33
ASSET MANAGEMENT PART I: STRATEGIC ASSET ALLOCATION Martijn Boons - Nova SBE

Asset Management - Lecture 1

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Asset Management

Citation preview

  • ASSET MANAGEMENT PART I:

    STRATEGIC ASSET ALLOCATIONMartijn Boons - Nova SBE

  • TODAY

    Strategic asset allocation: How to allocate wealth

    optimally across broad asset classes?

    What is an asset class?

    Intuition from answer to How much to invest in

    risky versus riskless asset? easily generalizes

    Asset allocation for short investment horizons Risky: aggregate stock market portfolio, e.g., S&P500

    Riskless: short-term Treasury bill

    Asset allocation for long investment horizons

    Advantages of being a long-term investor

    Horizon

    Buy and hold versus rebalancing

    When returns are not versus are predictable

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    2

  • RECALL FROM INVESTMENTS

    Investors should control the risk (= variance) of their portfolio not

    by re-allocating among risky assets, but through the split between

    risky and risk-free

    Optimal portfolio of risky assets: market portfolio

    Held by the aggregate market, and in CAPM equilibrium

    optimal for all investors

    If not exactly optimal, at least well-diversified and attractive

    Although theory suggests market portfolio contains all risky

    assets, aggregate stock market index usually used as proxy

    Uncertain market return equals capital gain + dividend:

    =

    with () = and () =

    Combine with short-term Treasury bills according to risk aversion

    (Nominally) Risk-free one-period return is known at time

    and equals =,

    ,

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    3

  • THE SINGLE-PERIOD PROBLEM

    Investor chooses fraction of wealth invested in risky

    asset to maximize mean-variance utility over portfolio

    return

    max(,)

    (,), with ,= +(1-)

    (,) = +(1 ) and (,) =

    Assumptions

    Wealth is 1$, to abstract from wealth effects

    Ascertains investor has constant relative risk

    aversion (CRRA): dollar investment in risky asset

    increases in wealth, but the share of wealth

    invested in risky asset remains constant

    No practical constraints: positivity or no short-sales

    (x 0), no leverage (0 x 1)

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    4

  • SOLUTION

    Unconstrained solution from FOC

    =

    !"

    #$

    increasing in , and decreasing in % and

    Example: = 8%, = 2%, = 20%, and %=3

    =1

    3

    6%

    (20%)= 0.50

    Traditional portfolio advice: put 50% of wealth in

    stocks

    Note, Sharpe ratio of optimal portfolio is independent of %:

    . =

    =( )

    The excess return per unit of risk offered by the market

    portfolio

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    5

  • THE CAPITAL ALLOCATION LINE

    /01

    =2%

    Slope=0.3

    0.5*20%=

    10%

    % = 3

    2%+0.5*

    6%=5%

    1. CAL plots expected

    return versus standard

    deviation of optimal

    portfolios

    2. Indifference curves

    determine which portfolio

    choice is optimal for

    each% (with utility

    increasing in northwest

    direction)

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    6

    =8%

    = 20%

    Question: for which % is 100% in the risky asset optimal?

    % = 1.5

  • THE DYNAMIC PORTFOLIO CHOICE

    PROBLEM

    1. Horizon of one period is unreasonable for most investors

    Pension funds (horizon of liabilities 20 years)

    Saving for a house, college, new campus etc.

    2. Investor may want to change portfolio weights every period

    over this horizon

    What is a period? Year (individuals), quarter (institutions),

    , second (high-frequency traders)?

    Why change?

    1. Time-varying investment opportunities (e.g.,

    predictable returns and volatilities as the investor

    passes through economic recessions / expansions),

    2. when approaching the horizon,

    3. or when risk aversion varies over time.

    Main insight from dynamic portfolio choice: optimal

    weight depends on horizon or time 3, or both

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    7

  • SETUP OF THE DYNAMIC PROBLEM (I)

    Consider the portfolio choice at time for an investor with horizon at time 4 > + 1

    Wealth dynamics: 7 = 7 1 + ,

    Wealth varies from to + 1 due to portfolio return, which is a function of the portfolio choice

    Suppose T=5

    The sequence of weights over time, {}, is called a dynamic trading strategy. Dynamic because weights can change over time.

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    8

  • SETUP OF THE DYNAMIC PROBLEM (II)

    Maximize expected utility of wealth at horizon T by choosing a dynamic trading strategy: max

    {9}(;(7

  • DYNAMIC PROGRAMMING (I)

    The solution to this problem is easily found working backwards

    Final wealth is the product of current wealth and uncertain one-

    period returns: 7> = 1 + , (1 + ,>)

    Assuming again current wealth 7 = 1

    Given uncertain wealth at t+4, choose portfolio weights that

    maximize expected utility at t+5(=T):

    max9@

    (;(7>)) = max9@

    (;(1 + ,>(A)))

    Solution to this single-period problem, assuming mean-variance

    utility:

    A =

    1

    %

    A ,A

    A

    Conditional moments, as state of economy at t+4 unknown

    Indirect utility: the maximum utility obtained at t+4,

    A = (;(1 + ,> A )

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    10

  • DYNAMIC PROGRAMMING (II)

    Now, solve the two-period problem: Given wealth at + 3, choose

    B and Ato maximize expected utility at t+5 (=T):

    max9C,9@

    (;(7>))

    The optimal strategy conditional on any outcome at + 3 is

    already known: A .

    Thus, re-write this problem as a one-period problem:

    max9C

    (;(1 + ,A(B))A)

    The first part is identical to what a single-period investor

    would do at + 3.

    The A-term captures the advantage of being a long-term

    investor. The utility derived from this A-term depends on

    uncertain wealth and investment opportunities at + 4

    Working back to , we are solving such a one-period problem at

    each point in time..

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    11

  • GRAPHICAL REPRESENTATION

    Note how different this approach is

    from buy and hold, which solves

    one five-period problem!

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    12

  • LESSONS

    Dynamic portfolio choice over long horizons is

    first and foremost about solving one-period

    portfolio choice problems!

    This view destroys two widely held

    misconceptions:

    1. Long-term investors are fundamentally different

    from short-term investors

    2. Buy-and-hold is optimal

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    13

  • 1. LONG-TERM INVESTING IS NOT SO

    DIFFERENT FROM SHORT-TERM INVESTING

    Dynamic programming shows that long-run investors do

    everything that short-run investors do!

    However, long-run investors can do more, because they have the

    advantage of a long horizon.

    The horizon effect enters through the indirect utility (VFG) in

    each one-period problem

    For instance, suppose at t you know that stock market returns

    will be high from t+1 to t+2. How might this affect the optimal

    portfolio choice xF?

    Some will invest more risky, because future return can

    compensate if returns are low from t to t+1

    Some will invest less risky, to ensure that they have

    sufficient money to invest when it is most attractive at t+1

    Exact solution depends, among other things, on

    Covt(,, ,) with mean-variance utility, and smoothing

    preferences with other utility functions

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    14

  • 2. A LONG-RUN INVESTOR SHOULD NOT

    BUY AND HOLD!

    Buy and hold solves a single, long-horizon problem

    Special case of dynamic investing where the investors

    optimal choice is to do nothing

    Thus, dynamic portfolios can do everything buy and

    hold portfolios do, but also much more!

    In practice, optimal long-horizon investing is not to buy

    and hold; long-horizon investing is a continual process of

    buying and selling.

    Suppose you calculate the optimal weight in stocks for

    the next ten years is 50%.

    You need to rebalance each period!

    If not, over a sufficiently long period of time, you will have

    100% in risky assets. That is not what you wanted, right?

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    15

  • REBALANCE WHEN RETURNS ARE NOT

    PREDICTABLE!

    Suppose returns are not predictable (i.i.d.) and the risk-free

    rate is fixed

    Returns are in fact hard to predict!

    In this case, the dynamic strategy is a series of identical

    one-period strategies

    Intuition: we can take A out of the maximization

    max9C

    (;(1 + ,A(B)))A

    Long-run weight (t) = Short-run weight (t) =

    !"

    #$

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    16

  • THE CASE FOR REBALANCING

    For the two asset case (stock market and risk-free asset),

    rebalancing is countercyclical:

    Buy (sell) stocks after low (high) returns

    Portfolio rebalancing ensures wealth remains to be

    allocated optimally (in line with risk preferences) over

    time, and is also advantageous if returns are

    mean-reverting / predictable: prices drop when

    expected future returns increase (more on

    predictability later)

    Example: Great depression

    Investors rebalance infrequently and incompletely

    Partial explanations include: inertia, natural tendency

    to invest more in assets that do well than in assets

    doing poorly, transaction costs (rebalancing bands)17

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

  • COUNTERCYCLICAL REBALANCING IN THE

    GREAT DEPRESSIONA

    MI -

    Stra

    tegic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    18

    With rebalancing: sell some stocks before they are hit hard in 1930,

    and buy some stocks before they rebound in 1932

    Reduces variance

    and increases returns

    Similar evidence obtains in recent financial crisis!

  • THE DIVERSIFICATION RETURN (SEE ERB

    AND HARVEY, 2006)

    Portfolio diversification decreases portfolio variance

    without reducing portfolio arithmetic return

    This benefit is obtained in a single period, but dies out if

    you do not rebalance (weight in risky asset 100%)

    However, what is less well understood is that

    diversification does increase portfolio geometric

    return

    This diversification return exists for a long-term investor

    and is collected by rebalancing (also known as rebalancing

    return or variance reduction)

    Which two consecutive returns do you prefer: (90%,-50%) or

    (10%,-10%)?

    Excel example

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    19

  • OPPORTUNISTIC STRATEGIES WHEN

    RETURNS ARE PREDICTABLE (I)

    If returns are predictable (not i.i.d.): additional benefits

    from long-term horizon

    Long-term weight (t) =

    1. Long-run myopic weight +

    2. (Short-run weight (t) Long-run myopic weight) +

    3. Opportunistic weight (t)

    Strategic asset allocation is the sum of these three

    components!

    1. Long-run fixed weight determined by long-run

    average return and volatility 1

    %

    I

    This is the constant rebalancing weight in the i.i.d. case!

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    20

  • OPPORTUNISTIC STRATEGIES WHEN

    RETURNS ARE PREDICTABLE (II)

    2. Tactical asset allocation: the response of both

    short- and long-run investors to changing means

    and volatilities

    !",

    #$

    !I"

    #$, where () = , () =

    If market Sharpe ratio is temporarily high: both

    short-and long-term investors can benefit.

    3. Captures how long-term investor can take

    advantage of time-varying, predictable returns in

    ways short-run investors cannot.

    The knowledge that market Sharpe ratio is going

    to be high in the future: only the long-term

    investor can benefit. 21

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

  • CHARACTERIZING THE OPPORTUNISTIC

    WEIGHT

    Difficult, but two broad determinants

    1. Investor-specific: risk tolerance (like in one-period portfolio) and horizon

    2. Asset-specific: how do returns vary over time?

    Interaction between horizon and time-variation is crucial:

    An asset with low returns (high volatility) today, but high returns (low volatility) in the (long-run) future is not attractive for short-term investors, but long-term investors might want to invest in them.

    We can obtain more insight into the opportunistic weight (or intertemporal hedge demand, as it was coined in Merton (1973)), thinking about optimal buy-and-hold portfolios as in Campbell and Viceira (CV, 1999, 2002, 2005)

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    22

  • THE CV-APPROACH

    CV set out to find the optimal portfolio choice for buy-and-

    hold investors with investment horizon K

    If returns are predictable, long-term portfolio choice is

    (among other things) determined by the conditional

    expectation and conditional variance of the risky assets

    returns over the investors horizon K

    More formally, (L) ((

    (L)), (

    L)), where (

    (L)) is

    the average expected per period return over horizon K

    ((L) defined analogously)

    Empirically, forecasts of returns and variances follow from

    a regression of stock and t-bill returns on a set of predictors

    (e.g., the dividend yield)

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    23

  • OPTIMAL BUY-AND-HOLD PORTFOLIOS (I)

    To get the necessary intuition, let us think about a

    case where ,is time-varying, but the market risk

    premiumM = , is constant

    Optimal investment in risky asset for investors with a

    K-period horizon are of the following approximate

    form:

    (L)

    1

    %

    (M L

    )

    (M L

    )+ (

    1

    % 1)

    /OP(M L

    , ,L)

    (M L

    )

    where /OP(M L

    , ,L

    ) is the average per period

    covariance of risky assets return with risk-free return

    over horizon K

    1. Myopic demand of a K-period investor (as before)

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    24

  • OPTIMAL BUY-AND-HOLD PORTFOLIOS (II)

    2. Intertemporal hedge demand defined over

    /OP(M L

    , ,L

    )

    Suppose the covariance is positive: on average, excess

    market returns are high whenever expected future returns

    on both market and t-bills are high (,L)

    Risk averse investor (%>1) will under-weight market portfolio

    (relative to myopic demand), because it pays off exactly when

    he does not need the money, i.e., when the future is bright

    Risk loving investor (%

  • OPPORTUNISTIC HEDGING DEMANDS IN

    PRACTICE

    Although elegant and intuitive, the optimal size of

    hedging demands is debated heavily

    CV estimate is large: risk-averse, long-run investor

    over-weights stocks dramatically. Why?

    Mean-reversion captured by the fact that dividend

    yield predicts stock returns with a positive sign in-

    sample

    When future expected stock returns increase,

    current prices decrease and dividend yield

    increases (/OP(M L

    , ,L

    )

  • CV: STOCKS ARE LESS RISKY IN THE LONG

    RUN

    27

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

  • ON MEAN REVERSAL AND PREDICTABILITY

    IN STOCK RETURNS

    Evidence in CV consistent with in-sample stock return

    predictability by a range of variables:

    Cash-flow based (dividend yield, earnings yield); Business

    cycle indicators (term spread); Technical (momentum)

    Recent research questions extent and exploitability of this

    predictability out-of-sample, i.e., for an investor that is making

    his investment decisions in real-time

    Goyal and Welch (2008): coefficients unstable in sub-samples;

    in-sample R2 small; out-of-sample R2 tiny

    State-of-the-Art recommendation by Ang

    the evidence for predictability is weak, so I recommend that both

    the tactical and opportunistic portfolio weights be small in practice.

    Opportunistic hedging demands become much smaller once investors

    have to learn about return predictability or when they take into

    account estimation error.

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    28

  • EXTENSION: LIABILITY HEDGING

    Few investors are without liabilities.

    With liabilities the optimal long-run portfolio advice becomes:

    First, meet the liabilities and then invest wealth, in excess of the

    present value of liabilities, as before

    Long-run weight (t) = Liability hedge (t) + Short-run weight

    (t) + Opportunistic weight (t)

    Liability hedge: portfolio that best ensures investor meets

    liabilities

    Invests in assets with large covariance with liabilities

    Intuition: if stock market return is high when liabilities

    increase in value, it is attractive as a hedge. The more risk

    averse the investor (%), the more weight he will place on

    liability hedging.

    Q

    !",

    #$ (

    1)

    RST(","U,)

    V(")

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    29

  • EXAMPLES OF LIABILITY HEDGE

    PORTFOLIOS

    1. Cash flow matching: Match a portfolio of fixed, future outflows

    with bonds of appropriate maturities

    2. Duration matching: Match duration of interest rate bearing

    liabilities with a portfolio of Treasury bonds

    3. Assetliability matching: Match liability characteristics besides

    just duration

    For most pension funds

    horizon exceeds longest available maturity of liquidly

    traded Treasury bonds

    liabilities denominated in real, not nominal, terms, whereas

    real, long-maturity bonds have only been traded in recent

    years, but not in every country

    Additional risks that need to be matched: liquidity risk,

    longevity risk, economic growth, and credit risk.

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    30

  • THREE-WAY SEPARATION IS POPULAR

    Practitioners frameworks usually consist of three buckets

    1. Protective portfolio, which covers personal risk. The portfolio is designed to minimize downside risk and is a form of safety first.

    2. Market portfolio, which is a balance of risk and return to attain market-level performance from a broadly diversified portfolio and is exposed to market risk.

    3. Aspirational portfolio, which is designed to take measured risk to achieve significant return enhancement. Aspirational risk is a property of an investors utility function and is a desire to grow wealth opportunistically to reach the next desired wealth target.

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    31

  • CONCLUSIONS

    Rebalancing is the foundation of any long-term

    investment strategy!

    Under i.i.d. returns the optimal policy is to

    rebalance to constant weights for both short- and

    long-term investors.

    When returns are predictable, the optimal short-

    run portfolio changes over time, and the long-run

    investor has additional opportunistic strategies

    Liabilities need to be adequately matched before

    the investment portfolio is constructed.

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion

    32

  • LITERATURE

    Books

    Ang, Asset Management, Ch. 2-4

    Campbell and Viceira, Strategic Asset Allocation, Ch. 2-3

    Articles

    Erb and Harvey, 2006, The Tactical and Strategic Value of

    Commodity Futures, Financial Analysts Journal.

    Merton, 1973, An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model,

    Econometrica

    Campbell and Viceira, 2005, The term structure of the risk-return

    trade-off, NBER Working Paper

    Campbell and Viceira, 2005, The term structure of the risk-return

    trade-off, Financial Analysts Journal

    Goyal and Welch, 2008, A Comprehensive Look at The Empirical

    Performance of Equity Premium Prediction, Review of Financial

    Studies

    33

    AM

    I -S

    trate

    gic A

    sset A

    lloca

    tion