29
ECN741, Urban Economics Professor Yinger Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

ECN741, Urban EconomicsProfessor Yinger

Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Page 2: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Class Outline

Household Demand for Public Services

The Median Voter Model

Estimating Household Demand

Page 3: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

The Starting Point

An household’s demand for local public services, like its demand for private goods, depends on its income, the price of the services, the price of alternatives, and its preferences.

But with 2 big twists:

◦There is no market price.

◦The demand for public services can be expressed in several different ways:

Page 4: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Lack of a Market Price

Most public services are funded by taxes, not prices.

Hence, the “price” is defined as the cost of an additional unit of service

And this price depends on the tax system.

Tax Price = How much would the individual pay if taxes were raised enough to provide one more unit of the service to everyone in the jurisdiction.

A more formal definition will be derived later.

Page 5: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

How Is Demand Revealed?

The demand for services can be expressed:

◦Through voting (today’s class)

◦Through bidding for housing and choice of a community (the subject of later classes)

◦Through the purchase of private substitutes, such as private schools, security guards, or access to a gated community (not covered in any class)

Page 6: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Household Demand for Public Services

A Household’s Budget Constraint

Income (Y) must be spent on housing (H with price P), property taxes (tV=tPH/r) and other stuff (Z with price 1):

1

Y Z PH tVPHZ PH trtZ PHr

Page 7: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

The Community Budget Constraint

In a community, sending per household (E) to achieve the desired service level (S) must equal property tax revenue per household (t multiplied by average V ).

We will skip state aid and other local revenue sources for now.

{ }E S tV A

Page 8: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Solving for Tax Price, 1

Solve the community budget constraint for t:

Substitute into the household budget constraint:

{ }E S AtV

( { } )V

VY Z PH E S A

Page 9: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Solving for Tax Price, 2

Tax price is the cost of one more unit of S, i.e., the derivative of the household budget constraint with respect to S, or,

where MC is the resource cost of another unit of S, and the ratio of V to average V is the tax share.

Note: If E is total spending, the tax share is V divided by total V—a true share.

Tax Price = = E V VTP MCS V V

Page 10: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Estimating Household Demand

With TP defined, we can write down a household demand function:

 The problem: How to estimate this

function?

◦One answer: through surveys.

{ , , Other Prices, Preference Variables}S S Y TP

Page 11: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Survey Studies of Household Demand

Approach 1: Surveys of voting on a referendum.

◦The demand function defines a latent variable, which can be studied with a discrete-choice model, with Y and TP as explanatory variables.

 ◦This approach also can be applied to a survey of

preferences for increasing, decreasing, or not changing spending.

Page 12: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Survey Studies of Household Demand, 2

Approach 2: Surveys of spending preferences: “How much would you like to spend?”

◦Use a multiplicative form with desired

spending (= (S)(AC)) as the dependent variable (assuming AC=MC):

VS AY TP AY MCV

1( )( ) VE S AC AY MCV

Page 13: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

The Median Voter Theorem

Although household voting is not observed, the outcomes of voting in a community are easy to observe—on referenda or in the form of spending or service levels.

The median voter model provides a way to estimate a demand model at the community level—where the data are!

Page 14: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Bergstrom and Goodman

This famous paper (AER 1973) starts with an obvious point (the voter in the middle of the demand distribution is always on the winning side)

It then adds assumptions about the structure of demand and taxes (that demand depends on Y and TP, that there is a property tax, and that the demand for H is a function of Y)

And shows that the voting outcome in a community is determined by the voter with the median Y and median TP.

Page 15: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Bergstrom and Goodman, 2

In symbols:

This was revolutionary because it specified the demand for S using data just on median Y and median TP, which are readily observed.

Scholars can proceed “as if” voting outcomes depend only on the demand of this abstract median voter.

{ , , } , ,MedianMedian Median Median

V

VS S Y TP X S Y MC X

Page 16: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Problems with Median Voter Models

1. Logical problems

◦ If demand is not one-dimensional and preferences do not take certain forms, the public choice mechanism may not be well defined. This is Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem: it is impossible to write down a general model of public choice for complex decisions.

◦Example: private schools. Some people with a high demand for public services under some circumstances (no private alternative) may have a low demand under others (a good private school nearby).

Page 17: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Problems with Median Voter Models, 2

2. Institutional problems

◦The median voter model says institutions are neutral. Politicians and bureaucrats have no impact on observed spending or service quality (except perhaps through inefficiency—more later). Also, results are assumed not to be skewed by non-participation. This may not be true.

◦Example: renters. The tax price idea applies only to owners. But it is very hard to find a significant renter variable in a median voter model.

Page 18: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Problems with Median Voter Models, 3

3. Tiebout bias

◦Basically, this is a form of selection bias in which people with low incomes but high demand for services based on unobserved factors end up in jurisdictions with high-quality services.

◦One possible approach is to control for the income distribution; but this rarely is significant.

Page 19: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

The Budget Constraints

The Median Voter’s Constraint

The Community Constraint

The Combined Constraint

{ }C SE tV A

e

1t

Y Z PH tV Z PHr

{ }V C S VY A Z PH

V e V

Page 20: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Components

Tax Price

Augmented Income

This term leads to the Bradford/Oates equivalence theorem: $1 of aid weighted by tax share should have the same impact on demand as $1 of income.

1 1Spending dC V VTP e MC e

S dS V V

A VY Y A

V

Page 21: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Constant Elasticity Demand

General Form

Linear Form to Estimate

1V VS K Y f A MC e

V V

* 1

* 1

* 1

*

ln{ } ln ln

ln 1 ln

ln ln 1 ln

ln

V VS K Y f A MC e

V V

A V VK Y f MC e

Y V V

A V VK Y f MC e

Y V V

A VK Y f

Y V

1 2 3ln ln lnV

MC eV

Page 22: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

The Big Problem: Endogeneity

Note that this equation includes MC, which depends on the level of S

It also includes e, which may depend on MC as well as on key explanatory variables, such as Y and tax share.

A solution: Model MC and e.

Most studies ignore these problems!

Page 23: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Table 4. Demand Estimation Regression Results (2001-2006)

Dependent Variable: Log of Student Performance Index

 Base

Without logged non-school costs ()

interacted with regional dummy

(RD)

Income and price variables (1) (2) (3)

Chapter 70 aid component of adjusted income1.576 1.871 1.917

  (2.47)** (2.57)** (2.58)**

Log of median income 0.082 0.076 0.075

  (2.09)** (1.96)* (2.01)**

Log of tax share -0.265 -0.288 -0.287

  (-4.05)*** (-3.87)*** (-3.75)***

Log of cost index -0.472 -0.513 -0.504

  (-6.38)*** (-6.33)*** (-6.08)***

Log of efficiency index 1.548 1.547 1.705

  (4.01)*** (3.87)*** (3.67)***

Log of non-school costs -0.020   -0.034

  (-1.82)*   (-1.92)*

Page 24: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Other variables      Regional districts (RD) (= 1 for RD and = 0 otherwise) -0.068 0.009 -0.079

  (-1.98)** (1.02) (-2.03)**

RD     -0.249

      (-2.48)**

Percent of college graduates 0.003 0.004 0.003

  (3.63)*** (3.60)*** (3.75)***

Percent of senior citizens 0.000 0.000 0.000

  (0.02) (0.07) (0.18)Percent of low-income students in comparison districts -0.001 -0.001 -0.001

  (-2.33)** (-2.30)** (-2.13)**Percent of special ed students in comparison districts 0.008 0.007 0.007

  (1.48) (1.37) (1.22)

Year dummies (2002, 2003, 2004, 2005, 2006) Yes Yes Yes

Constant Yes Yes Yes

Number of observations 1776 1776 1776

Page 25: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Tax Price with Parcel Tax

The budget constraints

Solve for P and substitute

{ }C SE tV A NP

e

{ }tV A C SY Z tV

N eN

Spending 1dC MCTP

S dS eN eN

Y Z tV P

Page 26: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

California Estimates (D/Y 2011)

About 900 school districts in two years (2003-04 and 2004-05)

Service is measured by an index (API) of several tests in several grades developed for the California school accountability system.

No fixed effects, but clustered errors.

Page 27: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

Demand Results from California

Page 28: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

California, 2

Page 29: Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches

Demand for Public Services

California, 3

These variables are instruments in the cost equation.