139
Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet Some Lessons From the Past Greg Taylor Oxford Internet Institute University of Oxford

Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Industrial Organisation Off and On the InternetSome Lessons From the Past

Greg Taylor

Oxford Internet InstituteUniversity of Oxford

Page 2: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Economics

I The study of constrained choice.

I Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.I Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.I Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.I But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions.I Thus another advantage of the mathematical approach:

encourages transparency of assumptions.

I Let’s take a look at a textbook example of how some simpleassumptions can be turned into a model.

Page 3: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Economics

I The study of constrained choice.I Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.

I Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.I Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.I But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions.I Thus another advantage of the mathematical approach:

encourages transparency of assumptions.

I Let’s take a look at a textbook example of how some simpleassumptions can be turned into a model.

Page 4: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Economics

I The study of constrained choice.I Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.

I Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.

I Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.I But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions.I Thus another advantage of the mathematical approach:

encourages transparency of assumptions.

I Let’s take a look at a textbook example of how some simpleassumptions can be turned into a model.

Page 5: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Economics

I The study of constrained choice.I Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.

I Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.I Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.

I But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions.I Thus another advantage of the mathematical approach:

encourages transparency of assumptions.

I Let’s take a look at a textbook example of how some simpleassumptions can be turned into a model.

Page 6: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Economics

I The study of constrained choice.I Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.

I Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.I Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.I But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions.

I Thus another advantage of the mathematical approach:encourages transparency of assumptions.

I Let’s take a look at a textbook example of how some simpleassumptions can be turned into a model.

Page 7: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Economics

I The study of constrained choice.I Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.

I Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.I Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.I But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions.I Thus another advantage of the mathematical approach:

encourages transparency of assumptions.

I Let’s take a look at a textbook example of how some simpleassumptions can be turned into a model.

Page 8: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Economics

I The study of constrained choice.I Build mathematical models of decision makers’ behaviours.

I Typically gives us very sharp conclusions.I Suggests effects of policy changes—comparative statics.I But hard: the world is very complex, so we need assumptions.I Thus another advantage of the mathematical approach:

encourages transparency of assumptions.

I Let’s take a look at a textbook example of how some simpleassumptions can be turned into a model.

Page 9: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Outline

Price discrimination: from assumptions to policy statements

Assumptions and applicability

Page 10: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Price discrimination

I Price discrimination is the practice of pricing such thatdifferent groups of consumers yield different price-costmargins for the firm.

Page 11: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

A price discrimination example

I Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varyingquality.

I Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q.I Let q be continuous.I Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q.

Let C ′(q) > 0 (increasing costs), C ′′(q) > 0 (convex costs),and C(0) = 0.

I There are two types of customer: low (L), and high (H).

I A type i ∈ {L,H} consumer enjoys surplus

Ui = θiq − p.

where p is the price to be paid to the firm, and θi is theconsumer’s willingness to pay for a one unit increase in quality.

I Let θL < θH .

Page 12: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

A price discrimination example

I Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varyingquality.

I Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q.I Let q be continuous.I Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q.

Let C ′(q) > 0 (increasing costs), C ′′(q) > 0 (convex costs),and C(0) = 0.

I There are two types of customer: low (L), and high (H).

I A type i ∈ {L,H} consumer enjoys surplus

Ui = θiq − p.

where p is the price to be paid to the firm, and θi is theconsumer’s willingness to pay for a one unit increase in quality.

I Let θL < θH .

Page 13: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

A price discrimination example

I Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varyingquality.

I Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q.I Let q be continuous.I Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q.

Let C ′(q) > 0 (increasing costs), C ′′(q) > 0 (convex costs),and C(0) = 0.

I There are two types of customer: low (L), and high (H).

I A type i ∈ {L,H} consumer enjoys surplus

Ui = θiq − p.

where p is the price to be paid to the firm, and θi is theconsumer’s willingness to pay for a one unit increase in quality.

I Let θL < θH .

Page 14: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

A price discrimination example

I Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varyingquality.

I Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q.I Let q be continuous.I Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q.

Let C ′(q) > 0 (increasing costs), C ′′(q) > 0 (convex costs),and C(0) = 0.

I There are two types of customer: low (L), and high (H).

I A type i ∈ {L,H} consumer enjoys surplus

Ui = θiq − p.

where p is the price to be paid to the firm, and θi is theconsumer’s willingness to pay for a one unit increase in quality.

I Let θL < θH .

Page 15: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

A price discrimination example

I Imagine a monopolist firm that sells some products of varyingquality.

I Assume that quality can be indexed by a number, q.I Let q be continuous.I Suppose that it costs C(q) to provide a product with quality q.

Let C ′(q) > 0 (increasing costs), C ′′(q) > 0 (convex costs),and C(0) = 0.

I There are two types of customer: low (L), and high (H).

I A type i ∈ {L,H} consumer enjoys surplus

Ui = θiq − p.

where p is the price to be paid to the firm, and θi is theconsumer’s willingness to pay for a one unit increase in quality.

I Let θL < θH .

Page 16: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First order discrimination

I In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumerit is facing.

I It could then design a product/price combination for eachtype.

I i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-typeconsumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH .

I The firm’s objective would then be to

maxqi,pi

pi − C(qi)

subject to the constraint

θiqi − pi ≥ 0.

I This kind of behaviour is called first degree pricediscrimination.

Page 17: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First order discrimination

I In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumerit is facing.

I It could then design a product/price combination for eachtype.

I i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-typeconsumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH .

I The firm’s objective would then be to

maxqi,pi

pi − C(qi)

subject to the constraint

θiqi − pi ≥ 0.

I This kind of behaviour is called first degree pricediscrimination.

Page 18: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First order discrimination

I In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumerit is facing.

I It could then design a product/price combination for eachtype.

I i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-typeconsumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH .

I The firm’s objective would then be to

maxqi,pi

pi − C(qi)

subject to the constraint

θiqi − pi ≥ 0.

I This kind of behaviour is called first degree pricediscrimination.

Page 19: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First order discrimination

I In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumerit is facing.

I It could then design a product/price combination for eachtype.

I i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-typeconsumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH .

I The firm’s objective would then be to

maxqi,pi

pi − C(qi)

subject to the constraint

θiqi − pi ≥ 0.

I This kind of behaviour is called first degree pricediscrimination.

Page 20: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First order discrimination

I In a perfect world, the firm would know the type of consumerit is facing.

I It could then design a product/price combination for eachtype.

I i.e. Sell a ‘budget’ product with q = qL at price pL to L-typeconsumers, and a ‘luxury’ product with q = qH at price pH .

I The firm’s objective would then be to

maxqi,pi

pi − C(qi)

subject to the constraint

θiqi − pi ≥ 0.

I This kind of behaviour is called first degree pricediscrimination.

Page 21: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First order discrimination

maxqi,pi

pi − C(qi) s.t. θiqi − pi ≥ 0.

I In fact, since the firm knows θi, it can just set pi = θiqi.

I Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives

maxqi

θiqi − C(qi).

I Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi, and cost byC ′(qi).

I It is therefore profitable to increase quality if and only ifθi > C ′(qi).

I So quality q∗i is produced where θi = C ′(qi), i.e. wheremarginal cost of qi is equal to marginal willingness to pay forit.

Page 22: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First order discrimination

maxqi,pi

pi − C(qi) s.t. θiqi − pi ≥ 0.

I In fact, since the firm knows θi, it can just set pi = θiqi.

I Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives

maxqi

θiqi − C(qi).

I Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi, and cost byC ′(qi).

I It is therefore profitable to increase quality if and only ifθi > C ′(qi).

I So quality q∗i is produced where θi = C ′(qi), i.e. wheremarginal cost of qi is equal to marginal willingness to pay forit.

Page 23: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First order discrimination

maxqi,pi

pi − C(qi) s.t. θiqi − pi ≥ 0.

I In fact, since the firm knows θi, it can just set pi = θiqi.

I Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives

maxqi

θiqi − C(qi).

I Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi, and cost byC ′(qi).

I It is therefore profitable to increase quality if and only ifθi > C ′(qi).

I So quality q∗i is produced where θi = C ′(qi), i.e. wheremarginal cost of qi is equal to marginal willingness to pay forit.

Page 24: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First order discrimination

maxqi,pi

pi − C(qi) s.t. θiqi − pi ≥ 0.

I In fact, since the firm knows θi, it can just set pi = θiqi.

I Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives

maxqi

θiqi − C(qi).

I Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi, and cost byC ′(qi).

I It is therefore profitable to increase quality if and only ifθi > C ′(qi).

I So quality q∗i is produced where θi = C ′(qi), i.e. wheremarginal cost of qi is equal to marginal willingness to pay forit.

Page 25: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First order discrimination

maxqi,pi

pi − C(qi) s.t. θiqi − pi ≥ 0.

I In fact, since the firm knows θi, it can just set pi = θiqi.

I Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives

maxqi

θiqi − C(qi).

I Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi, and cost byC ′(qi).

I It is therefore profitable to increase quality if and only ifθi > C ′(qi).

I So quality q∗i is produced where θi = C ′(qi), i.e. wheremarginal cost of qi is equal to marginal willingness to pay forit.

Page 26: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First order discrimination

maxqi,pi

pi − C(qi) s.t. θiqi − pi ≥ 0.

I In fact, since the firm knows θi, it can just set pi = θiqi.

I Substituting this into the maximisation problem gives

maxqi

θiqi − C(qi).

I Increasing qi by one unit increases revenue by θi, and cost byC ′(qi).

I It is therefore profitable to increase quality if and only ifθi > C ′(qi).

I So quality q∗i is produced where θi = C ′(qi), i.e. wheremarginal cost of qi is equal to marginal willingness to pay forit.

Page 27: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

What can we say about these qs?

I Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,we have left the latter with no surplus.

I However, that θi = C ′(qi) implies the chosen qualities areefficient!

I Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare:

(θiqi − p) + (p− C(qi)) = θiqi − C(qi).

I This is exactly what the firm is maximising!

I That θi = C ′(qi) also implies that qL < qH , and hencepL < pH .

Page 28: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

What can we say about these qs?

I Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,we have left the latter with no surplus.

I However, that θi = C ′(qi) implies the chosen qualities areefficient!

I Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare:

(θiqi − p) + (p− C(qi)) = θiqi − C(qi).

I This is exactly what the firm is maximising!

I That θi = C ′(qi) also implies that qL < qH , and hencepL < pH .

Page 29: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

What can we say about these qs?

I Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,we have left the latter with no surplus.

I However, that θi = C ′(qi) implies the chosen qualities areefficient!

I Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare:

(θiqi − p) + (p− C(qi))

= θiqi − C(qi).

I This is exactly what the firm is maximising!

I That θi = C ′(qi) also implies that qL < qH , and hencepL < pH .

Page 30: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

What can we say about these qs?

I Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,we have left the latter with no surplus.

I However, that θi = C ′(qi) implies the chosen qualities areefficient!

I Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare:

(θiqi − p) + (p− C(qi)) = θiqi − C(qi).

I This is exactly what the firm is maximising!

I That θi = C ′(qi) also implies that qL < qH , and hencepL < pH .

Page 31: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

What can we say about these qs?

I Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,we have left the latter with no surplus.

I However, that θi = C ′(qi) implies the chosen qualities areefficient!

I Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare:

(θiqi − p) + (p− C(qi)) = θiqi − C(qi).

I This is exactly what the firm is maximising!

I That θi = C ′(qi) also implies that qL < qH , and hencepL < pH .

Page 32: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

What can we say about these qs?

I Firstly, by giving firms so much information about consumers,we have left the latter with no surplus.

I However, that θi = C ′(qi) implies the chosen qualities areefficient!

I Social welfare given by consumer + firm welfare:

(θiqi − p) + (p− C(qi)) = θiqi − C(qi).

I This is exactly what the firm is maximising!

I That θi = C ′(qi) also implies that qL < qH , and hencepL < pH .

Page 33: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Segmentation breakdown

I Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend onthe consumer to buy the product designed for them.

I Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high qualityproduct, they get

θHqH − pH = θHqH − θHqH = 0,

whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get

θHqL − pL > θLqL − pL = 0.

I Thus, all consumers will buy the budget product—this iscalled adverse selection.

Page 34: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Segmentation breakdown

I Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend onthe consumer to buy the product designed for them.

I Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high qualityproduct, they get

θHqH − pH = θHqH − θHqH = 0,

whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get

θHqL − pL > θLqL − pL = 0.

I Thus, all consumers will buy the budget product—this iscalled adverse selection.

Page 35: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Segmentation breakdown

I Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend onthe consumer to buy the product designed for them.

I Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high qualityproduct, they get

θHqH − pH = θHqH − θHqH = 0,

whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get

θHqL − pL

> θLqL − pL = 0.

I Thus, all consumers will buy the budget product—this iscalled adverse selection.

Page 36: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Segmentation breakdown

I Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend onthe consumer to buy the product designed for them.

I Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high qualityproduct, they get

θHqH − pH = θHqH − θHqH = 0,

whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get

θHqL − pL > θLqL − pL

= 0.

I Thus, all consumers will buy the budget product—this iscalled adverse selection.

Page 37: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Segmentation breakdown

I Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend onthe consumer to buy the product designed for them.

I Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high qualityproduct, they get

θHqH − pH = θHqH − θHqH = 0,

whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get

θHqL − pL > θLqL − pL = 0.

I Thus, all consumers will buy the budget product—this iscalled adverse selection.

Page 38: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Segmentation breakdown

I Now, firms typically cannot observe θi and so must depend onthe consumer to buy the product designed for them.

I Therein lies a problem: if high consumers buy the high qualityproduct, they get

θHqH − pH = θHqH − θHqH = 0,

whereas if they buy the low quality product, they get

θHqL − pL > θLqL − pL = 0.

I Thus, all consumers will buy the budget product—this iscalled adverse selection.

Page 39: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Solution: mechanism designI Question: What can the firm do about this?

I Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.I Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of

type H with probability (1− α). The new problem is then:

maxqL,pL,qH ,pH

α(pL − C(qL)) + (1− α)(pH − C(qH))

subject to the constraint

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL (ICH)

θLqL − pL ≥ θHqH − pH (ICL)

θHqH − pH ≥ 0 (IRH)

θLqL − pL ≥ 0 (IRL)

I Solving such a problem is known as second degree pricediscrimination.

Page 40: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Solution: mechanism designI Question: What can the firm do about this?I Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.

I Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and oftype H with probability (1− α). The new problem is then:

maxqL,pL,qH ,pH

α(pL − C(qL)) + (1− α)(pH − C(qH))

subject to the constraint

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL (ICH)

θLqL − pL ≥ θHqH − pH (ICL)

θHqH − pH ≥ 0 (IRH)

θLqL − pL ≥ 0 (IRL)

I Solving such a problem is known as second degree pricediscrimination.

Page 41: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Solution: mechanism designI Question: What can the firm do about this?I Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.I Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of

type H with probability (1− α).

The new problem is then:

maxqL,pL,qH ,pH

α(pL − C(qL)) + (1− α)(pH − C(qH))

subject to the constraint

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL (ICH)

θLqL − pL ≥ θHqH − pH (ICL)

θHqH − pH ≥ 0 (IRH)

θLqL − pL ≥ 0 (IRL)

I Solving such a problem is known as second degree pricediscrimination.

Page 42: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Solution: mechanism designI Question: What can the firm do about this?I Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.I Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of

type H with probability (1− α). The new problem is then:

maxqL,pL,qH ,pH

α(pL − C(qL)) + (1− α)(pH − C(qH))

subject to the constraint

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL (ICH)

θLqL − pL ≥ θHqH − pH (ICL)

θHqH − pH ≥ 0 (IRH)

θLqL − pL ≥ 0 (IRL)

I Solving such a problem is known as second degree pricediscrimination.

Page 43: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Solution: mechanism designI Question: What can the firm do about this?I Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.I Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of

type H with probability (1− α). The new problem is then:

maxqL,pL,qH ,pH

α(pL − C(qL)) + (1− α)(pH − C(qH))

subject to the constraint

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL (ICH)

θLqL − pL ≥ θHqH − pH (ICL)

θHqH − pH ≥ 0 (IRH)

θLqL − pL ≥ 0 (IRL)

I Solving such a problem is known as second degree pricediscrimination.

Page 44: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Solution: mechanism designI Question: What can the firm do about this?I Answer: Change it’s maximisation problem.I Suppose a consumer is of type L with probability α and of

type H with probability (1− α). The new problem is then:

maxqL,pL,qH ,pH

α(pL − C(qL)) + (1− α)(pH − C(qH))

subject to the constraint

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL (ICH)

θLqL − pL ≥ θHqH − pH (ICL)

θHqH − pH ≥ 0 (IRH)

θLqL − pL ≥ 0 (IRL)

I Solving such a problem is known as second degree pricediscrimination.

Page 45: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

IRL is ‘binding’

I Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.that θLqL − pL = 0.

I This means that home users are left with no surplus.

I ICH says

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL ≥ θLqL − pL

I Thus, if θLqL − pL > 0, then it must also be true thatθHqH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind.

I But then the firm could increase both pL and pH withoutviolating any condition.

I This implies that IRL must bind at the optimum.

Page 46: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

IRL is ‘binding’

I Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.that θLqL − pL = 0.

I This means that home users are left with no surplus.

I ICH says

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL

≥ θLqL − pL

I Thus, if θLqL − pL > 0, then it must also be true thatθHqH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind.

I But then the firm could increase both pL and pH withoutviolating any condition.

I This implies that IRL must bind at the optimum.

Page 47: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

IRL is ‘binding’

I Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.that θLqL − pL = 0.

I This means that home users are left with no surplus.

I ICH says

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL ≥ θLqL − pL

I Thus, if θLqL − pL > 0, then it must also be true thatθHqH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind.

I But then the firm could increase both pL and pH withoutviolating any condition.

I This implies that IRL must bind at the optimum.

Page 48: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

IRL is ‘binding’

I Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.that θLqL − pL = 0.

I This means that home users are left with no surplus.

I ICH says

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL ≥ θLqL − pL

I Thus, if θLqL − pL > 0, then it must also be true thatθHqH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind.

I But then the firm could increase both pL and pH withoutviolating any condition.

I This implies that IRL must bind at the optimum.

Page 49: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

IRL is ‘binding’

I Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.that θLqL − pL = 0.

I This means that home users are left with no surplus.

I ICH says

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL ≥ θLqL − pL

I Thus, if θLqL − pL > 0, then it must also be true thatθHqH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind.

I But then the firm could increase both pL and pH withoutviolating any condition.

I This implies that IRL must bind at the optimum.

Page 50: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

IRL is ‘binding’

I Let’s begin by establishing that IRL holds with equality i.e.that θLqL − pL = 0.

I This means that home users are left with no surplus.

I ICH says

θHqH − pH ≥ θHqL − pL ≥ θLqL − pL

I Thus, if θLqL − pL > 0, then it must also be true thatθHqH − pH > 0 so that neither IRL nor IRH bind.

I But then the firm could increase both pL and pH withoutviolating any condition.

I This implies that IRL must bind at the optimum.

Page 51: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

ICH is ‘binding’

I We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. thatθHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worsethen H type consumers would switch to buying the budgetproduct.

I Suppose that this weren’t true:

θHqH − pH > θHqL − pL ≥ θLqL − pL = 0

I Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH.

I But then the firm could increase pH without violating anycondition.

I This implies that ICH must bind at the optimum.

Page 52: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

ICH is ‘binding’

I We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. thatθHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worsethen H type consumers would switch to buying the budgetproduct.

I Suppose that this weren’t true:

θHqH − pH > θHqL − pL

≥ θLqL − pL = 0

I Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH.

I But then the firm could increase pH without violating anycondition.

I This implies that ICH must bind at the optimum.

Page 53: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

ICH is ‘binding’

I We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. thatθHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worsethen H type consumers would switch to buying the budgetproduct.

I Suppose that this weren’t true:

θHqH − pH > θHqL − pL ≥ θLqL − pL

= 0

I Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH.

I But then the firm could increase pH without violating anycondition.

I This implies that ICH must bind at the optimum.

Page 54: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

ICH is ‘binding’

I We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. thatθHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worsethen H type consumers would switch to buying the budgetproduct.

I Suppose that this weren’t true:

θHqH − pH > θHqL − pL ≥ θLqL − pL = 0

I Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH.

I But then the firm could increase pH without violating anycondition.

I This implies that ICH must bind at the optimum.

Page 55: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

ICH is ‘binding’

I We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. thatθHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worsethen H type consumers would switch to buying the budgetproduct.

I Suppose that this weren’t true:

θHqH − pH > θHqL − pL ≥ θLqL − pL = 0

I Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH.

I But then the firm could increase pH without violating anycondition.

I This implies that ICH must bind at the optimum.

Page 56: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

ICH is ‘binding’

I We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. thatθHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worsethen H type consumers would switch to buying the budgetproduct.

I Suppose that this weren’t true:

θHqH − pH > θHqL − pL ≥ θLqL − pL = 0

I Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH.

I But then the firm could increase pH without violating anycondition.

I This implies that ICH must bind at the optimum.

Page 57: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

ICH is ‘binding’

I We next show that ICH holds with equality i.e. thatθHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I This means if the deal for the luxury product got any worsethen H type consumers would switch to buying the budgetproduct.

I Suppose that this weren’t true:

θHqH − pH > θHqL − pL ≥ θLqL − pL = 0

I Thus, if ICH does not bind then neither does IRH.

I But then the firm could increase pH without violating anycondition.

I This implies that ICH must bind at the optimum.

Page 58: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Can neglect IRH and ICL

I That ICH binds implies θHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I IRL implies θLqL − pL = 0.

I Thus we have

θHqH − pH = θHqL − pH > θLqL − pL = 0.

I So IRH can be neglected.

I This means that business customers get strictly positive utility.

Page 59: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Can neglect IRH and ICL

I That ICH binds implies θHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I IRL implies θLqL − pL = 0.

I Thus we have

θHqH − pH = θHqL − pH > θLqL − pL = 0.

I So IRH can be neglected.

I This means that business customers get strictly positive utility.

Page 60: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Can neglect IRH and ICL

I That ICH binds implies θHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I IRL implies θLqL − pL = 0.

I Thus we have

θHqH − pH = θHqL − pH > θLqL − pL = 0.

I So IRH can be neglected.

I This means that business customers get strictly positive utility.

Page 61: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Can neglect IRH and ICL

I That ICH binds implies θHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I IRL implies θLqL − pL = 0.

I Thus we have

θHqH − pH = θHqL − pH > θLqL − pL = 0.

I So IRH can be neglected.

I This means that business customers get strictly positive utility.

Page 62: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Can neglect IRH and ICL

I That ICH binds implies θHqH − pH = θHqL − pL.

I IRL implies θLqL − pL = 0.

I Thus we have

θHqH − pH = θHqL − pH > θLqL − pL = 0.

I So IRH can be neglected.

I This means that business customers get strictly positive utility.

Page 63: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Can neglect ICL

I It can also be shown that ICL does not bind.

I Briefly: since ICH binds θH(qH − qL) = pH − pL.

I But ICL says (after rearranging) θL(qH − qL) ≤ pH − pL.

I The inequality must be strict since θH > θL.

I This means that the home bundle is strictly more attractive tohome users than is the business edition.

Page 64: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Can neglect ICL

I It can also be shown that ICL does not bind.

I Briefly: since ICH binds θH(qH − qL) = pH − pL.I But ICL says (after rearranging) θL(qH − qL) ≤ pH − pL.

I The inequality must be strict since θH > θL.

I This means that the home bundle is strictly more attractive tohome users than is the business edition.

Page 65: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Can neglect ICL

I It can also be shown that ICL does not bind.

I Briefly: since ICH binds θH(qH − qL) = pH − pL.I But ICL says (after rearranging) θL(qH − qL) ≤ pH − pL.

I The inequality must be strict since θH > θL.

I This means that the home bundle is strictly more attractive tohome users than is the business edition.

Page 66: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Can neglect ICL

I It can also be shown that ICL does not bind.

I Briefly: since ICH binds θH(qH − qL) = pH − pL.I But ICL says (after rearranging) θL(qH − qL) ≤ pH − pL.

I The inequality must be strict since θH > θL.

I This means that the home bundle is strictly more attractive tohome users than is the business edition.

Page 67: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

qH is the set at the efficient level

I Now we will show that the chosen qH is q∗H—i.e. whereC ′(qH) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.

I This implies that the quality offered to B-types is sociallyoptimal.

I Suppose that the optimal qH has C ′(qH) < θH .I The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH topH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately (1− α)∆(θH − C ′(qH)) > 0.

I Thus, original qH was not optimal.

I Similarly, if C ′(qH) > θH : The firm can reduce qH to qH −∆,provided it cuts its price for H by at least ∆θH .

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately ∆(C ′(qH)− θH) > 0

Page 68: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

qH is the set at the efficient level

I Now we will show that the chosen qH is q∗H—i.e. whereC ′(qH) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.

I This implies that the quality offered to B-types is sociallyoptimal.

I Suppose that the optimal qH has C ′(qH) < θH .

I The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH topH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately (1− α)∆(θH − C ′(qH)) > 0.

I Thus, original qH was not optimal.

I Similarly, if C ′(qH) > θH : The firm can reduce qH to qH −∆,provided it cuts its price for H by at least ∆θH .

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately ∆(C ′(qH)− θH) > 0

Page 69: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

qH is the set at the efficient level

I Now we will show that the chosen qH is q∗H—i.e. whereC ′(qH) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.

I This implies that the quality offered to B-types is sociallyoptimal.

I Suppose that the optimal qH has C ′(qH) < θH .I The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH topH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately (1− α)∆(θH − C ′(qH)) > 0.

I Thus, original qH was not optimal.

I Similarly, if C ′(qH) > θH : The firm can reduce qH to qH −∆,provided it cuts its price for H by at least ∆θH .

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately ∆(C ′(qH)− θH) > 0

Page 70: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

qH is the set at the efficient level

I Now we will show that the chosen qH is q∗H—i.e. whereC ′(qH) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.

I This implies that the quality offered to B-types is sociallyoptimal.

I Suppose that the optimal qH has C ′(qH) < θH .I The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH topH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately (1− α)∆(θH − C ′(qH)) > 0.

I Thus, original qH was not optimal.

I Similarly, if C ′(qH) > θH : The firm can reduce qH to qH −∆,provided it cuts its price for H by at least ∆θH .

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately ∆(C ′(qH)− θH) > 0

Page 71: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

qH is the set at the efficient level

I Now we will show that the chosen qH is q∗H—i.e. whereC ′(qH) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.

I This implies that the quality offered to B-types is sociallyoptimal.

I Suppose that the optimal qH has C ′(qH) < θH .I The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH topH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately (1− α)∆(θH − C ′(qH)) > 0.

I Thus, original qH was not optimal.

I Similarly, if C ′(qH) > θH : The firm can reduce qH to qH −∆,provided it cuts its price for H by at least ∆θH .

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately ∆(C ′(qH)− θH) > 0

Page 72: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

qH is the set at the efficient level

I Now we will show that the chosen qH is q∗H—i.e. whereC ′(qH) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.

I This implies that the quality offered to B-types is sociallyoptimal.

I Suppose that the optimal qH has C ′(qH) < θH .I The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH topH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately (1− α)∆(θH − C ′(qH)) > 0.

I Thus, original qH was not optimal.

I Similarly, if C ′(qH) > θH : The firm can reduce qH to qH −∆,provided it cuts its price for H by at least ∆θH .

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately ∆(C ′(qH)− θH) > 0

Page 73: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

qH is the set at the efficient level

I Now we will show that the chosen qH is q∗H—i.e. whereC ′(qH) = θH just like in the first order discrimination case.

I This implies that the quality offered to B-types is sociallyoptimal.

I Suppose that the optimal qH has C ′(qH) < θH .I The firm could change qH to qH + ∆, and increase pH topH + ∆θH without violating ICH, IRH, or ICL.

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately (1− α)∆(θH − C ′(qH)) > 0.

I Thus, original qH was not optimal.

I Similarly, if C ′(qH) > θH : The firm can reduce qH to qH −∆,provided it cuts its price for H by at least ∆θH .

I When ∆ is small, the change in the firm’s profits isapproximately ∆(C ′(qH)− θH) > 0

Page 74: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Optimal prices

I Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices.

I Since IRL binds, we know that pL = θLqL.

I Since ICH binds, we know that θHqH − pH = θHqL − pL, orequivalently, that pH = pL + θH(q∗H − qL).

I Combining these two statements: pH = θLqL + θH(q∗H − qL).

Page 75: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Optimal prices

I Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices.

I Since IRL binds, we know that pL = θLqL.

I Since ICH binds, we know that θHqH − pH = θHqL − pL, orequivalently, that pH = pL + θH(q∗H − qL).

I Combining these two statements: pH = θLqL + θH(q∗H − qL).

Page 76: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Optimal prices

I Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices.

I Since IRL binds, we know that pL = θLqL.

I Since ICH binds, we know that θHqH − pH = θHqL − pL, orequivalently, that pH = pL + θH(q∗H − qL).

I Combining these two statements: pH = θLqL + θH(q∗H − qL).

Page 77: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Optimal prices

I Now we can set about characterising the optimal prices.

I Since IRL binds, we know that pL = θLqL.

I Since ICH binds, we know that θHqH − pH = θHqL − pL, orequivalently, that pH = pL + θH(q∗H − qL).

I Combining these two statements: pH = θLqL + θH(q∗H − qL).

Page 78: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Firm’s objective

I The firm’s objective is

maxqL,pL,qH ,pH

α(pL − C(qL)) + (1− α)(pH − C(qH)).

I Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: sinceqH = q∗H , we only need to worry about the choice of qL.):

maxqL

α(θLqL−C(qL))+(1−α) [θLqL + θH(q∗H − qL)− C(q∗H)] .

I We can easily calculate the qL that maximises this bydifferentiating:

α[θL − C ′(qL)

]+ (1− α) [θL − θH ] = 0

I Rearranging: C ′(qL) = θL − 1−αα [θH − θL] < θL

Page 79: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Firm’s objective

I The firm’s objective is

maxqL,pL,qH ,pH

α(pL − C(qL)) + (1− α)(pH − C(qH)).

I Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: sinceqH = q∗H , we only need to worry about the choice of qL.):

maxqL

α(θLqL−C(qL))+(1−α) [θLqL + θH(q∗H − qL)− C(q∗H)] .

I We can easily calculate the qL that maximises this bydifferentiating:

α[θL − C ′(qL)

]+ (1− α) [θL − θH ] = 0

I Rearranging: C ′(qL) = θL − 1−αα [θH − θL] < θL

Page 80: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Firm’s objective

I The firm’s objective is

maxqL,pL,qH ,pH

α(pL − C(qL)) + (1− α)(pH − C(qH)).

I Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: sinceqH = q∗H , we only need to worry about the choice of qL.):

maxqL

α(θLqL−C(qL))+(1−α) [θLqL + θH(q∗H − qL)− C(q∗H)] .

I We can easily calculate the qL that maximises this bydifferentiating:

α[θL − C ′(qL)

]+ (1− α) [θL − θH ] = 0

I Rearranging: C ′(qL) = θL − 1−αα [θH − θL] < θL

Page 81: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Firm’s objective

I The firm’s objective is

maxqL,pL,qH ,pH

α(pL − C(qL)) + (1− α)(pH − C(qH)).

I Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: sinceqH = q∗H , we only need to worry about the choice of qL.):

maxqL

α(θLqL−C(qL))+(1−α) [θLqL + θH(q∗H − qL)− C(q∗H)] .

I We can easily calculate the qL that maximises this bydifferentiating:

α[θL − C ′(qL)

]+ (1− α) [θL − θH ] = 0

I Rearranging: C ′(qL) = θL − 1−αα [θH − θL]

< θL

Page 82: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Firm’s objective

I The firm’s objective is

maxqL,pL,qH ,pH

α(pL − C(qL)) + (1− α)(pH − C(qH)).

I Substituting in the material we just derived (Note: sinceqH = q∗H , we only need to worry about the choice of qL.):

maxqL

α(θLqL−C(qL))+(1−α) [θLqL + θH(q∗H − qL)− C(q∗H)] .

I We can easily calculate the qL that maximises this bydifferentiating:

α[θL − C ′(qL)

]+ (1− α) [θL − θH ] = 0

I Rearranging: C ′(qL) = θL − 1−αα [θH − θL] < θL

Page 83: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Discussion of the model

I The name of the game is to separate clients into groups andmilk each group for as much as possible.

I The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high valuecustomers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.

I But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high valueconsumers will just buy the cheap product.

I Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budgetproduct to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it.

I Then the firm can charge a high price for the premiumproduct, without worrying about customers switching tocheaper versions.

Page 84: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Discussion of the model

I The name of the game is to separate clients into groups andmilk each group for as much as possible.

I The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high valuecustomers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.

I But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high valueconsumers will just buy the cheap product.

I Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budgetproduct to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it.

I Then the firm can charge a high price for the premiumproduct, without worrying about customers switching tocheaper versions.

Page 85: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Discussion of the model

I The name of the game is to separate clients into groups andmilk each group for as much as possible.

I The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high valuecustomers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.

I But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high valueconsumers will just buy the cheap product.

I Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budgetproduct to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it.

I Then the firm can charge a high price for the premiumproduct, without worrying about customers switching tocheaper versions.

Page 86: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Discussion of the model

I The name of the game is to separate clients into groups andmilk each group for as much as possible.

I The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high valuecustomers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.

I But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high valueconsumers will just buy the cheap product.

I Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budgetproduct to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it.

I Then the firm can charge a high price for the premiumproduct, without worrying about customers switching tocheaper versions.

Page 87: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Discussion of the model

I The name of the game is to separate clients into groups andmilk each group for as much as possible.

I The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high valuecustomers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.

I But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high valueconsumers will just buy the cheap product.

I Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budgetproduct to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it.

I Then the firm can charge a high price for the premiumproduct, without worrying about customers switching tocheaper versions.

Page 88: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Discussion of the model

I The name of the game is to separate clients into groups andmilk each group for as much as possible.

I The monopolist can squeeze more profit from high valuecustomers, who will pay more for a given increase in quality.

I But they can’t squeeze too hard—otherwise high valueconsumers will just buy the cheap product.

I Solution: deliberately degrade the usefulness of the budgetproduct to ensure that high-value customers refuse to buy it.

I Then the firm can charge a high price for the premiumproduct, without worrying about customers switching tocheaper versions.

Page 89: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Examples

£2/kg£2/kg £10/kg £18/kg

Page 90: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Examples

It is not because of the few thousand francs which would have tobe spent to put a roof over the third-class carriage or to upholsterthe third-class seats that some company or other has opencarriages with wooden benches. . . What the company is trying todo is prevent the passengers who can pay the second-class farefrom travelling third class; it hits the poor, not because it wants tohurt them, but to frighten the rich. . . (Ekelund [1970])

Page 91: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

I Note that the distortion of qL away from its optimal level is amarket failure.

I However, it does not follow that the optimal policy is toprevent firms from second degree discrimination. . .

Page 92: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

I Note that the distortion of qL away from its optimal level is amarket failure.

I However, it does not follow that the optimal policy is toprevent firms from second degree discrimination. . .

Page 93: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Second-degree discrimination & social welfareI What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?

I Will provide either q∗H at price θHq∗H , or q∗L at price θLq

∗L.

I In the efficient allocation, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

(we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around).I In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is

α [θLqL − C(qL)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

I If the firm offers only q∗H , social welfare is

(1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

Thus social welfare falls.I If the firm offers only q∗L, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗L − C(q∗L)] ,

so that welfare may fall or increase relative to second-orderPD.

Page 94: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Second-degree discrimination & social welfareI What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?I Will provide either q∗H at price θHq

∗H , or q∗L at price θLq

∗L.

I In the efficient allocation, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

(we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around).I In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is

α [θLqL − C(qL)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

I If the firm offers only q∗H , social welfare is

(1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

Thus social welfare falls.I If the firm offers only q∗L, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗L − C(q∗L)] ,

so that welfare may fall or increase relative to second-orderPD.

Page 95: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Second-degree discrimination & social welfareI What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?I Will provide either q∗H at price θHq

∗H , or q∗L at price θLq

∗L.

I In the efficient allocation, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

(we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around).

I In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is

α [θLqL − C(qL)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

I If the firm offers only q∗H , social welfare is

(1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

Thus social welfare falls.I If the firm offers only q∗L, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗L − C(q∗L)] ,

so that welfare may fall or increase relative to second-orderPD.

Page 96: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Second-degree discrimination & social welfareI What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?I Will provide either q∗H at price θHq

∗H , or q∗L at price θLq

∗L.

I In the efficient allocation, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

(we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around).I In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is

α [θLqL − C(qL)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

I If the firm offers only q∗H , social welfare is

(1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

Thus social welfare falls.I If the firm offers only q∗L, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗L − C(q∗L)] ,

so that welfare may fall or increase relative to second-orderPD.

Page 97: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Second-degree discrimination & social welfareI What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?I Will provide either q∗H at price θHq

∗H , or q∗L at price θLq

∗L.

I In the efficient allocation, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

(we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around).I In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is

α [θLqL − C(qL)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

I If the firm offers only q∗H , social welfare is

(1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

Thus social welfare falls.

I If the firm offers only q∗L, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗L − C(q∗L)] ,

so that welfare may fall or increase relative to second-orderPD.

Page 98: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Second-degree discrimination & social welfareI What will the firm do if it cannot price discriminate?I Will provide either q∗H at price θHq

∗H , or q∗L at price θLq

∗L.

I In the efficient allocation, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

(we can ignore the ps which simply move surplus around).I In the second order price discrimination case, social welfare is

α [θLqL − C(qL)] + (1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

I If the firm offers only q∗H , social welfare is

(1− α) [θHq∗H − C(q∗H)] .

Thus social welfare falls.I If the firm offers only q∗L, social welfare is

α [θLq∗L − C(q∗L)] + (1− α) [θHq∗L − C(q∗L)] ,

so that welfare may fall or increase relative to second-orderPD.

Page 99: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

More current examples

I In fact, when one thinks about it, there are similar-lookingcases in many information markets:

Page 100: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

More current examples

Page 101: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

More current examples

Page 102: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

More current examples

Page 103: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

More current examples

Page 104: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

More current examples

Page 105: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Outline

Price discrimination: from assumptions to policy statements

Assumptions and applicability

Page 106: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Assumptions, assumptions. . .

I But these examples are a little different to the ones consideredbefore:

I Cost to MS of “surprising” a customer by giving them theprofessional, rather than home edition of Windows is basicallyzero.

I Corresponds to C ′(q) = 0, C ′′(q) = 0—which is contrary toour assumptions.

I When we try to put this into the model things break down.Let’s see why. . .

Page 107: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Assumptions, assumptions. . .

I But these examples are a little different to the ones consideredbefore:

I Cost to MS of “surprising” a customer by giving them theprofessional, rather than home edition of Windows is basicallyzero.

I Corresponds to C ′(q) = 0, C ′′(q) = 0—which is contrary toour assumptions.

I When we try to put this into the model things break down.Let’s see why. . .

Page 108: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Assumptions, assumptions. . .

I But these examples are a little different to the ones consideredbefore:

I Cost to MS of “surprising” a customer by giving them theprofessional, rather than home edition of Windows is basicallyzero.

I Corresponds to C ′(q) = 0, C ′′(q) = 0—which is contrary toour assumptions.

I When we try to put this into the model things break down.Let’s see why. . .

Page 109: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)

Price

QuantityQuality

Page 110: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

Page 111: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)

Price

Willingness to pay

QuantityQuality

θH

qH

Page 112: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)

Price

QuantityQuality

C’(q)

Page 113: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)

Price

QuantityQuality

C’(q)Cost of production

qH

Page 114: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment (assuming α = 1/2)

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

θL

C’(q)

Page 115: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First degree discrimination

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

qHqL

θL

C’(q)

* *

Page 116: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

qHqL

C’(q)CS of high types from buyinglow quality good

qLθL=

pL

Page 117: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

qHqL

C’(q)CS of high types from buyinglow quality good

qLθL=

pL

Page 118: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

qHqL

C’(q)

qLθL=

pL

pHqH

Page 119: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

qHqL

C’(q)CS of high types from buyinghigh quality good

qLθL=

pL

pHqH

Page 120: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

qHqL qL+Δ

C’(q)

qLθL=

pL

Page 121: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

qHqL qL+Δ

C’(q)Loss (must reduce pH to maintain ICH)

qLθL=

pL

Page 122: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

qHqL qL+Δ

C’(q)Loss (must reduce pH to maintain ICH)

Loss (higher q is moreexpensive to produce)

Gain (can charge moreto low type consumers)

qLθL=

pL

Page 123: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Graphical treatment

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

qH

C’(q)

qL qL* *

qLθL=

pL

Page 124: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Constant marginal cost

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

C’(q)

qLθL=

pL

Page 125: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

What goes wrong?

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

C’(q)

qL qL+Δ

qLθL=

pL

Page 126: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

What goes wrong? (i)

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

C’(q)

qL qL+ΔqL qL+Δ

qLθL=

pL

Page 127: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

What goes wrong? (ii)

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

C’(q)

qL qL+ΔqL qL+Δ

qLθL=

pL

Page 128: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Declining marginal willingness to pay.

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

θL

C’(q)

Page 129: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Declining marginal willingness to pay.

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

Δq Δq

Declining ΔWTP

Page 130: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

First degree descrimination.

Price

QuantityQuality

θH

qHqL

θL

C’(q)

Page 131: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Profit effect of a quality increase.

θH

qH

θL

C’(q)

qL qL* *

Price Loss (Need to lower pH to maintain ICH)

Gain (Can charge more to low value consumers)

QuantityQuality

Page 132: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Other assumptions

In a similar manner, one can relax other assumptions e.g.:

I Oligopoly suppliers.

I Many consumer types.

I Non-continuous q.

Page 133: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Summary

I Social science is about understanding society.

I That, at least in part, means trying to understand thefundamental forces that drive social phenomena.

I Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by newtechnology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how tounderstand and interpret the present.

I Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often aninsight that exceeds the sum of its parts.

I Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts cangenerate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets.

I A key ingredient in making these links is an understanding ofthe assumptions upon which alternative conceptualisations arepredicated.

Page 134: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Summary

I Social science is about understanding society.

I That, at least in part, means trying to understand thefundamental forces that drive social phenomena.

I Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by newtechnology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how tounderstand and interpret the present.

I Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often aninsight that exceeds the sum of its parts.

I Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts cangenerate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets.

I A key ingredient in making these links is an understanding ofthe assumptions upon which alternative conceptualisations arepredicated.

Page 135: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Summary

I Social science is about understanding society.

I That, at least in part, means trying to understand thefundamental forces that drive social phenomena.

I Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by newtechnology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how tounderstand and interpret the present.

I Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often aninsight that exceeds the sum of its parts.

I Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts cangenerate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets.

I A key ingredient in making these links is an understanding ofthe assumptions upon which alternative conceptualisations arepredicated.

Page 136: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Summary

I Social science is about understanding society.

I That, at least in part, means trying to understand thefundamental forces that drive social phenomena.

I Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by newtechnology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how tounderstand and interpret the present.

I Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often aninsight that exceeds the sum of its parts.

I Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts cangenerate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets.

I A key ingredient in making these links is an understanding ofthe assumptions upon which alternative conceptualisations arepredicated.

Page 137: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Summary

I Social science is about understanding society.

I That, at least in part, means trying to understand thefundamental forces that drive social phenomena.

I Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by newtechnology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how tounderstand and interpret the present.

I Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often aninsight that exceeds the sum of its parts.

I Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts cangenerate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets.

I A key ingredient in making these links is an understanding ofthe assumptions upon which alternative conceptualisations arepredicated.

Page 138: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Summary

I Social science is about understanding society.

I That, at least in part, means trying to understand thefundamental forces that drive social phenomena.

I Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by newtechnology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how tounderstand and interpret the present.

I Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often aninsight that exceeds the sum of its parts.

I Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts cangenerate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets.

I A key ingredient in making these links is an understanding ofthe assumptions upon which alternative conceptualisations arepredicated.

Page 139: Industrial Organisation Off and On the Internet

Summary

I Social science is about understanding society.

I That, at least in part, means trying to understand thefundamental forces that drive social phenomena.

I Often, behaviour is fundamentally unchanged by newtechnology. Looking into the past can offer hints on how tounderstand and interpret the present.

I Moreover, the result of linking related phenomena is often aninsight that exceeds the sum of its parts.

I Sometimes the process works backwards: new contexts cangenerate insights into old puzzles—e.g. two-sided markets.

I A key ingredient in making these links is an understanding ofthe assumptions upon which alternative conceptualisations arepredicated.