53
JOBS WORKING PAPER Issue No. 56 Promoting Female Labor Force Participation Svetlana Pimkina and Luciana de la Flor

Promoting Female Labor Force Participation

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

JOBS WORKING

PAPERIssue No. 56

Promoting Female Labor Force Participation

Svetlana Pimkina and Luciana de la Flor

1

PROMOTING FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

Svetlana Pimkina and Luciana de la Flor

The publication of this report has been made possible through a grant from the Gender Group and

the World Bank’s Jobs Umbrella Trust Fund, which is supported by the Department for International

Development/UK AID, and the Governments of Norway, Germany, Italy, Austria, the Austrian

Development Agency, and the Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency.

_________________________________________________________________________________

2

© 2020 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank.

1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA.

Telephone: 202-473-1000; Internet: www.worldbank.org.

Some rights reserved

This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. The fi ndings,

interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily refl ect the views of The World

Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee

the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information

shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal

status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.

Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges and

immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved.

Rights and Permissions

This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 IGO license (CC BY 3.0 IGO)

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/igo. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are

free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the following

conditions:

Attribution—Please cite the work as follows: Svetlana Pimkina and Luciana de la Flor. 2020. “Female Labor

Force Participation Review Note.” World Bank, Washington, DC.

Translations—If you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the

attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should not be considered an official World

Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for any content or error in this translation.

Adaptations—If you create an adaptation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the

attribution: This is an adaptation of an original work by The World Bank. Views and opinions expressed in the

adaptation are the sole responsibility of the author or authors of the adaptation and are not endorsed by The

World Bank.

Third-party content—The World Bank does not necessarily own each component of the content contained

within the work.The World Bank therefore does not warrant that the use of any third-party-owned individual

component or part contained in the work will not infringe on the rights of those third parties. The risk of claims

resulting from such infringement rests solely with you. If you wish to re-use a component of the work, it is

your responsibility to determine whether permission is needed for that re-use and to obtain permission from

the copyright owner. Examples of components can include, but are not limited to, tables, figures, or images.

All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to World Bank Publications, The World Bank Group,

1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2625; e-mail: [email protected].

Images: © World Bank. Further permission required for reuse.

3

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

This report was prepared by the World Bank Group’s (WBG) Jobs Group. The principal authors are

Svetlana Pimkina and Luciana de la Flor. Eliana Carranza was Task Team Leader. The team thanks

Beth Zikronah Rosen, Nivedhitha Subramanian for their contribution to the first version of the

report. We also thank Isis Gaddis and Amparo Palacios-Lopez for inputs provided. The report was

prepared under the general direction and ongoing support of David Robalino, Alvaro Gonzales,

Jennifer N. Jossell, Sonia Madhvani, Fareeba Mahmood, and Siv Tokle.

The publication of this report has been made possible through a grant from the Gender Group and

the World Bank’s Jobs Umbrella Trust Fund, which is supported by the Department for International

Development/UK AID, and the Governments of Norway, Germany, Austria, the Austrian

Development Agency, and the Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency.

4

CONTENTS

PROMOTING FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION .....................................................................1

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ................................................................................................................ 3

CONTENTS ................................................................................................................................... 4

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ................................................................................................................. 5

INTRODUCTION ........................................................................................................................... 7

DRIVERS OF FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION .................................................................... 10

1. ENDOWNMENTS...................................................................................................................... 11

1.1. TIME ............................................................................................................................................. 11

1.2. SKILLS & EDUCATION ....................................................................................................................... 17

1.3. FINANCIAL ASSETS ........................................................................................................................... 20

1.4. NETWORKS & SOCIAL CAPITAL .......................................................................................................... 22

2. INTERNAL CONSTRAINTS ........................................................................................................... 23

2.1. PERCEPTIONS OF OPPORTUNITIES ....................................................................................................... 23

2.2. ASPIRATIONS & SELF-CONFIDENCE ..................................................................................................... 24

2.3. RESERVATION WAGES ...................................................................................................................... 25

2.4. NORMS ......................................................................................................................................... 26

3. EXTERNAL CONSTRAINTS ........................................................................................................... 29

3.1. INCOME SHOCKS ............................................................................................................................. 30

3.2. LABOR DEMAND ............................................................................................................................. 31

POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS & AREAS FOR FURTHER RESEARCH ................................................ 34

REFERENCES .............................................................................................................................. 38

5

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Women comprise half of the world’s adults, and therefore potentially half of its labor force. Their

participation in the labor force is essential to achieving gender equality, sustainable economic

growth, and household welfare. Yet, in nearly every country, women’s labor force participation is

significantly lower than men’s (International Labour Organization, 2019). While the available

literature generally focuses on female employment (women who are employed), this paper centers

on female labor force participation (FLFP, women who are either employed or looking for

employment). The distinction is key, in that women’s decision of whether to work is distinct from the

equilibrium outcome of whether they successfully find employment. The former represents the

potential supply of women’s labor able to meet firm labor demand for production, and thus

contribute to GDP.

This paper explores the specific constraints women face to entering and remaining in the labor

force, and how they can be effectively addressed by policymakers. We classify these barriers around

the key drivers of female labor force participation. First, we examine how constraints in

endowments such as time, education, financial and social capital limit women’s participation in the

labor force. Women’s time is split between paid labor, leisure, and domestic production (unpaid

labor) including housework, childcare, and elderly care responsibilities. These multiple claims on

women’s time, prevent many women from participating in the labor force. Notably, women with

children may require or value more flexible work schedules, which is more likely to be found in the

informal economy. In order to alleviate the constraint created by women’s unpaid domestic work, a

wide range of approaches is recommended, from legal access to family planning services, to access

to care and support for informal caregivers.

In addition, women do not always have the relevant skills and work experience for all jobs, and, even

when they do, they may lack a way to signal their qualifications to potential employers. Job training

programs are common policy intervention to address these constraints, but the empirical success of

these programs is mixed and heavily context-dependent. Successful experiences are often driven by

training in soft skills, such as self-esteem and communication. Another way that women can signal

their value to potential employers is through referrals. Yet, the literature indicates that women are

less likely to be referred through their network. Finally, women often lack access to finance,

including bank accounts and savings products. Financial inclusion and access to savings and credit

products can improve women’s incentives to work, and therefore their labor force participation, by

giving women power to make consumption and savings decisions over any potential earnings.

Second, after summing up constraints in endowments, we review evidence on the role of

preferences, aspirations, norms and beliefs of the labor market on FLFP as internal factors.

Perception of the labor market and of the work environment as well as beliefs about the self in

relation to the labor market may influence women’s decision to participate. Research suggests that

women are more likely to underestimate their skills and are less confident in their ability to obtain a

job, which constraints their participation in the labor market. Boosting women generalized self-

efficacy, or the belief in own ability to attain desired outcomes, increases the likelihood of women

enrolling in a program that offers work opportunities, as well as probability of having employment

In addition, social norms dictating what is and is not expected of women in society can also create

significant barriers to women’s participation in the labor market, starting with the development of

6

their aspirations as girls. The high prevalence of violence and harassment of women is also

intertwined with these social norms and can create impediments to women’s labor force

participation through mobility constraints. If a woman is unable to safely commute to work, due to

gender norms or safety concerns, she is theoretically less likely to participate in the labor force.

Examining potential connections between safe transit and women’s labor force participation and

employment is a growing area of research and policy intervention.

Third, we discuss how external constraints such as income shocks and demand-side factors inhibit

active engagement in the labor market. Low demand for female labor force participation is a direct

constraint. The empirical literature studying changes in demand for female labor through trade

liberalization and growth in specific sectors find that increases in demand for female labor are

associated with increase in female labor force participation. Similarly, targeted government

programs that guarantee jobs for women (e.g. in the form of quotas) are sought to increase FLFP.

However, the question of whether such quotas are desirable from a more general economic

perspective, such as in terms of productivity impacts, remains unanswered. One clear point

emerging from the literature, though, is the major potential barrier represented by discriminatory

hiring practices. While the evidence for this in developing countries is thin, studies have documented

bias in hiring practices in other contexts, suggesting the benefits of gender-blind hiring practices.

Government interventions from the demand-side focus on establishing equal employment

opportunity between men and women. But the direction of the impact will depend on the details of

the policies, as they may end up disincentivizing female hiring.

By exploring the constraints that inhibit female labor force participation, we can find evidence-

based, actionable policies to promote economic opportunities and shared prosperity for all. As this

paper discusses, there are several recommended pathways to boosting women’s labor force

participation, such as providing affordable, accessible, and high-quality childcare services that does

not create additional costs for employers. Yet, most of the policies and programs under

consideration have shown mixed results or require additional research. Specifically, though there is

more research on women’s employment, the overall literature on female labor force participation is

thin. By continuing to invest in this research agenda, we can better understand women’s decision of

whether to work and enable them to make a choice that benefits themselves, their households, and

their economies.

7

INTRODUCTION

Women comprise half of the world’s adults, and therefore potentially half of its labor force. Their

participation in the labor force is essential. Removing barriers that restrict women from entering the

labor market is a crucial part of the Sustainable Development Agenda, which seeks that all human

beings develop their full potential (UN SDG). This by itself is enough of a reason to mobilize

resources towards achieving equality. However, increasing female labor force participation also

matters from an economic perspective. Numerous researchs point out to the positive impacts in

economic growth as a result of addressing gender inequality (Klase, 1999; Klasen and Lamana, 2009;

Steinber and Nakne, 2012; Kabeer and Natali, 2013; Gonzales et al, 2015). Unfortunately, women

are 27 percentage points less likely to participate in the labor market than men (International Labour

Organization 2016). This low participation rate holds across all regions (see Figure 1).

Figure 1: Labor force participation by gender and region (%), 2019

Source: World Development Indicators. Note: Labor Force Participation (LFP) is ratio of active individuals to working age

population (15+) using modeled ILO estimates.

Middle East and Northern Adrica as well as South Asia have the lowest rates at around 20-23%. Sub-

Saharan Africa and East Asia and the Pacific have much higher rates, of between 59-61%. However,

none of them approach the 74% world average of MLFP. Additionally, male´s rates of participation

do not exhibit regional differences as extreme as the rates in women, the variance in male labor

force participation across regions is not as high as for women.

Moreover, trends not only differ by region, they also vary substantially across time within each

region (see Figure 2). In the Arab States and Northern Africa, FLFP across time is persistently very

low; and in Eastern Asia and Southern Asia it has decreased noticeably since the early 2000s.

Meanwhile, over the same period, FLFP experienced robust growth in Latin America and the

Caribbean, and in Sub-Saharan Africa. The former region is particularly striking as it has experienced

greater growth in FLFP than the rest of the developing world.

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

East Asia &

Pacific

Europe &

Central Asia

Latin America

& Caribbean

Middle East &

North Africa

Sub-Saharan

Africa

South Asia

Female LFP Male LFP

8

Figure 2: Trends in female vs male labor force participation across regions (%), 1990-2019

Source: World Development Indicators. Note: Labor Force Participation (LFP) is ratio of active individuals to working age

population (15+) using modeled ILO estimates.

Given such heterogeneity in female labor force participation across time and region, we seek to

explore in detail the existing empirical literature to identify important barriers that inhibit women

from entering the labor force. As the contexts in these regions differ greatly, we will consider a

broad array of literature – beyond the usual market constraints.

Furthermore, given the differences in trends in FLFP we will explore literature that covers policy

interventions, as well as changes in the identified barriers, to delineate successful policy

interventions. Throughout the review we seek to identify important gaps in the existence of these

barriers, on the policy that impacts FLFP, and in the research and evaluation of such policies.

We choose the main focus for this review to be on female labor force participation instead of

eployment, as a distinct and important measure for policy. While labor force participation and

employment are fundamentally linked, they do measure different aspects of women’s performance

in the labor market. Conceptually, female labor force participation is concerned with women’s

decision of whether to work, while female employment is concerned with whether women are

working. The female labor force participation rate is traditionally defined as the proportion of

women engaged actively in the labor market—currently employed or unemployed but actively

seeking to work—out of a country’s population of women in working-age (15 years and older) (ILO

2016). The female employment rate, on the other hand, is the proportion of those women who are

actively participating in the labor force: either who are employed or engaged in work.1 Thus, labor

force participation captures the decision to actively engage with the labor market while employment

represents an equilibrium outcome, resulting from the interaction of supply side (job seekers) and

demand side (employers) of the market for female labor.

The distinction we make between women’s labor force participation and employment is lacking or is

underemphasized in previous reviews, but it is not trivial. Female labor force participation does not

1 In this context, employment comprises both paid and unpaid work and both formal and informal work .

9

always move in tandem with employment, and it is possible for women’s employment to be high

even when their labor force participation remains low. Indeed, the global rate of female

employment— measured as percentage of the labor force—has remained relatively high at around

94%. In contrast, the global rate of female labor force participation has stood at around 50 percent2.

Employment rates, while useful, miss a large part of the story. Figure 3 illustrates this point, namely,

while employment rates are similarly high between men and women (blue line), a much greater

share of working age women are not in the labor force (green line). They also miss that the low rate

of FLFP has been stagnant over time and slowly declining, even as employment rates remain high.

Figure 3: Labor force participation and employment, global average

Source: World Development Indicators. Notes: Indicators are aggregate at the global level. Employment to Population

Ratio is defined as ratio of employed individiuals to working age population (15+). Labor Force Participation (LFP) is ratio of

active individuals to working age population (15+). Employment to Labor Force Ratio is ratio of employed individuals to

active labor force participants.

Empirical literature studying female labor force participation in developing countries is actually thin

and fragmented. Thus, we are obliged to include studies on female employment and self-

employment as well. Throughout the review we systematically denote whether the studies

discussed are concerned with either female labor force participation or female employment.

Moreover, much of the empirical literature on determinants and policy impacts is indirect. Only

some of the interventions discussed in this review were specifically implemented to directly improve

female labor supply (i.e. childcare policies). In most cases, evidence of policies on labor force

participation rates comes from unforeseen or unintended side-effects of policies that had different

primary aims, such as conditional cash transfers, rural electrification, or macro-level trade

liberalization policies.

The following review is organized around key drivers of and barriers to female labor force

participation. We explore them in detail in the following sections. First, we examine how constraints

in endowments such as time, education, financial and social capital limit women’s participation in

the labor force. Second we review evidence on the role of choices, preferences, norms and beliefs of

the labor market on FLFP as internal factors. Third, we discuss how external constraints such as

income shocks and demand-side factors inhibit active engagement in the labor market. Finally, we

2 There has been a gradual decline in FLFP after the global financial crisis in 2009. Worldwide rates average at 48% since

then.

10

conclude with some lesson learned form policy recommendations and draw up an agenda for future

research.

While additional studies and interventions focused on female labor force participation are an

important part of understanding and expanding women’s economic opportunities, increasing FLFP is

not a panacea on its own. Higher rates of FLFP do not necessarily imply improved empowerment for

women, because the measure does not consider the quality of the work. Labor that is unpaid,

informal, and low-return are all counted equally alongside high-paying, high-quality jobs. Thus, in

addition to increasing FLFP, policies that increase the availability of high-quality work for women are

also necessary to close the gender gaps in the economic arenas. This paper’s recommendations on

increasing FLFP should be considered in tandem with knowledge of the drivers of quality

employment, self-employment, and female entrepreneurship, as the one discussed by Mckenzie et

al (2019) in Kenya or by De Mel et al (2014) in Sri Lanka.

DRIVERS OF FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

Over the past century, women joined the labor market in increasing numbers. However, in the past

30 years we have seen a desaceleration in this trend and even a setback, as FLFP rates have been

slowly decreasing (see Figure 3). In developed countries such as the US, labor force participation of

women aged 16 and older doubled from 33.9% in 1950 to 64.6% in 1987. This rate then remained

stable and strated slightly decreasing, reaching 59% by the end of 2019 (U.S. Bureau of Labor

Statistics, 2020). In developing countries, as Klasen (2019) states, the trends are quite

heterogeneous. Since 1990, FLFP rates have decreased in South Asia, remained stagnant in East and

South East Asia, and have slightly increased in Latin America and the Caribbean. Overall, the big

picture of FLFP does not look promising. Estimates from Sivard (1985) place world rates of labor

participation among women in 1960 at 47% – with developing counties rates at 45% and developed

economies at 52%. Today, 60 years later, ILO estimates point to a 47% worldwide FLDP rate – 46%

for low and middle income countries and 53% for high income countries. There has been almost no

progress.

This section explores the key driver of FLFP and why there has been almost no progress in the past

50 years. A strand of the literature points to the combined effect of economic growth, technological

advances, rising education and declining fertility among women as the main drivers of FLFP for

periods of positive in the developing world. We will discuss these market conditions in the context

of how they impacted women’s enwoments and initial conditions to enter the labor force.

Particularly, how these positively affect women’s availability of time, level of education and type of

skills, level of financial inclusion, and access to networks.

On the side of fertility decline, literature in developing shows that it has freed up women's time

spent with being pregnant or caring for a small child substantially, enabling greater labor force

participation. The invention of contraceptive methods has foster this fertility decline and has

reduced the opportunity cost of engaging in long-term career investments (Goldin and Katz, 2002).

The diffusion of technology that allowed household chores to be less time consuming has reduced

the time burden of household chores (Fernandez, 2007). Similarly, the expansion of female

education and consequent closing of gender gaps in education in developing countries indirectly

11

enables labor market participation by facilitating a fertility decline and promoting female labor

market opportunities directly. Finally, the observed high per-capita growth rates in developing

regions boost labor demand and draws women into the labor force particularly given high existing

male participation rates (Klasen 2017).

However, the trends in FLPF rates are highly heterogeneous and suggest that economic growth,

fertility decline, and an expansion of female education need not translate into commensurate

increases in female participation (Klasen 2017). On the side of the fertility decline, there is evidence

that it can lead to lower female labor force participation, particularly among the poorer, rural, and

less educated women. Preibe (2010) associates this reduction with the relaxation of budget

constraint from having one less child. Moreover, the link between education and female labor force

participation is also not straightforward, as a U-shaped relationship is often observed, with high

participation rates at the very low end (women with no or very few years of schooling) as well as the

very high end (women with complete tertiary education). Lastly, economic growth must be

accompanied by adequate job opportunities specific to women in order to absorb them into the

labor market. This is not always the case, as the job-generating growing sectors of the economy may

not match the supply of female labor in terms of skills, norms, or preferences.

The mixed evidence fostered alternative explanaitions of why female labor force participation is

lower than male’s. Two stand out. One highlights the role of internal aspirations, personal

preferences and beliefs of the appropriate role of women as drivers of FLFP. According to this

litertature, it is women’s inner constraints that limits their low level of involvement with the labor

market, rather than the market itself pushing them out of it.

A second alternative explanation highlights the role of external shocks as drivers of the level of labor

force participation of women. Governemnt policies, shifts in technology, and social protection

schemes directly impact worker’s labor supply. Differentiated impacts by gender could be explained

by policies that disproportionately affect women, or by shifts in technology that affect a

predominantly female economic sectors. Finally, economic shocks that affect households where

men are traditionally wage earners may result in a differentiated effect on labor force participation

for women.

Below we summarize the most prominent studies in each of the three described group of drivers of

female labor force participation in the literature: endownments, internal constraints and external

constraints.

1. Endownments

1.1. Time

Given a limited time endownment, an invidual’s time is split between leisure, paid labor, and

household production (unpaid labor). The gendered distribution of tasks within the household,

where the woman is responsible for most household chores, leads to competing demands on

women’s time. The 2012 World Development Report on Gender Equality and Development notes

that women work more than men, once unpaid work is accounted for. As a result of the unequal

allocation of care responsibilities, many women experience time poverty which adversely affects

their ability to participate in the labor market and work in the jobs that they may desire (WBG,

12

2015). Furthermore, unequal domestic responsibility restrics women’s employment options to

occupational arrangements that allow time flexibility and management of care responsibilities.

Literature points that the most prominent elements competing for women’s time are fertility,

carework for children and elderly, and household tasks. We review the main evidence of how these

elements affects female labor force participation in this subsection.

Fertility

Choices regarding fertility, labor market participation, and (adult) human capital attainment are

linked, and dynamic in nature. Understanding the link between fertility and labor participation is

challenging for two reasons. First, the direction of the causality is unclear. While fertility and birth

timing have important impacts on labor market participation and wages, participation and wages

also influence timing and fertility decisions (Clarke, 2016). Second, two countervailing forces are at

play. An additional child increases the mother’s opportunity cost of labor through a higher domestic

workload, thus decreasing labor force participation; but at the same time, childbearing also

significantly increases demand for consumption goods in the household, which pushes mothers to

join the labor force. The net effect of these countervailing forces is uncertain, as it depends on the

context and on women’s budget constraints.

Some of the literature that points out to a negative relationship between fertility and labor

participation uses natural experiments – such as the introduction of birth control pills (Bailey 2013)

or changes in abortion legislation (Bloom et al. 2009 and Angrist and Evans 1996) – to conclude that

children have a negative effect on their mother’s labor supply. Similarly, instrumental variable

estimates are also a popular methodology employed to determine the effect of fertility on mothers.

Giving birth to twins is an unanticipated event, shifting the total number of children. Similarly,

parental preferences over mixed sibling-sex composition increases the number of children by an

additional one. Angrist and Evans (1998) are the first to find a negative impact of an additional child

on the FLFP in the US, using the abovementioned instrumental variables. Caceres-Delpiano (2008)

also use multiple births to explore the impact of childbearing on FLFP in 42 countries. Eventhough he

focuses on employment rather than labor force participation, which is also negatively affected by

having an additional child, the signs and magnitude of existing estimates largely point towards a

significant negative impact of the effect of fertility on labor market outcomes. However, the

negative effects he finds are not universal.

The sign and degree of the relationship between fertility and mother’s work behavior is often

mediated by the country’s stage of economic development (Aaronson et al 2017). Using

instrumental variable strategies on historic series of data spanning 103 countries between the 18th

and 21st centuries, Aaronson et al (2017) find that fertility has a negligible effect on female labor

supply in low-development contexts, but a large negative effect in high-development contexts.

Similarly, Agüero and Marks’ (2008) find no effect on women’s labor force participation for a group

of 6 Latin American countries. Their study explores an alternative instrument of childless mothers

undergoing infertility treatments. Although these findings suggest a lack of negative effect on poor

and developing countries, the criteria is not entirely straightforward. Godefroy’s (2017) analysis of

changes to women’s legal rights in Nigeria finds a robust negative relationship between fertility and

mother’s work, while Jaramillos’s (2016) study using instrumental variables in Peru finds a negative

13

relationship on women’s employment as well. Thus proving that the negative effects of fertility are

not circumscribed to developed economies.

Two key forces interact as wages increase during the process of economic development: households

face an increased time cost of fertility (substitution effect) but also experience increased income

through better job opportunities (income effect). Goldin (1995) argues that the substitution effect

dominates during economic development and arises from changes in the sectoral and occupational

structure of female jobs. In particular, as economies evolve, women’s labor market opportunities

transition from agricultural and self-employment to urban wage work. The latter tends to be less

compatible with raising children and causes some movement out of the labor force (Jaffe and Azumi

1960; McCabe and Rosenzweig 1976; Kupinsky 1977; Goldin 1995; Galor and Weil 1996; Edwards

and Field-Hendrey 2002; and Szulga 2013).

Given the impact that an additional child has on women’s FLFP, a growing literature documents a

causal relationship between access to child care or early education and the propensity of mothers to

work, a finding that is consistent with leaving the workforce when labor market opportunities

become less compatible with child rearing (Berlinski and Galiani 2007; Baker, Gruber, and Milligan

2008; Cascio 2009; Havnes and Mogstad 2011; Fitzpatrick 2012; and Herbst 2017). In line with this,

recent documented shifts to positive correlations between total fertility rate and FLFP in some

developed countries, which may be attributed to higher substitutability of direct childcare and

childcare outside the home, as well as access to higher quality childcare outside the home (Hwang,

et al 2017).

These results indicate that there are mediating factors in the fertility-FLFP relationship. The ability to

share the childcare burden for women in developing contexts is a factor in their availability to enter

or remain in the labor market. In a study exploiting regional differences in China’s second child law3,

Cao (2019) show that while a second child reduces maternal labor force participation, particularly

for women with migrant husbands, labor supply is not reduced for women living in three-generation

families. The author(s) attributes this to the availability of time and resources for childcare from

other family members. Similarly, using panel data from Ghana, Heath (2017) shows that fertility can

actually increase female labor supply given sufficiently high returns to financial investments in

children. The author finds that labor supply on the extensive margin (whether to work or not) drops

in the presence of children, but this effect is mediated by the presence of other adults in the

household.4

Given women’s disproportionate care burden, when deciding to join the labor force women may

place high value on flexibile work hours, parental leave, or support in terms of childcare. In the

absence of maternity leave, formal and informal chilcare, and flexible work arrangements (temporal

flexibility or part time work), women are left with options of the informal economy, or self

employment, in order to balance work and domestic responsibilitiles. Surveys and interviews with

women working in the informal sector have supported this connection between responsibilities and

3 In some parts of rural China, couples that have a female firstborn are allowed to have an additional child.

4 Interestingly, labor supply on the intensive margin (hours worked) actually increases as a result of a child for the women

who stay in the labor force. According to the authors the the increase in labor supply might correspond to a higher

pervceived importance of financial inputs in children, as compared to time investments.

14

informality or self employment. For example, 20% of women surveyed in the Philippines reported

family responsibilities as the reason they engaged in informal rather than formal work (Verceles &

Beltran 2004). A study of small businesses in Bangladesh found that 13% of women cited family

responsibilities as a reason they turned to entrepreneurship, as compared to 1% of men (Marcucci

2001).

Carework

Childcare

There is a growing body of evidence which suggests that the increased availability of childcare

options results in an increase in female labor force participation and employment rates. Part of this

literature has investigated this relationship mostly for younger age groups (preschool) in developed

countries with relatively high FLFP rates (Blau and Tekin (2007), and Blau and Currie (2006)

summarize some of this vast literature). The majority of these studies use non-experimental

methodologies, using childcare expansions, discontinuities in eligibility or other policy changes to

address this causal effect. Results for the US, Canada and European countries with similar FLFP are

mostly positive (Gelbach, 2002; Baker et al., 2008; Lefebvre and Merrigan, 2008; Nollenberger and

Rodriguez-Planas, 2015), generally finding that childcare increases the probability of mother’s labor

force participation and employment.

Evidence from developing and middle-income countries also shows a strong positive link between

access to childcare and maternal labor force participation. Evaluation of a childcare expansion policy

in Mexico, which covered 90% of the cost of enrolling children, increased women’s probability of

working (Calderon, 2012). The author uses triple differences and synthetic controls methods to

estimate the impact on FLFP. Additional studies in Brazil and Chile support the relationship between

female labor force participation and accessability of childcare options. In Brazil, de Barros et al.

(2011) evaluate the impacts of a lottery for selection into free childcare. They find sizeable effects on

women’s employment. The effects are large even among women who did not work before the

lottery, suggesting an increase in FLFP. In Chile, Martínez and Perticará (2017) performed

randomized evaluation on a program that gave mothers three hours of daily afterschool care for

children aged 6 to 13 years old. They showed that access to the program increased female labor

force participation by 7% and employment by 5%.

Other authors also focus on employment variables. Berlinski and Galiani (2007) use difference in

difference methodologies to estimate the impact of subsidized public schools in the context of large

scale pre-primary school construction project in Argentina. They find that the program has positive

effects on women’s employment. Similarly, Attanasio and Vera-Hernandez 2004, use instrumental

variables to identify the impact of a program in Colombia that provides informal child care. They find

that the programme has large positive effects on women’s employment rates and hours worked.

Notheworthy, the evidence indicates that the presence of childcare options are not enough – they

must be affordable and of good quality. For example, a study in Romania between 1989 and 1995

concluded that both the female labor force participation rates and the decision to use paid childcare

were associated with the price of childcare (Fong and Lockshin 2000). Another study, using data

15

from the European Community Household Panel, showed a correlation between female labor force

participation and the affordability of childcare (Del Boca and Locatelli 2006).

The importance of child care prices is also true for low and middle-income countries. Lokshin et al

(2000) analyze the effect of child care costs in Kenya. They find that higher costs disencourage

households from relying on formal childcare and negatively impacts mother’s labor participation.

Relatedly, in a thorough review of the relationship between childcare and female labor supply in

Latin America in particular, Diaz and Rodriguez-Chammussy (2016) argue that the cases where

childcare does not have a positive impact on female labor supply, including participation, are driven

by poor quality childcare.

Eldercare

In addition to childcare, women face the brunt of elderly care in the household, another factor

competing for women’s time. If the burden falls only on them, FLFP is expected to drop. Female

labor supply thus depends on whether women live with their parents or in-laws. But the empirical

results around this relationship are mixed and context dependent, as are norms around post-marital

residence that affect women’s time allocation. As seen in the abovementioned case of China, living

with elederly generations can also reduce a mother’s burden and thus increase their FLFP, if the

parents and in-laws provide child care support.

Several authors established a positive impact of intergenerational co-residence on the labor force

participation of married women: living with parents or in-laws increases the probability of female

labor force participation by 56 percentage points in the US (Kolodinsky and Shirey, 2000), by 28

percentage points in China when analysis is limited to co-residence with own parents (Shen et al.,

2016), by 19-24 percentage points in Japan (Oishi and Oshio, 2006), and by 7 percentage points in

urban China (Maurer-Fazio et al., 2011). All of these studies claim that the overall positive impact is

due to parental assistance with child care and housekeeping. Only Shen et al. (2016) explicitly test

and confirm this claim.

However, other recent empirical studies find a negative relationship between elderly care

responsibilities and female labor force participation, particularly in contexts with stricter normative

expectations around women’s activities. This can be especially detrimental to women’s lifetime

labor market outcomes, as the largest amount of intergenerational time transfers are provided by

middle-aged women (45-65 years old) both to their older and younger generations of family

members. Thus, the height of their care responsibilities often come during women’s most productive

years (Albertini et al. 2007; World Bank Group 2015). Landman et al (2016) find that the effect of

coresidence on female labor supply in Kyrgyzstan is negative and insignificant. The authors exploit a

tradition in Central Asia where the youngest son of a family usually lives with his parents, and

instrument co-residence with being married to a youngest son. The authors find that women who

co-reside in Kyrgyzstan have more children, spend similar time on housekeeping tasks and child care,

and invest more time in elder care compared with women who do not co-reside. These mechanisms

appear to be inherently different from those in less patrilocal settings where co-residing parents

relieve the women from household chores.

There are still few acceptable market-based options for eldercare in developing countries compared

with childcare (Todd 2013). In the developed context, motivated by the fast aging population, the

Japanese government introduced a long-term care insurance (LTCI) initiative that provided cash

16

allowances for elderly care services purchased through the formal sector, leading to growth in the

formal elderly care market. Sugawara and Nakamura (2014) estimate the effects of care

requirements on female labor supply in Japan for periods before and after the launch of the LTCI.

They find that while the female employment rate is negatively correlated with caregiving for

disabled elders, the magnitude of this negative correlation decreased after the introduction of the

LTCI. This is consistent with a model where the long-term care insurance initiative decreased costs of

formal elderly care, freeing up time for daughters-in-law to work outside the home. They find

heterogeneity of effects by gender of the elder. As a result of the LTCI, care for male elders no longer

formed an obstacle to female work, while care for female elderly still has negative effects on the

female labor supply, indicating that when a female elder is disabled, not only caregiving but also

housekeeping burdens are turned over to family members, thereby posing a more severe time

constraint for coresiding females.

Overall, it seems that the context and the expected role of women in each society determines

whether or not the presence of an elderly persons in the household will affect a women’s propensity

to work. In settings where living with elderly is common and not closely tied to them needing care,

coresidence may enhance the capacity for women to work, as older parents or parents-in-laws assist

with child-caring duties. In other settings, like the US, where coresidence is relatively uncommon

unless the older person needs care, the presence of elderly likely imposes demands on women that

compete with their capacity to work. Finally, in more traditional patriarchal society where women

are expected to sacrifice their careers for their husbands and parents/in-laws, eldercare is a

deterrant of FLFP.

Home Production

Besides allocating time to fertility and caring for others, women are also in charge of the home

production (e.g. cooking, cleaning). According to the 2020 Gender Snapshot of the United Nations5,

women work 3 times more than men on unpaid care work at home. They collect information from

various sources, including household surveys, national survey, and time use sueveys, among others.

Based on the latest data point from surveys in over 65 countries, women’s proportion of time spent

on domestic chores and care work is 10 percentage points (pp) higher than men. While men report

spending on average 6,8% of their time on household chores, women report spending 17,2% of their

time on household chores on average. Mexico is the most unequal in terms of the distribution of

time (with a gendered difference of 20 pp in the reported proportion of time spent in household

chores) and Belgium is the most equal of the group (with a 0.4 pp difference).

As women spend time doing household chores, it is expected that the introduction of new

technology and access to infrastructure such as electricity, gas, pipe water, and transportation

would reduce the the overall workload of domestic responsibilities in some contexts and lead to

increased female labor force participation.

Rural electrification has been a growing policy agenda in many countries, with potential to impact

labor supply. Dinkelman (2011) shows that large-scale household electrification post-Apartheid in

5 The Gender Snapshot is a report from the Women Count initiative of United Nations. The main goal of the project is

collect gender sensitive indicators to monitor advances in the SDGs. It aims at changing the way gender statistics are used,

created, shared and accessed. See more in: https://data.unwomen.org

17

South Africa led to a 9 to 9.5 percentage point increase in female employment. This was concurrent

with increases in electric lighting and electric cooking over the same five-year period – indicating

that decreases in time costs of home production were contributing to women’s decisions to join the

labor force. Similarly, household electrification in Nicaragua was found to increase young rural

women’s (women under the age of 35) propensity to work outside the home by 23% (Grogan and

Sadanand 2013). Access to electric light dramatically increased the length of the working day

allowing women the time-savings to work outside the home.

However, the increase in willingness to work due to electrification does not necessarily translate into

higher employment. Salmon and Tanguy (2016) model spouses’ joint labor supply decisions in

response to rural electrification in Nigeria using an instrumental variables strategy to identify the

causal effect of electrification. They find that employment probability is not significantly changed for

either men or women. In addition, when considering dependant labor supply decisions among

husbands and wifes, electrification only increases husbands’ working time.

Increasing women’s agency over their own fertility choices, expanding access to childcare and

eldcare, and ensuring access to basic services such as electrification and running water allow women

to participate in the labor market with grater involvement. The policy agenda in the developing

world might already be focusing on policies that free up women’s time. However, we must

acknowledge these policies do not ensure more opportunities (jobs), nor do it translate into good

quality employment.

Some policy circles highlight how good it will be for women to participate in the efforts to expand

the care industry. But again, while we agree that more opportunities may mean that more women

will end up working, there is a trade-off because those jobs tend to be of low quality, burdensome,

and badly paid. Thus, they might increase FLFP (by freeing up women’s time and offering

employment opportunities), but reduce quality of employment and reinforce gender-based

segregation.

1.2. Skills & Education

Educational attainment is one of the key determinants of labor market outcomes in developed and

developing countires. As the seminal work of Becker (1961) stated, individuals accumulate a set of

skills through education or training which they can then use to join the labor market, become more

productive or even earn higher wages. More recently, Heckman et al. (2010) found that educational

attainment at almost every level causally produces gains on the labor market.

Education levels of women have considerably improved in many developing contexts over the last

decades. In East Asia and the Pacific (EAP), girls used to complete less than one year of schooling in

1950. Now, they enroll and stay in school as or even longer than boys (World Bank Regional Report,

2018a). According to the regional report of EAP, girls are also learning as much or more than boys –

they outperform boys by one year in reading test scores.

Other regions follow a similar pattern. South Asia has not achieved universal enrollment, but has

significantly decreased the enrollment gap between boys and girls. India has managed to shrinked its

gap to near zero-levles. Similarly to East Asia, girls in primary and secondary school in South Asia

perform at the same level as boys. However, retention in post-secondary levels is still low and

women are tracked into low-productivity streams. When it comes to choosing fields in higher

18

education, women do not go for STEM fields, which has long term effects on their employment

opportunities and expected income (World Bank Regional Report, 2018b).

Such a lack of opportunity is also present in other regions. In the Middle East and North Africa, girls

outperform boys in literacy and numeracy since very early on. However, the region exhibits some of

the lowest female labor force participation around the world: only 20% of women participate in the

labor force. This paradox is partly explained by social norms in the region, which we will further

explore in the next section (World Bank Regional Report, 2018c). In the Africa region, there is not

much difference in performance between girls and boys, but girls are disproportionately left out of

lower-secondary and upper-secondary levels. Cultural practices such as child-marriage and early

pregnancies are a leading cause of this gender gap (World Bank Regional Report, 2018d).

There are several channels through which education can later affect female labor force participation.

We focus on two ways of acquiring skills and education—one is through formal schooling

(educational attainment) and the other one is through continuing education (vocational and job

training).

Educational attainment

Theorically, the higher the educational attainment, the better the labor outcomes. Higher levels of

schooling increase the opportunity cost of not entering the labor market, as higher education

corresponds with higher potential earnings. Schooling also affects labor market participation

indirectly as it raises the age of marriage and age at first birth, allowing women to develop stronger

ties to the labor market. More educated women may be more empowered to influence household

decision making or resisiting constricting social norms, leading to greater labor market activity

Empirically, contrary to common belief, the relationship between education and female LFP is weak

and the evidence that portrays this relationship is thin. As Klasen (2019) states, this relationship

often takes the form of a U-shaped function, with higher participation at lower levels of educational

attainment and at very high levels of education. The recent expansion of schooling around the

developing world has thus shifted women’s educational attainment to intermediate levels,

associated with lower levels of labor force participation (minimum of the U-shaped function).

Some research of the nature of this relationship has been found in Latin America and the Caribbean

and in East Asia. Gasparini and Marchionni (2017) find that in the past 2 decades the expansion of

education has allowed more women to get tertiary education, and that these women are more likely

to enter the labor market. Similarly, in Bangladesh, Rahman and Islam (2013) find that since the

1990’s economic growth acceleration, education and female labor force participation have been

increasing in tandem. However, women’s employment in Bangladesh during this period seems too

dependant on a single industry. The authors also find challenges related to wages and other aspects

of compliance with labor standards, that affect women disproportionately.

A specific case in Bangladesh is studied by Shamsuddin (2015). The Female Secondary Education

Stipend Programme provided girls with stipends, books, tuition fees, and exam fees, conditional on

school attendance in grades 6 to 10. A long-term impact evaluation of the program finds that

women who were exposed to the program for the full five years had 6 percentage points higher

labor force participation rates. However, participation actually decreased wages by 17% as the

surplus of secondary-school-educated women struggled to find productive employment.

19

In India, Klasen and Pieters (2012) analyze the trends in urban FLFP from 1983-2005, period where

India’s economy grew significantly. They find that economic pull factors (i.e. more job opportunities

and higher-paying jobs) only attract highly educated women into the labor force, increasing their

participation. For women with less than secondary school, no effect of higher wages on participation

is found.

Similarly to the evidence on labor force participation, gains in education do not always translate into

gains in employment, indicating presence of bottlenecks during the school to work transition. For

example, despite well documented effects of the Mexican conditional cash transfer program

Progresa/Oportunides on human capital accumulation, there is very little evidence of program

impacts on employment, wages or inter-generational occupational mobility among program

beneficiaries (Rodriguez-Oreggia and Freije, 2012). Levy (2007) warned beforehand about the

education conditionality of this cash transfer and the fact that increases in schooling as a result of

the program needed to be met with better economic and social conditions in order to result in

better labor market outcomes. Particularly, the author highlights the need of additional policies

from the supply side. Thus, even when education is accompanied with better economic conditions,

programs that aim to improve education and employability of the workforce need be complemented

by demand-side interventions.

Job and vocational training

Beyond formal educational attainment, vocational and job training programs are an increasingly

common policy intervention to skill-up the workforce and tackle unemployment in developing

countries.

Unfortunately, the empirical evidence linking training programs with female LFP is largely

inconclusive. This is mainly explained by the fact that the evidence is generally indirect, measuring

employment rates but not FLFP. Participants in job training programs are, by definition, already

active members of the labor force, since they are explicitly preparing for work. However, there is

little information on whether the programs pulled participants from inactivity into the labor force, or

whether they were already active. Moreover, the impacts of job trainings programs on employment

rates vary according to the context and content of the programs: depending on the nature of skills

taught (hard skill, soft skills, or life skills), duration of the program, and incentives for employers to

hire workers trained in these programs.

In the case that the targeted sample are school-age girls (and are thus inactive by definition), there is

indirect evidence of skills training programs improving labor force participation. Bandiera et al

(2017) experimentally evaluate a women’s empowerment program in Uganda where adolescent

girls gained vocational training and sex education through adolescent development clubs. The

authors find that four years after the intervention, girls who received the training were 48% more

likely to be involved in income-generating activities. This effect is driven by engagement with self-

employment, and there is no impact found on wage employment.

In Liberia, an impact evalatuion of the Adolescent Girls Initiative (EPAG) – a public-private

partnership aiming to support adolescent girls and young women in transitioning from school to

productive employment – provides evidence that skills training can be an effective policy option

for increasing employment among young women. The program led to a 47% increase in employment

20

and an 80% increase in average weekly income among project beneficiaries, compared to those in

the control group (Franck et al, 2014).

Despite the abovementioned positive effects, when it comes to the effect of job training program on

employment, there are some doubts on its effectiveness. One concern is that trainings affect

workers’ expectations of employment outcomes. If these expectations are not met by the labor

market, then workers may end up desincouraged. Acevedo et al. (2017) show the importance of

these expectations in Dominican Republic. They find that imbedding a soft skill component to a

vocational training program had positive effects on both skills and labor market expectations for

women, but only only improved expectations for men, with no impact on skills. This created the

conditions for discouragement as expectations exceed the returns to acquired skills. In the short

term, women had higher employment rates, in higher paying jobs, with higher satisfaction levels,

while men had zero and negative effects on employment outcomes. Over time, the women in the

control group were able to catch up and the men in the treatment group lowered their expectations,

accepting an employment that equalized them with the control group. While the program positively

improved women’s wellbeing, men were ultimately disappointed and discouraged, leading to

deterioration in the quality of their lives.

There is no consensus in the literature about a positive effect of job training on FLFP, but the

evidence seems to suggest that women respond positively to training. A still open policy question is

why women do not receive the same training opportunities as men. One hypothesis follows from

Lazer and Rosen (1990) who state that firms take into account the employees’ probability of finding

non-market rewards in the period following training before offering it. And, as women have a higher

probability of leaving the firm, firms often overlook them. An alternative hypothesis proposes that

women simply do not seek training opportunities—which could be explained by lack of information

about programs, lack of budget, competing responsibilities (e.g. childcare), credit constraints, or

negative perceptions about the relevance and quality of the training.

1.3. Financial Assets

Self-employment is an important avenue for women’s labor force participation. However, women

are often excluded from formal financial markets which constrains their entrepreneurial activities

both directly, via a lower capital stock for business development, and indirectly, via the

empowerment/ household decision-making channel.

Capital constraints

The Global Findex database shows that, while bank account ownership continues to grow globally,

gender inequality persists—particularly in developing economies where men are 9% more likely to

hold a bank account than women (Demirguc-Kunt et al, 2017). Limited access to financial products

results in reduced chances of overcoming capital constraints, a problem that is self-perpetuating as

lower starting capital means decreased ability to get capital using collateral6.

6 It is worth mentioning that recent literature is exploring promising and innovative ways around the credit constraint, such

as the use of psychometric data as collateral (see Alibhai et al, 2018 for instance).

21

Evidence about the impact of access to capital and financial inclusion on labor force participation is

very thin. Most studies measure labor supply on the intensive margin (i.e., hours worked) rather

than the extensive margin (i.e., labor market entry, including entrepreneurs), and the studies that do

explore female labor force participation as outcome do not differentiate by whether the respondent

was previously active in the labor market or not.

A strand of the (thin) literature suggests that financial inclusion does have a positive impact on self-

employment, wage-employment, and female empowerment (which may in turn affect female labor

force participation). Ausburg et al. (2015) explore the effects of offering loans to applicants who

were marginally rejected by a micro-finance institution on labor outcomes in Bosnia and find an

increase in labor supply and self employment among 16-19 year-old women. Similarly, Bruhn and

Love (2011) find sizeable positive effects of access to finance on labor market activity in the context

of the expansion of bank branches of Banco Azteca in Mexico. Access to finance reduced the

proportion of individuals not working. While men were more likely to become informal business

owners, women were more likely to become wage-earners.

Yet, other strand of the literature fails to find an impact of finance on labor outcomes. Crepon et al.

(2011) study the expansion of a microcredit program in rural Morocco. The authors find positive

effects of investment in the number of assets used for self-employment and in profits. However,

they fail to find effects on female empowerment, which included mobility inside and outside the

village. Similarly, Banerjee et al. (2015) study the effects of the expansion of a microcredit program

in Hyderabad, India. They find positive effects of access to credit on profits and investments, but no

effect on women’s empowerment.

Financial access and empowerment

Financial inclusion and access to savings and credit products can foster female labor force

participation by giving women agency to make consumption and savings decisions over household

income. For example, using data from an experiment in rural India, Desai and Joshi (2014) find that

the formation of self-help groups (SHGs) among rural women increases non-farm employment, and

decision-making and civic engagement among participating women. Via a mixture of increased

education, access to finance, and linkages to wider development programs, the SHGs help women

acquire greater personal automony. However, it is not clear whether the program affects LFP

decisions of previously inactive women and whether increased empowerment was the channel

through which the effect operates.

Furthermore, it is not only the availability of financial products but the type of products offered that

matter to lift constraints to female labor supply. Field et al. (2016) examine the role of supply-side

constraints linked to low household bargaining power and traditional gender norms in suppressing

female employment. Their hypothesis is as follows. Having a wife who works is a source of social

stigma or shame for Indian men who are expected to economically provide for the household

(Boudet et al., 2012). Low female bargaining power would thus induce latent female workers to stay

out of the labor force in order to abide by their husbands’ wishes. Increasing women’s bargaining

power could therefore draw women into the labor force and increase ability to control their own

22

income. This creates a positive feedback loop: an increase in control over their own earnings

incentivizes women’s work, which in turn increases earnings.

To test for this, the authors experimentally varied whether women’s wages from India’s public

workfare program were deposited into female-owned bank accounts instead of into the male

household head’s account (the status quo). The treatment increased women’s work, both in the

program and in the private sector, despite no change in market wages. Treatment effects are

concentrated among two groups of women: those who had not previously worked for the program

and those whose husbands disapprove of women working. The authors note that financial inclusion

alone did not move the needle on FLFP. Although the intervention roughly doubled the share of

women who had bank accounts, receiving only a bank account (with or without a supplementary

information session) had no observable impact on women’s employment or earnings. Thus access to

a safe place for a woman to keep her wages is not enough—resources need to be explicitly directed

to that savings account and women need to be given the basic tools to use it.

Innovations in digital financial products and services, such as mobile accounts and digital payments,

offer possible ways to lower the cost of access to financial services and enable women to control

and access financial transactions (such as remittances and wage payments) directly (World Bank

Group Gender Strategy 2016). Further research is needed about the extent to which increased

control over income and finances improve women’s labor force participation.

1.4. Networks & Social Capital

In the presence of information asymmetries between workers and firms, firms leverage networks to

identify and hire productive workers. Referred workers are more likely than non-referred workers to

be hired, all else equal (Pallais and Sands, 2015). Referral-based hiring has the potential to

disadvantage qualified women, highlighting another potential channel behind gender disparities in

the labor market. In Malawi, Beaman et al. (2018) show that men systematically refer few women,

despite being able to refer qualified women when explicitly asked for female candidates.

Similarly, using data on physicians’ referrals to surgeons in the US, Sarsons (2019) shows that

physicians become more pessimistic about a female surgeon’s ability than a male’s after a patient

death, indicated by a sharper drop in referrals to the female surgeon. Moreover, this effect is

projected onto other female surgeons (i.e., after a bad experience with a female surgeon, physicians

stop referring to other female surgeons)—this do not happen with male’s surgeons. Finally,

Magruder (2010) demonstrates that using the father’s networks has a positive effect on the son’s,

but not the daughters. The author also finds that mother’s connections do not seem to be matter.

Given that women are more constrained by lack of information about their productivity, tools that

help correct asymmetric information (such as networks) are valuable assets to increase the female

labor force participation. However, literature related to network and social capital mainly focuses on

the success of networking for matching job seekers to jobs (i.e., focuses on individuals that are

already part of the labor market), leaving out the relationship between networks and probability of

finding a job. The thin literature that explore this relation follows.

Stoloff et al. (1999) examine the effect of network structure on women’s paid labor force

participation in Los Angeles. Two findings regarding FLFP are worth mentioning. The first is that

women with more diverse and high quality social resources are more likely to enter the labor force,

23

after controlling for education and background. The second is that women from more disadvantaged

background with children rely on their social networks for childcare to enter the workforce. The

paper makes a distinction about the type of connections required for each outcome.

Puga and Soto (2018) also draw a distinction on different types of social capital. The authors draw

from empirical evidence from Chile to find that the relevant networks that drive women’s labor

force participation are those connections that are weaker but far-reaching. Networks connecting

women with high-status individuals. However, these networks are very unequal, as the positive

effects of using these networks are only valid among women in the richest quintile of the household

income. Given their findings, the authors reject the idea that policy should focus on social capital as

a way of increasing economic integration of women, as it shifts the responsibility of providing

women’s fair labor conditions from the state to the women.

Besides helping getting a job, networks also provide a bridge for women to join the labor force in

traditionally male-dominated sectors. Alibahi et al (2017) study the occupational gender gap among

entrepreneurs. Their findings show that women-owned enterprises that manage to crossover to

male-dominated sectors perform better on average than female entrepreneurs in female-dominated

sectors. They explore the mechanisms and find that it is not education nor skills what helps women

crossover, rather women’s network connections what helps them enter a the male-dominated

sectors. Specifically, the relationships with male relatives influences the probability of entering such

spaces. Pande et al. (2015) show that friendship networks also matter to join male-dominated

activities such as entrepreneurship. When women bring a friend to a business skills training, they are

more likely to take out a loan and to use it for business purposes, increase household income and

consumption, and less likely to report occupation as a housewife.

2. Internal Constraints

As the combined effect of purely economic factors is not enough to explain the low female labor

force participaton, an alternative strand of the literature hypothesizes that perceptions of the labor

market and beliefs about the self in relation to the labor market are likely drivers of women’s

decision to participate or not in the labor market. Empirical research around this relationship is

limited. We focus on three main internal constraints—perception of opportunities and the

environment, beliefs about self, reservation wages and norms.

2.1. Perceptions of opportunities

First, perceptions of opportunities available in the labor market (or lack thereof) may influence

women’s decision to participate. Several studies support the fact that availability of jobs and

perception of opportunities themselves are drivers of women’s empowerment. Jensen (2012), for

instance, provides evidence of how job recruitment services helped women in rural India get jobs in

a recently exogenously developed industry. As a result of job offers, women became less likely to

have children or get married and chose to enter the labor force, suggesting an increase in aspirations

for their careers.

Similarly, Heath and Mobarak (2015) study the impact of the expansion of ready-made garment

industry in Bangladesh. The authors find that the rise in job opportunities explains the decline in

fertility, the increase of age at marriage, and the increase of educational attainment among young

24

women. Majlesi (2015) studies the effect of job opportunitiy for both men and women in the

manufacturing industry of Mexico. The author finds that job opportunities increase women

bargaining power within the household, and the results are true for both working and non-working

women. Although neither paper directly addresses the reinforcement of labor force participation, as

the Jensen (2012) paper does, they do clearly state how perception of job opportunities lift women’s

internal constraint, as shown by higher bargaining power and the decision to delay marriage and

having children.

Second, even if opportunities are available, perception of the work environment (e.g.,

competitiveness, male dominance, etc.) may not be conducive to women entering the labor market.

Exploiting a natural experiment, Flory et al (2015) analyze whether competition incentives

differentially affect men’s and women’s labor choices, and the extent to which male connotations on

a job advertisement affect application patterns. The authors find that the applicant pool becomes

significantly more male dominated as the compensation package becomes more heavily reliant on

individual relative performance. This is mainly driven by women’s stronger aversion to competition,

rather than men’s preference for it. They also find that hiring into versions of the job that have

removed masculine connotations substantially attenuates gender differences in application

patterns.

This is consistent with Akerlof and Kranton (2000), who argue that gender–job associations are

drivers of gender-specific employment patterns and predict that women sort into employments

whose requirements match construed female attributes. Thus, it follows that, if available work

opportunities are (or are perceived to be) competitive or masculine, women would be less likely to

enter the labor market. However the extent to which this is a binding constraint to female labor

force participation is still an open question.

2.2. Aspirations & Self-confidence

Beliefs about own ability are also a key input to many economic decisions and are likely to impact

labor market outcomes (e.g. how job candidates present themselves). However, there is limited

empirical evidence from developed or developing countries linking psychological barriers such as

low aspirations or self confidence to female labor force participation. We expect this link to matter,

since there is evidence of the role of aspirations and self confidence on outcomes that are drivers of

LFP—such as education (Beaman et al., 2012)—and on outcomes related to LFP—such as

entrepreneurship (Campos et al., 2017) and employment (Heckman et al., 2006).

McKelway (2018) finds that women’s beliefs in own abilities are a constraint to employment and,

likely, labor force participation. Boosting women’s generalized self efficacy, or the belief in own

ability to attain desired outomes, increases likelihood of women enrolling in a program that offers

work opportunities, as well as probability of having employment. Similarly, McKelway finds that the

promotion of a work opportunity also leads to dramatic increases in enrollment for the work

opportunity but the promotion treatment (which was done with the family) has important

consequences for women’s control over income which in turn affects women’s decision to enroll in

the program7 A claim of impact on FLPF can be made to the extent that program enrollment is a

7 These findings are consistent with Field et al (2016) above, where money from a public workfare program was deposited

to female-owned accounts – instead of men-owned account. The treatment increased women’s work.

25

valid proxy for LFP. While the study uses a sample of women within a geographical cachment area,

there is no indication of their labor force status at baseline, and employment status was not a

sample selection criteria (a small fraction of women were employed at baseline).

Interestingly, the author also finds a positive feedback mechanism of employment on self efficacy.

Randomly offering a job to women who were enrolled in the program to receive work opportunities

results in higher scores on generalized self efficacy months later—supporting the hypothesis that

exclusion from the labor market is a driver of low self-confidence, which in turn further constrains

labor market participation.

Women are more likely to underestimate their skills (Niederle and Vesterlund, 2007) and are thus

less confident in their ability to obtain a job because of feelings of inadequacy or beliefs that no jobs

are available to fit their skill level. Coffman et al. (2019) study through laboratory and field

experiments the decision to apply to a more challenging and higher paying job. They find that

women were less likely to apply to jobs in male-dominated domains. Two factors drive this decision.

The first is that women have more pessimistic beliefs about their own abilities than men in male-

type domains. The second is that women’s belief of what is expected out of a candidate—referred

to “the bar” by the authors—is higher for a given opportunity. Although this paper provides

compelling evidence of the gendered difference of self-confidence, more research is needed to

understand whether this difference in beliefs also prevents women from participating in the labor

force.

2.3. Reservation Wages

Even though the gender gap in reservation wages is well documented, there is no direct evidence on

whether a change in the reservation wage may induce changes in labor force participation.

However, several strands of the labor literature combine to provide an insight into the role of

reservation wages as a driver of female labor force participation.

Gender differences in reservation wages may arise due to different preferences for non-working

time (Bowlus and Grogan, 2009), differing personality traits and anticipate discriminatory hiring

behavior by firms. Different personality traits include men being overconfident (see Barber and

Odean, 2001), women being risk averse (Eckel and Grossmann, 2008; Pannenberg, 2010), women’s

preferences for occupations with higher social prestige (Kleinjans and Fullerton, 2013) or women’s

preferences for workplace flexibility (Goldin, 2014). Anticipate discriminatory hiring behavior by

firms implies that women and adjust their reservation wage downwards to maximize future

employment prospects.

Furthermore, this reservation wage gap has been shown to be a key factor in the realized wage gap.

Caliendo et al. (2017) examine the importance of the gender differences in reservation wages for the

gender wage gap in a decomposition analysis using instrumental variables to address the potential

endogeneity of reservation wages. The authors find that the inclusion of reservation wages halves

the gender gap—making the remaining difference economically small and statistically insignificant,

and implying that reservation wages play an important role for the gender gap in realized wages.

Given the importance of reservation wages for realized wages, it is expected that the former also

play an important role in determining female LFP. Two opposing potential mechanisms are at play

when it comes to reservation wages and FLFP. They are either too high, deterring women from

26

working as their expectations are unrealistic (supply-side issue). Or they are too low, so wages don’t

exceed the reservation wages (demand-side issue). The evidence is not consistent on which of these

mechanisms is at play for different contexts and it should be part of a research agenda. A strand of

this (inconclusive) literature, which focuses on the relationship between cash transfers and

remittances and reservation wages, follows.

Low and middle-income countries have implemented conditional or unconditional cash transfer

schemes to improve income and alleviate poverty at the household level. One concern is that the

income effect from a cash transfer, combined with a sufficient preference for leisure, could lead

women to drop out of the labor force upon receiving cash transfers. However, the empirical

literature does not find this hypothesized negative impact of cash transfers on female labor force

participation in eligible households. Banerjee et al. (2015) study this relationship in the context of

seven conditional and unconditional cash transfer programs in six countries: Honduras, Indonesia,

Morocco, Mexico (two programs), Nicaragua and the Philippines. All of these cash transfer schemes

were implemented through randomized trials and aimed at reducing poverty. The authors do not

find significant effect of transfers on female (or male) labor force participation among eligible

households. Similarly, Alzua et al. (2013) empirically evaluate three of the same transfer programs

in Latin America (RPS in Nicaragua, PRAF in Honduras, and PROGRESA in Mexico) and similarly find

that the programs have not introduced any substantial disincentives to work and that they have had

no significant effect on labor supply for individuals or households in treatment localities.

Similar to other forms of non‐labor income, it is expected that remittances increase the reservation

wage of non‐migrants in the household and decrease their likelihood of entering or staying in the

labor market (Killingsworth, 1983). On the other hand, households may use the extra income to

invest in an existing household enterprise or to start a new business. This would likely increase the

demand for household labor and result in an increase in non‐migrants' labor supply. Empirical

evidence from studies on migrant sending countries supports the reservation wage hypothesis and

points to a decline in labor force participation—the effect is particularly important among women

(Rodriguez and Tiongson, 2001; Acosta, 2006; Amuedo‐Dorantes and Pozo, 2006; Lokshin and

Glinskaya, 2009; Mendola and Carletto, 2009).

2.4. Norms

Finally, the empirical literature also suggests that gender norms are one of the main drivers of

female labor force participation. Norms are persistent, culturally-specific, and passed down from

generation to generation (Fernandez et al., 2004; Fernandez and Fogli, 2009), but can change over

time (Fernandez, 2013). Agency, economic opportunities, and endowments are linked and often

reinforce gender equality outcomes (Duflo, 2005; 2013). Even when economic opportunities and

endowments are closer to gender equality, social norms can create barriers to success.

These constricting norms shape power relationships and restrict women’s mobility and network,

which in turn shape gender roles regarding time use and household responsibilities. Furthermore,

these usually turn into discriminatory legislation and practices (Klugman 2014, World Bank 2011b).

In the following subsections we provide an overview of some of the relationships between norms

and FLFP. It should be noted that we do not intend to include every aspect of social norms

essentially because norms underly everything.

Social Biases & Gender Norms

27

Firstly, it is well documented that gender social norms restrict women’s activity choices. Muñoz

Boudet et al. (2013) review qualitative studies from 370 focus groups in 20 countries and confirm

that, in contexts where it is considered inappropriate for women to engage socially or commercially

with unrelated men, women’s economic opportunities are restricted (e.g. being forbidden to work

outside of the home). In Pakistan, Adeel et al. (2017) find that, as a result of social norms

constraining women to avoid interaction with men in public spaces, women conduct far fewer trips

outside the home for work than men. Furthermore, when women do travel, the distance is much

shorter. In India, men explicitly state that they do not want their wives to work for pay outside the

home (Field et al., 2016). In Pakistan, a large proportion of women who do not work outside the

home report that their husbands and fathers exclusively made the decision of whether they were

allowed to work (Field and Vyborny, 2016). Norms also dictate how and to whom job opportunities

should be prioritized in context of weak demand for work. Particularly in northern Africa, Eastern

Europe, South Asia and east Asia, respondents to the World Values Survey (Wave 6), indicate that

when jobs are scarce, men should have more right to a job than women.

Unfortunately, the direct causal relationship between norms, men and women's personal

preferences, and women's actual labor market decisions is not well understood. Bernhardt et al

(2018) begin to fill that gap by investigating the extent to which women's versus their husbands'

support for (or opposition to) female labor predicts actual employment decisions. First, they find

evidence of important gender asymmetries in the perceived social costs associated with female

work: respondents report that the husband of a working wife will receive sanction from more

community members than the wife herself. Consistent with this, men are systematically more likely

than women to voice opposition to women working. Though the authors do not have causal

estimates, they find suggestive evidence that the husband’s beliefs about women’s work and the

wife’s perception of her husbands beliefs are stronger predictors of the wife’s employment than the

woman’s own beliefs.

Similarly, in the context of Saudi Arabia, where through the custom of guardianship men dictate

their wive’s labor supply decision, Bursztyn et al (2018) provide experimental evidence that

misperception of social norms is a source of labor market frictions and correcting normative beliefs

yields positive employment outcomes for women. They show that the vast majority of young

married men in Saudi Arabia privately support FLFP outside of home from a normative perspective,

while they substantially underestimate the level of support for FLFP by other similar men. Correcting

these beliefs about others increases married men's willingness to let their wives join the labor force

and this decision maps onto real outcomes: the wives of men whose beliefs about acceptability of

FLFP were corrected are more likely to have sought a job outside of home.

More research is needed to understand the causal effect of norms on FLPF, as well as the extent to

which the preferences of husbands, fathers, and other male figures regarding their women’s

participation in the labor market, relative to the woman’s own preferences, shape women’s supply

of labor.

However, the impact of gender norms on female labor force participation has indeed been largely

observed indirectly. For instance program effects are larger where norms are more equalitarian,

suggesting that more equalitarian norms are positively related with FLFP. By the contrary, countries

with strict gender norms and patriarchal values tend to have lower levels of FLFP. A clear example of

this pattern is observable in the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) region, where in spite of

28

reaching learning equality among boys and girls, FLFP rates are the lowest in the world. Many

authors have tried to provide an explanation to such paradox, and found that patriarchal norms and

personal values explain most of the variation in FLFP (Diwan and Varnatova, 2017; Assaad et al,

2018).

Other research also address the impact of gender roles on FLFP indirectly through evidence from

intrahousehold decision-making model. Lowe and McKelway (2017) use a field experiment to

examine the intrahousehold decision making regarding employment in India. The researchers

partnered with a manufacturing company to offer employment opportunities to married women.

Gender differences in work preferences meant there was an intra-household tension: women were

often interested in working outside of the home, while their husbands opposed the idea. By

experimentally varying the presentation of the work opportunity, the researchers were able to

examine how information and communication affects decisions around female employment.

First, there is no evidence that husbands strategically withhold information from their wives; they

fully disclose information about the employment opportunity and there are no gains to providing

the information to women in addition to or instead of husbands. The authors argue this is because

substantial bargaining power allows husbands to make decisions without needing to withhold

information. Second, bringing women to the decision-making table by encouraging discussion

lowered enrollment by 6 to 9 percentage points, indicating that joint decision-making can backfire,

possibly due to arguments or husband’s resentment of suggested equality in discussions. Finally, the

study finds that symbolically empowering women in decision-making by giving wives enrollment

tickets backfires in the short-run, dramatically raising dropout rates, due to men being less

supportive and accommodating of a decision that was not their own. Taken together, these results

suggest that careful consideration should be devoted to the presentation and encouragement of

women’s involvement in the household take-up decision.

Finally, it is important to note that norms are not fixed and static, and dramatic changes can be

possible. In the United States, for example, in 1936 fewer than 20 percent of people supported the

idea of wives working if husbands could support them. By 1998, that figure had increased to more

than 80 percent (Morton et al 2014). Developing countries have also progressed with respect to

these values according to the UNDP’s Gender Inequality Index, constructed on the basis of questions

such of whether men should have more right to jobs than women. However, the changes are very

different in magnitude. While the highest developed countries have gone from index values of 0.33

to 0.1758 in the past 20 years, developing economies have gone from 0.56 to 0.47.

And, even though a good deal of attention has been paid to the intergenerational cyclicality of

negative gender norms, positive intergenerational effects are possible as well. Fernandez et al.

(2011) argues that the growing presence of a new type of man—one brought up in a family in which

the mother worked—has been a significant factor in the increase in female labor force participation

over time. They present cross-sectional evidence showing that the wives of men whose mothers

worked are themselves significantly more likely to work. Growing up with a working mother either

influenced a man’s preferences for a working wife or directly made him a better partner for a

working woman (say, by increasing his ability to cooperate and be productive in household work).

8 The higher the Gender Inequality Index the higher the gender inequality is in a country.

29

The presence of this different type of man, in turn, made investing in market skills and becoming a

working woman more attractive. As the number of working mothers increased, so did the

proportion of men raised with this different family model, which then helped to increase the relative

supply of working women of the following generation. In this way, women who worked set an

example for their sons, and thus made it easier for the next generation of women to follow in their

footsteps.

In a similar fashion, Olivetti et al (2016) show that mothers and other female role models play an

important role in female labor supply decisions. The authors use the variation in student

composition within schools across cohorts to find that own mothers’ working hours and peers’

mothers’ working hours affect women’s own working hours in the future. They find that the

pathway is likely through transmission of norms rather than possible human capital accumulation

aided by working mothers’ increased investments in their children. Furthermore, peers’ mothers’

labor supply decisions have a larger impact when the adolescent girl is socially closer to her peers’

mothers.

Safety & Mobility

As with social norms and women’s economic activity, it is also a stylized fact that women’s mobility

is often constrained by risk of violence/harassment, lack of access to transportation, and gender

norms (Salon and Gulyani, 2010; Anand and Tiwari, 2006). This mobility constraint inevitably reduces

women’s labor supply. However, the extent to which mobility constraints are binding in inhibiting

entry into the labor market has not been widely empirically documented (Borker, 2017).

In developing countries, safety concerns and limited access to transport reduce the probability of

women participating in the labor market by 16.5%, with serious consequences on the economy: the

global GDP could grow by an additional $5.8 trillion if the gender gap in male and female labor force

participation is decreased by 25% by 2025 (ILO WESO Report, 2017). In response to these safety

concerns, countries as varied as Brazil, Egypt, India, Japan, and Mexico have offered women-only

transport options, such as women-only carriages on trains and cabs specifically for women, driven by

women. However, to our knowledge, there is still no evidence of the impact of these policies on

female labor participation.

In a related context, Borker (2017) builds a willingness-to-pay model for travel safety and finds that

young women in Delhi are willing to choose a lower quality university at which to study or pay an

additional nearly $300 than men to have a safer route to commute to university. This quantification

of the trade-offs that women make in educational decisions implies that mobility constraints are

likely impacting women’s labor force participation decisions as well.

3. External Constraints

Finally, another competing hypothesis to the belief that economic factors are the main drivers of

female labor force participation is the external constraints hypothesis. It is a fact that governemnt

policies, shifts in technology, and social protection schemes directly impact worker’s labor supply. If

these affect workers differently by gender, then we would expect that external factors also affect

the female labor supply. We focus on two main external constrains: income shocks and labor

30

demand. As in the internal constraints literature, evidence exploring the relationship between

female LFP and the constraints is limited. The most important evidence follows.

3.1. Income Shocks

In households where men are traditionally the wage-earners and women are responsible for home

production, increased employment uncertainty faced by men can lead to increased uncertainty in

household income. In periods of economic uncertaintly, two opposing forces affect female labor

force participation: the income effect predicts that women who are secondary wage earners will

tend to temporarily increase labor supply when their husbands suffer unemployment (known as the

added worker effect, AWE), while the substitution effect predicts that unfavorable economic

conditions will lead to discouragement and operate in the opposite direction. On the other hand, in

periods of economic growth, the income effect predics that lower unemployment and higher

earnings of male partners and the consolidation of social safety nets will alleviate women's pressure

to look for a job and negatively affect their LFP.

In practice, the strength of these effects depend on the relevance of other factors, such as the

availability of alternative strategies to cope with negative income shocks (child labor, unemployment

insurance, etc.) and the existence of imperfect credit markets together with liquidity constraints. For

instance, using data for the US, Mankart and Oikonomou (2016) find that households provide

insurance against labor income shocks---when the primary earner (the husband) becomes

unemployed, the wife joins the labor force. However, unemployment insurance distort this dynamic

because wives have less incentives to leave the labor force in the first place. Similarly, Garcia-Perez

and Rendon (2020) find that the AWE holds for the US labor market but the unemployment

insurance may significantly alter the labor decisions of married couples due to a reassignment of the

breadwinner role from men to women.

In developing economies the income effect may be larger because they usually lack extended

unemployment insurance benefits, many households face financial restrictions, and the role of

women as secondary workers is reinforced by solid traditional family structures with a strong

attachment to traditional gender roles, and low levels of women’s skills and educational attainment.

In addition, given the importance of the informal sector in the countries of the region, entry and exit

barriers in the labor market are relatively low, which facilitates changes in female participation (Basu

et al., 2014; Maloney, 2004).

Serrano et al (2017) find empirical evidence consistent with such a model using fixed effects

estimation of female labor force participation across eighteen Latin American countries between

1987 and 2014. The authors find a countercyclical pattern where better economic conditions for

primary workers cause a delay in secondary workers’ entrance into the labor market. This

relationship is stronger for married women (either in formal or consensual unions) that are rural

areas, and in low income households. They also provide evidence that the expansion in conditional

cash transfer programs is another relevant factor associated to the deceleration in female labor

supply in Latin America. In particular, the authors find that an increase in the coverage of such

transfers is associated with a fall in female LFP. This result is consistent with the hypothesis that

women decide to delay their entrance to the labor market due to higher unearned income and to

the time required to comply with the conditionalities associated with these programs.

31

There are several empirical studies that analyze the validity of the AWE hypothesis in the region. For

instance, Martinoty (2015) uses the collapse of the Argentina’s convertibility regime as a natural

experiment to evaluate the effect of husbands’ labor situation changes in the decision of their wives’

participation, finding evidence of a statistically significant AWE. Similar results are found by Cerrutti

(2000) and Paz (2009) also for Argentina in the 1990s and 2000s, respectively, Fernandes and Felicio

(2005) for Brazil, and Parker and Skoufias (2004) for Mexico. On the other hand, McKenzie (2003a)

and MacKenzie (2003b) find no evidence on the presence of AWE when studying household

strategies to compensate the negative shocks from the financial crises of 2002 in Argentina and 1995

in Mexico, respectively.

In a more recent work, Bhalotra and Umaña-Aponte (2010) use individual data from 63 developing

countries combined in a cross-country panel with aggregate variables such as GDP for the period

1986-2006. They find that the relationship between female labor and growth is negative on average

for Latin America and Asia, but positive for Africa, which, the authors suggest, is due to a

conventional family structure where income pooling is less the norm and there are fewer

opportunities for paid employment. The authors argue that the characteristics that magnify the

countercyclical pattern include the low levels of education, the positive assortative mating among

the less educated, rural residence, and high fertility, among other factors related to limited wealth.

Overall, these findings suggest that insurance motives underpin the dynamics of women’s work

participation.

3.2. Labor Demand

Increase in labor demand can both improve the employment rate among individuals already in the

labor force, and potentially increase female labor force participation among women who were not

previously working, who see accessible labor demand.

There are several ways in which changes in demand for employment (both perceived and actual)

affect female labor force participation. These can be divided in two broad categories: (i)

macroeconomic policies that lead to increased employment demand through public work, quotas, or

sectoral shifts; (ii) and firm-level policies affecting the costs and incentives to hire women.

Macroeconomic Policies

Many countries implement public works programs in order to build infrastructure and decrease

unemployment. Descriptive evidence suggests that these programs are associated with gains in

female labor force participation. Furthermore, these public works projects often demand low-skilled

labor, meaning that even those individuals who previously were not engaged with the labor force

can easily pick up the necessary skills on the job. This is particularly important for women, as women

tend to have lower skills and target low-skilled labor.

One example of such a program is the National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (NREGA) in India.

In this program, all households are eligible for 100 days of employment, which can be split between

adults in the household. The guaranteed work is low-skilled manual labor. However, about 30% of

jobs are reserved specifically for women. The program was developed to appeal to women

(especially women outside the labor force) as it guaranteed provision of work, pay that is equal

across genders and higher than prevailing wages for women, work is provided locally, and ensures

on-site child care. In a survey of female NREGA workers in 2008, about half said that if they hadn’t

32

been working through NREGA, they would not have been working at all (Khera and Nayak 2009).9

Using a natural experiment exploiting phases of implementation, Azam (2012) finds that NREGA has

a positive impact on labor force participation and wages, and both of these impacts are primarily

driven by impacts on female workers. Given that NREGA was designed to ease multiple constraints,

unclear which was the main factor (or combination of) responsible for observed increases in FLPF.

Again in India, Ghani et al (2013) find that female leaders allocate more jobs in the national public

works program to women, through local implementation, thus increasing demand for female labor

directly. Furthermore, there is a growing literature that points that increasing access to public goods

that women care about, such as roads and healthcare, under female political leaders, led to greater

female labor force participation (see Priyanka, 2019). Thus, evidence points that quotas for women

(by increasing the demand for labor, even if jobs are not expanding overall) can have an effect on

female participation. Then, the question is whether such quotas are desirable from a more general

economic perspective such as in tems of productivity impacts—i.e. it could be the case that impacts

are mixed depending on whether the jobs are high/low skills, but there is no enough evidence to

address this relationship.

Government economic reforms can also affect the female LFP. In Bangladesh, the government

pushed an aggressive economic reform to foster the export-oriented garment industry during the

decade of 1980. Heath and Mobarak (2015) study the impact of the increased labor demand due to

growth in this industry, which rewards literacy and numeracy skills. Using a difference-in-differences

approach, they find that growing up in a village that was within commutable distance of a garment

factory increases a woman’s probability of having ever worked outside the home, in any sector, by

about 13 percentage points. Furthermore, women who grew up in such villages attained higher

education and delayed childbearing, arguably in response to this noticeable labor demand in

garment factories for young women who had completed secondary school.

Similarly, liberalization of trade may also impact female LFP. For instance, the government of Brazil

reduced the trade protection during the 1987-1994 period. Gaddis and Pieters (2017) explore the

relationship between this reform and female LFP in the following years. Exploiting the geographic

exogenous variation in exposure to tariff reductions across states due to the trade liberalization and

find that tariff reductions were associated with an increase in female labor force participation and

employment after two years. The effect is explained by a shift of the economy from agriculture and

manufacturing (male-dominated industries) to trade and other services. Kis-Katos et al. (2017) also

explore the impact of trade liberalization of female labor outcomes for Indonesia. Using a similar

approach—exploiting geographic variation in tariffs—they find that the trade liberalization increased

employment and work hours for women. However, they do not find significant results on female

labor force participation, suggesting that impacts are driven by work on the intensive margin.

Worker Protection & Firm Incentives

9 One concern with growth in low-skilled labor demand for women, is that it might draw older girls out of school and into

the labor market (Sundaram and Vanneman 2008). However, Afridi et al (2013) actually find the converse in Andhra

Pradesh, India, in response to NREGA: their study finds that greater participation of mothers in NREGA compared to fathers

is associated with increased schooling of daughters.

33

Governments implement a variety of policies targeted at establishing equal employment

opportunity between men and women. Such policies include paid maternity leave, restrictions to

working hours, worker protections making it illegal to terminate a woman’s employment due to

pregnancy, and support for better provision of care services. These policies pose an interesting

contrast between the potential impact of these policies on women’s incentives to participate in the

labor market and firm’s incentives to hire women. They move in opposite directions, thus it is

unclear whether in the end the net effect of them on FLFP is positive or negative (i.e. because firms

would reduce demand for female labor, and reduced demand has a negative impact on

participation).

On one hand, such policies are designed to promote women’s employment—by placing legal

barriers to prevent firms from firing women or refusing to hire women due to fertility-related factors

such as pregnancy and early maternity care, or allowing women flexibility in working hours to ease

their ability to multitask wage work and housework and childcare obligations. Consistent with this,

Blau and Kahn (2013) study the relative decline in female labor force participation in the United

States compared to other OECD countries between the late 1990s and 2010. They find that over the

same time period as the decline, other OECD nations implemented family-friendly policies such as

length of parental leave, right to part-time work, equal treatment of part-time workers, and public

child care spending as a share of GDP, while the US did not. However, this increase in female labor

force participation in other OECD countries might be masking as shift to part-time work or lower-

level positions. Literature exploring these issues in developing countries is scarce because such

policies are rare to begin with and, moreover, an important proportion of women work in the

informal sector (Heath and Jayachandran, 2016).

Conversely, mandating that firms must provide maternity leave increases the costs to a firm for

hiring a woman in her childbearing years. As she is at high risk of fertility, the firm would expect to

have to pay wages during her maternity leave, without actually receiving the benefits of her labor.

Furthermore, there are transaction costs associated with hiring extra temporary labor, or reshuffling

work assignments to account for her time on maternity leave. Thus, mandating that a female

worker cannot be fired due to pregnancy and mandating paid maternity leave disincentivizes hiring

of female workers and leads to a downward shift of the labor demand curve. This could drive down

female employment rates and in turn discourage female labor force participation. Comparing

women of childbearing age to women past peak fertility in Colombia before and after enactment of

legislation which extended maternity leave by two weeks, Bustamante et al (2015) find that the

legislation led to a decrease of 0.7 percentage points in female labor force participation among

women of childbearing age who have more than a high school education, and a decrease of 0.9

percentage points for women with less than a high school education10. However, the study also

finds that women of childbearing age are more likely to be self-employed or working in the informal

sector after the policy change. Taken together, the results are consistent with a model where formal

employers have increased costs in hiring women of childbearing age after the policy change, and

women thus shift to self-employment or informal work or dropping out of the labor force

altogether.

10 Paternity leave is not guaranteed in this setting.

34

Legislation in Taiwan that restricted women’s working hours and mandated employer-provided

maternity benefits had more mixed effects. In a study looking at employment (rather than LFPF)

Zveglich and Rodgers (2003) exploit variation before and after the law went into effect in 1984, and

across sectors where the law did and did not apply (i.e., industry versus services), and find that

restricting working hours decreased the employment rate of women, while mandating maternity

benefits increased employment rates. The maternity leave result is in the opposite direction as what

Bustamante et al. (2015) find in Colombia. This may be explained because women in the service

sector were already de factor taking leave (more flexible, there is a reason why they sort themselves

into services and away from other sectors). This is consistent with a model where female workers

value maternity leave benefits more than the costs in Taiwan, but that the opposite is true in

Colombia.

In the United States, Gruber (1994) exploits variation in state and federal laws regarding whether

maternity benefits are mandated to be covered by health insurance, to estimate the effects of such

a mandate on the labor market. The study finds that employers shifted these costs onto employees,

but that employment probabilities did not change. However, the paper does not measure labor

force participation directly. In general, the literature is unclear on whether policies aimed to boost

LFP by protencting workers are offset by the incentives for firms to not hire workers due to higher

costs—in particular because there are not enough studies looking at FLPF (rather than employment).

POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS & AREAS FOR FURTHER RESEARCH

This review of drivers of FLFP has pointed out to different barriers that inhibit women from entering

and participating in the labor force. In the case of endowments, and specifically time, women’s

disproportionate burden of fertility, carework and home production, limit their labor supply.

Education, particularly in the form of job training, can boost FLFP. However, women seem to receive

disproportionately less training, both from the supply side – firms are less likely to favor women in

training – and from the demand side – women may demand less training given financial constraint

or lack of information. Financial constraints, in general, affect the ability to start a business or thrive

as self-employed. And although the relationship between access to finance and FLFP is still

debatable, women are often excluded from the financial market.

In the case of internal constraints, this review has shown how women’s labor force participation may

be negatively affected if perception of opportunities is scarce and the work environment is too

competitive, given women’s stronger aversion to compete. Other internal constraints that may also

hinder FLFP are lower perception of own skills and lack of confidence in the ability to obtain a job, as

self-confidence in general is a key driver of labor force participation.

This review also shows that there are external drivers of FLFP. Within this driver, the most relevant is

that of social norms. When norms are not inclusive or equalitarian, even economic opportunities

and endowments cannot offset them, and FLFP is likely to be lower. Persistence of social biases and

gender norms are a barrier to women’s participation in the labor market. Finally, one of the most

straightforward drivers of FLFP is labor demand. When labor demand is expanded, women who

were not previously working change their perception of accessible labor. If there are programs

specifically targeted to them, then FLFP will increase. Similarly, regulation with respect to worker’s

protection with a gender scope can help boost FLFP. However, if firms are mandated to establish

35

regulation that favors women, and this regulation is costlier on them, then they might be

disincentivize to hire women and thus imposing an additional barrier for FLFP.

As noted by the international literature, not all these barriers are present or represent a constraint

in every context. This section focuses on policy recommendations that lift constraints along the

abovementioned drivers. We must highlight that although the aim of these policy recommendations

is to increase female labor force participation, this should not be a means on itself. As we have seen

throughout the review, boosting FLFP can induce an equilibrium of lower wages, informal work and

job segregation for women. These potential outcomes should be considered when designing a policy

to increase FLFP. Such policies should be accompanied by interventions that ensure good quality

jobs.

While rising female participation rates are good for economic development (Goldin, 1990), the

welfare implication for women is less clear. To the extent that women are dropping out of

undesirable work due to improved household conditions, they may be better off. Thus, it is

important to note the push and pull factors that are at play in each context to understand the

welfare implications of FLFP. This is an area that requires further research. Other areas of research

and policy recommendations follow.

Understanding the relationships among fertility and female labor force participation are key. As

recounted above, the sign and degree of the relationship between fertility and mother’s work

behavior is often mediated by the country’s stage of economic development (Aaronson et al 2017).

But is never as straight forward as developed – developing countries. While additional evidence is

needed to understand the dynamics of the relationship, some policy recommendations can be draw

from the existing literature. The evidence has shown that expanding women’s legal access to family

planning services can expand their agency and allow for delayed childbearing (when preferred), and

boost women’s labor force participation. Beyond fertility services, it is also critical for societies to

provide access to high-quality, affordable, accessible care services or technologies that ease the time

burden of domestic tasks. This is demonstrated in several rigorous studies, ranging from Brazil to

China. Getting the exact details right, such as how to structure prices and whether care facilities

should be private, public, or a mix, will depend on the specific context.

Furthermore, while formal care provision is key, support for informal caregivers is also necessary

since families will likely continue to provide some unpaid care within the household. There are a

variety of different approaches and systems, tax incentives and allowances for care givers and/or

recipients (World Bank Group, 2015). The details of each policy are very important in shaping

women’s opportunities and constraints. However, depending on who bears the cost of these

policies, which are designed to reduce barriers for women of childbearing age, they can have mixed

impacts on female labor force participation. Notably, while policies addressing childcare have been

relatively well studied, understanding the needs of caregivers for the elderly and other care

recipients is an emerging area of research. As populations age globally, investing in more research in

this area is recommended. In addition, future research would be useful in better understanding the

impacts of the different policies suggested above, and in providing country-specific guidance on how

to get the mix right.

Regarding the acquisition of skills, additional research is needed in targeted incentive programs that

increase educational attainment, to see if this is an effective lever across contexts, what longer-run

36

impacts it can have on female labor force participation, and how best to implement these policies.

Up until now, evidence of the impact of additional years of schooling on FLFP is not conclusive.

On another hand, acquiring skills through training programs may be able to improve female labor

force participation – but the evidence for this is generally mixed and indirect, with much of the

success is dependent on the economic context and the exact structure of the program. While there

are many studies of training programs, they are quite heterogeneous (notably, in the skills taught,

duration of training, and incentives for employers to hire graduates) and show mixed results. Some

of the most successful training programs to date (in terms of changing employment rates) have been

driven by soft skills training, which focuses on self-esteem, decision-making, and agency, but this has

not been true across all contexts. To disentangle the differences in structure and skills and

understand the direct impact on FLFP, further analyses of the existing literature and more targeted,

systematic research is required.

Promoting women’s financial inclusion is a very important policy tool in improving female labor

force participation and other outcomes for women’s empowerment. The gap in women’s access to

finance is well-documented, and several policy options aim to tackle it: microcredit, savings

products, provision of bank accounts, individual direct deposit wages, psychometric scoring in place

of collateral, digital financial products and services, and self-help groups, among others. While some

of these policy options, such as psychometric scoring, are relatively new, others, such as microcredit,

have a plethora of research exploring their impacts. Studies have shown that accessing self-help

groups, microfinance, and microcredit, can improve women’s labor force participation. However,

more research studying the direct links between financial inclusion and female labor force

participation is needed to inform policies, and some of the specific approaches, such as

psychometric scoring as collateral, require additional study.

Exploiting social networks and capital is a way of reducing information asymmetries in the labor

markets. The literature does not point to women having a disadvantaged position in terms of

acquiring social capital in general. However, not all social ties are the same. On one side, tight

connections with family members offer women the possibility of entering the labor force by proving

childcare options. Weaker connections, but far reaching, on another side, increase the likelihood of

women entering the labor market. This is especially true when connections are with high status

individuals. However, as pointed by Puga and Soto (2018), such networks are unequal along the

income distribution. Thus, policy that focus on increasing social capital should be mindful of both the

type and distribution of these networks.

Lifting internal constraints for labor participation is a less explored policy arena, but there are some

positive experiences from which to learn from. Recruitment services, such as those studied in India

(Jensen, 2012), can increase women’s perception of availability of opportunities. In turn, higher

perception increase women bargaining power within the household, regardless of whether they end

up working or not. Instituting less competitive environments in the workplace, given the studied

lower aversion to compete of women, might also impact FLFP. However, this might reinforce the

gender-specific employment patterns, which would be concerning if these are sectors at the same

time more profitable. As explained by Bernhart et al. (2019), policies that support female

entrepreneurs to migrate to male-dominated sectors could prevent the gendered sorting.

Regarding social norms, studies indicate that strong female role models matter, so mentorship

programs may be useful, but more research on their potential links to FLFP is needed. As seen

37

above, mobility concerns directly connect to women’s labor decisions, as women cannot travel to

work if they are unable to do so by gender norms or safety constraints. Examining potential

connections between safe transit and women’s labor force participation and employment is a

growing area of research and policy intervention.

Up until now, policy options have been discussed from the supply-side. But of course, women’s labor

force participation also depends on demand-side factors. To address informational asymmetries

between women and employers, job referral and targeted recruitment of women for new industries

has shown to increase labor force participation. Governmental labor policies, such as mandated

maternity leave, can also impact female labor force participation. However, as highlighted before,

depending on the policy details, the impact may be positive or negative. The empirical evidence on

such policies is generally consistent with the expected mixed effects, though more research

specifically focusing on female labor force participation is needed.

As explored in this review, development policies can have a myriad of impacts on female labor force

participation. Most policies have ambiguous theoretical impacts on female labor supply, and in most

cases, the empirical evidence is also mixed. What the literature does tell us, however, is that the

impact of policies on female labor force participation depends on how the policies interact with

other aspects of the economy. Policies that alter female labor demand can only improve female

labor force participation if they address the unique constraints that women face: if women in the

population are sufficiently freed from home production, if they have sufficient skills and

qualifications to meet the labor demand, if they have access to finance, if they are not constrained

by cultural norms, and more. Policies that alter female labor supply can also only affect female labor

force participation if firms are willing to hire women and pay them sufficient wages.

Finally, although the focus of this review was on female labor force participation, many of the

studies reviewed in this paper focus on employment rate, since that is a more readily accessible

measure. However, measuring employment rate or entrepreneurship probability is not enough to

provide evidence on improving female labor market outcomes. Future research should take

advantage of existing labor force surveys or more nuanced measures of labor force participation in

primary data collection to shed light on barriers to female labor force participation specifically.

38

REFERENCES

A, C. M., Puentes, E., and Ruiz-Tagle, J. (2017). The effects of micro entrepreneurship program on

labor market performance: Experimental evidence from Chile.

Aaronson, D., Dehejia, R., Jordan, A., Pop-Eleches, C., Samii, C., and Schulze, K. (2017). The Effect of

Fertility on Mothers' Labor Supply Over the Past Two Centuries. NBER Working Paper Series. National

Bureau of Economic Research.

Abel, S. M., Burger, R. P., and Piraino, P. (2017). The value of reference letters. The World Bank,

Policy Research Working Paper Series: 8266.

Acevedo, P., Cruces, G., Gertler, P., and Martinez, S. (2017). Living Up to Expectations: How Job

Training Made Women Better Off and Men Worse Off.

Adeel, M., Yeh, A. G. O., and Zhang, F. (2016). Gender inequality in mobility and mode choice in

Pakistan. Transportation, 44(6), 1519-1534.

Adoho, F., Chakravarty, S., Korkoyah, Jr, D.T., Lundberg, M. and Tasneem, A. (2014) "The impact of

an adolescent girls employment program : the EPAG project in Liberia," Policy Research Working

Paper Series 6832, The World Bank.

Afridi, F., Mukhopadhyay, A., and Sahoo, S. (2013). Female Labour-Force Participation and Child

Education in India: The Effect of the National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme. Young Lives: An

International Study of Childhood Poverty Working Paper.

Agüero, J. M., and Marks, M. S. (2008). Motherhood and Female Labor Force Participation: Evidence

from Infertility Shocks. American Economic Review, 98(2), 500-504. doi:10.1257/aer.98.2.500

Akerlof, G. A., and Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and Identity*. Quarterly Journal of Economics,

115(3), 715–753.

Albanesi, S., & Olivetti, C. (2007). Gender Roles and Technological Progress. National Bureau of

Economic Research Working Paper Series, No. 13179.

Albertini, M., M. Kohli, and C. Vogel. (2007). Intergenerational Transfers of Time and Money in

European Families: Common Patterns, Different Regimes?” Journal of European Social Policy 319–

334.

39

Alesina, A., Giuliano, P., and Nunn, N. (2013). On the Origins of Gender Roles: Women and the

Plough. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(2), 469-530.

Alibhai, S., Buehren, N., Coleman, R., Goldstein, M., and Strobbe, F. (2018). Disruptive Finance: Using

Psychometrics to Overcome Collateral Constraints in Ethiopia. 10.1596/29746.

Alibhai, S., Buehren, N., Papineni, S., and Pierotti, R. (2017). Crossovers: Female Entrepreneurs Who

Enter Male Sectors. Evidence from Ethiopia. World Bank Group Policy Research Working Paper 8065.

Alibhai, Salman; Buehren, Niklas; Papineni, Sreelakshmi; Pierotti, Rachael. (2017). Crossovers--

Female Entrepreneurs Who Enter Male Sectors : Evidence from Ethiopia. Policy Research Working

PaperNo. 8065. World Bank, Washington, DC.

Altonji, J., and Blank, R. (1999). Race and Gender in the Labor Market Handbook of Labor Economics

(Vol. 3).

Alzua, M. L., Cruces, G., and Ripani, L. (2013). Welfare programs and labor supply in developing

countries: experimental evidence from Latin America. Journal of Population Economics, 26, 1255-

1284.

Anand, A. and G. Tiwari (2006). “A Gendered Perspective of the Shelter– Transport–Livelihood Link:

The Case of Poor Women in Delhi.” Transport Reviews 26(1): 63–80.

Angrist, J. D., and Evans, W. N. (1998). Children and Their Parents' Labor Supply: Evidence from

Exogenous Variation in Family Size. The American Economic Review, 88(3), 450-477.

Arthi, V., Beegle, K., De Weerdt, J., & Palacios-López, A. (2018). Not your average job: Measuring

farm labor in Tanzania. Journal of Development Economics, 130, 160-172.

Asian Development Bank. (2015). Policy Brief: A Safe Public Transportation Environment For Women

And Girls. Policy Brief. Asian Development Bank.

Assaad, Ragui A. and Hendy, Rana and Lassassi, Moundir and Yassin, Shaimaa, Explaining the MENA

Paradox: Rising Educational Attainment, Yet Stagnant Female Labor Force Participation. IZA

Discussion Paper No. 11385.

Attanasio, O., and M. Vera-Hernandez. (2004). Medium and Long Run Effects of Nutrition and Child

Care: Evaluation of a Community Nursery Programme in Rural Colombia. The Institute for Fiscal

Studies.

Attanasio, O., Kugler, A., & Meghir, C. (2011). Subsidizing Vocational Training for Disadvantaged

Youth in Colombia: Evidence from a Randomized Trial. American Economic Journal: Applied

Economics, 3(3), 188-220. doi:10.1257/app.3.3.188

Bailey, M. J. (2006). More Power To The Pill: The Impact Of Contraceptive Freedom On Women’s Life

Cycle Labor Supply. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(1), 288-320.

Baker, M., Gruber, J., & Milligan, K. (2008). Universal Child Care, Maternal Labor Supply, and Family

Well‐Being. Journal of Political Economy, 116(4), 709-745.

Bandiera, O., Buehren, N., Burgess, R., Goldstein, M., Gulesci, S., Rasul, I., & Sulaiman, M. (2017).

Women's Empowerment in Action: Evidence from a Randomized Control Trial in Africa.

Banerjee, A., Hanna, R., Kreindler, G and Olken, B. (2015). Debunking the stereotype of the lazy

welfare recipient: evidence from cash transfer programs worldwide. MIT working paper

40

Banerjee, A., Hanna, R., Kreindler, G., & Olken, B. A. Debunking the Stereotype of the Lazy Welfare

Recipient: Evidence from Cash Transfer Programs Worldwide. World Bank Research Observer.

Basu, A. K.; Chau, N. and R. Kanbur (2011). “Contractual dualism, market power and informality”. IZA

Discussion Papers, No. 5845, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).

Beaman, L., Keleher, N., & Magruder, J. (2016). Do Job Networks Disadvantage Women? Evidence

from a Recruitment Experiment in Malawi.

Becker, G. S. (1991). A Treatise on the Family: Enlarged Edition: Harvard University Press.

Beegle, K., & Gaddis, I. (2017). Informal employment in Africa: What do we know and what can we

do to know more? Paper presented at the World Statistics Congress, Marrakech.

Berlinksi, S., & Galiani, S. (2007). The effect of a large expansion of pre-primary school facilities on

preschool attendance and maternal employment. Labour Economics, 14(3), 665-680.

Berlinski, S. and S. Galiani 2007. “The effect of a large expansion of pre-primary school facilities on

preschool attendance and maternal employment”. Labour Economics.

Bernhardt, A., Field, E., Pande, R. & Rigol, N. (2019). “Household Matters: Revisiting the Returns to

Capital among Female Microentrepreneurs.” American Economic Review: Insights. 1: 141-160.

Bernhardt, A., Field, E., Pande, R., Rigol, N, Schaner, S. and Troyer-Moore, C. (2018). “Male Social

Status and Women’s Work,” AEA Papers and Proceedings, 108: 363–67.

Berniell, María Inés, and Carolina Sánchez-Páramo. 2011. “Overview of Time Use Data Used for the

Analysis of Gender Differences in Time Use Patterns.”

Bertrand, M., Crepon, B., Marguerie, A., & Premand, P. (2017). Contemporaneous and Post-Program

Impacts of a Public Works Program: Evidence from Cote d'Ivoire.

Bhalotra, S., & Umaña-Aponte, M. (2010). The Dynamics of Women’s Labour Supply in Developing

Countries. IZA Discussion Paper Series. IZA.

Bianchi, S. M., Sayer, L. C., Milkie, M. A., & Robinson, J. P. (2012). Housework: Who Did, Does or Will

Do It, and How Much Does It Matter? Soc Forces, 91(1), 55-63. doi:10.1093/sf/sos120

Blau, F. D., & Kahn, L. M. (2013). Female Labor Supply: Why Is the United States Falling Behind?

American Economic Review, 103(3), 251-256.

Blau, F. D., & Kahn, L. M. (2017). The Gender Wage Gap: Extent, Trends, and Explanations. Journal of

Economic Literature, 55(3), 789-865.

Bloom, D. E., Canning, D., Fink, G., & Finlay, J. E. (2009). Fertility, female labor force participation,

and the demographic dividend. Journal of Economic Growth, 14(2), 79-101.

Borker, G. (2017). Safety First: Perceived Risk of Street Harassment and Educational Choices of

Women.

Browning, M. (1992). “Children and Household Economic Behavior.” Journal of Economic Literature

1434-1475.

Bustamante, N. R., Uribe, A. M. T., & Vargas, C. O. (2015). Maternity and Labor Markets: Impact of

Legislation in Colombia. IDB Working Paper Series. IDB.

41

Caceres-Delpiano, Julio (2008). Keeping the best for last. impact of fertility on mother’s employment:

evidence from developing countries. Economics Working Papers, 08-68. Madrid: Universidad Carlos

III, Departamento de Economia.

Calderon, G. (2012). The Effects of Child Care Provision in Mexico. Stanford: Stanford University.

Can, T. (1994). Sexual Harassment in China. Chinese Education & Society, 27(4), 39-47.

Cao (2019): Cao, Y. (2019). Fertility and labor supply: evidence from the One-Child Policy in

China. Applied Economics, 51(9), 889-910.

Card, D., Ibarraran, P., Regalia, F., Rosas-Shady, D., & Soares, Y. (2011). The Labor Market Impacts of

Youth Training in the Dominican Republic. Journal of Labor Economics, 29(2), 267-300.

Carvajal, K.G., and Alam, M.M. (2018). Transport is not gender-neutral. World Bank Group blog.

Retrieved 4/24/2018.

Cascio (2009): Cascio, E. U. (2009). Maternal labor supply and the introduction of kindergartens into

American public schools. Journal of Human resources, 44(1), 140-170.

Cerrutti, M. (2000). Economic Reform, Structural Adjustment and Female Labor Force Participation

in Buenos Aires, Argentina. World Development, 28(5), 879-891.

Clarke 2016: Damian Clarke, 2016. "Fertility and Causality" CSAE Working Paper Series 2016-32,

Centre for the Study of African Economies, University of Oxford.

Coffman, Katherine B., Manuela Collis, and Leena Kulkarni. (2019) "Stereotypes and Belief

Updating." Harvard Business School Working Paper, No. 19-068, January 2019.

Connelly, R. (1992). The Effect of Child Care Costs on Married Women's Labor Force Participation.

The Review of Economic and Statistics, 74(1), 83-90.

Cruces, G., & Galiani, S. (2007). Fertility and female labor supply in Latin America: New causal

evidence. Labour Economics, 14(3), 565-573.

Dasso, R., & Fernandez, F. (2015). The effects of electrification on employment in rural Peru. IZA

Journal of Labor & Development, 4(1).

de Barros, R.P., P. Olinto, T. Lunde, and M. Carvalho. (2011). The Impact of Access to Free Childcare

on Women's Labor Market Outcomes: Evidence from a Randomized Trial in Low-income

Neighborhoods of Rio de Janeiro.

De Mel et al (2014) in Sri Lanka. De Mel, S., McKenzie, D., & Woodruff, C. (2014). Business training

and female enterprise start‐ up, growth, and dynamics: Experimental evidence from Sri Lanka,

Journal of Development Economics, 106(1), pp 199‐210.

Del Boca, D., and M. Locatelli. (2006). The Determinants of Motherhood and Work Status: A

Survey. Bonn: The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).

Demirguc-Kunt, A., Klapper, L., Singer, D., & Oudheusden, P. V. (2015). The Global Findex Database

2014: Measuring Financial Inclusion Around the World. Policy Research Working Paper 7255. World

Bank Group.

Desai, R. M., & Joshi, S. (2014). Collective Action and Community Development: Evidence from Self-

Help Groups in Rural India. The World Bank Economic Review, 28(3), 492-524.

42

Deutsch, R. (1998). Does Child Care Pay? Labor Force Participation and Earning Effects of Access to

Child Care in the Favelas of Rio de Janeiro. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.

Dhar, D., Jain, T., & Jayachandran, S. (2016). Intergenerational Transmission of Gender Attitudes:

Evidence from India.

Diaz, M. M., & Rodriguez-Chamussy, L. (2016). Cashing in on Education: Women, Childcare, and

Prosperity in Latin America and the Caribbean: The World Bank.

Dinkelman, T. (2011). The Effects of Rural Electrification on Employment: New Evidence from South

Africa. American Economic Review, 101(7), 3078-3108.

Diwan, Ishac, and Irina Vartanova. 2017. “The Effect Of Patriarchal Culture On Women’s Labor Force

Participation”.

Duflo, E. (2003). Grandmothers and Granddaughters: Old‐Age Pensions and Intrahousehold

Allocation in South Africa. World Bank Economic Review, 17(1), 1-25.

Duflo, E. (2005) Gender Equality in Development, BREAD Policy Paper 001, Durham, NC: Bureau for

Research in Economic Analysis of Development, Duke University

Duflo, E. (2012) ‘Women’s Empowerment and Economic Development’, Journal of Economic

Literature 50.4: 1051-79

Eduardo Rodrigues-Oreggia & Samuel Freije, 2012. "Long term impact of a Cash-Transfers Program

on Labor Outcomes of the Rural Youth," CID Working Papers 230, Center for International

Development at Harvard University.

Edwards and Field-Hendrey 2002: Edwards, Linda N. and Field-Hendrey, Elizabeth, (2002), Home-

Based Work and Women's Labor Force Decisions, Journal of Labor Economics, 20, issue 1, p. 170-

200.

Evertsson, M. (2004). Formal On-the-Job Training: A Gender-Typed Experience and Wage-Related

Advantage? European Sociological Review, 20(1), 79–94. doi:10.1093/esr/20.1.79

Fernandez, R. (2013). Cultural Change as Learning: The Evolution of Female Labor Force Participation

over a Century. American Economic Review 103(1), 472–500.

Fernandez, R. and A. Fogli (2009). Culture: An Empirical Investigation of Beliefs, Work, and Fertility.

American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1 (1), 146–177.

Fernandez, R., & Fogli, A. (2009). Culture: An Empirical Investigation of Beliefs, Work, and Fertility.

American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(1), 146-177.

Fernandez, R., A. Fogli, and C. Olivetti (2004). Mothers and Sons: Preference Formation and Female

Labor Force Dynamics. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(4), 1249–1299.

Fernández, Raquel. 2013. "Cultural Change as Learning: The Evolution of Female Labor Force

Participation over a Century." American Economic Review, 103 (1): 472-500.

Field, E., & Vyborny, K. (2016). Female Labor Force Participation: Pakistan Country Study for the

Asian Development Bank.

Field, E., Pande, R., Rigol, N., Schaner, S., & Moore, C. T. (2016). On Her Account: Can Strengthening

Women's Financial Control Boost Female Labor Supply?

43

Field, Erica, Seema Jayachandran, and Rohini Pande. 2010. “Do Traditional Institutions Constrain

Female Entrepreneurship? A Field Experiment on Business Training in India.” American Economic

Review, 100(2): 125–29.

Fitzpatrick, M. D. (2012). Revising our thinking about the relationship between maternal labor supply

and preschool. Journal of Human Resources, 47(3), 583-612.

Fong, M., and M. Lokshin. 2000. Child Care and Women's Labor Force Participation in Romania. The

World Bank.

Foster, A., & Rosenzweig, M. (1996). Comparative Advantage, Information and the Allocation of

Workers to Tasks: Evidence from an Agricultural Labour Market. The Review of Economic Studies,

63(3), 347-374.

Gaddis, I. and J. Pieters (2017). “Trade Liberalization and Female Labor Force Participation: Evidence

from Brazil”. The Journal of Human Resources, 52(2).

Gaddis, I., & Klasen, S. (2014). Economic development, structural change, and women’s labor force

participation: A reexamination of the feminization U hypothesis. Journal of Population Economics,

27, 639-681.

Gaddis, I., & Pieters, J. (2017). The Gendered Labor Market Impacts of Trade Liberalization. Journal

of Human Resources, 52(2), 457-490.

Gaddis, I., Oseni, G., Palacios-Lopez, A., and Pieters, J. (2017). Measuring farm labor: survey

experimental evidence from Ghana.

Galor, O., and Weil, D. (1996). The Gender Gap, Fertility, and Growth. The American Economic

Review, 86(3), 374-387.

Garcia-Perez, J. I. and S. Rendon (2020). “Family Job Search and Wealth: The Added Worker Effect

Revisited”. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia WP No. 20-17.

Gary Becker (1962) Investment in Human Capital: A Theoretical Analysis. Journal of Political

Economy 70(5).

Gasparini, L., and M. Marchionni. 2017. Bridging Gender Gaps? The Rise and Deceleration of Female

La- bor Force Participation in Latin America. Montevideo: Center for Distributive, Labor, and Social

Studies (CEDLAS).

Ghani, E., Mani, A., & O'Connell, S. D. (2013). Can Political Empowerment Help Economic

Empowerment? Policy Research Working Paper. The World Bank.

Goldberg, J. (2016). Kwacha Gonna Do? Experimental Evidence about Labor Supply in Rural Malawi.

American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 8(1), 129-149.

Goldin, C. (1992). Understanding the Gender Gap: An Economic History of American Women. Oxford:

Oxford University Press

Goldin, C. (1995). The U-Shaped Female Labor Force Function in Economic Development and

Economic History. In T. P. Schultz (Ed.), Investment in Women’s Human Capital and Economic

Development (pp. 61-90): University of Chicago Press.

Goldin, C., & Katz, L. F. (2002). The power of the pill: Oral contraceptives and women's career and

marriage decisions. Journal of Political Economy, 110(4), 730-770.

44

Goldin, C., & Rouse, C. (2000). Orchestrating Impartiality: The Impact of "Blind" Auditions on Female

Musicians. American Economic Review, 90(4), 715-741.

Grogan, L., & Sadanand, A. (2013). Rural Electrification and Employment in Poor Countries: Evidence

from Nicaragua. World Development, 43, 252-265. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2012.09.002

Gruber, J. (1994). The incidence of mandated maternity benefits. The American Economic Review,

84(3), 622-641.

Havnes, T., & Mogstad, M. (2011). Money for nothing? Universal child care and maternal

employment. Journal of Public Economics, 95(11-12), 1455-1465.

He, X., & Zhu, R. (2016). Fertility and Female Labour Force Participation: Causal Evidence from Urban

China. The Manchester School, 84(5), 664-674.

Heath (2017): Heath, Rachel, (2017), Fertility at work: Children and women's labor market outcomes

in urban Ghana, Journal of Development Economics, 126, issue C, p. 190-214,

Heath, R. and S. Jayachandran (2016). “The causes and consequences of increased female education

and labor force participation in developing countries”. National Bureau of Economic Research

Working Paper No. w22766.

Heath, R., & Jayachandran, S. (2017). The Causes And Consequences Of Increased Female Education

And Labor Force Participation In Developing Countries. NBER Working Paper Series. NBER.

Heath, R., & Mushfiq Mobarak, A. (2015). Manufacturing growth and the lives of Bangladeshi

women. Journal of Development Economics, 115, 1-15.

Heath, Rachel, and A. Mushfiq Mobarak. 2015. “Manufacturing growth and the lives of Bangladeshi

women.” Journal of Development Economics, 115: 1–15.

Heckman, J. J., J. Stixrud, and S. Urzua. 2006. “The Effects of Cognitive and Noncognitive Abilities on

Labor Market Outcomes and Social Behavior.” Journal of Labor Economics 24 (3): 411–82.

Heckman, J., Humphries, J.E., Urzua, s., and Gregory Veramendi (2010) "The effects of educational

choices on labor market, health, and social outcomes," Working Papers 2011-002, Human Capital

and Economic Opportunity Working Group.

Herbst, C. M. (2017). Universal child care, maternal employment, and children’s long-run outcomes:

Evidence from the US Lanham Act of 1940. Journal of Labor Economics, 35(2), 519-564.

Hill, E.J., V.K. Märtinson, M. Ferris, and R. Zenger Baker (2004). “Beyond the Mommy Track: The

Influence of New-Concept Part- time Work for Professional Women on Work and Family.” Journal of

Family and Economic Issues 121 –136.

http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/632421513000919521/pdf/WPS8266.pdf

http://fmwww.bc.edu/EC-P/wp904.pdf

http://pubdocs.worldbank.org/en/307351460397349024/Premand-et-al-2016.pdf

Hwang, J., Park, S., & Shin, D. (2017). Two Birds with One Stone: Female Labor Supply, Fertility, and

Market Childcare.

ICLS. (2013). ICLS Resolution 1. Paper presented at the International Conference of Labour

Statisticians.

45

ILO (2017) World Employment and Social Outlook (WESO): Trends 2017. International Labour

Organization.

ILOStat. (2018). Retrieved 1/25/2018 http://www.ilo.org/ilostat/faces/ilostat-

home/home?_adf.ctrl-state=a7fsszo9l_45&_afrLoop=359046357408253#!

International Finance Corporation, McKinsey and Company. (2011). Assessing and Mapping the

Global Finance Gap for Women-owned SMEs. Retrieved 4/23/2018

https://c.ymcdn.com/sites/www.andeglobal.org/resource/dynamic/blogs/20111212_151426_19862

.pdf

International Labour Organization. (2013). Women and Men in the Informal Economy: A Statistical

Picture (Second Edition). International Labor Office – Geneva, Switzerland.

International Labour Organization. (2016). Key Indicators of the Labour Market

International Labour Organization. (2016). Women at Work: Trends 2016. International Labor Office

– Geneva, Switzerland.

Jaffe and Azumi 1960: Jaffe, A. J., and K. Azumi. “The Birth Rate and Cottage Industries in

Underdeveloped Countries.” Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 9, no. 1, 1960, pp.

52–63. JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/1151922. Accessed 23 Sept. 2020.

Jarvis, L., & Vera-Toscano, E. (2004). The Impact of Chilean Fruit Sector Development on Female

Employment and Household Income. Policy Research Working Paper. World Bank.

Jaumotte, F. (2003). Female Labour Force Participation: Past Trends and Main Determinants in OECD

Countries. OECD Economics Department Working Papers. OECD.

Jensen, R. (2012). Do Labor Market Opportunities Affect Young Women's Work and Family

Decisions? Experimental Evidence from India. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(2), 753-792.

doi:10.1093/qje/qjs002

Jensen, R., & Oster, E. (2009). The Power of TV: Cable Television and Women's Status in India.

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(3), 1057-1094.

doi:http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/content/by/year

Joseph E Zveglich, J., & Rodgers, Y. v. d. M. (2003). The Impact of Protective Measures for Female

Workers. Journal of Labor Economics, 21(3), 533-555.

Keck, W., and C. Saraceno. (2009). “ Balancing Elderly Care and Employment in Germany (No. SP I

2009-401).” Discussion Paper, Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für Sozialforschung (WZB), Research

Professorship Demographic Development, Social Change, and Social Capital.

Khera, R., & Nayak, N. (2009). Women Workers and Perceptions of the National Rural Employment

Guarantee Act. Economic and Political Weekly, 44(43), 49-57.

Kilburn, M. R., & Datar, A. (2001). The availability of child care centers in china and its impact on child

care and maternal work decisions. Working Paper Series. RAND.

Killingsworth, M. R., & Heckman, J. J. (1986). Female Labor Supply: A Survey. In O. Ashenfelter & R.

Layard (Eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics (Vol. 1): Elsevier Science Publishers.

Kinoshita, Y., & Guo, F. (2015). What Can Boost Female Labor Force Participation in Asia? IMF

Working Paper. IMF.

46

Kis-Katos, K., Pieters, J. and R. Sparrow (2017). “Globalization and Social Change: Gender-Specific

Effects of Trade Liberalization in Indonesia”. IZA Discussion Papers, No. 10552, Institute for the Study

of Labor (IZA).

Klase, 1999: Klasen, Stephan. 1999. ‘‘Does Gender Inequality Reduce Growth and Development?’’

Policy Research Report Working Paper 7, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Klasen and Lamana, 2019: http://chicagopolicyreview.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/09/Gender-

and-Economic-Growth.pdf

Klasen, S., & Pieters, J. (2012). Push or pull? Drivers of female labor force participation during India's

economic boom.

Klugman, J., Hanmer, L., Twigg, S., Hasan, T., McCleary-Sills, J., and Santa Maria, J. (2014). Voice and

Agency: Empowering Women and Girls for Shared Prosperity. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Kristin Mammen and Christina Paxson (2000). Women's Work and Economic Development. The

Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 14, No. 4, pp. 141-164

Kupinsky 1997: Kupinsky, Stanley. 1977. "The Fertility of Working Women in the United States:

Historical Trends and Theoretical Perspectives." In The Fertility of Working Women: A Synthesis of

International Research, ed. Stanley Kupinsky. New York: Praeger Publishers.

Landmann, A., Seitz, H., & Steiner, S. (2016). Intergenerational Co-Residence and Female Labour

Supply.

Lazear, E. P. and Rosen, S. (1990). Male-Female Wage Differentials in Job Ladders, Journal of Labor

Economics, 8, 106–123.

Lefebvre, P., and P. Merrigan. (2008). “Child-Care Policy and the Labor Supply of Mothers with Young

Children: A Natural Experiment from Canada.” Journal of Labor Economics 26 (3): 519 –548.

Lei L., S. Desai and R. Vanneman (2019). “The Impact of Transportation Infrastructure on Women's

Employment in India.” Feminist Economics, 25:4, 94-125.

Lei, L., Desai, S., & Vanneman, R. (2017). Village Transportation Infrastructure and Women’s Non-

agricultural Employment in India: The Conditioning Role of Community Gender Context. India Human

Development Survey. University of Maryland.

Levy, S. (2007). Productividad, crecimiento y pobreza en Mexico: ¿Que sigue despues de Progresa-

Oportunidades? BID. Washington.

Lilly, M., Laporte, A., & Coyte, P. (2007). Labor Market Work and Home Care's Unpaid Caregivers: A

Systematic Review of Labor Force Participation Rates, Predictors of Labor Market Withdrawal, and

Hours of Work. The Milbank Quarterly, 85(4), 641-690.

Lokshin and fong (2006): Lokshin, Michael & Fong, Monica. (2006). Women's labour force

participation and child care in Romania. The Journal of Development Studies. 42. 90-109.

Lokshin et al (2000): Lokshin, Michael M. & Glinskaya, Elena & Garcia, Marito, 2000. "The effect of

early childhood development programs on women's labor force participation and older children's

schooling in Kenya," Policy Research Working Paper Series 2376, The World Bank.

Lokshin, M. (1999). Household Childcare Choices and Women's Work Behavior in

Russia. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

47

Magnani, E., & Rammohan, A. (2006). The effect of Elderly Caregiving on Female Labour Supply in

Indonesia.

Majlesi, K. (2015) Labor Market Opportunities and Women’s Decision Making Power within

Households. Journal of Development Economics.

Maloney, W. (2004). “Informality Revisited”. World Development, 32(7):1159-1178.

Mammen, K., & Paxson, C. (2000). Women's Work and Economic Development. Journal of Economic

Perspectives, 14(1), 141-164.

Mankart, J., and R. Oikonomou (2016). “Household Search and the Aggregate Labour Market”. The

Review of Economic Studies.

Marcucci, P.N. (2001). Jobs, gender and small enterprises in Africa and Asia: Lessons drawn from

Bangladesh, the Philippines, Tunisia and Zimbabwe, InFocus Programme on Boosting Employment

through Small Enterprise Development, Job Creation and Enterprise Department, ILO SEED Working

Papers: Series on Womenís Entrepreneurship Development and Gender in Enterprises WEDGE, No.

58, Geneva.

Martínez, C. A., & Perticará, M. (2017). Childcare effects on maternal employment: Evidence from

Chile. Journal of Development Economics, 126, 127-137.

McCabe and Rosenzweig (1976): McCabe, James L. & Rosenzweig, Mark R., 1976. "Female labor-

force participation, occupational choice, and fertility in developing countries," Journal of

Development Economics, Elsevier, vol. 3(2), pages 141-160, July.

McKay, C., & Mazer, R. (2014). 10 Myths About M-PESA: 2014 Update. CGAP Blog.

McKelway, M. (2018). Women’s self-efficacy and women’s employment: Experimental evidence

from india. In: Essays on the empowerment and employment of women in India (Doctoral

dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology).

Mckenzie et al (2019) in Kenya McKenzie, D, Puerto, S and Odhiambo, F, 2019. Unpacking the

determinants of entrepreneurship development and economic empowerment for women in Kenya,

3ie Impact Evaluation Report 95. New Delhi: International Initiative for Impact Evaluation (3ie).

Morton, Matthew; Klugman, Jeni; Hanmer, Lucia; Singer, Dorothe. 2014. Gender at work : a

companion to the world development report on jobs (English). Washington, DC : World Bank Group.

Muñoz Boudet, Ana María; Petesch, Patti; Turk, Carolyn; Thumala, Angélica. (2013). On Norms and

Agency: Conversations about Gender Equality with Women and Men in 20 Countries. Directions in

development: human development; Washington, DC: World Bank.

Muralidharan, K., & Prakash, N. (2017). Cycling to School: Increasing Secondary School Enrollment

for Girls in India. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 9(3), 321-350.

Nakamura, A., and M. Nakamura (1992). “The Econometrics of Female Labor Supply and Children.”

Econometric Review 1 –71.

Neupane, G., & Chesney-Lind, M. (2013). Violence against women on public transport in Nepal:

sexual harassment and the spatial expression of male privilege. International Journal of Comparative

and Applied Criminal Justice, 38(1), 23-38.

48

Niederle, Muriel, and Lise Vesterlund. 2007. “Do Women Shy Away From Competition? Do Men

Compete Too Much?” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (3): 1067–1101.

Nishitateno, S., & Shikata, M. (2017). Has improved daycare accessibility increased Japan's maternal

employment rate? Municipal evidence from 2000–2010. Journal of the Japanese and International

Economies, 44, 67-77.

OECD (2018), Gender wage gap (indicator). doi: 10.1787/7cee77aa-en (Accessed on 25 February

2018)

Olivetti, C., Patacchini, E., & Zenou, Y. (2016). Mothers, Peers and Gender Identity. Boston College

Department of Economics, Boston College Working Papers in Economics: 904. Retrieved from

https://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=eoh&AN=1568828&site=ehost-

live&scope=site

Paul Schultz, T. (2004). School subsidies for the poor: evaluating the Mexican Progresa poverty

program. Journal of Development Economics, 74(1), 199-250. doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2003.12.009

Perry, Guillermo E., William F. Maloney, Omar S. Arias, Pablo Fajnzylber, Andrew D. Mason, and

Jaime Saavedra-Chanduvi. (2007). Informality: Exit and Exclusion. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Pitt, M. M., & Khandker, S. R. (1998). The Impact of Group-Based Credit Programs on Poor

Households in Bangladesh: Does the Gender of Participants Matter? Journal of Political Economy,

106(6), 958-996.

Preibe 2010: Priebe, Jan, (2010), Child Costs and the Causal Effect of Fertility on Female Labor

Supply: An investigation for Indonesia 1993-2008, No 45, Courant Research Centre: Poverty, Equity

and Growth - Discussion Papers, Courant Research Centre PEG,

https://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:got:gotcrc:045.

Premand, P., Brodmann, S., Almeida, R., Grun, Rebekka, & Barouni, M. (2015). Entrepreneurship

Education and Entry into Self-Employment Among University Graduates. World Development 77,

311–327.

Psacharopoulos, GeorgeG., and Zafiris Tzannatos, Z. (1989). “Female Labor Force Participation: An

International Perspective.” The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 4, no. 2., 1989, pp. 187–201.

JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/3986509. Accessed 14 Nov. 2020.

Puga, I., & Soto, D. (2018). Social Capital and Women’s Labor Force Participation in Chile. Feminist

Economics, 24(4), 131-158.

Qian, N. (2008). Missing Women and the Price of Tea in China: The Effect of Sex-Specific Earnings on

Sex Imbalance. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(3), 1251-1285.

Rangel, M. (2006). Alimony Rights and Intrahousehold Allocation of Resources: Evidence from Brazil.

The Economic Journal, 116(July), 627-658.

Salmon, C., & Tanguy, J. (2016). Rural Electrification and Household Labor Supply: Evidence from

Nigeria. World Development, 82, 48-68. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2016.01.016

Salon, D. and S. Gulyani (2010). “Mobility, Poverty, and Gender: Travel ‘Choices’ of Slum Residents in

Nairobi, Kenya.” Transport Reviews 30(5): 641–57.

49

Sauré, P., & Zoabi, H. (2014). International trade, the gender wage gap and female labor force

participation. Journal of Development Economics, 111, 17-33. doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2014.07.003

Serrano, J., Gasparini, L., Marchionni, M., & Gluzmann, P. (2017). Economic Cycle and Deceleration of

Female Labor Force Participation in Latin America. Latin America and the Caribbean Economic

Association.

Shamsuddin, M. (2015). Labour Market Effects of a Female Stipend Programme in Bangladesh.

Oxford Development Studies, 43(4), 425-447. doi:10.1080/13600818.2015.1056133

Sivard, R. L. (1985). Women: A World Survey. Washington, D.C.: World Priorities.

Steinberg and Nakane 2012, https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12248.pdf

Stephan Klasen, What Explains Uneven Female Labor Force Participation Levels and Trends in

Developing Countries?, The World Bank Research Observer, Volume 34, Issue 2, August 2019, Pages

161–197, https://doi.org/10.1093/wbro/lkz005

Stoloff, J. A., Glanville, J. L., & Bienenstock, E. J. (1999). Women's participation in the labor force: the

role of social networks. Social networks, 21(1), 91-108.

Sugawara, S., & Nakamura, J. (2014). Can formal elderly care stimulate female labor supply? The

Japanese experience. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 34, 98-115.

doi:10.1016/j.jjie.2014.05.006

Sundaram, A., & Vanneman, R. (2008). Gender Differentials in Literacy in India: The Intriguing

Relationship with Women’s Labor Force Participation. World Development, 36(1), 128-143.

doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2007.02.017

Szulga (2013): Szulga, Radek S., A Dynamic Model of Female Labor Force Participation Rate and

Human Capital Investment (August 10, 2013). Available at

SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2182861 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2182861

Tan, P.-L., & Gibson, J. (2013). Impact of Foreign Maids on Female Labor Force Participation in

Malaysia. Asian Economic Journal, 27(2), 163-183. doi:10.1111/asej.12008

Thomas, D. (1990). Intra-Household Resource Allocation: An Inferential Approach. The Journal of

Human Resources, 25(4), 635-664.

Todd, P. E., & Wolpin, K. I. (2006). Assessing the Impact of a School Subsidy Program in Mexico:

Using a Social Experiment to Validate a Dynamic Behavioral Model of Child Schooling and Fertility.

The American Economic Review, 96(5), 1384-1417.

UN (2020) The Gender Snapshot. Progress on the Sustainable Development Goals. Statistics Division,

UN Department of Economic and Social Affairs.

UN SDGs: https://sustainabledevelopment.un.org/post2015/transformingourworld

United Nations Statisics Division Time use data portal

(unstats.un.org/unsd/gender/timeuse/index.html)

van Rooyen, C., Stewart, R., & de Wet, T. (2012). The Impact of Microfinance in Sub-Saharan Africa:

A Systematic Review of the Evidence. World Development, 40(11), 2249-2262.

doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2012.03.012

50

Verceles, N.A. and S.N. Beltran (2004). Reconciling work and family, Philippine country study,

unpublished Working Paper (Geneva, ILO, Conditions of Work and Employment Programme).

WHO (2013) Global and regional estimates of violence against women: Prevalence and health effects

of intimate partner violence and non-partner sexual violence.

World Bank (2018) Growing Smarter. Learning and Equitable Development in East Asia and the

Pacific. World Bank East Asia and the Pacific Regional Reports.

World Bank Group. (2015). “Why Should We Care About Care? : The Role of Informal Childcare and

Eldercare in Aging Societies”. Washington, DC: World Bank.

World Bank Group. (2015). Gender Strategy (FY16-23): Gender Equality, Poverty Reduction, and

Inclusive Growth. Washington, DC: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The

World Bank.

World Bank Group. (2015). Why Should We Care About Care? The role of informal childcare and

eldercare in aging societies. World Bank.

World Bank Group. (2015). Women, Business and the Law 2016: Getting to Equal. Washington, DC:

World Bank. doi:10.1596/978-1-4648-0677-3

World Bank. (2011). “Learning for All: Investing in People’s Knowledge and Skills to Promote

Development; World Bank Group Education Strategy 2020.” Washington, DC: World Bank.

World Bank. (2012). World Development Report 2013: Jobs. Washington, DC: World Bank. doi:

10.1596/978-0-8213-9575-2.

World Development Report (2012). Gender Equality and Development. Washington, DC: World

Bank. doi: 10.1596/978-0-8213-8810-5.

World Bank. (2016). The Little Data Book on Gender 2016. Washington, DC: World Bank.

doi:10.1596/978-1-4648-0556-1.

World Bank. (2016). World Development Indicators 2016. Washington, DC: World Bank.

doi:10.1596/978–1-4648–0683–4.

World Values Survey Wave 6. Retrieved 1/25/2018

http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org/WVSOnline.jsp

Most Recent Jobs Working Papers:

55. Structural Transformation and Labor Market Performance In Ghana (2020) Mpumelelo Nxumalo and Dhushyanth Raju

54. Just Coal Transition in Western Macedonia, Greece-Insights from the Labor Market (2020) Luc Christiaensen and Céline Ferré

53. Insights from Surveys on Business and Enterprises in South Sudan: Jobs, Recovery, and Peacebuilding in Urban South Sudan – Technical Report IV (2020) Arden Finn and Jan von der Goltz

52. Job Outcomes in The Towns Of South Sudan: Jobs, Recovery, And Peacebuilding In Urban South Sudan – Technical Report III (2020) Jan von der Goltz, Mira Saidi, Augustino Ting Mayai, and Melissa Williams.

51. The Macroeconomic Environment for Jobs in South Sudan: Jobs, Recovery, and Peacebuilding in Urban South Sudan – Technical Report II (2020) Joseph Mawejje

50. Job Outcomes in the Towns of South Sudan: Jobs, Recovery, and Peacebuilding in Urban South Sudan- Technical Report I (2020) Arden Finn, Jan von der Goltz, Mira Saidi, and Ambika Sharma.

49. Managing the Employment Impacts of the COVID-19 Crisis : Policy Options for Relief and Restructuring (English) (2020) Carranza, Eliana; Farole, Thomas; Gentilini, Ugo; Morgandi, Matteo; Packard, Truman; Santos, Indhira; Weber, Michael

48. Nepal: A Review of Jobs Portfolio (2020) Parikh, Vismay; Shakya, Anupama 47. Jobs Interventions for Refugees and Internally Displaced Persons (2020) Schuettler, Kirsten; Caron, Laura 46. Market study to understand job growth potential in SMEs in Nepal (2020)

Click here for full Jobs Paper Series

Address: 1776 G St, NW, Washington, DC 20006 Website: http://www.worldbank.org/en/topic/jobsanddevelopment

Twitter: @WBG_Jobs Blog: https://blogs.worldbank.org/jobs/