hefetz makale 2007

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    1/20

    This article was downloaded by: [ ]On: 23 December 2011, At: 01:07Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH,UK

    Local Government StudiesPublication details, including instructions for authors

    and subscription information:

    http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/flgs20

    Beyond the market versus

    planning dichotomy:

    Understanding privatisation andits reverse in US citiesAmir Hefetz

    a& Mildred Warner

    b

    aTechnion Institute, Haifa, Israel

    bCornell University, Ithaca, NY, USA

    Available online: 17 Jul 2007

    To cite this article: Amir Hefetz & Mildred Warner (2007): Beyond the market versus

    planning dichotomy: Understanding privatisation and its reverse in US cities, Local

    Government Studies, 33:4, 555-572

    To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03003930701417585

    PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

    Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

    This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes.Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expresslyforbidden.

    The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make anyrepresentation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up todate. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae, and drug doses should beindependently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liablefor any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand, or costs or damages

    http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03003930701417585http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/flgs20
  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    2/20

    whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connectionwith or arising out of the use of this material.

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    3/20

    Beyond the Market versus PlanningDichotomy: UnderstandingPrivatisation and its Reversein US Cities

    AMIR HEFETZ* & MILDRED WARNER***Technion Institute, Haifa, Israel

    **Cornell University, Ithaca, NY, USA

    ABSTRACT City service delivery requires planners and city managers to move beyondthe publicprivate dichotomy and explore the benefits of interaction between marketsand planning. Using International City County Management survey data on US local

    governments from 1992, 1997 and 2002, we find a shift where reverse contracting (re-

    internalisation) now exceeds the level of new contracting out (privatisation). We modelhow a theoretical shift from new public management to new public service in publicadministration mirrors a behavioural shift among city managers. Results confirm theneed to balance economic concerns with political engagement of citizens and lendempirical support to a theory of social choice that links communicative planning withmarket management.

    Dynamic Public Service Delivery Reflects New Public Administration

    and Planning Approaches

    There have been several waves of reforms in public administration and

    public service delivery. Since the early 1980s the new public management

    wave has captured the attention of city managers and public administration

    theorists (Hood, 1991; Kettl, 1997; Osborne & Gaebler, 1992). New public

    management argues that local government can become more efficient as a

    consequence of both market competition and adopting business-style

    management (Dunleavy & Hood, 1994; Megginson & Netter, 2001; Osborne

    & Plastrick, 1997). However, empirical evidence does not always support the

    superior efficiency of market delivery (Bel & Warner, 2008; Boyne, 1998a;

    Hodge, 2000), and city managers exhibit a more pragmatic and dynamic use

    Correspondence Address: Amir Hefetz, Department of Town and Regional Planning, Technion

    Institute, Haifa, Israel. Email: [email protected]

    Local Government Studies,

    Vol. 33, No. 4, 555 572, August 2007

    ISSN 0300-3930 Print/1743-9388 Online 2007 Taylor & Francis

    DOI: 10.1080/03003930701417585

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    4/20

    of markets by contracting out some services and bringing other previously

    privatised services back in house through reverse contracting or re-

    internalisation (Entwistle, 2005; Hefetz & Warner, 2004; Sclar, 2000;

    Warner & Hebdon, 2001).New public management reform stresses that markets could be superior,

    whereas current trends in public administration and planning urge the

    public sector to interact not only with markets, but also with communities

    to encourage democratic deliberation and enhance local quality of life

    (Denhardt & Denhardt, 2000; Frug, 1998; Nalbandian, 1999, 2005). This

    alternative reform has been coined the new public service in public

    administration (Denhardt & Denhardt, 2003) and communicative planning

    in the planning field (Healey, 1993). The result is a dynamic decision making

    process which integrates market mechanisms with citizen deliberation andvoice (Allmendinger et al., 2003; McGuirk, 2001; Rashman & Randor,

    2005).

    The new public management has achieved broad acceptance, both in

    theory and practice, across the world (Kettl, 1997). The new public service,

    which shifts emphasis toward public values and service quality (deLeon &

    Denhardt, 2000), is gaining interest among deliberative democracy theorists,

    but has not yet effectively challenged the hegemony of market based

    approaches to public service delivery. Communicative planning, by contrast,

    has obtained wide acceptance across the field of planning (Fischer &Forester, 1993; Healey, 1997). This has led some planners to articulate a

    theory of social choice which moves beyond the either/or dichotomy of

    markets or planning and argues for a balanced position where both

    markets and citizen deliberation can lead towards near-optimal solutions

    (McGuirk, 2001; Sager, 2001). By bringing together theoretical streams in

    both public administration and planning, we outline an ideological shift in

    theory. Using local government service delivery data from municipalities

    across the US for the last decade, we are also able to demonstrate a shift in

    practice.

    Most research has followed the privatisation decisions of local govern-

    ments (Boyne, 1998b; Hirsch, 1995; Savas, 2000), but relatively little

    attention has been given to reverse privatisation, with the exception of

    Warner and Hebdon (2001) in New York State, and Hefetz and Warner

    (2004) who studied this phenomenon across US municipalities from 1992 to

    1997 using International City/County Management Association (ICMA)

    data. No national survey directly measures reverse contracting. To do so, we

    paired ICMA survey responses over time. We found, surprisingly, that the

    level of reverse contracting was two-thirds the level of new contracting. In

    this paper, we follow this methodology and look at the most recent dataavailable for the period 19972002. In the earlier period, 199297,

    new contracting out was 50 per cent larger than the level of reverse

    contracting (18 per cent against 11 per cent). In the most recent period,

    19972002, the proportions flip and reverse contracting is preferred (at 18

    556 A. Hefetz & M. Warner

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    5/20

    per cent of all service delivery) over new contracting out (which falls to 12

    per cent). We find that stable public delivery over the two paired time

    periods, 199297 and 19972002, remains the most common form of service

    delivery at 44 per cent, and stable contracting, at roughly 27 per cent of allservice delivery, is also unchanged. What is interesting is the dynamic

    behaviour at the margin (Figure 1).

    To understand the dynamics of this shift, we build models for new

    contracting out and reverse contracting for each of the two paired time

    periods. Our explanatory variables provide empirical proxies for various

    conceptual concerns of new public management, new public service and

    communicative planning. We find the theoretical shift from new public

    management toward new public service and communicative planning

    mirrors a shift in practice. However, our empirical analysis providesevidence of a managerial and political learning process over the decade that

    moves beyond the market versus planning dichotomy of the theoretical

    debate and embraces the more comprehensive approach of social choice that

    balances attention to both market management and citizen voice.

    Shifts in Public Service Management A Theoretical Framework

    In this section we outline the shift in theory. Frustration with market failure

    arguments and the promise of market approaches offered by public choicetheory (Savas, 1987) led to the new public management and its enthusiasm

    for market competition and a customer focus in public service delivery

    (Osborne & Gaebler, 1992). As experience with new public management

    grew, however, frustration emerged on two fronts. First, recognition of

    the challenges of contract management led to new research on service

    Figure 1. Dynamics of local government service delivery, 19922002. Source: International City/County Management Association, Profile of Alternative Service Delivery Approaches, SurveyData 1992, 1997, 2002 Washington DC. Analysis by author.

    Privatisation and its Reverse in US Cities 557

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    6/20

    characteristics and greater attention to the importance of insights from

    transaction costs economics (Stein, 1990). Second, concern over the loss to

    citizenship in the consumer focus of new public management led to the

    elaboration of public deliberation in the new public service (Denhardt &Denhardt, 2003). Likewise, planning shifted from a technocratic manage-

    ment focus to give greater attention to deliberative democracy in decision

    making (Forester, 1999). The last decades of the twentieth century were

    characterised by a debate among academics over the relative importance

    of market and deliberative approaches (Savas, 1987; Sclar, 2000). But

    social choice theory moves us beyond this dichotomy toward a balanced

    position that recognises benefits from both markets and citizen engage-

    ment (Sager, 2002). We argue that the shift in local government practice

    toward more reverse contracting is, in fact, a rebalancing that reflectsthe emergence of a social choice position which values both markets and

    citizen voice.

    Market Failure and Market Possibilities

    When markets fail to meet optimal economic welfare, government inter-

    vention is necessary to provide goods and services. Reasons for markets

    not to function optimally relate to monopoly, information asymmetry,

    lower supply level, and myopic use of economic resources by self-interestedcitizens taking a short-term view (Alexander, 2001; Bozeman, 2002; Lowery,

    1998).

    Market theories and market failure theories are based on the economic

    rationale believed to motivate individuals. This rationale is challenged by

    new planning theories that presume a broader set of motivations influences

    individual and group behaviour (Allmendinger, 2002). In dense and con-

    gested metropolitan regions a simple private market is not enough (Hirsch,

    1995). The larger and more variable the community is, the more important

    the role local governments have in providing these market-failed goods and

    services (transportation, recreation, health, etc.) (Frug, 1999). In rural

    peripheral regions, at the other end of the scale, markets for public goods

    are limited so the market mechanism is less reliable (e.g. government may be

    the only available provider) (Kodrzycki, 1994; Warner, 2006; Warner &

    Hefetz, 2003).

    However, concern with overproduction of market-failed public services

    by government led to the notion of public choice theory which argued that a

    competitive mechanism for public services could exist at least at the local

    level (Tiebout, 1956). This provided the foundation for further elaboration

    of market based competitive service delivery through the new publicmanagement (Osborne & Gaebler, 1992) and led to increased support for

    the notion of privatisation (Savas, 1987). But markets for public services

    were found to be at best quasi-markets with limited competition and serious

    principal agent problems (Lowery, 1998).

    558 A. Hefetz & M. Warner

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    7/20

    Practical experience suggests that markets still are not adequately

    recognised for the many spontaneous ways in which they may organise

    urban life. Although cities face the challenge of congestion that creates

    public goods problems, they also enjoy the potential of market solutionsbased on agglomeration economies and voluntary bargaining (Webster &

    Lai, 2003). Thus, for example, both private shuttle buses and public transit

    exist side by side in most cities.

    Transaction Cost Theory

    Transaction cost economics acknowledges the governance structure of

    markets and the need to frame the make or buy (contracting) decision

    in the context of market structure and principal agent problems. Toevaluate the advantages and disadvantages of out-sourcing public services

    (Williamson, 1999), one must look at both the nature of the government

    organisation and the nature of the market (Williamson, 1987). As public

    administration scholars recognised the importance of transaction costs, they

    tended to divide this concept into two factions: the bureaucratic view and the

    market view which represent alternative emphases in calculating transaction

    costs. The bureaucratic view downplays problems with high transaction costs

    in the market and highlights the disadvantages of bureaucracy (Eggers &

    OLeary, 1995; Osborne & Plastrick, 1997; Savas, 2000). In this case, trans-action costs of government bureaucracy are assumed to be greater than

    transaction costs in the market. The core ideology of this view is that markets

    may work with the support of the right public regulatory framework, but

    with a limited direct delivery role for governments.

    In contrast to the bureaucratic view of transaction costs, the market view

    argues transaction costs in public service markets are high due to complex

    contract specification and performance monitoring (Brown & Potoski, 2003;

    Kavanagh & Parker, 1999; Lowery, 1998; Sclar, 2000). This view of trans-

    action costs builds on the rationale to deliver services within the public

    sector, unless transaction costs of outsourcing are lower than internal costs

    of in-house production (Nelson, 1997; Pitelis, 1991). Under this view, the

    nature of a specific service becomes very important, and the monitoring

    process is a key to success or failure of the outsourcing decision. For this

    reason, easily specified services like refuse collection are considered better

    candidates for contracting out than complex social services. However,

    empirical evidence on services such as water distribution and waste collec-

    tion has not shown consistent cost savings under privatisation (Bel &

    Warner, 2007; Domberger & Jensen, 1997). This failure is not simply due

    to transaction costs; it has to do with the industrial organisation of themarket itself (Warner & Bel, 2006). Similarly, research on reverse con-

    tracting finds lack of cost savings, difficulties in contract specification and

    monitoring and problems with market concentration (Warner & Hefetz,

    2004).

    Privatisation and its Reverse in US Cities 559

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    8/20

    From Public Choice to Social Choice

    Public choice theory focuses on the political motivations behind managerial

    decisions in the public sector and their source of influence (e.g. the effect ofpowerful groups on government regulation and subsidies) (Tullock, 1997).

    Public mangers, within the framework of public choice, are credited as self-

    interested agents who try to maximise their political utility through longer

    terms or larger budgets (Niskanen, 1971). The limit to public choice is that

    democratic choice and rational political systems cannot meet optimal social

    solutions simultaneously.

    Contemporary planning theory emphasises communicative rationality

    (Fischer & Forester, 1993). Social behaviour reflects social values, not

    just self-interest. Lowery (2000) points out that public choice does not allowfor interdependence and communication to affect individual preferences.

    Through deliberation it is possible to express collective desires (Healey,

    1996). Frug (1999) argues that community building is the ultimate public

    good which reflects the option to stay and exercise voice over services.

    Social choice theory takes this one step further and notes that through

    incremental dialogue, in an iterative process that combines both markets and

    planning, more socially optimal solutions can be reached. The social choice

    approach recognises the importance of both transaction cost theory and

    social communicative theory (Sager, 1998). The major assumption of socialchoice theory is that deliberation matters. More heterogeneous places, in

    which conflicting interests are present, face a higher level of constraints to

    specify services and a greater need for a public deliberative process. Local

    governments are public organisations that recognise the potential of market

    solutions and the need for debate to respond to diversity and resolve conflicts.

    For example, our analysis of the ICMA data shows that many US local

    governments contracted out recreation services in search of efficiency gains.

    But citizen concerns over access and control have fuelled a large reverse

    contracting process. These re-internalised services now benefit from more

    efficient market-style management (e.g. user fees) but also have built in more

    robust and explicit mechanisms to ensure community voice and control

    (neighbourhood or parent oversight committees) so that a social optimum,

    beyond mere economic efficiency, is reached.

    A key role of local government is to create the framework for a

    deliberative process whereby citizens develop the political capacity to engage

    their differences and identify solutions that do not divide the community

    (Nalbandian, 2005). A social choice approach can use a combination of

    market incentives and public deliberation to reach a solution that is socially

    optimal. Planning critics have argued that markets would yield moreinclusionary zoning than planning when the public review process is

    captured by special interests (Staley & Scarlett, 1997). But the market

    typically undersupplies public amenities parks, open space and affordable

    housing. Several cities have combined the deliberative mechanisms of

    560 A. Hefetz & M. Warner

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    9/20

    land use planning and zoning with market based development rights trad-

    ing schemes to promote land use and housing development that is more

    environmentally sustainable and socially equitable (Johnston & Madison,

    1997).The dichotomy between markets and planning is fading as transaction

    costs are used to help explain the relationships between government and

    market (Nelson, 1997; Williamson, 1999), and social choice brings in a

    dynamic view over space and time that shows how markets and planning

    can work together through deliberation (Sager, 2001). A social choice

    framework acknowledges that a mixed market and planning environment

    better fits the needs of complex cities.

    Figure 2 shows how managers in a social choice framework balance the

    benefits of competition (as argued by new public management), with theneed to structure markets (as argued by transaction cost economics) and to

    ensure citizen voice (as argued by new public service and communicative

    planning). We hypothesise that the shift in preference for new contracting

    out to reverse contracting over the decade 19922002 reflects a managerial

    learning process that recognises the limits of market competition, the need

    to manage markets and ensure public voice. We expect the importance of

    transactions costs and citizen voice will increase over the decade. These

    theoretical components support a theory of social choice and help explain

    the shift back towards public delivery as a rebalancing of service delivery tobenefit from markets as well as citizen deliberation.

    Data and Methods Longitudinal Outlook

    To measure structural shifts we combine the ICMA surveys from 1992, 1997

    and 2002 and look at patterns of service delivery over time. The ICMA data

    cover 64 public services in seven broad areas: public works, public safety,

    public utilities, human services, parks and recreation, culture and arts and

    support functions. The main alternatives to direct government delivery are

    contracts to private for-profit firms and intergovernmental contracting. The

    Figure 2. A framework for understanding local government service delivery.

    Privatisation and its Reverse in US Cities 561

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    10/20

    surveys also ask managers about factors that are motivators or obstacles to

    alternative service delivery.

    The ICMA sample frame includes all counties with more than 25,000

    population (roughly 1,600) and cities over 10,000 population (roughly3,300). Roughly a third of all governments contacted responded (31 per cent

    for 1992 and 32 per cent for 1997, 24 per cent for 2002) but only about 40

    per cent of respondents are the same in any two paired surveys. To track

    changes over time, we paired the surveys into two sets: 628 governments

    responded to the first two surveys (1992 and 1997), and 460 responded to the

    latest two (1997 and 2002).

    The ICMA surveys ask only how the service is provided currently, not

    whether this is a new contract or longstanding procedure. To determine the

    level of new contracting out and the level of reverse contracting we needed amethod to track changes in forms of service delivery for every service for

    each government. We coded the data into three exclusive categories. Our

    method distinguishes whether a service is provided entirely by government

    employees, by mixed public delivery and private contracts, or by contracts

    exclusively. We combined these exclusive alternatives over time to create a

    transition matrix that allows us to track changes in service delivery choice as

    shown in Figure 3. This matrix method enables us to compare stability in

    form of service delivery and to assess shifts towards direct public delivery

    or towards outsourcing. This technique is explained in more detail in Hefetzand Warners work (2004).

    Conceptual Framework and Model Variables

    In the first part of the paper we introduced the social choice theoretical

    framework, which uses both planning and public administration approaches.

    The new public management focuses on managerial capacity, while

    Figure 3. Matrix for tracking local government service delivery patterns over time (based onHefetz and Warner 2004).

    562 A. Hefetz & M. Warner

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    11/20

    transaction costs and market failure emphasise the nature of the service and

    the market-place. New public service and communicative planning concen-

    trate on political interaction and voice. Social choice brings all these concerns

    together into one theoretical framework. We compare changes in servicedelivery patterns using this theoretical framework. Transaction costs are

    assessed with measures of service characteristics and principal agent pro-

    blems. New public management concerns are addressed with management,

    fiscal stress and efficiency variables, and level of prior for-profit privatisation.

    Place is used to distinguish potential for market failure. A citizen voice index

    is created to test for new public service and communicative planning con-

    cerns. Means and standard deviations for all variables are shown in Table 1.

    Service Delivery Patterns

    Our dependent values are the level of new contracting out and the level of

    reverse contracting controlled for service provision level. Between 1992 and

    1997 on average 6.3 services were newly contracted out while 3.7 services

    were brought back in-house on a base of 34.5 services provided by the

    average government. This ratio flipped in the 19972002 period. Only 3.5

    services were newly contracted out, while 5.3 were reverse contracted.

    Although service shedding resulted in a lower number of publicly provided

    services in the 19972002 period (31.3 on average), the level of public

    Table 1. Descriptive Statistics for Variables in the Empirical Model

    1992 and 1997Paired Surveys

    1997 and 2002Paired Surveys

    Variable Mean St. Dev. Mean St. Dev.

    Number of Newly Contracted Out Services 6.3 6.1 3.5 3.8Number of Reverse Contracted Services 3.7 3.7 5.3 6.0Number of Services Provided Both Time Periods 34.5 8.7 31.3 8.9Percent Prior For-Profit Privatisation 0.17 0.115 0.20 0.161Prior Asset Specificity Score 1.78 0.563 1.51 0.710Current Asset Specificity Score 1.76 0.802 1.68 0.650Prior Measurement Difficulty Score 0.45 0.303 0.60 0.487Current Measurement Difficulty Score 0.52 0.420 0.47 0.382Fiscal Pressure (dummy, 1 yes) 0.59 0.492 0.52 0.500Prior Local Expenditure Per Capita

    (dfl 1992 100)1878.7 611.3 828.7 578.4

    Independent Rural Places (dummy, 1 rural) 0.24 0.425 0.20 0.402Core Cities (dummy, 1 core) 0.24 0.428 0.28 0.449Current Voice Index (% yes of 10 factors) 0.16 0.184 0.16 0.176Council Manager (dummy, 1manager) 0.72 0.448 0.74 0.440

    Prior Mixed Delivery 0.19 0.132 0.20 0.162Current Mixed Delivery 0.19 0.162 0.25 0.176N 628 460

    Source: International City/County Management Association, Profile of Alternative ServiceDelivery Approaches, Survey Data 1992, 1997, 2002 Washington DC.1U.S. Census of Government Finance Files 1992, 1997.Author calculations.

    Privatisation and its Reverse in US Cities 563

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    12/20

    delivery of those services that remained actually increased. We also see a

    dramatic increase (from 19 per cent to 25 per cent of all service delivery) in

    mixed delivery where public delivery and private contracts are combined for

    the same service. This redundancy was labelled benchmarking by Mirandaand Lerner (1995) who studied it in the first ICMA survey in 1982, a

    tradition followed by Brown et al. (2007) who focus only on transaction costs.

    However, we find mixed delivery is a form of market management used not

    only to control transaction costs but also to ensure citizen voice and govern-

    ment engagement in service delivery (Warner & Hefetz, 2007). Thus, mixed

    delivery is an important part of the dynamic use of markets and planning

    by local government. Other independent variables are described below.

    Transaction Costs

    The literature on transaction costs focuses on the nature of services

    themselves. Stein (1990) in his analysis of urban services and use of alter-

    native service delivery mechanisms, characterised services by their level of

    asset specificity and measurability. Brown and Potoski (2003) characterised

    each of the 64 ICMA services by level of asset specificity (low 1, high 5)

    and difficulty of measurement (easy 1, hard 5) based on survey rankings

    from 35 city managers. We advanced Brown and Potoskis measures with an

    industrial organisation framework by controlling them for provision level,and the probability to provide services by either public employees, or con-

    tracts with for-profit providers for each municipality.1 Higher asset specificity

    in publicly delivered services should reduce the likelihood of new contracting

    out. Greater difficulty in measuring for-profit contracts should decrease the

    probability of contracting out.

    Fiscal Stress and Efficiency

    Economists believe that the major motivation for reform is low efficiency

    and pressure to reduce expenditures. This belief is essential to new public

    management. However, we see a reduction in fiscal stress (as reported by

    city managers) over the two time periods. We also control for local

    expenditures using US Census of Government finance data on average

    expenditure per capita (deflated 1992 100). We see that on average

    expenditures dropped from $880 per capita in 1992 to $830 per capita in

    1997. We expect fiscal stress and efficiency measures to be significant in the

    first period when fiscal stress was higher, and less significant in the later

    period when fiscal stress fell and managers began to embrace a broader set

    of concerns raised by new public service. The new public management viewsmarket delivery as superior to government and we include prior level of for-

    profit privatisation as a measure of the enthusiasm for contracting out.

    However, if there are problems with external contracting, we would expect

    to see more reverse contracting in the later period.

    564 A. Hefetz & M. Warner

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    13/20

    Market Failure/Complexity

    Market failure is, in part, determined by place structure. Metro core

    governments, with a wider range of service responsibilities and moreheterogeneous populations may have more problems with market delivery.

    Rural independent places are expected to face less robust or competitive

    alternative supplier markets. Thus, both urban and rural places may have

    less new contracting and more reverse contracting but for different reasons.

    We expect cities to reverse their contracts due to the understanding that

    there must be a core public force to increase flexibility and enable

    responsiveness to changing circumstances, while rural places may reverse

    contracts due to lack of a viable private market for public services.

    We use Office of Management and Budget criteria to differentiate corecities from outlying suburbs. Core cities have 40 per cent of their residents

    working in the central city of the Metropolitan Statistical Area and

    employment residence ratios of at least 0.75. All other metropolitan cities

    are classified as outlying suburban. Rural independent municipalities are

    determined by the non-metropolitan status of their county (OMB, 2000).

    Suburbs are the reference category and are expected to be more favoured

    by market approaches (Warner, 2006; Warner & Hefetz, 2002a). New

    public service concerns would be evidenced by lower levels of new con-

    tracting out in the later period, and higher levels of reverse contracting.New public management would appear as continued preference for new

    outsourcing.

    Management and Citizen Voice

    Council manager forms of government are assumed to benefit from more

    professional management. New public management argues for a managerial

    learning process that leads toward more private production. New public

    service, on the other hand, encourages increased attention to citizen voice.

    We construct a voice index derived from managers answers to ten questions

    regarding citizen engagement in the process of service delivery based on an

    index used by Warner and Hefetz (2002b).2 We expect a shift where voice

    becomes significant in the later period. If managerial learning reflects the

    broader social choice approach, we would expect attention to transaction

    costs, market failure and citizen voice all to be reflected in the managerial

    learning process.

    Results Modelling the Framework in a Probit ModelWe tested this conceptual framework in a probit regression model3 where

    the dependent variables were the level of new contracting out and reverse

    contracting over the level of services provided in both time periods by each

    municipality. In addition, we calculated marginal effects for independent

    Privatisation and its Reverse in US Cities 565

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    14/20

    variables that were found to be significant.4 The model coefficients indicate

    only the direction of the independent effect. The marginal effect allows us to

    compare the strength of different independent effects.

    Several variables were found to affect the level of contracting direction(contracting out or reverse contracting) significantly, as shown in Table 2.

    Place structure (metropolitan status), mixed delivery, and asset specificity

    were significant in three of the four different models, giving support to the

    importance of market failure and transaction cost theories. Support for new

    public management is seen in the first period as governments experiment

    with contracting even when asset specificity is high. Support for new public

    service appears in the second period models where the citizen voice variable

    becomes significant for the first time.

    Transaction costs are of primary importance in explaining levels of newcontracting out. An increase in prior asset specificity scale by one unit

    increases new contracting out by 17 per cent suggesting that managers were

    following new public management ideology and experimenting with

    contracting out asset-specific services between 1992 and 1997. As a result,

    asset specificity of publicly provided services dropped with new contracting

    out in 1997. This effect disappears in the 19972002 period as managers

    learned that contracting out highly asset-specific services is problematic.

    Managerial learning also is shown in the reverse contracting model, where

    current asset specificity is higher among places with higher levels ofcontracting back in. Thus, the difficulty of contracting out asset-specific

    services reflects a managerial learning process over the two time periods.

    A similar process of managerial learning is found with measurability. New

    contracting out in the first period was higher when measurement difficulty

    was higher; this variable had the largest marginal effect. By the second

    period managers had learned not to contract out difficult-to-measure

    services and the relationship became negative. Measurement difficulty had

    no effect in the models of reverse contracting.

    Fiscal stress led to more contracting out in the second period but was not

    significant on reverse contracting. Per capita expenditures were only

    significant in the second period and show that both places with higher

    new contracting and higher reverse contracting had lower expenditures. This

    implies that efficiency gains can be achieved by market management

    contracting out and reverse contracting not by contracting out alone.

    Place matters and we see that core metro areas have lower levels of new

    contracting out in the second period and higher levels of reverse contracting

    than their suburban counterparts in both periods. The need to integrate

    planning with markets is especially important for complex, heterogeneous

    core cities. Rural municipalities also show lower levels of new contractingout in the later period and higher levels of reverse contracting in the first

    period but lower levels in the later period. This may reflect less capability

    to manage markets due to limited competition and less professional

    management.

    566 A. Hefetz & M. Warner

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    15/20

    Table2.ModelResultsExplainingShiftsinContractingandItsReverse

    NewContractingOut

    ReverseContracting

    19921997

    19972002

    19921997

    1997

    2002

    Variable

    Coeff.

    Marg.

    Effect

    Coeff.

    Marg.

    Effect

    Coeff.

    Marg.

    Effect

    Coeff.

    Marg.

    Effect

    PriorForProfit

    Delivery

    73.475

    714.6%

    71.229

    1.709

    70.135

    PriorAssetSpec

    ificationScore

    0.380

    17.0%

    70.025

    70.524

    71.0%

    70.059

    72.2%

    CurrentAssetSpecificationScore

    70.513

    710.1%

    70.078

    72.6%

    0.544

    27.5%

    70.025

    PriorMeasurem

    entDifficultyScore

    1.359

    32.0%

    0.424

    70.929

    70.093

    CurrentMeasurementDifficultyScore

    0.050

    70.211

    74.3%

    70.023

    0.037

    FiscalStress

    70.025

    0.086

    2.6%

    0.030

    70.049

    PriorPerCapita

    LocalExpenditure

    0.006

    70.106

    73.3%

    70.012

    70.049

    71.5%

    CoreMetro

    70.011

    70.078

    72.2%

    0.088

    1.0%

    0.158

    4.7%

    RuralIndependent

    0.007

    70.067

    71.9%

    0.103

    1.2%

    70.091

    72.5%

    VoiceIndex

    70.046

    70.335

    73.3%

    0.004

    0.211

    2.2%

    CouncilManage

    r

    70.018

    70.003

    0.016

    70.028

    PriorMixedDelivery

    70.996

    77.3%

    70.367

    73.3%

    1.779

    8.4%

    70.055

    70.5%

    CurrentMixedDelivery

    0.302

    3.3%

    0.125

    70.243

    70.8%

    0.332

    3.5%

    Constant

    70.662

    70.793

    71.617

    70.839

    GoodnessofFit

    w2

    3671

    P5

    0.001

    w2

    2170

    P5

    0.001

    w2

    1914

    P5

    0.001

    w2

    3012

    P5

    0.001

    Shadedcellsrepresentsignificantcoefficientatp

    5

    0.05

    Source:InternationalCity/CountyManagement

    Association,ProfileofAlternativeServiceDeliveryApproaches,SurveyData1992,1997,2002Washington

    DC.Analysisby

    Author.

    Privatisation and its Reverse in US Cities 567

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    16/20

    The voice index was insignificant in the first period for either model (out

    or reverse), but it became important in the second period leading to lower

    levels of new contracting out and higher levels of reverse contracting. This

    suggests that city managers recognise new public service and communicativeplanning concerns and seek to balance citizen voice with market manage-

    ment issues as implied by social choice theory. The council manager variable

    was not significant in any model but we believe that the managerial learning

    process has been captured in the transaction costs, place and voice variables.

    A high level of prior mixed service delivery diminishes the enthusiasm to

    contract out and encourages reverse contracting. In contrast, the current

    rate of mixed delivery encourages contracting out, but its effect on reverse

    contracting is inconsistent. In the first period it has a small negative effect,

    and later it positively affects the level of reverse contracting. Mixed deliveryfacilitates the decision to outsource services, but it also makes reverse

    contracting possible as government retains a position in the service delivery

    process. Building on the social choice approach, we consider mixed delivery

    as more than the intuitive benchmarking described by Miranda and Lerner

    (1995), and see it as a tool to enhance citizen voice and government

    involvement in service delivery (Warner & Hefetz, 2007).

    Current mixed service delivery complements new contracting out in the

    first period, but it complements reverse contracting during the later period.

    Reforms need a moderator and mixed delivery seems to play that role. Theidea of moderating between new contracting out and reverse contracting

    means that managers integrate costs from both make and buy options in

    order to get the best value. When it is difficult to specify the contract, it is

    better to maintain both alternatives through mixed delivery. These results

    indicate a learning process motivated first by an ideological pro-privatisation

    push (new public management), but moderated later by a pragmatic turn

    which gives greater attention to market management (transaction costs) and

    citizen voice (new public service, communicative planning) in a combined

    framework (social choice).

    Conclusion

    In this paper we have described a shift in theory from markets over planning

    as argued by new public management, to a more integrated and balanced

    view that combines markets and planning in an attempt to answer both

    efficiency concerns and citizen needs (social choice). We use this

    comprehensive social choice framework to explain why US municipalities

    have shifted from a preference for contracting to a preference for public

    delivery mixed with contracting out over the last decade.In the 199297 period, city managers were innovative and explored new

    public management reforms by testing the potential for more market based

    forms of service delivery. But something different explains the shift from

    market back to government delivery in the later, 19972002, period.

    568 A. Hefetz & M. Warner

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    17/20

    Managers have expanded their concerns beyond transaction costs and

    efficiency to give attention to citizen voice in the service delivery process.

    This broader set of concerns reflects the social choice approach that includes

    both market management and planning to create a nearly optimal solution.We learn that reforms, like other products, have a life cycle (Bel & Costas,

    2006). First there is the innovation (contracting out, new public manage-

    ment), then there is a period of wider use, and in the end the reform is

    replaced by another reform (reverse contracting, new public service).

    Innovative government, we claim, is the one that manages to fit the best mix

    of delivery options to each service and meet higher standards within its

    budget constraint. In order to find that mix, governments need to exercise

    alternative modes over time and develop monitoring and communicative

    tools that improve their control over service providers, on the one hand, andadvance their responsiveness to citizens, on the other.

    Although privatisation has been studied from many different angles, we

    still need to understand the interactions between markets and planning. In

    modern cities, many public services fail to meet the classic theory of market

    failure, but public delivery may still be required due to complexity and social

    demands. Governments are exploring alternative ways to deliver goods

    through a quasi-market mechanism. By viewing public service delivery as a

    planning tool, we can learn how governments use the service delivery

    process to improve efficiency and public engagement.We have shown theoretically how new public administration approaches

    can intersect with modern planning theories. Empirically we see evidence of

    a more comprehensive social choice approach emerging where city managers

    balance market delivery with attention to citizen voice. While public adminis-

    tration is recognising that political capacity requires a government role to

    engage and resolve urban conflict, the social choice approach recognises the

    power in combining market approaches with planning. It is the intersection

    between markets and planning that creates a more robust management

    process to meet social objectives. The combination of new contracting and

    reverse contracting reflects an effort by pragmatic managers to get the

    balance right.

    Acknowledgements

    Funding for this research was provided in part by the National Research

    Initiative of the Cooperative State Research, Education and Extension

    Service, U.S. Dept. of Agriculture, Grant No. NYC-121524.

    Notes

    1 The construction of these variables is as follows: for asset specificity, the score is the average

    of asset specificity across all services provided times the percentage of services provided

    entirely by public employees. The measurability score is the average measurability score

    across all services provided times the percentage contracted out to private firms.

    Privatisation and its Reverse in US Cities 569

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    18/20

    2 The voice index is the average number of yes responses to the following set of factor

    questions: active citizen group favouring privatisation; opposition from citizens; evaluation

    of feasibility by service recipients/consumers; evaluation of feasibility by citizens advisory

    committees; established a citizens advisory committee on private alternatives; surveyed

    citizens during implementation; kept the service complaint mechanism in-house; monitored

    citizen satisfaction after implementation; conducted citizen surveys after implementation,

    monitoring citizen complaints.

    One of the reviewers was concerned that the voice measure would fail to capture the role of

    voice among respondents who did not contract out any services. We checked the data and

    found 99 per cent of the sample restructured service delivery. Only 1 per cent of the sample

    did not externalise any services (5 places in 1992, 7 in 1997 and 5 in 2002).

    3 In the probit model, percentages are transformed into the inverse of the cumulative normal

    distribution so that probabilities that range from zero to one are normally distributed all

    along the scale.

    4 The marginal effect is the percentage increase or decrease in contracting out, or in reverse

    contracting, as a result of adding one extra unit of the independent variable. For continuous

    variables, this unit is the difference between the mean minus one standard deviation and the

    mean plus one standard deviation, while for a dichotomous variable it is the probability

    between zero and one units of this variable.

    References

    Alexander, E.R. (2001) Why planning vs. markets is an oxymoron: asking the right question,

    Planning and Markets, 4(1), http://www-pam.usc.edu/volume4/v4i1a2s1.html.

    Allmendinger, P. (2002) Towards a post-positivist typology of planning theory, Planning

    Theory, 1(1), pp.7799.

    Allmendinger, P., Tewdwr-Jones, M. & Morphet, J. (2003) Public scrutiny, standards and the

    planning system: assessing professional values within a modernized local government, Public

    Administration, 81(4), pp.761780.

    Bel, G. & Costas, A. (2006) Do public sector reforms get rusty? Local privatization in Spain,

    Journal of Policy Reform, 9, pp.124.

    Bel, G. & Warner, M.E. (2008) Challenging issues in local privatization, Environment and

    Planning C: Government and Policy (forthcoming).

    Boyne, G.A. (1998a) Public Choice Theory and Local Government: A Comparative Analysis of

    the U.K. And the U.S.A. (Houndmills, UK and New York City: Macmillan and St. Martins

    Press).

    Boyne, G.A. (1998b) The determinants of variations in local service contracting garbage in,garbage out?, Urban Affairs Review, 34(1), pp.150163.

    Bozeman, B. (2002) Public-value failure: when efficient markets may not do, Public

    Administration Review, 62(2), pp.145161.

    Brown, T.L. & Potoski, M. (2003) Managing contract performance: a transaction costs

    approach, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 22(2), pp.275297.

    Brown, T., Potoski, M. & van Slyke, D. (2007) Changing modes of service delivery: costs and

    constraints, Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy (forthcoming).

    deLeon, L. & Denhardt, R.B. (2000) The political theory of reinvention, Public Administration

    Review, 60(2), pp.8997.

    Denhardt, J.V. & Denhardt, R.B. (2003) The New Public Service: Serving, Not Steering

    (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe).Denhardt, R.B. & Denhardt, J.V. (2000) The New public management: serving rather than

    steering, Public Administration Review, 60(6), pp.549559.

    Domberger, S. & Jensen, P. (1997) Contracting out by the public sector: theory, evidence,

    prospects, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 13(4), pp.6778.

    Dunleavy, P. & Hood, C. (1994) From old public administration to new public management,

    Public Money and Management (JulySeptember), pp.916.

    570 A. Hefetz & M. Warner

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    19/20

    Eggers, W.D. & OLeary, J. (1995) Revolution at the Roots: Making Our Government Smaller,

    Better, and Closer to Home (New York: Free Press).

    Entwistle, T. (2005) Why are local authorities reluctant to externalise (and do they have good

    reason)?, Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 23(2), pp.191206.

    Fischer, F. & Forester, J. (1993) The Argumentative Turn in Policy Analysis and Planning

    (Durham, NC and London: Duke University Press).

    Forester, J. (1999) The Deliberative Practitioner: Encouraging Participatory Planning Processes

    (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).

    Frug, G.E. (1998) City services, New York University Law Review, 73(1), pp.2396.

    Frug, G.E. (1999) City Making: Building Communities without Building Walls (Princeton, NJ:

    Princeton University Press).

    Healey, P. (1993) Planning through debate: the communicative turn in planning theory, in:

    F. Fischer & J. Forester (Eds) The Argumentative Turn in Policy Analysis and Planning

    (Durham, NC and London: Duke University Press).

    Healey, P. (1996) The communicative turn in planning theory and its implications for spatial

    strategy formation, Environment and Planning B: Planning and Design, 23(2), pp.217234.

    Healey, P. (1997) Collaborative Planning: Shaping Places in Fragmented Societies (Vancouver:

    UBC Press).

    Hefetz, A. & Warner, M.E. (2004) Privatization and its reverse: explaining the dynamics of the

    government contracting process, Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory,

    14(2), pp.171190.

    Hirsch, W.Z. (1995) Contracting out by urban governments a review, Urban Affairs Review,

    30(3), pp.458472.

    Hodge, G.A. (2000) Privatization: An International Review of Performance (Boulder, CO:

    Westview Press).

    Hood, C. (1991) A public management for all seasons?, Public Administration, 69(Spring),

    pp.319.

    Johnston, R.A. & Madison, M.E. (1997) From landmarks to landscapes: a review of current

    practices in the transfer of development rights, Journal of the American Planning Association,

    63(3), pp.365379.

    Kavanagh, I. & Parker, D. (1999) Managing the contract: a transaction cost analysis of

    externalization, Local Government Studies, 26(4), pp.122.

    Kettl, D. (1997) The global revolution in public management: driving themes, missing links,

    Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 16(3), pp.446462.

    Kodrzycki, Y.K. (1994) Privatization of local public services: lessons for New England, New

    England Economic Review (May/June), pp.3146.

    Lowery, D. (1998) Consumer sovereignty and quasi-market failure, Journal of Public

    Administration Research and Theory, 8(2), pp.137172.Lowery, D. (2000) A transactions costs model of metropolitan governance: allocation versus

    redistribution in urban America, Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory,

    10(1), pp.4978.

    McGuirk, P.M. (2001) Situating communicative planning theory: context, power, and

    knowledge, Environment and Planning A, 33(2), pp.195217.

    Megginson, W.L. & Netter, J.M. (2001) From state to market: a survey of empirical studies on

    privatization, Journal of Economic Literature, 39(June), pp.321389.

    Miranda, R. & Lerner, A. (1995) Bureaucracy, organizational redundancy, and the

    privatization of public services, Public Administration Review, 55(2), pp.193200.

    Nalbandian, J. (1999) Facilitating community, enabling democracy: new roles for local

    government managers, Public Administration Review, 59(3), pp.187197.Nalbandian, J. (2005) Professionals and the conflicting forces of administrative modernization

    and civic engagement, American Review of Public Administration, 35(4), pp.311326.

    Nelson, M.A. (1997) Municipal government approaches to service delivery: an analysis from a

    transactions cost perspective, Economic Inquiry, 35(1), pp.8296.

    Niskanen, W.A. (1971) Bureaucracy and Representative Government (Chicago: Aldine

    Atherton).

    Privatisation and its Reverse in US Cities 571

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011

  • 8/3/2019 hefetz makale 2007

    20/20

    OMB (2000) Alternative Approaches to Defining Metropolitan and Nonmetropolitan Areas

    (Washington, DC: Office of Management and Budget), http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/

    fedreg/msa.html.

    Osborne, D.E. & Gaebler, T. (1992) Reinventing Government: How the Entrepreneurial Spirit Is

    Transforming the Public Sector (Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley).

    Osborne, D.E. & Plastrick, P. (1997) Banishing Bureaucracy (Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley).

    Pitelis, C. (1991) Market and Non-Market Hierarchies: Theory of Institutional Failure (Oxford:

    Blackwell).

    Rashman, L. & Radnor, Z. (2005) Learning to improve: approaches to improving local

    government services, Public Money and Management, 25(1), pp.1926.

    Sager, T. (1998) Meaningful collective choice? Public planning and Arrows theorem, Progress

    in Planning, 50(2), pp.75140.

    Sager, T. (2001) Positive theory of planning: the social choice approach, Environment and

    Planning A, 33(4), pp.629647.

    Sager, T. (2002) Democratic Planning and Social Choice Dilemmas: Prelude to Institutional

    Planning Theory (Aldershot, Hampshire and Burlington, VT: Ashgate).

    Savas, E.S. (1987) Privatization: The Key to Better Government (Chatham, NJ: Chatham House

    Publishers).

    Savas, E.S. (2000) Privatization and PublicPrivate Partnerships (New York: Chatham House

    Publishers).

    Sclar, E. (2000) You Dont Always Get What You Pay For: The Economics of Privatization

    (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press).

    Staley, S. & Scarlett, L. (1997) Market Oriented Planning: Principles and Tools (Los Angeles:

    Reason Public Policy Institute).

    Stein, R.M. (1990) Urban Alternatives: Public and Private Markets in the Provision of Local

    Services (Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press).

    Tiebout, C.M. (1956) A pure theory of local expenditures, Journal of Political Economy, 64(5),

    pp.416424.

    Tullock, G. (1997) Economics of Income Redistribution (Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic

    Publishers).

    Warner, M.E. (2006) Market-based governance and the challenge for rural governments: US

    trends, Social Policy and Administration: An International Journal of Policy and Research,

    40(6), pp.612631.

    Warner, M.E. & Bel, G. (2007) Managing markets for public service: the role of mixed public/

    private delivery of city services, Public Administration Review (forthcoming).

    Warner, M.E. & Hebdon, R. (2001) Local government restructuring: privatization and its

    alternatives, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 20(2), pp.315336.

    Warner, M.E. & Hefetz, A. (2002a) The uneven distribution of market solutions for publicgoods, Journal of Urban Affairs, 24(4), p.15.

    Warner, M.E. & Hefetz, A. (2002b) Applying market solutions to public services: an assessment

    of efficiency, equity and voice, Urban Affairs Review, 38(1), pp.7089.

    Warner, M.E. & Hefetz, A. (2003) Ruralurban differences in privatization: limits to the

    competitive state, Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 21(5), pp.703718.

    Warner, M.E. & Hefetz, A. (2004) Pragmatism over politics: alternative service delivery in local

    government, 19922002, in: The Municipal Yearbook 2004 (Washington, DC: International

    City County Management Association), pp.816.

    Warner, M.E. & Hefetz, A. (2007) Managing markets for public service: the role of mixed

    public/private delivery of city services, Public Administration Review (forthcoming).

    Webster, C.J. & Lai, L.W.C. (2003) Property Rights, Planning and Markets: ManagingSpontaneous Cities (Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar).

    Williamson, O.E. (1987) The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational

    Contracting (New York: MacMillan).

    Williamson, O.E. (1999) Public and private bureaucracies: a transaction cost economics

    perspective, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15(1), pp.306342.

    572 A. Hefetz & M. Warner

    Downloadedby[]at01:0723December2011