20
Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney ([email protected] ) (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February 08, 2013 Review Section Note from Rich: Feel free to print the slides or bring your laptop to class. If you feel comfortable with this material already, no need to come!

Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney ([email protected])[email protected] (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Net Present Value Analysis

Rich Sweeney([email protected])

(Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore)

February 08, 2013Review Section

Note from Rich: Feel free to print the slides or bring your laptop to class. If you feel

comfortable with this material already, no need to come!

Note from Rich: Feel free to print the slides or bring your laptop to class. If you feel

comfortable with this material already, no need to come!

Page 2: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Agenda

Fundamental Theories of Welfare Economics

Static Efficiency vs. Dynamic Efficiency (NPV)

Internal Rate of Return

Equivalent Annual Net Benefits

Readings on Benefit-Cost Analysis

Practice Problem(s)

Excel Workbook Embedded Here:

2

Page 3: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Fundamental Theories of Welfare Economics:Pareto Criterion and Pareto Optimality

Pareto Criterion: A policy change is an improvement if at least some people are made better off and no one is made worse off

Pareto Optimality: No other feasible policy could make at least one person better off without making anyone else worse off

3Adam’s Payment

Beth’s Payment

StatusQuo

Policy A

Policy B

Policy C

Policy D

Feasibility Frontier

Possible Payments to Adam and Beth Which satisfy Pareto Criterion?

‒ Policy A does ‒ Policy B does not‒ Policy C does not‒ Policy D does‒ All policies in light gray triangle

Which satisfy Pareto Optimality?

‒ Policy A does not ‒ Policy B does not‒ Policy C does‒ Policy D does‒ All policies on feasibility frontier (because nothing “better” from there)

$25 $100

$25

$100

Page 4: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Fundamental Theories of Welfare Economics:Kaldor-Hicks Criterion

Kaldor-Hicks Criterion: A policy change is an

improvement if the “winners” could fully compensate the

“losers” and still be better off themselves

– Also known as Potential Pareto Improvement Criterion

Kaldor-Hicks Criterion rules out policies with total

benefits smaller than total costs (that is, policies with

negative net benefits, where NB = TB - TC)

When the Kaldor-Hicks Criterion is used to compare

all feasible policy options, the best is that which

maximizes net benefits

– If all policies have negative net benefits, keep the status quo4

Page 5: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

0

5

10

15

20

25

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Ma

rgin

al B

en

efi

ts o

r M

arg

ina

l Co

sts

Quantity of Pollution Control

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

To

tal B

en

efi

ts o

r T

ota

l C

os

ts

Quantity of Pollution Control

Static Efficiency (Single time period)

Undertake policy to the point at which TB – TC is the

highest

marginal benefit = marginal cost

5

Total Benefits

Total Costs

Marginal Benefits

Marginal CostsNet Benefits

Q*

Total Benefits and Total Costs Marginal Benefits and Marginal Costs

Q*

Page 6: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Dynamic Efficiency: when B and C in different time periods

To achieve dynamic efficiency (multiple time periods),

undertake policy with highest net present value

If all policies have negative NPV, keep the status quo

Discount rate should reflect social opportunity cost

U.S. Office of Management and Budget (OMB)

published guidance on discount rate and benefit-cost

analysis in Circular A-4 (September 2003):http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/assets/regulatory_matters_pdf/a-4.pdf

6

T

tttt

r

CB

0 )1(NPV

Page 7: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

OMB Guidelines on C-B Analysis

“For transparency’s sake, you should state in your

report what assumptions were used, such as the time

horizon for the analysis and the discount rates

applied to future benefits and costs.

It is usually necessary to provide a sensitivity analysis

to reveal whether, and to what extent, the results of

the analysis are sensitive to plausible changes in the

main assumptions and numeric inputs”.

7

Page 8: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Why do we need discounting? (Circular A4, OMB)

Benefits or costs that occur sooner are generally more

valuable– Resources invested earn a positive return, so current consumption is more

expensive than future consumption, since you are giving up that expected

return on investment when you consume today. (Opportunity Cost).

– Postponed benefits also have a cost because people generally prefer

present to future consumption. (Positive time preference).

– Also, if consumption continues to increase over time, as it has for most of

U.S. history, an increment of consumption will be less valuable in the future

than it would be today (Principle of diminishing marginal utility).

8

Page 9: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

What is the appropriate discount rate?

“a real discount rate of 7 percent should be used as a

base-case for regulatory analysis”.

Why?

– “The 7 percent rate is an estimate of the average before-tax

rate of return to private capital in the U.S. economy.

– the returns to real estate and small business capital as well as

corporate capital.

– It approximates the opportunity cost of capital

– it is the appropriate discount rate whenever the main effect of

a regulation is to displace or alter the use of capital in the

private sector”.

9

Page 10: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

The appropriate discount rate ?

The effects of regulation do not always fall exclusively or primarily

on the allocation of capital.

When regulation primarily and directly affects private

consumption (e.g., through higher consumer prices for goods and

services), a lower discount rate is appropriate.

The alternative most often used is sometimes called the social

rate of time preference

…the rate at which society discounts future consumption flows to

their present value. – the rate that the average saver uses to discount future consumption as a

measure

Real rate of return on long-term government debt ( = 3%)

10

Page 11: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

How does discounting work?

Reciprocal of compounding

Benefits and costs far in the future are more sensitive to discount

rate than near-term benefits and costs

– Run discounting program in Excel workbook

11

r = 3% → NPV = $29M r = 10% → NPV = -$10M

-$250

-$200

-$150

-$100

-$50

$0

$50

$100

0 1 2 3 4 5 NPV

Net

Ben

efit

s (m

illi

on

s)

Undiscounted Net Benefits Discounted Net Benefits

-$250

-$200

-$150

-$100

-$50

$0

$50

$100

0 1 2 3 4 5 NPV

Net

Ben

efit

s (m

illi

on

s)

Undiscounted Net Benefits Discounted Net Benefits

Page 12: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

How does discounting work?

When costs are incurred up front and benefits occur in

the future, low discount rates result in higher NPVs than

high discount rates

12

Relationship between Discount Rate and NPVwith Upfront Costs and Future Benefits

-$50

-$40

-$30

-$20

-$10

$0

$10

$20

$30

$40

$50

0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% 12% 14% 16% 18% 20%

Net

Pre

sen

t V

alu

e (m

illio

ns)

r

Page 13: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Steps for NPV Analysis

Pick a discount rate

Estimate the static net benefits of the project in each

year for the entire life of the project.

Convert each period’s net benefits into present value

terms by dividing by (1+r)^t

Sum the discounted stream of net benefits to get the

present value over the project.

Select the project with the greatest NPV

13

Page 14: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Dynamic Efficiency:Power Plant Example

You are a special assistant to Gov. Schwarzenegger of

California. He wants to shut down a coal-fired power plant

and replace it with either a hydropower plant or a natural gas-

fired plant. He asks you to analyze the options.

Assumptions (unrealistic…)

– Both plants can be built in 1 year and operate for 5 years

– Both plants yield annual benefits of $50M relative to coal

– Hydropower plant has upfront fixed costs of $100M and

annual operating costs of $5M

– Natural gas plant has upfront fixed costs of $40M and

annual operating costs of $20M

– Discount rate is 7 percent, but also try 3 and 10 percent

14

Page 15: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Dynamic Efficiency:Power Plant Example

Hydropower has a slightly higher NPV than natural gas

at 7 percent discount rate, but lower at 10 percent

15

$0

$20

$40

$60

$80

$100

$120

r = 3% r = 7% r = 10%

Ne

t Pre

se

nt

Va

lue

(m

illio

ns

)

Hydropower Natural Gas

Page 16: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Discounting & Climate Change: The Stern Report

A time scale of centuries, so the brute power of compound interest– Manhattan purchase: 60 guilders ($ 1000) in 1626

– @ 7%: ~$80 trillion; @ 3%: ~ 15 million (5 million times)

The Stern Report conclusions are driven mainly by the low assumed discount

rate : (r = 1.4%)

– If r = 6%, the PDV of global-warming loss 100 years hence is <1/100 th

Question: Is it worthwhile to sacrifice costs C =1% of GDP now to

remove damages D = 5% of GDP a 100 years from now?

Stern’s B/C ratio = 4.5 (upper bound 5 if zero discount rate is chosen)

B/C ratio (@ r = 6%) = 0.1

Prof Martin Weitzman: “In fact, it is not an exaggeration to say that the

biggest uncertainty of all in the economics of climate change is the

uncertainty about which interest rate to use for discounting”

16

Page 17: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Health related costs and benefits

Question: is discounting even appropriate?

– lives saved today cannot be invested in a bank to save more

lives in the future.

Answer: Yes!

– People have been observed to prefer health gains that occur

immediately to identical health gains that occur in the future.

– If future health gains are not discounted while future costs

are, then what happens?

– an attractive investment today in future health improvement

can always be made more attractive by delaying the

investment

17

Page 18: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Equivalent Annual Net Benefits

Suppose the hydropower plant replacing the coal plant

in California can operate for 10 years and the natural

gas plant can still only operate for 5 years

– At r = 7 percent, NPVhydro = $216M and NPVgas = $83M

– At r = 32* percent, NPVhydro = $32M and NPVgas = $30M

* This is an unusually high discount rate, but it illustrates the point for the example numbers

Calculate equivalent annual net benefits to compare

these projects of different duration

– At r = 7 percent, EANBhydro = $27M and EANBgas = $16M

– At r = 32 percent, EANBhydro = $8M and EANBgas = $9M 18

Trr

rNPVEANB

)1(1

Page 19: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Readings on Benefit-Cost Analysis:Arrow et al. (1996)

Benefit-cost analysis is a important framework for

making regulatory decisions

– Careful consideration of benefits and costs

– Common unit of measurement for disparate impacts (dollars)

– Useful tool for improving effectiveness of regulation

– Techniques for incorporating uncertainty

But benefit-cost analysis should not be the sole basis

for making regulatory decisions

– Consideration of distributional impacts as well

– Perhaps not necessary to perform benefit-cost analysis for

minor regulations

19

Page 20: Net Present Value Analysis Rich Sweeney (rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu)rich_sweeney@hksphd.harvard.edu (Based on Notes from Avinash Kishore) February

Readings on Benefit-Cost Analysis:Goulder and Stavins (2002)

Discounting does not shortchange the future, so long as

an appropriate discount rate is used

– It simply puts current values and future values of benefits and

costs in equivalent monetary terms; apples-to-apples

comparison

– It accounts for time value of money (interest) and not inflation:

rnominal ≈ inflation + rreal

When the “winners” of a policy do not actually

compensate the “losers,” the Kaldor-Hicks criterion

carries less weight

Lowering the discount rate to increase NPV is

problematic because it mixes efficiency and equity 20