16
139 Economic AnAlysis & Policy, Vol. 43 no. 2, sEPtEmbEr 2013 Who Benefits from Tax Evasion? 1 James Alm 2 and Keith Finlay Department of Economics, Tulane University, 6823 St. Charles Avenue, 208 Tilton Hall, New Orleans, LA 70118 U.S.A. (Email: [email protected]) Abstract: In this paper, we examine the distributional effects of tax evasion, using results from theoretical, experimental, empirical, and especially the general equilibrium literatures on tax evasion. Much – if not all – of this evidence concludes that the main beneficiaries of successful tax evasion are the tax evaders themselves, with distributional effects that largely favor higher income individuals. However, when general equilibrium adjustments in commodity and factor prices are considered, the distributional effects become considerably more complicated. The work on tax compliance is also put in the broader context of the distributional effects of other types of criminal activities, where similar forces seem to be at work. We conclude with some suggestions for future research. I. InTroducTIon Who benefits from tax evasion? Answering this question may seem obvious: the evader (if successful of course) would seem to keep the evaded income in its entirety and so would seem to be the beneficiary of tax evasion. Indeed, the standard Allingham and Sandmo (1972) approach to the analysis of tax evasion is based on this implicit assumption, and much of the analysis of tax evasion, whether theoretical, experimental, or empirical, relies upon it. However, this assumption is likely to be incorrect, or least incomplete. The act of tax evasion sets in motion a range of adjustments, as individuals and firms react to the changes in incentives created by evasion. These adjustments lead in turn to factor and commodity price changes, which generate subsequent factor and commodity movements in a full general equilibrium setting. All of these adjustments affect the final prices of factors and commodities that determine the true distributional effects of evasion, and a full analysis of the distributional effects must recognize and incorporate these general equilibrium adjustments. In this paper we examine previous efforts to analyze the distributional effects of taxation, focusing on studies that fail to consider these various general equilibrium adjustments and, especially, those that do. We argue that, once these general equilibrium adjustments are 1 This paper is based on a keynote address at the conference “The Shadow Economy, Tax Evasion and Money Laundering” held in Münster, Germany at the university of Münster in July 2011. 2 corresponding author.

Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

139

Economic AnAlysis & Policy, Vol. 43 no. 2, sEPtEmbEr 2013

Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1

James Alm2 and Keith FinlayDepartment of Economics, Tulane University,

6823 St. Charles Avenue, 208 Tilton Hall, New Orleans, LA 70118

U.S.A. (Email: [email protected])

Abstract: Inthispaper,weexaminethedistributionaleffectsoftaxevasion,usingresultsfromtheoretical,experimental,empirical,andespeciallythegeneralequilibriumliteraturesontaxevasion.Much–ifnotall–ofthisevidenceconcludesthatthemainbeneficiariesofsuccessfultaxevasionarethetaxevadersthemselves,withdistributionaleffectsthatlargelyfavorhigherincomeindividuals.However,whengeneralequilibriumadjustmentsin commodity and factor prices are considered, the distributional effects becomeconsiderablymorecomplicated.Theworkontaxcomplianceisalsoputinthebroadercontextofthedistributionaleffectsofothertypesofcriminalactivities,wheresimilarforcesseemtobeatwork.Weconcludewithsomesuggestionsforfutureresearch.

I.InTroducTIon

Whobenefitsfromtaxevasion?Answeringthisquestionmayseemobvious:theevader(ifsuccessfulofcourse)wouldseemtokeeptheevadedincomeinitsentiretyandsowouldseemtobethebeneficiaryoftaxevasion.Indeed,thestandardAllinghamandSandmo(1972)approachtotheanalysisoftaxevasionisbasedonthisimplicitassumption,andmuchoftheanalysisoftaxevasion,whethertheoretical,experimental,orempirical,reliesuponit.However,thisassumptionislikelytobeincorrect,orleastincomplete.Theactoftaxevasionsetsinmotionarangeofadjustments,asindividualsandfirmsreacttothechangesinincentivescreatedbyevasion.Theseadjustmentsleadinturntofactorandcommoditypricechanges,whichgeneratesubsequentfactorandcommoditymovementsinafullgeneralequilibriumsetting.Allof theseadjustmentsaffect thefinalpricesof factorsandcommodities thatdeterminethetruedistributionaleffectsofevasion,andafullanalysisofthedistributionaleffectsmustrecognizeandincorporatethesegeneralequilibriumadjustments.

Inthispaperweexaminepreviouseffortstoanalyzethedistributionaleffectsoftaxation,focusingonstudiesthatfailtoconsiderthesevariousgeneralequilibriumadjustmentsand,especially, those that do.We argue that, once these general equilibrium adjustments are

1 Thispaperisbasedonakeynoteaddressattheconference“TheShadowEconomy,TaxEvasionandMoneyLaundering”heldinMünster,GermanyattheuniversityofMünsterinJuly2011.

2 correspondingauthor.

Page 2: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

Who bEnEfits from tAx EVAsion?

140

recognized,itisnolongerobviousthatthosewhobenefitfromtaxevasionaretheindividualsactuallyengaginginevasion;indeed,theseparticipantsmaynotbenefitatall.Becausesuccessfultaxevasiongeneratesimmediatewinners,comparabletoa“taxadvantage”(Martinez-Vazquez1996)generatedbythetaxlaws,replicationandcompetitionviathemobilityoffactorsandproductsshouldworktowardtheeliminationofthisadvantage.Thisgeneralequilibriumprocessofadjustmentshouldinturnaffecttherelativepricesoffactorsandcommoditiesasresourcesmoveintoandoutoftherelevantactivities,andthesechangesshouldtendtoeliminate,oratleasttoreduce,theinitialtaxadvantageoftaxevasion.

Thesetypesofgeneralequilibriumeffectsarenottypicallyconsideredinthestandardapproachtotaxevasion.Thisomissionconsiderablyweakenstheoverallrelevanceof thestandardapproach,atleastinitsconclusionsaboutthedistributionaleffectsoftaxevasion.considerasoneexampletaxevasionbydomestichelp,suchashousecleaners,babysitters,andyardcareworkers.Taxevasionheremayactuallybenefitthehigher-incomehouseholdshiringtheseservicesbecausethesehouseholdscanpaylowerpricesfortheservices.However,these(andother)typesofadjustmentsareoftenignored.

Evenso,itisnoteworthythatthesetypesofadjustmentshaveoftenbeenrecognizedinthemoregeneralcrimeliterature,ofwhichtaxevasionisadirectoffshoot.Forexample,thereisconsiderableempiricalworkthatdemonstratestheimpactofcrimeonthepriceofhousing.Similarly, theeffectsofcrimeonthepricesofconsumergoodsoronjobopportunitiesinhigh-crimeurbanareasarewell-recognized,asistheimpactofgreaterpoliceenforcementeffortsontheseneighborhoods.Thisresearchoncriminalactivitiesbroadlyhastodatehadlittleimpactonthenarrowerworkontaxevasion.

Inthispaperweanalyzethedistributionaleffectsofcrimegenerallyandoftaxevasionspecifically,focusingonthepriceeffectsofthegeneralequilibriumadjustmentsthataresetinmotionbytheseactivities.Inthefollowingsections,wediscusssignificantpreviousresearchontheincidenceofcrimeandoftaxevasion,highlightingespeciallysomeoftheerrorsthatresearchers – including us – can commitwhen they fail to consider general equilibriumadjustmentsandindicatingwhat“essentialelements”areneededinanappropriatemodel.Wethenpresentsomeofourownworkthatdemonstrateshowsomeofthese“essentialelements”canbeintroducedandwhatthesedifferentapproachescanilluminate.Wefinishwithsomesuggestionsforwaystoextendevenfurtherthesegeneralequilibriummodels.

II.SoMErELATEdWork

2.1 The Basic Portfolio Model of Tax Evasion

Intheiroriginalwork,AllinghamandSandmo(1972)appliedtheBecker(1968)economics-of-crimemodeldirectlytotaxevasion.3Theirbasicmodelisessentiallya“portfolio”approachtoincometaxevasion,inwhicharationalindividualcomparestheexpectedutilityofbeingdetectedandpayingapenaltyontaxevasiontotheexpectedutilityfrombeingabletokeeptheevadedincome.Theincidenceoftaxevasioninthisformulationissimple:thesuccessful

3 Seecowell(1990),Andreoni,Erard,andFeinstein(1998),SlemrodandYitzhaki(2002),andTorgler(2007)forcomprehensivesurveysoftheevasionliterature.SeeespeciallyAlm(2012)andSandmo(2012)forrecentdiscussionsandassessments.

Page 3: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

JAmEs Alm And KEith finlAy

141

evaderbenefitsexclusivelybykeepingtheevadedincomeinitsentirety.However,thisapproachignoresmarketforcesthatworktowardtheeliminationofthetaxadvantagecreatedbyevasionopportunities,asproductsandresourcesflowintoandoutofaffectedactivitiesandtherebychangebothcommodityandfactorprices.ourcentralthemeisthattheseforcescanonlybeanalyzedinageneralequilibriumframework.

However,thisportfoliomodelanditsmanyextensionsassumethattheunderlying“prices”(orincomeinthesimplestformofthemodel)arefixedandexogenous.Thismodelalsodoesnotconsiderthebroadereconomiccontextinwhichtheindividualmakestheevasiondecisions,includingthewaysinwhichtheindividualmayspendhisorher(evaded)income.Ageneralequilibriumframeworkisneededtoconsidertheseessentialelements.

2.2 Some Extensions

Severalstudieshaveinfactexaminedtaxevasion(andcloselyrelatedissuesliketheso-called“undergroundeconomy”)withsuchageneralequilibriumapproach,buildinguponthemodeloriginallypioneeredbyHarberger(1962).Inperhapsthemostcompleteanalysisofgeneralequilibriumeffectsofincometaxevasion,kesselman(1989)developsamulti-consumer,multi-sectorgeneralequilibriummodel,whichallowshimtomakequalitativeandquantitativeassessmentsoftheeffectsoftaxratechangesonevasionactivity,relativeoutputprices,andrealtaxrevenues.despitethemanyinsightsfromthiswork,includingtheanalysisofthedistributionaleffectsoftaxesviatheintroductionofindividualheterogeneitywithmultipleconsumers,kesselman(1989)doesnotallowforuncertaintyinindividualevasiondecisions.

Someotherworkallowsforsuchuncertainty.Forexample,Watson(1985)analyzesamodelwithtwolabormarketsthatofferdifferingevasionpossibilities,inordertoexaminetheeffectsofchangesintax,penalty,andauditratesontheallocationoflaboracrosslabormarkets.However,Watson(1985)modelsonlylabor(andnotcapital)markets,whichmeansthathecannotexaminethefullrangeofgeneralequilibriumpriceandincidenceeffectsthatevasionmaycreate.Indeed,Watson(1985,243)himselfwritesthat“…wehavenotdiscussedthepotentialinequitiesproducedbyevasion”.

LikeWatson(1985),Thalmann(1992)introducesuncertaintyintotheindividualevasiondecision. Inhisgeneralequilibriumframework, taxesareevadedwhenresourcesrelocatefromthe“reported”sectortothe“unreported”sector.ofsomerelevancetosomeofourlaterdiscussion,Thalmann(1992)usesanovelapproachthatrelegatestheuncertaintyofreturnsassociatedwithtaxevasiontothebudgetconstraintratherthanfollowingtheusualexpectedutilityapproach.However,Thalmann(1992)assumesasingle“representative”agent,andsoheisnotabletoexaminethedistributionaleffectsofevasion.4

2.3. Instructive Work from the Crime Literature

Toillustrateintheorytheeffectsofcrimeinageneralequilibriumsetting,considerasimplemetropolitanspatialeconomywithtwocities,populatedwithresidentsofsimilarpreferences

4 SeealsoJung,Snow,andTrandel(1993)anddavidson,Martin,andWilson(2007).

Page 4: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

Who bEnEfits from tAx EVAsion?

142

butdivided into two incomegroups that segregate throughTiebout (1956)mobility.5 Inthissetting,crimecanbeseenassimilartomanyotherurbanamenities.nowsupposethatthereisanexogenous,across-the-boardincreaseincrime.TheTieboutsegregationwillbeassociatedwithadifferentialwillingness-to-pay(WTP)toreducetheincreaseincrime.Forexample,supposethatresidentsoftherichcityhaveagreaterWTPtoreducecrime.Asaresult,therichcitywillinvestrelativelymoreinadditionalpolice(paidforbyapropertytax)tocombatthecrimerise,andsotherewillbearelativelygreaterreductionincrimeintherichcity.

HeterogeneityinWTPwillthencreateacrimedifferential,thesizeofwhichwillbeaffectedbythemarginalproductivityofpoliceandthemagnitudeofcrimechasingandcrimecapturingexternalities.Thedifferentialwillcausesomeresidentsofthepoorcitytomovetotherichcity.Thismigrationwillincreasedemandforhousingintherichcity,causingrentstoriseintherichcityandtofallinthepoorcity.Therentdifferentialwillfurthercausesomehousingcapital tomovefromthepoortotherichcityuntilhousingrentsarebackinequilibrium.Thisgeneralequilibriumresponsewillincreaserentsinthepoorcity,andwillexacerbatetheutilityreductionassociatedwiththerelativecrimeincreaseinthepoorcity.Finally,althoughpropertytaxeswillhaveriseninbothcitiestopayfortheincreaseinpolice,theincreasewillbegreaterintherichcitygivenitsresidents’higherWTPforreducedcrime.

Thesegeneralequilibriumresponseshaveimportantdistributionalimplications.Givenauniformincreaseincrime,richerresidentswillbebetterabletorespondgiventheirhigherWTP.However,byspendingmoreonpolice,theywillnonethelessbearacost.Thus,ascrime-avoidingactivitiesvaryacrossincomegroups,lesscrimeagainstonegroupmayreflectgreateravoidancebehavior,ratherthanalowerburdenofcrime.

Thegeneral equilibrationof rents in themetropolitanareawill further exacerbate theutilitydeclineinthepoorcity.Asinanysimilarmodel,ownersofimmobileassetswillbearthefullburdenofthecrimeincreaseifallotherfactorsaremobile,andsolandownersinthepoorcitywillloserelativelymorewealth.Insofaraspropertyownershipisevenlydistributedthroughoutthemetropolitanarea,thiswillfurtherburden(land-owning)residentsinthepoorcity.Iflocalresidentsdonotownthelandinthepoorcity,thenthedistributionalimpactislessclear(i.e.,itcouldshiftsomeoftheburdentotherich).Themoremobilearehousingcapitalandresidents,thelessutilitylosswillbeexperiencedbythemarginalrentersintheeconomy.6

Allofthesegeneralequilibriumresponsesclearlydependonthespecificmodelstructure.Evenso,thebroaderpointisthattheseadjustmentsaffectthedistributionofincomeinwaysthatthecrimeliteraturehasconsideredandanalyzedtheoreticallyusingageneralequilibriumframework.

Thecrime literaturehasalsoconsideredandanalyzedempirically thesedistributionaleffects.Indeed,alargeliteratureconsidersthelocaleffectofcrime(ortheperceptionofcrimerisk)onhousingprices.Theempiricalchallengehereistoidentifythecausaleffectofcrime

5 Forgeneralequilibriumtreatmentsofcrime,seeFurlong(1987),Imrohorogolu,Merlo,andrupert(2000,andBurdett,Lagos,andWright(2003).

6 Thereareotherfactorsthatmayaffectthedistributionaleffects,suchasinterjurisdictionalspilloversofpoliceinvestment,moregeneralexternalitiesofcrimethatmayaffectthemovementsofpeopleandcapitalinthemetropolitanarea(e.g.,thespatialmismatchofWilson(1987),andthe“brokenwindows”theoryofWilsonandkelling(1982)).

Page 5: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

JAmEs Alm And KEith finlAy

143

onpriceswithouttheconfoundingeffectsofotherneighborhoodcharacteristicsthatcorrelatewithcrime.recentstrategiesusepaneldataoncrimeandprices(IhlanfeldtandMayock2010)orplausiblyexogenousvariationincrimeriskperceptiongeneratedbysexoffenderregistries(Lindenandrockoff2008).Thisworkfindsverylocalizedandshort-runpriceeffects,anditisnotclearhowmuchgeneralequilibriumcontentiscontainedinthereduced-formandparticularlytheshort-runpricemeasures.

Alesscommonempiricalapproachtotheeconomicburdenofcrimeisthe“contingent-valuation”approach.Forexample,cohenetal.(2004)conductasurveytomeasurewillingness-to-paytoreducecrime,andtheyfindestimatesofWTPthataremuchlargerthaninmoreconventionalapproachesthatmeasurethesocialcostsofcrime.InsofaraswebelieveagentscanestimatetheirWTP,theseestimatesshouldincludegeneralequilibriumadjustments.

Again,theessentialpointhereisthatthepotentialroleofgeneralequilibriumadjustmentshasbeenexaminedinmanypartsofthecrimeliterature.Aswediscussnext,acompleteanalysisofthesefactorsrequiressome“essentialelements”.

3.WHATISnEEdEd:“ESSEnTIALELEMEnTS”oFAModELoFTAxEVASIonIncIdEncE

These studies have added considerably to our understanding of the general equilibriumadjustmentsthatoccurinthepresenceoftaxevasionandofcrime.Evenso,thesestudiesdonotaddressfullythemainissuessurroundingdistributionaleffects.Thereisnosinglestudythathasexplicitlyincorporatedallofthe“essentialelements”thatwebelieveamodelmusthaveinordertocapturethesedistributionaleffects.

Focusingmainlyontaxevasion,whatarethesefeatures?First, andmost obviously, themodel should be able to capture the potential general

equilibriumeffectsoftaxevasion.Thesegeneralequilibriumeffectsinducechangesintherelativepricesbothof factorsofproductionandofgoodsandservices,broughtaboutbymarketequilibriumforces.Ifthereisataxadvantagethatwillbereflectedinexpectedfactorincomeorfirms’expectedprofits,thepotentialmobilityofresourceswillleadtothenecessarypriceadjustmentsuntilthisadvantageiseliminated.relatedly,thisgeneralequilibriummodelshouldallowfordifferencesinendowmentsand/orinpreferencesamongindividualssothatdifferentgroupsmaybenefitdifferentlyfromchangesinrelativeprices.Ageneralequilibriummodelwithasinglerepresentativeagentcannotofcourseadequatelyexaminethedistributionofeconomicgainsandlossesacrossincomegroups.

Second,themodelshouldincorporatetheelementofuncertaintyinanindividual’sorafirm’sdecisiontoevadeinatleastonesectoroftheeconomy.Thisuncertaintymayreflectsimplytheelementoftaxevasionasanopportunityfacingtheagent,asintheAllinghamandSandmo(1972)approach.Morebroadly,itmayreflectthepossibilitythatatsomepointtheagentmaybesubjecttotaxation.

Third,themodelshouldallowforvaryingdegreesofcompetitionorentryacrosssectorsintheeconomy,includingthoseinwhichtaxevasionisprevalent.Thisincludesmobilityoffactors,suchaslaborinthecaseofincometaxevasion;italsoincludesfirmentryinseveralsectors,asinthecaseofsalestaxorcorporateincometaxevasion.Theelementofmobilityis

Page 6: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

Who bEnEfits from tAx EVAsion?

144

criticaltoanunderstandingofhowmuchofthetaxadvantagemayberetainedbytheinitialevadersandhowmuchisshiftedelsewhereviafactorandcommoditypricechanges.

Acompleteanalysisoftheincidenceoftaxevasionthereforerequirestheconsiderationof general equilibrium effects, in a setting inwhich agents can differ in preferences andendowments,inwhichuncertaintyispresent,andinwhichmobilityacrosssectorscanvary.Atoneextreme,withnoentryorcompetition, thoseparticipatinginevasionactivitiesarethefinalbeneficiaries,asthestandardapproachpredicts.Attheotherextreme,withperfectcompetitionandcompletelyfreeentry,taxevaders(evenifsuccessful)mayhardlybenefitatallbecauseanyinitialbenefitfromtheabsenceoftaxationiserodedviaentryandcompetition.Alloftheseconsiderations–plussomeadditionalonesdiscussedintheconclusions–argueforageneralequilibriumcomputationalapproachtotaxevasion.

Thefailure toconsider theseadjustmentscanleadtoavarietyofmistakes,orat leastomissions,allofwhichweillustratewithexamplesfromourownworkinordertodemonstratethatwearenotwithoutsin.

Theoretical Studies.As noted, most theoretical analyses of tax evasion focus on theindividualcompliancedecision,andsonecessarilyignoreanygeneralequilibriumimpactsoftheseindividualtaxcompliancechoices.Foratypicalexample,seeAlm(1988),whoextendsthestandardAllinghamandSandmo(1972)modelbutwhoretainsitsemphasisonasinglerepresentativeagentfacingfixed“prices”.

Experimental Studies.Much recent analysisof taxcompliancehasutilized laboratoryexperiments.Inatypicalexperiment,humansubjectsinacontrolledlaboratorysettingareaskedtodecidehowmuchincometoreport,wheretaxesarepaidatsomerateonallreported,notaxesarepaidonunderreportedincome,andunderreportingisdiscoveredandpenalizedwithsomeprobability.Intothismicroeconomicsystem,variouspolicychangescanbeintroduced,suchaschangesinauditprobabilitiesorauditrules,inpenaltyrates,intaxrates,inpublicgoodprovision,andinanyotherrelevantinstitutions.Virtuallyallaspectsofcompliancehavebeenexaminedinsomewayinexperimentalwork.

nowtherearesomeobviouslimitationsofexperimentalmethods,includingespeciallythesomewhatartificialnatureofthelaboratory.However,ofmostrelevancehereisthepartialequilibrium nature of all experimental studies of tax compliance.These studies typicallyexamineindividualcompliancechoicesinisolationfromthechoicesofotherparticipants,andthepossibleimpactofone’scompliancedecisionsonthereturnstootherparticipants’decisionsisseldomconsidered.Evenwhensomeinteractionsareconsideredvia,say,apublicgoodfinancedbyallsubjects’contributions,anendogenousauditselectionruledeterminedbyallsubjects’choices,orinformationexchangeamongthesubjects,thewaysinwhichthe“prices”facingsubjectsmaybeaffectedbycomplianceareneverconsidered.Thisdoesnotmeanthattheresultsfromthesemanyexperimentalstudiesareofnouse.Itdoesmeanthattheresultsareoflimitedrelevanceforsettingsinwhichcompliancechoiceshaveanoticeableimpactontheseprices.

Forexample,inatypicalexperimentalstudyAlm,Jackson,andMckee(2009)examinethecomplianceimpactoftypesofinformationdisseminationregardingauditfrequency,comparingtheeffectsof“official”informationdisseminatedbythetaxauthority,and“unofficial”,orinformal,communicationsamongtaxpayers.Theyfind that the taxauthoritycan improvecompliancebypre-announcingauditratescrediblyandbyemphasizingthepreviousperiod

Page 7: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

JAmEs Alm And KEith finlAy

145

audit frequency inannual reportingofenforcementeffort.However, thebasicparametersfacingsubjectsarefixedandexogenoustothedecisionsofthesubjects,sothattherearenoadjustmentsthatmightalterthetaxadvantageofevasion.Evenwhenthechoiceofasubjectaffectsthepayoffstootherparticipantsthroughinformationexchange,therearestillno“price”adjustmentsintheexperimentaldesign.

Empirical Studies.ofperhapsmostrelevance,empiricalstudiesoftaxcompliancetypicallytaketheeconomicenvironmentasfixedandunaffectedbyindividualcompliancedecisions.Thisimplicitassumptionleadstoavarietyof“mistakes”.

Mostobviousisthetraditionalexerciseinpublicfinancethatexaminestheprogressivityorregressivityofaparticulartaxoroftheentiretaxsystem.Frequently,findingsofverticalandhorizontalincidenceareadjustedtotakeintoaccounttheimpactofexistingevasion,suchasinthecaseofprofessionalsorunskilledworkersemployedintheinformalsectoroftheeconomy.Theseadjustmentsaremadeundertheassumptionthattheevadinggroupsbenefitexclusivelyandinfullfromtheassumedtaxevasion.Indeed,Alm,Bahl,andMurray(1991)conductthistypeofanalysisforJamaica,inwhichtheygenerateestimatesoftheamountoftaxevasionthatoccursviaboththeunderreportingofincomeonfiledreturnsandthenonfilingofincometaxreturns.However,theyassumethattaxevadersretainallbenefitsfromtheirevasion.Inmanycasesthisimplicitassumptionisnodoubtincorrect,andtheresultingestimatesofthe“true”burdenoftaxationarethereforemisleading.Similarly,AlmandWallace(2007)arguethat,iflaborincomeismorelikelytobegeneratedintheuntaxedorinformalsectorthaniscapitalincome,thentheexistenceoftaxevasionmakesthetaxsystemmoreprogressive.However,iftheadvantagesrealizedbyworkersgetcapitalizedorcompetedawaybymarketprocesses,thenthisconclusionisincorrect.

We utilize these guidelines to illustrate several different approaches that analyze theincidenceoftaxevasion,asdiscussednext.

IV.APProAcHESToGEnErALEquILIBrIuMModELInG7

Herewepresentthreemodelsthatincorporatemanyofthe“essentialelements”neededforanalyzingthegeneralequilibriumeffectsoftaxevasion.Thesemodelsareprogressivelymorecomplicated.Evenso,theymaintainthebasicfeaturesofthesimplestHarberger(1962)model:“factorsubstitutioneffects”(e.g.,thetaxedfactorbearsmoreoftheburden),“factorintensityeffects”(e.g.,thefactorusedintensivelyinthetaxedsectorbearsmoreoftheburden),and“demandeffects”(e.g.,consumerswhopurchasemoreofthetaxedproductbearmoreoftheburden).Allofthesebasicfeaturesdeterminethefinalpatternoftheincidenceoftaxevasion.

4.1. The General Equilibrium Model of Alm (1985)

Alm(1985)examinestheimpactoftaxesthatcreateanincentiveforresourcestoflowfromthe“official”(ortaxed)sectorto“underground”(oruntaxed)sectors,definedasalleconomicactivitiesthatcontributetooutputbutthatarenotincludedinofficialstatistics.Inhismodel,astylizedeconomyisdividedintothreesectors:afullytaxedabove-groundsectorthatproduces

7 Inallcases,seetheoriginalpaper(Alm1985;AlmandSennoga2010;AlmandTurner2012)foracompletediscussionofthemodel,itscalibration,itssolution,anditsresults.

Page 8: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

Who bEnEfits from tAx EVAsion?

146

outputX,anundergroundsectorYwhoseactivitiesaresubstitutesforthoseofthetaxedsector,and an underground sector Z inwhich traditionally criminal activities such as prostitution,gambling,anddrugdealingtakeplace.Bothundergroundsectorsareassumedtobeuntaxed.demandforeachoutputisassumedtobeafunctionofrelativeprices,andallagents(includinggovernment)areassumedforsimplicitytohavethesameaverageandmarginalpropensitytoconsumeeachcommodity.Eachgoodisproducedundercompetitiveconditionswithalinearlyhomogeneousproductionfunctionthatdependsupontheamountofcapital(K)andlabor(L).capitalandlaborareassumedtobefixedinsupplyintotal;theyarealsoassumedtobeperfectlymobileamongsectors.SincecapitalandlaborinsectorsYandZareassumedtobeuntaxed,thereareonlytworelevanttaxes:ataxoncapital(TK)andataxonlabor(TL)inthetaxedsectorX.Thetaxationofcapitalandlaborinonlysometheirusescreatesanincentiveforresourcestoflowfromthetaxedsector(X)totheuntaxedsectors(YandZ).Thismovementhasbothallocativeanddistributionaleffects;theallocativeeffectsarethefocusofAlm(1985),butthedistributionaleffectsarethefocushere.

Alm(1985)calibratesthemodelusingu.S.datafortheseparateyears1950,1960,1970,and1980.Healsomakesvariousassumptionsabouttherelevantparameters,suchastheelasticitiesofsubstitutionbetweencapitalandlaborandthecompensatedelasticitiesofdemand.Itturnsout that thecrucialelementaffectingthedistributionaleffects is thefactor intensities in theundergroundsectors,andAlm(1985)assumesthatthetwountaxedsectorsarelabor-intensive.As a result, the taxation of labor and capital in the above-ground sector generates generalequilibriumadjustmentsthatalwaysimposeagreaterburdenonthefactorusedintensivelyinsectorX(e.g.,thefactorintensityeffect),orcapital.Hiscalibrationalsodemonstratesthatthetaxrateoncapitalistypicallygreaterthanthatonlabor,sothatthehigherrelativetaxoncapitalinsectorX versuslaborinthesectorfurthergeneratesgeneralequilibriumadjustmentsthatalwaysreducetherelativepriceofcapital(e.g.,thefactorsubstitutioneffect).Finally,thesefactorandgoodsmovementsalwaysincreasethepriceoftheproductofsectorXrelativetothepricesofthetwoundergroundsectors,therebyimposingahigherburdenonconsumersofsectorX(e.g.,thedemandeffect).

overall,theburdenoftaxationoflaborandcapitalintheabove-groundsectorareclearlyshiftedbothtocapitalandtoconsumersoftheabove-groundproduct.Forexample,inatypicalsimulation,Alm(1985)estimatesthatmobilitydecreasesthepriceofcapitalrelativetolaborin1980by41to55percentcomparedtoitsinitialprice,dependingonthevariouselasticities.Similarly,thepriceofXincreasesbyroughly50percentandthepriceofYdeclinesbyabout2percent,bothrelativetothepriceofZ.Theseresultsarelargelyrobusttodifferentmodelassumptions.

However,Alm(1985)assumesasinglerepresentativeagent,mainlytofocusontheallocativeeffectsoftaxes.Asaresult,hecannotfullyexaminethedistributionaleffectsofthesegeneralequilibriumadjustments.Healsodoesnotallowforuncertaintyintheagent’sdecisions,sothathecannotexaminetheunderlyingtaxevasionchoicesoftheagent.

4.2. The General Equilibrium Model of Alm and Sennoga (2010)

AlmandSennoga(2010)addressatleastsomeoftheselimitations.Theyconstructageneralequilibriummodelofastylizedsmallstaticclosedeconomywithtwoconsumers,twofactors,andtwobroadlydefinedsectorscomposedofanabove-groundortaxedsectorthatproduces

Page 9: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

JAmEs Alm And KEith finlAy

147

outputXandanunderground,informal,ortax-evadingsectorwhoseoutputYisasubstituteforthetaxedoutput.Theyincorporatetheindividual’sdecisiontoevade,andtheyalsoallowforvaryingdegreesofmobilityviacompetitionand/orentryacrosssectorsintheeconomy.Theirfocusisonmeasuringhowmuchoftheinitialtaxadvantageofevasionisretainedbyincometaxevadersandhowmuchisshiftedviafactorandcommoditypricechangesstemmingfrommobility.

Specifically,AlmandSennoga(2010)makeseveralmainassumptions:• Therearetwoconsumers,aPoorhouseholdworkingentirelyintheinformalsector

andarIcHhouseholdworkingonly in the formalsector; thePoorhousehold’sconsumption is relativelyY-intensive, and the rIcH household’s consumption isrelativelyX-intensive.

• Laborisvariableinsupply,withastandardlabor-leisurechoice,andisimperfectlymobileacrosssectors.

• capitalisfixedintotalsupply,imperfectlyhomogenous,imperfectlymobileacrosssectors,andfullytaxed.

• Laborincomegeneratedintheabove-groundsector(sectorX)isfullytaxedatratet.• Laborincomegeneratedintheundergroundsector(sectorY)ishiddenfromtheauthorities

andmayescapetaxation;however,thisincomemaybedetectedandpenalized.• consumptionofbothsectorsissubjecttoanindirecttaxatrateτ.• SectorXconsumptionisfullytaxed;sectorYconsumptionmayescapetaxation,but

thisindirecttaxevasionmaybedetectedandpenalized.• The above-ground sector (sectorX) is relatively capital-intensive, and sectorY is

labor-intensive.• Spendingandincomeofthegovernment(GoVT)aredisaggregatedfromthatofthe

consumers,sothatthegovernmentistreatedasaseparateconsumerthatcollectstaxesinordertoprovideapublicgoodcalled“publicadministration”.

Also,producersareassumedtomaximizeprofitstakingpricesasgiven,andconsumersareassumedtomaximizeutilitysubjecttoabudgetconstraintthatdependsuponthevalueoftheirendowments.Theseassumptionsimplythatproducersearnonlynormalprofitsandthatconsumerscannotincreaseconsumptionofallgoods.

AlmandSennoga(2010)calibratetheirmodelwithdatathatdonotrepresentanyparticularcountry,andarechosensomewhatarbitrarilytoreflectsectoralcompositionsina“typical”developingcountry.TheystartwithaSocialAccountingMatrix(SAM),constructedundertheassumptionthattheconsumersand/orproducersintheformalsectorfullymeettheirtaxobligationswhiletheircounterpartsintheinformalsectorfullyevadetaxes(i.e.,fullcomplianceintheformalsectorandtaxevasionintheinformalsector).Theyconstructtheirmodelsothatitsinitialequilibriumreplicatestherelevantbenchmarkdata,beforeintroducingapolicyinnovation(e.g.,achangeinataxrate,achangeinanexpectedpenaltyrate)andexaminingitsdistributionaleffects.

Table 1presentssometypicalresultsfromAlmandSennoga(2010).ThetoppartofTable 1 indicates that the Poorhousehold initially benefits from evasion but only somewhat.Thisinitialgainiscomputedusingthedefaultelasticityofsubstitutionbetweenleisureandconsumption,or2;tosimulatelong-runentry(i.e.,mobility)intotheinformalsector, this

Page 10: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

Who bEnEfits from tAx EVAsion?

148

Table 1:GeneralEquilibriumEffectsinAlmandSennoga(2010)

Statutory ad valorem commodity tax = 0.1, Statutory proportional income tax rate = 0.25Expected penalty rate (commodity taxes) = 0.07, Expected penalty rate (income taxes) = 0.2

POOR Household RICH HouseholdMagnitude

(%)Percent Change

(%)

Magnitude(%)

Percent Change

(%)Initial Post-Evasion Welfare 2.43

-21.8-0.64

96.9Final Post-Evasion Welfare 1.90 -0.02Initial Price of Good X 5.99

-8.65.99

-8.6Final Price of Good X 5.47 5.47Initial Price of Good Y -6.30

9.8-6.30

9.8Final Price of Good Y -5.68 -5.68Initial Post-Evasion Rental Rate -0.89

365.1-0.89

365.1Final Post-Evasion Rental Rate 2.36 2.36Initial Post-Evasion Net Wage -4.02

-13.40.50

-184.0Final Post-Evasion Net Wage -4.56 -0.87Initial Post-Evasion Labor Supply 6.43

59.8-2.74

122.6Final Post-Evasion Labor Supply 10.28 0.62

Statutory ad valorem commodity tax = 0.1, Statutory proportional income tax rate = 0.25Expected penalty rate (commodity taxes) = 0.095, Expected penalty rate (income taxes) = 0.225

Initial Post-Evasion Welfare 1.08-23.2

-0.25112.0

Final Post-Evasion Welfare 0.83 0.03Initial Price of Good X 2.56

-9.42.56

-9.4Final Price of Good X 2.32 2.32Initial Price of Good Y -2.79

10.8-2.79

10.8Final Price of Good Y -2.49 -2.49Initial Post-Evasion Rental Rate -0.37

405.4-0.37

405.4Final Post-Evasion Rental Rate 1.13 1.13Initial Post-Evasion Net Wage -0.99

-25.20.60

-160.0Final Post-Evasion Net Wage -1.24 -0.36Initial Post-Evasion Labor Supply 2.80

59.6-1.18

130.5Final Post-Evasion Labor Supply 4.47 0.36

Notes:“Initial”referstotheoutcomewithlimitedcompetitionand/orentryintheinformalsector.“Final”refersto theoutcomewith increasedcompetitionand/orentry in the informalsector.“Magnitude” is thepercentagedifferencebetweenthepost-evasionandpost-taxoutcomeifbothPoorandrIcHhouseholdscompliedwithtaxes.“Percentchange”referstothepercentagechangebetweenthemagnitudeforthe“initial”and“final”outcome.ThesesimulationsareforthecasewheretherIcHhouseholdworksonlyintheformalsectorandthePoorhouseholdendowmentis33percentoftherIcHhouseholdendowment.

Source:AlmandSennoga(2010).

Page 11: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

JAmEs Alm And KEith finlAy

149

elasticityinincreasedto8.8TheyfindthattheinitialbenefitofevasionforthePoorhouseholddissipates as entry into the informal sector expands. Specifically,Table 1 shows that thePoorhouseholdretains78.2percentoftheinitial2.4percentincreaseinitswelfare,while21.8percentofthisinitialgaininwelfareiseliminatedasaresultofentryintotheinformalsector.9TherIcHhousehold’swelfareinitiallyfallsby0.64percent,butmobilityreducesthislosstoonly-0.02percent,whichrepresentsa96.9percentincreaseinwelfarefortherIcHhouseholdarisingfrommobilityintotheinformalsector.TheincreaseintherIcHhousehold’scommodityX-intensivewelfareismainlyattributedtoareductioninthetax-inclusivepriceofcommodityXasmobilityintotheinformalsectoroccurs.

Table 1alsoshowsthatthetax-inclusivepriceofcommodityXfallsby8.6percentwithmobilityintotheinformalsector,whilethepriceofgoodYincreasesby9.8percent.BecausethePoorhousehold’swelfareisassumedtobeintensiveincommodityY,anincreaseinthecommoditypriceofgoodYreducesthePoorhousehold’swelfare.Further,mobilityincreasestheamountoflaborsuppliedbythePoorandrIcHhouseholdsby59.8percentand122.6percent, respectively, leading toareduction in theirnet-of-taxwagesby13.4percentand184.0percent,respectively.

Increasingtheexpectedpenaltyrateonlyaltersthesizeofthesechangesandnottheirdirection,asshowninthelowerpartofTable1.Perhapssurprisingly,theincreasedpenaltyrateleadstoafinallevelofwelfarethatisactuallyhigherforbothrIcHandPoorhouseholdsthanthelevelofwelfareachievedintheabsenceoftaxevasion.Thisresultillustratesthatevasioncanalleviatesomeofthelabormarketdistortionsassociatedwithtaxation,especiallywhenahighexpectedpenaltyrategenerateslargedistortions.other(unreported)counterfactualexperimentsreinforcetheseresults.

Acrossallexperiments,AlmandSennoga(2010)findthatahouseholdthatsuccessfullyevadesitsincometaxliabilitieshasapost-evasionwelfarethatisonly1.1to3.4percenthigherthanitspost-taxwelfareifithadfullycompliedwiththeincometax.Further,thishouseholdkeepsonly75.3to78.2percentofitsinitialincreaseinwelfare,while21.8to24.7percentofitsinitialgainiscompetedawayasaresultofmobilitythatreflectscompetitionandentryintotheinformalsector.Althoughtheinitialpost-evasionwelfareeffectisnegativeforthehouseholdthatcomplieswithincometaxes,itswelfareincreasesby87.5to142.3percentwithcompetitionandentryintheinformalsector.

Morebroadly,thecounterfactualexperimentsofAlmandSennoga(2010)indicatethatthetaxevaderdoesnotbenefitexclusivelyfromevasion.Indeed,theirresultsindicatethatany“taxadvantage”fromevasiondiminisheswithmobilityintotheinformalsector,aswellaswithanincreaseintheexpectedpenaltyassociatedwithtaxevasion;thatis,theevadinghouseholdbenefitsbutonlysomewhatfromtaxevasion,andthisadvantageshrinkssignificantlywithmobility.Theirresultsalsosuggestthattherearesomecircumstancesunderwhichtaxevasionactually increases thewelfareofallhouseholds,asevasion reduces someof thedistortingeffectsoftaxation.

WhilerepresentinganadvanceoverthesimplemodelofAlm(1985),AlmandSennoga(2010)stilldonotincorporateall“essentialelements”.Theydonotfullyallowformobility,

8 “Initial”referstotheoutcomewithlimitedcompetitionand/orentryintheinformalsector.“Final”referstotheoutcomewithincreasedcompetitionand/orentryintheinformalsector.

9 The“initial”gainorlossreferstothepercentagechangebetweenthepost-evasionandpost-taxwelfare.

Page 12: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

Who bEnEfits from tAx EVAsion?

150

especiallymobilitythatcanbeaffectedbythedegreeofcompetitionintheproductionsectors.They also do not consider the potential for firm-level tax evasion.These limitations areaddressedbyAlmandTurner(2012).

4.3. The General Equilibrium Model of Alm and Turner (2012)

AlmandTurner(2012)assumeastylizedsmallstaticclosedeconomywithtwobroadlydefinedsectors,composedofanabove-groundortaxedsectorandanunderground,informal,ortax-evadingsectorwhoseoutputisasubstitutefortaxedoutput;theyalsoincorporateuncertaintyandvaryingdegreesofmobilityacrosssectorsintheeconomy.However,unlikeAlmandSennoga(2010),AlmandTurner(2012)modelfirmevasion,ratherthanindividualevasion.Theyalsoincorporatemoreexplicitlydifferentdegreesofcompetitionbyanalyzingseparatelyaperfectcompetitionmodeloffirmdecisionsandamonopolymark-upmodel.Theirfocusisonmeasuringhowmuchoftheinitialtaxadvantageofevasionisretainedbyincometaxevadersandhowmuchisshiftedviafactorandcommoditypricechangesstemmingfrommobility.

Specifically,AlmandTurner(2012)makeseveralmainassumptions:• Therearetwoconsumers,consumer1and2,withconsumer1’sconsumptionrelatively

x-intensive.• Therearetwogoods.• Therearetwoproducers(orproductionsectors):anon-evader(orcompliant)firm

withoutputX,andanevaderfirmwithoutputY,withtheevadingsectorrelativelylabor-intensive.

• Individuals/householdsmaximizeutilitysubjecttoabudgetconstraint,earningincomefromendowmentsoflaborandcapital.

• Producersmaximizeprofits(orexpectedprofits).• Therearetwotaxes,anadvaloremlabortaxandanadvaloremsalestax.• Twomarketcasesaremodeled:perfectcompetitionandmonopoly.

They conduct two main counterfactuals, one when there is perfect competition and asecondwhenthereismonopoly.Foreachofthesecounterfactuals,theymaketwodifferentcomparisons:betweenageneralequilibriumwithfullcompliancewiththerelevanttax(“Non-Evasion”)andanequilibriumwithevasion(“Evasion1”),andbetweenthepreviousevasionequilibrium(“Evasion1”)andoneinwhichtheelasticityofsubstitutionbetweenproductioninputsisincreasedcausingcapitalandlabortoflowmoreeasilybetweenproducersinsectors(“Evasion2”).Thecounterfactualsalsoallowforincreasesintheprobabilityofdetection,thefinerate,andthelabororsalestaxrate.

WepresentinTable 2somesummaryresultsonlyfromtheperfectcompetitionsimulationsandonlyforthelabortaxscenarios.Theresultsforthesalestaxscenarios,aswellasforthemonopolymarkupcase,arequalitativelythesame.

considertheperfectcompetitionsimulationsinTable 2fortheadvaloremlabortax.Thelabortaxwithoutanyevasion(Non-Evasion)lowersthepriceoflaborby44percent,andconsumer2’swelfaredecreasesrelativetothatofconsumer1duetoconsumer2’srelativelylargelaborendowment.Whenevasionoccurs(Evasion1)insector2withalowprobabilityofdetection(0.1)andalowfinerate(1.1)onevadedlabortaxes,thepriceoflaborincreasesby67.9percent(%∆Pre).Thepriceofcapitaldecreasesby20.1percent,andthustherelativepriceoflaborto

Page 13: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

JAmEs Alm And KEith finlAy

151

capitalincreasesandlaborflowsfromsectorXtosectorY.ThismovementincreasesevadersectorYoutput,whichleadstoadecreaseinitsprice.Thewelfareofconsumer2increases(7.5percent)becauseconsumer2consumesalargershareofthesectorYgood.ThereallocationofcapitalandlaboralsoreducesXoutputby31.5percent,andincreasesitspriceby11percent.Thewelfareofconsumer1decreases(12.9percent)becauseconsumptionisX-intensive.

Table 2:GeneralEquilibriumEffectsinAlmandTurner(2012)

competition Increasedcompetition

non-Evasion Evasion1 %∆Pre Evasion2 %∆PostWelfare1 1.07 0.93 -12.9% 0.96 3.4%Welfare2 0.93 1.00 7.5% 0.95 -5.3%xoutput 1.02 0.70 -31.5% 0.81 15.8%Youtput 0.98 1.28 30.8% 1.11 -12.8%Pricex 1.69 1.87 11.0% 1.50 -20.1%PriceY 1.68 1.34 -20.5% 1.24 -7.4%capitalPrice 1.70 1.36 -20.1% 1.40 3.4%LaborPrice(net) 0.56 0.93 67.9% 0.84 -10.4%consumer1Income 179.71 155.08 -13.7% 135.20 -12.8%consumer2Income 156.84 146.56 -6.6% 123.82 -15.5%

Notes:%∆Prereferstothepercentchangeofevasionovernon-evasionbeforeincreasingcompetition,and%∆Postreferstothepercentchangeofevasionoverevasionafterincreasingcompetition.Anincreaseincompetitionisadjustedbyincreasingtheelasticityofsubstitutioninproductioninputs.Thesesimulationsareforthecasewherethereisapartialfactortaxonlaborunderperfectcompetition.

Source:AlmandTurner(2012).

When the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor is increased (Evasion2),laborflowsintotheevadersectorY,whichreducesthepriceoflaborby10.4percent;thatis,replicationandcompetitionhavereducedsomeofthebenefitsofevasioncomparedtoEvasion1.Thepriceofcapitalincreasesby3.4percent,andtherelativepriceoflabordecreases,causingareallocationofcapitalandlabortowardssectorX.Thenon-evadersectoroutputXincreasesby15.8percent,anditspricedecreasesby20.1percent.consumer1’swelfareincreasesby3.4percentasaresultoftheincreaseinXoutputandthelargeshareofXinutility.outputinsectorYdecreasesby12.8percent,anditspricedecreasesby7.4percent.Theincreaseinthesubstitutabilityoflaborandcapitalbetweenthetwosectorsleadstogreaterreplicationandcompetitionamonglaborandcapital,andtransfersthebenefitsofevasionviaanincreasednetwageoflaborawayfromlaborinsectorYtoconsumersintheformoflowerpricesofsectorYoutput.LaborenteringtheevadersectorYcompeteswitheachotherandbidsdownthenetwagewithevasion,thustransferringthebenefitsofevasiontothesectorYproducer.SectorYfirm’scostofproductiondecreasesasaresultofthedecreaseinthepriceoflabor,resultinginthetransferofbenefitstoconsumersintheformoflowerprices(e.g.,thepriceofYdecreasesby7.4percent).

Page 14: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

Who bEnEfits from tAx EVAsion?

152

Inothersimulations,increasesintheprobabilityofdetection,thefinerate,andthelabortaxrateconfirmtheseresults.Inparticular,thebenefitsofevasionremainwiththeevadingsectorandbenefitthefactorusedmoreintenselythere(e.g.,labor),butwhentheelasticityofsubstitutionisincreasedtomakefactorinputsmorelikeperfectsubstitutes,thebenefitsofevasionarecompetedawaythroughreplicationandcompetition.

overall,AlmandTurner(2012)findthatthebenefitsofevasionmaybereplicatedandcompetedawaythroughentryorthroughreallocationoffactorinputs,dependingontherelativecompetitivenessof themarket.Further, industries inwhichone factor input isusedmoreintensivelythantheotherorinwhichthereismarketpowerwillbeabletoretainthesebenefits.

LikeAlmandSennoga(2010,thisapproachisanadvanceoverthesimplemodelofAlm(1985).Evenso,AlmandTurner(2012)stilldonotincorporateall“essentialelements”.Forexample,whileallowingforfirmevasion,theydonotconsiderindividualevasion.Thereisstillworktobedone.

V.concLuSIonS

distributionalconclusionsdrawnfromthestandardapproachtotaxevasionareunsatisfactorybecausethisapproachignoresthefactthattaxevasionismuchlikea“taxadvantage”inthelaw,sothatreplicationandcompetitionshouldworktowardtheeliminationofthisadvantage.Thisprocessofadjustmenttakesplacethroughchangesintherelativepricesofbothcommoditiesandfactorsofproduction,asmobilityoccursintoandoutoftherelevantsectors.Thestandardapproach takesonlyapartial equilibriumperspective, anddoesnot capture thesegeneralequilibriummobilityeffects.Thefailuretoconsidertheseeffectsleadstoawidevarietyof“errors”inthestandardanalysisoftaxevasion.

oncethesegeneralequilibriumeffectsareappropriatelymodeled,itistypicallyfoundthatthetaxevaderdoesnotbenefitexclusivelyfromevasion.Indeed,theseanalysesindicatethatanytaxadvantagefromevasiondiminisheswithmobilityintotheinformalsector,withgreatersubstitutionpossibilitiesinproduction,andwithgreaterdegreesofsectoralcompetition.Infact,therearesomecircumstancesunderwhichtaxevasionactuallyincreasesthewelfareofallhouseholds,asevasionreducessomeofthedistortingeffectsoftaxation.Inshort,thegainsfromevasionareshiftedatleastinpartfromtheevaderstotheconsumersoftheiroutputvialowerprices,asgeneralequilibriummobilityeffectsworkviarelativepriceandproductivitychangestoeliminatetheincentiveforworkerstoentertheinformalsectorbeyondsomemargin.

Therearemanypossibleextensionstothiswork,evenasidefromtheusualsensitivityanalyses.Theunderlyingframeworkcouldbegeneralizedtoconsidergreatertaxpayerheterogeneity,abroader rangeofgovernment activities, the impactofopeneconomyconsiderations, thepotentialforgovernmentcorruption,anddynamicincidencefactors.Animportantextensionhereistoincorporatemorefullymodelsofexpectedutility,andofnon-expectedutility.Itwouldbeinterestingtoexaminewhethertraditionaltaxequivalenceresultsstillholdinthepresenceoftaxevasion,suchasthepresumedequivalencebetweenaproportionalincometaxandaproportionalconsumptiontax(withanequalrateonallcommodities).

ofperhapsmostimportance,eventhesegeneralequilibriummodelsdonotincorporatesomeotheressentialelementsofthefiscalarchitecture,notablytheadministrativecostsoftaxationandthecompliancecostsoftaxation.

Page 15: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

JAmEs Alm And KEith finlAy

153

Thereislittledoubtthattherearesignificantcostsforgovernmentincollectingtaxes(orthe“administrativecosts”oftaxation).Theavailableevidencefromgovernmentbudgetaryinformationclearlyindicatesthatthebudgetcostofcollectingindividualincome,businessincome,andsalestaxesisgenerallyinexcessofonepercentoftherevenuesfromthesetaxesandcansometimesbesubstantiallyhigher.Similarly,implicitinmuchoftheevasionliteratureistheassumptionthatitiscostlessforindividualsandfirmstopaytheirtaxes.Thereislittlequestionthatthisissimplywrong.Therearenowanumberofestimates,derivedfromavarietyofmethodologies,oftheactualmagnitudesoftheindividualandfirmcompliancecostsintheunitedStatesandelsewhere(SlemrodandSorum1984;BlumenthalandSlemrod1996;Sandford1995).Theseestimatesvary,butoftensuggestthatcompliancecostscanrangefrom2to24percentofrevenuesforselectedtaxes.Intotal,thesestudiesclearlyindicatethatthecompliancecostsoftaxationaresignificant,oftenofcomparableorevenlargervaluesthanthemoretraditionalcalculationsoftheexcessburdenoftaxation.

Analysisofwhobenefitsfromevasionrequiresrecognitionofthedistributionaleffectsoftheseadministrativeandcompliancecosts,especiallyofthepriceeffectsthatemergeasindividualsandfirmsattempttoreduceand/oravoidthesecosts.Inconductingtheseanalyses,wethinkitunavoidablethatrigorousanalysiswillrequiretheuseofacomputablegeneralequilibriumframework,inwhichthedifferentconsiderationsaresequentiallylayered,oneatopanother,untilthefullmodelcapturesalloftherelevantfactors.computablegeneralequilibriumcomputationscanquantifywithastandardmeasurethetrade-offsthattaxesnecessarilycreate;theycanindicatetheareasinwhichourknowledgeisincomplete;theycanprovidespecificguidelinesinspecificcountrycircumstances;andtheycanprovideessentialinformationonwhoactuallybenefitsfromtaxevasion.

ultimately,wearehopeful that thegeneralequilibriumanalysisof taxevasioncanbeextendedtotheanalysisofcriminalactivitiesmorebroadly,ofwhichtaxevasionisonlyonesmallpart.Thesemanyextensionsawaitfuturework.

rEFErEncESAllingham,M.G.andA.Sandmo(1972). IncomeTaxEvasion:ATheoreticalAnalysis,Journal of

Public Economics.1:323-338.Alm,J.(1985).TheWelfarecostoftheundergroundEconomy,Economic Inquiry.23:243-263.Alm,J.(1988).compliancecostsandtheTaxAvoidance–TaxEvasiondecision,Public Finance

Quarterly.16:31-66.Alm,J.(2012).Measuring,Explaining,andcontrollingTaxEvasion:LessonsfromTheory,Experiments,

andFieldStudies,International Tax and Public Finance.19:54-77.Alm,J.,r.Bahl,andM.n.Murray (1991).TaxBaseErosion indevelopingcountries,Economic

Development and Cultural Change.39:849-872.Alm,J.,B.r.Jackson,andM.Mckee(2009).GettingtheWordout:IncreasedEnforcement,Audit

Informationdissemination,andcomplianceBehavior,Journal of Public Economics.93:392-402.Alm,J.andE.B.Sennoga(2010).Mobility,competition,andthedistributionalEffectsofTaxEvasion,

National Tax Journal.63:1055-1084.Alm,J.andS.Turner(2012).SimulatingthedistributionalEffectsofTaxEvasion.departmentof

EconomicsWorkingPaper,Tulaneuniversity.neworleans,LA.Andreoni,J.,B.Erard,andJ.S.Feinstein(1998).Taxcompliance,The Journal of Economic Literature.

36:818-860.

Page 16: Who Benefits from Tax Evasion?1 - GitHub Pages

Who bEnEfits from tAx EVAsion?

154

Blumenthal,M.andJ.Slemrod(1996).TheIncomeTaxcompliancecostofBigBusiness,Public Finance Review.24:411-438.

Burdett,k.,r.Lagos,andr.Wright(2003).crime,Inequality,andunemployment,The American Economic Review.93:1764-1777.

cohen,M.A.,r.T.rust,S.Steen,andS.T.Tidd(2004).Willingness-to-payforcrimecontrolPrograms,Criminology.42:89–110.

cowell,F.A.(1990).Cheating the Government: The Economics of Evasion.cambridge,MA:TheMITPress.dalBó,E.andP.dalBó(2011).Workers,Warriors,andcriminals:SocialconflictinGeneralEquilibrium,

Journal of the European Economic Association.9:646-677.davidson,c.,L.Martin,andJ.d.Wilson(2007).EfficientBlackMarkets?,Journal of Public Economics.

91:1575-1590.Furlong,W.J.(1987).AGeneralEquilibriumModelofcrimecommissionandPrevention,Journal of

Public Economics.34:87-103.Harberger,A.c.(1962).TheIncidenceofthecorporateIncomeTax,The Journal of Political Economy.

70:215-240.Ihlanfeldt,k.andT.Mayock(2010).PaneldataEstimatesoftheEffectsofdifferentTypesofcrime

onHousingPrices,Regional Science and Urban Economics.40:161-172.Imrohorogolu,A.,A.Merlo,andP.rupert(2000).onthePoliticalEconomyofIncomeredistribution

andcrime,International Economic Review.41:1-25.Jung,Y.H.,A.Snow,andG.A.Trandel(1994).TaxEvasionandtheSizeoftheundergroundEconomy,

Journal of Public Economics.54:391-402.kehoe,T.J.andJ.Serra-Puche(1983).AcomputationalGeneralEquilibriumModelwithEndogenous

unemployment:AnAnalysisofthe1980FiscalreforminMexico,Journal of Public Economics.22:1-26.

kesselman,J.r.(1989).IncomeTaxEvasion:AnIntersectoralAnalysis,Journal of Public Economics.38:137-182.

Linden,L.andJ.E.rockoff(2008).EstimatesoftheImpactofcrimeriskonPropertyValuesfromMegan’sLaws,The American Economic Review.98:1103-1127.

Martinez-Vazquez,J.(1996).WhoBenefitsfromTaxEvasion?TheIncidenceofTaxEvasion,Public Economics Review.1:105-135.

Persson,M.andP.Wissen(1984).redistributionalAspectsofTaxEvasion,Scandinavian Journal of Economics.86:131-149.

Sandford,c.T.(1995).Tax Compliance Costs: Measurement and Policy. Bath,uk:FiscalPublications.Sandmo,A.(2012).AnEvasiveTopic:TheorizingAbouttheHiddenEconomy,International Tax and

Public Finance.19:5-24.Slemrod,J.andn.Sorum(1984).Thecompliancecostoftheu.S.IndividualIncomeTax,National

Tax Journal.37:461-474.Slemrod,J.andS.Yitzhaki(2002).TaxAvoidance,Evasion,andAdministration,in:A.J.Auerbach

andM.Feldstein(eds.),Handbook of Public Economics.Amsterdam,Thenetherlands:ElsevierB.V.–northHollandPublishers:1423-1470.

Thalmann,P.(1992).FactorTaxesandEvasioninGeneralEquilibrium,Regional Science and Urban Economics.22:259-283.

Tiebout,c.M.(1956).APureTheoryofLocalExpenditures,The Journal of Political Economy.64:416-424.

Torgler,B.(2007).Tax Compliance and Tax Morale: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis.cheltenham,uk:EdwardElgarPublishing.

Watson,H.(1985).TaxEvasionandLaborMarkets,Journal of Public Economics.27:231-246.Wilson,J.q.andG.L.kelling(1982).BrokenWindows:ThePoliceandneighborhoodSafety,Atlantic

Monthly.29-38.Wilson,W.J. (1987).The Truly Disadvantaged: the Inner City, the Underclass, and Public Policy.

chicago,IL:universityofchicagoPress.