73
Dynamics and Heuristics of Investment Decision Making Under Time Constraints: an Eye-Tracking Experiment on Online Stock Marketplaces Master Thesis by Elvira Hobusch

Dynamics and Heuristics of Investment Decision Making Under Time Constraints: an Eye-Tracking Experiment on Online Stock Marketplaces

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Dynamics and Heuristics of Investment Decision Making

Under Time Constraints: an Eye-Tracking Experiment

on Online Stock Marketplaces

Master Thesis

by

Elvira Hobusch

4

Abstract

Rational deterministic normative models consider that the market agents are pos-

sessed with unlimited time and knowledge and discard the underlying cognitive pro-

cesses behind decision-making. Conversely, decision field theory implements a dy-

namic approach to decision processes under uncertainty, explaining systematic rela-

tions between variability of preferences and time constraints. Besides the theory

mentioned above, adaptive toolbox model further advances decision-making processes

by a composition of heuristics and adaptation to the environment structure. The hy-

potheses from these models are assessed in the eye tracking experiment which is

conducted using the information stimulus from three main stock marketplaces, e.g. the

Deutsche Börse, the London Stock Exchange, and the NASDAQ. The participants

made their decisions between buying or short selling stocks. The author examines the

dynamics of processing complex and excessive financial information provided by web-

based stock marketplaces in regards to a particular stock in the thesis. The experiment

investigates the dynamics of the participants’ attention to the particular information con-

tent in the decision-making process and identifies the heuristics behind the decision

process and how they are affected by time constraints. In this research, involving the

measure of attention, the author observed that participants did not rely on the

deliberative processing of information under time constraints but rather than on a col-

lection of simple heuristics. The results indicate that the content of the particular infor-

mation under the natural complexity of the provided financial information impacts the

decision-making process of participants under both time conditions.

Keywords: decision making, eye tracking, heuristics, stock marketplaces, time

constraints.

5

Table of Contents

Abstract ...................................................................................................................................... 4

Table of Contents ...................................................................................................................... 5

List of Abbreviations.................................................................................................................. 7

List of Figures ............................................................................................................................ 8

List of Tables.............................................................................................................................. 9

1 INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................................. 10

1.1 From Rational Models in Finance to the Study of Biases and Heuristics in

Behavioural Finance ........................................................................................................... 10

1.2 From static to dynamic decision: discovering the black box ................................... 12

1.3 Time constraints in decisions vs. time pressure ....................................................... 13

1.4 Eye-tracking perspective of research on decision-making ...................................... 14

1.5 Overall relevance of the topic and motivation of the research ................................ 15

1.6 The general and specific problems and the stated research questions ................ 17

1.7 The overview of the structure of the paper ................................................................ 18

2 LITERATURE REVIEW ....................................................................................................... 18

2.1 Eye-tracking research in economics and business .................................................. 19

2.1.1 Eye-tracking in consumer choice ........................................................................ 19

2.1.2 Eye tracking research in decision making under risk and uncertainty ........... 21

2.2 Financial and investment decisions under uncertainty and time pressure ................. 25

3 METHODOLOGY OF THE RESEARCH .......................................................................... 30

3.1 Methods and tools utilized in this area of research and justification of the adopted

methods ................................................................................................................................ 30

3.2 Description of possible and applied eye-tracking techniques, software, metrics

and tools ............................................................................................................................... 35

3.3 The design of the experiment...................................................................................... 37

3.3.1 Participants ............................................................................................................. 37

3.3.2 Eye tracking apparatus and measures ............................................................... 38

3.3.3 Stimuli ..................................................................................................................... 38

3.3.4 Procedure ............................................................................................................... 39

4 DESCRIPTION OF DATA ................................................................................................... 40

4.1 Detailed description of data collection, measures and recording ........................... 40

4.2 Definition of dependent variables ............................................................................... 44

4.3 Data procedure ............................................................................................................. 48

4.3.1 Cleaning and preparing data for R analysis ....................................................... 48

6

4.3.2 Descriptive statistics and regression................................................................... 50

4.3.3 Growth curve analysis........................................................................................... 50

5 RESULTS ............................................................................................................................. 52

5.4 Summary of the results ................................................................................................ 52

6 CONCLUSION ..................................................................................................................... 55

6.1 Overview of the research ............................................................................................. 55

6.2 Findings and limitations ............................................................................................... 58

6.3 Importance and further research questions .............................................................. 59

7 REFERENCE LIST .............................................................................................................. 60

ANNEX ..................................................................................................................................... 69

Appendix A ............................................................................................................................... 69

Appendix B ............................................................................................................................... 70

7

List of Abbreviations

aDDM Attention drift-diffusion model

AOI Areas of interests

arcsin Inverse sine function

ATB Adaptive toolbox model

b Billion

CPT Cumulative prospect theory

DCF Discounted cash flow

DDM Dividend discount model

DFT Decision field theory

EMH Efficient market hypothesis

EPS Earnings per share

EUH Expected utility hypothesis

Hz Herz

LCAM Leaky competing accumulator model

m Million

MDFT Multiattribute decision field theory

ms Millisecond

PCS Parallel constraint satisfaction model

PE Price/earnings ratio

PEG Price/earnings to growth ratio

SD Standard deviation

SEU Subjective expected utility

SMI SensoMotoric Instruments

EK ElringKlinger AG

Kr KRONES AG

3I III 3I GROUP PLC

FP FPO FIRST PROPERTY GROUP PLC

AD ADMA Biologics Inc.

Am AMGN Company

8

List of Figures

Figure 5.1.1: Mean percentage fixations for each AOI per company 53

Figure 5.1.2: Mean percentage fixation across trials 53

Figure 5.1.3: Gaze effect per company under time conditions 55

Figure 5.1.4: Accuracy of the decision under time conditions 56

Figure 5.1.5: Cross proportion between decision and accuracy 57

Figure 5.2.1: Mean proportion score of the AOI depending on the decision

made

61

Figure 5.3.1: Looking at AOI stock and a decision to buy or short sell the stock

over time

63

Figure 5.3.2: Gazing at AOI stock in correlation with a decision to buy or short

sell the stock over time

64

Figure 5.3.3: Gazing at AOI stock in correlation with an accuracy of the deci-

sion over time.

65

Figure A.1: Example of the stimulus provided in the experiment 82

Figure A.2: Growth curve analysis of gazing over time at the AOIs 82

9

List of Tables

Table 5.1.1: Differences between gazing information (ms) and decision out-

come per company

54

Table 5.1.2: The changes in stock price and an investor’s decision 56

Table 5.1.3: Percentage change in fixation durations in a task, depending on

the accuracy of the decision

56

Table 5.2.1: The p-values of t-test and a fit to a simple linear model 58

Table 5.2.2: The Pr(Chi) values of fitting to a mixed-effect model 58

Table 5.2.3: The p-values of a paired t-test 59

Table 5.2.4: The p-values of fitting to a linear model 59

Table 5.2.5: The significant predictors in a mixed-effect model 60

Table 5.2.6: Mean proportion score of gazing at the AOIs depending on made

decisions

61

Table 5.2.7: Mean proportion score of gazing at the AOIs depending on accu-

racy of decisions made

62

Table B.1: Loss of eye tracking data per participant (%) 83

Table B.2: Summary statistic of raw data adjusted for the R software analysis 83

Table B.3: Summary statistics for the numerical variables 84

Table B.4: Example of descriptive data for each AOI of the AD stock 84

Table B.5: Example of descriptive statistics of aggregating data with three tar-

get conditions: a company, accuracy of decision and time condition

84

Table B.6: Examples of paired t-test between conditions with the predictor, pu-

pil diameter, for AOI.stock

84

Table B.7: Example of fitting the data to mixed-effects models for the AOIs 85

Table B.8: Example of growth curve analysis in R 86

10

1 INTRODUCTION

1.1 From Rational Models in Finance to the Study of Biases and Heuristics in Behavioural Finance Recent developments in economics, especially in behavioural economics, finance and

decision making, indicate the limitations of deterministic normative models in describ-

ing the behavioural and cognitive grounds and processes behind decision-making. Ne-

oclassical models in economics and finance usually assume that people are rational,

“equipped with unlimited time, knowledge, and computational might”; thus, they behave

as utility maximizers, and their behaviour is effectively coordinated via the invisible

hand of the price mechanism (Gigerenzer & Goldstein, 1996, p.650).

Traditional finance is based on the following main theories, models and principles: the

modern portfolio theory of Markowitz (1952), the arbitrage principles of Miller and

Modigliani (1958), the capital asset pricing model of Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965) and

Black (1972), and the option-pricing model of Black, Scholes and Merton (1973)

(Kumar & Goyal, 2015). The models mentioned above hinge on the efficient market

hypothesis (EMH), which states that “in an efficient market, all the available information

is incorporated while estimating the prices of financial assets” and asserts that share

prices reveal all relevant information (Naveed et al., 2014, p.88). In addition, the ex-

pected utility hypothesis (EUH) of Daniel Bernoulli (1738) and von Neumann–

Morgenstern (1944) presumes that investors rationally evaluate all the alternatives by

their utility and the associated risk and subsequently make a balanced decision (Kumar

& Goyal, 2015). However, EMH’s and EUH’s assumptions that investors behave ra-

tionally in the financial market have proved to be inconsistent with irrational investor

behaviour (Naveed et al., 2014).

Therefore, the idea of bounded rationality by Herbert A. Simon (1957) emphasizes the

need for behavioural consideration in economics and points out that human agents,

although “intending to make rational decisions,” they are still bound by their “limited

ability to process information” (Augier, 2001, p.331). Whereas these approaches pro-

duce simple and tractable models, they cannot fully capture uncertainties that affect

everyday decisions. Furthermore, based on their empirical studies Daniel Kahneman

and Amos Tversky developed prospect theory and later cumulative prospect theory,

which is an alternative to EUH in explaining decision making under uncertainty where

investor’s decision making is based on potential gains and losses rather than on final

outcomes. This phenomenon occurs because of the cognitive biases that affect the

judgement of these gains and losses (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979). Daniel Kahneman,

Amos Tversky and their followers demonstrate that investors “all harbour idiosyncratic

ideas” and that they tend to act on these thoughts, “regardless of the costs to their

11 economic welfare” (Curtis, 2004, p.21). Thereafter, the research in this area is contin-

ued in both directions: recognizing anomalies in the EMH that behavioural models fea-

sibly describe (De Bondt & Thaler, 1985) and identifying individual investor behaviours

that conflict with classical economic theories of rational behaviour (Odean, 1999).

However, during this half of the century not only were the models improved to reflect

the reality and nature of investors’ behaviour but also the market mechanisms have

become more complex and demanding more sophisticated deliberation and investiga-

tion instruments (Pop, Iorga & Pelau, 2013). Firstly, the process of deliberating the fu-

ture price of stock for investors is becoming more demanding and complicated. Nu-

merous factors both global and domestic might affect stock prices, and some of these

factors can reduce an expected future price promptly and drastically. Secondly, the

time available for decision making is shortened, considering that overall complexity has

increased. Therefore, under such time constraints, it is questionable to deliberate all

available information even with a known personal utility function, and a personal prob-

ability distribution as proposed by Leonard Savage (1954) in subjective expected utility

theory (SEU). Thirdly, under volatile conditions, it is not feasible for any decision maker

to reason “a reliable joint probability distribution of all prospect proceedings” (Naveed

et al., 2014). And approximation of probability distributions leads to an uncertainty of

probability distributions concerning the prospect events. Previous researchers indicate

that the processing of uncertainty highly hinges on the situation and context

(Preuschoff, Mohr & Hsu, 2013). Therefore, the decision makers are dubious to define

a distinct utility function and as a result to maximize approximated utility function. Con-

sidering all the complexities mentioned above, constraints, and human cognitive limita-

tions as well as biased behaviour, perhaps these matters can lead to further profound

research to reconcile the decision-making process and deliberate possible variations of

satisfying outcomes.

Before moving to the methodological development of decision-making concepts, it is

necessary to clarify that the author applies the same definition of uncertainty in this re-

search as stated by Bland and Schaefer (2012) which separates meaning of uncertain-

ty into three main forms: expected uncertainty (including risk), unexpected uncertainty

and volatility. The investment decision maker addresses all three forms of the uncer-

tainty to some degree. This work is concerned mostly with decisions involving uncer-

tainty when a decision maker must deliberate possible multiple outcomes for which the

probabilities can be partially calculated or completely unknown due to lack of

knowledge, experience and time (Huettel et al., 2006).

12

1.2 From static to dynamic decision: discovering the black box

The author introduced the behavioural aspect to decision making in economics and

finance. Now it is time to glance at why the dynamic of decision-making is more ap-

pealing to study rather than a decision outcome. Therefore, it should be noted that the

same development pathway from deterministic static normative models to stochastic

dynamic descriptive models in decision making in economics and finance can be

traced from a methodological point of view. This approach is another look at the im-

portance of the topic of study. The extensions and modifications of EUH, for example

von Neumann-Morgenstern’s utility theorem (1944), multi-attribute utility analysis

proposed by W. Edwards (1954), SEU model of L. Savage (1954) culminated by

cumulative prospect theory (CPT) of Kahnemann and Tversky (1992) and the transfer-

of-attention exchange model of M. Birnbaum (1997), speculate that various “integration

of payoff and probability of outcomes” drive the individuals’ choice (Fiedler & Glöckner,

2012). CPT proposes that gains and losses are the carriers of value, “not final assets

and the value of each outcome is multiplied by a decision weight, not by an additive

probability” (Tversky & Kahneman, 1992, p.299). However, the models mentioned

above predict choices as outcomes and do not discuss the processes underlying the

decision making (Glöckner & Witteman, 2009). In the following literature Payne, John-

son, Schulte-Mecklenbeck and others state the significance of considering the underly-

ing processes in studies (Payne et al., 1988; Johnson et al., 2008; Franco-Watkins &

Johnson, 2011; Schulte-Mecklenbeck et al., 2011).

In this paper, the author focuses on simple heuristic models, i.e. the adaptive toolbox

model (ATB) by Gerd Gigerenzer (2001) and evidence accumulation models, i.e. deci-

sion field theory (DFT) of Jerome Busemeyer and James Townsend (1993) to explain

the results of the eye-tracking experiment. Simple heuristics models hypothesize that

individuals adapt their decisions to the situations by using simple shortcuts, optimal but

sufficient only for the immediate goals, and do not integrate all pieces of information.

Simon’s idea of “satisficing” heuristics in decision making introduces the importance of

order in which alternatives are evaluated. Because of the limitations of the human mind

and the structure of the environments in which the mind operates, individuals “must

use approximate methods to handle most tasks" (Simon, 1990, p. 6). Brandstätter

claims that priority heuristic or fast and frugal heuristic is based on a simple lexico-

graphic rule for decisions, and this heuristic better predicts the outcome between

gambles than the other ones (Brandstätter et al., 2006). Adaptive toolbox model ex-

tends the simplifying of the heuristics approach to “ecological rationality, frugality, ro-

bustness and building blocks of heuristics” where “domain specific heuristics” applies

to the decision under certain conditions and limitations (Gigerenzer, 2001, p.139).

13 On the other hand, evidence accumulation models such as DFT of Busemeyer and

Townsend (1993), the leaky competing accumulator model of Usher and McClelland

(2001) and the parallel constraint satisfaction model for risky choice of Glöckner (2008)

assume that individuals integrate information quickly, efficiently and sequentially “until

enough evidence has been accumulated to pass a decision threshold” (Hausmann,

2008, p.229). DFT considers “the variability of preferences and the systematic relation-

ship between preferences and deliberation time” (Busemeyer & Townsend, 1993,

p.455). The deliberation process includes not only an accumulation of information but

also an amount of attention allocated over time. In value based decisions, attention

fluctuates over attributed dimensions at each step in the accumulation process with the

differences in attributed values on the attended dimensions accumulated at each step.

Thus, dynamic models describe the decision-making process as influenced by uncer-

tain environments such as cognitive limitations, past experiences, expectations, prefer-

ences, emotional state, memory and time constraints. Therefore, “given that economic

actions are exerted by biological organisms embedded within their environment”, it is a

scientific responsibility to take into account the behavioural aspect of decision making

(Giordano, 2012, p.45).

1.3 Time constraints in decisions vs. time pressure

Hitherto, the author explains the choice of the topic by referring to the previous studies.

However, the decision-making area of research in economics and finance is very di-

verse. It is necessary to limit the study to a specific aspect. As known many decisions

in economics and finance are made under time constraints. Furthermore, payoffs in

many cases directly depend on the speed of decision making, for example when buy-

ing and selling stocks (Kocher & Sutter, 2006). Time constraints limit available re-

sources and deliberation of information which results in information overload. There-

fore, time constraints not only interfere with the decision-making processes but can al-

so lead to a less objective and more intuitive than a rational decision. Adopting some

heuristics, or mental shortcuts, individuals deliver applicable decisions under time con-

straints with limited logical decision-making deliberations.

Considering the points mentioned above, the author concludes that time constraints

are the main limitations in decision making that intensify the cognitive and tangible

drawbacks. Therefore, this research examines the decision-making process under time

constrained conditions as a significant part of decision making in applied economics

and finance. Additionally, the author separates time constraints from time pressure.

Even though the terms "time constraints" and "time pressure" are used interchangeably

in most of the previous literature, Ariely and Zakay (2001) indicate that “time con-

straints” “often is used as internally or externally imposed deadlines” (Ordóñez, Benson

14 III & Pittarello, 2016, p.520). Whereas “time pressure” mostly indicates “the subjective

feeling of having less time than is required (or perceived to be required)”. Therefore,

the author of this thesis agrees with Ariely and Zakay that there is a denotative differ-

ence between “time constraints” and “time pressure” and does not examine any emo-

tional aspect of time limitations, although both terminologies are considered for the re-

view in the literature part of this paper.

1.4 Eye-tracking perspective of research on decision-making

Now it is comprehensible why the study of dynamics and heuristics of the decision-

making process under time constraints is motivating to perform. However, the author

additionally commits to addressing the decision for the use of eye tracking techniques

for the research. Acknowledged, as early as 1596, Du Laurens, a sixteen-century

French anatomist and medical scientist, “referred to eyes as windows of the mind” (van

Gompel et al., 2007, p.3). Next, starting in 1924, the eye-tracking research in business,

in the field of marketing, was conducted by Nixon. Currently, over the last twenty years,

eye-tracking studies in economics have drastically increased. Assuming that the visual

system interacts with attention, cognition and behaviour (Yarbus, 1967, Rayner, 1998,

2009; Liversedge & Findlay, 2000), experimental economics tests the validity of eco-

nomic theories and endeavours to explain market mechanisms.

The eye movements in response to visual stimuli reveal the individual experience of

the world (Horsley et al., 2014). The eye-tracking technology is a research tool used to

measure visual attention. Attention allows individuals to monitor objects, subjects, or

areas of visual space and extract information from them to use for reporting or storage.

Moreover, considering that 83% of the information used in cognitive processing is

obtained visually, eye tracking measurement provides contextually relevant data that

can be analysed to advance models of decision making (Wästlund et al. 2010). The

recent research in neuroeconomics confirms that both saliency (key attentional mech-

anism) and value influence the final decision. To be precise, saliency affects fixation

locations and durations, which are predictors of choices (Towal, Mormann and Koch, 2013).

The following examples of the correlations between eye tracking measurements and

cognitive processing experimentally have been established: there is a close link

between fixations and comprehension (Rayner, 1998); an attentional shift to the target

location guides saccades (Kowler, Anderson, Dosher, & Blaser, 1995); the shifts in

attention are usually reflected in the fixations (Corbetta et al., 1998); pupil dilation

responses indicate emotion, arousal, or cognitive load (Wang, 2011). However, previ-

ously Yarbus in 1967 experimentally proved that the role of vision is much more com-

plex. On one hand, the analysis of eye-tracking data affirms the importance of the task

15 in determining where participants look. On the other hand, the particular fixations do

not disclose what the observer “really” thought while looking at these locations. There-

fore, “a given cognitive event might reliably lead to a particular fixation, the fixation it-

self does not uniquely specify the cognitive event” (Hayhoe, 2004, p.268).

Understanding the relationship between eye-tracking data and cognitive processes be-

hind them can help to comprehend how human economic behaviour can be affected by

the informational content, attention and emotional state. Recently, as eye tracking

technology has become more affordable and accessible to academics. It has become

more preferred to conduct an experiment with eye tracking application in behavioural

areas of economics and finance (Gould & Zolna, 2010).

Because this research comprises the information stimuli from the online stock market-

places, the web introduces new opportunities and challenges for an eye tracking re-

search. Scholars have utilized eye-tracking mostly for analysis of online human-

computer interactions and web searches, although it can be a very promising field of

research in the future because of increasing interest and usage of the internet in many

areas of human performance. Even though some techniques have been developed to

quantify, compare and aggregate eye movements linked to these online environments,

there are indeed some complications related to the usage of eye tracking in online con-

texts, for example, due to dynamic content. However, some experimental results

demonstrate its value and demand for further research (Granka, Feusner & Lorigo, 2008).

1.5 Overall relevance of the topic and motivation of the research

Previously the author designates the importance of studying the behavioural aspect of

the decision-making process under time constrained conditions and with eye tracking

techniques to comprehend the cognitive process of decisions in economics and finance

that lead to a specific investment decision. Additionally to the demands mentioned

above, it should be considered that the online share trading is “no longer restricted to

the expert brokers.” A vast and diverse population of investors with varying abilities,

knowledge and experience is making their investment decision every single day in the

markets (Richardson, Gregor and Heaney, 2012, p.523). Decision making in this con-

text can be suboptimal and risky. Thus, first of all, the research in this area is crucial to

understand the investors’ behaviour and decision-making processes behind their deci-

sions and consequently facilitate the investors to make better investment decisions in

the extremely complex and complicated financial markets (Naveed et al., 2014). Sec-

ond, the stock offering companies from all around the world strive to make improve-

ments in data representation available on their websites. The results of the research

are a first attempt to demonstrate what kind of information and data are more attentive

16 in investment decisions under time constraints. This paper focuses on financial infor-

mation provided by the online stock marketplaces to make a decision (buy or short sell

the stock) under time constraints. The author measures decisions of participants with

the SMI eye-tracker.

Hitherto scholars focused on creating an experimental design of alternatives that limit

and simplify all other possible influences in the decision-making process except one

aspect to be analysed and fitted to the model such as value, probabilities, etc. The ex-

perimental economists typically have designed “an artificial or hypothetical content,

which makes searching for information irrelevant” (Gigerenzer, 2001 p. 119). However,

the decision-making process always faces a complexity in natural settings. Therefore,

in this experiment the stimuli of the experiment are not created artificially, or manipu-

lated, they are actual representations of information from the websites themselves, and

participants make their decisions by deliberating actual information presented in online

stock marketplaces with a similar layout but without advertising windows. The author

restricts the experiment to the exactly defined areas of interests (AOI) to test the spe-

cific hypotheses, understanding the possible complications and indistinctness. The ex-

periment simplifies the analysis of the decision-making process by putting aside the

matter of comparison between stocks. Most important in this thesis is the deliberation

process of obtaining information about the performance of only one particular stock in

order to make a decision to buy or short-sell it. Considering this particular setting, the

author concentrates on the examination of attention to the specific kind of information

which influences the decision1.

This master’s thesis incorporates some of the techniques of eye-tracking analysis pub-

lished in the research of Susann Fiedler and Andreas Glöckner (2012) such as a

measure of attention and pupil dilation. However, the author of this thesis additionally

applies a few other experimental and behavioural economics’ methods in decision-

making processes by designing and conducting an own experiment on investment de-

cision making under time constraints. The experimental data is collected and examined

by using the eye tracking SMI software: Experiment Center and BeGaze and R statistical

software.

The main purpose of this master’s thesis is to investigate what kind of financial infor-

mation from online stock marketplaces, i.e. the Deutsche Börse, the London Stock Ex-

change and the NASDAQ, is more attentive for investors to make a decision under

time constraints and what heuristics the participants apply in their decision-making pro-

cess. Generally speaking, this master’s thesis examines the decision process by which

1 In most experiments, the provided options are a set of two alternatives. This experiment has one op-tion - an information block and two alternative choices - buy or short-sell.

17 “investors” process visual information to predict the future expected value of financial

assets and thus to invest accordingly (Duclos, 2015).

1.6 The general and specific problems and the stated research questions

The general idea of this research is an analysis of investment decision-making pro-

cesses under time constraints. Social challenges, learning and experience, cultural

background and time constraints influence the decision. Assuming the first three im-

pacts are being equal, the author measures only how time constraints affect the decision-

making process.

The following main questions are investigated in this paper: What type of information is

more attentive in making decisions under time constraints? What heuristics do

participants apply to make a decision under time constraints? The research measures

the attention and pupil dilation of the participants under time constraints and compares

the following main areas of interest (AOI): stock price summary or stock quotes, chart,

information about the company and ratios. The behaviour and experimental models of

the decision-making process such as adaptive toolbox (ATB) and decision field theory

(DFT) are tested on experimental data whether they can predict the choices made. The

thesis focuses on the main idea from ATB, i.e. domain depending or adaptive collection

of heuristics. DFT considers an accumulation of information, the amount of attention

and the time of deliberation that influences the decision-making process (Busemeyer &

Townsend, 1993). Therefore, as stated by researchers, “only the most prominent di-

mension tends to be processed, and the first alternative should be chosen more fre-

quently” under time constraints (Busemeyer & Townsend, 1993, p. 455). However,

with longer deliberation time, because additional information is considered, “the second

alternative should be chosen more frequently” (Busemeyer & Townsend, 1993, p. 455).

Consequently, the following hypotheses are formulated to test the attention to the con-

tent of the provided information that influences the decision under time constraints:

1. The fixation durations are stable over time and tasks.

2. The gaze cascade mechanism supports the decision (attentional bias).

3. Visual information such as graphs and charts impact the decision.

Additionally, following hypotheses based on ATB and DFT verifies the decision-making

process under time constraints:

1. The most prominent dimension tends to be processed the most and the first

(assumed that it is the summary of the stock price information).

2. The longest alternative should be chosen more frequently because of longer

deliberation time (i.e. the option to buy a stock).

18

3. Changing to simple heuristics decreases the accuracy of the decision or under

time constraints the accuracy of decision decreases.

1.7 The overview of the structure of the paper

The subsequent parts of the thesis are organized as follows. The second part of the

thesis presents the literature review of the previously published studies of investment

and financial decisions under time constraints employing different methods including

eye-tracking experiments. The third part defines the methodological framework for the

paper and explains the relevance of the adopted methods such as adaptive toolbox

and decision field theory and techniques such as eye tracking, statistical software R;

both of which are utilized to collect and analyse the experimental data. The following

fourth part provides the description of the experiment, the definitions, explanations and

reasoning behind the chosen variables, also detailed data collection conditions. The

fifth part introduces the interpretation of the results according to the stated hypotheses

in regards to the information content and heuristics employed in the decision-making

process and provides critical assessments of the findings. Finally, the research paper

concludes with the summary, importance of the research in the area of behavioural fi-

nance and description of limitations that the author has faced during the process of this

research and possible further extensions of the work.

2 LITERATURE REVIEW

In this paper, the literature review considers not only the studies of investment deci-

sions under time constraints using eye-tracking but also the publications in the area of

investment and financial decisions under time pressure and uncertainty using other

methods of behavioural and experimental economics. The author decides on this

approach for two reasons. First, to overview the extension of previous studies in this

area and the usage of different applications and methods. Second, to demonstrate that

this research is unique in applying eye tracking techniques to examine the decision-

making process of obtaining information from online stock marketplaces under time

constraints to make a decision to buy or short-sell the stock. Therefore, the author em-

ploys the following structure for the review of publications:

(1) publications in economics, finance and business that employ eye-tracking tech-

niques under time pressure and constraints, including:

(a) consumer economic decisions as a purchase choice,

(b) decision making under uncertainty (including risk, determined as uncertainty

with certain probabilities) and time pressure/constraints;

19 (2) decision making in economics and finance under uncertainty and time pres-

sure/constraints.

The publications are chronologically organized where it makes sense to review the de-

velopment of the ideas in certain areas of the research.

2.1 Eye-tracking research in economics and business

The analysis of eye movement has a long tradition dating back to the end of the 19th

century in several scientific disciplines. However, in economics and business, eye

tracking techniques have been used mostly in marketing over the last few decades, in

the analysis of consumer choices recently, in brand and product management occa-

sionally, and in the other areas of economics and finance very rarely. Such positioning

can be explained not only by expensive eye tracking equipment and complex eye-

tracking data analysis but also by the complexity of the financial information. The fol-

lowing publications apply eye-tracking to the research in business and marketing, for

example, Pieters and Warlop (1999) analyse eye movement data during the brand

choice, Pieters, Warlop and Wedel (2002) and Pieters and Wedel (2004) the attention

to advertisements. Feiereisen, Wong and Broderick (2008) apply eye-tracking to test

the role of visual attention in the context of product innovations. Zülch and Stowasser

(1999) discuss eye-tracking in the context of quality management in production (Zülch

and Stowasser, 2001). Successful applications of eye-tracking are also found in ac-

counting (Hunton & McEwen, 1997). However, as mentioned by Koller et al. (2012), the

previous studies that employed eye tracking were limited to certain topics, especially

“to facilitate our understanding of methodological issues” in economics and business.

Yang and Wang (2015) published a more recent review of using eye tracking applica-

tions in business research. They indicate the same lack of sufficient studies using eye

tracking in business disciplines and, as stated before, publications encompass mostly

the fields of marketing, electronic commerce, advertising and consumer behaviour.

In this review, the author focuses on publications that measure decisions under time

pressure and constraints in economics and finance using an eye tracker. Therefore,

publications in a field of marketing are not considered. However, a consumer economic

choice under time pressure can be regarded as a purchasing decision that involves

financial and economic factors, and therefore is taken into account.

2.1.1 Eye-tracking in consumer choice

One of the first eye-tracking studies in consumer choice under time pressure is

provided by Reutskaja and her colleagues in 2011. They analyse a subjects’ choice

between different numbers of items under time pressure using eye tracking to screen

20 the search process of the consumers. The scientists observe that subjects optimize

their search very well within the set of multiple items, which they saw on the screen,

even if the initial search process was random in value. With an increasing number of

alternatives, the subjects are “shortening the duration of their fixations”, but it had only

“a small impact on the quality of the choices” (Reutskaja, 2011). Additionally, subjects

of the experiment (or consumers) tend to have choice biases because of their attention

on certain focal regions of the display which lead them to choose more fixated items.

Reutskaja analyses internet consumers’ decisions, i.e. the effects of information

presentation on the consumers’ thoughtful choice. She observes that the table format

of information is strengthened while the map (or graph) weakened deliberateness of

the consumers’ value choice and lead to emotional choices vs. careful rational deci-

sions. The effect of presentation (or display) is mentioned by Huang and Kuo (2011).

Their research is one of the first attempts to investigate the joint effects of presentation

and decision orientation on careful consideration of the internet domain.

One year later Krajbich with his colleagues examines the validity of the attentional drift-

diffusion modelling on purchasing decisions. They further develop the drift-diffusion

model and tested it in an eye-tracking experiment (Krajbich & Rangel, 2011). The re-

sults indicate that the model provides a reasonably accurate quantitative description of

the relationship between choice, reaction time and visual fixations in this purchasing

decision. According to the experiment, “fixations to prices are shorter and less varia-

ble”; however, “the results suggest that they are also integrated noisily over time” in the

choice (Krajbich et al., 2012).

The same study with Krajbich and Rangel (2011) evaluates binary value choice in

comparison with trinary value choice. The results support the idea that the same com-

putational processes are taking place in simple binary vs. trinary value-based choices

and that the decision process is guided by visual attention in the conducted experi-

ment. Additionally, Krajbich and Rangel show that “the fixation process is not fully in-

dependent from the valuation process” and understanding how the fixation process

takes value into account can be the reasoning for further research in this area (Krajbich

& Rangel, 2011).

Previous studies were mostly focused on visual attention during consumer choice deci-

sions. The following paper by Lee (2013) investigates how a retail brand’s name affects

consumers' decision-making quality in the online shopping environment and how a

brand’s name influences on decision making. Lee (2013) demonstrates that branding

improves consumers' decision-making processes and enhances the quality of their de-

cisions by reducing cognitive effort and appealing emotionally through heuristic choices

to consumers. In addition, branding can increase trust towards products. Furthermore,

21 branding leads consumers to think positively about the quality of their decisions

(Lee, 2013).

The connection between visual attention and consumer behaviour, mentioned above,

has numerous implications in terms of understanding consumer purchasing decisions.

Therefore, in their introduction to eye tracking technology and methodology, Khacha-

tryan and Rihn (2014) explain how successfully eye-tracking technology can be used in

exploring the relationship between visual attention and consumer behaviour in con-

sumers’ decision making (Khachatryan & Rihn, 2014).

The influence of time pressure to the decision in connection with visual attention is the

topic of the next publication in this area. Meißner et.al (2015) recently publish their eye-

tracking study, which reveals decision processes in conjoint choices. This research

points out that combined choices take less time and are more accurate with practice.

Thus, greater speed and reliability of the decisions are a result of two simplification

processes: alternative focus gradually shifts attention towards options that represent

promising choices, while attribute focus directs attention to important attributes that are

most likely to alter or confirm a decision. Meißner with his colleagues detects a small

but consistent focus on positive aspects of the item chosen and negative aspects of the

items not chosen regarding biases. In conclusion, they point out that overall, the

conjoint choice is revealed to be a process that is largely formed by goal-driven values

that respondents bring to the task, one that is relatively free of distorted effects from

the task layout or random exposures (Meißner et. al, 2015).

As a result, publications in the area of consumer value-choice under time pressure

provide very important conclusions: (1) consumers optimize their choice strategies

under time pressure; (2) a presentation or a display of information influences the

decision; (3) a consumer decision is a subject to common cognitive biases; (4) the

decision process is guided by visual attention and (5) the same computational

processes are taking place in simple binary and trinary value-based choices (this is a

matter of the discussion in different articles).

2.1.2 Eye tracking research in decision making under risk and uncertainty

The next set of publications in economics and finance focus on decisions under risk

and uncertainty using eye tracking. Arieli, Ben-Ami and Rubinstein (2009) apply eye

tracking techniques to examine decision makers’ motivations and procedures in choice

problems between lotteries. In a simple choice between lotteries, the decision is based

on a comparison of prizes and probabilities rather than on calculation of expected utili-

ty. In motivation games, participants who selfishly behaved nevertheless take into con-

sideration the size of the payment compared to the other less selfish person. However,

22 overall participants are not motivated solely by selfishness in their decisions under un-

certainty (Amos, Yaniv & Rubinstein, 2009). Another experiment with lotteries conduct-

ed by Arieli, Ben-Ami and Rubinstein (2011) reinforces the same outcome: decision

makers often compared prizes and probabilities separately and this is particularly true

when the multiplication of sums and probabilities is laborious to compute.

Shavit et al. (2010) compare the performance of individual assets vs. portfolio in the

decision-making process. Using an eye tracker they conclude that investors spend

more time looking at the performances of an individual asset than at the performance

of the overall aggregated portfolio. Investors look at the net value change more than

the assets’ final value. Moreover, investors gaze at the change of the monetary value

longer than at change in percentages. Specifically, participants observe longer the val-

ue change of gaining assets than at the value change of losing assets leading to loss

aversion.

The following year, Glöckner and Herbold (2011), conducted the eye tracking

experiment of two gambles with two non-negative outcomes each in order to

investigate how the decision-making process, i.e. choices, decision times, and

information search fit with the hypotheses derived from cumulative prospect theory,

decision field theory, priority heuristic and parallel constraint satisfaction models. They

discover that individuals use compensatory strategies in their decisions. Even if their

choices are consistent with the predictions of cumulative prospect theory, decision pro-

cess measures testify that individuals do not consider the calculations of weighted

sums (Glöckner & Herbold, 2011).

The subsequent publication is based on the analysis of eye-tracking results of the pre-

vious research as well as the original one, where Fiedler and Glöckner (2012) describe

the underlying cognitive processes of risky choices by measuring attention and pupil

dilation and if they are consistent with existing models of decision theories. According

to the observation, the participants’ attention to an outcome of a gamble increased with

its probability and its value and that attention shifted toward the subsequently favoured

gamble after about two-thirds of the decision process, indicating gaze cascade effect.

Additionally, pupil dilation increased during the decision-making process and increased

with the mean expected value.

The debate over whether making a risky choice is based on a weighting and adding

process has a long history and is still unresolved. Su et al. (2013) address this question

in their research using eye tracking in single-play and multiple-play conditions. The re-

sults show that participants might use a weighting and adding process to make risky

choices in multiple-play conditions. In contrast, participants are not likely to use a

23 weighting and adding process to make risky choices in single-play conditions and are

more likely to use a heuristic process (Su et al., 2013).

However, the research of risky gamble decisions by Venkatraman, Payne and Huettel

(2014) supports the use of a simple heuristic that maximizes the overall probability of

winning (not losing) as a strategy for decision making involving complex (multiple

outcomes) mixed gambles. Another heuristic in decision making is supported by the

eye-tracking application in the experiment conducted by Hüsser and Wirt (2014). They

examine investors’ visual attention to parts of mutual fund disclosure. Results indicate

that prior fund performance, which is irrelevant normative information and non-useful in

predicting future performance, according to the authors’ opinion, receives considerable

attention from investors, and investors apparently believe in performance persistence.

Moreover, the participants are warned that past performance does not guarantee future

results at the beginning of the experiment.

In their investigation of how affective reactions influence investment decisions,

Rubaltelli, Agnoli and Franchin (2016) detect the impact of past performance in the

decision-making process. Taking into account individual differences regarding emo-

tional intelligence, the authors demonstrate that people who are more sensitive to af-

fective information have larger pupil dilation when looking at the past performance of a

stock fund. Additionally, the participants' larger pupil dilation has an impact on their in-

vestment decisions. Larger pupil dilation causes people to be more consistent and will-

ing to invest more money in a fund regardless of its past performance (positive or neg-

ative). Therefore, they indicate the impact of past performance and the trait of

emotional intelligence on investment decisions are significantly mediated by pupil

dilation.

This result is supported by another experiment conducted by Duclos (2015). In this ar-

ticle, he analyses how people process graphical displays of financial information (e.g.,

stock prices) to forecast future trends and invest accordingly. The results support that

the previous trading day bears in high importance on investment behaviour, even if no

real upward or downward trend can be identified by participants.

In their eye-tracking experiment and following after the verbal protocol on risky

gambling, Brandstatter and Korner (2014) establish direct relations between process

and choice and indicate that different components of a gamble attract different

amounts of attention depending on the participants' actual choice. Maximum losses

always have received most of the attention regardless of a choice (risky vs. safe

investment). Participants are concerned with the worst outcome in both loss/gain

games while simultaneously focusing on the probability of obtaining the best one. “This

effect was stronger for the loss than for the gain domain” (Brandstatter & Korner,

24 2014). Moreover, the last-fixated gamble but not the last-fixated reason predicts the

participants' choices that use cognitive processes similar to heuristics.

The decision making in economic gambles is the research topic of the recent article by

Kwak and his colleagues. They chose another angle to this problem, i.e. changes in a

human decision making over time. The authors examine the strategies used by ado-

lescents and young adults to resolve complex, multi-outcome economic gambles equa-

tions. The eye tracking data shows that prior to decisions being made, adolescents ac-

quire more information, and they engage in a more analytic processing strategy indica-

tive of trade-offs between decision variables and are more likely to make conservative,

loss-minimizing choices consistent with economic models (Kwak et al., 2015). In con-

trast, young adults' decisions are more consistent with heuristics that simplify the

decision-making process at the expense of analytic precision. Therefore, adolescents'

decisions are more consistent with rational-choice models, while young adults more

readily engage in task-appropriate heuristics because of lack of knowledge and experi-

ence (Kwak et al., 2015).

In the newly published article, Stewart, Hermens and Matthews (2016) conduct an eye-

tracking experiment on simple risky choices. They state the presence of gaze bias in

the decision-making process which is in contrast with prospect theory and the priority

heuristic. Additionally, they confirm that “the actually attributed values in the choice op-

tions are independent of the final choice” (Stewart, Hermens, & Matthews, 2016,

p.116). They specify that the participants chose the gamble they gazed at more often,

independently of the actual numbers they saw. Decision field theory, the decision by

sampling and the parallel constraint satisfaction model support the results of the

experiment.

It can be concluded from the preceding review that the application of eye tracking for

decision making is an approach which is developing rapidly and beginning to be uti-

lized more effectively in behavioural economics and the science of decision making

recently. This application shines some light on cognitive processes which underlie the

choice to understand the process of human decision making. The above-mentioned

publications of decisions in economics and finance under risk and uncertainty indicate

the following results: (1) decision makers separately compare values from probabilities

under time pressure and complex settings; (2) investors more focus on value change of

individual asset rather than on the performances of the overall aggregated portfolio or a

change in percentages; (3) they are concerned with the worst outcome in both

loss/gain games while simultaneously focusing on the probability of obtaining the best

one (second and third points support loss aversion tendency of investors); (4) investors

in their decisions rely on past performance of the fund; (5) visual attention influences a

25 choice or there is aptitude for the gaze cascade effect; (6) decision-making in multiple-

play conditions may be different than in single-play conditions; (7) adolescents'

decisions are more consistent with rational-choice models then young adults’

decisions.

2.2 Financial and investment decisions under uncertainty and time pressure

In this research paper, the review of previous publications on the decision under uncer-

tainty and time pressure is included even if the researchers did not employ eye-

tracking techniques in their experiments. The main reason for that is (1) to understand

the influence of time pressure on decisions under uncertainty employing the other

methods of behavioural and experimental economics and (2) to understand or estimate

if these studies can be supported with the outcomes of eye tracking applications.

Throughout the literature, it is affirmed that the decision maker is forced to select a

strategy that is less time consuming but also less accurate under time constraints and

time pressure (Ariely & Zakay, 2001). Earlier, Janis and Mann (1977) indicate that

emotional and stress factors affect the selection of a decision-making strategy.

However, many publications follow the approach as a decision maker changes his/her

criterion under time pressure rather than strategy (Albert, Aschenbrenner &

Schmalhofer, 1989; Aschenbrenner, Albert, & Schmalhofer, 1984; Busemeyer, 1985;

Busemeyer & Townsend, 1992, 1993; Diederich, 1995; Wallsten & Barton, 1982). The

previous publications also indicate that “time pressure is a very common feature of pro-

fessional and personal decision situations” including investment and financial decisions

(Maule & Endland, 2002).

The effects of time pressure on consumer supermarket shopping behaviour were

measured by Herrington and Capella as early as 1995. They observe that shopping

time and purchase amount are related. According to their results, supermarket shop-

pers tend to spend less time making any given purchase and more money in the over-

all time available to them. Moreover, time pressure overall decreases choice deferral,

but not when the choice involves low conflict or sets with common good and unique

bad features (avoidance‐avoidance conflict), according to Dhar and Nowlis (1999).

The research idea of Zur and Breznitz (1981) is comprehension of a risky choice under

time pressure. In their experiment of choosing between pairs of gambles, they observe

that subjects are less risky under high time pressure. Additionally, subjects tend to

spend more time observing the amount to loose and the probability of losing, whereas

they prefer observing their positive counterparts under low time pressure. This decision

behaviour is supported by prospect theory (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979), which states

that people put greater weight on losses rather than on gains.

26 Ordóñez and Benson III (1997) apply time constraints to both attractiveness ratings

and buying price tasks for a set of gambles and discover that decision makers multiply

probability and the amount information when stating buying prices with and without

being under time pressure, whereas they change their decision strategy when reporting

attractiveness ratings: they are using the same multiplicative decisions rather than

additive strategy as they tend to do without time pressure.

Although time pressure may influence risk taking, the precise nature of this influence

varies across different decision-making situations (Maule & Endland, 2002). Busemey-

er and Townsend in 1993 presented that the relationship between time pressure and

risk-taking is complex. Later Dror, Busemeyer and Basola (1999) state that participants

are less likely to take an action as risk levels increased; however, under time pressure,

participants are more conservative at the lower risk levels but are more inclined to take

risks at the higher levels of risk.

Similar results are provided by Huber and Kunz (2007) with quasi-realistic risky scenar-

ios where the initially risky alternative is chosen more often under time pressure.

Young and her colleagues support previous findings with the prospect theory frame-

work. They indicate that increases in time pressure lead to greater risk taking for posi-

tive and greater risk aversion for negative expected values. These findings suggest

that the risk preference under time pressure may depend on the overall expected value

among alternatives, whereby people are attracted to risks with positive expected value,

but averse to risks with negative expected value (Young et al., 2012).

Kocher, Pahlke and Trautmann (2013), who separated gain, loss and mixed prospects

(options), add to preceding results, such as an increase of gain seeking under time

pressure, the framing of the prospects. They point out that in cases of loss and mixed

prospects, the risk aversion attitude is increasing. Nursimulu and Bossaerts (2014) in-

dicate purchase impulsiveness under extreme time pressure on financial decisions.

However, sensitivity to expected reward does not depend on time according to the

researchers.

Will time pressure, in this case, reduce the quality and outcome of decision making?

This effect is noticed by Payne, Bettman and Johnson (1993), Bockenholt and Kroeger

(1993). They indicate that time pressure reduces the quality of decision making and

this reduction depends on the employed strategy (Maule and Endland, 2002). Howev-

er, Maule, Hockey and Bdzola (2000) analyse decision making under uncertainty and

show that time-pressured participants are more anxious, energetic and use a number

of different strategies to cope with the deadline. Kerstholt (1994) affirms in his study of

decision-making in dynamic situations under time pressure that information processing

is increasing with time pressure increasing. Nevertheless, the subject is not optimally

27 reacting to the time dimension of decision problems but waits until a specific value of

overall system performance is reached.

Mayer, Sonoda, and Gudykunst (1997) propose that the provision of information leads

to improved decision making, but time pressure has no effect on the quality of deci-

sions. Later Chu and Spires (2001) conclude that time-constrained decision makers

faster process information, although they manage less information and use less rigor-

ous decision strategies. However, properly designed decision support systems can

force decision makers to process more information and use more rigorous decision

strategies, which can result in enhanced performance. In support to that, Richardson,

Gregor and Heaney (2012) specify that with decision support even beginner level trad-

ers consistently outperformed those without support.

The effect of time pressure on description-based choice is different than experience-

based choice, as stated by Wegier and Spaniol (2015). If time pressure decreases risk

seeking for losses and increases for gains in description-based choice, there is no im-

pact of time pressure in outcomes that are learned through experience.

However, even experienced investors are comprised with behavioural biases, i.e. fram-

ing. Tversky and Kahneman (1981) compare the effects of frames on preferences to

the effects of perspectives on perceptual appearance. Svenson and Benson III (1993)

states that “the effects of time pressure were not as general as framing effect; when

there was an effect of time pressure, it was an interaction with the framing; when the

time was short, there was less or no effect of framing, and when time was long, there

was a stronger framing effect”. In line with this observation, Maule and Endland (2002)

found that the framing bias was weaker under time pressure. Therefore, some of the

publications mentioned above underline a better strategy and quality of investment de-

cisions under time pressure (Kerstholt, 1994; Maule, Hockey and Bdzola, 2000; Chu

and Spires, 2001). Unquestionably, the framing bias influences investment decisions

and is considered an important determinant of individual investment decisions, accord-

ing to Kumar and Lim (2006).

Throughout most of the publications on decision making under uncertainty and time

pressure, heuristics reflect as “efficient cognitive processes, conscious or unconscious,

that ignore part of the information” (Gigerenzer & Gaissmaier, 2011), or as decision

strategies that lack of complete relevant decisional information and therefore are seen

as less “rational” (Young et al., 2012). Gigerenzer and Gaissmaier (2011) indicate that

(a) individuals and organizations often rely on simple heuristics in an adaptive way, and

(b) ignoring part of the information can lead to more accurate judgments, for instance

for low predictability and small samples, than weighting and adding all information.

28 The research, that examines the effects of time pressure on decision making, has

found that a speed-accuracy trade-off can occur with time constraints. Investors

employ heuristic strategies, including acceleration, filtration of information, omission,

assessing across alternatives, changing in underlying decision rule and increased use

of attribute-based processing (Janis, 1983; Miller & Galanter, 1960; Verplanken, 1993;

Payne, Bettman, & Luce, 1996; Svenson, Edland, & Slovic, 1990; Zakay, 1993, Young

et al., 2012). Subjects seem to incline of using an ‘affect heuristic’, which improves

judgmental efficiency by deriving both risk and benefit evaluations from a common

source, as indicated by Finucane et al. (2000). In risky decisions, involving the possibil-

ities of both gains and losses, people often use a simple heuristic that maximizes the

overall probability of winning (Venkatraman, Payne & Huettel, 2014) and simplify the

decision problem at the expense of analytic precision (Kwak et al., 2015).

Thus, the publications, considered in this part of the literature review, suggest that time

pressure may change financial and investment decisions. However, the previous

studies indicate that these changes do not always take place in the same way, and

depend on (a) a decision maker strategy, (b) the types of options applied

(loss/gain/multi) and (c) the task structure of the experiment (Maule & Endland, 2002).

Therefore, (1) there is a relationship between time pressure and expected value (utility,

money), and (2) a tendency that decision makers under time pressure (a) take less risk

when the risk is lower, in case of losses, or negative values and (b) take more risk

when risk is higher, in case of gains, positive values, or impulse. (3) Time pressure al-

so has a complex impact on the quality of decisions, by reducing or increasing the

quality of decisions depending on (a) the employed strategy, (b) the additional provi-

sion of information provided or (c) other decision support. (4) Framing and loss aver-

sion biases under time constraints in some experiments are decreasing and on the

others are increasing, leaving open the question of the consequences of time pressure

on behavioural biases. (5) Throughout the previous publications, the idea of heuristics

is actively supported as a time-related strategy when a decision maker faces some

constraints, such as information overload, lack of knowledge and experience. In these

situations, investors (a) use the same methods as previous methods in their decisions,

(b) maximize the overall probability of winning, or (c) reason toward simplifying, accel-

erating and filtrating information to reach efficiency under time pressure.

To conclude the literature review, the author compares previous publications that utilize

eye-tracking techniques with other earlier methods of behavioural and experimental

economics. The following conclusion can be made which brings some discussion to

directions, depth and extensions of eye tracking applications in order to examine deci-

sion making under uncertainty and time pressure and constraints. Researchers who

29 are using eye tracking applications support some results of previous methods, for

example, optimizing choice strategies under time pressure, changes in loss aversion,

the impact of past performance in investment decision making or framing effects and

other biases. However, the cognitive biases require further explorations with different

sets and expected outcomes to test the sensitivity of biases dependent on environ-

ments under time pressure. In addition, eye tracking deepens the research on decision

making by observing the difference in decisions between simple-binary and multiple-

value-based choices, by comparing the influence of expected values separately from

probabilities in decision making under uncertainty and a value change of individual as-

sets from the performances of the overall aggregated portfolio. All of these studies be-

came possible due to eye tracking applications. The novel extensions of eye tracking

applications such as the gaze cascade effect where the decision-making process is

guided by visual attention and presentation of the information on the screen are only

some new directions in the analysis of the decision-making processes that are

discovered by using eye tracker applications.

Considering all the above mentioned background in this area of study, it can be

concluded that the previous studies (1) limit the experiment design by artificially

simplistic manipulated structure in order to measure one particular aspect of a

decision, (2) decision-making outcome or choice was the main research question of

prior experiments, not the decision-making process. Some recent studies investigate

the decision-making process however mostly from methodological application which is

discussed in detail in the next chapter. Therefore, this research is a single attempt in

applying eye tracking techniques to examine the decision-making process of obtaining

complex information from online stock marketplaces under time constraints to make a

decision to buy or short sell the stock. The author adapts natural online representation

of stock information as static screenshots to eliminate the influence of advertising pop-

ups and strictly defines and limits the areas of interest (AOI) to answer the stated re-

search questions. The following chapters of the research examine the methods and

measures that apply to the eye tracking data to test the research questions, i.e. delib-

eration of the information content under time constraints and heuristics in the decision-

making process.

30

3 METHODOLOGY OF THE RESEARCH

3.1 Methods and tools utilized in this area of research and justification of the adopted methods After evaluation of the publications in the area of decision making in economics and

finance under time constraints, it becomes evident that the extensive range of the pre-

vious research in this area are far from fulfilling the knowledge potential and discover-

ing the universal model of the decision-making process. Many aspects of the decision-

making process and models applicable to natural settings are not analysed or even

created yet. Taking into account these opportunities, the research, as mentioned in

previous chapters, focuses on the analysis of the information content deliberated by

participants of the experiment, and heuristics applied in the decision-making process.

Before providing the justification and describing the methods, technology, metrics and

tools adopted, the author presents a short overview of the previous methods that has

been utilized in this research area.

The decision-making area in economics and finance has progressed significantly. On

one hand, proclaiming rational logical methods of decision making founded on

expected utility theory, e.g. the neoclassical theorists such as von Neumann and

Morgenstern (1947) and Savage (1954) and, on the other hand, behavioural scientists

such as Edwards (1962), Kahneman and Tversky (1979) acknowledge the behavioural

principles behind the decision making process initiated by bounded rationality

principles. Since then a variety of methods has been developed to comprehend the

decision-making process in economics and finance. In greater detail, the difference be-

tween static vs. dynamic, normative vs. descriptive, deterministic vs. stochastic meth-

ods and models of the decision-making process are discussed in the works of

Busemeyer and Townsend (1993). Fiedler and Glöcker (2012) define two major clas-

ses of existing process models: simplifying heuristics and automatic integration models.

The complexity of the decision-making environments and time constraints require sim-

plifying and integrative approaches in the decision-making process to make a choice,

considering limited information-processing capacity (Payne, Bettman, & Johnson,

1993). Therefore, the heuristic methods previously studied by scholars can be defined

by the following features. First, the selection and filtration of information (Miller, 1960),

sequential choice (Gigerenzer & Goldstein, 1996) and finding the “satisficing” level of

reservation utility (Herbert Simons’ model, 1955) can have many different forms such

as using the preferential minimax or maximax heuristics (Brandstätter et al., 2006) or

choices decisions with an aspirational level (Luce, 1956; Simon, 1983). Second,

screening rather than acceleration in an information search task (Weenig & Maarleveld,

2002) or, third, search order (Caplin, Dean & Martin, 2011). Additionally, the previous

31 publications discussed repeatedly the recognition heuristic as more appropriate as ob-

served under time pressure (Klein, 1993). However, this heuristic can be only applied if

a decision maker has the previous knowledge or experience in regards to the subject

of the choice. Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman and their followers have committed

their research careers to the study of heuristics and biases (Kahneman & Tversky,

1974; Fiedler & von Sydow, 2015).

Even though heuristic methods accurately describe the decision processes in specific

conditions, the accuracy of these heuristics overall is questioned throughout the litera-

ture. For example, Gigerenzer and Brighton (2009) discuss the validity of fast and fru-

gal heuristics. Additionally, Kahneman and Tversky (1974) confirm that relying on heu-

ristics and biased approaches in the decision-making process leads to subjective

(overoptimistic or pessimistic) decisions in the stock marketplace; and the results are

price volatility or considerable loss in the portfolio. Fiedler and Glöcker (2012) state that

simple, non-compensatory models, such as the priority heuristics, lexicographic2, min-

imax, or maximax heuristics, do not predict search behaviour and processes in risky

decisions.

Another class of the decision methods, automatic integration models, is contrary to

heuristics and assumes that individuals “rely on powerful cognitive processes that allow

integration of considerable information very quickly and efficiently” (Fiedler & Glöcker,

2012). Evidence accumulation models of decision making under risk pertain to this

class. In this research, the author tests the hypotheses derived from decision field the-

ory (DFT, Busemeyer & Townsend, 1993) as an example of evidence accumulation

models. The hypotheses, based on DFT’s assumptions of the time limits, impose re-

strictions on the processing of information and therefore the “most prominent dimen-

sion tends to proceed, and the first alternative should be chosen more frequently”

(Busemeyer & Townsend, 1993, p.455). This approach will be discussed in greater de-

tail in the following part of the chapter. The following examples of evidence accumula-

tion models are the leaky competing accumulation model (LCAM, Usher & McClelland,

2004) and the parallel constraint satisfaction model (PCS, Glöckner & Herbold, 2011).

According to LCAM, information processing is a “gradual accumulation of intrinsically

noisy signals”. This model adds the effect of leakage (amplification of differences) in

the information accumulation process performed by the subject (Usher & McClelland,

2004, p.585). The PCS model identifies at least 3 steps in the decision-making

process: (1) activation of associated and relevant information in memory, (2)

parallelization of processes to maximize consistency in the context, for example by

2 Lexicographic strategy selects the alternative with the highest key value and with the highest validity (Gigerenzer, Todd, & ABC Research Group, 2000).

32 dominance structuring of information, (3) consulting mental representation with a

certain threshold, if it is fairly consistent, then a choice is made, if it is not analogous

then the next additional step (4) to change the decision on the basis of new

deliberations is considered (Glöckner & Hodges, 2011).

Some of the other noticeable methods of the evidence accumulation models are multi-

attribute decision field theory (MDFT, Diederich, 2003) and the attention drift-diffusion

model (aDDM) that are constructed hinge on a condition of certainty, i.e. purchasing

decision (Krajbich et al., 2012). Diederich’s MDFT assumes that a decision maker se-

quentially deliberates and compares attributes of alternatives over time. Therefore, un-

der time constraints, a decision maker modifies criterion rather than adjusts the strate-

gy of the decision. The aDDM method includes visual attention and the drift rate result-

ed from it, which “fluctuates continuously across time according to either a stationary or

Markov process” (Krajbich et al., 2012, p.10). Thus, visual attention accumulates more

evidence about the items to make a decision.

The short overview above demonstrates that the varieties of methods and models at-

tempt to explain inconsistencies of the static theories of the decision making. Most of

the recently developed models are indeed extensions or specifications or integrations

of simple heuristics or DFT. The author has reviewed only the most prominent methods

which applied to decision-making processes in economics and finance.

The authors’ decision toward the methods has a rational explanation rooted in the stat-

ed research questions and the capability of the SMI eye tracking technology. Taking

into account the features of the stimuli (information from online stock marketplaces)

and brainstorming possible correlations between visual attention to the financial

information, dynamics of the decision-making process and final decision, the author

assumes that the hypotheses and ideas of adaptive toolbox model (ATB) and decision

field theory (DFT) can explain the outcome of the experiment. ATB concept and DFT

are not only the most distinguished methods elucidating the decision-making process,

but they also apply to much complex decision-making processes. Therefore, noticing

that the experimental setting does not have an artificial, hypothetical content or ma-

nipulations of values in order to fit the outcome to a model, the research aims to test

hypotheses from ATB and DFT. May perhaps these models of the decision-making

process explain the outcome of the experiment? The real information content from the

online stock marketplaces was provided to participants of the experiment to test if the

models can explain a deliberation process of decision making, including attention to the

particular content of information and dynamics of the decision-making process. A more

detailed interpretation of the models and the motivation behind the decision of these

two models are given below.

33 In volatile equity markets, an investor has adaptive and goal-oriented behaviour. This

behaviour is a consequence not only of cognitive limits but first of all cognitive adapta-

tion (to time-space) limits. Having unlimited time and unlimited access, individuals po-

tentially can deliberate a rational and accurate decision based on specific goals and on

a specific time. Cognitive adaptation to the environment in order to make efficient deci-

sions employs various heuristics3. Gigerenzer and Gaissmaier (2011) demonstrate that

individuals often depend on “simple heuristics in an adaptive way”. Even though these

heuristics ignore part of the information in the decision-making process, they still lead

to accurate judgments in comparison with the time-consuming deliberation of weighting

and adding all available information. Adaptive toolbox model is adapted to the structure

of the applicable environment, i.e. “psychological plausibility, domain specificity and

ecological rationality” (Gigerenzer & Selten, 2002, p. 37). The author of this thesis con-

siders the premises of adaptive toolbox model that can be applied to the decision-

making process in the conducted experiment. The participants with the limited

knowledge and no experience deliberate the provided financial information from the

stock marketplaces to make a decision to buy or short sell the stock. This decision is

initially adaptive because of the complexity of unfamiliar information that the partici-

pants faced in the experiment. There is no comparison between the stocks, no recogni-

tion effects, i.e. the stocks chosen for the experiment are the offers of middle-size un-

noticed companies. The participants have to make a decision to buy or short-sell a

stock within one information block. What information content will be deliberated in the

decision-making process first, last and the most by participants? What will be ignored

and not considered at all in the decision? Will participants’ decisions be optimal, taking

into account (1) the goal of the experiment is to invest profitably and (2) participant’s

own goals and strategies? Which heuristics do participants use in this situation? All

these questions can be tested and answered within adaptive toolbox model. Therefore,

this method is considered as one of the most suitable in this type of the experiment.

Next, the author acknowledges decision field theory as a dynamic approach to decision

making in economics and finance. DFT principles explain numerous unclear

experimental results of individual decision-making processes in economics and finance

including “violations of stochastic dominance”, “violations of strong stochastic

transitivity”, “violations of independence between alternatives”, “serial position effects

on preference”, “speed-accuracy trade-off effects”, “the inverse relation between

decision probability and decision time”, “changes in the decisions of preferences under

3 The author of this paper agrees with Douglas H. on definition of “heuristic” as “an automatic perceptu-

ally based cognitive shortcut” and at the same time “conscious and effortful strategy that deliberately operate on a reduce amount of information and are guided by conscious stopping rules” (Douglas, 2016, p.135).

34 time pressure”, “slower decision times for avoidance as compared with approach

conflicts” and “preference reversals between decisions and prices” (Busemeyer &

Townsend, 1993, p.432). In other words, deriving their conclusions for DFT, Busemey-

er and Townsend step-by-step includes different conditions under which the decision-

making process can be changed.

In sum, preference direction, or attention can be switched from one event to another in

the decision-making process; the attention weight can vary caused by “difference in

subjective expected utilities” (Busemeyer & Townsend, 1993, p.336). In speed-

accuracy trade-off “the similarity or dissimilarity of the payoff produced by each action”

is taken into account (Busemeyer & Townsend, 1993, p.440). Prior knowledge or past

experience could be “an initial anchor point” that biases the decision under time con-

straints. However, when given a long time for sequential sampling processing of infor-

mation, the threshold bounds increase. The scholars demonstrate experimentally “the

inverse relation between decision probability and decision time” (Busemeyer & Town-

send, 1993, p.441). Moreover, the position of the sample has a greater effect on a

decision, and it takes a longer time to deliberate avoidance-avoidance rather than ap-

proach-approach decisions. Furthermore, the deliberation time is a continuous pro-

cess. Therefore, the changes in deliberation time, which is the main condition in the

experiment conducted by the author of this paper, leads to speed-accuracy trade-off,

unless there is a high threshold starting point. The participants do not have a high initial

anchor point to rely on their decision-making process. However, do they sequentially

deliberate information under time constraints or, as stated by Busemeyer and Town-

send, do they decrease the amount of attention allocated and deliberate only noticea-

ble information? Are there changes in attention over time? According to the DFT, neg-

ative values take more deliberation compared with positive values. Does the experi-

ment data support this assumption? If simple heuristics are applied in the decision-

making process, should the decrease in the accuracy of the decision take into account

low variance conditions (initial starting position)? Does the amount of time spend mak-

ing a decision affect the final decision? These are only the main questions that can be

answered to support or to contradict the model’s assumptions.

To sum up this part of the chapter, the author’s motivation behind the decision of

methods is based on (1) observability, e.g. presence of the most fundamental

principals in the models, (2) measurability, e.g. the capacity to explain the specific eye-

tracking data outcomes of the experiment, (3) reliability, e.g. the recognition and

successful adoption of these methods by the scientific society in economics and

finance. Therefore, ATB and DFT have been chosen as the fundamental methods of

this research paper.

35

3.2 Description of possible and applied eye-tracking techniques, software, metrics and tools Eye tracking technology, as mentioned in the introduction, is becoming a widespread

and accessible method in behavioural economics and finance recently. This approach

provides new crucial tools for measuring the actual dynamics of visual attention or

measure of where and when the eyes move during a complex task performance

(Godfroid, 2012).

Eye-tracking techniques are based on the main assumption that there is congruence

between visual attention and cognitive processes, or eye-mind relationships (Rayner,

2009). However, this assumption is a type of “Midas touch problem”, where the main

question is “how to differentiate attentive saccades with the intended goal of communi-

cation from the lower level eye movements that are just random or provoked by exter-

nal stimulation?” (Velichkovsky, Sprenger & Unema, 1997, p.509) In other words, is

there a robust correlation between visual attention to a stimulus and a cognitive pro-

cessing of information about this particular stimulus? However, this is a topic for anoth-

er research. Here, the author assumes that there is some correlation between visual

attention and the behaviours of the subjects.

Eye movements provide essential insights into comprehending human behaviour. Eyes

select and sample visual information (Horsley et al., 2014). The fixation locations de-

termine behaviour engagement with particular information and provide an objective

measure of ongoing cognitive processes during deliberation of the particular infor-

mation content (Horsley et al., 2014). Therefore, the assumption in regards to ongoing

cognitive processes and visual attention are carried out throughout the paper.

The experimental eye-tracking data can be scrutinized by a variety of statistical meth-

ods, as well as with visualization techniques provided by eye-tracking analytical soft-

ware such as BeGaze as used in this experiment (Blascheck et al., 2014). Eye tracking

equipment usually records the gaze points of the participants as raw data.

Subsequently, depending on a specified area and time span the gaze points are

spatially and temporally aggregated into fixations (or location and duration of gaze)

with an area of approximately 20-50 pixels and timespan between 200 and 300 ms;

saccades (location and length of eye movement) which are about 30 to 80 ms long;

and smooth pursuits with velocity around 10-30 degrees (Holmqvist et al, 2011). Spe-

cific regions of interest on the stimulus defined in the experiment such as areas of in-

terests (AOI) depend on the stated hypotheses (Blascheck et al., 2014). The author

follows the recommended measurements in the definition of fixation, saccades and

smooth pursuits. However, smooth pursuit data sets are not considered in this re-

36 search because smooth pursuit is initiated mostly by looking at a moving target and not

a static target.

Diversified methods and metrics have been developed throughout the previous studies

where an eye tracking device is adapted for collection of visual attention data, for

example, string editing algorithms (Duchowski, 2010), descriptive and inferential statis-

tical algorithms (Holmqvist et al., 2011) and visual analytics techniques (Andrienko,

2012). Visualization techniques are more explorative and qualitative compared with

statistical analysis, which largely provides quantitative results. Particularly, visual

methods specify different levels and spatiotemporal aspects in the analysis of complex

data. Additionally, the type of the stimuli used in the experiment influence on the design

of visualization techniques. The visual analysis can be point-based or AOI based

(Blascheck et al., 2014). This experiment used AOI based analysis, where correlations

between AOIs are more relevant to the aim of the stated research questions and point-

based or time binned growth curve analysis.

In this experiment, the raw data is directed from the Experiment Center to the BeGaze

software. This software simplifies the eye tracking data analysis not only by the visual

structuring of the data of the experiments but also by displaying the results of the ex-

periment in the different forms. Visualization of gaze plots and attention maps are

presented by scan path, bee swarm, gaze relay, focus map and heat map (BeGaze

Manual, 2014). If a scan path displays a gaze data overlay over a stimulus as a

sequence of alternating fixations and saccades, the focus and heat map shows gaze

patterns over a stimulus (BeGaze Manual, 2014). Preliminary to the detailed statistical

analysis, the author inspects the experimental data quality by BeGaze provided visual

data views. However, for deliberate study, the author has executed only statistical

analysis in R using raw data and event statistics.

Frequently, quantitative metrics of eye tracking data, such as fixation count, distribution

and position, saccadic amplitude, and pupil size specific to the AOI gives additional in-

formation about the decision-making strategies of the participants (Blascheck et al.,

2014). Common metrics for fixations are the number of fixations count, the fixation du-

ration in milliseconds and the fixation position given as x- and y-coordinates in pixels.

Fixation by itself does not provide meaning, only information where the participant fix-

ated. In general, fixation (percentage fixated, mean duration, position) is cross-

analysed with the AOI which indicates either interest to the AOI or perhaps difficulty in

understanding that AOI. Therefore, in this research, the fixation duration by itself can-

not be applied for analysis of participants’ interest to a particular area considering that

the graphical information is compared with textual required a significantly shorter dura-

tion (Granka, 2010). Additionally, the gaze cascade effect or duration of fixation is test-

37 ed to evaluate if it supports the stated hypotheses. Pupil dilation is an important pa-

rameter for determining cognitive load and the results of a shift of attention (Gamito,

2014). The author measures the mean of pupil dilation increase under time constraints

within and across trials to test the hypothesis of referencing to graphical information

and increase of cognitive activity under time constraints.

As mentioned previously, the following statistical software R was employed:

eyetracking R package and data.table, ezANOVA, ggplot, lmer packages. The

measures of central tendency such as mean, or the “balance point”, and median or the

“halving point” of fixation duration for a trial and each AOI is executed. Some of the

measures of position or location, such as quartiles and percentiles and measures of

dispersion such as standard deviation, range and the interquartile range illustrate the

degree of “spread” of the data and are provided in table format in the following chapter

(Godwin, 2016).

3.3 The design of the experiment

3.3.1 Participants

The author conducted an eye-tracking experiment to investigate the dynamics and

heuristics of investment decision making under time constraints. Twenty students from

the Hochschule Rhein-Waal participants’ pool completed the experiment (9 males and

11 females; age not recorded for participants, all are students of the University). Two

additional participants did not begin the experiment because they did not pass the

Screener Questionnaire suggested by Pernice and Nielsen (2015). They had eye-

related conditions that omitted them from participating. Data from two more students

had to be excluded from the analysis because their eye-tracking data was very low

quality (less than 40% tracking ratio)4. The students received a flat rate payment of

eight Euros for participation in the experiment. Decisions were not incentivized under

the assumption that the outcome of the investment decision is opportunistic. 40% of

the participants were assigned to sufficient time condition (given at least 10 minutes for

trial but not restricted), and 60% were limited by time in their decision-making process

(given 2.5 minutes for trial, or 30 seconds per stimulus). The participants had a 5-10

minute trial where they had time to familiarize themselves with the differences in the

layout of the online stock marketplaces.

4 The author uses tracking ratio applied by Amso, Markant and Haas (2014, p.3), or “the proportion of

time that the eye tracker recorded point of gaze coordinates over the entire task”, to improve quality of data. Participants with less than 40% tracking ratio contributes very little data and were excluded from analyses (1 male and 1 female).

38 3.3.2 Eye tracking apparatus and measures

Eye movements of the participants were recorded using the remote eye trackers (Sen-

soMotoric Instruments, SMI iView X RED250) while performing tasks. A five point cali-

bration is necessary to adapt the iView X eye tracking software to the participant's eye

characteristics. Additional points of validation to improve calibration quality were estab-

lished, and task stimuli were presented using the Experiment Center software

Integrated to SMI.

The experiment was carried out on three IBM-compatible desktop computers with built-

in SensoMotoric Instruments (SMI) software and the attached remote eye-trackers.

The stimuli were presented on three LCD monitors, which were controlled by Experi-

ment Center 2 (SMI). One was assigned to sufficient time conditions and the other two

were presented stimuli under time-constrained conditions. The viewing distance from a

participant to the monitor was approximately 70 cm. The participants’ eye movements

were recorded by the eye trackers with the infrared pupil and corneal reflex imaging

systems, at the sampling frequency of 120 Hz.

3.3.3 Stimuli

The following stimuli were presented in the experiment: screenshots from online stock

marketplaces as well as the questionnaire. Five screenshots for each of six companies

who trade their stock on the Deutsche Börse (the Frankfurt Stock Exchange), the Lon-

don Stock Exchange and the NASDAQ were presented as static stimuli on the display.

One day before the experiment, the information from the online stock marketplaces

were copied as screenshots except online advertising pop-ups which were deleted

from screenshots presentations. This approach is chosen to eliminate them as a dis-

traction to the decision-making process which is not aimed for analysis in this research.

The example of the screenshots is provided in Annex, Figure A.1. The first two compa-

nies are medium size, German engineering companies trading their equities on the

Deutsche Börse, for instance, ElringKlinger AG (market cap ≈ 1.38 b €) and KRONES

AG (market cap ≈ 3.22 b €) and were unfamiliar to most of the participants. The second

set of two companies is British financial companies who trade their stock on the Lon-

don Stock Exchange, such as III 3I GROUP PLC (market cap ≈ 4.36 b £) and FPO

FIRST PROPERTY GROUP PLC (market cap ≈ 60.59 b £), they were also unknown to

the participants. The third set of two companies, which also unfamiliar to the partici-

pants, is the U.S. biotechnology companies that trade their shares on the NASDAQ

Stock Market, such as ADMA Biologics Inc. (market cap ≈ 78.42 m $) and AMGN

Company (market cap 117.67 b $).

39 The reasons for choosing these particular companies are the following. First, in order

to diminish the familiarity bias, the author selects companies that unfamiliar to the par-

ticipants’ of the experiment. Second, the author randomizes the decision of the compa-

nies by their size, the first IPO (initial public offering) and performances. Moreover, the

author coordinates the screenshots with the information provided in each online stock

marketplace as (1-2) summary quote, (3) three years stock chart, (4) the company

information, including numerical performance and dividend information, and (5)

financial ratios in order to unify the analysis and comparison of stimuli. It should be

noted that the provided information is in a complex form which contains numbers,

words and visuals for each content defined AOI.

The displays of the companies were randomized, but the order of the stock information

was the same as enumerated above. To avoid confusion of obtaining information from

the displays, the author scaled the screenshots. Similar to the research conducted by

Stewart, Hermens, and Matthews (2015), the preliminary analysis of the data indicates

that the offsetting of the screenshots and randomization did not influence the decisions

or fixation durations.

The questionnaire includes some questions about participants’ attitudes and the strat-

egy they are going to use in the experiment and following at the end one additional

question about an actual strategy they applied in their deliberation of the stock infor-

mation. Each of six trials ends with the question about their decision between buying

and short selling a stock.

3.3.4 Procedure

Participants made six decisions between two options of buying or short selling stock in

the experiment. The information about the stock and company performance preceded

each decision. The author assumes that the price of the stock reflects all available in-

formation. The experiment lasted an average of 35 minutes which included the time to

answer the preliminary questionnaire, participation in a trial part, calibration phase, and

the eye tracking experiment. After signing up for the experiment, the participants were

required to answer the Screener Questionnaire. Successful candidates continued to

separate computers where they had approximately 5-10 minutes to browse chosen

online stock marketplaces to familiarize themselves with the layouts of each market-

place, i.e. the Deutsche Börse, the London Stock Exchange and the NASDAQ. Prac-

tice trials were obtained from a different set of stocks than those that applied to the

main task. This approach is a necessary step to prepare participants for the experiment

in order to optimize the decision-making process to prevent participant stress with the

40 complexity of the represented information and differences in the layout of the natural

settings.

Moreover, each participant was provided with the essential investor terminology

obtained from the NASDAQ Stock Exchange in order to fully inform participants of

stock exchange terminology such as earnings per share (EPS), EPS growth,

price/earnings ratio (PE) ratio, dividend yield, PEG (price/earnings to growth) ratio,

operating margin, return on capital employed, beta, market cap capitalization and 52

week high/low. They were not permitted to use the terminology cheat sheet during the

experiment, only during the trial. No eye tracking or any recordings were performed

during the trial. As soon as participants had experienced at least one trial with each of

the online stock marketplaces and understood the tasks, they proceeded to the main

session. Participants were asked to care about the decision that they were going to

make as if they were making the decision for them, i.e. take all given time, think delib-

erately and respond honestly.

The main part starts with a five-point calibration of the eye tracker and validation of the

calibration. Calibration was repeated as needed to obtain the best match. Participants

as aforementioned had to decide if they would buy or rather short-sell the stock. All the

information about the pricing and performance of the stock and company were

provided on the preceding five stimuli. The research is not only focused on the final

decisions but mostly in the processing of the provided information in order to make a

decision. Therefore, measures of attention and pupil dilation as a predictor of changes

in fixation durations are identified and investigated. The experiment is designed under

two conditions. Under the first condition, the participants had about 10 minutes to de-

liberate and search necessary information for the final decision. They had 2.5 minutes,

or 30 seconds per screen under time constrained conditions. The participants had the

option to return to any five previous stimuli if needed to review any of them in their

decision-making process. Therefore not only the dynamics across trials is intriguing to

examine but also within trials to determine, for example, the most referenced stimuli in

the decision-making process.

4 DESCRIPTION OF DATA

4.1 Detailed description of data collection, measures and recording

In the conducted experiment the participants' tasks are to evaluate the information

about the stock presented on the screen and decide if they would like to buy or short-

sell the particular stock. Students are usually considered as proxies for unsophisticated

investors (De Bondt & Thaler, 1985). Therefore, this research does not focus on a pro-

41 fessional decision-making strategy but on the decision-making process of a typical nov-

ice investor who is willing to invest his/her money via online stock marketplaces. Ac-

cording to the Bundesbank report, in 2013 approximately 11% (in middle quintile in-

come) of German households or about nine million people hold direct share investments.

In the experiment, each participant had six tasks with five static stimuli respectively per

task. The stimuli are organized sequentially according to the representation of the

stock information on the online stock marketplaces, i.e. (1-2) two summary pages

including stock quotes, volume, some ratios, in some cases company news headlines,

short information about the company and chart; (3) a three-year price chart chosen

against the provided interactive chart online, (4) the company information including

dividends, shareholders structure, market cap, company news; (5) financial ratios

together with some historical key data. Even though each of the five stimuli led to a de-

cision task, the participants could freely return to previous stimuli within a task if the

time allowed them to review the information again. The order of the trials was random-

ized to diminish the order effect. And as soon as a decision was made on the task, and

the participants began the next task, they could not return to the previous task to alter

their decision. Moreover, as mentioned in the previous chapter, the stocks are chosen

to be neutral in terms of familiarity to the participants.

According to Holmqvist, “a perfect experiment is one in which no factors systematically

influence the dependent variable (e.g. fixation duration) other than the ones controlled”

(Holmqvist, 2011, p.74). Therefore, the search5 for the content of the information to

make a decision is controlled by strictly defined and unified stimuli (AOIs), in conjunc-

tion with two different time conditions assigned to the participant to deliberate the dis-

played information in this experiment. On one hand, it is impossible to limit all of the

possible influential factors including emotional and physical differences or conditions to

simplify the complex nature of the decision-making process. However, on the other

hand by controlling the maximum possible conditions the results of the experiment can

be strictly applied only to the artificially controlled and manipulated settings which have

a detached relationship with the nature of the real world decision-making process.

Therefore, considering the particular design of the experiment, the eye movement data

was collected by the SMI’s Experiment Center 2 software with the following scope: (1)

movement measures, including variety of eye-movements and their properties; (2)

position measure, i.e. location, and “the properties of eye-movements at spatial

locations”; (3) numerical measure, particularly, “the number, proportion, or rate of any

countable eye-movement event”; and (4) latency measures, or “the duration from the

5 Information search means a deliberation process of obtaining relevant to the decision-making infor-mation in this paper.

42 onset of one event to the onset of a second event” (Holmqvist, 2011, p.3). The exam-

ples of the data collected represent direction, amplitude, duration, velocity, and accel-

eration of eye movements.

However, considering that the event data from the BeGaze software such as transition

matrices, scan path lengths and heat maps hinge on how fixations and saccades are

calculated by the software, e.g. filters in the velocity calculation, the author considers

mainly the raw data for the analysis. Additionally, the author does not apply any com-

plex measures that have not been validated by previous studies and have not been

linked to a particular cognitive process such as transition diagrams, position dispersion

measures, or scan path similarity measures. The other measurements such as smooth

pursuit gain and the anti-saccade measurement, even though executed extensively in

the preceding studies, they have been implemented in different fields of research, for

example, reading and scene perception. Recognizing that the validity of a dependent

variable is based on previous discoveries, no additional assumptions are made without

referring to the specific eye tracking research to support it. Moreover, in the selection of

measures and dependent variables, the author addresses certain points in time where

the participants are involved in the deliberation of the specific AOI, as recommended

by Holmqvist (2011), rather than prolonged gaze sequences.

Furthermore, the author takes into account the effect of how information is displayed,

i.e. that the participants tend to look more at the centre rather than the edges of the

monitor. Additionally, the participants make more horizontal than vertical saccades and

very few diagonal ones (Holmqvist, 2011). The representation effect and precision of

the samples are considered when the results are analysed in this paper because the

author does not manipulate or randomize the locations of the displayed information to

maintain the layout as it is online but varied them by representing the different online

stock marketplaces.

As stated by Andrienko and his colleagues (2012), eye tracking data can be assessed

by point-based or AOI-based approaches. If point-based measure considers the overall

eye movement and spatial or temporal distribution, then AOI-based metrics compare

the transition and relation between AOIs. The statistical analysis provided in this re-

search relies on both approaches: point-based (time binned) to investigate the dynam-

ics of the decision-making process and AOI-based techniques, to evaluate in what AOI

the participants are more fixated to make a decision.

The following noises are ignored in the experiment: (1) system-inherent noise because

the eye-tracker determines a spatial variance and not the researcher manually; (2)

43 oculomotor noise or jitter such as tremor, microsaccades, and drift6, and (3)

environmental noise, or “variation in the gaze position signal caused by external

mechanical and electromagnetic disturbances recording environment” (Holmqvist,

2011, p.34). Following Holmqvist’ recommendations such as “data quality results from

the combined effects of eye-tracker specific properties such as sampling frequency,

latency, and precision and participant-specific properties,” the author attempts to

mitigate possible noises in design and collection of data by following the suggestions

given in Experimental Center and BeGaze Manuals (Holmqvist, 2011. P.29). To im-

prove the quality of the dependent variables, all noisy and invalid data was removed,

for example, the invalid gaze data are originated from noise, eye blinks and extended

head movements that are beyond the eye tracker's range of detection. Conforming to

suggestions stated by Komogortsev (2010) and his colleagues, the author filtered long

duration invalid data of (more than 1,000 ms), noise and the blink duration data that are

less than 75 ms. Moreover, participants with a tracking ratio of less than 40% and a

calibration accuracy higher than 1° are not included in the analysis. Additionally, when

observing a less than ± 2° disparity in the participants’ right and left eye movements,

the same as Cornell and his colleagues (2003), and being convinced with the

conclusions of Eser and his fellows (2008) that approximately two-thirds of the people

have right eye dominance, the author analyses the data only from the right eye

movements in her research.

Providing details of the data collection process and measurements, the author briefly

reviews data recordings to demonstrate all available data forms for the analysis and

then defines the dependent variables which are considered for the research. As men-

tioned in the previous chapter, eye movement was recorded at the sampling rate of

120 Hz which means eye tracker recorded approximately 120 gaze points per second.

Considering 20 participants, six tasks and at least five stimuli per task (not including

options to browse between five stimuli if the given time permitted), the raw data col-

lected counts of over 1.5 million gaze points which afterward aggregated to the fixa-

tions, saccades, and blinks applying to the event detection algorithms. The following

statistical data was retrieved from BeGaze: raw data for each participant, fixation and

saccade parameters, AOI sequence, transition matrix, and event statistics with approx-

imately 100 statistical variables. However, the author relies only on raw data samples

to perform eye tracking analysis using R statistical software.

6 A drift is a systematic error or a disparity.

44

4.2 Definition of dependent variables

The experimental approach deals with the analysis of the effect of independent varia-

bles, e.g. displayed stimuli, on dependent variables measured as the participant’s reac-

tion to the stimulus, for instance, the examination of fixation durations or saccadic am-

plitude under controlled conditions of time constraints and sufficient time to make a de-

cision. The experiment demonstrates how manipulations of the independent variables

affect the dependent variables (Holmqvist, 2011).

The author is going to analyse the experimental data acquired over time and by the

AOIs, returning to the research questions stated in the introduction, to determine if they

are affected by time constraints. In this paper, the author has measured the attention

(mean percentage fixation duration) of the participants and pupil dilation provided in

BeGaze raw data sets. This approach allows the comparison of the chosen AOIs and

heuristics applied in the decision-making process under time constraints. In addition,

the author investigates a correlation between the AOIs and the final decisions.

A gain or loss as a consequence of the investment decision of each participant is

evaluated by the following stock performance: 25th of March stock price compared with

25th of January stock price as displayed in the experiment. The margin of safety princi-

ple is applied in this thesis to evaluate possible consequences of the decision. The

threshold for gain is a 20% increase (or decrease in the case of short selling) and a

10% decrease (or increase in the case of short selling) in price. The chosen approach

is explained in more detail in the next section of this chapter.

The main terminology in eye-tracking research is fixation which is generally correlated

with visual attention. A fixation is an aggregation of gaze points measured by an eye

tracker. Typically gaze points are combined by a specified area of interest and

timespan. A fixation is the longest the eye gaze remains still over time. There are no

standardized aggregation areas or set timespans for a fixation but usually about 20 to

50 pixels and between 200 and 300 ms is observed according to the Holmqvist’s eye

tracking bible (Holmqvist et al., 2011). However, the identification of eye fixations main-

ly depends on a task and an approach. Previously Duchowski (2007) demonstrated

that information complexity and task complexity influence on fixation duration. For ex-

ample, “the average fixation duration during silent reading is approximately 225 milli-

seconds, while other tasks, including typing, scene perception, and music reading ap-

proach averages of 300-400 milliseconds” (Granka, Feusner, & Lorigo, 2008, p.3). The

average fixation duration in this research is around 300 ms. Fixations are classified us-

ing a 35-pixel tolerance and a minimum fixation time threshold of 75 ms as recom-

mended by the SMI Manual and the previous eye-tracking literature (Holmqvist et al.,

45 2011; Fiedler & Glöckner, 2012). Fixations are connected by saccades or continuous

and rapid movements of eye gazes. During the eye fixation, the following processes

take place, as mentioned by Viviani (2004), encoding of a visual stimulus, a sampling

of the periphery, and planning for the next saccade. Fixations in a particular AOI are

usually grouped together in mean fixation duration. The prevailing metrics for fixations

are the fixation duration in milliseconds, the fixation count (i.e. number of fixations), and

the fixation position specified as x- and y-coordinates in the pixel.

According to the previous studies, fixations reveal where the participant’s attention is

focused and represent the examples and the order of information acquisition and pro-

cessing (Rayner, 1998). The previous experimental findings evidence a very high cor-

relation between fixation on a displayed stimulus and exact thoughts about this stimu-

lus. In addition, the fixation duration on certain items directly links to the degree of cog-

nitive processing (Just & Carpenter, 1980). Depending on the type of displayed infor-

mation, the possible differences in fixation duration can be explained by the time and

speed required to absorb the information. While the eye moves rapidly during reading,

a participant typically grasps key information from certain regions in the visual search

which supports the idea of using heuristics in information processing (Sullivan et al.,

2012). The research on eye movements in reading proposes that fixation durations ex-

tend with the complexity of the text (Rayner et al., 2012).

AOI’s fixation percentage, mean proportion fixation (or mean proportion gaze) are the

main dependent variables in this research which identify the percentage of time fixated

at the specific AOIs during a trial. The study also considers relevant AOI fixation densi-

ty which defines the percentage of time fixated at the specific AOIs.

As mentioned briefly above, saccades are the continuous, ballistic and rapid move-

ments of eye gazes from one fixation to another (Purves, Augustine & Fitzpatrick,

2001). These extremely rapid movements last only 30-80 milliseconds with velocities

approaching 500 degrees per second. Again, there is no established standard for

length and velocities of the saccades. Therefore, the author follows the recommenda-

tions of BeGaze software to divide fixation from saccades and cross checks the results

with the other current studies in this area (Holmqvist et al., 2011). Humans are not

aware of saccadic movements. However, eye tracking data by measuring saccadic

movements can reach deep into information processing and absorption of new infor-

mation. The following typical metrics for saccadic movements are retrieved from Be-

Gaze software: the saccadic duration in milliseconds, the saccadic amplitude (i.e. the

distance the saccade traveled), and the saccadic velocity in degrees per second

(Blascheck, 2014). Certainly, no information is perceived and acquired during rapid

saccadic movement because of “the unstable image on the retina during eye move-

46 ments and other biological factors” (Granka, Feusner, & Lorigo, 2008, p.3). Saccadic

movements from one AOI to the next are called transition and scan paths. They illus-

trate a complete sequence of fixations and saccades to examine the information delib-

eration in the decision-making process. In this case, the sum of durations from all fixa-

tions and saccades, which hit the particular AOI, is defined as a dwell. However, even

though the transition matrix demonstrates search order regarding transition (or chang-

es in fixations), a maximum of two order transitions provided by BeGaze software limits

the horizon of estimates and accuracy of assumptions. Therefore, the author does not

consider a sequence of fixations and saccades as a final variable for this research.

Next, scan paths are a sequence of alternating fixations and saccades and illustrate

the pattern of eye movement across the visual stimulus. A straight line to a specified

AOI can be regarded as an ideal scan path. However, deviance from this ideal scan

path is interpreted as poor search by Goldberg and Kotval (1999). Examples of scan

path metrics are specified by Blascheck and his colleagues (2014), including scan path

length in pixels, or scan path duration in milliseconds and the convex hull (i.e. which area

is covered by the scan path). The participant’s scan path behaviour presents an insight

into their navigation through a visual stimulus. Preceding studies propose that scan

path movement is not random, but depends on a participant’s emotional state, expecta-

tions and purpose (Yarbus, 1967). This research does not analyse specific patterns in

scan paths that can explain the dynamics of decision making but applies the growth

curve analysis to confront the stated hypotheses.

The next dependent variable is pupil diameter or dilation which is defined as a measure

of active processing and often linked to task difficulty (Kahnemann & Beatty, 1966). A

larger diameter indicates an individual’s arousal or interest in the viewed content.

Therefore, if pupil dilation increases in the particular AOI, the author can assume that

this type of information is important in decision making. Previous studies compare the

average pupil dilation in a specific AOI and additionally the average pupil dilation over

an entire stimulus or experimental time to explain how participants might cognitively

process the matter of various content (Hess & Polt, 1960; Rayner, 1998; Duchowski,

2002). Kahneman stated in his interview with the German news magazine Der Spiegel

that “the pupils reflect the extent of mental effort in an incredibly precise way” (Kahne-

man, 2012). Moreover, recently Fiedler and Glöckner (2012) have demonstrated that

an increase in pupil dilation correlates with an increasing mean of expected value. Ad-

ditionally, pupil dilation increases over the duration of the experiment. Not only cogni-

tive but also emotional events lead to pupil constriction and expansion. In this re-

search, the author analyses the pupil diameter as a predictor of the logit and mixed-

effects models.

47 The author does not consider smooth pursuit movements for the analysis because

these movements are associated with a dynamic stimulus or moving objects which are

not used in this study. The other eye movements such as vergence movements are

also assumed to be negligible and not applicable to this research.

The last variable to be explained is the future value of the stock. As mentioned before,

the author does not calculate the expected value of the stock. Since all stock pricing

information is taken as screenshots directly from the online stock marketplaces without

any manipulations on the 25th of January, there was no reason to speculate a future

expected value because the stock markets provided the exact price of the stock on

March 25th. Therefore, the author knows the precise price of the stock three months

after the decisions were made by participants.

Additionally, the investment decision process does not end with a decision (buying or

short selling the stock), it continues until an investor will have a gain or loss. Consider-

ing this rational, the author assumes that immature investors try to follow the best

strategy recommended by analytics to manage his/her stock decision (purchase or

short-sell). Possibly by collecting more information about the company performance

he/she will be able to estimate the expected future value, his/her expected return, and

intrinsic value of the stock. The value of any share of stock finally rests on the present

value of the company's future cash flows. However, valuation will always hold a degree

of uncertainty. Even though all the calculations are precise, they reflect the value of the

stock at a specific moment in time. The news or any other changes in the company

performance can alter the perspectives. Therefore, an investor has to aim for a strate-

gy over time. These are the reasons why investors heavily rely on the margin of safety

concept in investing, that the Wall Street advisers favoured.

Accordingly, the author assumes that the immature investor also tries to use the mar-

gin of safety principle: sell the stock when it drops more than 10% and when it increase

in value more 20% depending on risk attitude. In contrary with short selling stock: buy

back if the price decreases 20% or more, or if price increase 10% or more, to mitigate

losses depending on risk tolerance (Calandro, 2011). This strategy (1) allows minimiz-

ing the possible loss from a mistaken decision, (2) considers that there is another bet-

ter option to invest in the market (3) is supported by recent statistics of investment

behaviour. According to LPL Financial, NYCE (2012) statistics, the average holding

period for stock decreased to less than one year compared with more than eight years

in 1960. (4) This strategy takes into account cognitive biases such as sunk cost,

confirmation, optimism or pessimism, etc., or finding the most difficult reasons to sell

the stock. (5) Based on intrinsic value calculation which is subjective in this case, the

margin of safety includes a cushion against errors in calculation.

48 It will be interesting to investigate the predicted outcome of this type of strategy com-

pared with others such as the more academic discounted cash flow (DCF) method, the

dividend discount model (DDM), etc. However, it is the topic of another research.

Thus, the author adopts the stock price developed in three months as the future stock

price and applies the margin of safety principle that a rational investor will employ in

his/her decision to buy or short sell a stock. The author judges the accuracy of the par-

ticipant’s decisions based on previous assumptions.

To sum up, this research analyses dependent measures of eye movement over the

entire decision-making time. The author investigates the dynamics of changes in

gazing at AOIs. Metrics such as fixation duration, the number of fixations, and pupil di-

lation (based on diameter), are described per each AOI such as “stock”, “chart”, “com-

pany”, and “ratios” and over time. Because the author uses different online stock mar-

ketplaces to diminish the order or the presentation of information effects on the

decision-making process, the AOIs’ definitions based on web pages is not consistent.

Therefore, the author determines the AOIs based on the content of the provided infor-

mation. First, the AOI stock contains pricing information such as bid-ask prices, spread,

52 weeks high-low prices, the stock trading information including volume and in some

cases stock price related ratios such as beta, alpha, EPS. This block of information is

numerical and minimally textual. Second, the AOI.visuals comprises a three-year price

chart, supportive graphs and visuals of the stock volume. The AOI company consists of

company information including address, industry, short descriptions, shareholders’ in-

formation, information about dividends, also latest news headlines. The AOI ratio in-

cludes all the key financial and historical ratios assisting in determining the intrinsic

value of the stock.

4.3 Data procedure

4.3.1 Cleaning and preparing data for R analysis

After modifying the AOI, the experimental data is adjusted to the eye tracking package

in R to examine the data set. EyetrackingR deals with initial raw data where each row

specifies a sample measure. Because the author operates the SMI eye tracker with the

sampling frequency of 120 Hz, each row of data represents an equally spaced amount

of time of 8 ms based on fixation position and timing information. The samples that are

more than 8 ms long are omitted.

The author focuses on the analysis of the gaze proportion across AOIs and within the

time bin of 100 ms. Therefore, non-AOI gazing data is not included into the comparison

between AOIs. As a result, all fixations to the white space (non-AOI determined fixa-

tions) are excluded from the analysis. Accordingly, the data examination focuses on

49 the trade-off between defined AOIs and determines the gaze to the single AOI across

conditions. Additionally, the author uses the first stimulus page and the last stimulus

page to test the stated hypotheses derived from the decision field theory (DFT) and

adaptive toolbox model (ATB). Thus, to calculate gaze proportion at the particular AOI,

the author computes “time looking to the AOI divided by time looking to all other AOIs”

by following an option given by Dink & Ferguson’s (2015) eye tracking package.

Both data files with no time constraints and under time constrained conditions passed

the following cleaning and adjusting process. The research concentrates only on delib-

eration of the provided online stock information and the decision-making process of this

information. Therefore, only stimuli from the online stock marketplaces remain for the

analysis, i.e. six companies with five pages of information for a company. Each of the

pages is framed with the particular AOIs as mentioned above. Additionally, the author

deletes the data of 2 participants with a tracking ratio less than the 40% to have

enough eye movement data for a participant to judge individual decision making. The

data that does not qualify as any AOI or is determined to be a white space is also

deleted from the analysis. Moreover, the data that do not qualify as fixation, blink or

saccade is not considered for the examination. Some data loss takes place when the

eye-tracker cannot track the participant’s eyes because a participant accidentally turns

his/her head or suddenly looks away from the screen to deliberate information or blinks

often, where the gaze location has very low efficacy.

As indicated above, the experiment is designed around two-time conditions: the first

group of participants totaling nine students did not have any time constraints, but only

about 10 minutes per company was given to this group of participants; the second

group has the time constrained condition with 2.5 minutes or 30 sec per screen. No

one from the first group of students used the total given time condition of 10 minutes

per task. In the time-constrained condition of 2.5 minutes, a few participants attempted

to violate the time constrained condition by clicking forward and backward between the

pages. The data recorded at above 30 seconds duration per stimulus in the second

group is deleted, i.e. only for the two participants mentioned previously. Thus, approx-

imately one million gaze samples are considered for the eyetrackingR analysis after

cleaning the raw experimental data. The eye tracking package additionally (1) deter-

mines the amount of lost data in each trial and then (2) removes trials with over 25%

data loss. After analysis of the amount of lost data by participant and trials, approxi-

mately 402 trials are removed by the software and the additional two participants were

eliminated from the analysis. The author reports in Table B.1 the results of the lost data

per participant. As a result, the following data with the mean samples of 83.98% and

50 standard deviation (SD) equalling 3.00% contributed per trial, indicating that the devia-

tion of the data from the mean is minor.

4.3.2 Descriptive statistics and regression

In the next step, the author explains the results of the descriptive statistics analysis of

the data. The data summary provides the means and variance within each condition for

each participant or AOI, and some quick visualization of the variables. These graphs

represent the differences by plotting a line for each participant or AOI in each testing

condition. The provided descriptive statistics and plots correlate each participant and

trials to the different AOIs, time onset for a trial and pupil dilation by measuring pupil diame-

ter7 in mm.

Furthermore, the author performs a simple paired t-test using a single mean proportion

value (percentage of fixations to the particular AOI) for each time condition and each

participant. At this point, the author incorporates additional predictors into the analysis,

e.g. pupil dilation. After t-test, regression analysis additionally provides the following

dependent variables for the analysis, e.g. logit adjusted, empirical logit or corrected

logit transformed and arcsine square root transformed variables. The integration by

participants across the response window is realized by using arcsin function to trans-

form proportional data of dependent variables. However, this approach cannot inte-

grate one variable within another, for example, accumulated data by stimuli within par-

ticipants. In this case, the author follows with linear mixed-effect models applying lme4

package in R or empirical and adjusted logit transformed dependent variable. The au-

thor examines the fixation to the particular AOI (for example, the AOI stock) hinge on

the time condition of each trial, while computing for random intercepts and slopes

across trials and participants to determine if there are any significant differences be-

tween outcomes. In the end, the author tests an additional effect of pupil dilation that

may be correlated with changes in AOIs.

4.3.3 Growth curve analysis

Growth curve analysis is a multi-level regression model intended for the analysis of

time course or longitudinal data (Mirman, 2014). The previous analysis does not take

into account time course of the decision-making process across trials or participants.

Therefore, the author further advances the examination of data with growth curve anal-

ysis and visualization of data over the time course. In the decision-making process, the

changes in grasping particular information or focusing attention on the particular AOI

7 In this paper pupil dilation is measured by pupil diameter, which indicates the pupil size in a gaze sample.

51 demonstrates if participants develop some strategies or patterns that influence a final

decision and more effectively explain the decision-making process over time. Thus, for

the growth analysis, first, the data is separated into 100 ms time bins to calculate fixa-

tion proportion for each separate time bin over the course of the stimulus and statisti-

cally evaluate the bends in these curves (Dink & Ferguson, 2015). In other terms, this

model assesses raw gaze proportions or its transformations over time by simultaneous

regression of differences between time conditions. The author started with a linear time

model and further considers a non-linear change over time.

At this point, the author finalizes how the data analysis, previously explained, tests the

hypotheses stated in the introduction of this thesis. The following hypotheses were

formulated to test attention to the content of the provided information under time

constraints that influenced the decision. The author discusses them individually step-

by-step. First, the author following DFT assumes that the fixation duration is stable

over time, which is examined by fixation duration in each AOI per company and by

growth curve analysis. Second, the gaze cascade mechanism supports the decision

which indicates attentional bias. Participant based analysis of mean percentage fixation

duration tests this hypothesis. On average, how long is the participants’ gaze at the

particular AOI? This hypothesis furthermore is challenged with cross analysis of the

final decisions, i.e. if gaze cascade correlates with buying or short selling decision.

Third, visual information such as graphs and charts impacts the decision. The AOI

based determination of mean percentage fixation duration and regression across trials

and participants allows detection of time constrained conditions if they affect the fixa-

tion on the AOI visuals.

Additionally, the next three hypotheses verify the decision-making process under time

constraints or heuristics behind the decision dynamics. The fourth hypothesis states

that the most prominent dimension tends to be processed the most and the first com-

pare with others. The author assumes that the summary of the stock price or the AOI

stock’s stimuli impacts the decision process over time the most. However, how do the

effect of information presentation or the order impact the importance of the pricing in-

formation? Is the summary of a stock price prominent because it is presented on the

first page of all the online marketplaces, or because it is extremely valuable in decision

making and therefore presented the first? Fifth, according to DFT, the longest alterna-

tive should be chosen more frequently because of longer deliberation time. This hy-

pothesis has a different aspect than the attention bias concept. It conditions the time of

deliberation of information as an effective measure of a particular decision. Growth

curve analysis determines a change in the decision over time, which correlates with a

deliberation time. The last hypothesis is derived from DFT. However, if this hypothesis

52 is rejected, it supports adaptive toolbox model. Additionally upon rejection, the last hy-

pothesis affirms that changing to simple heuristics decreases the accuracy of the

decision. The author assumes that deliberation time reduces significantly under time

constraints. Therefore, simple heuristics are expected to be applied in the decision-

making process. The final decision accuracy directly depends on the hypothesis ac-

ceptance. The author regresses participant times in task duration (a decision to buy or

short-sell a stock) against their decision accuracy that is determined as mentioned be-

fore by a margin of safety principle to minimize the downside risk.

5 RESULTS

The analysis of the dependent measures elaborates and deepens over three main

steps of the data examination. The author starts with descriptive statistics providing a

description and summary of the data statistics such as mean, standard deviation (SD)

and variance. The next step is performing step-by-step regression and testing of the

eye tracking data with arcsin square root transformation to logit modelling to discover

nonlinear correlations and significant relations of the data set. Third, examining how

the differences and correlations between variables emerged over time by completing

the scrutinizing of the data with growth curve analysis. The last part summarizes the

results in connection with the assumed hypotheses.

[…Please send me email to receive visual and analytical part of this chapter.

Thank you!]

5.4 Summary of the results

To conclude the above provided statistical analysis of the gazing data samples, the au-

thor summarizes the findings by following the formulated hypotheses. However, it

should be mentioned beforehand, that there are some differences between laboratory

and field, the complexity of naturalistic decision making cannot be directly concluded

only based on the experimental founding. The experimental settings and the decision-

making conditions presumably affect the experimental results. Therefore, the summary

is based on step-by-step specifics of design, collection and analysis of data.

According to the research questions, this paper intends to analyse the information con-

tent and heuristics behind the decision-making process. Therefore, the following hy-

potheses are developed based on DFT and ATB models of the decision-making pro-

53 cess. The provided statistical analysis tests these specifically stated hypotheses in this

chapter.

Thus, the first hypothesis states that fixation duration is stable over time. The author

observes the complexity of this assumption in both conditions. Fixation duration as ap-

proximated around 200-300 ms can be considered as stable. However, the author indi-

cates in the previous analysis that fixation duration links to the information content or

depends on the presented stimulus (the AOI). The mean percentage fixation is varied

depending from the presented AOI and significantly impacted by time conditions.

Moreover, as mentioned in the previous research, fixation duration is idiosyncratic and

varies from participant to participant. Therefore, within the trials and as more simplistic

and familiar information is given, the fixation duration averages and remains more sta-

ble than observed by previous experiments (Horstmann et al., 2009). As presented by

the growth curve analysis the fixation is not precisely stable over time and slightly dif-

ferentiated because of the complexity and variety of the displayed information. Howev-

er, the author would agree with Glöckner and Herbold (2011) that the later fixations are

longer (Figure 5.3.1, graph number 4).

The next hypothesis asserts influence of attention or the gaze cascade effect over de-

cision making. The longer the gaze on a particular AOI the more preferences will be

given to it (Shinsuke Shimojo et al., 2003). In order to test this hypothesis, the author

regresses the decision made results against gaze proportions and additionally includes

growth curve analysis. The results support this hypothesis, especially in the given time

constrained condition, where the participants’ decisions are correlated directly with the

fixation duration over the particular company. Moreover, the previous results demon-

strate that the attention bias positively affects the final decision under time constraints,

where the effect is much higher or lower with sufficient time. The participants without

time constraints have plenty of time to deliberate information content; therefore, they

contrast their decisions despite the attention because of the negative or pessimistic

information content.

The third and fourth hypotheses are the levelled extensions of the gaze cascade

mechanism where the author analyses if fixation duration to the particular AOIs affects

the final decision. The results indicate that focus on visual information is only a little

higher under time constraints, but not significant in comparison with the other AOIs.

However, it should be taken into account the nature of cognitive processing of visual

information that requires less fixation duration in the stage of grasping the visuals.

Nevertheless, it increases with focusing on key information obtained from the graph or

chart. Growth curve analysis supports this reasoning. Furthermore, the author ob-

serves that there is not a significant impact on AOI stock over a decision under time

54 constraints. Nevertheless, the order of the stimuli might reduce the significance of this

AOI on a decision. Moreover, the pupil diameter changes over time. The correlation

between these changes in pupil diameter and fixation duration in each AOI confirms

the similar trend in each AOI. However under time constraints, the difference in gazing

at the specific AOI is more varying from trial to trial because participants become more

familiar with the information content and task, more confident in their strategy, more

selectively observe the information in order to fit into the given time frame. And these

changes overcome individual changes within the trial and between AOIs. Therefore,

the author rejects the third and fourth hypotheses.

The fifth hypothesis includes the deliberation time in the decision-making process and

states the tendency between deliberation time, fixation duration, and final decision.

Time conditions do not significantly impact the decision. The result demonstrates that

even though participants spent more time to gaze at a particular company stock, they

finally decided to short-sell the stock (despite the attention bias and deliberation time).

Therefore, the influence of unfavourable information such as a downside trend of the

stock price or other pessimistic information about the company’s future performance

can challenge the final decision against attention bias in cases of extended deliberation

time. The fifth hypothesis is also rejected.

Finally, the sixth hypothesis assumes a correlation between decision accuracy and

given time. Under time constraints, the participants employ simple heuristics which

eventually decrease the accuracy of their decisions. The statistical analysis of the eye-

tracking data does not support this hypothesis. There is no distinct difference between

gazing at the particular company to make a decision to buy or short-sell it and accuracy

of the decision over time. However, considering growth curve analysis the author takes

a glimpse at the sublevel of the decision accuracy depending on the particular AOIs

observed by the participants. It concludes that under time constraints the participant

who focused more on ratios and the summary of the stock better predicted the future

price of the stock. Additionally, participants, who had extra time to read over company

information, evaluated a possible future stock price better than participants under time

constraints.

55

6 CONCLUSION

6.1 Overview of the research

Decision making in economics and finance is a novel and at the same time very di-

verse area of research. In spite of some important advances, the decision-making pro-

cess is still an enigma that imposes significant challenges on research. Forasmuch in-

triguing as the topic contains and recognizing the complexity of subject matter; the au-

thor attempts to input originality to the research by designing and conducting an own

experiment to analyse the investment decision-making process under time constraints

exploiting the information from the online stock marketplace as stimuli for the experi-

ment.

In order to justify the motivation and topic importance, the author devotes the whole

introduction section to introduce step-by-step the definitions of the topic and back-

ground behind each term. The pathway from neoclassical principles of von Neumann–

Morgenstern (1944) to the behavioural matter of Kahneman and Tversky (1979) in

economics and finance is only about 35 years old, but it changes the perception and

approach including behavioural aspects of the agent or “utility maximizer” in pursuance

of improving economic models. Following after, the author gave the overview of the

progress in decision theory and how it directly relates to economics. Shifting from the

static model of Edwards (1954) to the dynamic model of Busemeyer and Townsend

(1993) is the way to recognize the complexity of the decision-making matter which is

no longer associated with the only outcome but opens the black box of inside pro-

cessing.

However, pondering further the nature of the decision-making process, the author indi-

cates that the time constraints that impose limitations and tangible drawback need to

be taken into account and investigated. Moreover, the author is interested in the cogni-

tive processes behind decision-making and hence applies the eye tracking techniques

to the research. Certainly, there are some assumptions to be made between eye

movement, attention and behaviour. However, the eye tracking techniques are

improving, and the eye tracking analysis is obtaining deeper levels. It might not be a

direct causal correlation between behaviour and gazing, but the eyes are one way to

understand the mind which impacts individual behaviour. Additionally, nowadays the

financial markets are no longer restricted to brokers; investors with different experience

and knowledge are trading shares by the click of the computer mouse. Therefore, all of

the above mentioned and furthermore indicated in this thesis have motivated the au-

thor to select this topic for the master’s thesis.

56 The main two research questions that the author focuses on in this study are (1) which

information content is more attentive in making decisions with time constraints and (2)

what heuristics are employed in the decision-making process under time constraints.

The author designed the eye tracking experiment to keep the natural settings of the

online stock marketplaces to a maximum. However, in order to formulate and test the

precise hypothesis, the author meticulously chose (1) identical content for each

company and online stock marketplace based AOIs, (2) three different layouts to

minimize the order effect on the decision, (3) six middle sized and little known to the

public companies to minimize recognition bias in decision-making.

Furthermore, the research requires grounds as to what was discovered and investigat-

ed in this area before. Therefore, in the next step, the author reviews previous publica-

tions in economics, finance and business that employ eye-tracking techniques under

time pressure and constraints, including consumer economic decisions as a purchase

choice and decision making under uncertainty and time pressure and constraints. Be-

cause the terms are not distinguished precisely in previous publications, the author

overviews the literature on time pressure and time constraints. Additionally, the litera-

ture review comprises of decision making in economics and finance under uncertainty

and time pressure and constraints. This approach is chosen to overview the extension

of previous studies in this area and the utilization of different methods and applications

and to demonstrate that this research is unique in applying eye tracking techniques to

examine the decision-making process of obtaining information from online stock mar-

ketplaces under time constraints.

After outlining this vast area of research in decision making, the author identifies and

discusses the previous methodology, methods and models that are utilized in this area

of study and reasons the adopted methods for the research. Following Fiedler and

Glöcker (2012), the author defines two major classes of existing process models: heu-

ristics models and automatic integration models. Most of the recently developed mod-

els are indeed extensions, specifications or integrations of simple heuristics or DFT

models.

The authors’ choice of the methods has a rational explanation rooted in the stated re-

search questions and the capability of the SMI eye tracking technology. Taking into

account the features of the stimuli (information from online stock marketplaces) and

brainstorming possible correlations between visual attention to the financial

information, dynamics of the decision-making process and final choice, the author

assumes that the hypotheses and ideas of adaptive toolbox model (ATB) and decision

field theory (DFT) can explain the outcome of the experiment.

57 To design the experiment, measure the attention of the participant and collect the eye

tracking data for the subsequent examination, the author utilizes SensoMotoric Instru-

ments, SMI iView X RED250, an eye tracker and Experiment Suite 360 software bun-

dle which includes Experimenter Center 2 and BeGaze 3.5.10 in it. To conclude the

design, 20 participants were exposed to 30 stimuli with six tasks to decide to buy or

short-sell based on observed and deliberated information provided on the screen. More

than 1.5 million samples of raw gaze data collected undergo a rigorous cleaning pro-

cess by only selecting measurable outcomes resulting in around one million gaze sam-

ples are being selected for eyetrackingR analysis.

The dependent variables such as fixation percentage mean and fixation density per

trial, task and participant are considered for evaluation of stated hypotheses. In this

research, the author also analyses the pupil diameter including this variable as a pre-

dictor of the logit and mixed-effects models. Taking into account the developed stock

price and the rationale behind the margin of safety principle, the author assigns the ac-

curacy factor to the each decision and uses it as another dependent variable to analyse the

hypothesis.

The R analysis tested six stated hypotheses derived from DFT and ATB models which

are widely discussed in previous publications: (1) fixation duration is stable over time;

(2) the gaze cascade mechanism supports the decision; (3) visual information impacts

the decision; (4) the AOI stock summary impacts the decision; (5) decision outcome

correlates with the deliberation time; (6) decision accuracy is decreasing under time

constraints. To deliver a thorough analysis, the author step-by-step expands the en-

quiry to find correlations between dependent and independent variables in order to ex-

plain the decision-making process.

First, the author begins with the summary of the data and descriptive statistics. Sec-

ond, the data are subjected to the simple t-test, regression, and linear modelling.

However, dealing with binary data, e.g. contrasting one AOI against others, the author

applies logistic regression to the research to convert the proportional scale of the

dependent variables to a logarithmic scale or logit transformed as well as to perform

the analysis on the transformed values in order to capture another level by aggregating

data by participants within trials. The author then examines if gazing at the specific AOI

under time conditions can be explained by the linear mixed-effects model. In this step

of multilevel modelling, the author is able to include random factors and estimate the

maximum likelihood of deviations from it. However, one step further attempted in the

analysis is to reveal the changes in dependent variables over time by performing the

growth curve analysis for each AOI, trial and participant duration gaze under time con-

ditions.

58

6.2 Findings and limitations

According to the research questions, this paper intends to analyse the information con-

tent and heuristics behind the decision-making process. The hypotheses derived from

DFT and ATB models are assessed in this paper. However, the thorough analysis indi-

cates a complexity of the stated hypotheses as a more sub-levelled examination of de-

pendent variables is discovered. The fixation duration is stable over time for the simple

homogeneous tasks. However, fixation duration links to the information content of the

AOIs, complexity of stimuli and is significantly impacted by time constraints. Within

trials, as more familiar information becomes evident, the fixation duration averages and

stays more stable. Moreover, fixation duration is idiosyncratic and therefore not stable

for each participant over time. The attention or gaze cascade affects the decision-

making process significantly under time constraints. The participants without time con-

straints have plenty of time to deliberate information content; therefore, they may con-

trast their decisions despite the attention bias because of negative or pessimistic in-

formation content. Moreover, the results do not support the assumption that visual in-

formation and the summary of stock quotes impact decision making under time con-

straints. However, it should be taken into account the nature of the processing of visual

information that requires fewer fixation durations in the stage of grasping the visuals.

However, it increases with focusing on key information obtained from the graph or

chart. Growth curve analysis demonstrates this effect. Time conditions do not signifi-

cantly impact the decision. The results reveal that even though participants spent more

time to gaze at a particular company stock, they finally decided to short-sell the stock

(despite the attention bias, and deliberation time). Finally, there are no distinct differ-

ences between gazing at the particular company to make a decision to buy or short-sell

this stock and accuracy of the decisions over time. To sum up, the outcomes indicate

that under the natural complexity of the provided financial information, the participants

rely on simple heuristics rather than accumulation information models in the decision-

making processes under time constraints. The content of the information impacts the

decision-making process of participants under both time conditions.

This work is a subject, similar to the other experimental analyses in the area of

behavioural economics and finance, of certain limitations such as the small sample

size of 20 participants who are students and cannot be considered as representatives

of the general population. Moreover, even though the author intends to mitigate meas-

urement precision and accuracy of the eye-tracking hardware and to increase synchro-

nization between stimulus presentation and eye movement recordings following the

recommendation of the experts, some errors may occur due to the author’s overlook

considering the 1.5 million data elements per participant. Moreover, the assumption

59 between attention and fixations is still a topic for ponderable argumentations according

to the recent literature. Therefore, considering the limitation mentioned above, possible

technical errors, and the assumption the results of the research indicate the tendency

of the decision-making process under certain experimental conditions and samples to

be in line and consistent with previous publications.

6.3 Importance and further research questions

To sum up, the eye tracking research in the area of decision making is crucial in order

to understand the investors’ behaviour and processes behind the decisions which con-

sequently facilitate the investors to make better investment decisions in the extremely

complex and complicated financial markets. Moreover, the stock offering companies

from all around the world strive to make improvements in data representation available

on their websites. The results of this research are a first attempt to demonstrate what

kind of information and data are more attentive in investment decisions under time

constraints.

A future research in this area perhaps will increase the understanding of investment

decision-making processes by conducting experiments involving different levels of in-

vestors according to their experience and knowledge, risk attitudes and even cultural

backgrounds. Moreover, the new techniques and a multiple-systems approach can be

added to the future research to delve deeper into the decision-making process. Finally,

the integration of these multidisciplinary approaches and methodologies helps to de-

velop more accurate models of decision-making in economics and finance.

60

7 REFERENCE LIST

Albert, D., K. M. Aschenbrenner and F. Schmalhofer (1989) Cognitive Choice Process-es and the Attitude-Behavior Relation. In: A. Upmeyer, ed., Attitudes and Behavioral Decisions, New York, USA: Springer, pp.61-99.

Amso, D., J. Markant, and S. Haas (2014) An Eye Tracking Investigation of Develop-mental Change in Bottom-up Attention Orienting to Faces in Cluttered Natural Scenes, PLOS ONE, 9(1), e85701.

Andrienko G. et al. (2012) Visual Analytics Methodology for Eye Movement Studies, IEEE Transactions on Visualization and Computer Graphics, 18 (12), pp.2889–2898.

Arieli, A., Y. Ben-Ami, and A. Rubinstein (2011) Tracking Decision Makers under Un-certainty, American Economic Journal, 3, pp.68-76.

Arieli, A., Y. Ben-Ami, and A. Rubinstein (2009) Fairness Motivations and Procedures of Choice between Lotteries as Revealed through Eye Movements, American Econom-ic Journal: Microeconomics, 3(4), pp.68-76.

Ariely, D. and D. Zakay (2001) A Timely Account of the Role of Duration in Decision Making, Acta Psychologica, 108, pp.181-207.

Aschenbrenner, K.M., D. Albert, and F. Schmalhofer (1984) Stochastic Choice Heuris-tics, Acta Psychologica, 56, pp.153—166.

Augier, M. (2001) Sublime Simon, Journal of Economic Psychology, 22 (3), pp.307-334.

Barr, D.J. (2008) Analyzing 'Visual World' Eyetracking Data Using Multilevel Logistic Regression, Journal of Memory and Language, 59(4), pp. 457-474.

BeGaze Manual V3.4: Manual (2014) SensoMotoric Instruments GmbH.

Bland A. and A. Schaefer (2012) Different Varieties of Uncertainty in Human Decision-Making. Frontiers in Neuroscience, 6(85), pp.1-11.

Blascheck, T. et al. (2014) State-of-the-Art of Visualization for Eye Tracking Data, Eu-roVis - STARs, pp.63–82.

Bockenholt, U. and K. Kroeger (1993) The Effects of Time Pressure in Multiattribute Binary Choice Tasks. In: O. Svenson and A.J. Maule, eds. Time Pressure and Stress in Human Judgment and Decision Making, New York: Plenum.

Brandstatter, E., C. Korner (2014) Attention in Risky Choice, Acta Psychologica (Amst), 152, pp.166-176.

Brandstätter, E., G. Gigerenzer, and R. Hertwig (2006) The Priority Heuristic: Making Choices Without Trade-offs, Psychological Review, 113, pp.409–432.

Busemeyer, J. R. (1985) Decision Making under Uncertainty: A Comparison of Simple Scalability, Fixed-Sample, and Sequential-Sampling Models, Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, & Cognition, 11, pp.538-564.

Busemeyer, J. R. and J. T. Townsend (1992) Fundamental Derivations from Decision Field Theory, Mathematical Social Sciences, 23, pp.255-282.

Busemeyer, J.R., J.T. Townsend (1993) Decision Field Theory: A Dynamic-Cognitive Approach to Decision Making in an Uncertain Environment, Psychological Review, 100, pp.432–459.

61 Calandro J. Jr (2011) The Margin of Safety Principle And Corporate Strategy, Strategy & Leadership, 39(5), pp.38-45.

Caplin, A., M. Dean, and D. Martin (2011) Search and Satisficing, The American Eco-nomic Review, 101, pp.2899-2922.

Chu, P. C. and E.E. Spires (1999) Cross-Cultural Differences in Choice Behavior and Use of Decision Aids: A Comparison of Japan and the United States, Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 77, pp.147–170.

Corbetta, M. et al. (1998) A Common Network of Functional Areas for Attention and Eye Movements, Neuron, 21, pp.761–773.

Cornell, E. D. et al. (2003) Errors of Binocular Fixation are Common in Normal Sub-

jects during Natural Conditions, Optometry and Vision Science, 80(11), pp.764– 771.

Curtis, G. (2004) Modern Portfolio Theory and Behavioral Finance, The Journal of Wealth Management, 7(2), pp.16-22.

De Bondt, W. F. M. and R. Thaler (1985) Does the Stock Market Overreact? The Jour-nal of Finance, 40(3), pp.793-805.

Dhar, R. and S. M. Nowlis (1999) The Effect of Time Pressure on Consumer Choice Deferral, Journal of Consumer Research, 25 (4), pp.369-384.

Diederich, A. (1995) A Dynamic Model for Multi-Attributive Decision Problems. In: J. P. Caverni, M. Bar-Hillel, F. H. Barron, and H. Jungermann, eds. Contributions to Deci-sion Making, Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp.175-191.

Diederich, A. (2003) MDFT Account of Decision Making under Time Pressure, Psycho-nomic Bulletin and Review, 10(1), pp.157–166.

Dink, J. W., and B.F. Ferguson (2015) eyetrackingR: An R Library for Eye-tracking Da-ta Analysis, Available from: <http://www.eyetrackingr.com> [Accessed 28 March, 2016].

Douglas H.W. (2016) Multialternative Choice Models. In: G. Keren, G. Wu, eds.The Wiley-Blackwell Handbook of Judgment and Decision Making, Malden, MA: Wiley-Blackwell, v.1, pp.117-140.

Dror, I. E., J. R. Busemeyer, and B. Basola (1999) Decision Making under Time Pres-sure: An Independent Test of Sequential Sampling Models, Memory & Cognition, 27(4), pp.713-725.

Duchowski A. T. et al. (2010) Scan Path Comparison Revisited, Proceedings of the 2010 Symposium on Eye Tracking Research & Applications, ETRA ’10, pp. 219–226.

Duchowski, A. T. (2002) A Breadth-First Survey of Eye Tracking Applications, Behavior Research Methods, Instruments, & Computers (BRMIC), 34(4), pp.455-470.

Duchowski, A. T. (2007) Eye Tracking Methodology: Theory and Practice, Secaucus, NJ, USA: Springer-Verlag New York, Inc.

Duclos, R. (2015) The Psychology of Investment Behavior: (De)biasing Financial Deci-sion-Making One Graph at a Time, Journal of Consumer Psychology, 25 (2), pp.317–325.

Eser, I. et al. (2008) Association between Ocular Dominance and Refraction, Journal of Refractive Surgery, 24(7), pp.685– 689.

62 Feiereisen, S., V. Wong, and A. J. Broderick (2008) Analogies and Mental Simulations in Learning for Really New Products: The Role of Visual Attention, The Journal of Product Innovation Management, 25, pp.593-607.

Fiedler, K. M. von Sydow (2015) Heuristics and Biases: Beyond Tversky and Kahne-man's (1974) Judgment under Uncertainty. In: M.W. Eysenck and D. Groome, Cogni-tive Psychology: Revising the Classical Studies, London: Sage.

Fiedler, S. and A. Glöckner (2012) The Dynamics of Decision Making in Risky Choice: An Eye-Tracking Analysis, Frontiers in Psychology, 3, 335, pp.1-18.

Finucane, M. L. et al. (2000) The Affect Heuristic in Judgments of Risks and Benefits, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 13, pp.1-17.

Franco-Watkins A. M. and J. G. Johnson (2011) Applying the Decision Moving Window to Risky Choice: Comparison of Eye-Tracking and Mouse-Tracing Methods Judgment and Decision Making, 6(8), pp.740–749.

Gamito, P.S. (2014) I See Me, You See Me: Inferring Cognitive and Emotional Pro-cesses from Gazing Behaviour, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Scholars Publishing.

Gigerenzer G, P.M. Todd, and the ABC Research Group (1999) Simple Heuristics that Make Us Smart, New York: Oxford University Press.

Gigerenzer G. and R. Selten, eds. (2001) Bounded Rationality: The Adaptive Toolbox, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp.297–317.

Gigerenzer, G. and D.G. Goldstein (1996) Reasoning the Fast and Frugal Way: Models of Bounded Rationality, Psychological Review, 103, pp.650–669.

Gigerenzer, G. and H. Brighton (2009) Homo Heuristicus: Why Biased Minds Make Better Inferences, Topics in Cognitive Science, 1, pp.107–143.

Gigerenzer, G. and W. Gaissmaier (2011) Heuristic Decision Making, Annual Review of Psychology, 62, pp.451-482.

Giordano, J., R. Benedikter, and N. Flores (2012) Neuroeconomics: An Emerging Field of Theory and Practice, Emerging Ideas, Finance and Economics, The European Business Review, 7, pp.45-47.

Glöckner, A. and A.-K. Herbold (2011) An Eye-Tracking Study on Information Pro-cessing in Risky Decisions: Evidence for Compensatory Strategies Based on Automat-ic Processes, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 24(1), pp.71–98.

Glöckner, A. and C. Witteman (2010) Beyond Dual-Process Models: A Categorization of Processes Underlying Intuitive Judgment and Decision Making, Thinking and Rea-soning, 16(1), pp.1-25.

Glöckner, A. and S.D. Hodges (2011) Parallel Constraint Satisfaction in Memory-Based Decisions, Experimental Psychology, 58, pp.180–195.

Godfroid, A. (2012) Eye Tracking. In: P.Robinson, ed. The Routledge Encyclopedia of Second Language Acquisition, New York, London: Routledge, pp.234-236.

Godwin, H. (2016) Analysing Eye-Tracking Data. University of Southampton, UK. Available from: <www.personal.soton.ac.uk/.../Analysing%20Eye-Tracking%20Data.pptx> [Accessed 15 March, 2016].

Goldberg, J. H., X.P. Kotval (1999) Computer Interface Evaluation Using Eye Move-ments: Methods and Constructs, International Journal Of Industrial Ergonomics, 24, pp.631–645.

63 Gould, N. and J. Zolna (2010) Eye Tracking and Web Usability: A Good Fit? A Look at the Science and Value Behind Eye Tracking Usability Studies, UX Magazine, 509. Available from: <https://uxmag.com/articles/eye-tracking-and-web-usability-a-good-fit> [Accessed 3 April, 2016].

Granka, L., M. Feusner, and L. Lorigo (2008) Eye Monitoring in Online Search. In: R. Hammoud, ed. Passive Eye Monitoring: Algorithms, Applications and Experiments, New York, NY: Springer, pp.283-304.

Granka, L.A. (2010) Media Imagery and Political Choice: How Visual Cues Influence the Citizen News Diet, Stanford, CA: Stanford University, 2011.

Hausmann, D. and D. Läge (2008) Sequential Evidence Accumulation in Decision Making: The Individual Desired Level of Confidence Can Explain the Extent of Infor-mation Acquisition, Judgment and Decision Making, 3 (3), pp.229-243.

Hayhoe, M.M. (2004) Advances in Relating Eye Movements and Cognition, INFANCY, 6(2), pp.267-274.

Herrington, J.D., J. Duncan and L.M. Capella (1995) Shopper Reactions to Perceived Time Pressure, International Journal of Retail & Distribution Management, 23 (12), pp.13-20.

Hess, E. and J. Polt (1960) Pupil Size as Related to Interest Value of Visual Stimuli, Science, 132 (3423), pp.349-350.

Holmqvist K. et al. (2011) Eye Tracking: A Comprehensive Guide to Methods and Measures, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Horsley M. et al. (2014) Current Trends in Eye Tracking Research, New York: Spring-

er.

Horstmann, N., A. Ahlgrimm and A. Glöckner (2009) How Distinct are Intuition and De-liberation? An Eye-Tracking Analysis of Instruction-Induced Decision Modes, Judgment and Decision Making, 4, pp.335–354.

Huang, Y.‐F. and F.‐Y. Kuo (2011) An Eye‐tracking Investigation of Internet Consum-ers' Decision Deliberateness, Internet Research, 21 (5), pp.541–561.

Huber, O. and U. Kunz (2007) Time Pressure in Risky Decision-Making: Effect on Risk Defusing, Psychology Science, 49 (4), pp.415-426.

Huettel et al. (2006) Neural Signatures of Economic Preferences for Risk and Ambigui-ty, Neuron, 49, pp.765–775.

Hunton, J. E. and R. A. McEwen (1997) An Assessment of the Relation between Ana-lysts’ Earnings Forecast Accuracy, Motivational Incentives and Cognitive Information Search Strategy, The Accounting Review, 72(4), pp.497-515.

Hüsser, A. and W. Wirt (2014) Do Investors Show an Attentional Bias Toward Past Performance? An Eye-Tracking Experiment on Visual Attention to Mutual Fund Disclo-sures in Simplified Fund Prospectuses, Journal of Financial Services Marketing 19, pp.169–185.

Janis, I. L. and L. Mann (1977) Decision Making: A Psychological Analysis of Conflict, Choice, and Commitment, New York: Free Press.

Janis, I.L. (1983) Short-Term Counselling: Guidelines Based on Recent Research, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

64 Johnson, E. J., M. Schulte-Mecklenbeck, and M. C. Willemsen (2008) Process Models Deserve Process Data: Comment on Brandstätter, Gigerenzer, and Hertwig (2006), Psychological Review, 115, pp.263–273.

Jolie, Angelina. Interview. 60 Minutes. CBS. WCBS, New York: 3 Feb. 2009. Televi-sion.

Just, M.A. and P.A. Carpenter (1980) A Theory of Reading: From Eye Fixations to Comprehension, Psychological Review, 87, pp.329-354.

Kahneman D., A. Tversky (1979) Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk, Econometrica, 47, pp.263–291.

Kahneman, D. (2012) Interview: Debunking the Myth of Intuition, SPIEGEL, 25 May, Available from: <http://www.spiegel.de/international/zeitgeist/interview-with-daniel-kahneman-on-the-pitfalls-of-intuition-and-memory-a-834407.html> [Accessed 21 March 2016].

Kahnemann, D., and J. Beatty (1966) Pupil Diameter and Load on Memory, Science, 23(154), pp.1583-1585.

Kerstholt, J.H. (1994) The Effect of Time Pressure on Decision Making Behavior in a Dynamic Task Environment, Acta Psychologica, 86, pp.89-104.

Khachatryan, H. and A. L. Rihn (2014) Eye-Tracking Methodology and Applications in Consumer Research, IFAS Extention, University of Florida.

Klein, G.A. (1993) A Recognition-Ruined Decision (RPD) Model of Rapid Decision Making. In: G.A. Klein, J. Orasanu, R. Calderwood, and C.E. Zsambak, eds. Decision Making in Action: Models and Methods, Norwood, NJ: Ablex, pp.138-147.

Kocher M.G. and M. Sutter (2006) Time is Money — Time Pressure, Incentives, and the Quality of Decision-Making, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 61(3), pp.375–392.

Kocher, M. G., J. Pahlke, and S. T. Trautmann (2013) Tempus Fugit: Time Pressure in Risky Decisions, Management Science, 59(10), pp.2380-2391.

Koller, M. et al. (2012) Broadening the Range of Applications of Eyetracking in Busi-ness Research, Anälise, 23(1), pp.71-77.

Komogortsev O.V. et al. (2010) Standardization of Automated Analyses of Oculomotor

Fixation and Saccadic Behaviors, IEEE Transactions on Biomedical Engineering, 57(11), pp.2635-2645

Kowler, E. A., B. Dosher, and E. Blaser (1995) The Role of Attention in the Program-ming of Saccades, Vision Research, 35, pp.1897–1916.

Krajbich, I. and A. Rangel (2011) Multialternative Drift-Diffusion Model Predicts the Re-lationship Between Visual Fixations and Choice in Value-Based Decisions, Proceed-ings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 108, pp.13852–13857.

Krajbich, I. et al. (2012) The Attentional Drift-Diffusion Model Extends to Simple Pur-chasing Decisions, Frontiers in Psychology, 3, pp.193.

Kumar, A., S. S. Lim (2006) How Do Decision Frames Influence the Stock Investment Choices of Individual Investors? Management Science, 54(6), pp.1052 – 1064.

65 Kumar, S. and N. Goyal (2015) Behavioural Biases in Investment Decision Making – a Systematic Literature Review, Qualitative Research in Financial Markets, 7(1), pp.88 – 108.

Kwak, Y. et al.(2015) The Rational Adolescent: Strategic Information Processing during Decision Making Revealed by Eye Tracking, Cognitive Development, 36, pp.20-30.

Lee, K. C. (2013) Exploring the Effect of the Human Brand on Consumers' Decision Quality in Online Shopping. An Eye-Tracking Approach, Online Information Review. 37(1), pp.83-100.

Liversedge, S. P. and J.M. Findlay (2000) Saccadic Eye Movements and Cognition, Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 4, pp.6–14.

Luce, R.D. (1956) Semiorders and a Theory of Utility Discrimination, Econometrica, 24, pp.178–191.

Maule, A. J. and A. C. Edland (2002) The Effect of Time Pressure on Human Judge-ment and Decision Making. In: ob Ranyard, W.Ray Crozier and Ola Svenson, eds. De-cision Making: Cognitive Models and Explanations, New York: The Taylor & Francis Group.

Maule, A.J., G.R. Hockey, and L. Bdzola (2000) Effects of Time-Pressure on Decision-Making under Uncertainty: Changes in Affective State and Information Processing Strategy, Acta Psychologica (Amst), 104(3), pp.283-301.

Mayer, M.E., K.T. Sonoda, and W.B. Gudykunst (1997) The Effect of Time Pressures and Type of Information on Decision Quality, Southern Communication Journal, 62, pp.280-292.

Meißner, M., A. Musalem, and J. C.Huber (2015) Eye-Tracking Reveals Processes that Enable Conjoint Choices to Become Increasingly Efficient with Practice, Journal of Marketing Research, 4.

Miller, G. A. and E. Galanter (1960) Some Comments on Stochastic Models and Psy-chological Theories. In: Kenneth J. Arrow, Samuel Karlin, Patrick Suppes (1959) Math-ematical Models in the Social Sciences: Proceedings of the First Stanford Symposium, Stanford Mathematical Studies in the Social Sciences, IV, Stanford, California: Stan-ford University Press, pp.277–297.

Mirman, D. (2014) Growth Curve Analysis and Visualization Using R, USA, Florida: Chapman & Hall/CRC.

Mirman, D., J.Dixon and J. S. Magnuson (2008) Statistical and Computational Models of the Visual World Paradigm: Growth Curves and Individual Differences, Journal of Memory and Language, 59, pp.474–494.

Naveed, M. et al. (2014) The Allusions of Behavioral Finance, Research Journal of Fi-nance and Accounting, 5(9), pp. 68-75.

Nursimulu, A. D. and P. Bossaerts (2014) Risk and Reward Preferences under Time Pressure, Review Of Finance, 18(3), pp.999-1022.

Odean, T. (1999) Do Investors Trade Too Much? American Economic Review, 89(5), pp.1279-1298.

Ordóñez, L., L. Benson III, A. Pittarello (2016) Time-Pressure Perception and Decision Making. In: Gideon Keren, George Wu, eds. The Wiley-Blackwell Handbook of Judg-ment and Decision Making, Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons, pp.517–542.

66 Ordóñezf, L. and L. Benson III (1997) Decisions under Time Pressure: How Time Con-straint Affects Risky Decision Making, Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 71 (2), pp.121–140.

Payne, J. W., J. R. Bettman, and E.J. Johnson (1988) Adaptive Strategy Selection in Decision-Making, Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cogni-tion, 14, pp.534–552.

Payne, J.W., J.R. Bettman, and E.J. Johnson (1993) The Adaptive Decision Maker, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Payne, J.W., J.R. Bettman, and M.F. Luce (1996) When Time is Money: Decision Be-havior under Opportunity-Cost Time Pressure, Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 66, pp.131–152.

Pernice, K. and J. Nielsen (2015) How to Conduct Eyetracking Studies Nielsen Nor-man Group. Available from: <https://www.nngroup.com/reports/how-to-conduct-eyetracking-studies/>[Accessed 20 December, 2015].

Pieters, R. and L. Warlop (1999) Visual Attention During Brand Choice: The Impact of Time Pressure and Task Motivation, International Journal of Research in Marketing, 16, pp.1-16.

Pieters, R. and M. Wedel (2004) Attention Capture and Transfer in Advertising: Brand, Pictorial, and Text-Size Effects, Journal of Marketing, 68 (2), pp.36-50.

Pieters, R., L. Warlop, M. Wedel (2002) Breaking through the Clutter: Benefits of Ad-vertisement Originality and Familiarity for Brand Attention and Memory, Management Science, 48 (6), pp.765-781.

Pop, N. A., A.M. Iorga, and C. Pelau (2013) Using Neuromarketing Studies to Explore Emotional Intelligence as a Key to the Buying Decision Process, Proceedings of the European Conference on Knowledge Management, 1(1), pp.29-37.

Preuschoff, K., P. N.C. Mohr, and M. Hsu (2013) Decision Making under Uncertainty, Frontiers in Neuroscience, 7(218), p.4-5.

Purves, D., G.J. Augustine, and D. Fitzpatrick. eds. Neuroscience, 2nd ed., Sunder-land, MA: Sinauer Associates.

Rayner, K. (1998) Eye Movements in Reading and Information Processing: 20 years of Research, Psychological Bulletin, 124, pp.372–422.

Rayner, K. (2009) Eye Movements and Attention in Reading, Scene Perception, and Visual Search, Quarterly Journal of Experimental Psychology, 62, pp.1457–1506.

Rayner, K. et al. (2012) The Psychology of Reading, 2nd ed., New York: Psychology

Press.

Reutskaja, E. et al. (2011) Search Dynamics in Consumer Choice under Time Pres-sure: An Eye-Tracking Study, American Economic Review, 101, pp.900–926.

Richardson, A., S. Gregor, and R. Heaney (2012) Using Decision Support to Manage the Influence of Cognitive Abilities on Share Trading Performance, Australian Journal Of Management, 37(3), pp.523-541.

Ro, S. (2012) Stock Market Investors Have Become Absurdly Impatient, Business In-sider, Available from <http://www.businessinsider.com/stock-investor-holding-period-2012-8?IR=T> [Accessed 4 April 2016].

67 Rubaltelli E., S. Agnoli, L. Franchin (2016) Sensitivity to Affective Information and In-vestors’ Evaluation of Past Performance: An Eye-Tracking Study, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 29, pp. 295-306.

Schulte-Mecklenbeck, M., R. O. Murphy, and Florian Hutzler (2011) Flashlight – Re-cording information acquisition online, Computers in Human Behavior, 27, pp.1771–1782.

Shavit, T. et al. (2010) Using an Eye Tracker to Examine Behavioral Biases in Invest-ment Tasks: An Experimental Study, The Journal of Behavioral Finance, 11, pp.185-194.

Shinsuke Shimojo et al. (2003) Gaze Bias Both Reflects and Influences Preference,

Nature Neuroscience 6, pp.1317 – 1322.

Simon, H.A. (1983) Reason in human affairs, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

Simon, H.A. (1990) Invariants of Human Behavior, Annual Review of Psychology, 41, p.1-19.

Simons, H. (1955) A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice, Quarterly Journal of Eco-nomics, 69, pp.99–188.

Stewart, N., F. Hermens, and W. J. Matthews (2016) Eye Movements in Risky Choice, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 29(2-3), pp. 116–136.

Su, Y. et al. (2013) Is Making a Risky Choice Based on a Weighting and Adding Pro-cess? An Eye-Tracking Investigation, Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 39, pp.1765–1780.

Sullivan, B.T. et al. (2012) The Role of Uncertainty and Reward on Eye Movements In

a Virtual Driving Task, Journal of Vision, 12(13), pp. 19.

Svenson, O. and L. Benson III (1993) Framing and Time Pressure in Decision Making. In: Time Pressure and Stress in Human Judgment and Decision Making, New York, NY: Plenum Press, pp.133-144.

Svenson, O., A. Edland, and P. Slovic (1990) Choices and Judgments of Incompletely Described Decision Alternatives under Time Pressure, Acta Psychologica, 75, pp.153-169.

Towal, R.B., M. Mormann, and C. Koch (2013) Simultaneous Modeling of Visual Sali-ency and Value Computation Improves Predictions of Economic Choice, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 110(40), pp.1-14.

Tversky, A. and D. Kahneman (1974) Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Bi-ases, Science, 185 (4157), pp.1124-1131.

Tversky, A. and D. Kahneman (1992) Advances in Prospect Theory: Cumulative Rep-resentation of Uncertainty, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, pp.297–323.

Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman (1981) The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice, American Association for the Advancement of Science, 211 (4481), pp.453-458.

Usher, M. and J.L. McClelland (2004) Loss Aversion and Inhibition in Dynamical Mod-els of Multialternative Choice, Psychological Review, 111, pp.757–769.

van Gompel R. et al., eds. (2007) Eye Movements: a Window on Mind and Brain, Am-

sterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.

68 Velichkovsky, B., A. Sprenger, and D. Unema (1997) Towards Gaze Mediated Interac-tion: Collecting Solutions of the "Midas Touch Problem", London: Chapman & Hall.

Venkatraman, V., J. W. Payne, S. A. Huettel (2014) An Overall Probability of Winning Heuristic for Complex Risky Decisions: Choice and Eye Fixation Evidence, Organiza-tional Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 125, pp.73–87.

Verplanken, B. (1993) Need for Cognition and External Information Search: Responses to Time Pressure during Decision-Making, Journal of Research in Personality, 27 (3), pp.238–252.

Viviani, P. (1990) Chapter 8. In: Kowler, E., ed. Eye Movements and Their Role in Vis-ual and Cognitive Processes, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.

Wallsten, T. S. and Barton, C. (1982) Processing Probabilistic Multidimensional Infor-mation for Decisions, Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory & Cogni-tion, 8, pp.361-384.

Wang, J. (2011) Pupil Dilation and Eye Tracking. In: M. Schulte-Mecklenbeck, A. Kuehberger, R. Ranyard, eds. A Handbook of Process Tracing Methods for Decision Research: A Critical Review and User’s Guide, New York, NY: Psychology Press, pp. 185-208.

Wästlund, E. et al. (2010) Consumer Perception at Point of Purchase: Evaluating Pro-

posed Package Designs in an Eye-Tracking lab, Journal of Business and Retail Man-agement Research, 5(1), pp.41–50.

Weenig, M.W. and M. Maarleveld (2002) The Impact of Time Constraint on Information Search Strategies in Complex Choice Tasks, Journal of Economic Psychology, 23(6), pp.689-702.

Wegier, P. and J. Spaniol (2015) The Effect of Time Pressure on Risky Financial Deci-sions from Description and Decisions from Experience, PLOS ONE, 10(4).

Yang, Y. and C.-C. Wang (2015) Trend of Using Eye Tracking Technology in Business Research, Journal of Economics, Business and Management, 3 (4), pp.447-451.

Yarbus, A. L. (1967. Eye Movements and Vision, New York: Plenum Press.

Young, D. L. et al. (2012) Decision Making under Time Pressure, Modelled in a Pro-spect Theory Framework, Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 118(2), pp.179–188.

Zakay, D. (1993) The Impact of Time Perception Processes on Decision Making under Time-stress. In: O. Svenson and A.J. Maule, eds. Time Pressure and Stress in Human Judgment and Decision Making, New York: Plenum Press, pp.59-72.

Zülch, G. and S. Stowasser (1999) Einsatz Der Blickregistrierung Zur Gestaltung Von Prüfarbeitsplätzen in Der Bekleidungsindustrie. Zeitschrift für Arbeitswissenschaft, 53 (25), pp.2-9.

Zülch, G. and S. Stowasser (2001) Usability Evaluation of Universal Interfaces with the Computer-Aided Evaluation Tool PROKUS. In: Universal Access in HCI: Towards an Information Society for All. Hrsg.: STEPHANIDIS, Constantine. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Publishers, pp.645-649.

Zur, H. B. and S. J. Breznitz (1981) The Effect of Time Pressure on Risky Choice Be-haviour, Acta Psychologica, 47 (2), pp.89-104.

69

ANNEX

Appendix A

Figure A.1: Example of the stimulus provided in the experiment

Figure A.2: Growth curve analysis of gazing over time at the AOIs

AOI stock

AOI visuals

AOI company

AOI ratios

70

Appendix B Table B.1: Loss of eye tracking data per participant (%)

Participant Trackloss (%)

p02 0.16

p03 0.15

p04 0.12

p05 0.17

p06 0.16

p07 0.17

p08 0.13

p10 0.13

p11 0.12

p12 0.22

p13 0.16

p14 0.14

p15 0.17

p16 0.14

p17 0.19

p18 0.16

p19 0.23

p20 0.17

Mean 0.84

SD 0.03

The eye tracking data of two additional participants were removed to follow 25% tracking loss threshold.

Table B.2: Summary statistic of raw data adjusted for the R software analysis

Participant Decision Accuracy Gender TrialNum Trials TimeFromTrialOnset

p04 :116338 Buy :625163 Min. :0.0000 F:542781 Min. : 1.00 dEKPage1: 61043 Min. : 0

p03 :109904 Sell:460596 1st Qu.:0.0000 M:542978 1st Qu.: 7.00 dKrPage1: 56530 1st Qu.: 4208

p08 : 93110 Median :0.0000 Median :14.00 dKrPage5: 55628 Median : 9904

p06 : 78460 Mean :0.4763 Mean :14.34 l3IPage1: 54795 Mean : 14041

p14 : 76078 3rd Qu.:1.0000 3rd Qu.:21.00 nAmPage1: 53003 3rd Qu.: 19192

p11 : 75733 Max. :1.0000 Max. :30.00 lFPPage2: 51946 Max. :116616

(Other):536136 (Other) :752814

TimeFromParticipantOnset AOIGroup AOI.stock AOI.visuals AOI.company AOI.ratios

Min. : 0 White Space:288496 Mode :logical Mode :logical Mode :logical Mode :logical

1st Qu.:108568 ratios :213251 FALSE:639644 FALSE:627881 FALSE:651986 FALSE:575754

Median :227864 visuals :160718 TRUE :147240 TRUE :159003 TRUE :134898 TRUE :211130

Mean :278488 stock :148886 NA's :298875 NA's :298875 NA's :298875 NA's :298875

3rd Qu.:410400 company :135864

Max. :930696 other :135812

(Other) : 2732

AOI.other Condition Opinion Category Trackloss Index PupilDiameter

Mode :logical Min. :1.000 DB :445179 Blink :126672 Mode :logical Min. : 0.00 Min. :0.00

FALSE:652271 1st Qu.:1.000 LSE :284085 Fixation:848218 FALSE:786884 1st Qu.: 9.00 1st Qu.:3.13

TRUE :134613 Median :3.000 NASDAQ:356495 Saccade : 80525 TRUE :298875 Median : 27.00 Median :3.48

NA's :298875 Mean :2.103 NA's : 30344 NA's :0 Mean : 38.61 Mean :3.10

3rd Qu.:3.000 3rd Qu.: 54.00 3rd Qu.:3.71

Max. :3.000 Max. :340.00 Max. :6.98

71

Table B.3: Summary statistics for the numerical variables

Mean SD Variance

Accuracy (between 0 and 1) 0.50 0.48 0.25

TrialNumber 14.34 8.49 72.02

TimeFromTrialOnset (ms) 14041.45 14654.66 214759040

TimeFromParticipantOnset (ms) 278487.50 212192.50 45025645671

PupilDiameter (mm) 1.22 3.10 1.50

Table B.4: Example of descriptive data for each AOI of the AD stock

Target.ad Condition Mean SD Var Min Max N NumTrials

(fctr) (int) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (int) (int)

1 AD 1 0.18922840 0.3916988 0.15342797 0 1 25586 5

2 AD 3 0.02892717 0.1676050 0.02809145 0 1 30326 4

3 Otherc 1 0.18098851 0.3850100 0.14823270 0 1 169418 18

4 Otherc 3 0.16175130 0.3682236 0.13558860 0 1 204099 20

Target.ad Condition Mean SD Var Min Max N NumTrials

(fctr) (int) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (int) (int)

1 AD 1 0.2974884 0.4571636 0.2089985 0 1 25586 5

2 AD 3 0.2413106 0.4278863 0.1830867 0 1 30326 4

3 Otherc 1 0.1630616 0.3694232 0.1364735 0 1 169418 18

4 Otherc 3 0.1752793 0.3802069 0.1445573 0 1 204099 20

Target.ad Condition Mean SD Var Min Max N NumTrials

(fctr) (int) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (int) (int)

1 AD 1 0.1924018 0.3941959 0.1553904 0 1 25586 5

2 AD 3 0.2680936 0.4429749 0.1962268 0 1 30326 4

3 Otherc 1 0.2795828 0.4487958 0.2014177 0 1 169418 18

4 Otherc 3 0.2152614 0.4110048 0.1689249 0 1 204099 20

Target.ad Condition Mean SD Var Min Max N NumTrials

(fctr) (int) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (int) (int)

1 AD 1 0.3208813 0.4668259 0.2179264 0 1 25586 5

2 AD 3 0.4616687 0.4985379 0.2485401 0 1 30326 4

3 Otherc 1 0.3763671 0.4844755 0.2347165 0 1 169418 18

4 Otherc 3 0.4477080 0.4972595 0.2472670 0 1 204099 20

Table B.5: Example of descriptive statistics of aggregating data with three target conditions: a company, accuracy of decision and time condition Target.kr Accuracy Condition Mean SD Var Min Max N NumTrials

(fctr) (int) (int) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (int) (int)

1 Kr 0 1 11549.462 7510.999 56415103 0 30000 21443 3

2 Kr 0 3 21182.228 15886.446 252379161 0 63152 21680 3

3 Kr 1 1 13508.303 8547.276 73055930 0 30000 24522 3

4 Kr 1 3 11718.390 7856.116 61718557 0 33584 16161 4

5 Otherc 0 1 10777.738 8186.546 67019531 0 30000 71666 17

6 Otherc 0 3 24431.725 23596.779 556807959 0 114944 91342 11

7 Otherc 1 1 9547.759 7673.486 58882394 0 30000 77373 17

8 Otherc 1 3 20544.610 15861.510 251587488 0 62272 105242 16

Table B.6: Examples of paired t-test between conditions with the predictor, pupil diameter, for AOI.stock Target.t Mean SD Var Min Max N NumTrials

(fctr) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (dbl) (int) (int)

1 limit 0.2664829 0.5291146 0.2799623 0 1.570796 4638 23

2 time 0.2052875 0.4766350 0.2271809 0 1.570796 3855 24

72

Welch Two Sample t-test

data: ArcSin by Target.t

t = 5.4032, df = 7847.7, p-value = 6.737e-08

alternative hypothesis: true difference in means is not equal to 0

95 percent confidence interval:

0.03899405 0.08339670

sample estimates:

mean in group limit mean in group time

0.2664829 0.2052875

term estimate std.error statistic p.value

1 (Intercept) 0.28572233 0.008160435 35.013125 8.630548e-250

2 Target.ttime -0.09702919 0.011929690 -8.133421 4.810016e-16

3 PupilDiameterC -0.06489075 0.009485137 -6.841309 8.433390e-12

4 Target.ttime:PupilDiameterC -0.01723911 0.014798998 -1.164883 2.441014e-01

Welch Two Sample t-test

data: ArcSin by Target.ek

t = 5.2436, df = 2863.5, p-value = 1.689e-07

alternative hypothesis: true difference in means is not equal to 0

95 percent confidence interval:

0.05267783 0.11560521

sample estimates:

mean in group EK mean in group Otherc

0.3587714 0.2746299

term estimate std.error statistic p.value

1 (Intercept) 0.283858093 0.01187340 23.9070589 4.225964e-118

2 Target.ekOtherc 0.005866971 0.01500058 0.3911164 6.957322e-01

3 PupilDiameterC 0.100034269 0.01274910 7.8463805 5.469226e-15

4 ConditionC 0.072804366 0.01170475 6.2200726 5.485125e-10

5 Target.ekOtherc:PupilDiameterC -0.205524098 0.01695341 -12.1228798 3.081747e-33

6 Target.ekOtherc:ConditionC -0.210829745 0.01491142 -14.1388071 2.582063e-44

7 PupilDiameterC:ConditionC -0.200595306 0.01258430 -15.9401267 1.721437e-55

8 Target.ekOtherc:PupilDiameterC:ConditionC 0.326966457 0.01689430 19.3536561 8.332160e-80

Table B.7: Example of fitting the data to mixed-effects models for the AOIs.

Model:AOI.stock

Elog ~ TargetC * PupilDiameterC + (1 + TargetC | Participant) +

(1 | Trials)

Df AIC LRT Pr(Chi)

<none> 54798

TargetC 1 54796 0.247 0.6193

PupilDiameterC 1 55029 232.512 < 2.2e-16 ***

TargetC:PupilDiameterC 1 54837 41.020 1.507e-10 ***

---

Signif. codes: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05 ‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1

Model:AOI.visuals

Elog ~ TargetC * PupilDiameterC + (1 + TargetC | Participant) +

(1 | Trials)

Df AIC LRT Pr(Chi)

<none> 56712

TargetC 1 56711 0.268 0.6047

PupilDiameterC 1 56925 214.331 <2e-16 ***

73 TargetC:PupilDiameterC 1 56710 0.023 0.8800

---

Signif. codes: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05 ‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1

Model:AOI.company

Elog ~ TargetC * PupilDiameterC + (1 + TargetC | Participant) +

(1 | Trials)

Df AIC LRT Pr(Chi)

<none> 56158

TargetC 1 56161 5.36 0.02064 *

PupilDiameterC 1 56478 321.55 < 2e-16 ***

TargetC:PupilDiameterC 1 56157 0.69 0.40464

---

Signif. codes: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05 ‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1

Model:AOI.ratios

Elog ~ TargetC * PupilDiameterC + (1 + TargetC | Participant) +

(1 | Trials)

Df AIC LRT Pr(Chi)

<none> 55831

TargetC 1 55829 0.198 0.6561267

PupilDiameterC 1 55910 81.542 < 2.2e-16 ***

TargetC:PupilDiameterC 1 55843 14.494 0.0001406 ***

---

Signif. codes: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05 ‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1

Table B.8: Example of growth curve analysis in R. (1) AOI stock

term estimate std.error statistic

1 (Intercept) 133.4448 25.75525 5.181265

2 TargetC 297.8906 56.64898 5.258534

3 ot1 5650.3265 1077.04105 5.246157

4 ot2 3561.4743 680.94226 5.230215

5 ot3 1283.1601 247.16730 5.191464

6 ot4 211.8076 41.31009 5.127260

7 TargetC:ot1 12447.4293 2369.22041 5.253808

8 TargetC:ot2 7835.4326 1497.90220 5.230937

9 TargetC:ot3 2814.0608 543.70173 5.175744

10 TargetC:ot4 462.0614 90.86856 5.084943

Model:

Elog ~ TargetC * (ot1 + ot2 + ot3 + ot4) + (1 | Participant) +

(1 | Trials)

Df AIC LRT Pr(Chi)

<none> 124273

TargetC 1 124298 27.641 1.461e-07 ***

ot1 1 124298 27.511 1.562e-07 ***

ot2 1 124298 27.344 1.703e-07 ***

ot3 1 124298 26.941 2.098e-07 ***

ot4 1 124297 26.279 2.955e-07 ***

TargetC:ot1 1 124298 27.591 1.499e-07 ***

TargetC:ot2 1 124298 27.352 1.696e-07 ***

TargetC:ot3 1 124297 26.778 2.282e-07 ***

TargetC:ot4 1 124297 25.847 3.696e-07 ***

---

Signif. codes: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05 ‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1

(2) AOI visuals

term estimate std.error statistic

1 (Intercept) -28.93364 27.86663 -1.0382898

74 2 TargetC -61.12665 61.29117 -0.9973159

3 ot1 -1124.62527 1165.30104 -0.9650942

4 ot2 -664.87458 736.74304 -0.9024511

5 ot3 -212.62616 267.42164 -0.7950971

6 ot4 -23.14054 44.69525 -0.5177403

7 TargetC:ot1 -2477.07977 2563.37024 -0.9663371

8 TargetC:ot2 -1448.95815 1620.64992 -0.8940599

9 TargetC:ot3 -451.51612 588.25587 -0.7675506

10 TargetC:ot4 -56.39763 98.31481 -0.5736432

Model:

Elog ~ TargetC * (ot1 + ot2 + ot3 + ot4) + (1 | Participant) +

(1 | Trials)

Df AIC LRT Pr(Chi)

<none> 129703

TargetC 1 129702 0.99461 0.3186

ot1 1 129701 0.93138 0.3345

ot2 1 129701 0.81440 0.3668

ot3 1 129701 0.63216 0.4266

ot4 1 129701 0.26805 0.6046

TargetC:ot1 1 129701 0.93378 0.3339

TargetC:ot2 1 129701 0.79932 0.3713

TargetC:ot3 1 129701 0.58912 0.4428

TargetC:ot4 1 129701 0.32906 0.5662

(3) AOI company

term estimate std.error statistic

1 (Intercept) 2.258072 26.03137 0.08674425

2 TargetC 8.113472 57.26241 0.14168933

3 ot1 154.478185 1089.06712 0.14184450

4 ot2 101.460563 689.14658 0.14722639

5 ot3 44.568766 250.46285 0.17794561

6 ot4 14.262627 42.12678 0.33856439

7 TargetC:ot1 339.826769 2395.80336 0.14184251

8 TargetC:ot2 216.368812 1515.74019 0.14274795

9 TargetC:ot3 84.787130 550.60077 0.15399021

10 TargetC:ot4 14.653497 92.24302 0.15885752

Model:

Elog ~ TargetC * (ot1 + ot2 + ot3 + ot4) + (1 + ot1 + ot2 + ot3 +

ot4 | Trials) + (1 + ot1 + ot2 + ot3 + ot4 | Participant)

Df AIC LRT Pr(Chi)

<none> 124235

TargetC 1 124219 -13.1727 1.0000

ot1 1 124229 -3.5894 1.0000

ot2 1 124235 1.9977 0.1575

ot3 1 124210 -23.0749 1.0000

ot4 1 124227 -6.1084 1.0000

TargetC:ot1 1 124223 -9.9579 1.0000

TargetC:ot2 1 124230 -2.8079 1.0000

TargetC:ot3 1 124230 -2.6898 1.0000

TargetC:ot4 1 124222 -10.1668 1.0000

(4) AOI ratios

term estimate std.error statistic

1 (Intercept) 82.62818 17.01007 4.857603

2 TargetC 183.96892 37.40838 4.917853

3 ot1 3511.90221 711.47901 4.936059

4 ot2 2237.11599 450.22397 4.968896

5 ot3 830.21644 163.60920 5.074387

75 6 ot4 146.37337 27.42502 5.337219

7 TargetC:ot1 7704.08558 1565.07121 4.922514

8 TargetC:ot2 4877.22898 990.16645 4.925666

9 TargetC:ot3 1763.48251 359.72209 4.902347

10 TargetC:ot4 286.58147 60.20393 4.760179

Model:

Elog ~ TargetC * (ot1 + ot2 + ot3 + ot4) + (1 + ot1 + ot2 + ot3 +

ot4 | Trials) + (1 + ot1 + ot2 + ot3 + ot4 | Participant)

Df AIC LRT Pr(Chi)

<none> 95180

TargetC 1 95208 29.610 5.284e-08 ***

ot1 1 95200 21.481 3.574e-06 ***

ot2 1 95198 19.107 1.236e-05 ***

ot3 1 95176 -2.895 1.00000

ot4 1 95201 22.461 2.145e-06 ***

TargetC:ot1 1 95207 28.195 1.097e-07 ***

TargetC:ot2 1 95210 31.982 1.556e-08 ***

TargetC:ot3 1 95183 4.268 0.03884 *

TargetC:ot4 1 95211 33.053 8.966e-09 ***

---

Signif. codes: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05 ‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1