Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    1/27

    Pay-What-You-Want Pricing:

    Can It Be Profitable?

    Yong Chao, Jose Fernandez, and Babu Nahata

    April, 2014

    Abstract

    Using a game theoretic framework, we show that not only can pay-what-

    you-want pricing generate positive profits, but it can also be more profitable

    than charging a fixed price to all consumers. Further, whenever it is more

    profitable, it is also Pareto-improving. We derive conditions in terms of two

    cost parameters, namely the marginal cost parameter for the seller, and the

    social-preference parameter of a consumer to incorporate behavioral consid-

    erations for paying too little compared to her reference price.

     JEL codes:  C70, D03, D21, D42

    1 Introduction

    Several field experiments using pay-what-you-want (PWYW) pricing, for exam-

    ple, by musicians (Radiohead band), coffee houses (Mosaic Coffee House in Seat-

    tle, Washington ), restaurants (Just around the Corner in London and Mon Cheri in

    Fukuoka, Japan), a movie theatre (near Frankfurt Germany (Kim et al.[6]), and an

    on-line magazine (Paste), have attracted attention in both economics and market-

    ing literature. Under PWYW pricing, the seller does not set the price. Consumers

    may choose any price to pay including zero.1 Those who practice this form of 

    pricing may not receive enough revenue to cover their costs. This problem isDepartment of Economics, College of Business, University of Louisville.1The significant difference between PWYW and name-your-own-price strategy is that, unlike

    under PWYW pricing, in the name-your-own-price strategy, the seller can always refuse a buyer’s

    final offer even when the buyer is willing to pay the required minimum price.

    1

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    2/27

    exacerbated when either a large fraction of consumers free ride or the voluntary

    payments they receive are below the marginal cost of production, thus potentiallymaking it an unprofitable pricing practice compared to charging a fixed price.

    This paper considers if PWYW pricing can generate positive profits and also

    earn profits in excess of those earned by using a fixed price. The paper makes the

    following contributions to the existing literature. First, we endogenize the choice

    of pricing strategies—PWYW price vs. fixed price. Thus rather than solely focus-

    ing on the profitability of PWYW pricing, we evaluate its profitability vis-a-vis

    uniform pricing. To the best of our knowledge this has not been done so far the-

    oretically. Second, we specify consumer utility to account for both economic and

    behavioral considerations. We show that when marginal cost is low and behav-

    ioral considerations are strong, then PWYW pricing can exploit the deadweight

    loss present under the uniform price to gain additional profit at the cost of servingsome free riders. Therefore, PWYW pricing can be more profitable than charging

    a fixed price especially when the marginal cost is low and the deadweight loss is

    high. Third, we demonstrate PWYW pricing is more attractive when the cost of 

    price setting is considerable or the market size is small.

    The empirical evidence examining PWYW pricing comes mainly from field

    experiments. Kim, Natter and Spann (2009)[6] conducted field experiments in a

    medium-sized town near Frankfurt, Germany, in which three firms used PWYW

    pricing. All three sellers (a lunch buffet in a middle-priced restaurant, a deli-

    catessen serving twelve different types of hot beverages and a multiplex cinema

    consisting of eight different movie theaters) reported receiving payments from

    all customers (no free riders). To explain such payment patterns, the authors posit

    that behavioral factors play an important role and how consumers react to a pricing

    practice may not be solely rational. Based on the experimental data they conclude

    that when buyers and sellers interact face-to-face, buyers will not free ride and

    will pay a positive price. Unlike the online offering by Radiohead, in all their ex-

    periments the interactions were face-to-face.2 Behavioral considerations such as

    2The British band  Radiohead   offered their album   In Rainbows  to consumers online, where

    the interaction was  anonymous. The PWYW experiment resulted in both paying customers (38

    percent worldwide and 40 percent in the U.S.  willingly paid) and free riders, who were as prevalent

    in the U.S. as in the rest of the world. From October 10~29, 2007, 1.2 million people worldwide

    downloaded the album from Radiohead ’s Website. The average paying consumer in the US paidconsiderably more, $8.05 compared to $4.64, than her international counterpart. The band did

    require a 45 pence minimum payment as a transaction fee. See http://www.inrainbows.com; and

    http://comscore.com/press/release.asp?press=1883; and the Wall Street Journal, October 3, 2007,

    p.C14.

    2

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    3/27

    fairness, altruism, satisfaction and loyalty affect a consumer’s reference price and

    that in turn influences the payment made by the consumer. These concerns be-come more significant when the interaction is face-to-face such that the consumer

    will not free ride.3

    Gneezy et al. (2012)[3] introduce two additional factors that also play an im-

    portant role in assessing the viability of PWYW pricing. Based on the results from

    three field experiments, they show that consumers would avoid free riding under

    PWYW pricing, in part, because consumers want to maintain their self-image of 

    being fair. Since both free riding and not paying a “fair” price create a negative

    self-image, to protect self-image, buyers rather prefer to forego purchasing from

    the firm using PWYW pricing in favor of the firm who uses a declared fixed-price.

    This no-purchase outside option, although helping to maintain the self-image,

    also results in fewer purchases under PWYW pricing. The authors conclude that“...choosing whether to purchase a product or service, and how much to pay for

    it, has a self signaling value. People feel bad when violating the norm and thus

    would avoid the situation by choosing not to buy the product or service. If they do

    choose to purchase the product or service, they often choose to pay a “fair” price

    that does not have a negative effect on their self-image (p.7240).” Using online

    laboratory experiments, Schmidt, Spann and Zeithammer (2014)[11] also reach

    the same conclusion when firms compete and consumers have an outside option.

    Machado and Sinha (2013)[8] specify a utility function to explicitly control

    for three behavioral factors, namely fairness, reciprocity and consumers’ bias to-

    ward a fixed-price strategy. Employing both laboratory and field experiments they

    explore when these three behavioral factors could make PWYW a viable pric-

    ing option. The utility function under PWYW pricing includes disutility from not

    paying a “fair” price, and a positive utility because of reciprocity consideration. In

    the absence of any posted or anchor price, a consumer’s internal reference price

    plays the main role in determining the “fair” price. They conclude that PWYW

    pricing has the potential to expand the market size because all buyers participate

    and thus it could serve as an effective mechanism to price discriminate. In their

    model specification, not only could PWYW pricing increase the market size, but

    because of reciprocity concerns it may lead to an unusual result of consumers

    paying more than their reference prices.

    Regner and Barria (2009)[10] analyze consumers’ payment patterns at the on-line music label Magnatune, where consumers can pay what they wish within a

    3Kim et al. (2009)[6] provide an extensive literature review that provides reasons why con-

    sumers might pay when they have an option not to pay.

    3

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    4/27

    specified  price range of $5-$18. They find that, on average, customers paid $8.20,

    far more than the suggested minimum price of $5, and even higher than the rec-ommended price of $8. The authors conclude that PWYW pricing  could  serve as

    a viable alternate pricing option because such open contracts encourage customers

    to make voluntary payments. They argue that voluntary payments can be due to

    reciprocity, “warm glow”—acts of kindness, or experiencing a large enough guilt

    from not paying a “fair” price. Repeated interactions or loyalty is another plausi-

    ble explanation. Since the focus of their analysis is mainly on payment patterns

    of consumers, no definitive conclusions can be drawn about the profitability of 

    PWYW pricing.

    Regner (2010)[9] uses the Magnatune data to find which behavioral determi-

    nants have the strongest affect on consumer payments. Consumers are categorized

    into three groups: Low payers who paid near the minimum price of $5 (15%), av-erage payers who paid near the recommended price of $8 (60%), and generous

    payers who paid substantially more than the recommended price (25%). The au-

    thor identifies reciprocity and fairness/guilt considerations as the primary drivers

    for generous payments and social norms as the driver for payments made around

    the recommended price.

    The extensive literature in behavioral economics, marketing and psychology

    studying PWYW pricing strongly suggests that many behavioral considerations

    play a significant role. For the profitability of PWYW pricing, it may not be

    possible to identify the single most significant determinant of both how much

    consumers would like to pay and how the profits are affected. Experimental stud-

    ies also show that, in spite of the option to free ride, not  all  consumers free ride.

    However, in the case of Radiohead’s online experiment about 68 percent did not

    pay at all. We argue that regardless of which behavioral factor is a dominant fac-

    tor in deciding whether to pay or not and how much to pay, a theoretical analysis

    should not, a priori, rule out free riding by focussing on specific behavioral fac-

    tors. Further, one cannot conclude that positive revenue under PWYW pricing

    implies higher profits compared to charging a fixed price without considering the

    magnitude of marginal cost and what fraction of buyers paid above or below the

    marginal cost. Even when free riding is ruled out and one focuses primarily on

    the payments, marginal cost still remains a relevant factor.

    The main motivation for the paper is to provide a plausible theoretical expla-nation incorporating both the economic and the behavioral considerations to two

    important questions. Not ruling out free-riding a priori based on some specific

    behavioral factors, when would some consumers pay and some free ride? Un-

    der what conditions could PWYW pricing generate higher profits than charging a

    4

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    5/27

    fixed price to all consumers? We provide answers to both these questions based

    on two parameters, namely the marginal cost of production for the seller and a“catch-all” social-preference parameter that serves as a proxy for all relevant be-

    havioral factors.

    We use a stylized game theoretical model based on profit maximization to en-

    dogenize the choice of pricing strategies between PWYW pricing and uniform

    pricing. Our basic framework relies upon the growing body of literature related to

    social preferences in experimental and behavioral economics. Fair-minded con-

    sumers are modeled to maximize   net  utility, where the utility function is com-

    prised of two parts: (1) consumers wish to maximize consumer surplus (defined

    as the difference between consumers’ private values for the good and the amount

    paid); and (2) consumers also wish to minimize transaction utility. Transaction

    utility incorporates the effects of social preferences that are typically ignored instandard models of utility maximization but quite relevant under PWYW pric-

    ing. For tractability reasons, it is impossible to explicitly incorporate every single

    social-preference factor, (e.g., fairness, warm glow, self-image, reciprocity etc.),

    into a consumer’s utility function. Such a specification will make a closed form

    solution for the demand functions highly complex, perhaps even impossible, as

    shown in Machado and Sinha (2013)[8]. However, by including a single “catch-

    all” social-preference parameter for the consumer that serves as a proxy for the

    behavioral factors mentioned above we get additional insight about the profitabil-

    ity of PWYW pricing that cannot be captured fully by experimental studies.

    Based on social preferences, a consumer experiences disutility whenever the

    voluntary payment made for the good is below some asked (fixed) reference price.

    The social-preference parameter measures the relative importance of the transac-

    tion utility within the net utility. Our tractable model is based on a profit maxi-

    mization assumption and states conditions based on two parameters—–a social-

    preference parameter encompassing the behavioral considerations for the buyers

    and a cost parameter for the seller. We extend the results for the case when the

    market size is small and price-setting is costly. Finally we allow random reference

    prices for the consumers.

    Lemma 1  states the necessary conditions for making voluntary payments by

    consumers even in the presence of a free ride option. Proposition 1 states the

    sufficient and necessary conditions for PWYW pricing to generate  positive prof-its when social preference considerations are included. Proposition 2 states the

    sufficient and necessary conditions for PWYW pricing to generate  higher  profits

    compared to charging a fixed price. Proposition 3 states that when PWYW pricing

    is more profitable, it is also Pareto improving compared to charging a fixed price.

    5

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    6/27

    Qualitatively speaking, we find that in our framework, PWYW pricing could

    generate higher profits than charging a fixed price when marginal cost is suffi-ciently low and social preference considerations are strong enough. The intuition

    is that when the social preference considerations become significant, the volun-

    tary payments from consumers who were excluded from the market under the

    fixed price could generate sufficient revenue to compensate for both the free rid-

    ers and the additional production cost. This increased revenue and low marginal

    cost could result in higher profits.

    The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the setting

    of the model. Section 3 describes consumer and firm behavior when a fixed price

    is used. Section 4 presents the main results of the paper. Section 5 offers two

    extensions to the model. In the first extension, we incorporate potential cost saving

    associated with price setting a price and allow for the market size to affect theoutcome. In the second extension, we relax the assumption of a constant anchor

    price for all consumers and show how profits under PWYW pricing are affected

    by random anchor/reference prices. Section 6 discusses the results and limitations

    with some recommendations for the direction of future research.

    2 Model Setting

    We consider a monopolist serving a continuum of heterogenous consumers

    with a constant marginal cost of production c, 0

      c <  1, who chooses between

    charging the uniform price or letting consumers choose what they want to pay.Each consumer demands a single unit of the good. Consumers’ valuations or

    willingness-to-pay (WTP) v  are assumed to be distributed uniformly with a sup-port [0; 1]. Consumers make purchasing decisions independently. A consumer’sutility function under the uniform price (UP) is given as

    U u = v  pu

    when she pays pu, and 0 otherwise.Under PWYW pricing, following Thaler (2004)[13], consumers are assumed

    to be motivated by two considerations: (1) to maximize the consumption utility;

    and (2) to minimize the transaction utility which is a function of social prefer-ences. As observed in experiments using this form of pricing, consumers get

    disutility based on social preferences when they do not pay at all or pay too little

    when choosing a payment. If consumers derive disutility when their payments are

    lower than some reference price, then this disutility can be captured by including a

    6

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    7/27

    social-preference parameter into the traditional utility maximization problem. We

    follow Fehr and Schmidt (1999)[2] and Thaler (1985)[12] to incorporate thesebehavioral considerations into the consumer’s utility function as follows.4

    U  pwyw = v  p (R  p)2. (1)

    The first term in (1), v  p, is the consumption utility, which is the same as underthe uniform price. The second term, (R  p)2, represents the transaction utilitythat internalizes the disutility from not paying a “fair” price and also highlights the

    importance of some reference price  R.5 The net utility is the difference betweenthe positive consumption utility and the disutility from paying a price below the

    reference price.

    Let  p   be the voluntary payment by a consumer, and  R   the reference price.The social-preference parameter    captures the degree of disutility experiencedby the consumer when her voluntary payment  p  is below her reference price  R.For simplicity, we assume that    is identical for all consumers and has a support 2 [0; 1). The social-preference parameter encompasses all the potential behav-ioral considerations. The social-preference parameter is increasing with respect to

    fairness, self-image, reciprocity, and warm glow as each of these behavioral con-

    siderations increases the importance of the transactional utility. Note, a consumer

    can always avoid disutility from these social preferences by paying their reference

    price.

    Consumers may construct reference prices from a variety of sources (i.e., ad-

    vertisements, the price of close substitutes, from private perception of seller’scost, from social preferences, from social norms, etc.). When consumers decide

    how much to pay, some external anchor price denoted as  pa matters. The refer-ence price cannot exceed a consumer’s reservation price—–the most a consumer

    is willing to pay for the good. Thus, the reference price is:

    R = minfv; pag.

    To illustrate why  R   is the minimum of  v   and  pa consider an example. A con-sumer may value Radiohead ’s newest music CD at $20, but the same CD may be

    purchased at a market price of $10. In this case, although her valuation v  is $20,

    4In a recent paper based on a field experiment, Just and Wansnik (2011)[5] use a similar ap-

    proach to analyze how variations in flat-fee charges affect consumers’ behavior at an all-you-can-

    eat pizza lunch buffet.5In general, the transaction utility function can be any montonic concave function. We choose

    the quadratic loss function for simplicity and to ensure a unique solution.

    7

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    8/27

    her reference price is more likely to be $10, and not $20. On the other hand, a

    different consumer’s valuation v  for the CD is $8, and the anchor price  pa

    equalsthe market price of $10. Thus, she is likely to have a reference price of $8 rather

    than $10 and will not buy the good at $10.

    The game is played in two stages. In the first stage, the firm chooses a pricing

    strategy: the uniform price or PWYW pricing. In the second stage, consumers

    observe the pricing strategy and choose to participate and make payments cor-

    respondingly. We seek a subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium, which is found by

    using backward induction. The firm solves the consumer’s problem under both

    pricing strategies and then chooses the pricing strategy that yields the highest

    profits.

    3 Benchmark: Uniform Pricing

    The monopolist chooses a price,  p, that maximizes profit. Only consumerswith v  p  buy the good. So the monopolist’s profit function,  u, is

    u = max p

    ( p c) (1  p). (2)

    The expressions for the profit-maximizing uniform equilibrium price pu, quantityq , and profits are standard and are given below.

     pu = 1 + c2

      ; q  =  1 c2

      ;   and u = 1 c2

    2 . (3)It is important to note the presence of consumers who have a positive value

    for the good v > 0, but are locked out of the market because v < pu. As we willsee, the voluntary payment pattern of these locked out consumers under PWYW

    pricing is critical for the viability of PWYW pricing.

    4 PWYW Pricing

    In this section, we first analyze consumers’ behavior under PWYW pricing,and then derive the PWYW firm’s profit function to derive the conditions under

    which PWYW pricing yields a positive profit.

    8

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    9/27

    4.1 Consumer Behavior under PWYW

    Under PWYW pricing, consumers independently choose their voluntary pay-ment p including zero to maximize their utility,

    U  pwyw = v  p (R  p)2:

    For simplicity, we assume the optimal uniform monopoly price represents the

    anchor price. That is, pa = pu. As a result,

    R = minfv;  1 + c2

      g;

    as shown in Figure 1 below.

    A type-v consumer’s marginal utility when she chooses to pay p is

    @U 

    @p  = 1 + 2 (R  p)

    = 2 (R   12

      p):

    Note that the upper bound of  R  is   1+c2

      . When   1+c2    1

    2, or     1

    1+c, then for any

     p    0  we have  R    12

       p   p    0. That is, for any positive payment, themarginal utility is non-positive and hence no one would pay anything in this case.

    By contrast, when   12

      <   1+c2

      , or   11+c

     < , consumers are segmented into three

    groups. For consumers with v    12

    , R  =  v  because   12

      <   1+c2

      , thereby for any

     p   0,  R    12

      p  =  v    12

       p   p   0. Thus, these consumers will pay0. The consumers with   1

    2  < v    1+c

    2  , R  =  v and will make a positive payment

     p =  v    12

     so that   @U @p

      = 0. For those with   1+c2

      < v   1, R  =   1+c2

      , and they will

    pay p =   1+c2    1

    2.

    The market segmentations for the above two cases are shown in Figure 1 be-

    low.

    9

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    10/27

    Figure 1: Reference Point and Market Segmentations

    Lemma 1 below states the conditions for consumers’ voluntary payments un-

    der PWYW pricing.

    Lemma 1 (Consumers’ Payments under PWYW)   Under PWYW pricing no one

     pays (i) when      11+c

     , and (ii) when   11+c

     <  , a type-v  consumer’s payment ruleis

     p(v) =8   0, a consumer is never willing to make a voluntary payment inexcess of the market price or his own WTP. In particular, whenever the consumer

    pays, she will downwardly adjust her payment from her reference price R  by anamount equal to   1

    2. As such,   1

    2 turns out to be the cutoff value of consumer’s val-

    uation below which the consumer will be a free rider. This condition highlights

    that even when social preferences are taken into account, there still exists an in-

    centive to free ride. But as the parameter   increases, the number of free riders

    will decrease. A firm, however, can lower the number of free riders by requiringa minimum payment, for example the $5 minimum set by Magnatune.6

    6As noted by Regner and Barria (2009)[10], a price floor or a minimum payment requirement,

    cannot rule out the free-rider problem entirely in the electronic music market due to widespread

    availability in P2P network.

    10

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    11/27

    The following corollary that follows from the Lemma 1 relates to how v and 

    affect p(v).Corollary 1   A consumer’s voluntary payment  p(v)  weakly increases with  v   aswell as the social-preference parameter  .

    An increase in the social-parameter  , a consumer’s voluntary payment ap-proaches her reference price and thus an increase in    encourages consumers topay more. Voluntary payments increase with private values for consumers who

    were previously excluded from the market under the uniform price. However,

    high-value consumers,   1+c2

      < v    1, experience no change because their refer-ence price does not increase with their private values.

    4.2 PWYW Firm’s Profit

    Lemma 1 states that when      11+c

    , the PWYW firm receives nothing from

    any consumer but must incur the total cost  c  to serve the whole market causingprofit to be equal to c. When   1

    1+c  < , the PWYW firm still serves the whole

    market, but receives voluntary payments from some consumers. Based on Lemma

    1, the PWYW firm’s profit will be

     pwyw = c +Z   1+c

    2

    1

    2

    v   1

    2

    dv +

    1 + c

    2    1

    2

    (1  1 + c

    2  )   (4)

    = 18  (3 6c c2 + 1 42   ).The PWYW firm’s profit function consists of three parts. The first term in (4)

    represents the total cost of serving the entire market as no consumer can be turned

    away. The second term accounts for the revenue obtained from some of those

    consumers who would not have been served under the uniform price, i.e.,  v 1+c2

      = pu. Only consumers with intrinsic valuations in excess of   12

     will contribute

    as the rest have an incentive to free ride. The last term is the revenue obtained

    from consumers who would have participated in the market under the uniform

    price, v >   1+c2

      = pu. These consumers have different intrinsic valuations for thegood, but each makes the same payment, because their reference price is identical,

    i.e., R  =   1+c2

      . The following lemma summarizes the PWYW firm’s profit.

    Lemma 2 (PWYW Firm’s Profit)  Under PWYW, the firm’s profits

    (i) when     11+c

     ,  pwyw = c.(ii) when   1

    1+c <  ,  pwyw is given by (4).

    11

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    12/27

    An immediate result following from the lemma is that the PWYW firm’s profit

    strictly decreases with the marginal cost c, but increases with the parameter .

    Corollary 2   When     11+c

      then   @pwyw

    @c   0.

    Although an increase in marginal cost also increases the average reference

    price, profits still decrease because the deadweight loss from the cost overrun

    increases even more. PWYW pricing cannot exclude anyone from the market.

    Therefore, the firm must pay the entire amount of the total cost  c. Secondly, whenthe social-preference parameter is sufficiently high, an increase in this parameter

    increases profits because the voluntary payments are weakly increasing in    as

    indicated in Corollary 1.Proposition 1 states the sufficient and necessary conditions when the PWYW

    firm would earn a strictly positive profit.

    Proposition 1 (When  pwyw > 0)   The profits under PWYW pricing is positive pwyw > 0  if and only if 

    0  c  2 +

    p c2 + 6c + 1

    3 6c c2   :   (R2)

    The first condition places an upper bound on the marginal cost. Since underPWYW pricing, the firm cannot exclude any consumers, the monopolist serves the

    entire market and incurs the total cost c. This implies that even if the monopolistis capable of capturing the entire area under the demand curve (consumers’ total

    willingness to pay), any value of the marginal cost greater than  c >   1=2  wouldstill lead to negative profits.7 Further, the presence of free riders implies that the

    marginal cost is strictly bounded below 1=2. To be more precise, the exact cut-off in (R1) accounts for the presence of free riders as well as the difference between

    the voluntary payments made by consumers and the reference price described in

    Lemma 1.  The condition (R2) places a lower bound on the parameter  . Recall

    from Lemma 1 that, all consumers will free ride when   1=(1 + c). So PWYWpricing may not generate positive profit even when marginal cost is equal to zeroif social preference considerations are not very important. In the absence of a

    7Note that the inverse demand curve in our model is  p   = 1   q   following from uniformdistribution on [0; 1]. The total area under the demand curve is 1=2.

    12

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    13/27

    strong, consumers have an incentive to free ride, resulting in zero profits. The two

    conditions (R1) and (R2) are shown in Figure 3 below.

    Figure 2: When  pwyw > 0

    4.3 Profits Comparison

    In this section, by comparing the monopolist’s profits under the uniform priceand PWYW pricing, we derive the sufficient and necessary conditions for PWYW

    pricing to be more profitable than the uniform price in the equilibrium.

    For any 0  c  0  , it followsthat u >  pwyw for the case when      1

    1+c. But, when   1

    1+c  < ,  pwyw > u is

    equivalent to the following inequality

    1

    8  (3 6c c2 + 1 4

    2  ) >

    1 c

    2

    2;

    which can be reduced to

    2 p 3c2 + 2c + 3 >  1

    :   (5)

    Since  > 0, for (5) to hold, we need:

    2 p 

    3c2 + 2c + 3 >  0;   (6)

    13

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    14/27

    and

    >

      1

    2 p 3c2 + 2c + 3 :   (C1)Because 0  c  1 =  1

    1 + c jc=0 :

    Thus, we have1

    2 p 3c2 + 2c + 3 >  1

    1 + c;

    for all 0  c <   13

    . This implies  >   11+c

     given (C1) and (C2) hold.

    The following proposition summarizes the sufficient and the necessary condi-

    tions for PWYW to be more profitable than the uniform price.

    Proposition 2 (When  pwyw > u)  Compared to the uniform price, profits under PWYW pricing will be higher   pwyw > u if and only if (C1) and (C2) hold.

    (C2) states that for PWYW pricing to be more profitable than the uniformprice, the marginal cost c  cannot be too high for two reasons. First, Corollary 1shows that when c is sufficiently large,  pwyw u.The exact upper bound of  c  =   1

    3 is specific to the linear demand because of 

    the  normalized  choke-price equal to one in our model. In general, the intuition

    behind an upper bound on the marginal cost is simple. Under the uniform price,

    the lower the marginal cost, the higher is the deadweight loss. The deadweight

    loss represents the potential lost profit that cannot be realized by charging theuniform price. The maximum size of the deadweight loss is reached when the

    8 @pwyw

    @c  = 3+c

    4    14

    .

    14

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    15/27

    marginal cost is zero. The deadweight loss can be viewed as the potential addi-

    tional profit that can be captured using PWYW pricing. However, the magnitudeof the deadweight loss under uniform pricing decreases as marginal cost increases.

    Hence, the potential gains from using PWYW pricing decrease as marginal cost

    increases. Further, the cost associated with free riding increases with marginal

    cost. This trade-off places an upper bound on the marginal cost. PWYW pric-

    ing should only be adopted when the marginal cost is relatively low compared to

    the choke price (demand price intercept). In other words, PWYW pricing is only

    suitable for high mark-up items.

    (C1) demonstrates that there is a lower bound of    for  pwyw > u. (C1) indi-cates that the value of    must increase with the marginal cost for PWYW pricingto be more profitable than the uniform price, as the term   1

    2

    p 3c2+2c+3

     is increasing

    in c. The simple intuition is that with a higher marginal cost, the marginal profitloss from free riders must increase and consequently, not only is a higher value

    of    required for more consumers to contribute, but also to contribute more whenthey pay. In particular, a higher    has two effects. First, it decreases the num-ber of free riders. Recall that consumers with private values v    1

    2 always free

    ride. The costs that these free riders impose is equal to   c2

    . Therefore, an increase

    in the parameter    can reduce the number of free riders to offset the increase inthe marginal cost. Second, recall from Lemma 1  that, for those who are paying

    under PWYW pricing, their voluntary payment p(v) is adjusted downward by theamount   1

    2  from their reference point  R. Thus, a higher   will make consumers’

    payments closer to their reference point, thus compensating for the increase in

    marginal cost.

    Proposition 2  implies that for a fixed  , PWYW pricing is less likely to beobserved for products with a high marginal cost of production. The two conditions

    (C1) and (C2) are shown in Figure 3 below.

    15

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    16/27

    Figure 3: When  pwyw > u

    From the bounds on    placed by conditions (C1) and (C2), it is easy to ver-ify that as the marginal cost approaches   1

    3, the minimum level of    necessary for

    PWYW pricing to be more profitable approaches infinity (as c !   13

    ,   12

    p 3c2+2c+3

     !

    1). The bound on

      will be satisfied only when

     c <

      1

    3

    .

    Behavioral considerations could potentially create an opportunity to eliminate

    the deadweight loss that can be shared between the consumers and the seller. The

    elimination of the deadweight loss increases the consumer surplus for the existing

    consumers and creates a surplus for those consumers who were previously ex-

    cluded from the market. These new entrants gain surplus by paying a price lower

    than their willingness to pay. The seller gains additional profits from payments

    made in excess of the marginal cost. Compared to the uniform price, the seller’s

    profit will be higher under PWYW pricing if the profit earned from the elimina-

    tion of the deadweight loss is large enough to off-set the revenue lost from the

    existing consumers and the additional cost in production (see Figure 4). That is

    why we never see luxury cars or private jets sold using PWYW pricing. Mostproducts under PWYW pricing—–hot beverages, menu items in a delicatessen

    and music CDs, used in the field experiments have a low marginal cost compared

    to the consumers’ willingness to pay, so the condition  c <   13

     is most likely to be

    satisfied.

    16

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    17/27

    Figure 4 illustrates the results of this section. Since consumers’ WTPs are

    drawn from a uniform distribution on   [0; 1], the monopolist faces a downwardsloping demand curve q  = 1 p, shown by the blue solid line. The payment sched-ule of consumers under PWYW pricing is indicated by the red solid line. Profit

    under the uniform price is the sum of Area I and Area II. Profit under PWYW

    pricing is Area II + Area III - Area IV. Therefore, the difference in profits is Area

    III - Area I - Area IV. If the additional profit gained from the new entrants (Area

    III) is greater than the revenue lost from the existing consumers (Area I) and the

    associated cost due to market extension (Area IV), then PWYW pricing is more

    profitable than the uniform price. It is worth noting that (i) as guilt increases (a

    higher ), Areas I and IV decrease but Area III increases allowing the firm to cap-ture more of the deadweight loss; (ii) as marginal cost approaches zero,  c

     ! 0,

    there is no deadweight loss in equilibrium. This happens without incurring anycost for expanding the market (Area IV disappears).

    Figure 4: If Area III - Area I - Area IV >0, then  pwyw > u.

    4.4 Welfare Comparison

    The proposition below follows immediately from the discussion above.

    17

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    18/27

    Proposition 3 (Pareto Improvement)   Whenever PWYW pricing is more profitable

    compared to the uniform price, it is also Pareto-improving.

    The simple intuition for the above proposition is as follows. The consumers

    who previously bought at the uniform price can still pay the same price, but they

    choose to pay a lower price so they must be better off. The consumers who were

    previously excluded under the uniform price are better off because they get some

    surplus previously not enjoyed. The seller’s profits are also higher. Since no one

    is worse off, it is Pareto-improving.

    5 Extensions

    5.1 Costly Price Setting and Market Size

    PWYW pricing option offers a source of cost savings by minimizing the

    transaction cost of price setting (e.g., market research). Since under PWYW pric-

    ing the seller does not incur the cost associated with price setting, by allowing a

    fixed cost F  under the uniform price, we incorporate the cost savings between thetwo pricing options. Additionally, we relax the assumption that the market size

    is equal to unity and let  N  be the market size. The equilibrium monopoly priceunder the uniform price and the fixed cost is not affected by the market size. How-

    ever, the monopolist’s profit under the uniform price with market size N  and fixed

    cost F   isu = N 

    1 c2

    2 F:   (7)

    For PWYW pricing, we focus only on the interesting case when profit under

    PWYW pricing can be positive. That is, when  >   11+c

    . With market size N , theprofit now becomes

     pwyw = N 

    3 6c c2

    8  +

     1 482

    :   (8)

    The following proposition states the sufficient and the necessary conditions

    for PWYW pricing to yield higher profits than the uniform price.

    Proposition 4 (Costly Pricing)   Given  >   11+c

     , price setting cost  F  and market size N  ,

     Case (i): if   F N 

      >   3c2+2c+38

      , then  pwyw > u.

    18

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    19/27

     Case (ii): if   F N     3c2+2c+3

    8  , then  pwyw > u if and only if 

    8><>:

    0  c <   2p 1+6F N 1

    3

    >   12

    p 3c2+2c+38 F 

    :

    Proposition 4  provides insight into why some of the firms mentioned earlier

    use PWYW pricing. An example of Case (i) is the exclusive restaurant in Japan

    with a small (low N ) niche market and has a modest marginal cost of production.Under the uniform price, it may experience a large cost of price setting (high

    F ). In this case, the average cost savings   F N 

     are large enough to offset the effects

    of marginal cost such that   F N    >   3c2

    +2c+38   . Additionally, the intimate nature of the restaurant creates a face-to-face interaction (high  ); thereby, ensuring therestaurant meets the second condition of   >   1

    1+c.

    On the other hand, Case (ii) resembles the case of  Radiohead . Given Radio-

    head’s   lack of pricing experience or lack of having a distribution network, the

    price setting costs could arguably be high, but the global fan base would tend

    to make cost savings small   F N 

    . Therefore, the band must rely on a strong and

    loyal fan base (high ) as well as a low marginal cost of production, because themusic is traded digitally to meet the requirements of higher profitability stated

    in Proposition 4. The example of  Radiohead  can be extended to other forms of 

    digital media where the producers face a significant cost of price setting, but can

    deliver the good with a low marginal cost (e.g. Linux allows for contributions, but

    downloads are free).

    The cost savings described in this section can also affect entry. On the margin,

    a firm only enters into a market if the expected profits are positive. One can argue

    that firms who would not have entered the market because a uniform price would

    have resulted in negative profits (u <   0) but may enter under PWYW pricingas the cost saving without market research may be significant enough to result in

    positive profits ( pwyw > 0).

    5.2 Random Reference Prices

    Information asymmetries across consumers may result in different anchor

    prices for different consumers as such anchor prices are formed from advertise-

    ments, past experiences, and word of mouth. Empirical research has found an-

    chor/reference prices to vary among consumers (see Winer, 1986[14]). Therefore,

    19

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    20/27

    we relax our assumption of a constant and equal anchor price for all consumers in

    this section.Consumers are assumed to know their anchor price, but the seller is unsure

    about consumers’ external anchor e pa. Thus the consumer’s reference price nowbecomes a random variable eR  = minfv; e pag. Applying Lemma 1, the expectedvoluntary payment from a consumer becomes

    E [ p(v)] = E [max

    eR   12

    ; 0

    ]   (9)

    = E [ eR   12

    eR >   1

    2] Pr( eR >   1

    2):

    We assume that the random external anchor price e pa is uniformly distributed on[ pu ; pu + ], where pu +   pu     1

    2 and the equilibrium uniform price

     pu =   1+c2

      .10

    Since the lower bound of the random reference price,  pu , is greater than1

    2, we have e pa >   1

    2 for all e pa 2 [ pu ; pu + ]. So consumers with any e pa will

    pay if  v >   12

    . We can write down the firm’s expected profit as

    E [ pwyw] = E 

    eR   12

    eR >   12

    Pr(eR >   12

    ) c

    =  1

    2[

    Z   pu+ pu

    Z   e pa

    1

    2

    (v   12

    )dvd

    e pa +

    Z   pu+ pu;

    Z   1

    e pa

    (

    e pa   1

    2)dvd

    e pa] c

    = 1

    8  (3 + 2c c2 + 1 4

    2  )   2

    6 :

    Note that when   = 0, E [ pwyw] is reduced to the same profit function   pwyw asin the full information case under PWYW pricing. Moreover, the expected profit

    decreases as the variance of reference prices   increases.Two major patterns in consumer payments are observed when the external

    anchor or the reference price is random. First, a random reference price can result

    in payments  exceeding  the uniform price. In our baseline model, the maximum

    payment per consumer is strictly below the uniform price, i.e.,  p = pu   12

    . Here

    for  >  1

    2 , when the reference price is allowed to vary, some payment amountmay  exceed   the uniform price, i.e., e pa   12

      > pu now becomes possible. This

    10We have already assumed that a consumer’s willingness to pay,  v , is uniformly distributed.Therefore, we need to assume a bivariate uniform distribution over the anchor price, e pa, and v  forthe ordered statistic to be well defined under the expection of the minimum.

    20

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    21/27

    result is consistent with the empirical findings by Regner and Barria (2009)[10]

    who record payments exceeding the recommended price of $8.Second, an increase in the variance of reference prices is found to decrease

    expected profit as shown by the last term in the equation above. A suggested

    minimum price might reduce the variance in consumers’ external anchors and

    thus their reference prices. This implies that a firm offering PWYW pricing may

    benefit from advertising a suggested price to reduce the variance of the reference

    prices among consumers.

    6 Discussion and Limitations

    By incorporating behavioral factors and using a game theoretical model, we en-dogenize the choice of pricing strategy between PWYW pricing and the uniform

    price. We provide the sufficient and necessary conditions for PWYW pricing to

    be more profitable than charging a uniform price. This significant result shows

    that PWYW pricing could emerge as a more profitable alternative to charging a

    fixed-price in equilibrium when the marginal cost is relatively low and some con-

    sumers’ behavioral considerations are significant enough to encourage voluntary

    payments. Further, whenever it is profitable, it is also Pareto-improving. Our

    results are robust to costly pricing and random reference prices.

    We discuss the following limitations of our model. First, for tractability, the

    social-preference utility is specified as a simple quadratic disutility function which

    is the difference between a consumer’s reference price and the voluntary payment.However, it can be generalized to any increasing and concave social-preference

    utility function, G(R  p), and keep the same qualitative results.11The second limitation of the model is that it does not allow for the volun-

    tary payment to exceed the reference price. That is, the model does not account

    for “warm glow”. PWYW pricing is sometimes used by charities who are sell-

    ing goods to collect funds. These goods may be of little value to donors, but the

    donors still provide generous voluntary payments for these goods in the form a do-

    nation. The donation enhances the donor’s utility due to “warm glow” and causes

    voluntary payments to approach or even exceed the consumer’s reference price,

    11For example, given consumer’s utility as  U   =   v  p  G(R  p), it is easy to derive theoptimal voluntary payment p  = max[R G01(1); 0]. Therefore, the voluntary payment is stillcharacterized by subtracting a fixed amount from the reference price. The relative magnitude

    of the discount factor is dependent upon the consumer’s non-pecuniary utility based on social

    preferences.

    21

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    22/27

    generating higher revenue for the firm. Yet, our model finds that PWYW pricing

    can still be viable and profitable even without the presence of “warm glow”. Inthis regard, the model is more conservative than the model that consider “warm

    glow”.12 In addition, the extension making reference prices random does allow for

    some buyers to have their voluntary payments exceeding the expected reference

    price.

    Another limitation relates to the role of fairness and self-image in using PWYW

    pricing. The model captures fairness and self-image via the social-preference util-

    ity function. Maintaining the self-image encourages payments closer to the con-

    sumer’s reference price. However, as noted by Gneezy et al. (2012)[3], protecting

    the self-image can also have a very strong opposite effect by discouraging market

    participation when PWYW is used. That is, preserving the self-image, can on the

    one hand encourage higher payments but, on the other hand, can discourage par-ticipation. The model presented does not capture this non-participation behavior

    by the consumer. In the monopoly case modeled here, consumers are always bet-

    ter off by participating in the market under PWYW pricing even when free riding

    because their outside option is assumed to be equal to zero.

    Schmidt, Spann and Zeithammer (forthcoming)[11] explore the effects of out-

    side option by introducing competition. They consider a duopoly. A firm using

    PWYW pricing competes with another firm that uses a fixed or a posted price.

    Using laboratory experiments via a computer network (no personal interactions)

    they demonstrate that in the presence of competition not only does a significant

    fraction of buyers turn away from the PWYW firm, but the voluntary payments

    also are significantly lower than under monopoly. As a result, the market penetra-

    tion may not be perfect but the PWYW firm ends up with a larger market share.

    However, the firm using a posted price earns higher profits.

    Chao, Fernandez and Nahata (2014)[1] analyze the role of competition in a

    duopoly under Bertrand price competition. In their model one firm uses PWYW

    and the other firm sets a uniform price. The outside option is endogenously deter-

    mined. For example, consumers can obtain the good either from the PWYW firm

    or from a different firm at some reference price without social-preference costs.

    They show that for some value of the social-preference parameter consumers pre-

    fer to purchase the good at the reference price from the firm using the uniform

    price and forgo purchasing the good from the PWYW firm. This result supportsthe conclusion reached by Schmidt et al. (2014)[11] from their online labora-

    12Isaac et al. (2010)[4] focus on a “warm glow” effect in a consumer’s utility function to explain

    PWYW pricing for donations.

    22

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    23/27

    tory experiments. The most novel result Chao et al. (2014)[1] obtain is that the

    outside option segments the market in such a way that, under certain conditions,both firms end up earning positive profits instead of zero profits in equilibrium;

    thus breaking the Bertrand Trap.13 However, the firm using the uniform price al-

    ways earns higher profits—–a result similar to the one obtained by Schmidt et al.

    (2014)[11] in their laboratory experiments.

    In addition, we acknowledge that PWYW pricing may be adopted for reasons

    other than those we consider in this model, such as cross-selling, loyalty effects,

    and so on. For instance, in the music industry, bands may use PWYW pricing for

    music albums to drive up the ticket sales for their live concerts in the future, rather

    than a major revenue stream for its own sake. To model these factors, we need to

    consider a multi-product dynamic setting, which is beyond the scope of this paper.

    We mention two potential directions for future research. First, we adopt astatic reduced form model to examine PWYW pricing without any loyalty consid-

    erations consumers may have for the seller. However, incorporating loyalty con-

    siderations involve repeated interactions that can be best captured in a dynamic

    setting. Exploring repeated interactions under some dynamic settings will be an

    interesting extension.

    Second, for comparison and simplicity we assume that consumers use the

    firm’s actual profit-maximizing uniform price as an external anchor. An endoge-

    nously determined external anchor price and therefore a reference point could be

    another extension of our model (K ˝ oszegi and Rabin, 2006[7]).

    13In Bertand price competition, when both firms set a fixed price the standard result is that bothfirms set price equal to marginal cost and earn zero  economic profits.

    23

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    24/27

    Appendix

    Proof of Corollary 2.  Based on Lemma 1,

    @ pwyw

    @c  =

      1   when     11+c

    3+c4

      when   11+c

     <   ;

    so   @pwyw

    @c    12

    , thereby   @pwyw

    @  > 0.

    Proof of Proposition 1.   From Lemma 2, when     11+c

    ,  pwyw = c. So it isimpossible to have strictly positive profit in this case.

    When  1

    1+c   < ,   pwyw

    =  1

    8   (3  6c  c2

    +  14

    2   ). Hence,  pwyw

    >   0   isequivalent to

    1 42

      > c2 + 6c 3:   (10)Note that  >   1

    1+c  >   1

    2 follows from 0   c <  1. Thus, the left hand side (LHS)

    of (10) is always negative. In order for (10) to hold, we must have the right hand

    side (RHS) to be negative, too. That is,

    c2 + 6c 3  u, we must haveCS  pwyw > C S u, thereby T S  pwyw > T S u.

    Under the uniform price, a type-v  consumer gets utility  v   pu. Thus, theconsumer surplus under the uniform price is

    CS u =

    Z   1

     pu(v  pu)dv =  (1 c)

    2

    8  :   (11)

    Under PWYW pricing, when     11+c

    , all consumers are free riders, thus the

    firm would never adopt PWYW pricing in this case. So for the welfare compari-

    son, only the region where the firm chooses PWYW pricing is relevant. That is,when   1

    1+c < .

    When   11+c

      < , for a consumer with  0   v    12

    , she pays nothing, and her

    utility is v  v2; for a consumer with   12

      < v    1+c2

      , she pays v    12

    , and her

    utility is v(v   12

    )[v(v   12

    )]2 =   14

    ; and for a consumer with   1+c2

      < v  1,

    24

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    25/27

    she pays   1+c2    1

    2, and her utility is  v  (1+c

    2    1

    2)   [1+c

    2  (1+c

    2    1

    2)]2 =

    v   1+c

    2   +  1

    4 . Hence, the consumer surplus under PWYW is

    CS  pwyw =

    Z   12

    0

    (v v2)dv +Z   1+c

    2

    1

    2

    1

    4  dv +

    Z   1

    1+c2

    (v  1 + c2

      +  1

    4)dv

    = 1

    8  [(1 c)2 + 2

        1

    32]:   (12)

    Thus,

    CS  pwyw CS u =   18

      (2   13

    )

    > 0 ( because in the relevant region,  >   11 + c >  12).

    From Proposition 2   pwyw > u, and we have shown above that  C S  pwyw >CS u, therefore we must have  T S  pwyw > T S u within the relevant region of    andc.Proof of Proposition 4. From (7) and (8),  pwyw > u can be reduced to

    1 42

      > 3c2 + 2c 1 8  F N 

      (13)

    Denote A

      3c2 + 2c

    1

    8

      F N 

    . Note that  >   11+c

     >   12

    , which implies that the

    LHS of (13) is negative. So in order for (13) to hold, we require A  3c2 + 2c + 3, then (14) is true for any   >   11+c

    . In

    this case, A 12

    p 3c2+2c+38 F 

    . Recall that we also require A <   0, which is equivalent to

    c <  2

    p 1+6 F 

    N 1

    3  . Moreover, it is easy to verify that   1

    2p 

    3c2+2c+38 F N 

    >   11+c

     in this

    case.

    25

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    26/27

    References

    [1] Y. Chao, J. Fernandez, and B. Nahata. Pay-what-you-want pricing and com-

    petition: Breaking the bertrand trap.  Working Paper , 2014.

    [2] E. Fehr and K. M. Schmidt. A theory of fairness, competition, and coopera-

    tion.  The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3):817–868, 1999.

    [3] A. Gneezy, U. Gneezy, G. Riener, and L. D. Nelson. Pay-what-you-want,

    identity, and self-signaling in markets. Proceedings of the National Academy

    of Sciences, 2012.

    [4] R. M. Isaac, J. P. Lightle, and D. A. Norton. The pay-what-you-like business

    model: Warm glow revenues and endogenous price discrimination.  WorkingPaper , 2010.

    [5] D. R. Just and B. Wansink. The flat-rate pricing paradox: conflicting effects

    of "all-you-can-eat" buffet pricing.  The Review of Economics and Statistics,

    93(1):193–200, 2011.

    [6] J.-Y. Kim, M. Natter, and M. Spann. Pay what you want: A new participative

    pricing mechanism.  Journal of Marketing, 73(1):44–58, January 2009.

    [7] B. Koszegi and M. Rabin. A model of reference-dependent preferences. The

    Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4):1133–1165, 2006.

    [8] F. Machado and R. K. Sinha. The viability of pay what you want pricing.

    Working Paper , 2013.

    [9] T. Regner. Why consumers pay voluntarily: Evidence from online music.

    Working Paper , 2010.

    [10] T. Regner and J. A. Barria. Do consumers pay voluntarily? the case of online

    music.   Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 71(2):395 – 406,

    2009.

    [11] K. M. Schmidt, M. Spann, and R. Zeithammer. Pay what you want as a

    marketing strategy in monopolistic and competitive markets.   Management 

    Science, Forthcoming.

    [12] R. Thaler. Mental accounting and consumer choice.   Marketing Science,

    4(3):199–214, 1985.

    26

  • 8/21/2019 Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Can It Be Profitable

    27/27

    [13] R. H. Thaler.  Mental accounting matters. Russell Sage Foundation. Prince-

    ton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2004.

    [14] R. S. Winer. A reference price model of brand choice for frequently pur-

    chased products.  Journal of Consumer Research, 13(2):pp. 250–256, 1986.

    27