

    .24

    Bonus 0.153 0.040* 2.304** 0.401 (1.18) 6.80 .13sectional variation in executive compensation. To investigate this issue, we estimate the

    following model:

    COMPi a0 a1COCi a2ROAi a3PERFi ei 4

    where PERF is either SEVA, or DMVA.The estimates of this model for the total sample of 1965 observations are presented in

    Table 5. With PERF defined as DMVA, and for all components of compensation, thecoefficients of COC, ROA, and DMVA are positive and significant at the 1% level.

    ( 1.39) (1.69) (2.39) ( < .01)TDC 1.379

    ( 1.37)0.647***

    (7.28)

    12.704

    (1.48)

    4.215***

    (2.91)

    28.70

    ( < .01)

    .41

    Panel B: COMPi = a0 + a1SEVAi + a2COCi + a3FSALESi + eiSalary 0.047

    ( 0.37)0.722***

    (4.36)

    2.061*

    (1.89)

    0.344*

    (1.88)

    12.43

    ( < .01)

    .23

    Bonus 0.037( 0.26)

    1.234***

    (6.09)

    1.134

    (0.91)

    0.400*

    (1.91)

    17.60

    ( < .01)

    .30

    TDC 1.607**( 2.03)

    8.697***

    (3.76)

    14.908**

    (2.05)

    4.856

    (1.61)

    21.36

    ( < .01)

    .34

    Panel C: COMPi = a0 + a1ROEi + a2COCi + a3FSALESi + eiSalary 0.190

    ( 1.43)0.086

    (1.19)

    3.348***

    (2.98)

    0.386*

    (1.96)

    5.78

    ( < .01)

    .11

    Bonus 0.264( 1.65)

    0.172**

    (1.98)

    3.131**

    (2.31)

    0.465*

    (1.96)

    5.40

    ( < .01)

    .10

    TDC 3.222***( 2.74)

    0.370

    (0.58)

    30.519***

    (3.07)

    5.353***

    (3.08)

    7.69

    ( < .01)

    .15

    Panel D: COMPi = a0 + a1ROAi + a2COCi + a3FSALESi + eiSalary 0.750

    ( 0.56)1.250***

    (3.17)

    1.802

    (1.50)

    0.300

    (1.56)

    9.04

    ( < .01)

    .17

    Bonus 0.049( 0.41)

    2.347**

    (2.29)

    0.248

    (0.17)

    0.304

    (1.02)

    13.88

    ( < .01)

    .25

    TDC 1.958*( 1.71)

    13.663***

    (4.02)

    12.570

    (1.21)

    4.387***

    (2.66)

    14.01

    ( < .01)

    .25

    ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.a COMPi is the measure of executive compensation, TDC is total direct compensation, COCi is the cost of

    capital, DMVAi is the change in market value added, SEVAi is the standardized economic value added, ROEi isthe return on equity, ROAi is the return on assets for firm i, and FSALESi is the ratio of overseas sales to total

    sales. t statistics are in parenthesis.

  • A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179 169Table 5

    Tests for the relative explanatory power of performance measures for the sample of 1965 observations between

    1992 and 1995a

    Compensation

    measure

    Intercept COC ROA SEVA DMVA F statistic( P value)

    Adjusted

    R2

    Salary 0.345***( 3.87)

    5.988***

    (7.08)

    0.496**

    (2.41)

    0.109***

    (3.68)

    66.04

    ( < .01)

    .09

    Bonus 0.314***( 4.27)

    4.034***

    (5.47)

    1.459***

    (4.44)

    0.074***

    (3.07)

    97.05

    ( < .01)

    .13

    TDC 4.956***( 5.35)

    50.666***

    (6.02)

    11.813***

    (3.91)

    1.201***

    (3.52)

    111.39

    ( < .01)

    .14

    Salary 0.418***( 4.08)

    6.448***

    (6.74)

    1.388

    (0.95)

    0.949( 0.54)

    36.48

    ( < .01)

    .05

    Bonus 0.343***( 4.54)

    4.609***

    (6.38)

    1.206*

    (1.85)

    0.367

    (0.47)

    66.60

    ( < .01)

    .09

    TDC 5.332***( 5.48)

    61.258***

    (6.13)

    3.399

    (0.56)

    11.025

    (1.31)

    60.53

    ( < .01)

    .08

    Salary 0.372*** 5.222*** 2.297 2.152 0.142*** 66.50 .12Moreover, the adjusted R2 values fall in the range .09.14. When only COC and ROA are

    used as independent variables, the adjusted R2 values are in the range .05.09 (see Panel

    D, Table 3). Thus, it can be concluded that MVA is indeed a significant predictor of cross-

    sectional variations in executive compensation and provides additional information in

    explaining the cross-sectional variation in executive compensation.

    In the second panel of Table 5, PERF is defined as SEVA. Regardless of how executive

    compensation is measured, the firm-size adjusted EVA has no additional explanatory

    power. In fact, the explanatory power of ROA is also virtually eliminated. We suspect that

    this is due to the high correlation between ROA and SEVA (q=.66). The high degree ofmulticolinearity makes interpretation of the significance levels of the models parameters

    difficult. In the last panel of Table 5, performance is defined to encompass all three

    measures of performance (ROA, EVA, and MVA). Once again, while the coefficients on

    SEVA are insignificantly different from zero, those on MVA are significant at the 1%

    level. Since MVA is a measure of the increase in shareholder wealth, our results indicate

    that cross-sectional variation in executive compensation can best be explained by the

    extent to which their actions increase shareholder wealth.

    To further examine the relationship between compensation and firm performance in the

    context of the firms global position, we replicate the analysis presented in Table 5 for the

    ( 3.94) (4.66) (1.34) (1.03) (2.59) ( < .01)Bonus 0.317***

    ( 4.26)3.926***

    (4.96)

    1.713**

    (2.22)

    0.303( 0.34)

    0.079**

    (2.57)

    73.40

    ( < .01)

    .13

    TDC 4.943***( 5.40)

    51.013***

    (5.61)

    10.996*

    (1.74)

    0.976

    (0.12)

    1.186***

    (3.32)

    83.55

    ( < .01)

    .14

    ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.a TDC is total direct compensation, COCi is the cost of capital, DMVAi is the change in market value added,

    SEVAi is the standardized economic value added, and ROAi is the return on assets for firm i. t statistics are in

    parenthesis.

  • sample of 119 observations in 1995 for which we were able to obtain data on the ratio of

    overseas sales to total sales. In Table 6, we report our estimates of the following model:

    COMPi a0 a1COCi a2ROAi a3PERFi a4FSALESi ei 5

    In the first panel, firm performance is measured by MVA. Our estimates of a2 and a3 areall positive and significantly different from zero when firm performance is measured using

    DMVA. These results are similar to those reported in Table 5 for the full sample: MVA is asignificant predictor of cross-sectional variation in executive compensation and provides

    additional explanatory power beyond the traditional accounting measure of performance

    (ROA). Moreover, none of our estimates of a4 (the coefficient on FSALES) are significantin this case. Thus, the pay-for-performance relationship is not dependent on the extent of

    the firms global position if performance is measured by the MVA.

    In the second panel of Table 6, we find that when firm performance is measured by the

    size-adjusted economic value added (SEVA) in addition to ROA, compensation is

    significantly positively related to the former. Thus, unlike the results presented in Table

    5, where we found no significant relationship between compensation and SEVA, a positive

    relationship is observed when we control for the extent of the firms global nature. Finally,

    in the last panel of Table 6, where firm performance is measured by ROA, SEVA, and

    Table 6

    Tests for the relative explanatory power of performance measures for the sample of 119 observations in 1995a

    Compensation

    measure

    Intercept COC ROA SEVA DMVA FSALES F statistic( P value)

    Adjusted

    R2

    A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179170Salary 0.502

    (0.41)

    0.590

    (0.51)

    1.120***

    (3.05)

    0.049***

    (4.48)

    0.222

    (1.25)

    12.92

    ( < .01)

    .29

    Bonus 0.041

    (0.27)

    0.618( 0.45)

    2.254***

    (5.10)

    0.035***

    (2.66)

    0.249

    (1.16)

    12.72

    ( < .01)

    .28

    TDC 0.342( 0.47)

    2.859( 0.30)

    12.004*

    (1.91)

    0.619**

    (2.49)

    3.402

    (1.42)

    29.32

    ( < .01)

    .49

    Salary 0.025( 0.20)

    1.634

    (1.40)

    0.482

    (1.06)

    0.649***

    (3.06)

    0.317*

    (1.71)

    9.61

    ( < .01)

    .23

    Bonus 0.020

    (0.14)

    0.011

    (0.01)

    1.269**

    (2.48)

    0.911***

    (3.84)

    0.328

    (1.58)

    15.34

    ( < .01)

    .33

    TDC 1.388( 1.28)

    10.634

    (1.10)

    4.830

    (1.27)

    7.463***

    (4.23)

    4.852***

    (2.97)

    16.51

    ( < .01)

    .34

    Salary 0.051

    (0.40)

    0.653

    (0.56)

    1.006**

    (2.14)

    0.105

    (0.39)

    0.045***

    (3.16)

    0.231

    (1.28)

    10.29

    ( < .01)

    .28

    Bonus 0.030

    (0.20)

    0.114( 0.08)

    1.335**

    (2.43)

    0.842***

    (2.70)

    0.006

    (0.34)

    0.317

    (1.51)

    12.20

    ( < .01)

    .32

    TDC 0.342( 0.47)

    2.876( 0.29)

    12.036*

    (1.78)

    0.029(0.01)

    0.620***

    (2.10)

    3.400

    (1.49)

    23.25

    ( < .01)

    .49

    ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.a TDC is total direct compensation, COCi is the cost of capital, DMVAi is the change in market value added,

    SEVAi is the standardized economic value added, ROAi is the return on assets for firm i, and FSALES is the ratioof overseas to total sales. t statistics are in parenthesis.

  • A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179 171DMVA, we find that MVA is, in general, a stronger determinant of the cross-sectionalvariation in salary and TDC, but not bonus.

    3.2. Compensation and decision-making

    The evidence presented above suggests that executive compensation is positively

    related to MVA and to a lesser extent to EVA. Since MVA is the present value of future

    expected EVA, and since the relationship between MVA and compensation is strong, why

    then is the relationship between compensation and EVA weaker? To explore this issue

    further, we sort our sample into groups based on SEVA and DMVA. As argued below, thisclassification of the sample enables us to distinguish firms based on their growth

    opportunities and economic returns earned.

    All firms in the sample are ranked independently based on these two variables. The

    sample is then divided into three groups of equal size based on SEVA values. A similar

    partitioning of the sample into three equal-sized groups is carried out using DMVA values.Combinations of rankings based on SEVA andDMVA thus yields nine subsamples. We thenanalyze the following four subsamples further: high SEVA/high DMVA; high SEVA/lowDMVA; low SEVA/high DMVA; low SEVA/low DMVA. We denote these four subsamplesas HH, HL, LH, and LL, respectively (the first letter in the subsample designation refers to

    the SEVA ranking, while the second letter refers to the DMVA ranking).We view these four subsamples in the following manner. The HH subsample consists of

    firms that generate high economic returns with a high market value; firms which may be

    positioned to enjoy a prolonged period of economic rents. The HL subsample firms

    generate high economic return with a relative low market value; firms with limited growth

    prospects and low expected economic profits (an alternative interpretation is that these

    firms are window dressing their current income). The LL subsample represents firms

    whose current and future ability to generate economic profits is severely limited. Finally,

    the LH subsample represents firms with low current profits making investments in

    valuable real options.

    Table 7 provides descriptive statistics on the components of executive compensation for

    these four subsamples. Compensation variables have been normalized by beginning-of-

    year capital to account for firm-size differences. The most striking result from this table is

    the difference in compensation levels between the HH and LL subsamples. For example,

    the average salary of executives in the HH subsample is 0.74, while that for executives in

    the LL subsample is 0.32. Similar differences are observed for all other components of

    salary. All of the differences in compensation between these two subsamples are

    significant at the 1% level.

    These differences in compensation levels suggests that, on average, the compensation

    policy of these firms is rational: executives that generate high economic and market value

    for the firm are compensated significantly higher than executives that do not.

    We next examine the relationship between compensation, EVA and MVA for each of

    the four subsamples. The first four panels of Table 8 report our estimates of the model in

    Eq. (5) using SEVA as the measure of firm performance. The next four panels contain the

    results when DMVA is used as the measure of performance. Results reported in the first

    two panels, the HH and HL subsamples, indicate that the estimates of the coefficients on

  • A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179172SEVA are positive and generally significant. Thus, for firms that generate high economic

    profits, EVA is a significant determinant of compensation.

    The next panel contains results of the regressions for the low SEVA/high DMVAsubsample, i.e., firms making large investments in valuable options with long-term

    Table 7

    Descriptive statistics (means) for subsamples of firms based on SEVA and DMVA valuesa

    High SEVA/high DMVA High SEVA/low DMVA

    N 233 234

    SEVA 0.0968 0.0707

    DMVA 2.4140 0.9965Salary 0.7402 0.4232

    Bonus 0.5832 0.3121

    CashComp 1.3234 0.7353

    TDC 3.2179 1.4199

    Low SEVA/high DMVA Low SEVA/low DMVA

    N 225 198

    SEVA 0.0801 0.0752DMVA 1.2463 0.8697Salary 0.4549 0.3232

    Bonus 0.2406 0.1295

    CashComp 0.6954 0.4527

    TDC 1.4549 0.9646

    a Compensation variables are expressed as percent of BOYCAP.payoffs. For these managers, compensation is negatively correlated with EVA. The

    estimates of the coefficients on SEVA are all negative and significantly so. It appears

    that foregoing opportunities to report higher current-period income results in a compen-

    sation penalty. Moreover, the adjusted R2 values are the highest of all for subsample

    regressions, ranging between .30 and .47. Our results for the LL subsample, reported in the

    fourth panel of Table 8, further indicate that SEVA is not a significant determinant of pay

    for firms limited current or future growth possibilities.

    The next four panels report the estimates of the equation where DMVA is used as ameasure of performance. The results indicate that this measure of performance is, in

    general, positively correlated with compensation, especially for the subsamples where the

    MVA is above average.

    A similar pattern emerges when we include both SEVA and DMVA as performancemeasures for the firm. In Table 9, we report the results of the estimation of the model with

    both explanatory variables (along with a control for risk differences). MVA emerges as a

    significant determinant of compensation in all but the high SEVA/low DMVA subsample.Further, in the subsample where EVA is below average but MVA is above average, the

    results are similar to those presented in Table 8. The estimates of the coefficients on

    DMVA are all significantly positive, while those on SEVA are all significantly negative,i.e., higher SEVA brings in a compensation penalty, but higher DMVA is rewarded(Further, the adjusted R2 values are the highest of all four subsamples.) These results

    therefore run counter to the argument that managers are rewarded for myopic behavior.

  • Table 8

    SEVA and DMVA regressions for HH/HL/LH/LL groups (3 3 sorting, only 4 used in estimation)Salary Bonus TDC Salary Bonus TDC

    High SEVA/high DMVA High SEVA/low DMVA

    N 233 233 233 234 234 234

    Intercept 0.539( 1.40)

    0.630( 1.50)

    3.972( 1.44)

    0.020

    (0.11)

    0.207( 1.09)

    1.823**( 1.70)

    COC 0.094***

    (3.15)

    0.084**

    (2.59)

    0.509**

    (2.38)

    0.025**

    (1.76)

    0.029**

    (1.95)

    0.227**

    (2.57)

    SEVA 0.606

    (1.21)

    1.240**

    (2.28)

    6.144**

    (1.72)

    1.191***

    (3.29)

    2.099***

    (5.52)

    5.328**

    (2.21)

    F statistic

    ( P value)

    6.92

    ( < .01)

    7.64

    ( < .01)

    5.50

    ( < .01)

    8.32

    ( < .01)

    19.83

    ( < .01)

    11.08

    ( < .01)

    Adjusted R2 .05 .05 .04 .06 .14 .08

    Low SEVA/high DMVA Low SEVA/low DMVA

    N 225 225 225 198 198 198

    Intercept 2.035**( 2.26)

    1.077**( 2.49)

    6.436**( 2.45)

    0.330***( 2.83)

    0.276**( 2.11)

    2.186**( 2.44)

    COC 0.062**

    (2.54)

    0.061***

    (2.62)

    0.276***

    (2.74)

    0.052***

    (4.48)

    0.039***

    (3.89)

    0.279***

    (4.02)

    SEVA 22.507**( 1.98)

    8.031( 1.62)

    60.388**( 1.87)

    0.480( 0.79)

    0.796

    (1.17)

    1.843

    (0.40)

    F statistic

    ( P value)

    101.72

    ( < .01)

    49.46

    ( < .01)

    74.07

    ( < .01)

    17.84

    ( < .01)

    8.08

    ( < .01)

    8.12

    ( < .01)

    Adjusted R2 .47 .30 .39 .15 .07 .07

    High SEVA/high DMVA High SEVA/low DMVA

    N 233 233 233 234 234 234

    Intercept 0.317( 0.86)

    0.542( 1.29)

    2.289( 0.87)

    0.007( 0.04)

    0.254( 1.27)

    1.943**( 1.72)

    COC 0.063**

    (2.16)

    0.074**

    (2.25)

    0.272

    (1.32)

    0.032**

    (2.13)

    0.038**

    (2.34)

    0.252***

    (2.70)

    SEVA 0.103***

    (4.86)

    0.070***

    (2.91)

    0.825***

    (5.50)

    0.032( 0.75)

    0.092**( 1.99)

    0.184( 0.53)

    F statistic

    ( P value)

    18.61

    ( < .01)

    9.34

    ( < .01)

    19.60

    ( < .01)

    3.07

    (.05)

    6.09

    ( < .01)

    7.03

    ( < .01)

    Adjusted R2 .13 .07 .14 .02 .04 .05

    Low SEVA/high DMVA Low SEVA/low DMVA

    N 225 225 225 198 198 198

    Intercept 1.494***( 2.84)

    0.904***( 3.56)

    5.039***( 3.17)

    0.236**( 2.15)

    0.218**( 1.70)

    1.783**( 2.02)

    COC 0.007

    (0.15)

    0.040**

    (1.79)

    0.123

    (0.89)

    0.054***

    (4.57)

    0.041***

    (4.10)

    0.288***

    (4.17)

    SEVA 1.503***

    (7.74)

    0.565***

    (6.03)

    4.115***

    (7.02)

    0.087

    (1.38)

    0.157**

    (2.57)

    0.745**

    (1.77)

    F statistic

    ( P value)

    31.76

    ( < .01)

    23.26

    ( < .01)

    27.69

    ( < .01)

    18.99

    ( < .01)

    10.89

    ( < .01)

    9.72

    ( < .01)

    Adjusted R2 .22 .17 .19 .15 .09 .08

    A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179 173

  • Table 9

    SEVA and DMVA regressions for HH/HL/LH/LL groups (3 3 sorting, only 4 used in estimation)

    A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179174Salary Bonus TDC Salary Bonus TDC

    High SEVA/high DMVA High SEVA/low DMVA

    N 233 233 233 234 234 234

    Intercept 0.323( 0.68)

    0.540( 1.29)

    2.326( 1.41)

    0.020

    (0.11)

    0.208( 1.10)

    1.825**( 1.69)

    COC 0.066**

    (1.67)

    0.073**

    (2.20)

    0.296**

    (2.12)

    0.024

    (1.64)

    0.025

    (1.61)

    0.220**

    (2.44)

    SEVA 1.330( 1.49)

    0.436

    (0.63)

    8.586( 0.92)

    1.174***

    (3.21)

    2.032***

    (5.32)

    5.211**

    (2.36)

    DMVA 0.139***(2.68)

    0.058**

    (1.89)

    1.060**

    (1.93)

    0.015( 0.36)

    0.063( 1.43)

    0.110( 0.36)

    F statistic

    ( P value)

    14.25

    ( < .01)

    6.35

    ( < .01)

    14.59

    ( < .01)

    5.57

    ( < .01)

    13.96

    ( < .01)

    7.45

    ( < .01)

    Adjusted R2 .15 .06 .15 .06 .14 .08Rather, they are consistent with the argument that executive compensation is closely linked

    to shareholder value creation.

    Taken together, the results presented in Tables 79 indicate executive compensation

    levels are related to the level of EVA and MVA generated by the firm. Moreover, both

    EVA and MVA as measures of firm performance help explain the cross-sectional

    variation of compensation within and across subsamples formed on the basis of the

    levels of EVA and MVA generated. In all cases, except for the high SEVA/low DMVAsubsample, compensation is significantly positively related to DMVA. More importantly,when MVA is high, compensation can be a negative function of EVA. This negative

    relationship suggests that for firms with valuable growth options, those managers that

    create value through these options are compensated in proportion to the value created.

    Those managers that forego the opportunities in favor of improving current-period EVA

    are penalized.1

    Low SEVA/high DMVA Low SEVA/low DMVA

    N 225 225 225 198 198 198

    Intercept 2.486***( 2.67)

    1.253***( 2.82)

    7.689***( 2.80)

    0.265**( 2.52)

    0.151( 1.10)

    1.603**( 1.69)

    COC 0.016

    (0.50)

    0.043

    (1.62)

    0.147

    (1.24)

    0.053***

    (4.48)

    0.042***

    (4.17)

    0.289***

    (4.19)

    SEVA 19.821**( 2.16)

    6.983**( 1.72)

    52.929**( 2.02)

    0.410( 0.68)

    0.931

    (1.38)

    2.472

    (0.53)

    DMVA 0.947**(2.55)

    0.370**

    (1.92)

    2.630**

    (2.16)

    0.084

    (1.30)

    0.164***

    (2.67)

    0.762**

    (1.80)

    F statistic

    ( P value)

    91.84

    ( < .01)

    41.71

    ( < .01)

    64.54

    ( < .01)

    12.78

    ( < .01)

    7.93

    ( < .01)

    6.55

    ( < .01)

    Adjusted R2 .55 .35 .46 .15 .10 .08

    1 While it would be interesting to replicate the results in Tables 8 and 9 in the context of the firms global

    presence, the limited sample size (119) for which we have data on FSALES prevents us from doing so.

  • 3.3. Compensation and the reward/incentive hypothesis

    Finally, we examine whether executive compensation serves as a reward for

    managerial effort based on superior past performance or as an incentive for improved

    future firm performance. These tests are conducted using lagged and leading values of

    firm performance. If compensation rewards managers for superior performance in the

    current period only, then neither the lagged nor the leading values of firm performance

    would be significant in explaining current period compensation. If compensation rewards

    managers for prior superior performance, then only the lagged performance variables

    would be significant. Conversely, if compensation is used to motivate managers to

    improve performance in the future, only the leading values of performance would be

    significant.

    We examine compensation on two lagged and two leading values of SEVA and DMVAafter controlling for differences in firm risk. Since a total of 5 years of firm performance is

    A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179 175required to test this hypothesis, the sample size is reduced to 1871 observations. We use

    the compensation data from 2 years (1992 and 1993). Thus, year t is defined as one of

    these 2 years and lagged and leading measures of performance are measured relative to

    this base year. We estimate the following model:

    COMPi;t a0 a1COCi;t a2PERFi;t2 a3PERFi;t1 a4PERFi;t a5PERFi;t1 a6PERFi;t2 ei 6

    Table 10 presents the estimates of this models parameters using SEVA as the measure

    of firm performance. The estimates of the coefficients on contemporaneous and lagged

    values of SEVA are insignificantly different from zero. Thus, at least when firm

    performance is measured by SEVA, there is no evidence to support that compensation

    rewards managers for past or current performance. However, the results reported in Table

    10 provide limited support for the incentive pay hypothesis. The estimates of a5 arepositive and significant for the cash components of compensation (salary and bonus).

    Table 10

    Test of the reward/incentive hypothesis for EVA as a determinant of compensation, for the sample 1871

    observations in 1992 and 1993a

    Salary Bonus TDC

    Intercept 1.776*** ( 4.38) 1.497*** ( 4.65) 6.073*** ( 3.98)COCt 0.373*** (9.65) 0.258*** (8.51) 1.167*** (7.80)

    SEVAt 2 3.937 (1.52) 1.485 (0.90) 1.609 (0.24)SEVAt 1 0.760 (0.00) 2.205 (0.00) 10.039 (0.00)SEVAt 7.345 ( 0.71) 1.352 (0.42) 16.390 ( 0.69)SEVAt + 1 12.255** (1.80) 7.893*** (2.92) 7.002 (0.40)

    SEVAt + 2 4.485** ( 2.07) 0.139 ( 0.11) 15.677** (2.17)F statistic ( P value) 38.45 ( < .01) 48.72 ( < .01) 9.72 ( < .01)

    Adjusted R2 .11 .13 .03

    ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.at statistics are in parenthesis.

  • DMVAt 2 0.072 (1.34) 0.170*** (2.87) 0.516** (2.27)DMVA 0.254 (0.00) 0.224 (0.00) 0.171 (0.00)

    A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179176Moreover, the estimate of a6 is also significantly greater than zero for total compensation,but not for bonus, and in fact is significantly negative for salary. Thus, at least in the short

    run, salary and bonus act as incentives for maximizing EVA, while TDC does so in the

    longer term.

    In Table 11, we present the estimates of the model using DMVA as the measure of firmperformance. Our estimates of the coefficient on DMVA0 (a4) are positive and signifi-cantly different from zero for all three measures of compensation. Thus, executives are

    rewarded for maximizing current period MVA. Moreover, the estimates of the coefficients

    on DMVAt 2 (a2) are also positive and significantly different from zero for bonus andTDC. These results are therefore consistent with the hypothesis that compensation rewards

    managers for current and past performance measured in terms of the shareholder wealth

    added.

    The coefficients on the leading terms of DMVA (a5 and a6) are insignificant for salaryand bonus. However, we find a significant positive relationship between TDC and

    t 1DMVA0 0.532** (1.73) 0.673*** (3.72) 2.687*** (3.00)DMVAt + 1 0.054 (0.29) 0.058 ( 0.24) 2.450*** ( 2.74)DMVAt + 2 0.280 (1.55) 0.059 (0.28) 2.172*** (2.95)F statistic ( P value) 55.82 ( < .01) 102.79 ( < .01) 59.84 ( < .01)

    R2 .15 .25 .16

    ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.at statistics are in parenthesis.Table 11

    Test of the reward/incentive hypothesis for MVA as a determinant of compensation, for the sample 1871

    observations in 1992 and 1993a

    Salary Bonus TDC

    Intercept 1.537*** ( 2.71) 1.732*** ( 4.00) 9.697*** ( 5.00)COCt 0.264*** (5.49) 0.172*** (4.93) 0.832*** (5.12)DMVAt + 2, as evidenced by our estimates of a6. Since TDC includes salary, bonus, andother noncash compensation, the significance of the coefficient in the TDC regression is

    driven by the noncash components of compensation. Since the noncash component

    includes stock options granted to executives, the value of these options increases with

    the market value of the firm, resulting in higher executive compensation.

    Taken together, our results suggest that executives are rewarded for their efforts to

    create economic and market value for the firm. Further, their compensation also acts as an

    incentive for creating additional market value in the future.

    4. Summary and conclusions

    In this study, we examine the relationship between executive compensation and

    measures of performance capturing the economic profit earned by the firm (EVA and

    MVA). Consistent with prior studies examining top manager compensation, we deseg-

    regate the compensation package of top managers into cash, merit pay (bonus), and TDC,

  • A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179 177which includes long-term incentives such as stock options. We also investigate the causal

    direction between the wealth creation activities of the firm and the compensation of its top

    managers.

    We document that executive compensation is positively related to the level of risk borne

    by the firm. We find that the MVA to the firm is a significant determinant of executive

    compensation. Comparing traditional measures of firm performance and MVA, we find

    that including MVA in assessing executive compensation provides additional information

    about the nature of top manager compensation. In general, we find that EVA and MVA are

    better predictors of cross-sectional variation in top manager pay than traditional perform-

    ance measures such as ROA, although the relationship between EVA and compensation is

    found to be weaker.

    We also examine whether executive compensation is an increasing function of the

    extent of the firms global activities measured by the ratio of overseas sales to total sales.

    We find that, in general, the basic pay-for-performance relationship is unaffected by the

    extent of the firms global activities. However, we also present limited evidence, albeit

    based on a smaller sample, that executives of firms with significant overseas operations

    enjoy somewhat higher compensation.

    Perhaps one of the most significant findings of our study is arrived at when we divide

    our sample firms into four groups based on their rankings of market and EVA. By

    grouping firms into cohorts based on relative levels of performance for both performance

    measures, we identified four distinct groups. The performance cohorts may be referred to

    as winners (high MVA and EVA), losers (low MVA and EVA), holders of real

    options (high MVA/low EVA), and problem children (low MVA/high EVA). We find

    that when EVA is achieved at the expense of MVA (i.e., the problem children group),

    such behavior brings in a compensation penalty. Accordingly, it can be inferred that

    compensation contracts are generally set in a manner that encourages managers to act in

    the long-term interest of the shareholders, even when doing so may mean lower short-

    term profits.

    Finally, we assess whether top manager pay is an incentive for future performance or

    reward for past behavior. Our evidence suggests that top managers are not only incented to

    increase the EVA of the firm, but also rewarded for current and past additions to MVA. We

    also assess the causal direction of the pay-for-performance relationship. We demonstrate

    that achieving superior wealth creation for owners is accomplished by linking top manager

    pay to the economic value created in the current period and by the ability of managers to

    signal the marketplace about the progress (real options) being created by the firm for future

    periods. Thus, our study indicates that the best wealth-creating top managers are

    responsible for multidimensional behavior of the firmEVA additions today as well as

    in the future (and hence, MVA).

    An interesting extension of our work would consider including additional information

    regarding analysts estimates of future earnings as a measure of future MVA performance.

    This would help clarify whether the marketplace expects the performance of winners, or

    executives are rewarded for performance surprises. Further, while we provide small

    sample-based evidence of the pay-for-performance relationship in an international envi-

    ronment, extending this study would help assess whether compensation plans for interna-tional managers can be structured in the same manner as for domestic managers.

  • A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179178References

    Agarwal, N. (1981). Determinants of executive compensation. Industrial Relations, 20(1), 3645.

    Becker, G. (1964). Human capital. New York: National Bureau for Economic Research.

    Carpenter, M., Sanders, W., & Gregersen, H. (2001). Building human capital with organizational context: the

    impact of international assignments experience on multinational firm performance and CEO pay. Academy of

    Management Journal, 44(3), 493511.

    Copeland, T., Koller, T., & Murrin, J. (1995). Valuation: measuring and managing the value of companies. New

    York: Wiley.

    Deckop, J. R. (1988). Determinants of chief executive officer compensation. Industrial and Labor Relations

    Review, 41(2), 215226.

    Demski, J. S., & Sappington, D. E. (1989). Hierarchical structure and responsibility accounting. Journal of

    Accounting Research, 27(1), 4058.

    Dodd, J. L., & Chen, S. (1996). EVA: a new panacea? Business and Economic Review, 42(4), 2628.

    Dodd, J. L., & Johns, J. (1999). EVA reconsidered. Business and Economic Review, 45(3), 1318.

    Fama, E. (1980). Agency problems and the theory of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 88, 288307.

    Freedman, R. (2000). Long-term incentive plans: U.S. multinational firms erase the borders. Journal of Com-

    pensation and Benefits, 16(5), 2628.

    Gomez-Mejia, L., Tosi, H., & Hinkin, T. (1987). Managerial control, performance and executive compensation.

    Academy of Management Journal, 30(1), 5170.

    Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. (1983). An analysis of the principal agent problem. Econometrica, 51, 745.

    Hadlock, C. J., & Lumer, G. B. (1997). Compensation, turnover, and top management incentives: historical

    evidence. Journal of Business, 70(2), 153187.

    Hall, B., & Liebman, J. B. (1998). Are CEOs really paid like bureaucrats? Quarterly Journal of Economics,

    113(2), 653691.

    Harris, M., & Raviv, A. (1979). Optimal incentive contracts with imperfect information. Journal of Economic

    Theory, 20, 231259.

    Hodak, M. (1994). How EVA can help turn mid-sized firms into large companies. Journal of Applied Corporate

    Finance, 98102.

    Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership

    structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305360.

    Jensen, M., & Murphy, K. (1990). Performance pay and top-management incentives. Journal of Political

    Economy, 98(2), 225264.

    Kramer, J. K., & Peters, J. R. (2001). An interindustry analysis of economic value added as a proxy for market

    value added. Journal of Applied Finance, 11(1), 4149.

    Kroll, M., Simmons, S., & Wright, P. (1990). Determinants of CEO compensation following major acquisitions.

    Journal of Business Research, 20, 349366.

    Lehn, K., & Makhija, A. (1996, May/June). EVA and MVA as performance measures and signals for strategic

    change. Strategy and Leadership, 3438.

    Leonard, J. S. (1990). Executive pay and firm performance. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43,

    1329.

    Mehran, H. (1995). Executive compensation structure, ownership and firm performance. Journal of Financial

    Economics, 38(2), 163184.

    Miller, D. (1995). CEO salary increases may be rational after all: referents and contracts in CEO pay. Academy of

    Management Journal, 38(5), 13611385.

    Murphy, K. J. (1985). Corporate performance and managerial remuneration: an empirical analysis. Journal of

    Accounting and Economics, 7, 1142.

    Pavlik, E. L., & Belkaoui, A. (1991). Determinants of executive compensation. Westport, CT: Quorum Books.

    Platt, G. (2002). CEOs find performance does matter. Global Finance, 16(4), 2627.

    Porac, J., Wade, J., & Pollock, T. (1999). Industry categories and the politics of the comparable firm in CEO

    compensation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44(1), 112144.

    Rappaport, A. (1986). Creating shareholder value: the new standard for business performance. New York: Free

    Press.

  • Richard, J. (2000). Global executive compensation: a look at the future. Compensation and Benefits Review,

    32(3), 3538.

    Shiely, J. (1996). Is value management the answer? Chief Executive, 119, 5457.

    Spinner, K. (1995, November). Signed and sealedbut can EVA deliver? CFO Magazine, 9395.

    Stewart, G. (1991). The quest for value: a guide for senior managers. New York, NY: Harper Collins.

    Tosi, H., Werner, S., Katz, J., & Gomez-Mejia, L. (2000). How much does performance matter? A meta-analysis

    of CEO pay studies. Journal of Management, 26(2), 301339.

    Tully, S. (1993, September). The real key to creating value. Fortune, 3844.

    Uyemura, D. G., Kantor, C. C., & Pettit, J. M. (1996, Summer). EVA for banks: value creation, risk management,

    and profitability management. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 94113.

    Weaver, S. C. (2001). Measuring economic value added: a survey of the practices of EVA proponents. Journal of

    Applied Finance, 11(1), 5060.

    Werner, S., & Tosi, H. L. (1995). The effect of ownership on compensation strategy and managerial pay.

    Academy of Management Journal, 38(6), 16721691.

    White, H. (1980). A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direst test for heteroskedas-

    ticity. Econometrica, 48, 817838.

    Winn, D., & Shoenhair, J. D. (1988). Compensation-based (dis)incentives for revenue-maximizing behavior: a

    test of the revised Baumol Hypothesis. Review of Economics and Statistics, 154158.

    A. Fatemi et al. / Global Finance Journal 14 (2003) 159179 179

    Wealth creation and managerial pay: MVA and EVA as determinants of executive compensationIntroductionDataResultsDeterminants of executive compensationCompensation and decision-makingCompensation and the reward/incentive hypothesis

    Summary and conclusionsReferences