37
02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US Department Store c.1910-1965 Abstract By analysing the US department store between c.1910-1965, this article deepens our understanding of the nature of the transition to phases of ‘maturity’ and ‘decline’ that are fundamental to models of retail change (retail wheel, retail life-cycle). By employing a close reading of key marketing and management writing of the period, it finds that “lock- in” to an organisational structure associated with a single downtown store posed significant obstacles to suburban branched expansion. Only partial organisational centralisation occurred with the formation of holding companies in the 1920s, which contrasted with chains of general-merchandise and some department store retailers that were efficiently structured and better able to exploit suburban growth. When major department store companies finally embraced branched expansion they were forced to significantly revise their operational structures. Keywords: retail failure; retail wheel; retail life-cycle; department store; central buying. Steve Wood School of Management, University of Surrey. Guildford, Surrey GU2 7XH Email: [email protected] Tel: +44 (0)1483 686344 Fax: +44 (0)1483 686346 Revised manuscript: April 2009 Accepted for publication in The Service Industries Journal

Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

02/04/2009 09:52

Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory:

Examining the US Department Store c.1910-1965

Abstract

By analysing the US department store between c.1910-1965, this article deepens our

understanding of the nature of the transition to phases of ‘maturity’ and ‘decline’ that are

fundamental to models of retail change (retail wheel, retail life-cycle). By employing a

close reading of key marketing and management writing of the period, it finds that “lock-

in” to an organisational structure associated with a single downtown store posed

significant obstacles to suburban branched expansion. Only partial organisational

centralisation occurred with the formation of holding companies in the 1920s, which

contrasted with chains of general-merchandise and some department store retailers that

were efficiently structured and better able to exploit suburban growth. When major

department store companies finally embraced branched expansion they were forced to

significantly revise their operational structures.

Keywords: retail failure; retail wheel; retail life-cycle; department store; central buying.

Steve Wood School of Management, University of Surrey. Guildford, Surrey GU2 7XH Email: [email protected] Tel: +44 (0)1483 686344 Fax: +44 (0)1483 686346

Revised manuscript: April 2009

Accepted for publication in The Service Industries Journal

Page 2: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

1

INTRODUCTION AND PURPOSE

The standing of marketing theory has been criticised for both its lack of a theoretically driven focus

and acceptance within broader management thinking (Burton, 2005), yet two key explanatory

models of retail change endure: namely the retail life-cycle and the wheel of retailing (Davidson et

al., 1976; McNair, 1958). Both models retain interest and relevance in conceptualising

contemporary retail change (Palmer, 2005; Schultz, 2002) and seek to describe the adaptation of

retailers following introduction to the market as they respond to competitive pressure. The retail

wheel asserts ‘that retail institutions commence as cut price, low cost, narrow margin operations

which subsequently “trade up”’ (Brown, 1987, 10). Meanwhile the retail life-cycle charts the

innovation, accelerated development, maturity and decline phases experienced by retail formats

(Davidson et al., 1976; see Figure 1).

The development of both models was significantly influenced by the experiences of the US

department store following its emergence in the late 19th century. The decline of the department

store format is partly attributed to inadequate adaptation to its competitive environment. As a

closed-system theorisation, the retail wheel contends that ‘retail change is both stimulated and

explained by the activities of the institutions themselves’ (Alexander and Phillips, 2006, 71). The

department store is seen as “trading upward”, substantially decreasing its competitiveness

(Converse, 1959; Crask, 1980; Hollander, 1960) – a disadvantage that was exacerbated as the

format proved ‘slow to recognise the market potential of the rapidly growing suburbs in the post-

war period’ (Brown, 1987, 8). This is viewed as leading to exposure to competition from highly

efficient, chained, low margin, price-focused competition.

However, these factors alone do not explain the unsuccessful response to competitive challenge. As

Hollander (1960, 41) asked in his seminal paper examining McNair’s wheel model: ‘Why should

reasonably skilled businessmen make decisions that consistently lead their firms along seemingly

profitable routes to positions of vulnerability?’ Clearly then there is a need to move beyond a simple

and generic closed-system conceptualisation of retail change to cast further light on the inflection

points between various stages of the models – in the case of department stores, the transition to

Page 3: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

2

periods of decline. We need to enrich our understanding regarding why retailers do not act to

maintain market position in the face of deteriorating performance. As Palmer (2005, 719) notes with

the case of the retail life-cycle, explanatory accounts of these episodes have been under-developed

both theoretically and within academic research which often:

‘…underplays the pressures faced by executives during the turning or inflection points between the various stages. In other words, it does not account for the types of pressures faced by retailers….[furthermore]… there is little indication of how firms break through the life cycle inflection points, and whether such points are prolonged periods. Put differently, the retail life cycle does not indicate the processes by which the retailer will progress from one stage to another’.

Therefore, with Hollander’s key question regarding organisational inertia framing our analysis, the

aim of this paper is to examine the organisational adaptation of US department stores between

c.1910-1965. In doing so, we seek to make linkages between both the spatial and structural

elements of retail organisation (cf. A Alexander, 1997; Shaw et al., 1998).

More explicitly, first we seek to understand why department stores seemingly delayed wide-ranging

suburban expansion. Second, we offer greater explanation as to why department store cost

structures increased and operating efficiency deteriorated – a factor specifically represented in the

retail wheel model. We achieve these through a close reading of the key marketing, retail, economic

and management writing of the period.1 Our explanations have their origin in the ‘built in

organizational rigidities, cumbersomeness, a slowness to act, a lack of receptivity to new ideas’ that

came to characterise some department store retailers (May and McNair, 1977, 57). Our analysis also

has its focus in “lock in” to principles of organisation that can become engrained with decades of

successful operation but which can ultimately serve to resist adaptation (cf. Jensen, 1993;

Schoenberger, 1997).

** Figure 1 about here **

The article is organised as follows: first, we examine the development of the ‘department-manager

plan’ – an operating structure designed for stand-alone downtown department stores. Although

effective, the structure proved inflexible and would subsequently limit branch development and

Page 4: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

3

adaptation. Second, we analyse how traditional department stores struggled to replicate the

centralised efficiency of chain stores within their organisations even after extensive merger and

acquisition activity. Third, we explore the challenges associated with post-1945 suburban growth

and interpret traditional department store organisational responses. The paper concludes by

discussing the implications for marketing theory, retail change and the avoidance of retail failure

more widely.

THE DOWNTOWN DEPARTMENT STORE: ORGANISATIONAL STRUCTURE AND

INITIAL BRANCHING ACTIVITY

The emergence of the downtown department store and its ‘golden age’ of expansion has been a

feature of marketing and business history research (e.g. Coles, 1999; Hower, 1943; Laermans, 1993;

Pasdermadjian, 1954; Resseguie, 1965; Tadajewski, 2008). However, there has been minimal

coverage after the period of initial growth and the sector’s subsequent participation in large-scale

systems of Fordist production and consumption during the 20th century. In this first section we

examine how US department stores had formalised their operating structures by the 1930s but

struggled to replicate this efficiency with initial forays into branch store development.

The advent of the single downtown store department-manager plan

Mirroring the revolution occurring in manufacturing at the time, from 1910 there was a focus in the

marketing literature on realising advances in the operation of distribution: ‘the administration of

department stores in general is so far behind that of modern factories as to constitute the former a

particularly promising field for the application of scientific management’ (Thompson, 1915, 268;

see also Walker, 1913; Weld, 1923). One of the most formidable advances in the organisation of the

single site department store – and a structure that served to make wide-ranging branched

development later problematic – was acceptance of a four division model of responsibility (see

Figure 2). First suggested by Paul Mazur (1925a; 1927), the model provided the necessary division

of labour to the store with the development of specialists in each of the main divisions.

** Figure 2 about here **

Page 5: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

4

The organisational structure saw each department sales manager possess full control of buying and

selling, along with responsibility for departmental expenses and profits (Tolman, 1921) – in turn

codifying the late 19th Century tendency to give ‘buyers a free rein in running their departments’

(Benson, 1986, 16) . Each department was ‘considered as a separate speciality store or shop. Its

accounts are kept separate; and under normal conditions it must stand on its own feet’ (Nystrom,

1919, 256). The fusing of the buying and selling functions was partly driven by the belief that tacit

knowledge gained from a physical presence in the store was required for the store buyer to make

fully informed merchandise decisions. Doubman and Whitaker’s (1927, 117-118) comments are

typical of the period when they note that ‘in order that our large retail stores may do their buying

efficiently, it is necessary that continuous representation takes place’ in order ‘to maintain adequate

or complete stocks of merchandise and yet be in a position to secure maximum turnover’.

Concomitant with the formalisation and acceptance of an organisational structure suited to the

downtown department store was the introduction of scientific principles of management to the

shopfloor, often driven by time and motion studies (Graham, 2000). Non customer–facing store

organisation was enhanced with the introduction of the retail price inventory method (Filene, 1930;

Savitt, 1999), along with credit and store overhead control (Jeacle, 2004). In practice these

measures constrained the dominance of the buyer to a greater degree than previously (Walsh and

Jeacle, 2003), as a war of attrition commenced between managers’ desire for lean stocks and

frequent reordering versus the buyers’ yearning for ‘larger authorizations and more autonomy’

(Benson, 1986, 50). Critically though these changes did not separate the buying and selling

function, thereby retaining considerable influence for the buyer, which ultimately had significant

future implications for multi-unit department store development.

Early branching initiatives of traditional US department stores and organisational structures,

1910-1945

Before World War II, department stores focused largely on the single downtown unit. However, the

late 1920s saw some early attempts at branching along with limited retail decentralisation which

partially challenged the appropriateness of the single site, department-manager organisational

Page 6: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

5

structure. These initial forays were partly facilitated by the emergence of neighbourhood and

community centres that were intended to supply lower-order goods to growing populations outside

of the downtown (Longstreth, 1992; 1997a). Most new branches that were opened in these areas

during the inter-war period were considerably smaller than downtown stores (at less than 50,000 sq

ft) and focused on clothing and accessories (Longstreth, 1997b, 246). Only in Los Angeles did the

branches more closely resemble their downtown parents at 150,000 sq ft of selling area, stocking a

wider range of goods to attract more affluent consumers (see Longstreth, 1997c).

The extent of retail decentralisation remained modest but pre-dated large scale suburbanisation of

the population. A study of Illinois retailing found that branches of department stores were typically

first established between 1927-1943 (Tonning, 1955). Marshall Field’s first branches were

constructed in the late 1920s (Wendt and Kogan, 1952) while Goldblatt’s had nine large outlets

outside of the Metropolitan area by 1936 (Longstreth, 2007). Elsewhere, by 1931 Strawbridge and

Clothier had two Philadelphia branches (Longstreth, 1997a), while Macy’s, which had acquired a

portfolio of six downtown stores by the start of World War II, only operated one branch (Bingham

and Yunich, 1965).

One of the first department stores to experiment with branched activity was H B Claflin Company

of New York that had grown to a chain of 40 stores. However, it filed for bankruptcy in 1914 partly

due to its inefficient decentralised operating structure that saw ‘no attempt to buy cooperatively so

as to gain the price reductions which joint buying makes possible’ (HBR, 1926, 467; New York

Times, 1914). Evidently while there were a number of tentative steps towards constructing

additional stores, branches were rarely conceived as possessing equal importance to the dominant

downtown unit that often retained managerial control, with the branch typically considered ‘as a

service station for customers of the main store’ (HBR, 1927, 84; Pasdermadjian, 1954).

While the department store advantage was based on scale by being a downtown ‘universal provider’

to customers with an organisational structure to match, these initial branches offered a reduced

product range and stretched the resources of downtown store management. However, there were

Page 7: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

6

some notable exceptions: in 1915, W A Wieboldt’s (based in Chicago) expanded its department

store operation by running its two stores as a single operation. As Longstreth (2007, 20) comments,

the expansion to a third store in 1924 underlined ‘the efficiencies of centralized management with

uniform buying and merchandising procedures as well as advertising’. In addition, historical

analysis of T C Power department store of Montana at the turn of the century uncovered the growth

of a small portfolio of stores that were administered centrally. However, pro-active branch

managers complemented decision-making at head office to realise a ‘fairly good balance between

centralized decision making and decentralization’ (Klassen, 1992, 699). Such examples, however,

remained the exception as the single downtown unit predominated, supported by an appropriate

organisational structure.

THE RISE OF THE CHAINS, DEPARTMENT STORE CONSOLIDATIONS AND THE

CENTRALISATION CHALLENGE

The chained concept and the centralisation imperative

The dependence of the traditional department store on a single downtown unit contrasted with the

rapid expansion of numerous chain stores after the turn of the century. As one department store

owner commented, ‘chain stores have matched the mass production of the modern manufacturer

with mass distribution’ (Filene, 1924, 7). The literal (albeit small scale) example of this was car

manufacturer, Henry Ford’s chained commissary retail stores (Hollander and Marple, 1960; Freathy

and Sparks, 1995). In the light of centralised retail operations, the marketing literature reflected on

the serious implications for the single site, downtown department store:

‘the chain stores are armed with most of the advantages of the large department store, with the ubiquity of a whole group of retailers, They are like department stores mobilized and out for conquest’ (Clapp, 1920, 56).

There was an implicit understanding that a response was required from traditional retailers to

‘devote themselves to the organization and improvement of their own methods of doing business’

(Palmer, 1929, 290; see also Lazurus, 1926; Martin, 1930).

The initial rise of the chain store was impressive (see Figure 3). By 1927 J C Penney’s had a store

Page 8: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

7

estate of over 1,000; W T Grant 109; Kresge’s 435 and F W Woolworth’s 1,581 (Leach, 1993, 274).

In the rapidly expanding grocery field, A&P had expanded from 4,224 stores in 1919 to 15,400 by

1929 (Oi, 2004).

** Figure 3 about here **

While adherence to chain principles was no guarantee of success with numerous chain stores failing

in the early stages of development, the accomplishment of the multi-unit concept was undeniable

and based on a number of key factors. First, there was an emphasis on centralised scale economies

in marketing and, more importantly, buying (Bradshaw, 1943). Multi-unit retailers had the scale of

regional (and ultimately national) markets underpinning orders. Hence with a focus on ‘low-cost,

high-volume, high-speed through-put of goods’ at the expense of customer service (Madison, 1976,

104), chains bought in greater volume than the isolated department store, and could thus eliminate

the middleman, wholesaler, jobber and, in some cases, the manufacturer (Chandler, 1990; Mullen,

1924). Furthermore, many chains pursued vertical integration that offered control over the supply

chain, reduced reliance on manufacturers and proved efficient given the scale of operations (Haney,

1920; McNair, 1950; Nystrom, 1919).

The centralised organisational form of chains left store managers with reduced autonomy to adapt

assortments to local circumstance (Raff, 2003). Instead, local management were tasked with

maintaining low operating costs and high sales volumes as regional headquarters ‘determined store

locations and handled accounting, transportation, personnel policies, buying and pricing of

merchandise, and sales promotion’ (Raucher, 1991, 132). Whilst foregoing some flexibility, the

chains’ efficiency contrasted with single site downtown department stores which, although large

stand-alone institutions, had their scale economies diluted by a preponderance of 100 departments

or more (McNair, 1931c), leading one department store owner to warn that ‘no department store can

buy in such quantities as the large chain’ (Filene, 1927, 4).

Second, there was increasing entry of chain stores into market segments previously dominated by

department stores. Before the mid 1920s, chains had been largely confined to the drug and grocery

Page 9: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

8

retail sectors, but after this time there was an increased penetration of chains selling clothing and

home furnishings lines (Pasdermadjian, 1954). The growth of ladies’ ready-to-wear was of

particular concern and contrasted with the multiples’ previous specialisation in staple merchandise

(Phillips, 1937). Larger chained department stores such as Sears and Montgomery Ward grew by

adding hardline offers, including auto tires and appliances into the 1930s (Tedlow, 1996). Such

commodities were a growth market yet were largely neglected by downtown department stores

despite accounting for an increasing proportion of household expenditure.

Third, a new focus on scientific management and consolidated control allowed the chain store to

facilitate effective centralisation, signalling the emergence of ‘modern merchandising – a new

science’ (Hess, 1924, 5; Hodge, 1925). Highly skilled buyers based in head offices analysed the

performance of product lines, adjusting buying patterns and merchandise offers accordingly. In

essence, chain stores reflected wider developments in the economy that saw the integration of a

greater number of enterprises, the adoption of departmentalised structures, and the introduction of

control by salaried managers (Chandler, 1977; 1990).

Finally, without dependence on any one location, chains were able to spread risk throughout their

store portfolio. They typically offered a convenient decentralised location, close to residential areas

(Nystrom, 1919). In contrast, the downtown department store demanded the highest rentals,

increasingly suffered from downtown congestion and saw affluent residents relocate to the edge of

city environs (Burnham, 1940).

The development of the chain concept in department store retailing: Penney, Sears and Ward

To simplistically depict all department stores as inactive in the inter-war chain movement is

inaccurate. Some department store retailers either multiplied and centralised control quickly

(thereby overcoming any dependence on the department-manager organisational form), or

alternatively became chained department stores from the outset, having developed from a

background in mail order retailing. For example, mail order retailers such as Sears, Roebuck &

Company and Montgomery Ward developed as store based concerns in the 1920s (Raff and Temin,

1997; Tedlow, 1996). Meanwhile, J C Penney expanded from 312 stores in 1920 to 1,452 stores in

Page 10: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

9

1930 (Schragger, 2005).

Importantly, these operators developed stores in low rent locations, well away from downtown high

rentals and increasing congestion (Longstreth, 2006). In the case of J C Penney ‘more than half its

stores in 1929 were in towns of 5,000 or fewer people’ (Raucher, 1991, 154). Furthermore, these

retailers typically centralised their buying. As Emmet and Jeuck argue in their biography of Sears,

the specialisation of the buying function resulted in considerable advantages over the buyers at

traditional department stores:

‘Many department-store buyers confine their purchases largely to primary sources, well known and usually conveniently located, mainly because such buyers lack the knowledge, time, or willingness to look elsewhere, Sears’s buyers on the contrary, when they find primary sources unsatisfactory, examine secondary sources which, though less well known and perhaps off the beaten path, produce quality merchandise often available at lower prices than that of primary sources’ (Emmet and Jeuck, 1950, 398).

This meant that decisions had to be made on the basis of data interpreted at-a-distance rather than

from the tacit knowledge that came from a continual presence on the shopfloor as at traditional

department stores. As Sears Chairman General Wood testified:

‘As a business becomes larger and has branches all over the country, it becomes impossible for the executive to follow it and control except by figures. These figures have to be carefully and rapidly compiled, available immediately, and the executive must be able to interpret them properly - read behind the figures’ (cited by Chandler, 1962, 263).

Consolidation and co-operation activity: ‘chained’ department stores or decentralised

‘holding companies’?

Informal grouping of department stores

The strategic options for the independent downtown department store in the light of multi-unit

retailers seemed ‘to indicate a trend away from the [traditional] department store’ (Mazur, 1924,

434) and ‘a transition from entrepreneurial flair to business control and scale economies’ (Jeacle,

2004, 1172). Organisational and operational centralisation was perceived as critical:

‘There is good ground for the general belief that there is a definite trend toward larger distributive units with increased centralization of control, for the faith held by many people in the economies of mass distribution, economies which might perhaps parallel with those of mass production’ (Lewis, 1930, 37).

Page 11: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

10

Paul Nystrom, best known for his classic text The Economics of Retailing (1919), argued that

separate department store retailers could co-operate to purchase direct from producers on a single

contract while retaining their independent status (Clark et al., 1926). On one level this would mean

a partial movement away from a reliance on the isolated downtown buyer (Converse et al., 1929)

but could also see department stores share statistics, fashion and style information, along with

selling strategies (Clapp, 1920; Patterson, 1915; Nystrom, 1933).

Filene’s was one of the first department stores to promote co-operation in this manner, through the

formation of the Retail Research Association (RRA) in 1917. Its remit was to study problems of

merchandising and store operation, and for the first time agreed upon a uniform system of record-

keeping (Bluestone et al., 1981). In 1918 this initiative was superseded by the formation of

Associated Merchandising Corporation (AMC), consisting of 16 non-competing stores (HBR,

1926). Its expanded purpose was to facilitate collaboration between retailers in buying merchandise,

recruitment, employee training and improved advertising. Similar institutions subsequently formed

such as the Associated Retailers of America (1925) and the Cavendish Trading Company (1926)

(HBR, 1926). Finally, this co-operation extended internationally with the formation of the

knowledge sharing International Association of Department Stores (1928) (Pasdermadjian, 1954).

While known to be successful in more standardised retail categories such as grocery (French, 2008),

the extent of the pooled buying for traditional department stores remained limited. By the mid

1930s, one researcher found that while three out of four department stores had been members of a

cooperative buying group, the typical store ‘will not find it advantageous to purchase more than 10

per cent to 20 per cent cooperatively’ (Gault, 1937, 398).

Formal consolidation and organisational centralisation?

Beyond the formation of co-operative groups, there were calls for formal consolidation to realise

organisational centralisation and scale economies (Griffen et al., 1928; HBR, 1926; Mazur, 1924;

New York Times, 1925; see Table 1). Probably the best known argument came from Edward Filene

in a 1927 speech which forecast that departments would be highly specialised with the

Page 12: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

11

centralisation of buying supported by ‘facts and scientific knowledge’ (p 13) to allow the best

buyers to serve in central offices tempered by ‘decentralized operation and selling’ (p 12).

Purchasing would be from ‘approved vendors’ and, given the scale of orders, ‘the manufacturer of

vision, therefore, should be anxious to become a preferred source’ (Converse et al., 1929, 44).

** Table 1 about here **

The response of the US department store industry to the cries for action stopped far short of that

demanded. Typically, transactions consolidated a number of previously independent department

stores into holding companies and included the formation of May Department Stores (1910);

Associated Dry Goods Corporation (1913); Hahn Department Store Inc (1928) and Federated

Department Stores (1929) (see Table 2).

** Table 2 about here **

Importantly there was minimal consolidation of buying or development of shared services, and

hence few synergistic benefits were realised. Instead, operating independence was largely retained;

something lamented at the end of the 1920s:

‘…most department store groups have been financial consolidations primarily. Until they add to that finance, enterprise, operating skill, knowledge and effectiveness, you won’t begin to see the real results of operating efficiency’ (Mazur, 1929, 16).

For Doubman and Whitaker writing in 1927, there was optimism that efficiencies would still be

achieved:

‘The recent development of consolidation of department stores and the growth of department-store chains are based on certain advantages that are likely to accrue. These advantages will lie to a very great extent in the field of buying. Not only will such organizations be able to take advantage of quantity prices, but they will be in a better position to get cash discounts on purchases’ (p 20).

However, the changes in ownership would only be accretive with restructuring of the new

configuration (cf. Wood, 2002). As Nystrom argued at the time, ‘changing the ownership without

changing the service, merely results in deflecting retail net profits…from private owners to co-

Page 13: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

12

operative owners’ (Clark et al., 1926, 257). This meant that while mergers had unified ownership,

they did not yield ‘the advantages of group management’ (Griffen et al., 1928, 27). By the 1930s it

was noted tersely that while the economies of central buying were advanced as the justification for

the consolidations, ‘an examination of a number of organizations, each operating several

department stores, reveals that central buying is being applied to a very limited extent’ (Falk, 1930,

265; see Table 3).

** Table 3 about here **

There were some exceptions to the lack of central buying that were widely debated (e.g. New York

Times, 1927; 1929). By 1930 Associated Merchandise Corporation was using central buying for

shoes, luggage, cheap dresses and china; Gimbel Brothers experimented with central purchasing for

men’s shoes in four of its stores and Hale Brothers trialled central procurement for c.30% of its

departments in five of its stores in 1927 (Falk, 1930). More adventurous forays into centralisation

included the use of a consolidated buying office at American Department Stores to source

considerable proportions of non-style merchandise sold across its 18-store portfolio (Falk, 1930).

Overall though, the independent and buyer-focused, single-unit organisational structure remained

insufficiently challenged:

‘The main obstacle to the establishment of chains of department stores is the separation of the buying and selling functions. As long as it is considered necessary that merchandise shall be bought under the direction of the same person who is responsible for its sale, consolidated purchasing for a group of stores is impossible. And without consolidated purchasing, the full efficiency of centralized ownership and management cannot be realized’ (HBR, 1929, 381).

It was certainly not in the interests of buyer-managers to voluntarily divest themselves of

responsibility, even if it was for the ultimate benefit of the retailer (Kaufman, 1932). Such self-

interest was clearly expressed in a New York Times article of 1920 where one buyer noted with

frustration:

‘I am now part and parcel of a collective group of brains and the results I get are not credited to my individual ability. In other words, the system gets the credit and I come in for a very small share of the praise’ (p 37).

Page 14: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

13

Nevertheless, the buyer-manager plan became increasingly questioned by commentators who

argued that a reliance on scientific management of sales trends meant that ‘it is no longer essential

for the buyer to have contact with customers to learn their particular desires’ (Falk, 1930, 270). In

particular, Filene’s Model Stock Plan (1930) provided strategic assistance in merchandising

branches from a central node as it ‘recognizes market variations and consumer preferences by

paying attention to the realities of different markets differentiated by price levels’ (Savitt, 1999,

316). However, what was often lacking was the trust, confidence, and willingness to trial the

mediation between central buying office decisions based on statistics and those on the basis of the

tacit knowledge gained within local markets at traditional department stores:

‘Only in the rare case of a seller’s complete confidence in the judgement of a buying office, located and functioning separately from the several sales units, will the buying have any effectiveness as a selling factor’ (Mazur, 1924, 440).

Efficiency realisation and cost implications

The general failure of the consolidations to form efficient holding companies contributed to relative

cost increases and ultimately efficiency declines that are well represented by the wheel of retailing:

‘With the growth of large department stores there has not come the reduction in operating expense

which is often connected in the minds of most business men with large sales volume’ (Mazur,

1925b, 3). These concerns were increasingly expressed in both marketing articles and data from the

1930s until the onset of significant retail decentralisation in the mid-1950s (see McNair’s series of

papers: 1931a, 1931b, 1931c). The standard record of aggregate department store performance for

the period was the Harvard Bureau of Business Research (Perkins and Freedman, 1999). Based on

this, Figure 4 charts department store expense as a percentage of sales increasing from 29% in the

mid 1920s to around 35% by the mid 1950s. Moreover, the decentralised department store holding

companies that had formed in the 1920s were even less competitive with ‘the total expense rates of

ownership groups…some 20% of sales higher than that of true chains’ (McNair, 1950, 136).

** Figure 4 about here **

Page 15: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

14

In part, the declining efficiency reflected the costs and decreasing desirability of operating in

downtown locations due to congestion and a lack of parking (Burnham, 1938; Tamilia and Reid,

2003) but also – as the wheel of retailing suggests – attempts to “trade up” in order to out-compete

other retailers through the provision of customer services with a resulting unproductive allocation of

manpower (HBR, 1927; Kaufman, 1932). For McNair, writing in 1958, this move upmarket was

partly due to traditional downtown department stores being high-cost and high-margin retail

enterprises that ensured they were disproportionately exposed to discounters, chains and

supermarkets. Service was seen as a differentiator. As Kenneth Collins (1940), a former executive

at Macy’s and Gimbel’s noted, there was a gradual shift in the location of merchandise to positions

behind fixtures and counters, away from the customer where salesmen could cater to the needs of

the clientele. Such strategies significantly added to department store cost structures:

‘As costs of service have risen, the policy of relying on service has itself been brought into question, since competitors, unhampered by the high costs of free delivery, rest rooms, subsidized cafes, credit and the rest, have pushed the price feature in their ‘cash and carry’ policy’ (Lewis, 1945, 91).

In a particularly damning critique, Hypps (1937, 73) bemoaned the retail format’s ‘elephantiasis’

that saw a lack of focus on costs, an emphasis on driving volume and an expansion of merchandise

‘far afield from their original business’.

CHALLENGING DECENTRALISED ORGANISATIONAL STRUCTURES: POST-1945

SUBURBAN BRANCHING

Suburban population and branch growth

Significant shifts in the geography of population and retailing that occurred post-1945 left

traditional department stores particularly vulnerable given the “lock-in” to single downtown units

and associated decentralised organisational structures. The scale of population decentralisation was

spectacular (see Table 4). Between 1950-1960 total US population increased by 18%, yet suburban

population increased 40% (Dawson, 1974). For the first five years of the 1950s, suburban

populations grew more than seven times faster than central cities, as 80% of population growth

occurred in the Metropolitan areas outside of the central city (Tarver, 1957). In addition, by 1970,

Page 16: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

15

80% of US families owned an automobile so were less constrained by the schedules of public

transportation (Dawson, 1974).

** Table 4 about here **

Initially, retail decentralisation consisted of commercial facilities strung haphazardly along major

transport arteries out of a city on ‘suburban freeway corridors’ (Baerwald, 1978). This process

gathered pace throughout the 1950s and 1960s, when shopping centre developers began to realise

the economic potential of the expanding marketplace (Muller, 1981). Appearing in the 1950s,

covered shopping centres possessed many advantages when compared to downtown areas, being

enclosed, away from the street and benefitting from a carefully controlled tenant mix (Palmer, 1953;

Stedman, 1955):

‘Centralized management enabled the shopping center to function as an integrated business rather than as just a concentration of stores. The management selected the tenants… so that the presence of each establishment could reinforce those of the others’ (Longstreth, 1992, 5).

In part facilitated by a broadly laissez-faire view of Government until the 1960s (Dawson and Lord,

1985), Figure 5 shows the remarkable scale and speed of US shopping centre development. The

1950s proved only the start. With time, Gruen’s two level centre model gave way to the larger

regional shopping centre with a vast market catchment (Muller, 1981). Carlson (1991), for example,

estimates 19,000 centres were constructed from 1960 until 1980.

** Figure 5 and Table 5 & 6 about here **

As the suburban environment flourished, the previously seemingly invulnerable downtown areas

suffered from under-investment (Gruen, 1963; Sturdivant, 1968), traffic congestion, a lack of

parking and declining footfall (Gras, 1940; Madison, 1976; see Table 5). While numerous

downtown initiatives were forecast to successfully address these difficulties (New York Times,

1955c; 1956), suburban shopping centres equated a new definition of one-stop-shopping as retailers

exploited economies of agglomeration, becoming ‘the very heart of the retail market’ (Alevizos and

Beckwith, 1954, 111). Less successful department store owners ignored the changes occurring and

Page 17: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

16

incorrectly ‘remained complacent in the knowledge that they were the center of retailing activity’

(Webb-Vignery, 1989, 130).

Department store holding companies ‘initially resisted the move to the suburbs’ until the late 1950s

(Ghosh and McLafferty, 1991, 257), when the organisational structure of the retailers would have to

be revolutionised. The eventual change in store portfolio development is demonstrated in Table 6.

Initially, department stores cautiously avoided each other in the new suburban retailing spaces. Only

when it became apparent that competitors were choosing similar locations, which divided business

in the local market, did department stores consciously decide to congregate together, competing

head-on to anchor shopping centres (Muller, 1981). Progressively some department stores

developed their own shopping centres. Such innovative retailers included J L Hudson’s in Detroit,

Dayton’s in Minneapolis, May’s of St. Louis, Dillard’s in Arkansas, along with Allied Stores and R

H Macy of New York (Carlson, 1991; Rosenberg and Rao, 1989).

When it commenced the pace of change was rapid. For example, in 1955 Allied Stores announced

that it would complete ten shopping centres within three years at a cost of $293m, while the expense

of the seven centres undergoing construction at that time totalled $238m (New York Times, 1955a;

1955b). Frequently multiple centres developed in close proximity. Cohen (1996) notes that over a

period of six months in 1957, Paramus, New Jersey was host to the opening of both R H Macy's

Garden State Plaza and Allied Stores’ Bergen Mall, located three quarters of a mile from each other.

Both retailers had independently recognised the commercial potential of the location. By 1960 ‘each

shopping center had two to three department stores as anchors (distinguishing it from many pre-war

projects built around a single anchor), surrounded by fifty to seventy smaller stores’ (Cohen, 1996,

1053). Alongside the organic growth there was a rush to acquire regional operators that could

further enhance market position. Between 1951 and 1965, the 20 largest department store

companies had acquired 73 companies operating 168 establishments (Bucklin, 1972; see Table 7).

** Table 7 about here **

Page 18: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

17

Tackling organisational change

The time taken for traditional department stores to embrace opportunities offered by suburban

branches can undoubtedly be attributed to the sunk cost in downtown locations, but also in part to

the organisational rigidities attached to the buyer-manager plan. The marketing literature of the

1950s and early 1960s emphasised how the traditional structure became ‘increasingly poorly suited

to the developing multiple-establishment system’ (Bucklin, 1964, 41). Similarly, Oaks (1956, 255)

commented that ‘traditional department store organizational patterns…as the framework for a large-

scale multiunit operation has been seriously questioned’.

While department store branches within holding companies had developed prior to 1945, they were

limited in their coverage, retained proximity to the downtown store, and were most often controlled

and administrated by it (Bucklin, 1964; 1972). This often caused friction between the downtown

buyer and the branch manager (Oaks, 1956) but more importantly, the buyer-managers of the

downtown store became over-burdened as the number of branches increased (Bingham and Yunich,

1965; Noyelle, 1987). In the case of Allied Stores, one former divisional President explained:

‘You have a central department store, and you now have satellites all over. Well alright, so you have one store and one store so the buyer in the main store can go visit the small store – for the first one that’s fine. Then you have two and he can still do that. Then all of a sudden you wake up one day and instead of having two or three, you have ten or fifteen spread not only in your State but in other States. It is a physical impossibility for the buyer who had responsibility for the merchandise selection and the merchandise presentation in the old days to be able to do this’ (Personal Interview).

Traditional department store retailers gradually realised the importance of branches to their business

and the necessary adaptation toward an ‘equal store plan’ that this warranted (New York Times,

1964). However, the time taken to move away from the established model of organisation

‘hampered spatial expansion’ (Laulajainen, 1987, 225). While complete decentralisation of buying

to each unit would be ‘the most suitable with respect to this institution's traditional marketing

strategy’ it was correct that ‘many of the branches are too small and were not planned to be self

sufficient’ (Bucklin, 1964, 44). What was required was a vastly increased degree of centralisation in

the process of buying (Brooks, 1948).

Page 19: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

18

Bingham and Yunich (1965) provide an interesting case study of R H Macy’s with regard to the

lengthy introduction of a revised organisational structure. As Macy’s opened 39 suburban stores

between 1946 and 1964, the failure of the buyer-manager system became evident with buyers

stretched given their responsibility for clone departments in branches as well as goods,

procurement, promotion, sales and staffing at the downtown store. A separation of the buying and

selling functions would be necessary with data informing decision-making rather than a

perpetuation of the ‘longstanding belief that the buyer must have contact with customers and the

selling force in order to learn the wants of his clientele’ (Falk, 1930, 269; see also HBR, 1924).

These changes enforced a critical change in the mindset of department store buying executives:

‘… the downtown store was no longer to be thought of as the “mother hen with her branch-store chickens”. Each store was to be regarded as having equal status, and no one store was in an way to have priority over another’ (Bingham and Yunich, 1965, 138).

This was a challenging process and one that was resisted initially. At Allied Stores it was similarly

noted by one former executive:

‘What evolved became somewhat difficult for the buyers to accept; that the branch store man at the top was responsible and had as much authority as the other four and you, as a buyer, could not go into a branch store and tell them to redo things because that was no longer your responsibility. Your responsibility was the merchandise selection’ (Personal Interview).

An increasingly centralised buying structure emerged within holding companies that relied on

interpreting sales data by a reduced number of buyers but that also had some sensitivity and input

from local branch managers (Hollander, 1986). In the case of Macy’s, such restructuring was

introduced to the Bamberger’s division of the holding company in 1959 and the Macy’s New York

division as late as 1963 (Bingham and Yunich, 1965). By 1964 similar structures were in place at

Burdines (Florida) and Lit Brothers (Philadelphia) (New York Times, 1964). Increasingly across the

nation’s suburbanising department stores, the constraints posed by a dependence on the department-

manager plan were being overcome.

Page 20: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

19

CONCLUSIONS

Our analysis has explored the reasons for traditional department stores’ apparent organisational

inertia and recess toward a period of relative decline which are inherent characteristics of

established models of retail change. As Clifford (1973) notes, threshold periods often consist of

notable instances of environmental change that demand adjustment from the firm. However, we

have found that the traditional department store became “locked in” to a locational and

organisational structure which constrained the necessary adaptation.

Whilst a limited number of successful chains of department stores centralised organisation and

expanded their store networks (contrary to the explanatory thrust of models of retail change),

typically traditional downtown department stores were slow to adapt strategically, geographically

and organisationally. While in simple economic terms downtown stores represented considerable

sunk costs (cf. Clark and Wrigley, 1997), the format’s slow response to competitive and

environmental challenge owed a great deal to ‘the inertia of management arising from long

experience with present methods – from habit and tradition’ (HBR, 1929, 380). As early as the

1930s, McNair (1931c) commented that the challenge was to develop a central organisation that

could be superimposed on the existing administration to produce chains of department stores – this

was not achieved until the mid-1960s. Such rigidity ultimately contributed to a steadily declining

share of General Merchandise, Apparel, Furniture (GAF) sales from the late 1930s (see Figure 6).

** Figure 6 about here **

We find that the wheel of retailing and the retail life-cycle are only partially useful descriptive

representations of retail change that are clearly restricted by their closed system underpinning, their

determinism, and their lack of quantitative validation ‘to historical data in any systematic fashion’

(Savitt, 1989, 336). In a simplistic sense, the retail wheel turned and the retail life cycle progressed

to decline as the department store lost its competitive advantage. However, the causes of these

developments had as much to do with environmental changes in terms of developing multi-unit

business models and a decentralising population geography as the internal inertia of management

within the constituent firms. Consequently, this study has underlined how a wider, open systems

Page 21: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

20

interpretation of retail change is required to fully understand how formats may lose supremacy and

delay necessary strategic change.

So what are the wider implications of this study for retailers wishing to sustain market position in

the face of the shifting environmental and competitive landscape? It is well-established that delving

into retail history can offer relevant insights to contemporary problems (N. Alexander, 1997;

Hollander, 1986). Understanding the nature of decline is all the more relevant amid a background of

an increasing academic focus on retail failure and divestiture (Burt et al., 2003; Etgar and Rachman-

Moore, 2007). In our case, clearly the formation of holding companies in the 1920s served to

protect the largely independent operating nature of traditional department store retailers, arguably

ossifying the established independent structures and mindsets. While McNair’s wheel theory

underlines the importance of human agency and entrepreneurialism in the initial entry of a retailer

to the market (Brown, 1995), so human nature can restrict adaptation.

Necessary change can be blocked by those employees who seek to defend their own personal asset

structures, and as a result, foreclose certain kinds of corporate strategies regardless of whether they

are necessary (Mellahi et al., 2002). In this way, traditional department store companies largely

retained the organising principles of independent downtown stores rather than adopting a

centralised operating structure that would allow active pursuit of the opportunities posed by retail

decentralisation. In a more general sense, Schoenberger (1997, 227) argues that such ‘lock-in’ can

be potentially disastrous for the firm as ‘massive resources can be mobilized in defense of an

historical model of industrial practice whose ineffectiveness in changed circumstances has been so

thoroughly and repeatedly demonstrated’ (see also Jensen, 1993). Similarly other historical studies

have noted how failure is often rooted in the company becoming ‘complacent and committed to

established routines, processes and strategies’ with management failing ‘to assess the potential

impact of these changes and develop appropriate strategies’ (McGovern, 2007, 900). As a result,

maintaining such rigidity in threatening situations can lead to a natural tendency to maintain the

status-quo rather than adapt (Pal et al., 2006). Tedlow (2008) regards such a lack of response as

‘denial’, with management failing to face the facts of the new competitive position.

Page 22: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

21

Inertia from competitive reality underlines the need to maintain a flexible and innovative culture

(O’Cass and Ngo, 2007). Firms should be free to experiment with new business models and

maintain a structure that allows such adaptation while not threatening the legitimacy of the core

business (Kaplan and Norton, 2006). The onus, as Peters and Waterman (2004) note, is to be “tight”

in terms of executing efficiency, but also “loose” and adaptable to new circumstances.

Unsurprisingly the message of avoiding rigidity is a key implication of the retail life-cycle – as

Davidson et al. noted over thirty years ago, ‘a company can never afford to get “locked in” to some

particular approach or philosophy’ (Davidson et al., 1976, 95). The penalty, as the traditional

department store found to its cost, is another turn of the retail wheel or further advance of the retail

life-cycle which allows competitors to exploit inaction and leverage their cost and locational

advantages.

ENDNOTE 1 This article is primarily based on a close analysis of the extensive business, retail and marketing literature of the time. However, it is also part of a wider project which involved over 30 interviews with current and previous retail executives to which the paper refers where they yield relevant information to the historical developments in question.

Page 23: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

22

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to gratefully acknowledge the constructive comments of two anonymous referees as well as Andrew Alexander and Alan Hallsworth on previous drafts of the manuscript. The PhD research upon which this paper is loosely based benefited from the supervision of Neil Wrigley. All errors and omissions are my own.

FIGURES AND TABLES

Figure 1: Two Models of Retail Change

The Retail Life-cycle

The Retail Wheel

Source: Brown (1987)

Figure 2: Generalised Four Divisional Structure for the Larger Downtown Department Store in the

1920s

Merchandising Division Publicity of Sales

Division

Store Management

Division

Controlling Division

(a) Planning of stocks

(b) Control of stocks

(c) Buying

(a) Advertising

(b) Display

(a) Personnel

(b) Selling force

(c) Service

(d) Maintenance

(a) Accounting

(b) Expense control

(c) Statistics

(d) General merchandise

control

Source: Mazur (1924; 1925a; 1927)

Page 24: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

23

Figure 3:

Number of Stores Operated by Five Chains 1913-1922

1,501

1,970

2,803

4,123

4,630

5,266

5,7646,180

6,494

7,670

0

1000

2000

3000

4000

5000

6000

7000

8000

9000

1913 1914 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922

Year

Source: Mann (1923)

Table 1: The Case for Department Store Consolidation

Problems Pre-

Consolidation

� Dependence upon department manager � Lack of intensive specialisation and singleness of effort � Dilution of the value of volume when reduced into

purchasing power of many markets

Proposed Benefits of

Consolidation

� Purchasing power of direct value in buying staples, which

form an important part of the volume of sales � Engineer huge purchases beyond the reach of an individual

unit � Ability to buy suppliers and equipment in large quantities at

appreciable saving � Ability to co-operate on style purchases without destroying

individual local selection � Experiments can be made with the advantages of distributing

risk � European markets can be extensively developed � Opportunities for growth will attract men of the right quality � Opportunity of developing buying service units. Removes

complete dependence on local store personnel

Source: Mazur (1924) and various other trade literature of the 1920s and 1930s

Page 25: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

24

Table 2: Selected Department Store Consolidations and Co-operative groups 1910-1930

Year Nature of Consolidation

Formation of May Department Stores taking in Shoenberg Mercantile Company (St Louis); May Store & Clothing Company (Denver;) May Company (Cleveland)

1910

H.B. Claflin & Co. acquires Tefft-Weller Co.

National Retail Dry Goods Association formed 1911

May acquires William Barr Dry Goods Company

1912 May acquires M O’Neil Company (Akron, Ohio) and Bogg & Buhl (Pittsburgh )

Formation of Associated Dry Goods Corporation – JP Morgan helps reorganise Siegal Coopers and John Claflin’s stores in New York. Other founding stores include: Hahne & Co. (Newark, NJ); Lord & Taylor (New York); William Hengerer Co. (Buffalo, NY); Stewart & Co. (Baltimore, MD)

1916

Retail Research Association (RRA) formed

1918 Associated Merchandising Corporation (AMC) replaces Retail Research Association (RRA) with a wider remit

1921 Jordan Marsh buys A Shuman Company

1922 Formation of National Department Stores

RH Macy acquires Hamburger & Sons; LaSalle & Koch (Toledo); Davison-Paxon Stokes Store (Atlanta)

National Department Stores takes ownership of Frank & Seder stores

1923

Gimbel Brothers purchases Saks

1924 Gimbel Brothers purchase Kaufman and Baer (Pittsburgh)

1925 Jordan Marsh buys CF Hovey Company

1927 May acquires Bernheim-Leader of Baltimore

1928 Hahn Department Store Inc forms – a group of 28 established department stores. This was later reorganised into Allied Stores in 1933

Formation of Federated Department Stores brought together a number of famous family owned stores, including Abraham and Strauss, F & R Lazarus and Filene’s

RH Macy acquires Bambergers (Newark)

Marshall Field acquires Fredrick and Nelson (Seattle & Washington)

1929

Hahn acquires The Bon Marche

1930 Bloomingdale’s joined Federated Department Stores Sources: Bluestone et al. (1981); Bucklin (1972); Doubman and Whitaker (1927); HBR (1926; 1927; 1929); Mazur

(1929); Madison (1976); Nystrom (1919; 1930); Pasdermadjian (1954); Raff (1991)

Table 3: Simplified Spectrum of Centralised Buying in the Retail Sector in the late-1920s

Degree of

centralisation

Centralized –

minimal store

autonomy

Centralized for most

items

Decentralized – group

buying is the

exception

Type of retailer Chain store Chain department/ apparel stores

Conventional Department Stores (inc. majority in “holding groups”)

Examples Woolworths; Kresge, Grant, McCrory

J C Penney; Montgomery Ward, Sears, Roebuck & Company; W. T. Grant Company

Hahn Department Stores; Associated Dry Goods Corp.; May Department Stores; Federated Department Stores

Page 26: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

25

Figure 4:

US Department Store Gross Margin, Total Expense and Net Operating Profit

1920-1960

0.00%

5.00%

10.00%

15.00%

20.00%

25.00%

30.00%

35.00%

40.00%

45.00%

1920

1921

1922

1923

1924

1925

1926

1927

1928

1929

1930

1931

1932

1933

1934

1935

1936

1937

1938

1939

1940

1941

1942

1943

1944

1945

1946

1947

1948

1949

1950

1951

1952

1953

1954

1955

1956

1957

1958

1959

1960

Year

%

-8.0%

-6.0%

-4.0%

-2.0%

0.0%

2.0%

4.0%

6.0%

8.0%

10.0%

12.0%

% NOP

Gross Margin Total Expense* Net Operating Profit

Annual Operating Results of Department Stores: 1920-1960.

All Firms Reporting to the Harvard Bureau of Business Research in the Respective Years (Weighted Common Figures)

* Total expense includes 6% imputed interest on selected assets

Source: McNair and May (1963).

Page 27: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

26

Figure 5:

Initial US Shopping Centre Construction (all types), 1947-1960

0

50

100

150

200

250

1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960

Year

No. of centres

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

million sq ft

No. centres constructed that yr. Total sq. ft. constructed that yr.

Source: Hanchett (1996)

Table 4: Relative Percentages of Urban Population Growth, 1900-1970

Decade Population

growth rate of

cities

Population

growth rate of

suburbs

Percent total

SMSA growth

in cities

Percent total

SMSA growth

in suburbs

Suburban

growth per

100 increase

in central city

1900-1910 37.1 23.6 72.1 27.9 38.7

1910-1920 27.7 20.0 71.6 28.4 39.6

1920-1930 24.3 32.3 59.3 40.7 68.5

1930-1940 5.6 14.6 41.0 59.0 144.0

1940-1950 14.7 35.9 40.7 59.3 145.9

1950-1960 10.7 48.5 23.8 76.2 320.3

1960-1970 5.3 28.2 4.4 95.6 2153.1 Source: Muller, 1981, p 22

Page 28: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

27

Table 5: Retail Change, by City Size Class, 1954-1967

Population of metropolitan area (in thousands)

3,000+ 1,000-3,000 500-1,000 250-500

a) Percentage change in sales: current dollars

CBD 12.1 8.3 -3.7 -6.7

Central city 34.3 26.8 58.4 61.4

Suburbs 132.2 175.0 209.9 193.1

b) Percentage change in numbers of establishments

CBD -26.0 -26.9 -38.2 -37.6

Central city -26.3 -23.7 -8.4 -8.4

Suburbs 29.9 30.3 51.3 48.0 Source: Berry and Kasarda, 1977, p 258.

Table 6: Branch Store Sales as a Percentage of Total Department Store Sales

Year No. of firms No. of stores % of branch store sales to total

sales

1951 104 193 4

1952 107 206 6

1957 104 289 23

1958 104 316 28

1959 99 303 35 N.B. Only department stores with annual sales of $10 million or more were included

Source: Brown and May, 1961, p 2.

Table 7: Suburbanisation Rates of the Major Department Store Corporations

Corporation Date when Sales from Branches Reach 50%

Allied 1970

Associated 1967

Macy’s 1963

Federated 1967

May’s 1962

Dayton Hudson 1969

Carter Hawley Hale 1950s Source: adapted from Laulajainen, 1987, p 235.

Page 29: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

28

Figure 6:

Retail Channels as % of

General Apparel and Furniture (GAF) Sales

0.0%

5.0%

10.0%

15.0%

20.0%

25.0%

30.0%

35.0%

40.0%

1929

1930

1931

1932

1933

1934

1935

1936

1937

1938

1939

1940

1941

1942

1943

1944

1945

1946

1947

1948

1949

1950

1951

1951*

1952

1953

1954

1955

1956

Year

%

Department Stores inc. Mail order Variety Stores Apparel Group Furniture and Appliance Group

GAF includes general merchandise group, apparel group, furniture and appliance group combined. Source: sourced from data located at McNair and May (1963), p 15

Page 30: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

29

REFERENCES

Alevizos, J. and Beckwith, A. (1954) ‘Downtown dilemma’, Harvard Business Review, 32 (1): 109-119. Alexander, A. (1997) ‘Strategy and strategists: evidence from an early retail revolution in Britain’, International Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research, 7 (1): 61-78. Alexander, A. and Phillips, S. (2006) ‘‘Fair play for the small man’: perspectives on the contribution of the independent shopkeeper 1930-c.1945’, Business History, 48 (1): 69-89. Alexander, N. (1997) ‘Objects in the rearview mirror may appear closer than they are’, International Review

of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research, 7 (4): 383–403. Baerwald, T. (1978) ‘The emergence of a new “downtown”’, Geographical Review, 68: 308-318. Benson, S. (1986) Counter Cultures. Saleswomen, Managers, and Customers in American Department

Stores, 1890-1940, University of Illinois Press, Chicago. Berry, B. and Kasarda, J. (1977) Contemporary Urban Ecology, Macmillan, London. Bingham, W. and Yunich, D. (1965) ‘Retail reorganization’, Harvard Business Review, 43 (4): 129-146. Bluestone, B., Hanna, P., Kuhn, S. and Moore, L. (1981) The Retail Revolution. Market Transformation,

Investment and Labor in the Modern Department Store, Auburn House, Boston. Bradshaw, T. (1943) ‘Superior methods created the early chain store’, Bulletin of the Business Historical

Society, 17 (2): 35-43. Brooks, J. (1948) ‘The organization of the selling function in a department store’, Journal of Marketing, 13 (2): 189-194. Brown, M. and May, E. (1961) Operating Results of Multi-Unit Department Stores, Harvard Business School, Division of Research, Harvard, MA. Brown, S. (1987) ‘Institutional change in retailing: a review and synthesis’, European Journal of Marketing, 21 (6): 5-36. Brown, S. (1995) ‘Postmodernism, the wheel of retailing and will to power’, International Review of Retail,

Distribution and Consumer Research, 5 (3): 387-414. Bucklin, L. (1964) ‘Merchandising in department store chains’, California Management Review, 6: 41-46. Bucklin, L. (1972) Competition and Evolution in the Distributive Trades, Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Burnham, E. (1938) ‘The influence of size of business on department store operating results’, Harvard

Business Review, 16: 211-225. Burnham, E. (1940) ‘The department store in its community’, Harvard Business Review, 18: 455-471. Burt, S., Dawson, J. and Sparks, L. (2003) ‘Failure in international retailing: research propositions’, International Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research, 13(4): 355–73. Burton, D. (2005) ‘Marketing theory matters’, British Journal of Management, 16: 5-18. Carlson, H. (1991) ‘The role of the shopping center in US retailing’, International Journal Retail and

Distribution Management, 19 (6): 13-20.

Page 31: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

30

Chandler, A. (1962) Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of American Enterprise, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Chandler, A. (1977) The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Chandler, A. (1990) Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Clapp, E. (1920) ‘A New York experiment in business co-operation’, American Economic Review, 10 (1): 48-58 Clark, F., Onthank, H., Dodd, A., Nystrom, P., Griffen, C., Lyon, L., McGarry, E. (1926) ‘Reducing the costs of marketing’. Papers and Proceedings of the Thirty-Eighth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, American Economic Review, 16 (1): 250-265. Clark, G. and Wrigley, N. (1997) ‘The spatial configuration of the firm and the management of sunk costs’, Economic Geography, 73: 285-304. Clifford, D. (1973) ‘Growth pains of the threshold company’, Harvard Business Review, 51 (5): 143–154. Cohen, L. (1996) ‘From town center to shopping center: the reconfiguration of community marketplaces in postwar America’, American History Review, 101 (4): 1050-1081. Coles, T. (1999) ‘Department store as innovators in retail marketing: some observations on marketing practice and perception in Wilhelmine, Germany’, Journal of Macromarketing, 19 (1): 34-47. Collins, K. (1940) ‘The trend toward self-service’, Journal of Retailing, 16: 98-102. Converse, P (1959) ‘Mediocrity in retailing’, Journal of Marketing, 23 (4): 419-420. Converse, P., Reyer, K., White, W., Warshawer, W. (1929) ‘Marketing’, Papers and Proceedings of the Forty-First Meeting of the American Economic Association, March, 1929, American Economic Review, 19 (1): 37-44. Crask, M. (1980) ‘Department stores vs. discount stores: an academic’s point of view’. In R. Stampfl and E. Hirschman (eds.) Competitive Structure in Retail Markets: The Department Store Perspective, American Marketing Association Proceedings, Chicago, IL., pp.33-42. Davidson, W., Bates, A. and Bass, S. (1976) ‘The retail life cycle’, Harvard Business Review, 54 (6): 89-96. Dawson, J. (1974) ‘The suburbanization of retail activity’. In J. H. Johnson (ed.) Suburban Growth -

Geographical Processes at the Edge of the Western City, John Wiley and Sons, London, 155-175. Dawson, J. and Lord, D. (1985) ‘Federal and State intervention in shopping centre development in the USA’. In Dawson, J. and Lord, D. (eds.) Shopping Centre Development: Policies and Prospects, Croom Helm, Kent, pp 9-37. Doubman, J. and Whitaker, J. (1927) The Organization and Operation of Department Stores, John Wiley & Sons, New York. Emmet, B. and Jeuck, J. (1950) Catalogues and Counters. A History of Sears, Roebuck and Company, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL. Etgar, M. and Rachman-Moore, D. (2007) ‘Determinant factors of failures of international retails in foreign markets’, International Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research, 12(2): 191–219.

Page 32: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

31

Falk, D. (1930) ‘Central buying by department store mergers’, Harvard Business Review, 8 (3); 265-274. Filene, E. (1924) The Menace of the Chains: A Discussion of Chain Store Distribution and its Serious

Menace to the Manufacturer Whose Business Depends on Finding and Keeping a Market for His Product, Mills Advertising Company, Indianapolis. Filene, E. (1927) The Present Status and Future Prospects of Chains of Department Stores. An address delivered before the American Economic Association, Washington DC, December 27, 1927. This paper was republished in American Economic Review, 18 (1): 17-28. Filene, E. (1930) The Model Stock Plan, McGraw-Hill, New York. Freathy, P. and Sparks, L. (1995) ‘Henry Ford and retailing: the Ford commissaries 1919-1942’, Irish

Marketing Review, 8: 42-47. French, M. (2008) ‘Cultures of service: strategies of Scottish grocers, 1915-1965’, International Review of

Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research, 18 (3): 269-282. Gault, E. (1937) ‘Cooperation by business groups’, Journal of Marketing, 1 (4): 396-400. Ghosh, A. and McLafferty, S. (1991) ‘The shopping center: a restructuring of post-war retailing’, Journal of

Retailing, 67 (3): 253-267. Graham, L. (2000) ‘Lilian Gilbreth and the mental revolution at Macy's, 1925-1928’, Journal of

Management History, 6 (7): 285-305. Gras, N. (1940) ‘An old store still young’, Bulletin of the Business Historical Society, 14 (3), 33-40. Griffen, C., Copeland, M., Clark, F., Filene, E., Beckman, T., Tosdal, H. and Schmalz, C. (1928) ‘Marketing’, Papers and Proceedings of the Fortieth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, March 1928, American Economic Review, 18 (1): 17-28. Gruen, V. (1963) ‘Who is to save our cities?’ Harvard Business Review, 41 (3): 107-115. Hanchett, T. (1996) ‘US tax policy and the shopping center boom of the 1950s and 1960s’, American

Historical Review, 101 (4): 1082-1110. Haney, L. (1920) ‘Integration in marketing’, American Economic Review, 10 (3): 528-545. Harvard Business Review [HBR] (1924) ‘Case studies in business: separation of the buying & selling functions in a department store’, Harvard Business Review, 2 (3): 362-367. Harvard Business Review [HBR] (1926) ‘Summaries of business research: department-store consolidations’, Harvard Business Review, 26 (4): 459-470. Harvard Business Review [HBR] (1927) ‘Case studies in business: department store expansion’, Harvard

Business Review, 6 (1): 81-89. Harvard Business Review [HBR] (1929) ‘Case studies in business: department store group buying’, Harvard

Business Review, 7 (3): 375-382. Hess, H. (1924) ‘Selling distribution and its new economies’, Annals of the American Academy of Political

and Social Science, 115: 1-7. Hodge, A. (1925) ‘The use of estimates in control of merchandising operations’, The University Journal of

Business, 3 (4): 397-412.

Page 33: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

32

Hollander, S. (1960) ‘The wheel of retailing’, Journal of Marketing, 24: 37-42. Hollander, S. (1986) ‘A rearview mirror might help us drive forward – a call for more historical studies in retailing’, Journal of Retailing, 62 (1): 7-10. Hollander, S. and Marple, G. (1960) Henry Ford: Inventor of the Supermarket? Marketing and Transportation Paper No. 9, Bureau of Business and Economic Research, Michigan State University. Hower, R. (1943) History of Macy’s of New York 1858-1919. Chapters in the Evolution of the Department

Store, Harvard University Press, Cambridge. Hypps, F. (1937) ‘The department store – a problem of elephantiasis’, Annals of the American Academy of

Political Science, 193: 70-87. Jeacle, I. (2004) ‘Emporium of glamour and sanctum of scientific management – the early twentieth century department store’, Journal of Management History. In Management Decision, 42 (9): 1162-1177. Jensen, M. (1993) ‘The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems’, Journal of Finance, 48 (3): 831-880. Kaplan, R. and Norton, D. (2006) ‘How to implement a new strategy without disrupting your organization’, Harvard Business Review, 84 (3): 100-109. Kaufman, M. (1932) ‘Present day department store organization’, Harvard Business Review, 11: 244-252. Klassen, H. (1992) ‘T.C. Power & Bro.: the rise of a small western department store, 1870-1902’, Business

History Review, 66: 671-722. Laulajainen, R. (1987) Spatial Strategies in Retailing, D. Reidel Publishing, Dordrecht. Laermans, R. (1993) ‘Learning to consume: early department stores and the shaping of modern consumer culture, 1860-1914’, Theory, Culture and Society, 10: 79-102. Lazarus, A. (1926) ‘What can be done for the smart store?’, Dry Goods Economist, June 5, p 82. Leach, W. (1993) Land of Desire: Merchants, Power, and the Rise of a New American Culture, Pantheon Books, New York. Lewis, H. (1930) ‘Distribution’, Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 149 (1): 36-44. Lewis, W. (1945) ‘Competition in retail trade’, Economica, n. s., 12, 202-234. Reprinted in K. A. Tucker and B. S. Yamey (1973) Economics of Retailing, Penguin Education, Middlesex. Longstreth, R. (1992) ‘The neighbourhood shopping center in Washington D.C., 1930-1941’, Journal of the

Society of Architectural Historians, 51 (1): 5-34. Longstreth, R. (1997a) ‘The diffusion of the community shopping center concept during the interwar decades’, Journal of the Society of Architectural Historians, 56 (3): 268-293. Longstreth, R. (1997b) ‘The mixed blessings of success: the Hecht Company and department store branch development after World War II’, Perspectives in Vernacular Architecture, 6: 244-262. Longstreth, R. (1997c). City Center to Regional Mall: Architecture, the Automobile, and Retailing in

California, 1920-1950, MIT Press, Cambridge.

Page 34: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

33

Longstreth, R. (2006) ‘Sears, Roebuck and the remaking of the department store, 1924-1942’, Journal of the

Society of Architectural Historians, 65 (2), 238-279. Longstreth, R. (2007) ‘Bringing “downtown” to the neighbourhoods. Wieboldt’s, Goldblatt’s, and the creation of department store chains in Chicago’, Buildings and Landscapes, 14: 13-49. McGovern, T. (2007) ‘Why do successful companies fail? A case study of the decline of Dunlop’, Business

History, 49 (6): 886-907. McNair, M. (1931a) ‘Department store rentals I, Harvard Business Review, 9 (2): 178-190. McNair, M. (1931b) ‘Department store rentals II, Harvard Business Review, 9 (3): 339-347. McNair, M. (1931c) ‘Trends in large scale retailing, Harvard Business Review, 10 (1): 30-39. McNair, M. (1950) ‘Thinking ahead’, Harvard Business Review, 28 (3): 18-144. McNair, M. (1958) ‘Significant trends and developments in the post war period’. In A. B. Smith (ed.), Competitive Distribution in a Free High Level Economy and Its Implications for the University, University of Pittsburgh Press. McNair, M. and May, E. (1963) The American Department Store 1920-1960. A Performance Analysis Based

on the Harvard Reports. Bureau of Business Research Bulletin No. 166, Harvard University, Boston, MA. Madison, J. (1976) ‘Changing patterns of urban retailing’. In Uselding, Paul (ed.) Business and Economic

History Second Series, Volume Five. Papers Presented at the 22nd

Annual Meeting of the Business History

Conference, 12-13 March 1976, 102-111. Mann, L. (1923) ‘The importance of retail trade in the United States, American Economic Review, 13 (4): 609-617. Martin, B. (1930) ‘The independent, et al., versus the chains’, Harvard Business Review, 9 (1): 47-56. May, E. and McNair, M. (1977) ‘Department stores face stiff challenge in the next decade’, Journal of

Retailing, 53 (3): 47-58. Mazur, P. (1924) ‘Future developments in retailing’, Harvard Business Review, 2, 434-446. Mazur, P. (1925a) ‘The logic of department store organization’, Harvard Business Review, 3: 287-296. Mazur, P. (1925b) ‘Is the cost of distribution too high?, Harvard Business Review,4 (1): 2-16. Mazur, P. (1927) Principles of Organization Applied to Modern Retailing, Harper and Bros., New York. Mazur, P. (1929) Some Problems of Distribution. The Development of Chain Store Merchandising and its

Economic Effects, An Address Delivered before the New York Chapter Robert Morris Associates at a Meeting Held on January 22, 1929, Harvard Club, New York. Robert Morris Associates, Landsdowne, Penna. Mellahi, K., Jackson, P., Sparks, L. (2002) ‘An exploratory study into failure in successful organizations: the case of Marks & Spencer’, British Journal of Management, 13 (1): 15-30. Mullen, W. (1924) ‘Some aspects of chain store development’, Harvard Business Review, 3 (1): 69-80. Muller, P. (1981) Contemporary Suburban America, Prentice-Hall, New Jersey. New York Times (1914) ‘Claflin assists in reorganization’, 29 July, p5.

Page 35: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

34

New York Times (1920) ‘Some drawbacks in group buying’, 8 August, p 37. New York Times (1925) ‘Consolidation of department stores’, 26 July, p E7. New York Times (1927) ‘Changes going on in store methods’, 28 August, p E11. New York Times (1929) ‘Buyers job secure, Dr Nystrom holds’, 13 January, p 51. New York Times (1955a) ’10 shopping centers scheduled for Allied Stores within 3 years’, 13 January, p 37. New York Times (1955b) ‘Chairman of Allied Stores holds big city outlets most profitable’, 10 April, p F1. New York Times (1955c) ‘Merchants lose downtown blues’, 27 February, p F7. New York Times (1956) ‘Sidelights: hope still is held for ‘downtown’’, 25 October, p 48. New York Times (1964) ‘Equal-store plan expected to widen’, 5 June, p 46. Noyelle, T. (1987) Beyond Industrial Dualism. Market and Job Segmentation in the New Economy, Westview Press, Boulder. Nystrom, P. (1919) The Economics of Retailing, Second Edition, Ronald Press Company, New York. Nystrom P. (1930) Chain Stores, Domestic Distribution, Dept Chamber of Commerce of the United States Washington DC. Nystrom, P. (1933) ‘Retailing in retrospect and outlook’, Proceedings of the American Statistical Association, March 1933, Journal of the American Statistical Association (Supplement), 28 (1): 84-89. O’Cass, A. and Ngo, L. (2007) ‘Market orientation versus innovative culture: two routes to superior brand performance’, European Journal of Marketing, 41 (7/8): 868-887. Oaks, C. (1956) ‘Organizing for retail decentralization’, Journal of Marketing, 20 (3): 255-261. Oi, W. (2004) ‘The supermarket: an institutional innovation’, Australian Economic Review, 37 (3): 337-342. Pal, J., Medway, D. and Byrom, J. (2006) ‘Analysing retail failure from an historical perspective: a case study of A Goldberg & Sons Plc’, The Service Industries Journal, 26 (5): 513-535. Palmer, C. (1953) ‘The shopping center goes to the shopper’, New York Times, 29 November, p SM14. Palmer, J. (1929) ‘Economic and social aspects of chain stores’, The Journal of Business of the University of

Chicago, 2 (3): 272-290 Palmer, M. (2005) ‘Crossing threshold periods in the retail firm's life cycle: insights from Wal-Mart international’, European Management Journal, 23 (6): 717- 729. Pasdermadjian, H. (1954) The Department Store: Its Origins, Evolution and Economics, Newman Books, London. Patterson, E. (1915) ‘Co-operation among retail grocers in Philadelphia, American Economic Review, 5 (2): 279-291. Perkins, J. and Freedman, C. (1999) ‘Organisational form and retailing development: the department and the chain store, 1860-1940’, The Service Industries Journal, 19 (4): 123-146.

Page 36: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

35

Peters, T. and Waterman, R. (2004) In Search of Excellence: Lessons from America’s Best Run Companies, Harperbusiness (New York). Phillips, C. (1937) ‘The chain store in the United States and Canada’, American Economic Review, 27 (1): 87-95. Raff, D. (1991) ‘Robert Campeau and Innovation in the Internal and Industrial Organization of Department Store Retailing: Are the ‘80s and ‘90s the ‘20s and ‘30s All Over Again (and Why Does it Matter)?’, Paper presented at the 37th Annual Meeting of the Business Historical Conference, Toronto, March, 1991, Business and Economic History, Second Series, Volume 20, 52-61. Raff, D. (2003) The Wholesale and Retail Trade in the United States, Working Paper No 7 2003, Reginald H. Jones Center, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. Raff, D. and Temin, P. (1997) Sears Roebuck in the Twentieth Century: Competition, Complementarities,

and the Problem of Wasting Assets, National Bureau of Economic Research Historical Paper No. 102, June. Raucher, A. (1991) ‘Dime store chains: the making of organization men, 1880-1940’, Business History

Review, 65 (1): 130-163. Resseguie, H. (1965) ‘Alexander Turney Stewart and the development of the department store 1823-1876’, Business History Review, 39: 301-322. Rosenberg, L. and Rao, C. (1989) ‘William T Dillard: A pioneer merchant in suburban shopping centers’, Essays in Economic and Business History, 7: 230-236. Savitt, R. (1989) ‘Looking back to see ahead: writing the history of American retailing’, Journal of

Retailing, 65 (3): 326-355. Savitt, R. (1999) ‘Innovation in American retailing, 1919-1939: improving inventory management’, The

International Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research, 9 (3): 307-320. Schoenberger, E. (1997) The Cultural Crisis of the Firm, Basil Blackwell, Oxford. Schragger, R. (2005) The Anti-Chain Store Movement, Localist Ideology, and the Remnants of the

Progressive Constitution, 1920-1940, University of Virginia Law School, Public Law and Legal Theory Working Paper Series, Paper 21. Schultz, D. (2002) ‘Another turn of the wheel’, Marketing Management, 11 (2): 8-9. Shaw, G., Alexander, A., Benson, J. and Jones, J. (1998) ‘Structural and spatial trends in British retailing: the importance of firm-level studies’, Business History, 40 (4): 79-93. Stedman, G. (1955) ‘The rise of shopping centers’, Journal of Retailing, 31: 11-26. Sturdivant, F. (1968) ‘Better deal for ghetto shoppers’, Harvard Business Review, 46 (2): 130-139. Tadajewski, M. (2008) ‘Relationship marketing at Wanamaker’s in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries’, Journal of Macromarketing, 28: 169-182. Tamilia, R. and Reid, S. (2003) ‘Origin and evolution of the golden era of the department store, 1846-1930’, Proceedings of the 11th Conference on Historical Analysis and Research in Marketing (CHARM): The

Romance of Marketing History, pp89-100. Tarver, J. (1957) ‘Suburbanization of retail trade in the standard metropolitan areas in the US, 1948-1954’, American Sociological Review, 22: 427-453.

Page 37: Organisational Rigidities and Marketing Theory: Examining the US …epubs.surrey.ac.uk/209756/1/Organisational Rigidities and... · 2013. 9. 23. · 02/04/2009 09:52 Organisational

36

Tedlow, R. (1996) New and Improved: The Story of Mass Marketing in America, Harvard Business School Press, Cambridge MA. Tedlow, R. (2008) ‘Leaders in denial’, Harvard Business Review, 86 (7/8): 18-19. Thompson, C. (1915) ‘Scientific management in practice’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 29 (2): 262-307. Tolman, M. (1921) Positions of Responsibility in Department Stores and other Retail Selling Organizations, The Bureau Of Vocational Information, New York City and Division of Education, Harvard University, Cambridge MA. Tonning, W. (1955) ‘Department stores down state Illinois, 1889-1943’, Business History Review, 29 (4): 335-349. Walker, A. (1913) ‘Scientific management applied to commercial enterprises, The Journal of Political

Economy, 21 (5): 388-399. Walsh, E. and Jeacle, I. (2003) ‘The taming of the buyer: the retail inventory method and the early twentieth century department store’ Accounting, Organizations and Society, 28: 773-791. Webb-Vignery, J. (1989) Jacome’s Department Store: Business and Culture in Tucson, Arizona, 1896-1980, Garland Studies in Entrepreneurship, Garland Publishing, New York. Weld, L. D. (1923) ‘Do principles of large scale production apply to merchandising?’ American Economic

Review, 13 (1): 185-197. Wendt, L. and Kogan, H. (1952) Give the Lady What She Wants! The Story of Marshall Field & Company, South Bend, Indiana. Wood, S. (2002) ‘The limits to portfolio restructuring: lessons from regional consolidation in the US department store industry’, Regional Studies, 36 (5): 515-529.