42
LAND REFORM, POVERTY REDUCTION, AND GROWTH: EVIDENCE FROM INDIA* TIMOTHY BESLEY AND ROBIN BURGESS In recent times there has been a renewed interest in relationships between redistribution, growth, and welfare. Land reforms in developing countries are often aimed at improving the poor’s access to land, although their effectiveness has often been hindered by political constraints on implementation. In this paper we use panel data on the sixteen main Indian states from 1958 to 1992 to consider whether the large volume of legislated land reforms have had an appreciable impact on growth and poverty. We argue that such land reforms have been associated with poverty reduction. I. INTRODUCTION Finding effective means to relieve poverty is a de ning mission for development economics. To this end, a wide range of policy alternatives has been implemented. However, the bene ts of many such efforts have been questioned. Some argue that political constraints on implementation deny the poor the bene ts of redistributive efforts. Others suggest that bene ts to the poor are undermined by disincentives to generate income. Worse still, these disincentives can afflict the nonpoor who try to qualify for assistance. This in turn leads policy analysts to question the wisdom of implementing redistributive policies at all, focusing instead on policies that promote economic growth. Combatting such pessimism requires empirical evidence that some redistribu- tive policies have achieved their stated goals. This paper studies land reform as a redistributive policy. Throughout the postcolonial period, improvement in the asset base of the poor has been viewed as a central strategy to relieve endemic poverty {Chenery et al. 1970}. In a poor agrarian economy, typical of those in many less developed countries, this implies improving the terms on which the poor have access to land. Signi cant political changes, such as decolonization, have sometimes afforded the opportunity to undertake far-reaching land reforms that transfer property rights to the poor. However, * The authors are grateful to Alberto Alesina, Ahbijit Banerjee, Pranab Bardhan, Clive Bell, Francois Bourgignon, Jean Dre `ze, Lawrence Katz, Michael Lipton, Rohini Pande, Martin Ravallion, a number of seminar participants, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. Timo Henckel and Cecilia Testa provided able research assistance. We also thank STICERD for invaluable nancial support. r 2000 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 2000 389

Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

LR in India

Citation preview

Page 1: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

LAND REFORM, POVERTY REDUCTION, AND GROWTH:EVIDENCE FROM INDIA*

TIMOTHY BESLEY AND ROBIN BURGESS

In recent times there has been a renewed interest in relationships betweenredistribution, growth, and welfare. Land reforms in developing countries areoften aimed at improving the poor’s access to land, although their effectiveness hasoften been hindered by political constraints on implementation. In this paper weuse panel data on the sixteen main Indian states from 1958 to 1992 to considerwhether the large volume of legislated land reforms have had an appreciableimpact on growth and poverty. We argue that such land reforms have beenassociated with poverty reduction.

I. INTRODUCTION

Finding effective means to relieve poverty is a de�ningmission for development economics. To this end, a wide range ofpolicy alternatives has been implemented. However, the bene�tsof many such efforts have been questioned. Some argue thatpolitical constraints on implementation deny the poor the bene�tsof redistributive efforts. Others suggest that bene�ts to the poorare undermined by disincentives to generate income. Worse still,these disincentives can afflict the nonpoor who try to qualify forassistance. This in turn leads policy analysts to question thewisdom of implementing redistributive policies at all, focusinginstead on policies that promote economic growth. Combattingsuch pessimism requires empirical evidence that some redistribu-tive policies have achieved their stated goals.

This paper studies land reform as a redistributive policy.Throughout the postcolonial period, improvement in the assetbase of the poor has been viewed as a central strategy to relieveendemic poverty {Chenery et al. 1970}. In a poor agrarianeconomy, typical of those in many less developed countries, thisimplies improving the terms on which the poor have access toland. Signi�cant political changes, such as decolonization, havesometimes afforded the opportunity to undertake far-reachingland reforms that transfer property rights to the poor. However,

* The authors are grateful to Alberto Alesina, Ahbijit Banerjee, PranabBardhan, Clive Bell, Francois Bourgignon, Jean Dreze, Lawrence Katz, MichaelLipton, Rohini Pande, Martin Ravallion, a number of seminar participants, andtwo anonymous referees for helpful comments. Timo Henckel and Cecilia Testaprovided able research assistance. We also thank STICERD for invaluable�nancial support.

r 2000 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute ofTechnology.The Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 2000

389

Page 2: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

such instances are rare, and more incremental measures arecommon. This is the case in India where land reforms have beenon the policy agenda since independence. These reforms haveinvolved only limited efforts at land redistribution, mostly throughlegislated ceilings on landholding. Legislation aimed at regulat-ing tenancies, for example by improving tenurial security, andreducing the power of absentee landlords and intermediaries aremore common. While the latter need not change the distributionof landholdings, they may improve tenants’ claims to the returnsfrom their land. This may also bene�t the landless by raisingagricultural wages.

India is an important case study of land reform. It is bothhome to a signi�cant fraction of the poor in the developing worldand in the postindependence period was subjected to the largestbody of land reform legislation ever to have been passed in soshort a period in any country {Thorner 1976}. The efficacy of thislegislation has, however, been much debated. The conventionalwisdom following the in�uential commentary of Bardhan {1970} isthat, while land reform legislation abounds, the real impact on theconditions of the poor is muted by unenthusiastic implementationof proposed changes. However, broad-based quantitative testingof this notion does not appear to have been attempted previously.This paper takes advantage of the state level panel data availablefor the sixteen main Indian states from 1958 to 1992 to assessthis. The state is the natural unit of analysis for land reform giventhat state governments have jurisdiction over land reform legisla-tion. The relatively long time period covered by the data alsoallows respectable efforts to deal with some econometric concerns.Our principal �nding is that land reforms do appear to have led toreductions in poverty in India. This �nding is robust to a numberof methods of estimation, and the inclusion/exclusion of manydifferent controls.

We also use our data to investigate the relationship betweenland reform and growth. This relates to more general debatesabout how inequality and growth interact. Alesina and Rodrik{1994} and Persson and Tabellini {1995} have argued that initialinequality is bad for economic growth. The link is through thepolitical system—greater inequality encourages redistributiveactivities that blunt accumulation incentives. However, Hoff andLyon {1995}, Banerjee and Newman {1993}, and Benabou {1996},among others, have emphasized that when markets are incom-plete, then redistribution can alter the terms of agency problems

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS390

Page 3: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

in credit markets and foster accumulation decisions, thus under-mining the standard equity efficiency trade-off. If accumulation isenhanced by redistribution along the growth path, then we wouldexpect to �nd a positive relationship between redistributiveefforts and economic growth. The existing literature has focusedpredominantly on �scal redistributions. By affecting access toland, land reform may have a more lasting effect on poverty. Thisview is consistent with the literature that points to early redistri-butions of land leading to relatively egalitarian access as being animportant precondition for high growth in East Asia (see, forexample, Rodrik {1995}).

Most existing empirical evidence on the links between redis-tribution and growth comes from cross-country data (see Perotti{1996} for a careful review). While informative, there are insur-mountable problems of comparability of data across countries anddealing with concerns about endogeneity. The fact that our datacome from one country with similar data collection strategies ineach state, and the relatively long time period, allow us to makeprogress on this.

Empirical studies of the impact of land reform are rare sincereliable estimation requires data from the pre- and postreformperiods. In India there are numerous case studies of land reform(reviewed below), but few attempts to look at the overall picture.Discussion of the theoretical impact of land reform has beendominated by the frequently found inverse farm size-productivityrelationship, whence small farmers are supposed to achievehigher yields (see Binswanger et al. {1995}). This suggests that�nding means of evening the distribution of landholding shouldlead to productivity gains in addition to redistributive bene�ts.However, land reforms in India are rarely of a form that coulddirectly exploit this possibility. Moreover, careful analyses, suchas Banerjee and Ghatak {1997} show that the theoretical effectson productivity are inherently ambiguous when assessing theimpact of tenancy reforms that allow tenants greater security.

Our main �nding is that there is a robust link between landreform and poverty reduction. Closer scrutiny reveals that, in anIndian context, this is due primarily to land reforms that changethe terms of land contracts rather than actually redistributingland. Consistent with the antipoverty impact, we �nd that landreform has raised agricultural wages. The impact of land reformon growth also depends upon the type of land reform. Overall,there is some evidence that the gain in poverty reduction did come

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 391

Page 4: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

at the expense of lower income per capita. We show that all ofthese results are consistent with a simple model of agriculturalcontracting.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The nextsection discusses background and data issues. Section III exam-ines the impact that land reforms have had on poverty and dealswith potential problems in interpreting the basic results. SectionIV addresses the issue as to whether land reforms can havegeneral equilibrium effects by examining their impact on agricul-tural wages. Section V then turns to the issue of how land reformshave affected economic growth. In Section VI we examine theextent to which land reforms have been redistributive in terms oftheir effect on the distribution of land and income. In Section VIIwe develop a theoretical framework that allows us to interpret ourresults in the light of the literature on agricultural contracting.Section VIII concludes. A Data Appendix details the constructionand sources of the key variables used in the analysis.

II. BACKGROUND AND DATA

Under the 1949 Indian Constitution, states were granted thepowers to enact (and implement) land reforms. This autonomyensures that there has been signi�cant variation across statesand time in terms of the number and types of land reforms thathave been enacted (see Table I). We classify land reform acts intofour main categories according to their main purpose (see Mearns{1998}). The �rst category is acts related to tenancy reform. Theseinclude attempts to regulate tenancy contracts both via registra-tion and stipulation of contractual terms, such as shares in sharetenancy contracts, as well as attempts to abolish tenancy andtransfer ownership to tenants. The second category of land reformacts are attempts to abolish intermediaries. These intermediarieswho worked under feudal lords (Zamandari) to collect rent for theBritish were reputed to allow a larger share of the surplus fromthe land to be extracted from tenants. Most states had passedlegislation to abolish intermediaries prior to 1958. However, �ve(Gujarat, Kerala, Orissa, Rajasthan, and Uttar Pradesh) did soduring our data period. The third category of land reform actsconcerned efforts to implement ceilings on landholdings, with aview to redistributing surplus land to the landless. Finally, wehave acts that attempted to allow consolidation of disparatelandholdings. Although these reforms, in particular the latter,

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS392

Page 5: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

TAB

LE

IS

UM

MA

RY

OF

MA

INVA

RIA

BL

ES

Sta

te

Rur

alpo

vert

yga

p

Rur

alh

ead

cou

nt

Agr

icu

ltu

ral

wag

es

Sta

tein

com

epe

rca

pita

Agr

icu

l-tu

ral

yiel

d

Cu

mu

lati

veto

tall

and

refo

rmle

gisl

atio

n

Cu

mu

lati

vete

nan

cyre

form

legi

slat

ion

Cu

mu

lati

veab

olit

ion

inte

rmed

iari

esle

gisl

atio

n

Cum

ula

tive

land

ceil

ings

legi

slat

ion

Cu

mu

lati

vela

nd

con

soli

dati

onle

gisl

atio

n

And

raP

rade

sh14

.87

50.5

94.

5310

0433

.40

1.52

80.

528

1.00

00

0(5

.11)

(11.

61)

(1.1

0)(2

60)

(33.

11)

(0.5

06)

(0.5

06)

(0)

(0)

(0)

Ass

am10

.69

48.9

15.

3590

350

.54

2.00

00.

611

00.

472

0.91

6(2

.67)

(9.1

6)(1

.04)

(196

)(3

7.59

)(1

.069

)(0

.494

)(0

)(0

.506

)(0

.280

)B

ihar

20.8

864

.65

4.07

633

42.6

44.

305

2.63

90

1.66

70

(4.6

7)(6

.40)

(1.0

1)(1

10)

(39.

95)

(1.9

24)

(0.9

30)

(0)

(1.0

42)

(0)

Gu

jara

t15

.81

53.4

94.

3911

7625

.21

3.05

61.

472

0.66

70.

917

0(4

.94)

(9.9

9)(0

.78)

(272

)(2

3.84

)(1

.264

)(0

.654

)(0

.478

)(0

.280

)(0

)H

arya

na7.

1130

.00

—14

4423

.22

00

00

0(2

.15)

(6.9

0)(3

57)

(20.

46)

(0)

(0)

(0)

(0)

(0)

Jam

mu

and

7.20

34.5

5—

1021

51.5

31.

333

0.47

20

00.

861

Kas

hm

ir(2

.59)

(8.1

3)(2

28)

(43.

28)

(0.7

17)

(0.5

06)

(0)

(0)

(0.3

51)

Kar

nat

aka

16.9

954

.46

3.85

1037

25.2

62.

833

1.41

70

1.41

70

(3.8

6)(8

.08)

(0.6

6)(2

16)

(24.

26)

(1.3

84)

(0.6

92)

(0)

(0.6

92)

(0)

Ker

ala

19.7

056

.92

6.24

864

65.7

55.

444

2.41

71.

972

1.05

60

(7.9

8)(1

4.53

)(1

.56)

(182

)(6

0.26

)(3

.376

)(1

.556

)(1

.000

)(0

.860

)(0

)M

adh

ya18

.03

57.2

63.

8184

317

.01

2.80

60.

944

00.

917

0.94

4P

rade

sh(4

.11)

(7.4

5)(0

.83)

(190

)(1

6.07

)(0

.710

)(0

.232

)(0

)(0

.280

)(0

.232

)M

ahar

ash

tra

19.7

163

.82

3.55

1288

20.8

41.

861

0.97

20

0.88

90

(4.3

8)(9

.64)

(0.7

1)(3

31)

(20.

57)

(0.4

24)

(1.6

67)

(0)

(0.3

19)

(0)

Ori

ssa

17.4

256

.63

4.07

873

25.0

65.

056

1.94

40.

583

1.94

40.

583

(4.6

2)(9

.53)

(0.8

5)(1

86)

(20.

23)

(3.1

16)

(1.0

93)

(0.5

00)

(1.0

93)

(0.5

00)

Pu

nja

b6.

1426

.22

8.16

1732

34.5

50.

583

0.58

30

00

(2.8

8)(8

.23)

(1.0

9)(3

84)

(29.

70)

(0.5

00)

(0.5

00)

(0)

(0)

(0)

Raj

asth

an16

.96

53.4

15.

1278

516

.27

0.94

40

0.94

40

0(3

.81)

(7.4

8)(0

.68)

(136

)(1

5.75

)(0

.232

)(0

)(0

.232

)(0

)(0

)Ta

mil

Nad

u18

.58

58.0

43.

9210

1536

.59

4.91

74.

028

00.

889

0(4

.40)

(8.5

6)(0

.52)

(272

)(3

2.66

)(2

.545

)(2

.336

)(0

)(0

.319

)(0

)U

ttar

Pra

desh

12.8

446

.70

4.71

874

4.64

3.75

01.

417

1.41

70.

917

0(3

.14)

(7.6

8)(1

.38)

(140

)(3

8.23

)(1

.251

)(0

.554

)(0

.554

)(0

.280

)(0

)W

est

Ben

gal

14.9

251

.48

6.12

1173

60.5

96.

139

3.83

30

0.61

11.

694

(5.3

2)(1

2.42

)(1

.81)

(191

)(5

7.20

)(5

.581

)(3

.476

)(0

)(0

.993

)(1

.369

)T

OTA

L15

.01

50.7

94.

799

1030

35.4

92.

910

1.45

50.

411

0.73

10.

312

(6.2

8)(1

4.08

)(1

.584

)(3

46)

(37.

36)

(2.7

49)

(1.7

07)

(0.6

92)

(0.8

25)

(0.6

35)

Sta

nda

rdd

evia

tion

sar

ein

pare

nth

eses

.—de

not

esa

mis

sin

gva

riab

le.S

eeth

eD

ata

App

end

ixfo

rd

etai

lson

con

stru

ctio

nan

dso

urc

esof

vari

able

s.T

he

data

are

for

the

sixt

een

mai

nst

ates

.H

arya

na

spli

tfr

omth

est

ate

ofP

un

jab

in19

65.F

rom

this

dat

eon

,we

incl

ud

ese

para

teob

serv

atio

ns

for

Pu

nja

ban

dH

arya

na.

Th

eex

cep

tion

isru

ral

wag

esw

her

eth

ere

isn

ose

para

tese

ries

for

Har

yan

aor

for

Jam

mu

and

Kas

hm

ir.S

tate

inco

me

per

cap

ita

isob

tain

edby

exp

ress

ing

esti

mat

esof

stat

edo

mes

tic

prod

uct

inre

alpe

rca

pit

ate

rms.

Agr

icu

ltu

raly

ield

mea

sure

sre

pre

sen

tth

era

tio

ofre

alag

ricu

ltu

ral

stat

edo

mes

tic

pro

duct

ton

etso

wn

area

mea

sure

din

thou

san

dsof

hec

tare

s.T

he

wag

ed

ata

refe

rto

the

dail

yw

age

rate

for

mal

eag

ricu

ltu

rall

abor

ers

and

isex

pres

sed

inre

alte

rms.

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 393

Page 6: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

were justi�ed partly in terms of achieving efficiency gains inagriculture, it is clear from the acts themselves and from thepolitical manifestos supporting the acts that the main impetusdriving the �rst three reforms was poverty reduction. It istherefore interesting to assess whether these reforms were effec-tive in achieving their stated aims.

Existing assessments of the effectiveness of these differentreforms are highly mixed. Although promoted by the center invarious Five Year Plans, the fact that land reforms were a statesubject under the 1949 Constitution meant that enactment andimplementation was dependent on the political will of stategovernments {Bandyopadhyay 1986; Radhakrishnan 1990; Appu1996; Behuria 1997; Mearns 1998}. The perceived oppressivecharacter of the Zamandari (and their intermediaries) and theirclose alliance with the British galvanized broad political supportfor the abolition of intermediaries and led to widespread implemen-tation of these reforms most of which were complete by the early1960s {Appu 1996; Mearns 1998}.1 Centre-state alignment on theissue of tenancy reforms was much less pronounced.2 With manystate legislatures controlled by the landlord class, reforms thatharmed this class tended to be blocked, although where tenantshad substantial political representation, notable successes inimplementation were recorded. Despite the considerable publicityattached to their enactment, political failure to implement wasmost complete in the case of land ceiling legislation. Hereambivalence in the formulation of policy and numerous loopholesallowed the bulk of landowners to avoid expropriation by distrib-uting surplus land to relations, friends and dependents {Appu1996; Mearns 1998}. As a result of these problems, implementa-tion of both tenancy reform and land ceiling legislation tended tolag well behind the targets set in the Five Year Plans {Bandy-opadhyay 1986; Radhakrishnan 1990}.3 Land consolidation legis-lation was enacted less than the other reforms and, owing partly

1. There were nonetheless some major design �aws, most notably the failureto limit the size of home farms of Zamindars or to protect short-term tenants.

2. Warriner {1969} commented that the Congress party (the main politicalforce for most of our period) ‘‘provided both the motivation for land reform and theopposition to it, as a socialist head with a conservative body.’’

3. The Fifth Plan gives a frank assessment of the situation which is directly inline with that of Bardhan {1970}: ‘‘A broad assessment of the programme of landreform adopted since Independence is that the laws for the abolition of intermedi-ary tenures have been implemented fairly efficiently whilst in the �elds of tenancyreforms and ceilings on holdings, legislation has fallen short of the desiredobjectives, and implementation of the enacted laws has been inadequate’’ {FifthFive Year Plan, 1974–79, 2: 43}.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS394

Page 7: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

to the sparseness of land records, implementation has beenconsidered to be both sporadic and patchy only affecting a fewstates in any signi�cant way {Radhakrishnan 1990; Appu 1996;Behuria 1997; Mearns 1998}.

Village level studies also offer a very mixed assessment of thepoverty impact of different land reforms (see Jayaraman andLanjouw {1997}). Similar reforms seemed to have produced differ-ent effects in different areas leaving overall impact indeterminate.There is some consensus that the abolition of intermediariesachieved a limited and variable success both in redistributingland toward the poor and increasing the security of smallholders(see, e.g., Wadley and Derr {1990}). For tenancy reform, however,whereas successes have been recorded, in particular, wheretenants are well organized, there has also been a range ofdocumented cases of imminent legislation prompting landlords toengage in mass evictions of tenants and of the de jure banning oflandlord-tenant relationships pushing tenancy underground andtherefore, paradoxically, reducing tenurial security (see, e.g.,Gough {1989}). Land ceiling legislation, in a variety of villagestudies, is also perceived to have had neutral or negative effects onpoverty by inducing landowners from joint families to evict theirtenants and to separate their holdings into smaller proprietaryunits among family members as a means of avoiding expropria-tion (see, e.g., Chattopadhyay {1994}). Land consolidation is alsoon the whole judged not to have been progressive in its redistribu-tive impact given that richer farmers tend to use their power toobtain improved holdings (see, e.g., Dreze, Lanjouw, and Sharma{1998}).

Table II gives a complete picture of land reform legislation,and its classi�cation, during our data period. Our empiricalanalysis aggregates reforms within each category. If land reformshave any effect, then we doubt that this would be instantaneous.Thus, we cumulate land reforms over time, generating a variablethat aggregates the number of legislative reforms to date in anyparticular state. While crude, we believe that it provides asensible �rst pass at analyzing the quantitative effects of landreform. The mean of that variable aggregated across the fourcategories of land reform is given in column 6 of Table I. Similarmeans for the different categories of reform are given in columns7–10. The table demonstrates considerable variation in overallland reform activity across states with states such as Uttar

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 395

Page 8: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

TA

BL

EII

IMP

OR

TA

NT

EV

EN

TS

INL

AN

DR

EF

OR

MS

ININ

DIA

NS

TA

TE

SS

INC

E19

50

Sta

teY

ear

Tit

leD

escr

ipti

onC

lass

And

hra

Pra

desh

1950 (a

men

ded

1954

)

(Tel

enga

na

Are

a)Te

nanc

yan

dA

gri-

cult

ura

lLan

dsA

ctTe

nan

tsre

ceiv

edpr

otec

ted

ten

ancy

stat

us;t

enan

tsto

hav

em

inim

um

term

ofle

ase;

righ

tof

purc

hase

ofn

onre

sum

able

lan

ds;t

rans

fer

ofow

ner

ship

topr

otec

ted

ten

ants

inre

spec

tof

non

resu

mab

lela

nds

;as

are

sult

13,6

11pr

otec

ted

ten

ants

decl

ared

own

ers.

1

1952

Hyd

erab

adA

boli

tion

ofC

ash

Gra

nts

Act

Abo

liti

onof

allt

he

975

jagi

rsin

Tele

nga

na.

2

1954

Inam

Abo

liti

onA

ct(a

bsor

bed)

encl

aves

Abo

liti

onof

inam

s(w

ith

few

exce

ptio

ns).

2

1955

(Hyd

erab

adJa

gird

ars)

Act

Abo

liti

onof

allt

he

975

jagi

rsin

Tal

enga

na.

219

56In

am(A

boli

tion

and

Con

vers

ion

into

Ryo

twar

i)A

ctA

cqu

isit

ion

of11

,137

esta

tes;

abol

itio

nof

1.06

mil

lion

min

orin

ams.

2

1956 (a

men

ded

1974

)

Ten

ancy

Act

Ten

ancy

con

tin

ues

up

to2/

3of

ceil

ing

area

;law

does

not

prov

ide

for

con

fer-

men

tof

own

ersh

ipri

ght

onte

nant

sex

cept

thro

ugh

righ

tto

purc

has

e;co

nfe

rsco

ntin

uou

sri

ght

ofre

sum

ptio

non

lan

dow

ner

s.

1

1957

Inam

Abo

liti

onA

ctA

boli

tion

ofin

ams

(wit

hfe

wex

cept

ions

),st

ruck

dow

nby

the

Hig

hC

ourt

in19

70.

2

Ass

am19

51S

tate

Acq

uis

itio

nof

Zam

inda

riA

ctA

boli

tion

ofin

term

edia

ryri

ghts

invo

lvin

g0.

67m

illi

onh

ecta

res.

219

54L

ush

aiH

ills

Dis

tric

t(A

cqu

isit

ion

ofC

hie

fsR

igh

ts)A

ctS

ame

asab

ove.

2

1956 (a

men

ded

1976

)

Fix

atio

nof

Cei

lin

gon

Lan

dH

oldi

ngs

Act

Sel

f-ex

plan

ator

y.3

1960

Con

soli

dati

onof

Hol

din

gsA

ctIn

trod

uct

ion

ofco

mpu

lsor

yco

nso

lida

tion

.4

1971

Ten

ancy

Act

Cla

ssi�

este

nan

tsin

tooc

cupa

ncy

and

non

occu

pan

cyte

nan

ts;f

orm

erh

asse

curi

tyof

ten

ure

,may

acqu

ire

lan

dlor

d’s

righ

tof

hol

din

gby

payi

ng

50ti

mes

the

lan

dre

ven

ue;

subl

etti

ngis

disa

llow

ed.

1

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS396

Page 9: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

Bih

ar19

50L

and

Ref

orm

sA

ctA

boli

tion

ofza

min

dari

;im

plem

enta

tion

ofth

isac

tve

rysl

ow.

219

57H

omes

tead

Ten

ancy

Act

Con

fers

righ

tsof

perm

anen

tte

nan

cyin

hom

este

adla

nds

onpe

rson

sh

oldi

ng

less

than

one

acre

ofla

nd.

1

1961 (a

men

ded

1973

)

Lan

dR

efor

ms

Act

Pro

hibi

tssu

blet

tin

g,pr

even

tin

gsu

bles

see

from

acqu

irin

gri

ght

ofoc

cu-

pan

cy.

1

1961

Lan

dC

eili

ng

Act

Impo

siti

onof

ceil

ing

onla

ndh

oldi

ngs

of9.

71–2

9.14

hec

tare

s(1

960–

1972

)an

dof

6.07

–18.

21h

ecta

re(a

fter

1972

).3

1973 (a

men

ded

1982

)

Act

12(a

men

dmen

tto

Lan

dR

efor

ms

Act

)In

trod

uce

dpr

ovis

ion

sre

lati

ng

toth

evo

lun

tary

surr

ende

rof

surp

lus

lan

d.3

1976

Act

55P

rovi

ded

for

the

subs

titu

tion

ofle

galh

eir;

ceil

ing

area

shal

lbe

rede

ter-

min

edw

hen

clas

si�c

atio

nof

land

chan

ges;

orde

red

that

the

lan

dhol

der

nec

essa

rily

reta

inla

ndtr

ansf

erre

din

con

trav

enti

onof

the

Act

.

3

1986

Ten

ancy

(Am

endm

ent)

Act

Pro

vide

sde

�nit

ion

ofpe

rson

alcu

ltiv

atio

n;p

rovi

des

for

acqu

isit

ion

ofoc

cu-

pan

cyri

ghts

byu

nde

rrai

yats

.1

Gu

jara

t19

48 (am

ende

d19

55an

d19

60)

Bom

bay

Ten

ancy

and

Agr

icu

ltur

alL

ands

Act

Ten

ants

enti

tled

toac

quir

eri

ght

ofow

ners

hip

afte

rex

piry

ofon

eye

aru

pto

ceil

ing

area

;con

fers

own

ersh

ipri

ght

onte

nan

tsin

poss

essi

onof

dwel

lin

gsi

teon

paym

ent

of20

tim

esan

nu

alre

nt;

law

does

not

con

fer

any

righ

tson

subt

enan

ts.

1

1960

Agr

icu

ltur

alL

ands

Cei

lin

gA

ctIm

pose

dce

ilin

gon

lan

dhol

din

gsof

4.05

–53.

14he

ctar

es(1

960–

1972

)an

dof

4.05

–21.

85h

ecta

res

(aft

er19

72).

3

1969

Dev

asth

anIn

ams

Abo

liti

onA

ctA

boli

shes

allg

rade

sof

inte

rmed

iary

ten

ure

s,bu

tla

ww

aspa

rtia

lly

inju

nct

edfr

omim

plem

enta

tion

byor

der

ofS

upr

eme

Cou

rt.

2

1973

Am

endi

ng

Act

Pro

vide

sop

port

un

ity

toac

quir

eow

ner

ship

ofho

ldin

gsbu

tla

rgel

yov

er-

ridd

enby

nu

mer

ous

prov

isio

ns.

1

Har

yan

a19

53P

un

jab

Sec

uri

tyof

Lan

dTe

nu

res

Act

Pro

vide

sco

mpl

ete

secu

rity

ofte

nure

for

ten

ants

inco

nti

nu

ous

poss

essi

onof

lan

d( ,

15ac

res)

for

12ye

ars;

gran

tste

nan

tsop

tion

alri

ght

ofpu

r-ch

ase

ofow

ner

ship

ofn

onre

sum

able

lan

d;n

oba

ron

futu

rele

asin

g.

1

1955

Pep

suTe

nan

cyan

dA

gric

ult

ura

lL

and

Act

Sam

eas

abov

e.1

(con

tin

ued

onne

xtpa

ge)

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 397

Page 10: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

TA

BL

EII

(CO

NT

INU

ED

)

Sta

teY

ear

Tit

leD

escr

ipti

onC

lass

Jam

mu

1962

Con

soli

dati

onof

Hol

din

gsA

ctIn

trod

uct

ion

ofco

mpu

lsor

yco

nso

lida

tion

.4

and

Kas

hm

ir19

76A

grar

ian

Ref

orm

sA

ctA

llri

ghts

,tit

les,

and

inte

rest

sin

land

ofan

ype

rson

not

cult

ivat

ing

itpe

r-so

nal

lyin

1971

are

exti

ngu

ish

edan

dtr

ansf

erre

dto

the

stat

e;pr

ovid

esfo

rco

nfe

rmen

tof

own

ersh

ipri

ghts

onte

nan

tsaf

ter

allo

win

gre

side

ntla

ndl

ord

tore

sum

ela

nd

for

pers

onal

cult

ivat

ion

.

1

Kar

nat

aka

1954

Mys

ore

(Per

son

alan

dM

isce

llan

eous

)In

ams

Abo

liti

onA

ctA

boli

shed

allt

hela

rge

inam

dari

inte

rmed

iari

es;p

roce

ssof

impl

emen

ta-

tion

very

slow

.2

1955

Mys

ore

(Rel

igio

usan

dC

har

itab

le)

Inam

sA

boli

tion

Act

Sam

eas

abov

e.2

1961

Lan

dR

efor

ms

Act

Pro

vide

sfo

r�

xity

ofte

nu

resu

bjec

tto

lan

dlor

d’s

righ

tto

resu

me

1/2

leas

edar

ea;g

ran

tste

nant

sop

tion

alri

ght

topu

rcha

seow

ner

ship

onpa

ymen

tof

15–2

0ti

mes

the

net

rent

;im

posi

tion

ofce

ilin

gon

lan

dhol

din

gs.

1,3

1974

Lan

dR

efor

ms

(Am

endm

ent)

Act

Impo

siti

onof

ceil

ing

onla

ndh

oldi

ngs

of4.

05–2

1.85

hec

tare

s(a

fter

1972

);re

mov

alof

allb

uton

eof

the

exem

ptio

ns

from

tena

ncy

legi

slat

ion

.1,

3

Ker

ala

1960

Agr

aria

nR

elat

ion

sA

ctA

boli

shes

inte

rmed

iari

es,b

ut

law

stru

ckdo

wn

byS

upr

eme

Cou

rt.

219

63L

and

Ref

orm

sA

ctC

once

des

ten

ant’s

righ

tto

purc

hase

the

lan

dfr

omla

ndow

ner

s.1

1969 (a

men

ded

1979

)

Lan

dR

efor

ms

(Am

endm

ent)

Act

Con

ferm

ent

offu

llow

ner

ship

righ

tson

ten

ants

;2.5

mil

lion

ten

ants

cou

ldbe

com

ela

ndo

wn

ers;

righ

tof

resu

mpt

ion

expi

res;

alth

ough

far-

reac

hin

gon

pape

r,la

w‘‘n

otco

ndu

cive

toso

cial

just

ice’

’bec

ause

ofco

nce

aled

ten

-an

cy;i

mpo

siti

onof

ceil

ing

onla

ndh

oldi

ngs

of6.

07–1

5.18

hec

tare

s(1

960–

1972

)an

dof

4.86

–6.0

7h

ecta

res

(aft

er19

72);

abol

itio

nof

inte

rme-

diar

yri

ghts

.

1,2,

3

1974

Agr

icu

ltur

alW

ork

ers

Act

Cal

led

for

empl

oym

ent

secu

rity

,�xe

dh

ours

,min

imu

mw

ages

,etc

.1

Mad

hya

Pra

desh

1950

Abo

liti

onof

Pro

prie

tary

Rig

hts

(Est

ates

,Mah

als,

Ali

enat

edL

ands

)Act

Abo

liti

onof

inte

rmed

iary

righ

ts.

2

1951

Un

ited

Sta

tes

ofG

wal

ior,

Indo

re,

and

Mal

wa

Zam

inda

riA

boli

tion

Act

Sam

eas

abov

e.2

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS398

Page 11: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

1951

Abo

liti

onof

Jagi

rA

ctS

ame

asab

ove.

219

52V

indh

yaP

rade

shA

boli

tion

ofJa

girs

and

Lan

dR

efor

ms

Act

Sam

eas

abov

e.2

1959

Lan

dR

even

ueC

ode

Lea

sin

gpr

ohib

ited

;en

titl

esoc

cupa

ncy

tena

nts

toow

ner

ship

righ

tsof

non

-re

sum

able

area

onpa

ymen

tof

15ti

mes

the

lan

dre

ven

ue;

impl

emen

ta-

tion

ofre

form

inef

fici

ent,

one

reas

onbe

ing

that

shar

ecro

pper

san

dte

n-an

tsar

en

otre

cord

ed.

1

1959

Con

soli

dati

onof

Hol

din

gsA

ctIn

trod

uct

ion

ofco

mpu

lsor

yco

nso

lida

tion

.4

1960

Cei

lin

gon

Agr

icu

ltu

ralH

oldi

ngs

Act

Impo

sed

ceil

ing

onla

ndh

oldi

ngs

of10

.12

hec

tare

s(1

960–

1972

)an

dof

4.05

–21.

85h

ecta

res

(aft

er19

72).

3

Mah

aras

htr

a19

50H

yder

abad

Tena

ncy

and

Agr

icu

ltu

ral

Lan

dsA

ctP

rovi

des

for

suo

mot

totr

ansf

erof

owne

rsh

ipto

ten

ants

ofno

nre

sum

able

lan

ds(a

ppli

esto

Mar

atha

wad

are

gion

).1

1958

Bom

bay

Ten

ancy

and

Agr

icu

ltur

alL

and

Act

Pro

vide

sfo

rtr

ansf

erof

owne

rsh

ipto

ten

ants

wit

hn

onre

sum

able

land

s(w

ith

effe

ctfr

om1-

4-96

).1

1961

Agr

icu

ltur

alL

and

(Cei

lin

gon

Hol

d-in

gs)A

ctIm

posi

tion

ofce

ilin

gon

land

hol

din

gs.

3

Ori

ssa

1951

Est

ate

Abo

liti

onA

ctA

imed

atab

olis

hin

gal

lin

term

edia

ryin

tere

sts.

219

72L

and

Ref

orm

sA

ctE

nti

tled

ten

ants

toac

quir

ery

otir

igh

tsov

eren

tire

lan

dh

eld

byth

em.

219

60 (am

ende

d19

73an

d19

76)

Lan

dR

efor

ms

Act

Pro

vide

sfo

r�

xity

ofte

nu

reof

non

resu

mab

lear

ea;p

roh

ibit

ssu

blet

ting

;im

plem

enta

tion

poor

;�n

anci

alhe

lpfo

rpu

rch

ase

ofow

ners

hip

righ

tla

ckin

g;m

ost

leas

esin

form

ofsh

arec

ropp

ing

but

shar

ecro

pper

sno

tre

cord

edas

ten

ants

;im

posi

tion

ofce

ilin

gon

lan

dhol

ding

sof

8.09

–32.

37h

ecta

res

(196

0–19

72)a

nd

of4.

05–1

8.21

hect

ares

(aft

er19

72).

1,3

1972

Con

soli

dati

onof

Hol

din

gsan

dP

re-

ven

tion

ofF

ragm

enta

tion

ofL

and

Act

Intr

odu

ctio

nof

com

puls

ory

con

soli

dati

on.

4

Pu

njab

1953

Pu

nja

bS

ecu

rity

ofL

and

Ten

ure

sA

ctP

rovi

des

com

plet

ese

curi

tyof

tenu

refo

rte

nan

tsin

con

tin

uou

spo

sses

sion

ofla

nd

( ,15

acre

s)fo

r12

year

s;gr

ants

ten

ants

opti

onal

righ

tof

pur-

chas

eof

own

ersh

ipof

non

resu

mab

lela

nd;

no

bar

onfu

ture

leas

ing.

1

(con

tin

ued

onne

xtpa

ge)

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 399

Page 12: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

TA

BL

EII

(CO

NT

INU

ED

)

Sta

teY

ear

Tit

leD

escr

ipti

onC

lass

1955

Pep

suTe

nan

cyan

dA

gric

ult

ura

lL

and

Act

Sam

eas

abov

e.1

1972

Lan

dR

efor

ms

Act

Per

mis

sibl

eli

mit

(cei

ling

)is

7h

ecta

res;

5ac

res

ofla

nd

are

secu

red,

the

rest

may

bere

sum

ed;o

ptio

nal

righ

tof

purc

has

eof

own

ersh

ip;s

har

e-cr

oppi

ng

not

con

side

red

ten

ancy

;ten

ants

ofte

nco

erce

dto

‘‘vol

unta

rily

surr

ende

r’’l

and;

lan

dle

ases

not

regi

ster

edu

nde

rpr

ovis

ion

ofte

nanc

yla

ws.

1

Raj

asth

an19

52L

and

Ref

orm

san

dR

esu

mpt

ion

ofJa

gir

Act

Abo

lish

esal

lin

term

edia

ryri

ghts

.2

1953

Bom

bay

Mer

ged

Terr

itor

ies

and

Are

a(J

agir

Abo

liti

on)A

ctS

ame

asab

ove.

2

1954

Hol

ding

s(C

onso

lida

tion

and

Pre

ven

-ti

onof

Fra

gmen

tati

on)A

ctIn

trod

uct

ion

ofco

mpu

lsor

yco

nso

lida

tion

.4

1955

Ajm

erA

boli

tion

ofIn

term

edia

ries

and

Lan

dR

efor

ms

Act

Abo

lish

esin

term

edia

ryin

tere

sts

inot

her

area

s.2

1955

Ten

ancy

Act

Con

fers

secu

rity

ofte

nu

reto

tena

nts

and

subt

enan

ts;o

wn

ersh

ipri

ghts

can

betr

ansf

erre

d;pr

ovis

ions

ofvo

lun

tary

surr

ende

rm

ade

legi

slat

ion

‘‘mer

efa

rce.

’’

1

1959

Zam

inda

rian

dB

isw

edar

iAbo

liti

onA

ctA

boli

shes

inte

rmed

iary

inte

rest

sin

oth

erar

eas.

2

Tam

ilN

adu

1948

Est

ates

(Abo

liti

onan

dC

onve

rsio

nin

toR

yotw

ari)

Act

XX

VI

Ase

ries

ofla

ws

enac

ted

(th

roug

hlo

ng

inte

rval

s)fo

rth

eab

olit

ion

ofva

riou

sty

pes

ofin

term

edia

ries

.2

1952

Th

anja

vur

Tena

nts

and

Pan

naiy

alP

rote

ctio

nA

ctP

rovi

des

grea

ter

secu

rity

ofte

nu

re.

1

1955 (a

men

ded.

1965

)

Mad

ras

Cu

ltiv

atin

gTe

nant

sP

rote

c-ti

onA

ctP

rohi

bits

any

cult

ivat

ing

ten

ant

from

bein

gev

icte

dbu

tal

low

sfo

rre

sum

p-ti

onu

pto

1/2

ofla

nds

leas

edou

tto

tena

nt.

1

1956

Cu

ltiv

atin

gTe

nan

ts(P

aym

ent

ofF

air

Ren

t)A

ctA

boli

shes

usu

ryan

dra

ck-r

enti

ng.

1

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS400

Page 13: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

1961

(am

.71)

Pu

blic

Ten

ants

Act

Pro

vide

sth

atn

opu

blic

tru

stca

nev

ict

its

cult

ivat

ing

tena

nts.

119

61L

and

Ref

orm

s(F

ixat

ion

ofC

eili

ng

onL

and)

Act

Impo

siti

onof

ceil

ing

onla

ndh

oldi

ngs

of12

.14–

48.5

6h

ecta

res

(196

0–19

72)

and

of4.

86–2

4.28

hec

tare

s(a

fter

1972

).3

1969

Agr

icu

ltur

alL

and-

Rec

ords

ofTe

n-

ancy

Rig

htA

ctP

rovi

des

for

prep

arat

ion

and

mai

nte

nan

ceof

com

plet

ere

cord

ofte

nan

cyri

ghts

.1

1971

Occ

upa

nts

ofK

udi

yiru

ppu

Act

Pro

vide

sfo

rac

quis

itio

nan

dco

nfe

rmen

tof

owne

rsh

ipri

ghts

onag

ricu

ltu

r-is

ts,a

gric

ultu

rall

abor

ers,

and

rura

lart

isan

s.1

1976

Ru

ralA

rtis

ans

(Con

ferm

ent

ofO

wn

-er

ship

ofK

udi

yiru

ppu)

Act

Sam

eas

abov

e.1

Utt

arP

rade

sh19

50 (am

ende

d19

52,1

954,

1956

,195

8,19

77)

Zam

inda

riA

boli

tion

and

Lan

dR

efor

ms

Act

All

ten

ants

are

give

nco

mpl

ete

secu

rity

ofte

nu

rew

itho

ut

any

righ

tof

resu

mpt

ion

for

the

lan

dow

ner

;lea

ses,

inge

ner

al,a

reba

nned

;law

pro-

vide

dfo

rtr

ansf

erri

ng

and

vest

ing

ofal

lzam

inda

ries

tate

s;za

min

dari

was

abol

ish

edov

er60

.2m

illi

onac

res

(ou

tof

tota

lsta

tear

eaof

72.6

mil

-li

onac

res)

.

1,2

1953

Con

soli

dati

onof

Hol

din

gsA

ctIn

trod

uct

ion

ofco

mpu

lsor

yco

nso

lida

tion

.4

1960

Impo

siti

onof

Cei

lin

gson

Lan

dhol

d-in

gsA

ctIm

posi

tion

ofce

ilin

gon

land

hol

din

gsof

16.1

9–32

.37

hec

tare

s(1

960–

1972

)an

dof

7.30

–18.

25h

ecta

res

(aft

er19

72).

3

Wes

tB

enga

l19

50B

arga

dars

Act

Sti

pula

ted

that

the

barg

adar

and

the

lan

dow

ner

cou

ldch

oose

any

prop

or-

tion

acce

ptab

leto

them

.1

1953

Est

ates

Acq

uis

itio

nA

ctL

andh

olde

rsli

mit

edto

ace

ilin

g;pr

ovid

edfo

rab

olit

ion

ofal

lin

term

edia

ryte

nur

es.

1,2,

3

1955 (a

men

ded

1970

,197

1,19

77)

Lan

dR

efor

ms

Act

Pro

vide

sth

atla

ndow

ner

can

resu

me

land

for

pers

onal

cult

ivat

ion

such

that

tena

ntis

left

wit

hat

leas

t1

hec

tare

;sh

arec

ropp

ing

not

con

side

red

ten

ancy

(in

Wes

tB

enga

lmos

tte

nan

tsar

esh

arec

ropp

ers)

;pro

vide

sfo

rla

nd

cons

olid

atio

nif

two

orm

ore

lan

dow

ner

sag

ree.

1,4

1972

Acq

uis

itio

nan

dS

ettl

emen

tof

Hom

e-st

ead

Lan

d(A

men

dmen

t)A

ctTe

nan

tsof

hom

este

adla

nds

are

give

nfu

llri

ghts

.1

1975

Acq

uis

itio

nof

Hom

este

adL

and

for

Agr

icul

tura

lLab

orer

s,A

rtis

ans

and

Fis

her

men

Act

Ove

r25

0,00

0pe

ople

wer

egi

ven

hom

este

adla

nd

(abo

utei

ght

cen

tsea

ch)

up

toJa

nu

ary

1991

.1

(con

tin

ued

onne

xtpa

ge)

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 401

Page 14: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

TA

BL

EII

(CO

NT

INU

ED

)

Sta

teY

ear

Tit

leD

escr

ipti

onC

lass

Wes

tB

enga

l(c

ont.

)

1977

Lan

dR

efor

ms

(Am

endm

ent)

Act

‘‘Rai

ses

pres

um

ptio

nin

favo

rof

shar

ecro

pper

s’’{

Yuga

ndh

aran

dIy

er19

93,

p.48

}.1

1981

Lan

dR

efor

ms

(Am

endm

ent)

Act

Des

ign

edto

plu

gth

elo

oph

oles

inth

eea

rlie

rA

cts

rela

tin

gto

the

ceil

ing

ofla

ndh

oldi

ngs

.3

1986

Lan

dR

efor

ms

(Am

endm

ent)

Act

Sou

ght

tobr

ing

allc

lass

esof

land

un

der

the

ceil

ing

prov

isio

ns

byw

ith

-dr

awin

gpr

evio

us

exem

ptio

ns;p

rovi

ded

for

regu

lato

rym

easu

res

toch

eck

indi

scri

min

ate

conv

ersi

onof

land

from

one

use

toan

oth

er;l

awn

otye

tfu

lly

impl

emen

ted.

3

1990

Lan

dR

efor

ms

(Am

endm

ent)

Act

Sam

eas

abov

e.3

Th

eco

nte

nt

ofla

nd

refo

rmac

tsar

ecl

assi

�ed

into

fou

rca

tego

ries

(15

ten

ancy

refo

rm,

25

abol

itio

nof

inte

rmed

iari

es,

35

ceil

ings

onla

ndh

oldi

ngs

,4

5co

nso

lida

tion

ofla

nd

hol

din

gs),

wh

ere

itis

poss

ible

for

agi

ven

act

tobe

lon

gto

mor

eth

anon

eca

tego

ry.I

nth

eza

man

dar

ilan

dte

nu

resy

stem

,wh

ich

cove

red

56p

erce

nt

ofpr

ivat

ely

own

edla

nd

inB

riti

shIn

dia,

the

lan

dw

asve

sted

inth

ela

nd

lord

know

nas

Zam

inda

r.B

etw

een

him

and

the

real

cult

ivat

orth

ere

wer

ese

vera

llay

ers

ofre

ntr

ecei

vin

gin

term

edia

ries

.Jag

irs

and

inam

sw

ere

free

gran

tsof

subg

ran

tsfr

omth

est

ate

wit

hth

eri

ght

toco

llec

tan

dap

prop

riat

ela

nd

reve

nu

e,th

ough

wit

hth

epa

ssag

eof

tim

e,ja

gird

ars

and

inam

dars

beca

me

the

virt

ual

own

ers.

Inth

eir

con

cept

ion

the

ryot

war

ian

dm

ahal

war

ilan

dte

nu

resy

stem

sdi

dn

otre

cogn

ize

any

inte

rmed

iary

betw

een

the

stat

ean

dth

ecu

ltiv

ator

(th

ough

ryot

san

dm

ahal

sdi

dh

ave

full

righ

tsto

sale

,le

asin

gan

dtr

ansf

erof

lan

d).I

n�

ltra

tion

ofm

oney

len

ders

and

trad

ers

into

agri

cult

ure

and

the

leas

eof

them

tote

nan

tsle

dto

crea

tion

ofan

inte

rmed

iary

clas

sev

enin

area

sty

pi�

edby

thes

ela

nd

ten

ure

syst

ems.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS402

Page 15: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

Pradesh, Kerala, and Tamil Nadu having a lot of activity whilePunjab and Rajasthan have very little.

Our poverty data come from a consistent set of �gures for therural and urban areas of India’s sixteen major states spanning theperiod 1958–1992 compiled by Ozler, Datt, and Ravallion {1996}.The measures are based on consumption distributions from 22rounds of the National Sample Survey (NSS) spanning thisperiod. The poverty line is based on a nutritional norm of 2400calories per day and is de�ned as the level of average per capitatotal expenditure at which this norm is typically attained. Twopoverty measures are considered: the headcount index and thepoverty gap.4 Given that NSS surveys are not annual, weightedinterpolation has been used to obtain values between surveys.5

Our study should be seen in the context of a signi�cant overallreduction in poverty throughout our data period—the all-Indiarural headcount measure has fallen from around 55 percent to 40percent, and the rural poverty gap from 19 percent to around 10percent. That said, there is considerable cross-sectional variationin performance across states.6 Agricultural wage data were alsocollected to enable us to examine whether land reforms hadgeneral equilibrium effects and were thus capable of reachinggroups of the poor (e.g., landless laborers) who did not directlybene�t from the reforms.

Real values of per capita agricultural, nonagricultural, andcombined state domestic product are also available to examine thedeterminants of growth. Agricultural state domestic product wasde�ated using the Consumer Price Index for Agricultural Labor-ers while the Consumer Price Index for Industrial Workers wasused to de�ate the nonagricultural state domestic product. Wealso constructed a variable to measure agricultural yields. Thiswas de�ned as real agricultural state domestic product divided bythe net sown area. This crudely captures technological changes inagriculture.

Public �nance data at the state level were also collectedchie�y as a means to control for other government interventionsbesides land reform. On the expenditure side, the main classi�ca-

4. The headcount index is the proportion of the population living below thepoverty line. The poverty gap is the average distance below the line expressed as aproportion of the poverty line, where the average is formed over the wholepopulation (counting the nonpoor as having zero distance below the line).

5. Below, we check that our results are robust to including only those yearswhere there was an NSS survey round.

6. See Datt and Ravallion {1998} for further discussion.

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 403

Page 16: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

tion available for our data period is into development andnondevelopment expenditure. While development expendituredoes include expenditure on economic and social services, there isno particular connection between this category and government’sefforts to develop the population or infrastructure in their states.7

Development expenditures are therefore further disaggregatedinto health and education expenditures that we might expect tohave appreciable impacts on poverty. We put these in real percapita terms. We also collected total state taxes as a share of statedomestic product as a crude measure of the size of state govern-ments and state redistributive taxes per capita8 to capture theeffort of state governments to redistribute from rich to poor.Population estimates from the �ve censuses for 1951, 1961, 1971,1981, and 1991 were used as additional controls. Between any twocensuses these were assumed to grow at a constant (compound)rate of growth, derived from the respective population totals.

III. LAND REFORM AND POVERTY REDUCTION

A. Basic Results

The empirical approach is to run panel data regressions of theform,

(1) xst 5 a s 1 b t 1 g yst 1 c lst 2 4 1 e st,

where xst is some measure of poverty in state s at time t, a s is astate �xed effect, b t is a year dummy variable, yst is a vector ofvariables that we treat as exogenous (detailed below), lst 2 4 is thestock of past land reforms four periods previously, and e st is anerror term which we model as AR(1) process where the degree ofautocorrelation is state-speci�c; i.e., e st 5 r s e st 2 1 1 ust. Estimationvia generalized least squares will also allow for heteroskedasticityin the error structure with each state having its own errorvariance.

Equation (1) is a reduced-form model of the impact of landreform. Thus, any effect of land reform on poverty is picked up by

7. Economic services include agriculture and allied activities, rural develop-ment, special area programs, irrigation and �ood control, energy, industry andminerals, transport and communications, science, technology, and environment.Social services include education, medical and public health, family welfare, watersupply and sanitation, housing, urban development, labor, and labor welfare,social security and welfare, nutrition, and relief on account of natural calamities.

8. These include land tax, agricultural income tax, and property tax all ofwhich are under the control of state governments.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS404

Page 17: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

that variable along with other effects that change the claims thattenants have to land. The land reform variable will also pick upany general equilibrium effects of land reform through changes inwages and prices. Below, we discuss what kind of theoreticalmodel is consistent with our empirical �ndings.

The approach is also reduced form because land reformlegislation is used as regressor—we are unable to measurewhether land reforms are actually implemented. We cannotdistinguish, therefore, between ineffective and unimplementedland reforms. Even though we have no measure of this, there isanecdotal evidence that some land reforms were not fully imple-mented. Hence, the coefficient on land reform in (1) is likely toprovide a lower bound on the true effect of an implemented landreform. We have lagged the land reform variable four periods fortwo main reasons.9 First, because even effective legislation willtake time to be implemented and to have an impact. Second, itmay help to allay concerns that shocks to poverty will be corre-lated with land reform efforts, an issue to which we return below.Fixed effects at the state level control for the usual array ofcross-state differences in history and economic structure thathave been constant over our sample period, while the year effectscover for macro-shocks and policies enacted by the central govern-ment that affect poverty and growth.

Table III gives the basic picture from our data. In column (1)we control for other factors affecting poverty only by using stateand year effects. Land reform is represented only by the cumula-tive land reform variable where all types of land reforms areaggregated. The negative and signi�cant association betweenland reform and the rural poverty gap measure is clear from this.Column (2) con�rms that this result is not sensitive to using theinterpolated years when there were no NSS rounds. In column (3)land reforms are disaggregated into their component types, alsolagged four periods. This suggests that tenancy reforms and theabolition of intermediaries are driving the aggregate effects, whileland ceiling legislation and consolidation of landholdings have anegligible impact on rural poverty. Below, we will suggest atheoretical interpretation of the results that is consistent withthis �nding. The fact that land ceiling legislation is unimportantcon�rms anecdotal accounts of the failure to implement thesereform measures in any serious way {Bardhan 1970; Appu 1996;

9. The results are not sensitive to the exact lag speci�cation chosen here.

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 405

Page 18: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

Behuria 1997; Mearns 1998}. Column (4) checks the sensitivity ofthe �ndings to using an alternative measure of poverty—thehead-count index. A similar negative impact of tenancy reformand the abolition of intermediaries on poverty is found here.

If land reform is really responsible for these results (ratherthan some omitted variable that is correlated with land reform),

TABLE IIILAND REFORM AND POVERTY IN INDIA: BASIC RESULTS

Model

Ruralpoverty

gap

Ruralpoverty

gap

Ruralpoverty

gap

Ruralheadcount

Urbanpoverty

gap

Povertygap

difference

Povertygap

difference

Head-count

difference

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

GLSAR(1)

GLSAR(1)

GLSAR(1)

GLSAR(1)

GLSAR(1)

GLSAR(1)

GLSAR(1)

GLSAR(1)

Four-year laggedcumulative landreformlegislation

2 0.281(2.18)

2 0.443(3.21)

0.085(1.05)

2 0.534(5.24)

Four-year laggedcumulativetenancy reformlegislation

2 0.604(2.52)

2 1.378(3.13)

2 0.736(3.27)

2 1.916(4.37)

Four-year laggedcumulativeabolition ofintermediarieslegislation

2 2.165(4.08)

2 4.354(4.11)

2 1.327(2.59)

2 3.364(3.73)

Four-year laggedcumulative landceilinglegislation

0.089(0.11)

0.734(0.86)

0.230(0.61)

0.888(1.14)

Four-year laggedcumulative landconsolidationlegislation

0.456(0.82)

2 0.208(0.19)

2 0.210(0.42)

2 1.737(1.62)

State effects YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YESYear effects YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YESNumber obser-

vations507 300 507 507 507 507 507 507

z-statistics are in parentheses. See the Data Appendix for details on construction and sources of thevariables. The data are for the sixteen main states. We use data 1961–1992 for fourteen states. For Haryanawhich split from the Punjab in 1965, we use data 1965–1995 and for Jammu and Kashmir we use data1961–1991 as there was no NSS survey in 1992. This gives us a sample size of 507. The sample size in column(2) is smaller as it is only run for years when NSS surveys were carried out. Poverty measures in otherregressions have been interpolated between survey years. The GLS AR(1) model allows a state-speci�c AR(1)process—see equation (1) in the text for details. In columns (6) and (7) the poverty gap difference is thedifference between the rural and urban poverty gap. In column (5) the headcount difference is the differencebetween the rural and urban head-count index.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS406

Page 19: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

then we would not expect to see such effects on urban poverty.There is no good reason to think production and distributiondecisions in the urban sector would be affected (apart from somecomplex general equilibrium reasons). This is con�rmed in col-umn (5) of Table III which �nds no signi�cant negative associationbetween land reform and urban poverty as measured by the sameNSS data. This adds credence to the idea that our land reformvariable is picking up something peculiar to the rural sector.

Columns (6)–(8) use the difference between rural and urbanpoverty as the left-hand-side variable. As we observed fromcolumn (5), urban poverty does not respond to land reform. Thishelps to control for any omitted variables that have commoneffects on poverty in both places.10 Column (6) con�rms our �ndingthat aggregate cumulative land reforms lagged four periods arenegatively associated with a reduction in rural-urban povertydifference. Results broken out by type of land reform are consis-tent with those for rural poverty: tenancy reforms and theabolition of intermediaries have had a signi�cant impact inclosing rural-urban poverty gap while the impact of the other twotypes of land reform are insigni�cant (column (7)). Using the gapbetween rural and urban head-count index yields similar �ndings(column (8)).

Taken together, these results demonstrate a consistent pic-ture.11 Land reform in general appears to be associated withreductions in rural poverty, with these effects most strongly

10. Unlike poverty levels, it is also a variable that does not trend downwardovertime. In the levels regression the cumulative nature of our land reformvariable makes it difficult to identify its effect separately from a state-speci�c timetrend. Indeed, including state-speci�c time trends as regressors in a poverty levelsregression leads to the land reform variable becoming less signi�cant. However,when the poverty difference is included as the left-hand-side variable, the effectof land reforms remains signi�cant even when state-speci�c time trends areincluded.

11. These results assume that the effects of each land reform work indepen-dently from one another. To re�ect the possibility that packaging of certain reformsis important, we ran our basic speci�cations including interactions between thedifferent types of land reforms. No general pattern emerges from this exercise,although there is some suggestive evidence that undertaking both tenancy reformand abolition of intermediaries together enhances the impact of land reformfurther. However, this �nding is somewhat sensitive to the exact measure ofpoverty used and the inclusion of particular control variables. We also consideredwhether there was a difference between land reforms enacted recently comparedwith those more than ten years ago. To this end, we reran the main resultsseparating out a variable cumulating recent land reforms and those more than tenyears old. We found that both enter negatively and signi�cantly in the povertyregressions, with the older land reforms frequently taking an (absolutely) largecoefficient. Following Moene {1992}, we also investigated whether land reforms inmore densely populated states appeared to have a larger impact on poverty. Formost of the speci�cations that we looked at, this was indeed the case.

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 407

Page 20: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

associated with land reforms that seek to abolish intermediariesand reform the conditions of tenancies.

B. Robustness

While these results are clean, they leave two signi�cantconcerns unmet. First, they make no effort to allow for otherpolicies that affect poverty—land reform may be proxying forother policies that are correlated with poverty reduction. Second,land reform could be endogenous and responding to the sameforces that drive poverty. We now address both of these concerns.

Table IV reports results that include an array of additionalcontrols. All regressions now include the population growth rateand agricultural yield lagged four periods. The latter may proxyfor other policies that could have enhanced agricultural productiv-ity and are correlated with land reform. It may also pick upexogenous technological change. Our policy measures are in twocategories: re�ecting the expenditure and tax policies of stategovernments. Our expenditure variables are health expendituresper capita, education expenditures per capita, and other expendi-tures per capita.12 The former two might be thought to beimportant determinants of poverty reduction efforts. On the taxside, we have two rather crude measures that give a picture of thegeneral policy stance of the government in office. State taxesexpressed as a share of state domestic product crudely serve tomeasure the size of the state government. We can also measurehow much the government is intent on designing a tax systemthat is geared toward taxing the better off. We create a measure ofthe progressiveness of the tax system under state control. This isthe sum of land taxes, agricultural income taxes, and propertytaxes expressed in real per capita terms. All policy variables arelagged four periods to give the same timing structure as the landreform variables and to minimize concerns about the possibleendogeneity of these policy variables.

In columns (1)–(6) of Table IV we replicate the regressions ofland reform on poverty including these other policies.13 Irrespec-tive of the speci�cation, state redistributive taxes and state taxshare exert signi�cant negative impacts on rural poverty whereas

12. That is total expenditure excluding health and education.13. We experimented with an array of speci�cations that included a larger

array of controls for government expenditure including those on food security,famine relief, rural infrastructure, and other social services and �ner disaggrega-tions of taxes. Including these variables did not affect our key results in anysigni�cant way so we have decided to use a more parsimonious speci�cation.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS408

Page 21: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

TAB

LE

IVL

AN

DR

EF

OR

MA

ND

PO

VE

RT

YIN

IND

IA:

CO

NT

RO

LL

ING

FO

RO

MIT

TE

DP

OL

ICY

EF

FE

CT

S

Mod

el

Ru

ral

pove

rty

gap

Ru

ral

pove

rty

gap

Ru

ral

hea

dco

un

tU

rban

pove

rty

gap

Pov

erty

gap

diff

eren

ceH

ead

cou

nt

diff

eren

ce

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

GL

SA

R(1

)G

LS

AR

(1)

GL

SA

R(1

)G

LS

AR

(1)

GL

SA

R(1

)G

LS

AR

(1)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

cum

ulat

ive

lan

dre

form

legi

slat

ion

20.

378

(3.7

8)0.

037

(0.0

42)

20.

539

(4.6

3)2

1.29

8(5

.04)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

cum

ulat

ive

tena

ncy

refo

rmle

gisl

atio

n2

0.56

5(2

.32)

20.

897

(1.9

8)F

our-

year

lagg

edcu

mul

ativ

eab

olit

ion

inte

rmed

iari

esle

gisl

atio

n2

1.79

0(2

.81)

23.

14(2

.48)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

cum

ulat

ive

lan

dce

ilin

gle

gisl

atio

n2

0.35

2(0

.82)

20.

121

(0.1

4)F

our-

year

lagg

edcu

mul

ativ

ela

nd

con

soli

dati

onle

gisl

atio

n0.

164

(0.3

2)2

1.00

0(1

.02)

Pop

ula

tion

grow

thra

te2

90.6

1(1

.14)

297

.99

(1.2

1)2

87.5

9(0

.50)

274

.32

(1.2

2)74

.81

(0.9

1)2

145.

05(0

.90)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

per

capi

taed

uca

tion

expe

ndi

ture

0.06

3(2

.04)

0.07

0(2

.24)

0.07

6(1

.10)

0.04

1(1

.73)

0.07

7(2

.18)

0.03

4(0

.42)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

per

capi

tah

ealt

hex

pend

itur

e0.

038

(0.8

8)0.

041

(0.9

1)0.

072

(0.7

6)2

0.00

3(0

.09)

0.04

2(0

.83)

0.21

8(1

.76)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

per

capi

taot

her

expe

ndi

ture

0.02

0(2

.69)

0.01

7(2

.31)

0.02

6(1

.56)

0.01

2(2

.40)

0.00

09(0

.12)

20.

008

(0.4

0)F

our-

year

lagg

edpe

rca

pita

redi

stri

buti

vest

ate

taxe

s2

0.13

0(2

.70)

20.

142

(2.9

2)2

0.36

4(3

.25)

20.

045

(1.2

5)2

0.18

2(3

.53)

20.

422

(3.2

1)F

our-

year

lagg

edst

ate

taxe

sas

ape

rcen

tage

ofst

ate

dom

esti

cpr

oduc

t2

49.5

9(2

.99)

249

.11

(2.9

4)2

87.3

3(2

.46)

227

.70

(2.2

3)16

.43

(0.9

7)4.

790

(0.1

3)F

our-

year

lagg

edag

ricu

ltu

raly

ield

0.00

1(0

.05)

20.

003

(0.0

2)2

0.50

7(1

.19)

20.

006

(0.4

2)0.

031

(1.4

5)2

0.01

3(0

.30)

Sta

teef

fect

sY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SYe

aref

fect

sY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SN

um

ber

ofob

serv

atio

ns

436

436

436

436

436

436

z-st

atis

tics

are

inpa

ren

thes

es.S

eeth

eD

ata

App

end

ixfo

rde

tail

son

con

stru

ctio

nan

dso

urc

esof

the

vari

able

s.T

he

data

are

for

the

sixt

een

mai

nst

ates

.We

hav

eda

ta19

64–1

992

for

nin

est

ates

.F

orP

un

jab

we

hav

eda

ta19

69–1

992,

for

Har

yan

aw

hic

hsp

lit

from

the

Pu

nja

bin

1965

we

hav

eda

ta19

70–1

975

and

1978

–199

2,fo

rJa

mm

uan

dK

ash

mir

1968

–199

1,fo

rB

ihar

and

Gu

jara

t19

64–1

975

and

1977

–199

2,fo

rT

amil

Nad

u19

64–1

975

and

1978

–199

2an

dfo

rB

ihar

1964

,196

9an

d19

72–1

977.

Th

isgi

ves

us

ato

tals

amp

lesi

zeof

436.

Inco

lum

n(5

)th

epo

vert

yga

pd

iffe

ren

ceis

the

diff

eren

cebe

twee

nth

eru

ral

and

urb

anpo

vert

yga

p.In

colu

mn

(6)

the

hea

d-co

un

tdi

ffer

ence

isth

ed

iffe

ren

cebe

twee

nth

eru

ral

and

urb

anh

ead-

cou

nt

inde

x.T

heG

LS

AR

(1)m

odel

allo

ws

ast

ate-

spec

i�cA

R(1

)pro

cess

—se

eeq

uati

on(1

)in

the

text

for

deta

ils.R

edis

trib

uti

veta

xes

are

agri

cult

ura

linc

ome

taxe

s,la

nd

taxe

s,an

dpr

oper

tyta

xes.

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 409

Page 22: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

education and health expenditure, per capita yield, and popula-tion growth are generally insigni�cant at conventional levels.14 Incolumn (1) we include the full set of policy control variables in thebasic regression of cumulative land reform on the rural povertygap measure. Despite controlling for these many dimensions ofstate activity, cumulative land reform continues to exert a nega-tive and signi�cant impact on rural poverty. In column (2) we runthe same regression while disaggregating the land reform vari-able. We continue to �nd that tenancy reforms and the abolition ofintermediaries exert a negative and signi�cant impact on therural poverty gap measure whereas land ceiling and land consoli-dation legislation exert no signi�cant in�uence. Replacing thepoverty gap measure with the head-count index as is done incolumn (3) produces a similar set of results. When we examine theurban poverty regression (column (4)), we �nd that, in commonwith the rural poverty regressions, health and education expendi-ture and yield have no signi�cant impact and tax share has asigni�cant impact. State redistributive taxes are insigni�cant inthis regression suggesting that their impact is restricted to therural sector. Inclusion of these extra variables has no effect on theinsigni�cant impact of cumulative land reform on urban poverty.

Columns (5) and (6) regress the difference between rural andurban poverty on cumulative land reform and the full set ofcontrol variables. Note that compared with column (1) of thistable, only the land reform variable and state redistributive taxesremain signi�cant in this speci�cation.15 Other policy effectsappear to be common to both rural and urban sectors, becominginsigni�cant in this regression. Contrasting columns (5) and (6)con�rms that results are robust to the type of poverty measurebeing used. Taken together, the results presented in Table IV offerfurther con�rmation of our initial �nding of a signi�cant negativeassociation between lagged land reform and rural poverty.

A further concern with the speci�cation in equation (1) is thepotential endogeneity of the land reform variable. It is notpossible to ascertain the direction of bias due to this a priori. If

14. The expenditure results are interesting given the priority attached, incurrent debates, to expansion of expenditures on education and health as a keymeans of reducing poverty (see Dreze and Sen {1995}). If anything, educationexpenditures per capita seem to exert a positive in�uence on the rural poverty gap(columns (1) and (2)) but not on the rural head-count ratio (column (3)). However, itis possible that we would need �ner measures of the ways in which particularprograms are prioritized to make progress on this.

15. An exception is education expenditure per capita in the poverty gapspeci�cation (see column (5)).

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS410

Page 23: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

land reform is purposefully aimed at poverty reduction, then wewould expect policy effort to focus on where poverty is highest,leading to downward bias. However, if responsiveness to landreform is greater where poverty is highest, then the effect may goin the other direction. While lagging land reform as we have in (1)goes some way toward minimizing concerns about this, there issome residual worry that long-lived shocks to poverty that affectantipoverty legislation could bias the results.

To �x this problem requires an instrument for land reform.16

To this end, we exploit the fact that land reform is intenselypolitical, with different groupings in state legislatures (the Vid-han Sabha) being more likely to enact land reform legislation.However, this can be problematic if, as seems likely, shocks topoverty affect who is elected. To mitigate this problem, we proposeusing long lags of the political variables as instruments for landreform. Speci�cally, political variables from four periods prior tothe land reform (eight periods before the poverty observation) areused as an instrument for land reform. This is legitimate providedthat contemporaneous shocks to poverty are uncorrelated withshocks that lead to particular groups being elected eight yearspreviously. Such an assumption seems defensible given both thefrequency of elections and policy shifts in India and because it isdifficult to think of long-lasting shocks affecting both currentpoverty and political structure eight years ago.

This strategy implies a �rst-stage equation for land reform:

(2) lst 5 µlst2 4 1 as 1 bt 1 cyit 1 dzst2 4 1 h st,

where lst is the cumulative land reform variable, as is a state �xedeffect, bt is a year dummy variable, yst is a vector of variables thatwe treat as exogenous, and the variables zst2 4 are politicalvariables re�ecting the seat shares of different political groups,each lagged by four years. These are constructed from records ofthe number of seats won by different national parties at each ofthe state elections under four broad groupings. (The partiescontained in the relevant group are given in parentheses after thename of the grouping.) These are (i) Congress Party (IndianNational Congress 1 Indian Congress Socialist 1 Indian Na-tional Congress Urs 1 Indian National Congress Organization),(ii) a hard left grouping (Communist Party of India 1 Communist

16. This will also help to deal with measurement error which is a concerngiven that we measure only legislated land reforms.

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 411

Page 24: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

Party of India Marxist), (iii) a soft left grouping (SocialistParty 1 Praja Socialist Party), and (iv) Hindu parties (BhartiyaJanata Party 1 Bhartiya Jana Sangh). We express these as ashare of total seats in the legislature. Congress has tended todominate the assemblies over the period, although hard leftparties have also recorded majorities in Kerala and West Bengal.Over time there has been a decline in the importance of Congressand a rise in the importance of religious and regional parties.

Table V presents estimates of equation (2) for the differentkinds of land reforms. As we would expect, all cases �nd laggedland reforms to be strongly signi�cant. The political variables alsomatter for land reform legislation, and are jointly signi�cant in allcolumns. In column (1) we see that, relative to the omitted ‘‘other’’category, which is composed of a amalgam of regional, indepen-dent, and Janata parties, Congress and soft left decrease theprobability of enacting land reform legislation, while hard leftexerts a positive in�uence and Hindu parties are insigni�cant.Looking across columns (2) to (5), we see that the negativein�uence of Congress is spread across all types of land reform, butit is particularly pronounced for tenancy reforms and abolition ofintermediaries. The negative in�uence of soft left parties is alsospread across the board with the exception of land consolidation.The overall positive in�uence of hard left parties, however, seemsto originate principally through a strong positive effect on thepassage of land ceiling legislation. This is interesting given ourfailure to �nd evidence that such reforms reduce poverty. Hinduparty representation appears to exert no in�uence on the passageof tenancy reforms or the abolition of intermediaries. However,they exert a signi�cant positive in�uence on land ceiling and asigni�cant negative in�uence on land consolidation.

Table VI presents our results from instrumental variablesestimation. Column (1), which uses political variables and laggedland reforms as instruments, continues to �nd a negative andsigni�cant impact of land reform on the rural poverty gap. We �nda similar result when we use the head-count poverty measure inplace of the poverty gap measure in column (2). Columns (3) and(4) follow a similar instrumentation procedure but break out totalland reforms into constituent types. This con�rms our earlierresults; both tenancy reforms and abolition of intermediariesremain negative and signi�cant while other types of land reform

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS412

Page 25: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

TABLE VLAND POLICY DETERMINATION

Model

Cumulativetotal land

reformlegislation

Cumulativetenancyreform

legislation

Cumulativeabolition of

intermediarieslegislation

Cumulativeland ceilinglegislation

Cumulativeland

consolidationlegislation

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS

Four-year laggedcumulativeland reform leg-islation

0.406(12.23)

Four-year laggedcumulative ten-ancy reformlegislation

0.693(16.26)

2 0.002(0.16)

2 0.009(0.38)

0.021(1.13)

Four-year laggedcumulative abo-lition of inter-mediaries legis-lation

0.041(0.53)

0.664(14.21)

0.109(1.51)

2 0.029(1.06)

Four-year laggedcumulativeland ceiling leg-islation

2 0.131(2.11)

2 0.172(0.65)

0.631(15.60)

2 0.045(1.44)

Four-year laggedcumulativeland consolida-tion legisla-tion

0.694(5.06)

2 0.038(1.14)

0.174(2.93)

0.772(7.85)

Four-year laggedcongress partyshare of seats

2 0.460(2.81)

2 0.472(4.78)

2 0.098(2.37)

2 0.066(1.85)

2 0.075(1.85)

Four-year laggedhard left shareof seats

2.837(2.95)

0.476(0.72)

0.149(0.97)

1.437(5.46)

2 0.302(0.73)

Four-year laggedsoft left share ofseats

2 3.921(3.09)

2 2.363(3.25)

2 1.101(2.60)

2 1.990(3.63)

2 0.426(1.06)

Four-year laggedhindu partiesshare of seats

0.270(0.33)

2 0.089(0.19)

2 0.045(0.15)

0.556(2.01)

2 0.410(2.08)

State effects YES YES YES YES YESYear effects YES YES YES YES YESNumber of obser-

vations474 474 474 474 474

t-statistics are in parentheses. All regressions are reported with robust standard errors. All monetaryvariables are in real terms. See the DataAppendix for details on construction and sources of the variables. Thedata are for the sixteen main states. We have data 1962–1992 for eight states. Punjab and Haryana split intoseparate states in 1965. For Punjab we have data 1962–1989 while for Haryana we have data 1969–1991. ForJammu and Kashmir we have data 1965–1991, for Kerala and West Bengal 1962–1991, for Gujarat andMaharashtra 1963–1992 and for Bihar 1962–1989. This gives us a total sample size of 474. The partiescontained in the relevant group are given in parentheses after the name of the grouping. These are (i)Congress Party (Indian National Congress 1 Indian Congress Socialist 1 Indian National CongressUrs 1 Indian National Congress Organization), (ii) a hard left grouping (Communist Party ofIndia 1 Communist Party of India Marxist), (iii) a soft left grouping (Socialist Party 1 Praja Socialist Party),and (v) Hindu parties (Bhartiya Janata Party 1 Bhartiya Jana Sangh).

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 413

Page 26: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

TAB

LE

VI

LA

ND

RE

FO

RM

AN

DP

OV

ER

TY

ININ

DIA

:IN

ST

RU

ME

NT

AT

ION

Mod

el

Rur

alpo

vert

yga

p

Rur

alh

ead

cou

nt

Rur

alpo

vert

yga

p

Rur

alhe

adco

unt

Pov

erty

gap

diff

eren

ce

Rur

alpo

vert

yga

p

Ru

ral

head

coun

t

Rur

alhe

adco

unt

Ru

ral

pove

rty

gap

Ru

ral

head

cou

nt

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

IV1

IV1

IV1

IV1

IV1

IV2

IV2

IV2

IV3

IV3

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

cum

ula

tive

land

refo

rmle

g-is

lati

on2

0.73

2(6

.02)

21.

360

(5.6

8)2

0.43

8(3

.60)

20.

659

(4.0

9)2

1.19

2(3

.67)

20.

599

(3.1

8)2

1.26

3(3

.24)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

cum

ula

tive

ten

ancy

refo

rmle

gisl

atio

n2

0.99

8(3

.16)

22.

404

(3.6

7)2

4.59

5(4

.69)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

cum

ula

tive

abol

itio

nof

inte

rmed

iari

esle

gisl

atio

n2

2.27

1(2

.58)

25.

701

(3.6

4)2

7.40

8(4

.10)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

cum

ula

tive

land

ceil

ing

leg-

isla

tion

21.

372

(2.3

4)0.

432

(0.3

8)2

1.99

8(1

.89)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

cum

ula

tive

land

cons

olid

a-ti

onle

gisl

atio

n1.

624

(1.7

2)1.

969

(1.0

0)2

4.02

7(1

.45)

Ove

ride

nti�

cati

onte

stp-

valu

e0.

930.

980.

990.

980.

990.

930.

980.

980.

920.

96St

ate

effe

cts

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

Year

effe

cts

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

Num

ber

ofob

serv

atio

ns41

041

041

041

041

041

041

041

041

041

0

t-st

atis

tics

are

inpa

ren

thes

es.A

llre

gres

sion

sar

ere

port

edw

ith

robu

stst

anda

rder

rors

.See

the

Dat

aA

ppe

ndi

xfo

rde

tail

son

con

stru

ctio

nan

dso

urc

esof

the

vari

able

s.T

he

data

are

for

the

sixt

een

mai

nst

ates

.We

hav

eda

ta19

66–1

992

for

twel

vest

ates

.For

Har

yan

a,w

hic

hsp

lit

from

Pu

nja

bin

1965

,we

hav

ed

ata

1973

–199

2,fo

rJa

mm

uan

dK

ash

mir

1969

–199

2,an

dfo

rG

uja

rat

and

Mah

aras

htr

a19

67–1

992.

Th

isgi

ves

us

ato

tals

ampl

esi

zeof

410.

Inco

lum

n(5

)pov

erty

gap

dif

fere

nce

isth

edi

ffer

ence

betw

een

rura

lan

du

rban

pove

rty.

IV1:

Inst

rum

ents

for

the

endo

gen

ous

poli

cyva

riab

le(c

um

ula

tive

lan

dre

form

sla

gged

fou

rpe

riod

s)ar

esh

are

ofse

ats

inst

ate

asse

mbl

yoc

cupi

edby

Con

gres

s,h

ard

left

,sof

tle

ft,a

nd

Hin

dup

arti

esla

gged

eigh

tp

erio

dspl

us

lan

dre

form

vari

able

sla

gged

eigh

tpe

riod

s.IV

2:In

stru

men

tsfo

rth

een

dog

enou

spo

licy

vari

able

(cu

mu

lati

vela

nd

refo

rms

lagg

edfo

ur

peri

ods)

are

shar

eof

seat

sin

stat

eas

sem

bly

occu

pie

dby

Con

gres

s,h

ard

left

,sof

tle

ft,a

nd

Hin

dup

arti

esla

gged

eigh

tp

erio

dsp

lus

cum

ula

tive

lan

dre

form

spa

ssed

inge

ogra

phic

ally

con

tigu

ous

stat

esla

gged

eigh

tpe

riod

s.IV

3:In

stru

men

tsfo

rth

een

doge

nou

spo

licy

vari

able

(cu

mu

lati

vela

nd

refo

rms

lagg

edfo

ur

per

iods

)ar

esh

ares

ofse

ats

inst

ate

asse

mbl

yoc

cup

ied

byC

ongr

ess,

har

dle

ftan

dso

ftle

ftp

arti

esla

gged

eigh

tpe

riod

s(l

agge

dla

nd

refo

rmva

riab

les

are

excl

ud

edh

ere)

.Th

eov

erid

enti

�ca

tion

test

we

empl

oyis

due

toS

arga

n{1

958}

.Th

en

um

ber

ofob

serv

atio

ns

tim

esth

eR

2

from

the

regr

essi

onof

the

stat

e2

resi

dual

son

the

inst

rum

ents

isd

istr

ibu

ted

x2

(T1

1),w

her

eT

isth

en

um

ber

ofin

stru

men

ts.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS414

Page 27: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

are insigni�cant.17 Column (5) con�rms that land reform still hasa signi�cant impact in closing the gaps between rural and urbanpoverty. We also report tests of our overidentifying restrictions forthe instrumental variables regressions. The political and laggedland reform variables pass standard statistical tests of overidenti-�cation and therefore, at least on econometric grounds, wouldappear to be suitable instruments for land reforms.18 Thus, whenthe instrument set includes political variables and lagged landreforms, the picture is consistent with the patterns of resultsshown in Tables III and IV.

The remainder of Table VI experiments with alternatives tousing lagged land reforms as instruments. In columns (6)–(8) weuse cumulative land reforms passed in geographically neighbor-ing states (lagged eight periods) in our instrument set in place ofcumulative land reforms lagged eight periods. These neighboringland reforms could proxy for regional waves of support for landreform. Using these, together with the political variables asinstruments, yields robust results. Aggregate land reforms con-tinue to exert a negative and signi�cant impact on the ruralpoverty gap (column (6)) or rural head count (column (7)). Whenwe break out land reforms by type, we again �nd tenancy reformsand abolition of intermediaries exerting the strongest negativein�uences on the head-count index (column (8)). The overidenti�-cation tests are also passed. In columns (9) and (10) of Table VI, wedrop lagged land reforms completely from the instrument set. Wecontinue to obtain a negative impact of land reforms on the ruralpoverty gap (column (9)) or the rural headcount (column (10)) foraggregate land reforms.19

Taken together, Table VI �nds a pattern of results that isconsistent with those presented in Tables III and IV.20 It is alsoreassuring that the magnitude of coefficients remains roughly

17. With the exception of land ceilings in column (3).18. The test we employ is due to Sargan {1958} and tests whether the

instruments are correlated with residuals from the second-stage (poverty) regres-sion. See notes to Table VI.

19. We did not obtain signi�cant effects for disaggregated land reforms in thisspeci�cation.

20. We also experimented with a fourth instrumentation procedure where theendogenous policy variable (cumulative land reforms lagged four periods) isinstrumented using a ‘‘simulated’’ cumulative land index created by cumulatingvalues from a linear probability model which predicts whether a land reform takesplace in a given year based on political composition of the state parliament (laggedfour periods) and year and state effects. As with the three other procedures, wefound that instrumented aggregate land reform had a signi�cant negative impacton the rural poverty gap.

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 415

Page 28: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

constant across the different instrumentation procedures. On thewhole, the instrumented coefficients on land reform are largerthan the baseline results of Tables III and IV. Overall, theseresults are best thought of as a robustness check on our earlier�ndings rather than trying to present a carefully thought outstructural model.

IV. LAND REFORM AND AGRICULTURAL WAGES

It would be surprising if land reforms that affected povertydid not impact on other aspects of the rural economy. We nowconsider whether such reforms have an effect on agriculturalwages. The wage data are for the daily agricultural wages of malelaborers expressed in real terms.21 Agricultural wages are arobust indicator of the welfare of landless laborers who comprise asigni�cant fraction of the poor in rural India (see World Bank{1997}). If land reform pushes up agricultural wages, this repre-sents an additional mechanism through which these reforms canreduce rural poverty.

The results using the agricultural wage as a left-hand-sidevariable are in Table VII. Column (1) contains results for theaggregate land reform variable. This demonstrates a positive andsigni�cant impact of land reform on wages. In column (2) thiseffect is disaggregated across types of land reform and shows thatthis effect is primarily attributable to legislation to abolishintermediaries. These results con�rm the impact of land reformson the rural economy. They also illustrate an indirect routethrough which land reform may positively affect the welfare oflandless laborers even if they do not bene�t directly from thereforms. In Section VII we discuss why such effects might bepresent in theory.

V. LAND REFORM AND GROWTH

Even if land reform does help the poor, it could do so at a costto economic performance. We turn now, therefore, to exploringwhether land reform has a positive or negative effect on agricul-tural output per capita. In this case, we use the log of real stateincome per capita as the left-hand-side variable with the right-hand side augmented by lagged log real state income per capita to

21. See the Data Appendix for details.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS416

Page 29: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

model dynamics in a very simple way and to allow for convergenceover time.22 We therefore have a regression of the form,

(3) xst 5 l xst 2 1 1 a s 1 b t 1 g yst 1 c lst 2 4 1 e st.

This is basically the same form of regression that has becomepopular in the cross-country growth literature summarized inBarro {1997}, although our panel data allow us to use �xed effectsand year effects. We will also continue to allow for a state-speci�cAR(1) error speci�cation with heteroskedasticity.

Table VIII presents the main results for the regression ofstate income per capita on cumulative land reform. In column (1)we present results for a GLS model of total state income per capitaon land reform containing only state �xed effects and year effectsas controls. We �nd that the disaggregated land reform variables

22. Statewise estimates of total and agricultural state domestic product areavailable for the 1960–1992 period. See the Data Appendix. These state domesticproduct estimates are used as our proxy of state income.

TABLE VIILAND REFORM AND AGRICULTURAL WAGES

Model

Real agriculturalwages

Real agriculturalwages

(1) (2)

GLSAR(1)

GLSAR(1)

Four-year lagged cumulative land reformlegislation

0.081(2.71)

Four-year lagged cumulative tenancyreform legislation

0.049(0.88)

Four year lagged cumulative abolition ofintermediaries legislation

0.339(2.61)

Four-year lagged cumulative land ceilinglegislation

0.069(0.09)

Four-year lagged cumulative consolida-tion of land holdings legislation

0.018(0.13)

State effects YES YESYear effects YES YESNumber of observations 441 441

z-statistics are in parentheses. The wage data refer to the daily wage rate for male agricultural laborersexpressed in real terms. See the Data Appendix for details on construction and sources of the variables. Thedata are for fourteen states—data for Haryana and Jammu and Kashmir are not available. For thirteen ofthese states we have data 1961–1992 and for Rajasthan we have 1967–1991. This gives a sample size of 441.GLS AR(1) model allows a state-speci�c AR(1) process—see equation (1) in the text for details.

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 417

Page 30: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

TAB

LE

VII

IL

AN

DR

EF

OR

MA

ND

GR

OW

TH

ININ

DIA

Mod

el

Log

ofst

ate

inco

me

per

capi

ta

Log

ofag

ricu

ltu

rals

tate

inco

me

per

capi

ta

Log

ofag

ricu

ltu

rals

tate

inco

me

per

capi

taL

ogof

agri

cult

ura

lyie

ldL

ogof

agri

cult

ura

lyie

ld

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

GL

SA

R(1

)G

LS

AR

(1)

GL

SA

R(1

)G

LS

AR

(1)

GL

SA

R(1

)

On

e-ye

arla

gged

log

ofst

ate

inco

me

per

capi

ta0.

497

(12.

53)

On

e-ye

arla

gged

log

ofag

ricu

ltu

rals

tate

inco

me

per

capi

ta0.

195

(4.1

7)0.

167

(3.2

9)F

our-

year

lagg

edcu

mul

ativ

ete

nan

cyre

form

s2

0.00

2(0

.43)

20.

037

(4.5

4)2

0.03

3(2

.94)

20.

050

(6.5

5)2

0.03

8(3

.92)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

cum

ulat

ive

abol

itio

nof

inte

rmed

iari

es2

0.00

5(0

.54)

0.00

5(0

.27)

20.

016

(0.7

6)2

0.00

2(0

.12)

20.

013

(0.4

9)F

our-

year

lagg

edcu

mul

ativ

ela

nd

ceil

ing

legi

slat

ion

20.

002

(0.2

2)0.

019

(1.2

6)0.

012

(0.6

4)0.

015

(0.9

5)0.

015

(0.8

8)F

our-

year

lagg

edla

nd

cons

olid

atio

nle

gisl

atio

n2

0.01

3(1

.29)

0.06

5(3

.31)

0.05

7(2

.12)

0.07

4(3

.87)

0.05

4(2

.15)

Pop

ula

tion

grow

thra

te2

2.56

7(0

.75)

4.16

6(1

.11)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

per

capi

taed

uca

tion

expe

ndi

ture

s0.

003

(1.4

8)0.

003

(1.6

7)F

our-

year

lagg

edpe

rca

pita

hea

lth

expe

ndit

ures

20.

005

(1.9

7)2

0.00

2(0

.77)

Fou

r-ye

arla

gged

per

capi

taot

her

expe

ndi

ture

s2

0.00

04(0

.99)

20.

0002

(0.4

0)F

our-

year

lagg

edpe

rca

pita

tax

reve

nu

efr

omre

dist

ribu

tive

taxe

s2

0.00

4(1

.51)

20.

003

(1.0

5)F

our-

year

lagg

edst

ate

taxe

sas

ape

rcen

tage

ofst

ate

dom

esti

cpr

odu

ct0.

474

(0.5

4)0.

278

(0.3

1)F

our-

year

lagg

edlo

gof

agri

cult

ura

lyie

ld0.

010

(0.1

7)2

0.01

8(0

.32)

Sta

teef

fect

sY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

Year

effe

cts

YE

SY

ES

YE

SY

ES

YE

SN

um

ber

ofob

serv

atio

ns

484

484

433

488

433

z-st

atis

tics

are

inpa

ren

thes

es.S

tate

inco

me

per

cap

ita

isob

tain

edby

expr

essi

ng

esti

mat

esof

stat

edo

mes

tic

pro

du

ctin

real

per

capi

tate

rms.

Agr

icu

ltu

raly

ield

mea

sure

sre

pres

ent

the

rati

oof

real

agri

cult

ura

lsta

ted

omes

tic

pro

duct

ton

etso

wn

area

.Red

istr

ibu

tive

taxe

sar

eag

ricu

ltu

rali

nco

me

taxe

sla

nd

taxe

s,an

dp

rop

erty

taxe

s.S

eeth

eD

ata

Ap

pen

dix

for

deta

ils

onco

nst

ruct

ion

and

sou

rces

ofth

eva

riab

les.

Th

ed

ata

are

for

the

sixt

een

mai

nst

ates

.For

colu

mn

s(1

)an

d(2

)we

hav

eda

ta19

61–1

992

for

twel

vest

ates

,for

Pu

nja

ban

dH

arya

na,

wh

ich

spli

tin

1965

,we

hav

eda

ta19

66–1

992;

for

Jam

mu

and

Kas

hm

ir19

65–1

992;

and

for

Bih

ar19

61,1

966,

and

1969

–199

2.T

his

give

sa

sam

ple

size

of48

4.T

he

sam

ple

size

inco

lum

n(4

)is

slig

htl

yla

rger

asit

does

not

con

tain

ala

gged

depe

nde

nt

vari

able

asre

gres

sor.

For

colu

mn

s(3

)an

d(5

)w

eh

ave

dat

a19

64–1

992

for

nin

est

ates

,fo

rP

un

jab

1969

–199

2,fo

rH

arya

na

1970

–197

5an

d19

78–1

992,

for

Jam

mu

and

Kas

hm

ir19

68–1

992,

for

Bih

aran

dG

uja

rat

1964

–197

5an

d19

77–1

992,

for

Ass

am19

69an

d19

72–1

992

and

for

Tam

ilN

adu

1964

–197

5an

d19

78–1

992.

Th

isgi

ves

asa

mpl

esi

zeof

433.

GL

SA

R(1

)m

odel

allo

ws

ast

ate-

spec

i�c

AR

(1)p

roce

ss—

see

equ

atio

n(1

)in

the

text

for

deta

ils.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS418

Page 31: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

lagged four periods have no signi�cant impact on total stateincome per capita. In column (2) we look only at agricultural stateincome per capita. This makes sense given that land reform ispredominantly concerned with affecting production relations inagriculture. This suggests that tenancy reform has a negativeeffect on agricultural output with land consolidation having theopposite effect. No effect is observed for the other kinds of landreform. Column (3) shows that both the tenancy reform and landconsolidation effects are robust to including our other policyvariables lagged four years. In column (4) we show that theseeffects remain when agricultural yields rather than income percapita is the left-hand-side variable.23 In column (5) we show thatthis effect of tenancy reform is robust to including other policyvariables.

VI. LAND REFORM AND LAND INEQUALITY

Taken together, our results hint at an equity-efficiency trade-off for tenancy reforms—both poverty and output per capita arelower after such reforms are enacted. No such trade-off emergesfor abolition of intermediaries. Ceilings on landholdings do notseem to have an effect on either output measures or poverty, whileland consolidation promotes output increases in agriculture with-out affecting poverty. The failure of land ceiling legislation to showany signi�cant impact on poverty reduction or output levels isconsistent with Bardhan’s {1970} claim that such reforms haverarely been implemented with any degree of seriousness.

Overall, these results suggest that the impact on povertycomes mainly through reforms that affect production relations,rather than by altering the distribution of land. This interpreta-tion is underlined by looking at the limited evidence available onthe relationship between land reforms and land distribution overour data period. Data on land distribution has only been gatheredby NSS special surveys at four points; 1953–1954, 1961–1962,1971–1972, and 1982 (see Sharma {1994}). We classify states ashigh or low land reform depending on whether they had more orless than a total of three land reforms (of any type) during the1958–1992 period.24 We then investigate whether high land

23. Our measure of yield is real agricultural state domestic product dividedby net sown area. See the Data Appendix for details.

24. Under this system Andra Pradesh, Assam, Haryana, Jammu and Kash-mir, Madya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Punjab, and Rajasthan are low land reform

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 419

Page 32: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

reform states classi�ed in this way experienced the largest drop inthe gini for land operated and proportion of landless householdsover the period.25 The overall impression that we have from thiscrude exercise, is of persistent inequalities in land operatedwithin both groups of states (see also Sharma {1994}). Thus, theidea that the major impact of land reform on poverty must comemainly through mechanisms that did not involve land redistribu-tion gains further support. In further con�rmation of this, wefailed to �nd a signi�cant effect of aggregate land reform on thegini coefficient for rural per capita consumption.26

Thus, in making sense of the results, it is imperative to thinkabout land reforms that have changed production relations inagriculture rather than altering the pattern of landholdings. All ofthis notwithstanding, there is evidence that the impact of landreforms on poverty is greatest in those states where land inequal-ity was greatest in 1953–1954. To test this, we interacted thepercentage of landless individuals and the land gini coefficientwith our land reform variable. This interaction term was negativeand signi�cant in every case when we looked at aggregate landreform activity.27

VII. MAKING SENSE OF THE RESULTS

Our empirical analysis suggests that poverty reduction isassociated with land reform and this is primarily attributable tolegislation that has abolished intermediaries and reformed theterms of tenancies. The role of land redistribution per se seems tohave been of limited importance in the Indian context. Theempirical analysis also uncovers some evidence of general equilib-rium effects on wages. Our theoretical model focuses on twothings: a model of agricultural contracting and a model of labor

states, while Bihar, Gujarat, Karnataka, Kerala, Orissa, Tamil Nadu, UttarPradesh, and West Bengal are high land reform states.

25. For high land reform states the land gini falls from 0.686 in 1953/54 to0.669 in 1982 (a fall of 0.017), whereas the drop in low land reform states is from0.653 to 0.643 (a drop of 0.010). For high land reform states the average drop in theproportion landless is from 14.97 percent to 12.03 percent (a fall of 2.94 percent),whereas for low land reform states the drop is from 12.40 percent to 10.91 percent(a fall of 1.49 percent).

26. To look at this issue, we ran the basic regression shown in column (1) ofTable III but replaced the rural poverty gap with the gini coefficient for rural percapita consumption. Our inability to �nd a signi�cant impact on rural inequalitycould be explained by the fact that land reform may be shifting income from themiddle income groups to the poor rather than from the rich to the poor.

27. The results are available from the authors on request.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS420

Page 33: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

supply by tenants. The former focuses on how rents to tenantsshift in response to land reforms, and the latter gives rise to effectson agricultural wages. This focus on contractual problems cap-tures the spirit of recent models of the inequality-growth relation-ship that emphasize agency problems, particularly in creditmarkets. (See Benabou {1996} for a survey.) Here, we emphasizeagency problems in tenancy contracts and how they can be alteredby land reform, even if the ownership pattern is unchanged.

There are three groups: landlords who rent out land as well asfarming some of the land themselves, tenants who rent land, andlandless laborers. The poor are made up predominantly of thelatter two groups. Tenants and landless laborers supply labor tothe labor market where it is demanded by landlords who choose tobe owner-cultivators. Tenants and landless laborers care aboutconsumption c and labor supply l. Their preferences are u(c) 2f (l), where u(·) is increasing and concave and f (·) is increasingand convex. Suppose that the agricultural wage is v . Then, anindividual with nonlabor income x, has optimal labor supply of

l*(x,v ) 5 larg max u(x 1 v l) 2 f (l) .

It is straightforward to check that labor supply is decreasing in x.Now de�ne v(x,v ) 5 u(x 1 v l*(x,v )) 2 f (l*(x, v )) as the indirectutility of a tenant with nonlabor income x. Hence, we expectlandless laborers to supply l*(0, v ), while for tenants x is equal tothe value of their tenancy. As the value of tenancy increases as aresult of land reform, we would expect tenants to reduce laborsupply to the market.

We now consider the agricultural contracting problem of atenant and landlord. Suppose that the output on a given piece ofland under tenancy is given by R(e) where e denotes effort appliedto the land by the tenant. We suppose that the cost of this effort isseparable from labor supply and is measured in units of disutility.Effort is also committed before the labor supply decision is made.We assume that R(·) is smooth, increasing, and concave.

We suppose that tenants need to be monitored in order to putin effort on the land. Speci�cally, we imagine that a contractspeci�es an effort level of e. However, the tenant may choose to‘‘shirk,’’ putting in zero effort, in which case the landlord catcheshim with probability p and he is �red, becoming a landless laborerand receiving a payoff of v(0, v ). The tenant can now only beinduced to supply effort if the threat of eviction is sufficientlystrong and some rents are earned from being a tenant. Suppose,

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 421

Page 34: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

then, that the tenant receives a payment of w to farm the land,which he receives only if he is not caught shirking. Thus, a tenantis willing to put in an effort level e at payment w if and only theincentive constraint (1 2 p)v(w,v ) 1 pv(0, v ) # v(w, v ) 2 e issatis�ed. Solving this as an equality gives the payment schedulew(e, v ) needed to induce effort level e as

w(e, v ) 5 v 2 1(v(0, v ) 1 e/ p).

The contract must now specify a payment/effort pair consis-tent with this schedule. The optimal effort that the landlordchooses to induce is given by

e( p,v ) 5 arg maxe

5 R(e) 2 w(e,v ) .

It is easy to verify that e( p,v ) is increasing in p. The tenant’sequilibrium payoff is V( p, v ) 5 v(0, v ) 1 e( p, v ) (1 2 p)/ p which islarger than the payoff from being a landless laborer.

It is straightforward to calculate the impact of changes in p onoutput and the tenant’s payoff. An increase in p will increasenet-output since e( p, v ) is increasing. The effect on the tenant’spayoff (and hence poverty) is given by

­ V( p,v )

­ p5

­ e( p,v )

­ p

1 2 p

p2 e( p, v )

1

p2 .

The �rst term is positive—an increase in the eviction probabilityelicits higher effort and hence raises the tenant’s rent. The secondeffect works in the opposite direction. For a given effort level, thetenant’s rent is lower since he must be paid less now to preventhim from shirking. We are interested in cases where the tenantenjoys a more secure right to the land so that p falls. In this case,the tenant will bene�t from a tenancy reform that reduces theprobability that he will be evicted if caught shirking if theelasticity of effort with respect to the probability of eviction( ­ e( p, v )/­ p · p/e( p,v )) is less than 1/{(1 2 p) p2}. If tenants’ rentsincrease from receiving higher tenure security, then this will leadthem to reduce their labor supply to the market, and we wouldpredict that such a tightening of the labor market would lead toincreased agricultural wages.28

This framework can be applied to the cases of abolition ofintermediaries and tenancy reform. To include an intermediary in

28. These changes in wages would also be expected to reinforce reductions inoutput on farms that hire in labor.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS422

Page 35: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

the analysis, we suppose that there are three parties to theagricultural contract: a tenant, landlord, and an intermediary. Webegin by making the strong assumption that intermediaries havea very strong bargaining position can make take-it-or-leave-itoffers to the landlord and tenant. This is very much in line withthe view that intermediaries captured the surplus from the land.In this world the tenant will receive a payoff of V( p, v ), and thelandlord will receive his reservation payoff which we denote by vL.The intermediary receives the surplus {R(e( p,v )) 2 e( p, v )} 2V( p,v ) 2 vL.

After the intermediary is abolished, this surplus is nowavailable for distribution provided that p remains the same. Onlyif the tenant obtains no bargaining power at all with his landlord,would we expect to observe no effect on the tenant’s payoff.Otherwise, we would expect to see the tenant’s payoff rise.Assuming that tenants are a signi�cant group of poor in India,this is consistent with our �nding that poverty is reduced by theabolition of intermediaries. We would not expect to see any changein effort and hence output unless p were different when landlordsand intermediaries negotiated contracts. Rent increases for ten-ants also would be associated with higher agricultural wages, bythe general equilibrium mechanism we have identi�ed.

We now turn to the impact of tenancy reforms. Such reformsare multifarious which make it difficult to offer a de�nitivetheoretical account. This would require much more institutionalcontent as in the analysis of West Bengal’s land reforms byBanerjee and Ghatak {1997}. Nonetheless, it is still useful to thinkthrough a simple model in order to check that our empirical�ndings conform to the predictions of the theory laid out above.Suppose therefore that the landlord has all the bargaining powerand can make take-it-or-leave-it offers to tenants before and afterthe tenancy reform. We shall model the effect of a tenancy reformas making it more difficult to evict tenants if they shirk. In termsof our model this is equivalent to a fall in p. As we have alreadyargued, this has two effects. First, we expect effort, and therefore,output to fall. Second, we expect a change in the payoff to thetenant as his rent could go up or down. We showed that this ispositive under reasonable conditions, and thus we would expectpoverty to be reduced which is what we found in the data. This isalso consistent with higher agricultural wages if increased rentsto tenants lead them to reduce their labor supply.

To summarize, the empirical �ndings are consistent with a

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 423

Page 36: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

stylized model of agricultural contracting and labor supply bytenants. While many complicating features could be added to thetheory, the general thrust of the trade-off captured here isrelevant.29 It is well-known that in a variety of contexts, rents areused to motivate tenants. Thus, land reforms that affect howagency problems are solved will typically generate both outputand distributional effects. We would expect these rents to affectlabor supply and result in changes to agricultural wages.

VIII. CONCLUDING REMARKS

The main contribution of this paper is to test whether landreform legislation is associated with poverty reductions usingstate-level data from India. The high incidence of poverty and thelarge volume of land reforms enacted to counter this problem inthe post-Independence period make this an issue of considerableinterest. We show that there is robust evidence of a link betweenpoverty reduction and two kinds of land reform legislation—tenancy reform and abolition of intermediaries. Another impor-tant �nding is that land reform can bene�t the landless by raisingagricultural wages. Although the effects on poverty are likely tohave been greater if large-scale redistribution of land had beenachieved, our results are nonetheless interesting as they suggestthat partial, second-best reforms which mainly affect productionrelations in agriculture can play a signi�cant role in reducingrural poverty.

As well as being important to policy debates in India, such�ndings may help to diffuse the more general pessimism that canundermine redistributive effort in developing countries. In arecent study {World Bank 1997}, much emphasis was placed onthe role of economic growth in explaining the decline of poverty inIndia. While our results are consistent with this �nding, theyemphasize that redistributive effort has also played its part.Using the average number of land reforms implemented, our �rstcoefficient in Table III implies that a reduction of the all-Indiapoverty gap of 1 percent can be explained by land reform. This isone-tenth of the actual reduction in poverty over the period of ourdata. This remains true even after factoring in the possibility thatoutput per capita is reduced by some kinds of land reform (Table

29. Following Banerjee and Ghatak {1997}, it would be possible to introduceinvestment into the model. In general, we would expect increased tenurial securityto increase investment.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS424

Page 37: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

VIII). To put this in perspective, we compared the effect of landreforms on poverty with the effect of changes in per capita income.This comparison suggests that implementing a land reform has asimilar effect on poverty reduction to a 10 percent increase in percapita income, or around four to �ve years growth at the all-Indiaaverage growth rate over this period.30

Since the effects of redistributive intervention on poverty andgrowth are not known a priori, a signi�cant literature has testedthese links using cross-country data. Benabou {1996} reviews thisliterature and emphasizes the diverse �ndings. While adding toour general understanding, the difficulties of �nding reliablecross-country measures of redistribution is a signi�cant drawbackin this research agenda. There seems little doubt, therefore, thatexploiting policy variation due to the federal structure of somedeveloping countries may be an important additional source ofevidence on policy incidence. It will also help to get behind broadbrush policy categories such as education or health expendituresthat mask important policy variations. Our study underlines that,even within a particular area of government intervention (i.e.,land reform), the empirical effects may vary depending on theexact form that the intervention takes. This is true, moreover,even though our policy measures are themselves fairly broad.Future efforts to quantify the empirical relationship betweengrowth, poverty, and redistribution will doubtless bene�t evenmore from a detailed speci�cation of how particular policy inter-ventions are structured and implemented across space and time.

DATA APPENDIX

The data used in the paper come from a wide variety ofsources.31 They come from the sixteen main states listed in TableI. Haryana split from the state of Punjab in 1965. From this dateon, we include separate observations for Punjab and Haryana.

30. Thus, we regressed poverty on per capita income (along with state effectsand year effects) and compared the coefficient on per capita income with thatobtained on land reform. (It made essentially no difference whether we did this byincluding both land reform and per capita income in one regression, or ranseparate regressions in one case including only land reform and in the other onlyincome per capita.) Results are available from the authors on request.

31. Our analysis has been aided by Ozler, Datt, and Ravallion {1996} whichcollects published data on poverty, output, wages, prices indices, and populationto construct a consistent panel data set on Indian states for the period 1958 to1992. We are grateful to Martin Ravallion for providing us with these data, towhich we have added information on land reform, public �nance, and politicalrepresentation.

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 425

Page 38: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

Land Reform

To construct the land reform variable used in the regressions,we begin by recording all land reform acts that were passed in agiven state and year. By examining the content of each landreform, we then classify each land reform act into four categories(1 5 tenancy reform, 2 5 abolition of intermediaries, 3 5 ceilingson landholdings, 4 5 consolidation of landholdings) where a singleland reform can belong to several types (see Table II). For eachland reform type this gives us a variable that is 0 or 1 in givenstate s and year t. We cumulate these variables over time to giveus four cumulative land reform variables that capture the stock ofland reforms passed to date in each of the four categories. We alsoaggregate across all four land reform categories to give us anaggregate cumulative land reform variable that gives us a mea-sure of the total stock of land reforms passed in state s by year t.Amendments to acts are treated as new pieces of legislation. TheIndex to Central and State Enactments (Ministry of Law andJustice, Government of India) was used to identify Acts pertainingto land reform in different states. To examine the exact content ofthese acts, we mainly used Haque and Sirohi {1986} and Zaidi{1985}, although a range of secondary sources were used todouble-check the correctness of the information provided by thesetwo books and to �ll in and update the detail regarding speci�clegislations. The secondary sources included Appu {1996}, Behu-ria {1997}, Bonner {1987}, Borgohain {1992}, Kurien {1981},Mearns {1998}, Pani {1983}, Singh and Misra {1964}, and Yugand-har and Iyer {1993}.

Poverty Data

We use the poverty measures for the rural and urban areas ofIndia’s sixteen major states, spanning 1957–1958 to 1991–1992put together by Ozler, Datt, and Ravallion {1996}. These measuresare based on 22 rounds of the National Sample Survey (NSS)which span this period. Not all 22 rounds of the survey can becovered for each of the 22 rounds for each of the 16 states.32 TheNSS rounds are also not evenly spaced: the average interval

32. For 11 states (Andra Pradesh, Assam, Bihar, Karnataka, Kerala, MadhyaPradesh, Orissa, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, Uttar Pradesh, and West Bengal), all 22rounds have been covered. Because Haryana only appears as a separate state fromPunjab in 1965, we have adopted including separate series for these two statesfrom this date onward. For Gujarat and Maharashtra, twenty rounds are included,beginning with the sixteenth round in 1958–1959 (before 1958–1959, separatedistributions are not available for these two states as they were merged under the

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS426

Page 39: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

between the midpoints of the surveys ranges from 0.9 to 5.5 years.Surveys were carried out in the following years: 1958, 1959, 1960,1961, 1962, 1963, 1965, 1966, 1967, 1968, 1969, 1970, 1971, 1973,1974, 1978, 1983, 1987, 1988, 1990, 1991, and 1992. Because otherdata are typically available on a yearly basis, weighted interpola-tion has been used to generate poverty measures for years wherethere was no NSS survey. The poverty lines used are thoserecommended by the Planning Commission {1993} and are asfollows. The rural poverty line is given by a per capita monthlyexpenditure of Rs. 49 at October 1973–June 1974 all-India ruralprices. The urban poverty line is given by a per capita monthlyexpenditure of Rs. 57 at October 1973–June 1974 all-India urbanprices. See Datt {1995} for more details on the rural and urbancost of living indices and on the estimation of the povertymeasures. The headcount index and poverty gap measures areestimated from the grouped distributions of per capita expendi-ture published by the NSS,33 using parameterized Lorenz curvesusing a methodology detailed in Datt and Ravallion {1992}.

Agricultural Wages

The primary source for the data is Agricultural Wages inIndia (Ministry of Agriculture, Government of India). Nominalwage data from this series have been de�ated using the ConsumerPrice Index for Agricultural Laborers to obtain real agriculturalwages. No agricultural wage data are available for the state ofJammu and Kashmir, and no separate wage data are available forthe state of Haryana.

Income Data

The primary source for data on state income is an annualgovernment publication Estimates of State Domestic Product(Department of Statistics, Department of Statistics, Ministry ofPlanning). The primary source for the Consumer Price Index forAgricultural Laborers (CPIAL) and Consumer Price Index forIndustrial Workers (CPIIW) which are used to de�ate agriculturaland nonagricultural state domestic product respectively is anumber of Government of India publications which include In-

state of Bombay). For Jammu and Kashmir, only eighteen rounds can be included,beginning with the sixteenth round for 1960–1961, due to a lack of data.

33. Reports from the National Sample Survey Organisation, Department ofStatistics, Ministry of Planning, Government of India and Sarvekshena, Journal ofthe National Sample Survey Organisation, Department of Statistics, Ministry ofPlanning, Government of India.

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 427

Page 40: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

dian Labour Handbook, the Indian Labour Journal, the IndianLabour Gazette, and the Reserve Bank of India Report on Currencyand Finance. Ozler, Datt and Ravallion {1996} have furthercorrected CPIAL and CPIIW to take account of interstate cost-of-living differentials and have also adjusted CPIAL to take accountof rising �rewood prices. Using their data allows us to puttogether a consistent and complete series on real total, agricul-tural, and nonagricultural state income for the period 1960 to1992. Our measure of agricultural yield is obtained by dividingreal agricultural state domestic product by net sown area for allcrops which is obtained from a government publication Area andProduction of Principal Crops in India (Directorate of Economicsand Statistics, Ministry of Agriculture).

Public Finance Data

The primary source for state level information on taxes andexpenditures is an annual publication, Public Finance Statistics(Ministry of Finance, Government of India). This information isalso collated in the Reserve Bank of India’s annual publicationReport on Currency and Finance.

Population Data

The population estimates are constructed using Census datafrom the �ve censuses for 1951, 1961, 1971, 1981, and 1991(Census of India, Registrar General and Census Commissioner,Government of India). Between any two successive censuses, thestate-sectoral populations are assumed to grow at a constant(compound) rate of growth, derived from the respective populationtotals.

Political Variables

Political variables are the main instruments used in thepaper. Data on the number of seats won by different nationalparties at each of the state elections are from Butler, Lahiri, andRoy {1991}. These primary data are aggregated into four politicalgroupings which are de�ned in the text and expressed as shares ofthe total number of seats in state legislatures. State politicalcon�gurations are held constant between elections.

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS,LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS428

Page 41: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

REFERENCES

Alesina, Alberto, and Dani Rodrik, ‘‘Distributive Politics and Economic Growth,’’Quarterly Journal of Economics, CIX (1994), 465–490.

Appu, P. S., Land Reforms in India: A Survey of Policy Legislation and Implemen-tation (New Delhi: Vikas, 1996).

Bandyopadhyay, D., ‘‘Land Reforms in India: An Analysis,’’ Economic and PoliticalWeekly, June 21–28, 1986.

Banerjee, Abhijit, and Maitreesh Ghatak, ‘‘Empowerment and Efficiency: TheEconomics of Tenancy Reform,’’ mimeo, Massachusetts Institute of Technol-ogy, and University of Chicago, 1996.

Banerjee, Abhijit, and Andrew Newman, ‘‘Occupational Choice and the Process ofDevelopment,’’ Journal of Political Economy, CI (1993), 659–684.

Bardhan, Pranab, ‘‘India,’’ in Chenery et al., eds., Redistribution with Growth(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1970).

Barro, Robert, Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country EmpiricalStudy (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1997).

Behuria, N. C., Land Reforms Legislation in India: A Comparative Study (NewDelhi: Vikas, 1997).

Benabou, Roland, ‘‘Inequality and Growth,’’ NBER Macroeconomics Annual(Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996).

Binswanger, Hans, Klaus Deininger, and Gershon Feder, ‘‘Power, Distortions,Revolt and Reform inAgricultural Land Relations, in Jere Behrman, and T. N.Srinivasan, eds., Handbook of Development Economics (Amsterdam: Elsevier,1995).

Bonner, Jeffrey P., Land Consolidation and Economic Development in India—AStudy of Two Hariana Villages (Riverdale: The Riverdale Company, 1987).

Borgohain, Rooplekha, Politics of Land Reforms in Assam (New Delhi: ReliancePublishing House, 1992).

Butler, David, Ashok Lahiri, and Prannoy Roy, India Decides: Elections 1952–1991(New Delhi: Aroom Purie for Living Media India, 1991).

Chattopadhyay, S. N., ‘‘Historical Context of Political Change in West Bengal: AStudy of Seven Villages in Bardhaman, Economic and Political Weekly, March28, 1992.

Chenery, Hollis, Montek Ahluwalia, Clive Bell, John Duloy, and Richard Jolly,Redistribution with Growth (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1970).

Datt, Gaurav, ‘‘Poverty in India 1951–1992: Trends and Decompositions,’’ PolicyResearch Department, World Bank, 1995.

Datt, Gaurav, and Martin Ravallion, ‘‘Growth and Redistribution Components ofChanges in Poverty Measures: A Decomposition with Applications to Braziland India in the 1980s,’’ Journal of Development Economics, XXXVIII (1992),275–295.

Datt, Gaurav, and Martin Ravallion, ‘‘Why Have Some Indian States Done Betterthan Others at Reducing Poverty?’ ’ Economica, LXV (1998), 17–38.

Dreze, Jean, andAmartya Sen, India: Economic Development and Social Opportu-nity (Oxford, Clarendon Press, 1995).

Dreze, Jean, Peter Lanjouw, and Naresh Sharma, ‘‘Economic Development 1957–1993,’’ in Peter Lanjouw and Nicholas Stern, Economic Development inPalanpur over Five Decades (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1998).

Gough, Kathleen, Rural Change in Southeast India: 1950s to 1980s (Delhi: OxfordUniversity Press, 1989).

Haque, Tajamul, and Amar Singh Sirohi, Agrarian Reforms and InstitutionalChanges in India (New Delhi: Concept Publishing Company, 1986).

Hoff, Karla, and Andrew B. Lyon, ‘‘Non-Leaky Buckets: Optimal RedistributiveTaxation and Agency Costs,’’ Journal of Public Economics, LIII (1995),365–390.

Jayaraman, Raji, and Peter Lanjouw, ‘‘Living Standards in Rural India: APerspective from Longitudinal Village Studies,’’ mimeo, Cornell Universityand World Bank, 1997.

Kurien, Christopher Thomas, Dynamics of Rural Transformation—A Study ofTamil Nadu: 1950–1975 (Madras: Orient Longman, 1981).

Mearns, Robin, ‘‘Access to Land in Rural India: Policy Issues and Options,’’ mimeo,World Bank, 1998.

LAND, POVERTY, AND GROWTH: INDIA 429

Page 42: Land Reforms- Besley Burgess

Moene, Karl Ove, ‘‘Poverty and Land Ownership,’’ American Economic Review,LXXXII (1992), 52–64.

Ozler, Berk, Gaurav Datt, and Martin Ravallion, ‘‘A Data Base on Poverty andGrowth in India,’’ mimeo, World Bank, 1996.

Pani, Narendar, Reforms to Pre-empt Change—Land Legislation in Karnataka(New Delhi: Concept Publishing Company, 1983).

Perotti, Roberto, ‘‘Income Distribution, Democracy, and Growth: What Does theData Say,’’ Journal of Economic Growth, I (1996), 149–187.

Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini, ‘Is Inequality Harmful for Growth: Theoryand Evidence,’’ American Economic Review, LXXXIV (1994), 600–621.

Planning Commission, Report on the Expert Group on the Estimation of theProportion and Number of Poor (New Delhi: Government of India, 1993).

Radhakrishnan, P., ‘‘Land Reforms: Rhetoric and Reality,’’ Economic and PoliticalWeekly, November 24, 1990.

Rodrik, Dani, ‘‘Getting Interventions Right: How South Korea and Taiwan GrewRich,’’ Economic Policy, XX (1995), 53–97.

Sargan, John Denis, ‘‘The Estimation of Economic Relationships Using Instrumen-tal Variables,’’ Econometrica, XXVI (1958), 393–415.

Sharma, H. R. ‘‘Distribution of Landholdings in Rural India, 1953–54 to 1981–1982: Implications for Land Reforms,’’ Economic and Political Weekly, Septem-ber 24, 1994.

Singh, Baljit, and Shridhar Misra, A Study of Land Reforms in Uttar Pradesh(Honolulu: East-West Center Press, 1964).

Thorner, Daniel, Agrarian Prospect in India (New Delhi: Allied Publishers, 1976).Wadley, S. S., and B. W. Derr, ‘‘Karimpur 1925–1984: Understanding Rural India

through Restudies,’’ in Pranab Bardhan, ed., Conversations between Econo-mists and Anthropologists (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1990).

Warriner, Doreen, Land Reform in Principle and Practice (Oxford: Oxford Univer-sity Press, 1969).

World Bank, ‘‘Poverty in India: 50 Years after Independence,’’ World Bank, mimeo,1997.

Yugandhar, B. N., and K. Gopal Iyer, Land Reforms in India: Bihar—InstitutionalConstraints (London: Sage Publications, 1993).

Zaidi, A. Moin, Not by a Class War—A Study of Congress Policy on Land Reformsduring the Last 100 Years (New Delhi: Document Press, 1985).

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS430