Why the 31st Dáil should not be the default Dáil - Paschal Donohoe TD

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/7/2019 Why the 31st Dil should not be the default Dil - Paschal Donohoe TD

    1/4

    WHY THE 31ST DIL SHOULD NOT BE THE DEFAULT DIL

    Paschal Donohoe TD

    Default is a term that Ireland is becoming all too familiar with. So many people are now no

    longer able to pay their home mortgages. Too many home owners have now either

    defaulted or face the prospect of defaulting on these loans, with tragic and severe

    consequences and the idea that Ireland should default on sovereign debt is gaining

    momentum.

    Default advocates point to our level of national debt as proof of why default is necessary.

    Even with no increase in the cost of rescuing our banking system the debt challenges are

    immense. Our gross debt levels will increase from 148 billion in 2010 to 184 billion in

    2014. The consequent rise in our debt service costs is huge, approximately 8 billion in

    2013.

    This paper analyses what sovereign default actually means and reviews recent examples of

    default showing what the likely consequences would be for Ireland.

    What is a Sovereign Default?A sovereign debt default occurs when a country, the sovereign, decides not to pay its debt.

    This decision is made by the government.

    Sovereign debt consists (mostly) of government bonds. The holders of these bonds

    therefore incur the immediate impact of this decision. The Government of the defaulting

    state decide either not to pay back the capital on their bonds or the rate of interest on their

    debt. This imposes a loss on the bond holder and a reduction in the liability of the

    defaulting state.

    Why do Sovereigns Default?They tend to occur in bad times according to a comprehensive review of defaultliterature, theory and history1. A number of key factors cause the majority of defaults.

    First, sovereign defaults occur after a period of intense credit growth. The end of this

    credit growth tends to be associated with the onset of a banking crisis.

    Second, levels of national borrowing are too high and a small shock to this level of

    borrowing triggers a default. This tends to be associated with a change in the interest rate

    on the debt.

    Third, during economic contraction where national debt exceeds national income, and a

    Government cannot credibly borrow on international capital markets.

    A Brief History of DefaultsA long and varied history of sovereign defaults exists. The first recorded default occurred

    in fourth century B.C., when ten Greek municipalities in the Attic Maritime Associationdefaulted on loans from the Delos Temple!

    An IMF study2 indicates that 257 defaults have occurred between 1824 and 2004.

    1 The Economics and Law of Sovereign Defaults, Ugo Panizza, FredericoSturzenegger and Jeromin Zettelmeyer, Journal of Economic Literature 47:3,

  • 8/7/2019 Why the 31st Dil should not be the default Dil - Paschal Donohoe TD

    2/4

    0

    50

    100

    150

    1824- 2004

    200 Years of Defaults

    Af r i c aAs i aEast EuropeLatin AmericaWest Europe

    As indicated above a distinct geographical allocation exists across defaults. Latin America

    and Africa account for 74% of all defaults. A sovereign default has not occurred in Western

    Europe since the Great Depression.

    Defaults tend to come in waves. The first wave of defaults, in the period covered by this

    study, occurred between 1824 and 1840, following a lending boom by newly independent

    Latin American countries. The next cluster commenced in 1861 and ended in 1920, with

    most of the defaults again occurring within Latin America. The last default peak occurred

    between 1921 and 1940 when 39 sovereign defaults occurred, as governments grappled

    with the impact of the Great Depression.

    More recent prominent defaults are noted below.

    Country Date DefaultRussia 1998 Occurred in aftermath

    of Asian crisis and

    collapse of LTCMColombia 1999 Defaulted on Brady

    Bonds

    Argentina 2001 Defaulted on 82

    billion after bankingcrisis

    This long and varied history allows an understanding of what happens when the sovereign

    defaults.

    The consequences of Sovereign Defaults

    - Swift Budgetary Adjustment: When a sovereign defaults, their ability to borrow ishugely and quickly reduced as the Government loses access to capital markets. A

    defaulting government can only spend what it can directly raise through taxation or

    through significantly lower borrowing. Such economies tend to be in deficit where

    current spending is greater than taxes raised. In the immediate period after default

    the Government either balances their budget or moves to a current surplus to pay

    interest on restructured debt. Indeed, the median primary surplus during the three

    2 The Costs of Sovereign Default, Eduardo Borenstein & Ugo Panizza, IMF

  • 8/7/2019 Why the 31st Dil should not be the default Dil - Paschal Donohoe TD

    3/4

    years after default was about 2% of GDP in the sample consisting of all economies that

    defaulted since 1976..3.

    - Exclusion from capital markets. As losses are imposed on bond holders they arewary of supplying credit to defaulting governments for fear of incurring future loss.

    During the 1980s defaulting countries were excluded from capital markets for an

    average period of 4 years. A recent study of exclusion concluded that sovereign

    defaulters between 1980 and 2005 regain(ed) partial market access after 5.7 years

    on average (median of 3.0 years) while it takes 8.4 years on average (median of 7.0

    years) to regain full market access..4.

    - Higher Cost of Borrowing. In the period after the default the cost of borrowingincreases. This is in recognition of the greater risk to the lender of dealing with a

    defaulting sovereign. A study on the impact of bond spreads for defaulting

    economies stated that a default in year t 1 has a large and statistically significant

    effect on spreads amounting to 400 basis points5. The same study concluded that the

    risk premium moved to 250 points in the second year before returning to normal

    trends.

    - Reputational Damage. Literature in this area concludes that the reputation ofgovernments is impacted by sovereign defaults. If a government defaults once, the

    market expectation is that a future default is always likely. This assessment drives

    all of the above reactions.

    All of these assessments are based on empirical studies of decades of defaults. However

    there are a number of reasons why an Irish default would be unprecedented and unique.

    What makes Ireland different?

    The Irish economy has 3 factors that are vital in consideration of default consequences.

    First, Ireland is a member of a single currency zone. An immediate step taken by all

    modern defaulting economies has been to devalue their currency. This is to provide a

    quick stimulus of export competitiveness. As Ireland does not have a national currency

    this option is not open to an Irish Government.

    Second, Ireland is a developed country. All recent academic research focuses on the impact

    of defaults in emerging economies. The collateral impact of a developed economy default

    will be larger due to greater integration with the European economy.

    Third, the lender of last resort is already present in the Irish State. Defaulting economies

    make recourse to the IMF. Ireland has already done so with our participation in the

    IMF/EU support programme. A default involving non payment to our lenders of last resort

    would be unprecedented and history offers little guidance as to their reaction.

    3 Defaults in Todays Advanced Economies: Unnecessary, Undesirable, and

    Unlikely, Carlo Cottarelli, Lorenzo Forni, Jan Gottschalk & Paolo Mauro, IMF StaffPosition Note, September 2010.4 Duration of Capital Market Exclusion: Stylized Facts and Determining Factors,

    Christine Richmond and Daniel Dias, March 2009.5 The Costs of Sovereign Default, Eduardo Borensztein and Ugo Panizza, IMF

  • 8/7/2019 Why the 31st Dil should not be the default Dil - Paschal Donohoe TD

    4/4