126
Report No. 43737-PE PERU Trajectories towards Formality JUNE 16, 2008 Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Bolivia, Ecuador, Peru and Venezuela Country Management Unit Latin America and the Caribbean Region Document of the World Bank Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

PERU Trajectories towards Formality

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    9

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

Report No. 43737-PE

PERU

Trajectories towards Formality

JUNE 16, 2008

Poverty Reduction and Economic Management

Bolivia, Ecuador, Peru and Venezuela Country Management Unit

Latin America and the Caribbean Region

Document of the World Bank

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Page 2: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

REPUBLIC OF PERU FISCAL YEAR January 1 to December 31

CURRENCY EQUIVALENTS Currency Unit

1 US Dollar

=

=

Soles

S/. 2.85

WEIGHTS AND MEASURES Metric System

ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS

AAA Analytical and Advisory Activities BCRP Central Reserve Bank of Peru (Banco

Central de Reserva del Perú)

BONOPYME Training and technical assistance vouchers

CIT Corporate Income Tax CNC National Competitiveness Council

(advisory body to the PCM)

COFIDE Development Financial Corporation (Corporación Financiera de Desarrollo

SA)

COFOPRI Comission to Formalize Informal Property (Comisión de Formalización de

la Propiedad Informal)

CONFIEP Peruvian Private Business Association (Confederación Nacional de

Instituciones Empresariales Privadas)

CONSUCODE Council of State Procurement (Consejo

Superior de Contrataciones y

Adquisiciones del Estado)

CTS Compensation for time in service (compensación por tiempo de servicio)

DNMYPE National Directorate for Micro and

Small Companies (Dirección Nacional de la Micro y Pequeña Empresa)

ENAHO National Household Survey (Encuesta

Nacional de Hogares) FIAS Foreign Investment Advisory Service

GDP Gross Domestic Product

GOP Government of Peru GNP Gross National Product

ICA Investment Climate Assessment

IDB Inter-American Development Bank IFC International Finance Corporation

IGV General sales tax (Impuesto General a

las Ventas)

ILO International Labor Organization

IMF International Monetary Fund

INDECOPI National Institute for Consumer and Intellectual Property Defense

INEI National Statistics Institute (Instituto

Nacional de Estadística e Informática)

LAC Latin America and Caribbean Region MSEs Micro and Small Enterprises

MEF Ministry of Economy and Finance

METR Marginal Effective Tax Rate MTPE Ministry of Labor and Employment

Promotion (Ministerio del Trabajo y

Promoción del Empleo) MYPEs Micro and Small Enterprises (Micro y

Pequeñas Empresas)

NRS National Registry of Suppliers to the State (Registro Nacional de Proveedores)

OLS Ordinary Least Squares

PCM Office of the Prime Minister (Presidencia del Consejo de Ministros)

PRODAME Self-Employment and Micro enterprise

Promotion Program (Programa de Autoempleo y Microempresa)

PRODUCE Ministry of Production (Ministerio de la

Producción) PROMPEX Export Promotion Agency (Comisión para la

Promoción de Exportaciones)

PROMPYME Comission for Promotion of the Small and Micro Enterprise (Comisión para la

Promoción de la Pequeña y Micro Empresa)

RER Special Tax Regime (Régimen Especial de la Renta)

RUC Tax identification Lumber (Registro Único

de Contribuyente) RUS Simplified Single Regime (Régimen Unico

Simplificado)

SBS Superintendency of Bank and Insurance (Superintendencia de Banca y Seguros)

SMEs Small and Medium Enterprises SUNARP National Registry (Superintendencia

Nacional de

Registros Públicos)

SUNAT Government Tax Agency (Superintendencia

Nacional de Administración Tributaria)

UIT Income Tax Unit VAT Value Added Tax

Vice President, LCR: Pamela Cox Director, LCC6C: C. Felipe Jaramillo

Director, LCSPR: Marcelo Giugale

Sector Director, LCSPE: Rodrigo Chaves Sector Leader, LCSPE: Carlos Silva-Jauregui

Task Team Leader: Oscar Calvo-Gonzalez /

Rossana Polastri

Page 3: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

3

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

This report was prepared by a team led by Oscar Calvo-Gonzalez (LCSPE) and Rossana

Polastri (Senior Country Economist, LCSPE) under the overall supervision and guidance

of Rodrigo Chaves (Sector Manager, LCSPE) and Carlos Siva-Jauregui (Lead Economist

and Sector Leader, LCSPR). C. Felipe Jaramillo (Country Director, LCC6C) linked the

team to the Bank’s overall strategy and steered them in that direction. Mauricio Carrizosa

(Adviser, IEGCR) and Vicente Fretes-Cibils (IDB) provided initial guidance on the

study.

The team also included Luis Barrantes (LCSPE), Sebastian James (CICRS), Jan Loeprick

(CICKM), David McKenzie (Senior Economist, DECRG), Rashmi Shankar (LCSPE),

and Rich Stern (Program Coordinator for Business Taxation, FIAS). Contributions were

also received from Cesar Baldeon (CFOMR) and Gladys Triveño (Proexpansión). Ipsos

APOYO Opinión y Mercado conducted the survey of micro and small businesses and

CONECTA carried out the focus groups and in-depth interviews with micro and small

entrepreneurs. Maria Ines Thorne provided valuable logistical and production support.

The peer reviewers for the report were Alvaro Escribano (Universidad Carlos III), Pablo

Fajnzylber (Senior Economist, LCRCE), Luke Haggarty (General Manager, CLALA),

Vincent Palmade (Lead Economist, AFTFP), and Jamele Rigolini (Economist, EASHD).

The report also benefited from substantive comments from a variety of people during

various stages of this project, including Jacqueline Coolidge (Lead Policy Investment

Officer, CICAF), Gladys Lopez-Acevedo (Senior Economist, LCSPP), Juan Carlos

Mendoza (Senior Financial Economist, LCSPF), and Ian Walker (Lead Social Protection

Specialist, LCSHS).

The team received valuable guidance through meetings with various authorities.

Important insights and contributions were gained through interviews with a wide variety

of individuals and groups representing officials of the Peruvian Government, institutions,

and private sector (micro and small) firms. Particular thanks to the entrepreneurs who

generously granted us their time through numerous interviews. The team would like to

thank the Peruvian authorities for their continued cooperation, especially the support of

the Ministry of Economy and Finance (MEF), the Ministry of Labor (MTPE), the

Ministry of Production (PRODUCE), the National Institute of Statistics (INEI), the

Superintendence of Tax Administration (SUNAT), the Superintendence of Banks and

Insurance (SBS), the National Council of Competitiveness (CNC), and the Central Bank

of Reserve (BCRP).

Page 4: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

4

Page 5: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

5

Trajectories towards Formality in Peru

Table of contents

Executive summary and policy implications ...................................................................... 9

1. Introduction .............................................................................................................. 19

Informality in the sectors selected for the survey .................................................... 26

2. Determinants of informality ..................................................................................... 31

A. Who is our source of information? ..................................................................... 32

B. What do micro and small business owners tell us? ............................................. 35

C. Econometric analysis of the determinants of informality ................................... 61

D. Dynamics out of informality ............................................................................... 65

3. The impact of informality ........................................................................................ 69

A. Is informality a cause of low profitability? ......................................................... 69

B. What is the impact of informality on access to credit? ....................................... 73

List of references............................................................................................................... 78

Annex A. Measures of informality based on the ENAHO using different definitions . 80

Annex B. Econometric results on the choice of tax regime and determinants of tax inspections ....................................................................................................................... 98

Annex C. Econometric results on the determinants of informality ............................. 103

Annex D. The impact of informality – methodology and impact on profits and on access to credit ................................................................................................................ 104

Annex E. Trajectories towards formality .................................................................... 114

Annex F. Database of sector-specific labor regulations - methodology ..................... 115

Annex G. The Marginal Effective Tax Rate Methodology ......................................... 116

Annex H. Data for calculating the marginal effective tax rate .................................... 125

List of boxes

Box 1: What do we mean by informality? ........................................................................ 19

Box 2: A dedicated survey to study informality in Peru ................................................... 24

Box 3: Understanding the incentives of tax regimes – the Marginal Effective Tax Rate of

the different corporate income tax regimes in Peru .......................................................... 44

Box 4: What do businesses know about the Special Labor Regime for micro firms? ...... 51

Box 5: Severance payments de jure and de facto ............................................................. 56

Box 6: Sector-specific labor regulations and the prevalence of informality .................... 58

Box 7: Case studies – formality is also a ‘refuge’ ............................................................ 65

Page 6: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

6

List of tables

Table 1.1: Measures of informality based on the household survey in the sectors selected

for the survey and in the economy .................................................................................... 26

Table 2.1: Number of businesses surveyed ....................................................................... 32

Table 2.2: Selected informality characteristics of surveyed businesses ........................... 33

Table 2.3: Benefits and costs of formalizing perceived by micro and small business

owners ............................................................................................................................... 35

Table 2.4: Reasons for not having a municipal license .................................................... 39

Table 2.5: Overview of corporate income taxation .......................................................... 41

Table 2.6: Results from econometric analyses of the choice of tax regime ..................... 47

Table 2.7: Definitions of micro and small enterprises in the labor code and

correspondence with tax regulations ................................................................................. 48

Table 2.8: Business owners’ estimates of how common is for workers to earn less than

the minimum wage and not being on the payroll .............................................................. 54

Table 2.9: Reasons for self-employment .......................................................................... 56

Table 2.10: Variables that help predict having a municipal license and an RUC number 62

Table 2.11: Variables that help predict having both a municipal license and an RUC

number .............................................................................................................................. 63

Table 2.12: Summary of steps towards formalization ...................................................... 67

Table 3.1: Impact of different formality characteristics on firm profits ........................... 72

Table A.1: Special fiscal regimens for small taxpayers in Latin America ....................... 88

Table A.2: Regulatory labor burden in comparative perspective ..................................... 88

Table A.3: Main informality characteristics among surveyed businesses, by city ........... 89

Table A.4: Main informality characteristics among surveyed businesses, by sector ....... 89

Table A.5: Most important problem affecting micro and business owners ...................... 90

Table A.6: Obstacles for micro and small businesses - detailed questionnaire ................ 91

Table A.7: Sales of micro and small businesses surveyed, by customer type and business

size .................................................................................................................................... 92

Table A.8: Elements of formality ..................................................................................... 92

Table A.9: Factors affecting the choice of tax regime ...................................................... 93

Table A.10: Participation in state-supported programs .................................................... 94

Table A.11: Key factors behind the decision not to have a license, by business size ...... 95

Table A.12: Knowledge of where to formalize ................................................................ 95

Table A.13: Share of workers earning less than minimum wage, by business size ......... 96

Table A.14: Reasons for not paying the minimum wage, by business size ...................... 96

Table A.15: Percent of workers not on the payroll, by business size ............................... 97

Table A.16: Reasons for not having workers on payroll, by business size ...................... 97

Table B.1: Choice of tax regime - probit regression ......................................................... 98

Table B.2: Choice of tax regime - multinomial logit (general regime) ............................ 99

Table B.3: Choice of tax regime - multinomial logit (RUS) .......................................... 100

Table B.4: Choice of tax regime - multinomial logit (RER) .......................................... 101

Table B.5: Probit regression on the determinants of tax inspections .............................. 102

Table D.1: "Impact" of having an RUC on log profits ................................................... 105

Table D.2: "Impact" of having a municipal license on log profits ................................. 106

Table D.3: OLS Regression of log profits on both municipal license and an RUC number

......................................................................................................................................... 107

Page 7: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

7

Table D.4: Businesses with and without bank accounts ................................................. 108

Table D.5: Sources of finance among businesses that have borrowed in 2007 or 2006 . 108

Table D.6: Use of credit to purchase inputs .................................................................... 109

Table D.7: Sources of start-up capital............................................................................. 110

Table D.8: Borrowing by sector...................................................................................... 110

Table D.9: Sources of finance for most recent loan........................................................ 111

Table D.10: Terms of loan (annual or monthly rates) by source of finance ................... 111

Table D.11: Average length of loan in months ............................................................... 112

Table D.12: Home ownership - percent of entrepreneur owning their home ................. 112

Table D.13: Business taking credit cards and checks, percent ....................................... 112

Table D.14: Impact on getting a loan of having a license and RUC number ................. 113

Table E.1: Time lapsed from opening business to getting RUC number and municipal

license ............................................................................................................................. 114

List of figures

Figure 1.1: Informality in Peru and other countries in Latin America and the Caribbean 21

Figure 1.2: Informality by firm size, selected sectors and economy-wide ....................... 27

Figure 1.3: Map of informality prevalence by region ....................................................... 28

Figure 1.4: Informality prevalence by region and income per capita ............................... 29

Figure 1.5: Informality rate and economic growth, 2003 to 2006 .................................... 30

Figure 2.1: Share of surveyed businesses at different degrees of formality ..................... 34

Figure 2.2: Benefits from having a municipal license and reasons not to have one ......... 38

Figure 2.3: Benefits from having an RUC number and reasons not to have one ............. 40

Figure 2.4: Distribution by turnover of businesses filing under different tax regimes ..... 43

Figure 2.5: Relationship between the number of workers and those with health coverage

and pension ....................................................................................................................... 50

Figure 2.6: Kernel distributions of monthly income for private salaried workers –

Metropolitan Lima ............................................................................................................ 53

Figure 2.7: Minimum wage in Peru and selected countries in the region......................... 53

Figure 2.8: Informality prevalence for workers, by pay system (piece-rate or not) ......... 55

Figure 2.9: Formality characteristics among surveyed businesses, by age of business .... 68

Figure 3.1: Difference in profitability between the business with a municipal license and

those without ..................................................................................................................... 70

Figure 3.2: Difference in profitability between the business with an RUC number and

those without ..................................................................................................................... 71

Figure 3.3: Financial depth ............................................................................................... 73

Figure A.1: Calculating the productive definition of informality based on the ENAHO . 80

Figure A.2: Map of informality prevalence by region ...................................................... 81

Figure A.3: Map of informality prevalence by region ...................................................... 82

Figure A.4: Map of informality prevalence by region ...................................................... 83

Figure A.5: Informality prevalence by region and income per capita .............................. 84

Figure A.6: Informality prevalence by region and income per capita .............................. 85

Figure A.7: Informality prevalence by region and income per capita .............................. 86

Figure A.8: Informality rate and economic growth, 2003 to 2006 ................................... 86

Figure A.9: Informality rate and economic growth, 2003 to 2006 ................................... 87

Figure A.10: Informality rate and economic growth, 2003 to 2006 ................................. 87

Page 8: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

8

Page 9: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

9

Executive summary and policy implications

Context

ES. 1. Informality in Peru is high compared to other countries in the Latin

America and the Caribbean region. Measuring informality is notoriously difficult, in

large part because informality is not easily defined. Alternative measures of informality

include a so-called ‘productive’ definition focused on the characteristics of the productive

unit and a ‘legalistic’ definition focused on the coverage of workers by mandated social

protection. According to the so-called productive definition of informality, 76 percent of

the economically active population in Peru is informal (the third highest share in the

Latin America and the Caribbean region). Taking the legalistic definition of informality,

around 86 percent of the economically active population lack access to a pension, 86

percent work without a contract, and 80 percent lack healthcare insurance. Peru reports

the third-highest rate of informality in Latin America and the Caribbean as measured by

the percent of workers without a contract and without health insurance, while Peru is in

the middle of the table in the region with regard to access to a pension.

ES. 2. Addressing informality is a priority in the policy agenda of the

Government of Peru. The Peruvian economy has enjoyed a relatively long period of

stable and sustained growth. Poverty numbers are coming down and formal employment

is picking up. However, informality is still prevalent and this raises questions about the

sustainability of growth in the medium term. The country is investing efforts in access to

larger markets through trade agreements and if micro and small firms find it difficult to

remain formal due to an onerous state, little can be expected for them in this context.

More broadly, informality means that most people are not covered by labor protections.

Without a pension, the living standards in old age of many Peruvians are at risk. Without

health insurance workers face significant risks to their livelihoods. President García

himself referred in April 2008 to informality as the “slavery of the twenty-first century.”

But informality also erodes the social contract between the population and the state,

making the provision of public services more difficult by reducing the available revenue

base. In addition, informality may have a negative impact on business performance –

though the cross-country evidence is mixed. It is in this context that the Government of

Peru has set the goal of reducing informality by one-third by 2011.

ES. 3. This study is timely, as the authorities’ interest in analyses of informality

has increased. This report is the outcome of very close cooperation with the authorities

of the Government of Peru. The authorities have been involved in all stages of the

process, going back to the first phase of this programmatic study. The authorities proved

instrumental in helping design the focus of this report, including the scope of a survey of

businesses conducted for this study, the survey questionnaire itself, they also suggested

specific topics to be explored – which are presented throughout the report mainly in the

form of boxes.

Page 10: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

10

ES. 4. ‘Formality’ is better understood as having different dimensions. In this

report we explore four of those dimensions: business licensing, tax, labor relations

and pensions, and business incorporation. It is well known that informality is not a

straightforward concept. As a result, it is not easy to agree on a single definition of

informality or to measure it easily. The important conclusion to draw from this is that

informality can be better understood as being a multi-dimensional concept. In this report

we take a pragmatic approach by exploring four dimensions of ‘formality’: business

licensing, tax, labor relations and pensions, and business incorporation. Of course, a

business person can legally operate with only service providers and no employees; or as a

natural person and not a business with a separate legal entity. However, the choice of

these aspects of what ‘formality’ may be stems from the result of focus groups with

micro and small business owners – these are the very issues they have in mind when they

think of ‘formality.’

ES. 5. This report focuses on the trajectories towards formality of micro and

small businesses, drawing insight by polling those businesses directly. For the

purpose of this report, micro businesses are those with up to 10 workers and small

businesses those with 11 to 50 workers. This working definition is a practical choice that

also reflects the criteria regarding maximum number of workers in the existing Peruvian

legislation. It also helped us to design a dedicated survey of 802 micro and small

businesses conducted for this study. Informality is widespread across all sectors of the

economy and affects all types of firms but it is particularly high among small businesses.

Drawing from the day-to-day experiences of micro and small businesses is at the core of

this report. The analysis adds value to the authorities’ information set by presenting new

evidence on what are the most critical steps in the formalization process and what are the

key considerations at those junctures. By focusing on practices and decision-making of

businesses, this report complements the analysis of labor market and labor legislation that

was a key part of the first phase of the programmatic study.

ES. 6. Informality represents not only the exclusion of many workers but also

reflects a decision by economic agents to exit the formal sphere. The approach

followed here is informed by the analytical work for the World Bank’s Informality. Exit

and Exclusion flagship report of the Latin American and Caribbean Vice-Presidency of

the World Bank in 2007. In particular, this approach recognizes that informality not only

undermines the social contract but is also a consequence of the limited value for the

population of the services provided by the state. In other words, informality results also

from decisions of economic agents about the optimal level of engagement with the state.

Micro and small entrepreneurs use implicit cost-benefit analysis as to whether to remain

informal or to formalize. Digging deeper into those choices and cost-benefit

considerations is the subject of this report.

Page 11: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

11

Main findings

The study finds no significant impact of certain characteristics of formality, such as

having a municipal license or being registered with the tax authorities, on the

profitability of businesses or on their probability of obtaining a loan. These results must

be accompanied, however, by the caveat that establishing the impact of informality

econometrically is notoriously difficult. The methodology used in this report does not

attempt to capture the negative effects that informality may have on the performance of

formal firms, or the effects that informality may have in undermining social trust and the

overall business environment.

The study also finds informality to be particularly persistent in the area of labor relations

and access to pension, driven largely by high costs of being formal, limited enforcement

of labor relations, and a preference for flexible labor relations.

These two findings combined suggest that: (i) efforts to increase the access to health

insurance and pension coverage of workers through a shift from informal arrangements

to existing formal labor relations will prove difficult; and (ii) alternative methods to

increase access to health and pension coverage are well-worth exploring. The rest of

these main findings concentrate on the conclusions of the study regarding the

determinants of informality and what prompts businesses to move towards formality.

ES. 7. What is an informal business? Micro and small entrepreneurs consider

themselves to be formal if they pay (some) taxes, have a tax ID number and a

municipal business license. Micro and small business owners do not typically consider

that not having workers on the payroll is being informal. At some level business owners

know that having workers on the payroll is mandated by law but the practice of not doing

so is so widespread that it does not register with them as an informal practice. This

implicit definition shared by micro and small entrepreneurs of what makes a business

formal or informal is an important starting point. It helps to identify that any policy aimed

at formalization of labor relations (or any aspect absent from the implicit definition) will

face key communication and enforcement challenges.

ES. 8. As businesses grow they tend to become more formal – but not in the area

of labor relations. The first step of formalization among micro and small businesses is to

obtain a tax ID number (Registro Único de Contribuyente, RUC) and a municipal license.

Most of these businesses pay taxes on some of their actual income. As micro and small

businesses grow businesses consider incorporating the business into a separate legal

entity with limited liability. However, at the same time informal labor relations persist

even as the business grows. Businesses with 11 to 50 workers display a very complex

mix of labor relations among their workers. But these complex relations are largely

informal even among the core group of stable workers.

ES. 9. The trajectory of businesses towards formality is driven by how the costs

and benefits across different dimensions of informality change as the business

grows. The study draws on both a quantitative survey of 802 micro and small businesses

as well as on qualitative data gathered from seven focus groups, interviews, and case-

studies. Overall, the different sources of evidence presented in this study present a

consistent pattern of how micro and small entrepreneurs make their choices regarding

Page 12: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

12

whether to cross into formality or to remain informal. This pattern, which we now discuss

in more detail, can be characterized in broad terms as reflecting largely the costs and

benefits faced by business owners. At the same time, some evidence was also found that

certain behaviors may be partly explained by a persistent ‘culture of informality’ by

which micro and small businesses would remain informal simply because this is the

societal norm.

ES. 10. In many cases, the main driver behind the formalization process is the

fact that enforcement makes it costly to remain informal. In the areas of business

licensing and paying taxes the costs of remaining informal increase notably as the

business grows. Enforcement is the critical factor affecting the decision to obtain a

municipal license which otherwise is seen as conferring no benefits to the business. In

addition, businesses perceive the process to get a municipal license as unnecessarily

burdensome and arbitrary. Thus, micro and small businesses exploit any opportunity to

avoid compliance. Businesses are less likely to get the municipal license if they operate

in sectors such as textiles because they can operate workshops without being detected. In

some cases, businesses prefer to pay off inspectors rather than obtain the license, but as

the business grows so also does the number of visits by inspectors, thus making the

strategy of paying them off not worthwhile, most businesses end up obtaining a

municipal license.

ES. 11. Businesses perceive benefits from formalizing only in the area of paying

taxes and business incorporation. While enforcement of taxes is a key factor in

ensuring compliance, businesses do see benefits in being registered with the tax

authorities and regularly paying taxes (at least on some of their actual income). Benefits

from formalizing in the area of paying taxes include an expanded client base since the

business can issue receipts and can therefore sell to larger clients that require receipts and

also to the state. In addition, there is some limited evidence to show that being registered

with the tax authority and in a position to show regular payment of taxes may improve

access to credit. The analysis also suggested that incorporating the business may be an

important step in the formalization process. Micro and small business owners consider

that incorporating the business under a separate legal entity with limited liability provides

not only a way to preserve the individual patrimony but also business opportunities as the

business gains credibility in the marketplace.

ES. 12. But the existing tax regimes may need to be fine-tuned as they currently

do not encourage formalization. This applies when special tax regimes do not

encourage micro and small businesses to move to the general regime as they grow and to

incorporate as separate legal entities. Few businesses choose to file taxes under the

special regime for corporate income tax (Régimen Especial de la Renta, RER). Instead

businesses prefer to remain under the much simpler, but more onerous, simplified regime

(Régimen Único Simplificado, RUS) or the general regime – despite the fact that the latter

imposes the full set of requirements designed for larger enterprises. These filing patterns

suggest that compliance costs may be high under the RER – discouraging businesses

from moving from the RUS to the RER. In addition, the constraint under the simplified

tax regime (RUS) by which most legal entities are prevented from filing taxes under that

regime, may result in businesses choosing to remain operating as natural persons for

Page 13: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

13

longer than they otherwise would, which may have a negative impact in business access

to credit and market opportunities. Overall, current practices contrast with the goal of

having small businesses under the special regimes and larger businesses under the general

regime.

ES. 13. In the absence of enforcement, businesses keep informal labor relations

and explain them partly on the grounds of a need for greater flexibility. The very fact

that businesses do not consider this an aspect of informality is indicative of how prevalent

it is. Based on the survey conducted for this study more than 80 percent of micro and

small businesses have no workers with a contract. This high number is unsurprising given

what we know from the household survey about the economically active population in

Peru (again around 80 percent of the labor force without a pension). What is more

remarkable is that the proportion of businesses with no workers on the payroll decreases

only slightly among businesses with 11 to 50 workers, of which approximately two-thirds

have no workers on their payrolls. As for the reasons why labor relations are so informal,

the analysis from the focus groups suggested that in part this stems from a need to keep

flexible labor relations in what is a rapidly changing and highly cyclical marketplace.

While this may be true for smaller businesses, this reason is also claimed among larger

businesses of 11 to 50 workers, which typically have a stable group of core workers yet

often those core workers are still reported to be service providers who simply issue

receipts for their services (recibos por honorarios).

ES. 14. Micro entrepreneurs claim that the minimum wage and holiday pay

impose not only a high burden but are also hard to reconcile with their preference

for piece-rate pay arrangements. In some cases the foremost concern of micro and

small business owners with the formal requirements regarding minimum wage and

holiday pay does not appears to be their level but the fact that they perceive it to be in

opposition to the piece-rate pay arrangement (destajo). Micro entrepreneurs are often

confused when it is suggested that a minimum wage could be paid as a floor for their

workers’ salaries. This perception is all the more puzzling given the complex mix of

labor arrangements that micro and small businesses actually have. One interpretation of

this finding is that minimum wages would be in fact binding for a large proportion of the

workforce (for more than half of the workforce if the survey results are taken at face

value). Hence the minimum wage may truly have the disincentive effects on effort that

micro entrepreneurs fear. The survey conducted for this study provides some supportive

evidence that two-thirds of all businesses surveyed consider that their business is not

productive enough to allow paying the minimum wage. At the same time, the survey also

provides evidence that there is a group of workers who earn more than the minimum

wage but who are not on the payroll, for which the preference for piece-rate pay

arrangements (on the side of the employer) and for higher take-home pay instead of

benefits (on the part of the worker) seems to play a role.

ES. 15. Firing costs are also perceived to be high and a deterrent to include

workers on the payrolls. Most micro and small entrepreneurs consider that the

compensation that workers receive upon been fired is not only too high but also a more

important factor than the actual wage to be paid in explaining why workers are not on the

payroll. Firing is also perceived to be complicated and the process prone to legal disputes

Page 14: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

14

and costs. In this regard, and somewhat paradoxically, there may be an incentive to

incorporate the business into a legal separate entity as a way to protect the entrepreneur

from labor-related litigation. In addition to the level of firing costs, the study uncovered

evidence that the de facto severance payments differ considerably from the de jure

severance payments. To the extent that this results in increased uncertainty about the true

costs of firing, this may further discourage the formalization of labor relations.

ES. 16. Overall, micro and small business owners have limited information about

the regulatory frameworks affecting them. Most notably, the Special Labor Regime,

which provides for a much reduced burden of social benefits on the part of the employer,

is virtually unknown among micro and small entrepreneurs. The limited knowledge of the

Special Labor Regime for micro businesses highlights the communication challenges

implied in addressing the issue of labor informality. In addition, there is limited

information among micro and small entrepreneurs about the new regulatory framework

for municipal business licensing. The interaction between the entrepreneur and the state

is also made more difficult by the existence of different definitions of what constitutes a

micro or a small business for tax and labor purposes and, more importantly, the fact that

those definitions overlap only partially with each other.

ES. 17. Micro and small businesses typically obtain information about the costs

and benefits from their peers or from an accountant to formalize their business. This

finding, which emanated from the qualitative research conducted for this study, helps to

explain why, for example, factors such as owner education do not affect the choice of tax

regime. The choice of tax regime is effectively not made by the owner but by the

accountant. This qualitative research suggests that a similar pattern may also affect other

decisions to formalize, particularly the decision to incorporate the business as a separate

legal entity.

Policy implications

The following conclusions are meant to serve as input for the ongoing policy dialogue

with the authorities of the Government of Peru (GOP). Policy implications that can be

implemented in a relatively shorter time-frame will be discussed here first, followed by

those that will pose greater challenges to implement.

‘Quick-wins’

ES. 18. Unify the definition of a micro and small enterprise for tax and labor

purposes. While there is no standard international practice for what the criteria should be

to consider a business to be a micro and small enterprise (MSE), the guiding principle

should be one of clarity. The preferred solution is to have a single definition agreed by all

different ministries and applied consistently. Alternatively, the number of criteria that a

business has to meet to qualify under the different regulations could be reduced. One

possibility would be to define eligibility for certain tax regimes on the basis of turnover

and to define eligibility for the special labor regime on the basis of the number of

employees. The decision to include additional criteria as a way of preventing certain

businesses from ‘getting through’ under a more simple framework (e.g., a capital-

Page 15: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

15

intensive and high-turnover business with few employees would qualify for the special

labor regime) ought to be carefully weighed against the disincentive that complexity and

partially overlapping criteria pose to formalization.

ES. 19. Eliminate the register of eligible suppliers to the state in order to expand

the benefits of formalization. Peru mandates that 40 percent of all state purchases to be

sourced from MSEs. In practice less than 20 percent of purchases are sourced from

MSEs. In part, the effectiveness of this legal requirement is weakened by the additional

bureaucratic and cost burden that MSEs have to face in order to compete for state

contracts, as all businesses wanting to supply the state have to pay to be registered on a

list of eligible providers. A way to reduce the bureaucratic burden on micro and small

business would be to eliminate the register of eligible suppliers, establishing that all

formal businesses (e.g., those with a RUC number) are eligible to bid in public

procurement tenders by default. If necessary the GOP could replace the register of

eligible suppliers with a listing of ineligible suppliers: those fined by SUNAT or the

Ministry of Labor. This change would have some impact on expanding the benefits of

formalization without unduly compromising the integrity of the system since the register

of eligible suppliers does not carry inspections. Overall, improved market access must be

emphasized as a key benefit of formalization, given that micro and small business owners

already perceive this a benefit of formalizing in terms of paying taxes and of business

incorporation.

ES. 20. Continue with simplification efforts in municipal business licensing. In

Lima the Tramifácil project, with support from the IFC, reduced the time to obtain a

license from a month to a week and cut the number of procedures from 33 to five. Such

efforts are being expanded across an increasing number of municipalities and are

expected to alleviate somewhat the concerns of micro and small business owners

regarding the bureaucratic burden posed by municipal business licensing. To ensure that

the costs of the municipal license remain affordable, municipalities need to ensure that, as

provided by the regulatory framework, the fees charged to businesses reflect only cost

recovery considerations. The cost of the municipal license in 2007 ranged from 1.7

percent of per capita GDP in Lima to 9.7 percent of per capita GDP in Huancayo. These

figures are relatively high compared to a selection of 65 municipalities in the Latin

America and the Caribbean region monitored by the IFC Municipal Scorecard, in fact

Huancayo was the lowest ranked municipality of all 65, and Lima, while being the

highest ranked in Peru, was only the nineteenth of the regional sample.

ES. 21. Review the costs of complying with the different tax regimes to identify

ways to reduce them, and re-calibrate the simplified and special tax regimes. Costs

of complying with the requirements in the different tax regimes may be a significant

factor affecting the choice of tax regime under which businesses are filing their taxes.

However, more analysis is needed as the drivers of the choice of tax regime remain

unclear. The restriction that only natural persons can file under the simplified regime:

RUS, may discourage businesses from incorporating into separate legal entities, this

study suggests that this is an important step in the formalization process.

Page 16: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

16

ES. 22. Step up communication efforts, possibly in partnership with associations

of accountants, those who are close to the micro and small entrepreneurs. The

finding that micro and small entrepreneurs often based their decisions to formalize on the

information they gather from other MSEs poses a challenge for effectively

communicating with them. However, the finding that MSEs also rely heavily on the

accountant that files their taxes opens up an opportunity for the GOP to partner with

associations of accountants to improve the effectiveness of efforts to relay relevant

information, such as that regarding the labor regime available to micro enterprises.

ES. 23. Target businesses that already participate in some state programs

(purchases, etc) to provide information relevant to those businesses. An additional

opportunity to improve the reach of information to MSEs is to make the most of the fact

that some MSEs are already in contact with the state through participation in a number of

state-sponsored programs. Yet the survey evidence suggests that even among these MSEs

knowledge of the Special Labor Regime was poor. The GOP may therefore want to

explore making use of the opportunity to be in contact with the MSEs to introduce this

information and to present options like the Special Labor Regime as an opportunity to

reduce costs compared to the general labor regime. An additional point of contact with

the MSEs would be through the SUNAT, though this is likely to be a less efficient way to

relay information since the set of businesses dealing the state-sponsored programs is in

effect a self-selected group. For municipalities to efficiently perform as a link in the

relays of information, an even bigger effort would be required given the still broadly

negative view that micro and small entrepreneurs have of the municipalities.

Longer-term challenges

ES. 24. Consider ways to expand access to health care insurance and pensions

that do not necessarily involve including workers in the general labor regime. Given

the intrinsic difficulties in establishing the link between informality and business

performance measures, the econometric results presented in this study must be interpreted

with great caution. However, they suggest that the key negative aspects of informality

relate to the lack of social protection of workers. Given the tough hurdles that need to be

overcome to make the labor regulatory environment more conducive to the expansion of

formal employment in MSEs (see challenges below), it seems worthwhile to explore the

feasibility of broad access schemes that will help expand health care insurance and

pension coverage. In exploring policy options the potential impact of reforms on the

incentives to contribute under the existing system needs to be carefully examined. A

particular concern to bear in mind is that super-imposing non-contributory programs on

top of a contributory system may actually create incentives for informality.

ES. 25. Alleviate the burden of labor regulations on micro and small businesses,

especially regarding social benefits and firing costs. The burden of labor regulation in

Peru is among the highest in Latin America, as the first phase of this study documented.

For example, in the Doing Business indicators 2008, Peru had a difficulty of hiring index

of 44 (compared to 37 for the region on average). The new evidence uncovered in

preparation of this second phase provides further support to the conclusion that labor

regulations remain a barrier to formalization. The evidence compiled for this study

Page 17: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

17

suggests that benefits such as holiday pay and high firing costs are perceived to be among

the most important factors which deter businesses from including workers in their

payrolls. In addition, severance payments that workers receive de facto are substantially

(and somewhat unpredictably) lower than what workers are entitled to de jure. This adds

to the uncertainty about what the actual firing costs may turn out to be, and hence firing

costs and procedures may act as a deterrent to formal employment. Reducing firing costs

to bring them in line with the average de facto severance payments would reduce

uncertainty. An important caveat, however, applies to the case of micro businesses since

most of these entrepreneurs do not know about the reduced benefits and firing costs that

the Special Labor Regime for micro businesses allows. Expanding the coverage of this

special regime to larger businesses may provide an alternative, though crucially reform

efforts would be in vain if information failed to reach the MSEs.

ES. 26. Consider ways to improve the minimum wage regime so that they become

less of a binding constraint, including considering the appropriateness of region-

specific minimum wage rates. The survey of micro and small businesses conducted for

this study provides evidence that the minimum wage is perceived to be as too high,

especially for the smaller businesses. In fact, the statutory minimum wage is slightly

below the median wage for the economy as a whole. The level of the minimum wage

ranks high for businesses among the reasons why workers are not paid the minimum

wage. More than 70 percent of businesses with 1 to 5 workers consider that their business

is not productive enough to pay the minimum wage to workers. This proportion is lower

for larger businesses but even of those with 11 to 50 workers, more than half of surveyed

businesses consider that they are not profitable enough to pay the minimum wage to

workers.

ES. 27. Once an adequate regulatory labor regime is in place it is important to

enforce it firmly and consistently. The combination of weak enforcement and overly

strong de jure labor regulations may undermine the rule of law and cultivate a social

norm of non-compliance. This calls for improvements in the regulatory regime, as noted

above. It also calls for a more effective enforcement once an adequate regime is in place.

The role of weak enforcement was also highlighted by the results of the survey. The

finding that the share of workers outside the payroll is higher than the share of workers

earning the minimum wage indicates that there are workers for which the minimum wage

is not the binding constraint impeding formalization. In turn, this finding suggests that

opportunistic behavior may be a driving force of labor informality, at least for some

workers. Moreover, the analysis found some support for the role of labor inspection rates

in affecting the probability of a business to employ workers under formal labor relations.

Improving the enforcement of labor laws will likely require an increase in resources

given the number of inspectors that the Ministry of Labor (MTPE) currently has at its

disposal. In this regard, the addition of 104 new labor inspectors to the MTPE, bringing

the total to 450, brought the number of inspectors to around 1 per 40,000 members of the

economically active population. This is still a low figure as Peru would need

approximately three times as many inspectors to reach the benchmark suggested by ILO

(2006) for industrializing countries of 1 inspector per 15,000 workers. Peru would still

need to almost double its number of inspector to reach the ratios observed in Argentina,

Brazil, or Chile, all of which have ratios of 1 inspector per 20,000 to 25,000 workers.

Page 18: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

18

Page 19: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

19

1. Introduction

1.1 This report, the second part of a programmatic study, focuses on the

trajectories of Peruvian businesses towards formality. This is the second phase of a

programmatic study on informality in Peru the objective of which is to analyze the causes

and effects of informality so as to provide policy options for a reform agenda. The first

phase took stock of the characteristics of informality, and focused on how the labor

market and labor legislation in Peru may be associated with informality (World Bank,

2007a). While the first phase of the study noted strong incentives to remain informal,

particularly due to labor and tax codes, it also argued the need to better understand the

businesses’ perspective on the costs and benefits of informality and to map the steps that

businesses need to take towards formalization.

1.2 ‘Formality’ is better understood as having different dimensions. It is well

known that informality is not a straightforward concept (Box 1). As a result, it is not easy

to agree on a single definition of informality or to measure it easily. The important

conclusion to draw from this is that informality can be better understood as being a multi-

dimensional concept covering areas such as business licensing, tax, labor relations, and

(as discussed below) also business incorporation. The focus of this study is to document

the trajectories of businesses towards formality along these different dimensions. The

interest in the trajectories towards formality is rooted in the fact that, regardless of their

size, most businesses have some characteristics that are to a degree informal. Hence,

answers to questions about which dimensions of formality are achieved first, and why,

can help the policy discussion on how to reduce different aspects of informality.

Box 1: What do we mean by informality?

The term informality means different things to different people. Some are concerned about

workers not enjoying the protection of existing labor laws, with the corresponding impact on

equity and welfare. Others are concerned about efficiency and productivity, as informality is seen

as being associated with firms that are too small. Informality is also a source of concern for those

who see it as eroding the legitimacy of public institutions and as suggestive of poor policy

regimes. Reflecting in part these different concerns, multiple measures of informality have been

advanced in the literature, commonly classified in two broad groups:

(i) The productive definition of informality, which focuses on the characteristics of the productive

unit. One such productive measure of informality is the one traditionally used by the International

Labor Organization, which defined the informal sector as economic units “with scarce or even no

capital, using primitive technologies and unskilled labor, and then with low productivity” (ILO

1991). To make this definition operational, it is common to assume that the self-employed, family

units, and micro-entrepreneurs and their employees fit under the description of activities with low

capital and low productivity and are therefore considered to represent informal employment.

(ii) The legalistic definition of informality, which focuses on coverage of workers by mandated

social protections. A common example of a measure of informality inspired by the legalistic

definition of informality is to consider that a worker without rights to a pension is an informal

worker. This approach has the advantage of recognizing that informal employment can be found

Page 20: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

20

in firms of all sizes and in all sectors of the economy. It is particularly useful in the case of Peru

since participation in the state pension system is mandatory for all workers on the payroll of a

firm (strictly speaking, this participation is optional for workers under the special labor regime for

micro firms with less than 10 employees, but participation in this regime is limited to only around

thirty thousand micro firms, see Box 4).

Informality covers many aspects, and in practice many indicators of informality are widely

applied. While helpful, the use of other proxies creates the potential for ambiguity in the meaning

of: ‘informality’. To that end, we will now make clear which proxy measure we are using for

informality.

This box draws from Chapter 1 of World Bank (2007b).

1.3 In this report we explore four of those dimensions of formality: business

licensing, tax, labor relations and pensions, and business incorporation. In this report

we take a pragmatic approach by exploring four dimensions of ‘formality’: business

licensing, tax, labor relations and pensions, and business incorporation. Some of these

dimensions are more easily understood as referring to the formality-informality divide: to

be formal a business has to comply with business licensing requirements and pay the

required taxes. Regarding labor relations, an entrepreneur could in principle have no

employees on the payroll and still be in full compliance with the law, as it is possible to

pay for services through a contractual relation that is not of an employment nature.

However, such a situation goes against the spirit of the labor protection legislation and, in

the legalistic definition of informality, is typically considered to be one of the dimensions

of informality. Finally, the report also considers one more dimension of formality: the

incorporation of a business as a separate legal entity. A business person can legally

operate as a natural person. But, as will be shown below, entrepreneurs themselves

consider this an important aspect of the formalization process. It is also worth stressing

that this report is not only concerned with illegal economic activity, which by definition,

cannot be conducted in a formal way.

1.4 The report has been designed and prepared in close cooperation with the

authorities to help draw implications for the Government’s priority of reducing the

size of the informal sector. This suggests that there is much to gain from a detailed

analysis of what is formal and informal at different stages of the development of a

business. Documenting the reasons why and when a business chooses to formalize and

the reasons why it may do so with regard to one facet of informality (say tax) but not

another (say labor) is of interest to Government authorities as they consider policies that

will help increase the speed with which businesses traverse the trajectories toward

formality. It is also an area where, as identified in the first phase of the study and the in

concept stage of this report, the World Bank can add value to the existing literature on

informality in Peru.

Page 21: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

21

Figure 1.1: Informality in Peru and other countries in Latin America and the Caribbean Percent of workers that are informal, according to different definitions

Informal workers (productive definition)

0

20

40

60

80

100

Hai

ti

Bol

ivia

Peru

Para

guay

Gua

tem

ala

Ecua

dor

Nic

arag

ua

Hon

dura

s

Col

ombi

a

Jam

aica

El S

alva

dor

Bra

zil

Mex

ico

Ven

ezue

la

Dom

inic

an R

ep.

Pana

ma

Arg

entin

a

Uru

guay

Cos

ta R

ica

Chi

le

Workers without a pension

0

20

40

60

80

100

Col

ombi

a

Gua

tem

ala

Bol

ivia

El

Salv

ador

*

Uru

guay

Para

guay

Bra

zil

Peru

Arg

entin

a*

Nic

arag

ua

Chi

le

Ven

ezue

la*

Mex

ico*

Ecua

dor

Workers without health insurance

0

20

40

60

80

100

Hai

ti

Ecua

dor

Peru

Para

guay

Nic

arag

ua

Gua

tem

ala

Jam

aica

El S

alva

dor

Arg

entin

a

Mex

ico

Ven

ezue

la

Col

ombi

a

Cos

ta R

ica

Chi

le

Workers without a contract

0

20

40

60

80

100

Nic

arag

ua

El S

alva

dor

Peru

Gua

tem

ala

Ecu

ador

Bol

ivia

Dom

inic

an

Rep

.

Mex

ico

Pana

ma

Chi

le

Note: Data for different countries do not all refer to the same year. * Refers only to salaried workers. Source: Gasparini and Tornarolli (2006) and ENAHO (2006) for Peru.

Page 22: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

22

1.5 The interest of the authorities in understanding the trajectories towards

formality stems from their development objective of reducing informality. The

Peruvian authorities’ interest is high compared to other countries in Latin America and

the Caribbean according to some measures (Figure 1.1). The Government has a formally

stated goal of reducing informality by one-third by 2011. Most recently in April 2008

President García referred to informality as the “slavery of the twenty-first century” and

stressed that, without access to a pension, the living standards in old age of many

Peruvians are at risk.1

1.6 The first phase of the study raised a number of questions about informality

in Peru that required additional data and further analysis. In broad terms, the first

phase of the study argued that informality is driven by: (i) strong incentives to remain

informal, particularly related to the high cost of labor and tax codes; (ii) bureaucratic

obstacles to formalization; (iii) insufficient incentives to become formal, including

greater access to credit, markets, and government-funded business services, combined

with enforcement and penalties for those who do not formalize; (iv) a pervasive “culture

of informality” that encourages regulation evasion; and (v) a frequently-changing array of

laws and regulations which inhibits long-range planning and acts as a disincentive to

formality. However, the first phase of the study also noted that it was often not possible

to identify which factors were most critical given the limited availability of data.

1.7 The path towards formality reflects the choices made by businesses to stay

informal or to formalize. This report explores why and how firms make those

choices. Regardless of the measure with which one proxies informality, a common thread

is the fact that informality reflects a lack of compliance with legal norms. This raises the

question as to why agents are not in compliance with the law. The answer to this question

has often been framed in terms of the exclusion of workers, which are involuntarily left

outside formal institutions and are also without the protections given to formal workers.

However, a second view emphasizes that there is an exit dimension to the actions of

agents, by which firms and workers may simply opt into informality not finding any net

benefit of interacting with the state (World Bank 2007b). A key objective of this report is

to contribute to a better understanding of this exit dimension of informality in Peru from

the perspective of the small business owner or self-employed person. To do so the World

Bank has gathered new firm-level data to complement existing information.2

1 The goal of reducing informality was stated by President García in his latest annual address on the

state of the nation on July 28, 2007. The reference to informality as the new slavery of the twenty-first

century is from remarks by President García to the press on April 23, 2008. 2 Phase I of the study was largely based on data from national household survey (ENAHO). The

literature on informality in Peru has been based mainly on the ENAHO and other household surveys.

For example, De la Roca and Hernández (2004) draw on the Encuesta Nacional de Niveles de Vida

conducted in May 2000 by the Instituto Cuánto. To the best of our knowledge the survey

commissioned as part of this report constitutes the first business-level survey with a focus on decisions

regarding formalization issues.

Page 23: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

23

1.8 To this end, this report provides new business-level evidence on the

determinants of informality in Peru. The main value added of this study is to draw

from new business-level data to shed light on the determinants of informality in Peru and

in the policy debate. Therefore, the focus throughout the text will be to present and

analyze this new information. Design and analysis of the research has been greatly

influenced by recent efforts to explain the phenomenon of informality in Latin America,

most notably the World Bank’s Informality. Exit and Exclusion flagship report of the

Latin American and Caribbean Vice-Presidency (World Bank, 2007b). For the sake of

brevity, references to broader regional trends and to theoretical considerations are kept to

a minimum throughout the text. The interested reader is referred to the flagship report for

a broader context and for a discussion of theoretical issues. For an international

perspective on informality in Peru the reader is referred to the report produced during the

first phase of this programmatic study.

1.9 By focusing on business-level data the report helps to fill a gap in the

literature. As noted in the first phase of this programmatic study there are only a limited

number of studies that address the determinants of informality in Peru using business-

level information. Jaramillo (2004) asked a sample of firms in the garment industry in

Lima for the reasons that explained their decision to become formal: 85 percent answered

access to more suppliers and customers; 70 percent answered access to credit from a

formal source; 63 percent to avoid the payment of fines and 40 percent to avoid the

payment of bribes. Yamada and Chacaltana (2007) document six successful cases of

firms expanding and generating employment. Access to exports markets was an

important factor for firm expansion in the cases studied. The Municipal Scorecard report

for 2007 asked firms that had obtained their business operating licenses and construction

permits the main reasons why they decided to go formal. These firms identified not

paying fines and law enforcement as the main reasons, while access to the judicial system

and better credit were ranked as the least important reasons. While informative, these

studies do not always provide systematic treatment of the different dimensions of

informality nor do they have a broad coverage in terms of the number of businesses

polled.

1.10 The report also studies the impact of informality on businesses’ profitability

and access to credit. The first contribution of the report is to study the factors affecting

informality controlling for a large number of business characteristics. A second

contribution of the report is to analyze the impact of those factors. This requires

econometric analyses that can establish the ‘causal’ links between the determinants of

informality and variables of interest such as profitability or access to finance. While these

analytical techniques have shortcomings, the estimates provide a contribution to the

discussion of informality in Peru as a careful econometric analysis of the impacts of

informality that was not available previously.

1.11 A key building block for the analysis in this report is a dedicated survey of

802 micro (up to 10 workers) and small (11 to 50 workers) businesses, both formal

and informal. The National Household Survey (Encuesta Nacional de Hogares,

ENAHO) provides a good basis for determining the extent of informality in Peru. It

allows us to provide a clear answer to the extent of informality according to the legalistic

Page 24: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

24

definition, since it contains information on whether the respondents to the survey are

covered by a pension or not. There is also information that can be used to construct a

measure of informality according to the productive definition (as was done in phase I of

this programmatic study). However, the objective of this study is to move one step further

and explore the impact and determinants of informality. To answer these questions we

need a firm-level data set of both formal and informal businesses that will allow us to

control for a large number of business characteristics such as size, age, education of the

owner, etc., that may be thought to affect the choices of firms on their trajectory towards

formality. To this end the World Bank commissioned a dedicated business survey, as

detailed in Box 2.3 While the survey conducted provides us with a cross-section of data

by including questions such as ‘how long did the business operate before obtaining a

license?’ it allowed us also to obtain information about the trajectories of businesses

towards formality.

Box 2: A dedicated survey to study informality in Peru

To better understand the factors behind informality in Peru the World Bank commissioned a

dedicated survey of businesses, both formal and informal. A total of 802 businesses were

interviewed face-to-face in five cities: Arequipa, Cusco, Huancayo, metropolitan Lima, and

Trujillo. These five cities were selected to reflect a cross-section of urban centers, accounting

for more than 10 million inhabitants in total or around 36 percent of Peru’s estimated

population. We restricted the survey to cities since urban informality has been the focus of the

debate in Peru, largely on account that it is perceived to be in cities where the potential for

reducing informality is greatest. In addition, informality in urban and rural areas may not share

common characteristics.

Conducting a survey of both formal and informal businesses poses the challenge that there is

no readily available census data to use as a frame from which to draw a random sample of

businesses. To ensure as much as possible a random sample of respondents, the sampling was

designed as a three step process. First, on the basis of the population census, a certain

geographical area within a city was selected at random. Second, an enumerator was sent to that

particular geographical area and was asked to list all businesses that could be found. While this

necessarily introduces some selection bias, it is a pragmatic approach for addressing the

complex issue of how to construct a frame from which a random sample can be drawn with

limited resources. It is also an approach that has been successfully used in other cases (De Mel

et al., 2007). Third, a random sample of businesses to interview was drawn from that list.

For businesses in metropolitan Lima (except those in transport) the first and second steps of the

methodology were unnecessary since the survey firm already had a proprietary census carried

out in 2007 of more than 100,000 firms covering the sectors of activity of interest. A pure

random sample of informal and formal businesses would have resulted in a very large number

of single-person businesses and very few businesses of 6 to 10 employees and of 11 to 50

employees. Therefore stratification quotas by city, industry, and firm size were applied to

ensure that the sample covered sufficient observations to enable a statistical analysis of the

results by different firm sizes and other categories (see Chapter 2 for descriptive statistics).

3 The design of the survey has benefited from the experience with a similar survey recently undertaken

for World Bank (2008a), Republic of Bolivia: Policies for Increasing Firms’ Formality and

Productivity (Report No. 40057-BO).

Page 25: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

25

Only businesses operating in seven sectors of the economy were surveyed. The selected sectors

were chosen to represent a broad cross-section of manufacturing and services activities: (i)

shoe and leather manufacturing; (ii) textile and apparel manufacturing; (iii) wood products and

furniture manufacturing; (iv) metal products manufacturing; (v) retail sales of foodstuffs; (vi)

transport by land; and (vii) restaurants and hotels. In 2006 the combined seven groups of

activity accounted for around 30 percent of Peru’s economically active population, and a

somewhat higher figure of employment in micro and small firms. Transport by land accounted

for 4.6 percent of GDP in 2006, restaurants and hotels for 3.7 percent, textile and leather

manufactures for 2.2 percent, metal products manufacturing for 1.2 percent, and wood products

and furniture manufacturing for 0.5 percent of GDP. However, it is not possible to exactly

match the weight of the retail sales of foodstuffs in GDP (retail activities as a whole account

for around 14 percent of GDP).

1.12 Focus groups, in-depth interviews, and case studies complemented the

quantitative data gathered from the quantitative survey. The dedicated survey of

businesses was complemented with qualitative information gathered from seven focus

groups and 15 in-depth interviews with micro and small entrepreneurs. Participants in

focus groups were micro and small entrepreneurs with at least two years in business. This

allowed us to probe focus group participants about their trajectory towards formality.

Participants in focus groups were grouped according to the size of their businesses. In

particular, two focus groups were dedicated to entrepreneurs with up to 4 workers, two

more for entrepreneurs with 5 to 10 workers, and three groups with owners of businesses

with 11 to 50 workers. Participants in the focus groups undertook their business in one of

the following areas of activity: manufacturing (textiles and apparel, wood and furniture,

leather and shoes, metal products), retailing of foodstuffs, transport, hotels and restaurant,

and construction. The in-depth interviews were targeted at business owners who also took

an active role in an association of micro and small businesses (gremios), which tend to be

better informed. This ensured that the data gathering effort polled those better informed

micro and small business owners while avoiding that their presence in a focus group

would affect the group dynamic and that they would come to dominate the focus group

discussion. In-depth interviews were held with leaders representing associations of micro

and small businesses in a range of activities: manufacturing of wood products and

furniture (four interviews); manufacturing of metal products (three); textile and apparel

manufacturing (three); shoe and leather manufacturing (one); retail of foodstuffs (one);

transport (one); and construction (one). Different research guides were prepared for the

focus groups and for the in-depth interviews. Both the focus groups and in-depth

interviews took place in January 2008 in metropolitan Lima.

Page 26: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

26

Informality in the sectors selected for the survey

1.13 The degree of informality observed in the sectors selected for the survey is

close to the one seen for the economy as a whole (see Table 1.1). In addition to

allowing us to compare measures of the legalistic and productive definition of

informality, the ENAHO captures other characteristics of a business, where a respondent

works, that can be thought of as reflecting how formal or informal the business is. In

particular, the ENAHO contains questions on whether the worker has healthcare

coverage; has a contract or not; whether the employer is a business that is registered with

its own legal personality; and whether the business where the respondent works keeps

any accounting books. As noted in the first phase of the study, informality in Peru is high

regardless of the definition or aspect of it that one chooses to examine. As shown in

Table 1.1, the same is also the case for the sectors selected to be included in our

dedicated survey. However, the ENAHO is not a good source of information for

understanding the trajectories of businesses towards formality since it does not provide us

with information as to the reasons why businesses choose to remain informal or to

formalize.

Table 1.1: Measures of informality based on the household survey in the sectors selected for

the survey and in the economy

Percent of economically active population …

... informal

according to

the productive

definition*

...without

a pension

(legalistic

definition)

...without

health

coverage

...working

without a

contract

…working in

firms without

legal

personality

…working

in firms that

keep no

accounting

books

Aggregate of

selected sectors

for the survey

85.7 85.6 79.9 85.9 88.1 82.3

All economic

activities 75.9 80.8 71.7 73.4 81.5 76.9

Notes: Data for 2006. * See Appendix A for details on how this measure was constructed.

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO.

1.14 Informality affects all sectors of the economy selected for the survey but is

particularly high among retail firms. Informality is a phenomenon that affects all

sectors of the economy. The widespread prevalence of informality across sectors is

reflected in the sectors selected for the survey.4 Among the seven sectors selected for the

survey, the share of workers with a pension ranges from 71 percent in the case of metal

and machinery manufacturing to 89 percent in the case of retailers of foodstuffs and

4 The inclusion of retail and transport – two sectors traditionally highly informal – is also justified on the

basis that these are dynamic sectors. In fact, Chong et al. (2007) argue that one reason for the increase

in informality observed during the 1990s is precisely the structural change towards retail and transport.

Page 27: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

27

hotels and restaurants. Other measures of informality display a similar pattern, with retail

of foodstuffs having the highest share of workers without a contract (92 percent) and the

highest share of employees working in firms that are not registered with their own legal

personality (93 percent). Among the manufacturing sectors included in the survey the

share of workers without a pension is highest in footwear and leather manufacturing and

in furniture manufacturing (86 percent in both cases).

1.15 Informality is particularly high among micro firms (with 10 or less workers). In both the sectors selected for the survey and in the economy as a whole, informality is a

phenomenon that is highly correlated with firm size. As shown in Figure 1.2 the share of

workers without a pension is around 90 percent for firms with up to 10 employees. The

share of workers without a pension declines among those working in firms with 11 to 50

employees, although it is still relatively high at more than 60 percent. These data make it

clear that controlling for firm size, and any other observable characteristics of firms, is

essential to draw conclusions about the determinants of informality. The analysis

underpinning Figure 1.2, in addition to other tables and figures was repeated using the

different indicators of informality from the household survey, as reported in Table 1.1.

The results obtained using these additional indicators are reported in Figure A.2 to Figure

A.10 in Annex A.

Figure 1.2: Informality by firm size, for selected sectors and for the economy as a whole As measured by the ratio of workers without a pension in firms of different sizes (2006)

Sectors selected for the survey All economic activities

.5.6

.7.8

.91

Info

rma

lity p

reva

len

ce

1 to 5 6 to 10 11 to 50

Number of employees

.5.6

.7.8

.91

Info

rma

lity p

reva

len

ce

1 to 5 6 to 10 11 to 50

Number of employees

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO.

1.16 The five cities included in the survey are located in regions with a diverse

incidence of informality – within the high rates seen across the country. By including

businesses from Trujillo (La Libertad), Huancayo (Junín), and Cusco, the survey draws

from cities in regions where the share of workers without a pension is relatively high

(above 85 percent) compared to Lima and Arequipa (70 percent), as shown in Figure 1.3.

Page 28: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

28

Figure 1.3: Map of informality prevalence by region Percent of workers without a pension (2006)

Note: Informality rates are shown at the departmental level since this is the most disaggregated geographical unit for which the

annual ENAHO survey provides a representative sample of the population.

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO.

1.17 Even though urban areas are typically richer, the choice of cities for the

survey reflects a range of average incomes and incidence of informality. Informality

is highly correlated with income levels, as Figure 1.4 shows. This is an important factor

when designing any research into informality and when interpreting the results. In our

case, the inclusion of cities such as Cusco and Trujillo ensured that the dedicated survey

did not only cover the richest areas of the country. Finally, the positive correlation

88.5

83.9

83.7

85.2

89.0

70.8

60.4

71.8

71.8

71.5

88.4

87.195.4

96.0

85.1

85.5

93.0

95.8

88.5

94.5

94.7

90.1

91.8

94.2

68.6

Five less informal departments

Second five less informal departments

Third five less informal departments

Second five more informal departments

Five more informal departments

Legend

Five less informal departments

Second five less informal departments

Third five less informal departments

Second five more informal departments

Five more informal departments

Legend

Page 29: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

29

between average incomes and formality makes the importance of exploring possible

directions of causality very clear: is it that formality contributes to higher incomes or that

those with higher incomes self-select themselves into more formal arrangements? These

questions are explored in Chapter 3, which includes an analysis of the impact of

informality on the profitability of businesses.

Figure 1.4: Informality prevalence by region and income per capita Informality as measured by the ratio of workers without a pension (2006)

Amazonas

Ancash

Apurímac

Arequipa

Ayacucho

Cajamarca

Callao

Cusco

Huanca-

velica

Huánuco

Ica

JunínLa Libertad

Lambayeque

Lima

Loreto

Madre de Dios

Moquegua

PascoPiura

Puno

San Martín

Tacna

Tumbes

Ucayali

.6.7

.8.9

1In

form

alit

y p

revale

nce

4000 5000 6000 7000 8000 9000 10000 11000 12000

Average annual income per capita, Nuevos soles

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO and INEI.

1.18 The sectors selected for the survey are also representative of the economy as

a whole with regard to trends in informality. Informality, as measured by the share of

workers with a pension, has declined in the sectors selected for the survey in line with the

decline observed for the economy as a whole. As measured by the proportion of workers

without a pension, informality declined from around 87 percent in 2003 to around 80

percent in 2006. Informality also declined in the sectors selected for the survey, as shown

in the left panel of Figure 1.5. These declines in the level of informality have taken place

in a context of accelerating economic growth since 2004, as shown in the right panel of

Figure 1.5. This evidence suggests that while informality may be a persistent

phenomenon, strong economic growth has contributed to its reduction in recent years.

However, using alternative indicators of informality based on the ENAHO, there has

been no significant decline in recent years in the share of workers without a contract or

working in businesses without a separate legal personality or without accounting books

(Figure A.8 to Figure A.10 in Annex A).5 In addition, one has to bear in mind that the

5 While the relationship between long-run and short-run informality has not been formally examined

here, this evidence suggests the possibility that, while different measures of informality are typically

highly correlated, different ‘dimensions’ of informality may respond faster than others to transient

Page 30: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

30

decline in informality, as measured by the lack of access to a pension, has required ever

increasing rates of economic growth, as shown in the right panel of Figure 1.5.

Figure 1.5: Informality rate and economic growth, 2003 to 2006 Informality as measured by the percent of workers without a pension

Informality rate for sectors selected for the

survey and for all economic activities

Informality rate (all economic activities)

and economic growth

70

75

80

85

90

95

2003 2004 2005 2006

Info

rmal

ity

rat

e

All economySelected sectors

70

75

80

85

90

95

3.5% 4.5% 5.5% 6.5% 7.5% 8.5%

Real GDP growth

Info

rmal

ity

rat

e

2005

20032004

2006

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO and INEI.

1.19 The remainder of the report reviews, in turn, the determinants of informality

(Chapter 2) and its impact (Chapter 3). As part of the analysis of the determinants of

informality the study identifies the trajectories of micro and small businesses towards

formality. In addition, a number of boxes in the report pay particular attention to: (i)

taxation of micro and small enterprises; (ii) sector-specific labor regimes; and (iii) unfair

dismissal costs. These topics were selected in close cooperation with the authorities of the

Government of Peru to address specific queries that the authorities had. In this regard the

report contributes to the knowledge base for policy-makers by: (i) quantifying the tax

burden on new capital investment by micro and small businesses under different tax

regimes: (ii) providing a detailed compilation of labor regulations affecting different

sectors; and (iii) producing a new data set that allows for a comparison between the

payments to which a dismissed worker is entitled de jure and the actual payments that the

dismissed worker receives after a conciliation process.

shocks. For a discussion of the link between long-run and short-run changes in informality see Loayza

and Rigolini (2006).

Page 31: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

31

2. Determinants of informality

Scope: To explore why businesses choose to keep certain aspects of their

operations informal we ask businesses themselves, through the dedicated

survey and focus groups. We ask about businesses’ perceptions but also about

their actual level of formalization along a range of dimensions and about a

large number of characteristics of their businesses. This allows us to explore

the determinants of informality econometrically.

Structure: The chapter is structured in four sections.

First, we provide information about the characteristics of the sample of

businesses from which we are drawing information.

Second, we report what our respondents tell us, through the survey and focus

groups, about the factors that drive their choices regarding formality and

informality along a range of issues. This section is structured along four

broad dimensions of informality: (i) business licensing; (ii) paying taxes; (iii)

labor relations and access to a pension; and (iv) business incorporation.

Third, the chapter exploits the information from the survey to establish

econometrically what factors affect the probability that a business is formal

(as captured through some characteristics associated with formality). In

addition, the chapter includes a number of boxes reviewing specific issues

selected with the authorities as areas of particular interest: (a) taxation of

micro and small enterprises; (b) sector-specific labor regimes; and (c) unfair

dismissal costs.

Fourth, the chapter sums up the information from the different data sources,

quantitative and qualitative, to describe the common paths towards formality

among micro and small businesses.

Page 32: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

32

A. Who is our source of information?

2.1 Businesses surveyed cover a broad spectrum of micro and small enterprises... Details of the actual businesses surveyed in terms of their size, location, and sector of

activity is provided in Table 2.1. The qualitative data-gathering effort also took account

of the heterogeneity of micro and small businesses. Therefore different focus groups were

arranged for businesses of different sizes. In total, four focus groups were conducted with

businesses of 10 or less workers and three focus groups were conducted with businesses

of 11 to 50 workers. An additional source of information gathered was through in-depth

interviews with micro and small business owners who are also representatives in

associations (gremios) of micro and small businesses.

Table 2.1: Number of businesses surveyed

By size No. of

businesses By city No. of

businesses By sector No. of

businesses

1 – 3 workers 226 Arequipa 111 Shoe and leather 117

4 – 5 workers 195 Cusco 108 Textile and apparel 119

6 – 10 workers 201 Huancayo 93 Wood products 126

11 – 20 workers 149 Lima (met.) 368 Metal products 118

21 – 50 workers 31 Trujillo 122 Retail foodstuffs 105

Transport 95

Restaurants 122

Total 802 Total 802 Total 802

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

2.2 … and a wide range of situations regarding how formal or informal they are. The ‘dimensions of informality’ that are explored in this chapter can be grouped into four

broad categories: (i) business licensing; (ii) paying taxes; (iii) labor relations; and, (iv)

incorporation of businesses as separate legal entities. Some of these dimensions of

informality, like paying taxes and business licensing, are directly linked with the

definition of informality as not being compliant with the laws and regulations. Others,

like labor relations, have a direct link with the legalistic definition of informality

discussed above (as it covers the extent to which workers have access to a pension).

Finally, while a businessperson can operate formally as a natural person, the registration

of the business as a separate legal entity emerged from the focus groups as a step that has

important implications for a business. Table 2.2 shows the characteristics of the

businesses surveyed along those four dimensions of informality, including a breakdown

by size of business.

Page 33: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

33

Table 2.2: Selected informality characteristics of surveyed businesses Percent of businesses surveyed

All

businesses

1 – 5

workers

6 – 10

workers

11 – 50

workers

Business licensing

Firm has municipal license 67 59 67 83

Firm has permanent municipal license 51 44 50 67

Taxes

Firm pays taxes* 69 56 77 89

Percent of sales reported for tax purposes** 53 51 58 53

Firm has RUC number 78 65 90 96

Firm files under RUS 28 33 31 14

Firm files under Special Regime (RER) 11 7 19 11

Firm files under General Regime 38 24 38 70

Firm never gives facturas or boletas 19 29 11 6

Labor relations

Firm has no workers with a labor contract 83 92 83 63

Firm has no workers with health insurance 71 83 71 45

Firm has no workers with pension coverage 83 93 84 59

Business incorporation

Firm has limited liability (SA, SRL, SAC) 17 6 16 44

Sample size 802 421 201 180

Notes: * Businesses were asked to detail their outlays for a month and to include how much they pay in taxes in that month. The figure

reported in the table represents the share of businesses which reported a positive amount being paid in taxes; ** The question asked was: “Let us suppose that the true sales of a business are 1,000 soles a month. How much do you think that a business owner like

yourself would report for tax purposes?”

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

2.3 Bigger businesses are more formal across all dimensions of formality but are

still largely informal regarding labor relations and often operate as natural persons.

There are differences in the degree of informality along the different dimensions of

informality analyzed and for businesses of different sizes. Bigger businesses, especially

those with 11 to 50 workers, are more formal than smaller businesses. However, there is

low formalization with regard to labor issues even among businesses with 11 to 50

workers: 59 percent of the businesses of that size surveyed have no workers with pension

coverage and 63 percent have no workers with a written contract. Similarly, less than half

of the businesses with 11 to 50 workers are incorporated as a separate legal entity with

limited liability. Among businesses with 11 to 50 workers, formality along the other

Page 34: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

34

dimensions is much greater: 83 percent have a municipal license and 89 percent pay

taxes. However, the assessment of how much income goes unreported to the tax

authorities is similar for businesses of different sizes. (Additional breakdowns by city and

sector of activity can be found in Annex B.)

2.4 Smaller businesses are relatively formal with regard to business licensing and

paying taxes. While micro businesses of up to 10 workers are largely informal with

regard to labor relations, they are relatively formal with regard to getting a municipal

license and paying taxes. Even among businesses with 1 to 5 workers, 59 percent have a

municipal license; 56 percent pay taxes; and 65 percent have a tax (RUC) number. The

share of businesses with a RUC number increases to 90 percent among businesses with 6

to 10 workers. Smaller businesses are relatively more sophisticated regarding tax issues

than may have been expected: 24 percent of businesses with 1 to 5 workers report filing

taxes under the general regime.6 In fact, some large businesses use the simplified tax

regime (designed for small businesses) and some small ones use the general tax regime

(designed for larger businesses), an issue which will be explored further below.

2.5 The survey data confirms that there are different stages along the continuum

from informality to formality. The survey provides us with a large number of formality

characteristics for our sample of firms. To study which combinations of formality are

most common we use principal components analysis. This allows us to identify which

characteristics of informality are interrelated and can be grouped together. The results

from this exercise are provided in Figure 2.1, showing that formality along the

dimensions of business licensing and paying taxes are most common.

Figure 2.1: Share of surveyed businesses at different degrees of formality Percent of firms by groups of formality characteristic

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

1 to 5 workers 6 to 10 workers 11 to 50 workers

Other combinations of formality

RUC, municipal license, all workers with

labor contract, and limited liability

RUC, municipal license, and all workers

with labor contract

RUC, municipal license, and limited liability

Municipal licenseand RUC

RUC only

Municipal license only

Nothing

Note: The underlying data is reported in the appendix in Table A.8.

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

6 The breakdown of businesses filing under the different regimes in our sample (among those with a

RUC number: 36% file under RUS, 14% under RER, and 49% under the general regime) is similar to

the breakdown for all firms registered with SUNAT. Among the 834,000 firms with sales under

360,000 soles in 2006, 41% were under RUS, 10% under RER, and 49% under the general regime.

Page 35: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

35

B. What do micro and small business owners tell us?

2.6 The pattern of selective formalization as businesses grow reflects the

perception of costs and benefits associated with each dimension of formality. The

focus group technique and the in-depth interviews with micro and business persons

provide us with some insight into the decision-making process regarding formalization.

Table 2.3 summarizes the key considerations when making those decisions as reported by

micro and small entrepreneurs in the focus groups and interviews.

Table 2.3: Benefits and costs of formalizing perceived by micro and small business owners

Issue Benefits Costs Key rationale for

decisions regarding

formalization

Dominant

force driving

formali-

zation

Munici-

pal

business

license

Informal

(not

having a

license)

- Avoid paying the

license fee

- Avoid heavy

bureaucracy

- Possibility of fines

and payments to

inspectors

Municipal license is

perceived to convey no

benefits and as a heavy

bureaucratic burden, often

unreasonably enforced.

As firms grow and are

more easily detected, they

obtain the license to avoid

repeated fines. Firms

operating behind closed

doors further delay

obtaining the license.

Enforcement

Formal

(having a

license)

- Avoiding fines - Annual fees

- High cost of dealing

with the bureaucracy

- Fines still possible

due to unreasonable

inspections

Taxes Informal

(not

paying,

no RUC,

no use of

receipts)

- Avoid paying

taxes

- Selling without

receipts makes tax

evasion easier

- Possibility of fines if

detected

- Lost customer base

due to inability to

issue receipts

Registering with the tax

authority (getting RUC

number) is perceived to be

easy and not expensive.

Very limited information

about the tax regime –

decisions which are left to

the accountant.

As firms grow the risk of

being detected increases

and the need to issue

receipts makes firms

register with the tax

authority and pay taxes.

Enforcement

and

expanding

customer

base.

Key role

played by

accountant

(choosing tax

regime for

smaller

firms).

Formal

(paying,

having

RUC,

using

receipts)

- Avoiding fines

- Slightly better

access to credit

for larger amounts

- Paying the

accountant

- Tax payments,

perceived to be too

high (same tax rate

for all businesses

draws criticism)

Labor

relations

Informal

(no staff

in pay-

roll)

- Avoid paying

social benefits

- Greater flexibility

in labor relations

- More incentives

for productivity

- None mentioned

(some recognize the

need for health care

coverage but provide

for core group of

workers privately)

Preference for pay by

piece rate (on grounds of

productivity) and desire

for flexibility dominate

among smaller firms.

Firms claim that workers

prefer higher take-home

pay instead of benefits.

Enforcement is not a key

factor – as labor

inspections are rare.

Lack of

enforcement

and need for

flexibility.

Being able to

sell to larger

firms/abroad

(though this is

generally a

weak factor)

Formal

(staff in

payroll)

- None mentioned - Social benefits and

minimum wage are

too costly and

discourage hard work

- Makes firing costly

Page 36: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

36

Issue Benefits Costs Key rationale for

decisions regarding

formalization

Dominant

force driving

formali-

zation

Business

incorpo-

ration

Informal

(work as

natural

person)

- None mentioned

(perhaps unaware

of the

requirements for

filing under RUS)

- Limits customer base

(cannot sell to the

state)

- Lack of a business

brand limits

customer base (large

firms do not consider

you credible)

Large differences across

firm size: smaller firms

see no benefits and fear

high costs. Larger firms

already established as

separate legal entities see

broad range of benefits

and point to limited costs.

The requirement to be a

natural person to file taxes

under the RUS was not

raised, possibly reflecting

the fact that choices about

tax regimes are not made

directly by the business

owner.

Expanding

customer base

(selling to the

state and

larger firms)

and improved

access to

credit.

Key role

played by

accountant

(providing

information

about what it

entails).

Formal

(separate

legal

entity)

- Expand customer

base (state, larger

firms, exporting)

- Some perceive

slightly better

access to credit

- Larger firms note

the benefit of

protecting own

capital

- Businesses with 1 to

5 workers fear high

fixed and recurrent

costs if setting up as

a separate legal

entity

Source: World Bank focus groups and in-depth interviews with micro and small businesses.

Business licensing

2.7 The procedures for obtaining the municipal license draw heavy criticism

from micro and small businesses. Evidence from the focus group analysis suggests that

the municipal license is perceived to be an unnecessarily burdensome bureaucratic hurdle

that conveys no benefits to the micro and small entrepreneur. The safety inspection

(certificado de inspección técnica de seguridad en defensa civil) is perceived more as an

opportunity for municipalities to obtain revenue from businesses than as a legitimate

means to ensure the safety of operations. Checking compliance with zoning requirements

is also perceived to be unnecessarily burdensome, as it is claimed that it may also result

in an additional inspection. The business polled did not perceive the benefits of such

regulations.7 As an interviewee put it: “my business is located in an industrial park and I

still have to pay for them to come and check that this is an area where one can set up a

manufacturing business.” There is also the perception that municipal licenses need to be

renewed every year, especially among the micro business owners, that a business needs

to get a different license for every type of activity that they conduct. Overall, the micro

and small entrepreneurs that were polled consider that the municipal license conveys no

benefits to the business owner. A small entrepreneur that participated in one of the focus

groups for businesses with 5 to 10 workers put it most starkly when he commented on the

municipal license: “it is an obligation; it does not give you any benefit.”

7 Public policy has a legitimate role to play in terms of zoning and planning to avoid negative outcomes

such as: unrestricted growth that does not follow basic safety codes for construction or operation: or

significant levels of pollution.

Page 37: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

37

2.8 Businesses have not yet perceived the recent improvements in the municipal

licensing framework. To some extent businesses’ perceptions of municipal licensing do

not reflect the latest changes in the regulatory framework, by which municipal licenses

are to be issued with indefinite validity and can encompass several areas of activity

(Framework Law of Municipal Licenses, Law 28976 of January 20, 2007). Evidence

from the municipal licensing simplification project Tramifácil, supported by IFC,

suggests that improvements in the municipal licensing administration are taking place, as

reported in the IFC Municipal Scorecard.8 The cost of the municipal license in 2007

ranged from 1.7 percent of per capita GDP in Lima to 9.7 percent of per capita GDP in

Huancayo. These figures are relatively high compared to a selection of 65 municipalities

in the Latin America and the Caribbean region monitored by the IFC Municipal

Scorecard. In fact Huancayo was the lowest ranked municipality of all 65, and Lima,

while being the highest ranked in Peru, was only the nineteenth among the regional

sample.

2.9 The probability of being detected is the key factor affecting the decision to

obtain a municipal license. Business owners state that the key consideration when

deciding to obtain a municipal license is how likely they are to be inspected. Those

operating behind closed doors, such as textile workshops that operate in relative

quietness, are less likely to obtain a license even as the business grows. In some cases,

especially among micro firms, the entrepreneur prefer to pay off inspectors, allegedly for

as little as 20 nuevos soles according to information from the focus groups, rather than go

through the hassle of obtaining the license. Those that expressed a preference to pay off

inspectors said they do so partly because businesses fear that the license will become

invalid should they change their activity, for example if they change the type of goods

that they sell. As businesses grow, however, the costs of paying off inspectors increase

and the cost-benefit calculus prompts business owners to obtain the license.

2.10 The survey results lend support to two conclusions regarding licenses: (i)

they are perceived to have only one benefit: avoiding fines, and (ii) they are

perceived to pose a heavy bureaucratic burden. Results from our dedicated survey of

micro and small businesses confirms that most businesses perceive little benefit from

having a municipal license other than avoiding fines and being in compliance with the

law (left-panel in Figure 2.2). In addition, the perception that the process to obtain a

license is overly burdensome is also reflected in the survey results. Thus, among

businesses that do not have a license, factors that can be thought of as reflecting a

‘culture of informality’, such as the fact that no business like mine has a license, are not

stated as the main reason for not having a license. This result holds even among the

smallest businesses surveyed (right-panel in Figure 2.2) and is unsurprising given the

definition of informality that respondents from the in-depth interviews and focus groups

have in mind: an “informal” business is one that does not have a RUC number or

municipal license and that does not typically give receipts to its customers.

8 A reform to make public zoning clearer was also introduced in the municipality of Lima in parallel

with the operating licensing reform. The zoning reform aims to make it easier to find out what

activities are permitted in different parts of the city.

Page 38: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

38

2.11 There may be other channels, not explored in this report, whereby having a

municipal license may convey benefits to businesses, particularly regarding greater

access to credit. Not having a municipal operating license increases the probability for a

business to be closed down and is therefore a risk factor that, in principle, creditors may

want to take into account when allocating credit. We would therefore expect that

businesses with a municipal license have greater access to credit. However, as the left-

panel in Figure 2.2 shows, improving access to credit is perceived to be the main benefit

of having a license only by very few entrepreneurs, and the econometric analysis shown

in the next chapter does not refute this view. One possible explanation for these results is

that having a municipal license may not affect the probability of getting a relatively small

amount of credit. For larger amounts of credit the risks of a business being closed down

due to not having a license may become too high and the creditor may start asking for

evidence of a license after a certain loan amount. Given the design of our research it is

not possible to corroborate or refute this hypothesis, simply because most businesses

surveyed may not be sufficiently big to have crossed the threshold where not having a

license may be a constraining factor for access to credit. These issues are explored further

below.

Page 39: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

39

B. What is the impact of informality on access to credit?

Figure 2.2: Benefits from having a municipal license and reasons not to have one Percent of businesses

Main benefit of having a license

(single answer) Main reason not to have a license

(single answer)

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workers

Other

To access credit

To issue receipts

To avoid fines

To comply withthe law

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workers

No business likemine has a license

It is notcompulsory

It is too expensive

It is too difficultto get

250 135 149Number of

respondents

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workers

No business likemine has a license

It is notcompulsory

It is too expensive

It is too difficultto get

171 66 31 Number of

respondents

Note: Other includes ‘to avoid bribes’, ‘to attract new clients’, and ‘none’.

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

2.12 Cost-benefit calculations drive businesses’ decision to obtain a license,

enforcement plays a key role. Besides asking about the main reason for not having a

municipal license, the survey also questioned business owners without a license in more

detail about whether certain reasons had played a role or not in their decision not to have

a license. The results suggest that factors related to the costs of getting a license were

consistently perceived as more important than lack of information or other factors that

one can think of as reflecting a ‘culture of informality’ (Table 2.4). A detailed

econometric analysis is presented below in section ‘C. Econometric analysis of the

determinants of informality.’ For now, it is simply worth noting that the econometric

results are consistent with the view that businesses in sectors of activity that are more

visible to the authorities are more likely to obtain a license. However, as the regression

analysis will show, a variable specifically capturing the probability of inspection by city

and by industry fails to significantly explain the probability of a business obtaining a

municipal license. This latter result could reflect difficulties in distinguishing

econometrically between the information captured in the different variables (the sector-

specific variables and the variable with the inspection rate). Additionally, it could also

reflect the possibility that, as businesses internalize the higher probability of being

detected by being more likely to obtain the license, the municipalities do not need to

inspect those businesses all that often. Therefore, ex post, there would be no significant

difference in inspection rates by sector.

Table 2.4: Reasons for not having a municipal license

In brackets the percent of businesses without a municipal license that reported that this factor

was one reason why they do not have a license

Page 40: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

40

Notes: Based on responses by the 268 businesses without a license. See Table A.11 in the annex for a breakdown by business size. *

This factor may also reflect genuine information constraints.

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Cost-benefit factors ‘Culture of informality’ factors

More

important

The process is too time – consuming

(69 percent)

The costs of operating a business with a

license are too high (63 percent)

The process is too expensive

(56 percent)

My business is too small to have a

license (57 percent)

I see no benefits in getting it

(55 percent)

Less

important

The forms are too complicated

(46 percent)

There is no obligation to get it

(46 percent)

No point obtaining it since fines are rare

(37 percent)

No business like mine has a license

(42 percent)

To get the license they ask for bribes

(36 percent)

I do not know how to obtain it*

(40 percent)

Page 41: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

41

Paying taxes

2.13 Obtaining a RUC number is relatively easy, but business owners know little

about tax issues and often rely on third-parties for decisions regarding taxes. Evidence from the focus groups suggests that obtaining a RUC number is straightforward

and imposes a limited burden. Having a RUC number and paying taxes (on some of the

income) are indeed considered to be core aspects of what constitutes a ‘formal’ business.

As for paying taxes, focus group participants were in general unable to explain the

reasons behind the choice of regime (this contrasted with the relatively clear views on

other issues). There appeared to be a limited understanding of the tax obligations under

different tax regimes. What emerged was that in many cases, decisions regarding tax

issues were delegated by the business owner to an accountant or some other person who

is perceived to be better-informed than the business owner.

2.14 Having a RUC number is perceived to have some benefits, mainly through

expanding the customer base and improving access to credit. In contrast with the

negative view on the municipal license, the focus groups and interviews with micro and

small businesses suggest that having a RUC number conveys concrete benefits. Having

an RUC number is perceived to allow the business to grow its customer base because one

can issue receipts and hence sell to formal businesses. A small furniture manufacturer put

it simply: “some customers place large orders and demand a receipt” while another

noted that “I was working with firms and needed to issue receipts, that’s why I got the

RUC.” In addition, some interviewees perceive that having a RUC number improves

access to credit and overall, the positive aspects of having a RUC number are deemed to

outweigh the costs, which are mainly the perception of a greater monitoring by the tax

authorities. The result that having a RUC number is perceived to have the benefit of

attracting clients because of the ability to issue receipts finds support in the survey results

(Figure 2.3).

Figure 2.3: Benefits from having a RUC number and reasons not to have one Percent of businesses

Main benefit of having a RUC number

(single answer) Main reason not to have a RUC number

(single answer)

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workers

Other

To access credit

To avoid fines

To issue receipts

To comply withthe law

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workers

No business likemine has a RUCnumberIt is too expensive

It is notcompulsory

It is too difficultto get

273 181 173Number of

respondents

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workers

No business likemine has RUC no.

It is too expensive

It is notcompulsory

It is too difficultto get

120 18 6 Number of

respondents

Note: Other includes ‘to avoid bribes’, ‘to attract new clients’, and ‘none’.

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 42: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

42

2.15 The survey also provides information on the use of the different tax regimes

available to micro and small businesses. Corporate income taxation is structured in a

three-tier system: the general regime and two special regimes for MSMEs: the RUS and

the RER. The simplified regime (RUS) is aimed mainly at natural persons. The RUS is a

single tax (monotributo) that substitutes both the corporate income tax and the sales tax

(Impuesto General a las Ventas, IGV). The RER does not replace one’s liability for IGV.

The key features of these different regimes are provided in Table 2.5. An overview of tax

regimes for small enterprises in Latin America is presented in Table A.1 in the annex.

Table 2.5: Overview of corporate income taxation

Simplified Regime

RUS (Régimen Único Simplificado)

Special regime

RER (Régimen Especial de

la Renta)

General

Regime

Rationale Single tax (monotributo) that replaces

both IGV and corporate income tax

Simplified corporate income

tax but liable for VAT

Tax liability on

net income

Can expenses be

deducted from corporate income?

No No Yes

IGV liability? Not liable. Cannot issue receipts

(facturas) that generate IGV credit

Liable Liable

Qualifying criteria

Annual turnover Maximum 360,000 Nuevos soles Maximum 360,000 Nuevos

soles

None

Assets Maximum 70,000 Nuevos soles Maximum 87,500 Nuevos

soles

None

Legal entity restrictions

Only for natural persons (and very

restricted legal entities)

Natural persons and legal

entities

All

Type of activity All, with some exceptions (e.g., transport,

show business, notaries)

All, with some exceptions

(e.g., transport, construction, medical)

All

Tax liability Fixed monthly quota as follows:

Cate-gory

If gross monthly

turnover (soles)

and total monthly

purchases (soles)

Monthly quota

(soles)

1 < 5,000 < 5,000 20

2 < 8,000 < 8,000 50

3 <13,000 <13,000 200

4 <20,000 <20,000 400

5 <30,000 <30,000 600

1.5% of turnover for

manufacturing and commerce;

2.5% of turnover for services

30% of net

income

Bookkeeping

requirements

None RUC number.

Register of sales and purchases, and balances

RUC number.

14 accounting books in total

Note: The following changes were introduced In December 2006: (i) the maximum annual turnover to qualify for RUS

and RER was raised from 240,000 soles to 360,000 soles; (ii) the tax rates under the RER were lowered for

manufacturing and commerce businesses from 2.5% to 1.5% of gross income, and from 3.5% to 2.5% of gross income

for businesses in the service sector; (iii) the physical parameters used to determine the eligibility of firms for RUS and

RER (number of employees, locations, and electricity consumption) were removed.

Source: Based on information provided by SUNAT.

Page 43: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

43

2.16 Many businesses with a low turnover file taxes under the general regime. In

addition, some businesses with a relatively high turnover file taxes under the simplified

and special regimes, as shown in Figure 2.4. This adds to the evidence presented in Table

2.2, by which 24 percent of businesses with 1 to 5 employees file taxes under the general

regime. The fact that some small businesses file under the general regime suggests a high

level of sophistication in the decisions affecting tax issues. This contrasts, however, with

the findings from the focus groups and interviews. How can these two be reconciled? An

answer may be found in the role played by the accountant regarding tax filing issues. It

appears that whoever makes decisions on taxes for the businesses, and often this may be

the accountant, has a sophisticated understanding of the incentives and disincentives

behind the different tax regimes.

2.17 Some businesses with a high turnover and employees are filing under the

simplified regimes. For a few businesses filing under both the RUS and the RER, the

turnover declared to the survey is actually higher than the actual limit for those regimes.

Businesses may be choosing regimes for which they ought not to qualify. But, more

importantly, the overall distribution by turnover for businesses filing under different

regimes (Figure 2.4) is not much different across tax regimes. In our sample, 14 percent of

businesses with 11 to 50 employees file taxes using the RUS. The RUS system is an

appropriate instrument for taxing micro enterprises. However, the RUS imposes a

relatively high tax burden on investment (see Box 3 for calculations of the marginal

effective tax rate on incremental investment), which suggests that a factor for larger

businesses remaining under the RUS is to pass off as smaller businesses and avoid paying

that tax.

2.18 These filing patterns contrast with the goal of having small businesses under

the special regimes and larger businesses under the general regime. The overlap of

tax regimes for businesses of different sizes and turnovers presents an unclear picture of

the underlying motivations of choosing one regime over another. In addition to tax

evasion, mentioned above in the context of larger businesses’ filing under the RUS, other

factors also appear to play9 a role. In fact the survey provides some evidence on the

importance of ‘having always filed under that regime’ as a reason behind the choice of

tax regimes.10

10

The reason “I have always been in that regime” is the second-most important reason for businesses

filing under the RUS or the RER and the third-most important for those filing under the general

regime. See the detailed results in Table A.9 in the annex.

Page 44: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

44

Figure 2.4: Distribution by turnover of businesses filing under different tax regimes Percent of businesses filing within each of the tax regimes

Distribution of businesses filing under the simplified regime, RUS (sample = 228)

05

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Percent of busin

esses

up to 20

20 to 40

40 to 60

60 to 80

80 to

100

100 to 120

120 to 140

140 to 160

1600 to 180

180 to 200

200 to 220

220 to 240

240 to 260

260 to 280

280 to 300

300 to 320

320 to 340

340 to 360

360 to 380

380 to 400

400 to 420

420 to 440

440 to 460

460 to 480

480 to 500

Thousand Nuevos Soles

Distribution of businesses filing under the special regime, RER (sample = 86)

05

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Percent of busin

esses

up to 20

20 to 40

40 to 60

60 to 80

80 to 100

100 to 120

120 to 140

140 to 160

1600 to 180

180 to 200

200 to 220

220 to 240

240 to 260

260 to 280

280 to 300

300 to 320

320 to 340

340 to 360

360 to 380

380 to 400

400 to 420

420 to 440

440 to 460

460 to 480

480 to 500

Thousand Nuevos Soles

Distribution of businesses filing under the General Regime (sample = 304)

05

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Perc

ent of busin

esses

up to

20

20 to

40

40 to

60

60 to

80

80 to

100

100 to 120

120 to 140

140 to 160

1600

to 180

180 to 200

200 to 220

220 to 240

240 to 260

260 to 280

280 to 300

300 to 320

320 to 340

340 to 360

360 to 380

380 to 400

400 to 420

420 to 440

440 to 460

460 to 480

480 to 500

Thousand Nuevos Soles

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 45: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

45

2.19 The low take-up rate of the special tax regime (RER) calls for a review of tax

regimes, especially since the RER has some features that make it the most conducive

regime for investment. The special tax regime (RER) is in place mainly to protect the

VAT chain, as it requires businesses to comply with the VAT and to pay a presumptive

turnover tax. The analysis of the marginal effective tax rate suggests that the RER is in

fact the most conducive for investment (see Box 3). Yet, in our sample only 14 percent of

businesses with a RUC number file under the RER. Why does it have such a low take-up

rate?

Box 3: Understanding the incentives of tax regimes: the Marginal Effective Tax Rate of

the different corporate income tax regimes in Peru

How does the tax system affect the decision by economic agents to invest in capital? This box

addresses this question by providing a measure of the tax burden that a micro entrepreneur

faces when making an incremental investment. It does so by calculating Marginal Effective

Tax Rate (METR) on capital. The METR is a summary measure of the effective rate of tax

imposed on the rate of return generated by the last, or marginal, unit of capital that a firm

invests in. The METR therefore summarizes the effect of the total distortion in the rate of

return to capital imposed by the entire business tax system (through the rates of tax,

depreciation, capital taxes, special regimes, etc.).

The METR exploits the fact that, at the margin, an investment must earn a rate of return after

the payment of all business taxes which is equal to the hurdle rate of return required by the

business stakeholders. The derivation of the METR formula can be quite complicated (see

Annex G), but the idea can be conveyed with a simple example. Say the hurdle rate of return,

i.e., the minimum rate of return required by the stakeholders in the project after the payment of

all business taxes, is 10 percent. Say the business tax system is such that in order to earn a rate

of return of 10 percent after business taxes, an investment must earn a rate of return of 15

percent before business taxes. The METR is then 33 percent (determined as (0.15-0.10)/0.15).

The METR therefore measures the share of the investment’s pre-tax required rate of return

needed to cover the tax costs associated with the investment.

This box provides estimates of the METR for corporations resident in Peru for four broad

classes of capital: equipment, building, land, and inventory. We can then calculate the METR

across sectors with varying degrees on the use of different classes of capital: manufacturing,

agriculture, finance, tourism and mining (the actual capital mix used is based on international

survey data). The METR is calculated for small businesses (assumed to source their funds

domestically) under the three possible tax regimes (RUS, RER, and general regime) as well as

for large businesses (assumed to have access to funds in international financial markets). The

table below provides the main results of the analysis (see Annex H for details of the data and

assumptions used).

Page 46: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

46

Marginal Effective Tax Rates for corporations in different sectors of activity

Manufacturing Tourism Agriculture Mining Finance

Small businesses

RUS 44 28 27 48 39

RER 11 12 11 15 12

General Regime 28 35 19 31 32

Large businesses 24 32 15 36 28

Source: World Bank staff calculations.

The first thing to note is that METRs vary widely from the standard corporate income tax rate

of 30 percent. Taking the case of large businesses as the benchmark, the accelerated

depreciation rate of 20 percent on straight line basis lowers the METRs for manufacturing. On

the other hand the low depreciation rate for buildings of 3 percent on a straight line basis raises

the METR for investments in the tourism sector as this sector is more building intensive in its

asset pool. The METRs for investments in the mining sector are higher than the corporate tax

rate due to the royalty rate of 3 percent for large mining business and despite the accelerated

depreciation for buildings. The agriculture sector has an METR just equal to the lower

corporate tax for this sector of 15 percent with depreciation benefits and penalty just about

balancing each other. As large businesses can offset VAT on inputs from VAT on sales the

VAT imposes no burden on capital.

Second, the METRs for small businesses under the general regime are higher than for large

businesses reflecting the different assumptions about the source of funds (though in the case of

mining it is actually lower as they pay a lower mining royalty of 1 percent).

Third, businesses filing under the RUS face the highest METRs in most sectors of activity. The

METRs are particularly high in sectors that use relatively more machinery and equipment,

which is assumed to be sourced from the formal sector and hence liable to VAT. In those cases,

the burden on investment from not being able to offset VAT on inputs is quite high. In

manufacturing, the VAT exemption accounts for 31 percentage points (ppts) of the overall 44

percent METR. The equivalent figures for the VAT exemption for the other sectors are: 15 ppts

in tourism and agriculture; 31 ppts in mining; and 25 ppts in finance.

Fourth, the METR is lowest for small businesses filing under the special regime (RER). This is

primarily because businesses under this regime face lower input taxes on their machinery and

equipment and also a lower turnover tax as compared to the RUS regime. Even though

businesses cannot deduct expenses from corporate income (as they would under the general

regime), the lower turnover tax results in more beneficial treatment than under the general

regime. The METRs under the RER were somewhat higher prior to the December 2006 reform

(on average 3 percentage points higher) but still the METRs were the most favorable of all

regimes even before the turnover tax rates were lowered.

2.20 Compliance costs may be a reason for the low take-up rate of the special tax

regime (RER), but no estimate of tax compliance costs exists. The requirements under

the RER for book keeping and complying with IGV impose compliance costs on

business. Given the advantageous tax rate treatment, it would appear that high

compliance costs are offsetting the advantages of the RER. Businesses for which

complying with accounting requirements and IGV filing may be too cumbersome would

Page 47: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

47

remain under the RUS, thus discouraging businesses from progressing from one regime

to another. Businesses that are able to meet the accounting and IGV requirements may

also be in a position to meet the requirements under the general regime.11

Little is known,

however, about the actual compliance costs of meeting the accounting requirements vis-

à-vis the costs of complying with the IGV filing requirements. Measuring the costs of

compliance, a request from the Government on which the World Bank has already started

to work, for each of the separate regimes will help to identify administrative measures to

reduce those costs and to help define separate regimes.

2.21 The key factors driving the choice of tax regime are business characteristics

such as size and being incorporated as a separate legal entity with limited liability. The choice of tax regime among the surveyed firms was explored econometrically

through probit and multinomial logit models. These models help us to identify the factors

that, controlling for a large number of characteristics such as firm size, age, etc., have a

significant impact on the probability that a given business would choose one tax regime

over another. The results from these analyses suggest that firm characteristics are more

important than the characteristics of the owner such as the level of education. In

particular, larger businesses and those incorporated with limited liability are more likely

to file under more sophisticated regimes. The result that owner characteristics do not play

a role is consistent with the insight from the focus groups that tax decisions affecting

micro and small businesses are often made by an accountant.

2.22 Tax evasion motives may also be playing a role in the choice of tax regimes. The survey data also allows us to indirectly explore the impact of tax evasion on the

probability of filing under one regime or another. We do so by testing whether proximity

to a SUNAT office affects the choice of tax regime, on the basis that businesses located

closer to a SUNAT office are in fact more likely to be inspected and hence their

propensity to evade taxes maybe lower (see Annex B). In this regard, businesses that are

closer to an office of SUNAT are relatively more likely to file taxes under the special

regime (RER) (strictly speaking, businesses are less likely to file under the RUS and less

likely to file under the general regime). One interpretation of this result is that, faced with

a greater probability of being inspected, tax evasion motives may play a lesser role,

diminishing the attraction of the RUS (prone to under-reporting of sales given limited

inspections) and the general regime (where sales can be netted with expenses to end up

with little or no profits on which taxes are levied).

11

Although the marginal effective tax rate under the RER is lower than under the general regime, the

possibility of deducting expenses from corporate income may be particularly attractive to businesses as

it may make tax evasion easier. The result from the econometric analysis discussed above would be

consistent with this interpretation that the RER would not be the tax regime ‘of choice’ for evasion

purposes.

Page 48: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

48

Table 2.6: Results from econometric analyses of the choice of tax regime

Based on Choice

analyzed

Main results

Marginal

effects from

probit

analyses

RER

vs.

RUS

­ No effect of education of owner

­ More likely under RER if business has limited liability

­ More likely under RER in wood products (compared to restaurants)

­ More likely under RER in Arequipa, Trujillo, Cusco (compared to Lima)

­ More likely under RER for larger businesses (cf. to 1 to 5 workers)

RER

vs.

General

Regime

­ University educated more likely to be in the general regime (compared to

owners with less than secondary education)

­ More likely under general regime if business has limited liability

­ Less likely under general regime in shoe/leather (compared to restaurants)

­ Less likely under general regime in Arequipa, Trujillo, Cusco (cf. to Lima)

Marginal

effects from

multinomial

logit model

of choice

among the

three

alternatives

RUS

vs.

others

­ No effect of any owner characteristics

­ Less likely if business has limited liability

­ Less likely in businesses with 6 to 10 or 11 to 50 workers

­ Less likely the closer the business is to a SUNAT office

RER

vs.

others

­ More likely in businesses with 6 to 10 workers than 5 or less

­ More likely in Arequipa than Lima

­ No other factor is significant. The limited sample size (86 businesses) may

be a factor affecting results

General

regime

vs.

others

­ No effect of any owner characteristics

­ More likely among larger businesses (11 to 50 workers) and those with

limited liability

­ Less likely the closer the business is to a SUNAT office

­ Less likely in Huancayo and Cusco than in Lima

­ More likely if business is in metal products, less likely in shoe/leather

Note: See Annex B for estimation results.

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

2.23 The limited understanding by MSEs of the requirements under different tax

regimes is not helped by a complex web of different definitions of what it means to

be an MSE. At the moment there is no single definition across different ministries of the

GOP of what a MSE is. In particular, the criteria used by the SUNAT and the MTPE are

only partly consistent (see Table 2.7). The current co-existence of multiple and partly

overlapping definitions of what an MSE is may lead to confusion and act as a further

barrier to formalization.

Page 49: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

49

Table 2.7: Definitions of micro and small enterprises in the labor code and correspondence

with tax regulations

Maximum

number of

workers

Maximum

gross sales

Other criteria

Microenterprise

Labor Ministry 10 525,000

nuevos soles* ­ No

Tax (RUS

requirements) None

360,000

nuevos soles

­ Natural persons only (with few exceptions)

­ Limit on assets (70,000 nuevos soles)

­ Restrictions on certain sectors (e.g.,

transport, show business, notaries)

Small enterprise

Labor Ministry 50 2,975,000

nuevos soles* ­ No

Tax (RER

requirements) None

360,000

nuevos soles

­ Limit on assets (87,500 nuevos soles)

­ Restrictions on certain sectors (e.g.,

construction, medical, transport)

­ RUC number and keeping register of sales

and purchases, and balances

Note: * Strictly speaking the limit is set at 150 tax units (UITs) for micro enterprises and 850 UITs for small

enterprises. The equivalent amount of a UIT in nuevos soles is announced annually by SUNAT. For 2008 the UIT

amounts to 3,500 nuevos soles, up from 3,450 nuevos soles in 2007, and 3,400 nuevos soles in 2006.

Source: SUNAT and MTPE.

Labor relations and access to pension12

2.24 Businesses perceive only costs from formalizing their labor relations, while

informal arrangements are valued in part for the flexibility they provide. Focus

groups and interviews suggest that the costs of formalizing labor relations are high. The

perception from businesses is that costs would be too high in terms of holidays, social

benefits, as well as firing costs. In addition, businesses state that formal labor relations

provide a disincentive to work. Conversely, informal labor relations not only provide the

advantage of avoiding having to pay social benefits but also are valued in part because of

the flexibility that they provide to the business owner. In particular, piece rate work is

valued by many businesses as an arrangement that ensures the right incentives for the

workers, an arrangement that they do not see how they could marry with entitlements

such as minimum wage and holiday pay. A flexible contractual arrangement is also

12

This section deals with labor issues in so far as the focus groups and survey results provide new

evidence. For a broader coverage of labor issues and informality the reader is referred to the report of

the first phase of this programmatic study (World Bank, 2007a).

Page 50: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

50

sought because of the high fluctuations in workload that small entrepreneurs face. As a

small furniture manufacturer put it: “customer orders and output are not constant. It is

rare that a workshop could bear having three or four permanent workers; in peak times it

can reach up to 30 or 50 workers, and usually maybe eight to 10…”

2.25 Yet labor regulations are at the bottom of the list of obstacles for micro and

small businesses, perhaps because respondents to the survey do not find these

regulations binding. When asked about a long list of possible obstacles to their business,

those most highly ranked are crime, corruption, economic instability, and political

instability, the only four factors which are considered to be serious obstacles by more

than half of our sample of micro and small businesses (Table A.6 in the annex).13

In

contrast, labor regulations are ranked at the very bottom of a list of 15 factors. At first

sight, this would appear to suggest some contradiction with the finding from the focus

groups that micro and small entrepreneurs only see costs in formalizing labor relations.

The apparent paradox can be explained by the fact that employers have most workers

outside formal labor relations and therefore are de facto outside the scope of labor

regulations. In other words, in practice labor regulations may not be perceived as a

serious obstacle simply because they are largely bypassed.

2.26 Larger businesses include only a small share of their workers in their

payrolls. The resistance to formalize labor relations does not decrease as businesses grow

in size and become more complex. In short, larger businesses are more likely to have at

least some workers on the payroll, with health insurance and pension rights, but the share

of those on the payroll may be low. Businesses of 11 to 50 workers typically have a very

complex mix of workers. They typically have a core group of stable workers but only a

small portion of those core workers are in fact on the payroll.

2.27 The complexity in labor arrangements grows with firm size, as businesses

report a preference for informal practices, even for workers nominally on the

payroll. Among workers on the payroll, the officially reported pay is often supplemented

with informal payments. Other core workers are systematically hired as providers of

services, often issuing receipts to the business for the provision of their services as

allegedly independent contractors. Finally, the truly non-core part of the workforce,

which can be large in some sectors of activity such as textiles that are highly seasonal, –

is typically employed on a piece-rate basis without any formal arrangement. Some of the

business owners also emphasize that the informal labor relations are in fact demanded by

workers, who prefer to increase the take-home pay rather than having access to certain

benefits. In some cases, the provision of basic health care is perceived as a benefit for the

business, since it helps to keep a core group of workers happy. However, business owners

prefer to provide some support for those core workers when contingencies occur or, more

rarely, provide for the purchase of health insurance in the private market.

13

It is noteworthy that economic instability ranks so highly, given real GDP growth of 9 percent and

inflation of 3.9 percent in 2007. A possible reason for this result is that memories of past episodes of

economic crises are still very much in the minds of micro and small business owners.

Page 51: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

51

2.28 Survey evidence confirms that even businesses with 11 to 50 workers are

mostly informal with regard to labor issues. Labor relations are by far the most

informal dimension of informality found in this study. In addition, the process of firm

growth does not provide for a set of circumstances that make formalization of labor

relations more likely. As shown in Figure 2.5 below, the proportion of workers with

health and pension coverage is not higher among larger businesses in our sample. It is

therefore unsurprising that having workers on the payroll is not perceived to be a part of

the implicit definition of what is a ‘formal business.’14

Figure 2.5: Relationship between the number of workers and those with health coverage

and pension Each dot represents a business – those with all workers covered are on the 45 degree line

Vertical axis:

number of workers with health coverage Vertical axis:

number of workers with pension

01

02

03

04

05

0

0 10 20 30 40 50

Number of workers

01

02

03

04

05

0

0 10 20 30 40 50

Number of workers

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

2.29 Survey evidence suggests that the high cost of providing social benefits is

perceived to be a major factor in explaining informal labor relations. The dedicated

survey of micro and small entrepreneurs queried respondents in some detail about the

reasons for not having workers on the payroll (see detailed results in Table A.15 in the

annex). In addition to the fact that there are plenty of workers willing to do so, the most

highly ranked response was the fact that one would have to pay the workers’ holidays and

other benefits. Among the lowest ranked responses were concerns about the paperwork

that would be necessary to have workers on the payroll and factors capturing the ‘culture

of informality’ (in particular ‘no business in my sector has its employees on the payroll’

and ‘you do not need to include family members on the payroll’). These results suggest

that concerns about the costs of providing social benefits are among the most critical

14

There is also evidence that at least some workers without a contract, health insurance or a pension do

not consider themselves to be informal: a survey of 400 individuals conducted by the Grupo de

Opinión Pública de la Universidad de Lima in April 2008 indicated that only 43 percent of those

employed reported having an informal job (compare this with the ENAHO survey results of more than

70 percent of informality under any measure used, see Table 1.1). While other factors may help to

explain this result, it suggests that, as in the case of the entrepreneurs polled in our survey, the implicit

definition of what constitutes informality among workers does not necessarily match the standard

definitions.

Page 52: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

52

factors preventing the formalization of labor relations. Yet, when the survey asked open-

ended questions about the major obstacles to business growth, labor regulations are not

generally perceived as a serious obstacle (see Table A.6 in the annex). However, this may

reflect the fact that they simply ignore them.

2.30 Although few know about the true costs of providing social benefits under

the Special Labor Regime for micro businesses. The dedicated survey of micro and

small businesses allows us also to explore in detail what micro businesses really know

about the Special Labor Regime for micro businesses. Few businesses know of the

special regime, especially among those businesses with 10 employees or fewer, precisely

those who can potentially benefit from this regime. In addition, the survey also showed

that, among those that know of that special regime, they underestimate the savings that it

could provide for them (see Box 4 for details).

Box 4: What do businesses know about the Special Labor Regime for micro firms?

A Special Labor Regime (SLR) was put in place in 2003 (Law 28015) to ease the labor

regulatory burden of micro firms (i.e., those with up to 10 employees and sales of 150 tax units

a year: equivalent to 525,000 nuevos soles in 2008). The key features of the regime are that

employers only need to make contributions for health care and for 15 days of holiday a year.

This compares with the employer contributions required under the general labor regime: family

compensation; extraordinary bonus salaries paid in July and December; the compensation of

time in service; and a higher 30-day holiday period. In addition, under the SLR signing up for a

pension scheme is voluntary. As of December 2007 there were 33,289 businesses registered

under the SLR for micro businesses. This figure is low given the large universe of businesses

that could potentially sign up for the SLR. What helps to explain this low take up rate?

Evidence from the survey suggests that lack of information about the SLR may help to explain

this low take-up rate. Of the 802 businesses surveyed only 85 respondents (11 percent) knew

about the SLR. The lack of information is even more pronounced among businesses with 10

workers or fewer, those that can potentially make use of the regime: out of the 622 businesses

with 10 workers or fewer surveyed only 57 respondents (9 percent) knew about the SLR. Of

those 57 respondents, there are 13 businesses which declare to have at least some workers

under the SLR. In addition there are 11 businesses that in principle should not be able to

qualify for the SLR (since they report 11 or more workers and therefore can no longer be

considered micro businesses) and that have employees under the SLR. This is a notable result

given that in our sample there are only 180 businesses with 11 or more workers. Thus, in our

sample the take-up rate of the SLR is substantially higher among firms that fit into the SLR

only through under-reporting of employees. In some cases they report having as many as 18,

21, 24, and 26 employees to the survey. However, the survey uncovered limited evidence that

the SLR led to a benefit erosion, as only 5 of the 24 businesses that have workers under the

SLR reported that they had been previously registered under the general labor regime. In most

cases, the workers who were signed up under the SLR had not been previously registered with

the Ministry of Labor.

Knowledge of the SLR is greater among businesses that participate in some type of state-

sponsored program (see Table A.10 in Annex A for a list of programs about which the

respondents were asked). However, knowledge is far from universal across the businesses that

participate in state programs: out of the 57 businesses that report participating in some state

program only 14 knew of the SLR (around 25 percent, compared to around 11 percent of

Page 53: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

53

businesses knowing of the SLR for the entire sample). This suggests that there is the potential

for improving awareness about the SLR by providing information to micro and small

businesses that come into contact with the state through other programs.

Even those respondents that know of the SLR know little about it. Of the 85 business owners

that know about the SLR only a third (28) provided an answer on the amount of the monthly

contributions borne by the employer for a worker that gets paid the minimum wage. The mean

response by these 28 business owners is that for a worker getting paid the minimum wage and

registered under the SLR they would need to pay 184 soles per month. This figure is far below

the 307 nuevos soles per month that they estimate they would need to pay under the general

labor regime, but well above the 68 nuevos soles that they would need to pay in reality

(calculations by the Ministry of Labor made for the previous minimum wage rate of 500

nuevos soles per month). While any result on the basis of such few observations has to be

interpreted with great caution it may be noted that the estimate of the respondents on the

monthly contribution by an employer under the general regime (307 nuevos soles) is much

closer to the actual cost as calculated by the Ministry of Labor (303 nuevos soles). The results

do not change if we consider only those businesses that actually have workers registered under

the SLR.

The above results suggest that decisions regarding the labor regime, as in the case of decisions

about tax regimes, may not be made directly by the micro business owner but perhaps are

implicitly made by the person to whom the administrative tasks are outsourced. This may have

implications about the prospects of any information campaign and the appropriate channels for

disseminating information. In this regard the focus groups also provided some insight

regarding the lack of knowledge of the SLR. Among the micro business owners that

participated in the focus groups none knew about the SLR. In addition, when the facilitator

explained some characteristics about the regime, there was no interest among micro business

owners to find out more about it. It appeared as if micro business owners have well-defined

channels through which they get their information, mainly through peers and the accountant,

and are not accustomed to using other sources or are reluctant to trust any other sources.

Overall, the evidence from the survey and the focus groups confirms that there is very little

knowledge of the SLR and the contributions that would need to be borne by employers.

However, the evidence also cautions against any optimistic view that a general information

campaign may increase the use of the SLR. Any strategy for disseminating information about

the SLR would first need to identify more clearly how decisions regarding the compliance with

regulatory issues are made by micro entrepreneurs and how the information would be used.

2.31 Survey results suggest that the high level of the minimum wage may be a

constraint to the formalization of at least half of the informal workforce. The

dedicated survey of micro and small entrepreneurs asks respondents about specific

reasons why workers are paid less than the statutory minimum wage. While the most

important factor is the availability of labor willing to work for less than the minimum

wage, the second issue with the highest score is the claim that the business is not

profitable enough to allow for payment of the minimum wage. This is particularly the

case among the smallest businesses with 1 to 5 workers (where 71 percent of respondents

agree that the business cannot afford to pay the minimum wage) but it is also true for the

larger businesses (51 percent of businesses with 11 to 50 workers report that the business

simply cannot afford to pay the minimum wage). (See detailed results in Table A.14 in

the annex.) A comparison between minimum wage and distribution of earnings is

Page 54: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

54

presented in Figure 2.6 below. The clear spikes in the wage distribution of both formal

and informal workers that can be observed in 2003 may be indicative that the minimum

wage has a wide-reaching effect, as the minimum wage may be used to lock in wages to

the minimum (Kristensen and Cunningham, 2006).

Figure 2.6: Kernel distributions of monthly income for private salaried workers –

Metropolitan Lima Vertical line represents the minimum wage

2003 2005

0.5

1

Pa

rzen

Ke

rne

l D

ensity F

unctio

n

2 4 6 8 10Logarithm of Worker's Monthly Income

Informal Salaried Workers Formal Salaried Workers

ENAHO 2005

Source: 2003 from Jaramillo (2004), 2005 World Bank (2007a).

2.32 The minimum wage may be indeed a binding constraint that would make

formalizing these jobs non-viable, as argued in the first phase of this study (World

Bank, 2007a). In this regard, the statutory minimum wage, measured in relation to the

productivity of workers in a country, is higher in Peru than in other countries like

Mexico, Uruguay or Brazil (see Figure 2.7). Evidence from Latin American countries

suggests that the minimum wage has far-reaching effects, particularly in cases where it is

sufficiently high so as to distort the wage distribution in the formal sector, as Figure 2.6

shows for the case of Peru (Maloney and Nuñez, 2001).

Figure 2.7: Minimum wage in Peru and selected countries in the region Mandated minimum wage as a percent of the average value added per worker

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

Par

agu

ay

Co

lom

bia

Ecu

ado

r

Per

u

Bo

liv

ia

Arg

enti

na

Ven

ezu

ela

Bra

zil

Uru

gu

ay

Mex

ico

Note: Data on the statutory minimum wage is collected annually. The chart reflects the latest data available for each country. Source: Doing Business 2008.

Page 55: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

55

2.33 In some businesses and for some workers the minimum wage does not

appear to be the most critical constraint that keeps labor relations from being

formalized. The survey also asked respondents to provide an estimate of the proportion

of workers that, in the area of activity of the respondent, earn less than the minimum

wage. Additionally, respondents were also asked about the proportion of workers that

they estimate are not in the payroll, again in their area of activity. The results show that

the share of workers earning less than the minimum wage is indeed lower than the share

of workers that are outside the payroll (see Table 2.8 below). This suggests that the

minimum wage may not be the binding constraint preventing the formalization of the

labor relation between the employer and the employee at least for those workers that earn

above minimum wage but are not on the businesses’ payroll.

Table 2.8: Business owners’ estimates of how common it is for workers to earn less than the

minimum wage and not be on the payroll Percent of workers

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workers

All

businesses

Estimated share of workers earning less than the

minimum wage 62 52 45 56

Estimated share of workers not on the payroll 75 68 61 70

Difference between estimated share of workers on the

payroll and earning less than the minimum wage 13 16 16 14

Note: See Table A.13 and Table A.15 in the annex for the wording of the questions asked and further breakdowns by

sector and city.

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

2.34 In some cases the minimum wage (and holiday pay) impose not only a high

burden but businesses find them hard to reconcile with piece-rate pay arrangements

as they fear disincentive effects from minimum wages. An insight from the focus

group was the preoccupation among micro and small business owners with the

disincentive effects of formal labor relations, and in particular minimum wages. Micro

and small entrepreneurs also find it difficult to reconcile their preference for paying on a

piece-rate basis (al destajo) with formal contracts. The ENAHO allows us to explore

further this issue. To this end, we compare, for workers of a given income, the proportion

of those that are informal within the sub-groups of piece-rate workers with workers under

any other pay arrangement. To ensure greater comparability across the two sub-groups

we only use blue-collar workers as our starting sample. As shown in Figure 2.8, the

prevalence of informality, conditional on income level, among workers on piece-rate pay

is higher than among non piece-rate workers, especially at the higher end of the income

distribution. While no causal links are explored here, this evidence from the ENAHO is

consistent with the view that this type of pay arrangement has an impact on whether the

labor relation will be formalized or not.

Page 56: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

56

Figure 2.8: Informality prevalence for workers, by pay system (piece-rate or not) Informality rate measured by having a pension.

0

.2.4

.6.8

10

.2.4

.6.8

1

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100

Non piece rate worker

Piece rate worker

Info

rmalit

y p

revale

nce

Income centile

Notes: Workers at a given income level are classified as piece rate workers or not and the proportion of those without a pension is

then calculated. The calculation is based only on blue-collar workers (categories 4 and 5 from the ENAHO – see Annex A).

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO. Data refer to 2006.

2.35 In some cases the worker may prefer an informal labor relation. The micro

and small entrepreneurs that participated in the focus groups often suggested that workers

also opt for informal labor relations to maximize take-home pay at the expense of social

benefits. While this research was not designed to test such a hypothesis, evidence from

the ENAHO on the reasons for self-employment suggests that the motivation for higher

earnings and flexibility are key to explaining self-employment (and conceivably they

may also help to explain the preference of some workers for informal labor relations to

maximize take-home pay, see Table 2.9).15

This preference for an informal labor relation

therefore suits both the worker and the employer. A small business owner interviewed

summed it up as follows: “the worker wants to have the money cash in hand, he doesn’t

want to contribute because he doesn’t believe in the state’s health benefits, and, on the

other hand, the business owner is not concerned because he sees formal labor relations

as increasing the costs.”

15

In the survey of the Universidad de Lima noted in footnote 14 the main reasons why respondents want

a formal job have to do with: security (33 percent want it because of greater security and 15 percent to

have fixed income); and higher pay (33 percent), more so than access to health insurance (18 percent).

Page 57: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

57

Table 2.9: Reasons for self-employment

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

Involuntary (could not find salaried employment) 40 40 34 33 28

Voluntary

Higher earnings 30 26 29 29 25

Has more flexibility 16 21 26 23 27

Family tradition 5 4 5 7 7

Other 8 9 6 8 13

Sum of all voluntary reasons 60 60 66 67 72

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO.

2.36 Firing costs are also perceived to be high and a deterrent to including

workers on the payroll. The cost of firing features also prominently among the reasons

that micro and small entrepreneurs provide for not having workers on the payroll. The

cost and difficulty of firing are indeed the third-highest rated factor in explaining labor

informality according to the respondents to our dedicated survey of micro and small

businesses (see Table A.16 in Annex A for detailed results). These concerns are

particularly acute among the micro entrepreneurs with 1 to 5 workers or 6 to 10 workers,

for whom it is not only the cost of firing by also how complex it actually is to fire a

worker. In this regard, the complexity of the process adds to uncertainty as to the actual

costs of terminating an employee’s contract (an issue which is also explored in Box 5 in

relation to the wedge between the severance payments to which dismissed workers are

entitled and the actual payments that they receive). Moreover, if we take into account that

many dismissal processes do not end in a conciliation but rather go on to the courts, the

uncertain length of the litigation adds to the uncertainty about the actual severance

payments that a business may have to pay a dismissed worker.

Box 5: Severance payments de jure and de facto

Dismissed workers are entitled to a variety of benefits ranging from back holiday pay to

compensation of time in service (CTS). They may also include any accrued but yet unpaid

bonuses for July and December, as well as redundancy compensatory payment. Upon being

laid off the worker can request an estimate of these entitlements from the Ministry of Labor.

Should the worker be dissatisfied with the resolution of the dismissal, the worker can make use

of the services provided by the Ministry of Labor to arrange for a conciliation hearing between

the worker and the employer. Attendance by the employer at these conciliation hearings is

compulsory. The purpose of these conciliations is to reach a mutually satisfactory agreement so

that the matter can be settled without recourse to the labor tribunal.

Evidence from more than 1,700 conciliations in metropolitan Lima was compiled for this study

and cross-referenced with the initial estimates provided by the Ministry of Labor’s workers’

entitlements. This data had not been previously processed (due to the fact that the two data sets

were collected separately without a direct link to cross check them).

Results indicate that on average the actual settlement received by dismissed workers amounts

to around 64 percent of the payments to which the worker is entitled according to the initial

estimate provided by the Ministry of Labor. Results by type of worker (no breakdown by sector

was available) suggests no large differences between the share received by employees and by

Page 58: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

58

workers. Unfortunately the outcome of the conciliations specifies only the total settlement but

not a breakdown by type of benefit.

The results that the severance payment that workers receive de facto is substantially lower than

what they are entitled to de jure has implications for the debate on whether firing costs in Peru

are high or not (an issue which was also touched upon in the report of the first phase of this

programmatic study). To the extent that this adds to the uncertainty about what the actual firing

costs may turn out to be, they may act as a deterrent to formal employment.

Perhaps more relevant than the average ratio of the de facto to de jure severance payments is

the distribution among cases. This is because the more uncertain the wedge between the two

measures the more negative its consequences. The evidence suggests that there is indeed a

wide dispersion of this wedge between entitlements and settlements, as shown in the chart

below. This distribution is shown below for the two types of workers that are recorded in the

system (‘employees’ or white-collar and ‘workers’ or blue-collar). This suggests some

uncertainty about the eventual outcome of a dismissal, – even those that are settled by mutual

accord through the conciliation process.

05

1015

20

0 25 50 75 100 125 150 0 25 50 75 100 125 150 0 25 50 75 100 125 150

Employees Workers All

Sha

re o

f wo

rke

rs (

perc

ent

)

Ratio of settlement to amount owed (percent) Source: World Bank staff calculations based on data from MTPE.

This finding about the uncertainty of the outcome of conciliation processes is supported by the

fact that the wedge between entitlements and settlement does not show any distinct pattern

when mapped against any worker characteristics (gender, age, and length of tenure in the firm)

Page 59: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

59

for which the dataset contains information. However, caution must be exercised in interpreting

the wedge between the entitlement and the actual settlement. The initial estimate of the

entitlements is prepared by the Ministry of Labor without prejudice and on the basis of

information provided by the worker, information that cannot always be verified. In the

conciliation process there is an element of discovery of facts, as the employer may provide

documentary evidence challenging the basis for the initial estimate. In some cases, as shown in

the chart, some workers actually receive more at the settlement than was initially estimated.

While these cases are rare they underscore the fact that the process is not only a mere

negotiation whose outcome is determined by the relative bargaining power of the two parties.

2.37 In addition, sector-specific labor regulations may add to the disincentives to

formalize in particular sectors of activity. The burden of labor regulation in Peru is

high even when compared with other countries in Latin America, as the first phase of this

study documented (see Table A.2 in Annex). This burden is particularly high in a number

of sectors which face a number of sector-specific constraints, in addition to the general

regulatory framework. While no attempt to identify which of those specific constraints

may be most constraining, this study took a first step towards exploring those issues by

concentrating on documenting the actual number of legal instruments of a labor

regulatory nature that are applicable to specific sectors of activity, and mapping that

information with the actual informality rate observed in that sector of activity (Box 6).

Box 6: Sector-specific labor regulations and the prevalence of informality

This box provides a first look at how the number of labor regulations affecting specific sectors

of activity may be related to the level of informality in that sector of activity. A total of 83

labor regulations were identified as being sector-specific (see Annex F for details).

As shown in the charts below, this data calls for further examination of whether the relatively

large number of sector-specific labor regulations on sectors that already have a high degree of

informality, such as construction, may be contributing to informality.

Informality rate across sectors and number of labor regulations issued during 2001 to 2007

specifically for a given sector of activity

Informality rate as measured by percent of

workers without a pension Informality rate as measured by percent of

workers without a contract

Note: See Annex F for details on how the number of laws affecting labor regulations in specific sectors was constructed. Source: World Bank staff calculations based on Ministry of Labor database of laws and ENAHO.

Agriculture

Fishing

Hydrocarbons

Mining

Energy

Construction

Water transport

Ports

R & D

Other business

Health

Recreation

Other services

Private households

05

10

15

Num

ber

of

law

s

0 20 40 60 80 100

Informality rate

Agriculture

Fishing

Hydrocarbons

Mining

Energy

Construction

Water transport

Ports

R & D

Other business

Health

Recreation

Other services

Private households

05

10

15

Num

ber

of

law

s

0 20 40 60 80 100

Informality rate

Agriculture

Fishing

Hydrocarbons

Mining

Energy

Construction

Water transport

Ports

R & D

Other business

Health

Recreation

Other services

Private households

05

10

15

Num

ber

of

law

s

0 20 40 60 80 100

Informality rate

Agriculture

Fishing

Hydrocarbons

Mining

Energy

Construction

Water transport

Ports

R & D

Other business

Health

Recreation

Other services

Private households

05

10

15

Num

ber

of

law

s

0 20 40 60 80 100

Informality rate

Page 60: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

60

Business incorporation as a separate legal entity

2.38 Incorporating the business as a separate legal entity is perceived to be an

important step in the formalization process. Participants in the focus groups often

noted that moving from operating as a natural person to incorporating the business as a

separate legal entity was a key step in what they consider their formalization process. Of

particular interest in the focus groups was the fact that the perceptions of costs and

benefits of incorporating a business were quite different between the group that had

already incorporated and those that were still operating as natural persons. This

difference in the assessments of the ‘haves’ and the ‘have-nots’ was a distinct feature of

this dimension of informality. As an example of this contrast, a micro entrepreneur with

five to 10 workers noted that incorporation “was good for nothing” while a number of

small entrepreneurs noted many benefits of incorporation, including: “to be able to take

part in public tenders” and “to protect your personal capital.” This difference in

perceptions was in stark contrast with most other issues discussed in the focus groups

where, despite there being businesses on both sides of the formality divide, businesses

typically agreed on what were the main pros and cons of the different choices. The

importance of incorporating the business as a separate legal entity was also underscored

in three case studies of the trajectory of businesses towards formalization that were

commissioned for this study (and which will be introduced and discussed in section D.

Dynamics out of informality).

2.39 Businesses with legal personality perceive that they are better positioned to

sell to large companies and to the state, and to have better access to credit. Micro and

small entrepreneurs that have already incorporated their businesses consider that the

separate legal personality has helped them in marketing terms. The perception is that this

greater credibility allows businesses to sell to a different type of client, particularly bigger

firms and also to the state. Evidence from the survey shows some positive correlation

between the extent to which businesses are integrated in larger supply chains and

measures of formality, including operating the business as a separate legal entity (Table

A.8 in the annex). Selling to the state, however, is perceived to be particularly difficult as

it involves additional fixed costs simply to try to do so. The fee required to appear in the

Registry of Providers to the State (RPS) managed by CONSUCODE is non-negligible for

micro and small entrepreneurs.16

In this regard, the perception among micro and small

business owners that participated in the focus groups was that the state provided no

service for this fee. Some small entrepreneurs report having had better access to credit

from financial institutions following incorporation. As a small businessperson put it, “I

changed to a separate legal personality so that they give me more credit for purchasing

machinery.” Finally, it was also noted that operating the business as a separate legal

entity served as a way of protecting the personal property.

16

The registration fee depends on the annual sales of the business as follows: 35 nuevos soles for

businesses selling up to 45,500 nuevos soles; 280 nuevos soles for those with sales from 45,500 to

262,500 nuevos soles; 560 nuevos soles if sales between 262,500 and 525,000 nuevos soles; 1,295

nuevos soles if sales between 525,000 and 2,975,000; and 2,100 soles for those with sales above

2,975,000 nuevos soles.

Page 61: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

61

2.40 Yet, few MSEs set up their business as a separate legal entity, in part due to

limited knowledge about the costs and processes involved. Among the surveyed micro

and small businesses, only 139 businesses, or 17 percent of the sample, are incorporated

as businesses with separate legal personality. This begs the question why, on the face of

the perceived benefits of incorporation, so few micro and small businesses choose to do

so. A tentative answer based on the focus groups would revolve around gaps in the

information available to micro and small entrepreneurs. In particular, micro businesses

consider that setting up the business as a separate legal entity would be costly and, in

addition, imply high recurrent costs. It appeared that many micro businesses simply did

not know what incorporation entailed, nor their costs or benefits. In this regard the role of

the accountant again appears to play a critical role in suggesting to micro business owners

that they incorporate. It is therefore possible that the constraint by which only natural

persons (with few exceptions) can file under the RUS may be a factor that the owner, if

not the accountant, would have in mind as a factor to not incorporate.

Page 62: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

62

C. Econometric analysis of the determinants of informality

This section presents the results of estimating a series of probit equations on the

likelihood of a firm’s being formal, i.e., having a municipal license, a RUC number, and

workers with health coverage). This allows us to determine which variables are robust

determinants of informality, in the sense that those variables help predict whether a

business is formal or not. In particular we are able to control for: (i) characteristics of

the business such as size and age; (ii) characteristics of the business owner such as

education, gender or marital status; (iii) the city and industry in which the business

operates; and even: (iv) enforcement as captured by inspection rates by city and industry.

2.41 Among business characteristics the older the business the more likely it is

that it will have a municipal license or a RUC number. The impact is, however,

relatively small. A business that is 10 years old is around 7 to 8 percent more likely to

have a municipal license (Table 2.10). Larger businesses are more likely to have a license

or a RUC number, again controlling for a wide range of other variables that could

potentially also help predict whether a business is formal or not. The decision of jointly

holding a license and a RUC number is also analyzed. The results of this additional

analysis, shown in Table 2.11, suggest that the conclusions are robust to different

specifications.17

2.42 The more educated the business owner, the more likely the business is to

obtain a license or a RUC number. In contrast, no other personal characteristic of the

owner such as gender, age, or marital status appears to be a robust determinant of

informality. Similarly, whether the parent of the entrepreneur was also in business or the

reasons for being in business: to care for the family or for prospect of growth, is not a

significant determinant of whether a business obtains a license or a RUC number.

2.43 The sector of activity matters, with businesses in shoe and leather, and

textiles and clothing less likely to obtain a municipal license and a RUC number.

The effects are large. Being in the textile and clothing sector decreases the probability of

having a municipal license (compared to the base case of restaurants) by around 40

percent. This result is fully consistent with the argument that those businesses operating

in sectors of activity that are less visible to the authorities are less likely to obtain a

license. Businesses in these less visible sectors are also less likely to have a RUC

number, though the impact is much smaller than in the case of the municipal license.

Businesses in transport are much less likely to have a RUC number. A possible

interpretation of this result is that, faced with the requirement to file taxes under the

general regime, as they are not allowed to use the RUS or RER, (see Table 2.5), transport

operators simply fall back into greater informality in this area.

2.44 Businesses in Arequipa and Trujillo are less likely to have a municipal

license (relative to businesses in Lima). A possible reason behind this result is that the

observed differences by city may result from differences in the costs of dealing with the

17

The identification of these coefficients is determined by businesses that have a license but no RUC.

There are few larger businesses like that, which may affect the results from this joint estimation.

Page 63: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

63

authorities or, perhaps differential enforcement of the rules (more on this below). As

expected, the differences across cities are greater regarding the probability for obtaining a

municipal license than a RUC number.

Table 2.10: Variables that help predict having a municipal license and a RUC number

Marginal effects from probit estimation

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Female owner -0.00274 -0.00509 0.00554 -0.0257 -0.0208 -0.0131 -0.00292 -0.0241

(0.041) (0.041) (0.041) (0.046) (0.034) (0.034) (0.031) (0.031)

Owner's Age -0.00164 -0.00223 -0.00109 -0.000428 -0.00231* -0.00260* -0.000659 0.000378

(0.0017) (0.0018) (0.0018) (0.0019) (0.0014) (0.0014) (0.0013) (0.0012)

Owner is Married 0.0147 0.0267 0.0224 -0.00433 0.0506* 0.0518* 0.0398 0.0226

(0.038) (0.038) (0.038) (0.041) (0.030) (0.030) (0.027) (0.025)

Owner has Tecnico education 0.0416 0.0426 0.0331 0.0418 0.0994*** 0.0917** 0.0707** 0.0596**

(0.061) (0.061) (0.062) (0.067) (0.036) (0.037) (0.033) (0.028)

Owner has University education 0.184*** 0.200*** 0.169*** 0.161*** 0.191*** 0.176*** 0.126*** 0.0775***

(0.046) (0.046) (0.048) (0.054) (0.030) (0.031) (0.030) (0.030)

Owner has complete secondary education 0.00688 0.0114 0.00760 0.0307 0.0722** 0.0611* 0.0471 0.0400

(0.047) (0.048) (0.048) (0.051) (0.035) (0.035) (0.032) (0.029)

Parent owned a business -0.0104 -0.00690 -0.00344 0.000235 -0.0455 -0.0471 -0.0440 -0.0492*

(0.037) (0.037) (0.037) (0.040) (0.031) (0.031) (0.028) (0.026)

Age of firm 0.00799*** 0.00814*** 0.00695*** 0.00677*** 0.00640*** 0.00670*** 0.00472*** 0.00519***

(0.0021) (0.0021) (0.0021) (0.0023) (0.0017) (0.0017) (0.0015) (0.0015)

Municipal inspection rate in city*industry -0.0850 -0.134 -0.134 -0.0674

(0.24) (0.24) (0.24) (0.26)

Shoe/Leather -0.301*** -0.316*** -0.325*** -0.302*** -0.193** -0.195** -0.206*** -0.158**

(0.10) (0.10) (0.11) (0.11) (0.078) (0.078) (0.080) (0.080)

Textiles/Clothing -0.433*** -0.455*** -0.459*** -0.442*** -0.265*** -0.272*** -0.264*** -0.221**

(0.11) (0.11) (0.11) (0.12) (0.078) (0.079) (0.081) (0.086)

Wood products -0.296*** -0.297*** -0.301*** -0.301*** -0.101 -0.0987 -0.0923 -0.176**

(0.089) (0.089) (0.091) (0.097) (0.068) (0.069) (0.065) (0.081)

Metal products -0.184** -0.171* -0.153* -0.155 -0.0186 -0.0248 0.000548 -0.0415

(0.092) (0.092) (0.093) (0.098) (0.064) (0.065) (0.055) (0.062)

Food stuffs -0.0355 -0.0259 -0.0177 -0.0218 0.0554 0.0572 0.0604 0.0507

(0.078) (0.077) (0.077) (0.082) (0.053) (0.053) (0.043) (0.037)

Transport -0.180* -0.207* -0.201* -0.192* -0.409*** -0.411*** -0.422*** -0.484***

(0.10) (0.11) (0.11) (0.11) (0.080) (0.081) (0.086) (0.098)

Arequipa -0.160** -0.187*** -0.154** -0.131* -0.153*** -0.146** -0.106* -0.0391

(0.063) (0.065) (0.065) (0.070) (0.059) (0.059) (0.055) (0.045)

Trujillo -0.279*** -0.309*** -0.288*** -0.326*** 0.0821 0.0788 0.0879** 0.0488

(0.072) (0.072) (0.074) (0.078) (0.055) (0.056) (0.042) (0.044)

Huancayo -0.0390 -0.0565 -0.00894 -0.0287 -0.106 -0.1000 -0.0382 0.00844

(0.074) (0.076) (0.073) (0.079) (0.078) (0.078) (0.064) (0.048)

Cusco -0.0425 -0.0587 0.00340 -0.0114 -0.0369 -0.0321 0.0260 0.0558

(0.075) (0.077) (0.074) (0.082) (0.067) (0.067) (0.050) (0.034)

Log distance to the Municipality Office -0.0765*** -0.0740** -0.0797*** -0.0616**

(0.029) (0.029) (0.029) (0.031)

Log distance to City Center -0.0181 -0.0266 -0.0168 -0.0349 0.00730 0.00923 0.0216 0.00610

(0.028) (0.029) (0.029) (0.032) (0.029) (0.029) (0.026) (0.023)

In business to care for family -0.0717* -0.0601 -0.0438 -0.0550* -0.0346 -0.0272

(0.039) (0.039) (0.043) (0.030) (0.028) (0.026)

In business for flexibility 0.167*** 0.169*** 0.172*** -0.0121 -0.00185 0.0000304

(0.048) (0.049) (0.053) (0.036) (0.033) (0.032)

In business because can't find wage job 0.0280 0.0381 0.0311 0.00506 -0.00174 0.00698

(0.041) (0.042) (0.044) (0.034) (0.030) (0.028)

In business for prospect of growth -0.0632 -0.0839 -0.0779 0.131* 0.0978 0.0277

(0.065) (0.062) (0.069) (0.070) (0.066) (0.055)

SUNAT inspection rate in city*industry -0.183 -0.178 -0.131 -0.156

(0.14) (0.14) (0.13) (0.11)

Log distance to the SUNAT Office -0.0559* -0.0603* -0.0593** -0.0237

(0.032) (0.032) (0.028) (0.025)

6 to 10 workers 0.0805** 0.0293 0.158*** 0.0774***

(0.040) (0.048) (0.021) (0.024)

11 to 50 workers 0.216*** 0.186*** 0.205*** 0.110***

(0.037) (0.050) (0.020) (0.026)

Log November Sales 0.0317* 0.0836***

(0.017) (0.013)

Observations 801 801 801 694 801 801 801 694

Municipal Licence RUC

Note: omitted dummies are Restaurants, Lima, <5 workers, Male, and Less than Secondary Education.

Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Page 64: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

64

Table 2.11: Variables that help predict having both a municipal license and a RUC number

Marginal effects from probit estimation

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Female owner 0.0223 0.0242 0.0405 0.0158

(0.044) (0.044) (0.045) (0.051)

Owner's Age -0.00211 -0.00254 -0.000629 0.000616

(0.0019) (0.0019) (0.0020) (0.0022)

Owner is Married 0.0318 0.0401 0.0341 0.0169

(0.041) (0.041) (0.042) (0.046)

Owner has Tecnico education 0.113* 0.108* 0.0943 0.0868

(0.063) (0.063) (0.065) (0.071)

Owner has University education 0.263*** 0.265*** 0.222*** 0.195***

(0.048) (0.049) (0.053) (0.060)

Owner has complete secondary education 0.0483 0.0462 0.0367 0.0445

(0.051) (0.051) (0.053) (0.057)

Parent owned a business -0.00931 -0.00734 -0.00209 0.000505

(0.040) (0.040) (0.041) (0.044)

Age of firm 0.0100*** 0.0101*** 0.00842*** 0.00936***

(0.0023) (0.0023) (0.0023) (0.0026)

Municipal inspection rate in city*industry -0.0215 -0.0831 -0.106 -0.193

(0.28) (0.28) (0.29) (0.31)

SUNAT inspection rate in city*industry -0.264 -0.218 -0.179 -0.0878

(0.20) (0.21) (0.21) (0.22)

Shoe/Leather -0.374*** -0.388*** -0.416*** -0.400***

(0.097) (0.096) (0.097) (0.11)

Textiles/Clothing -0.475*** -0.493*** -0.516*** -0.533***

(0.098) (0.096) (0.097) (0.099)

Wood products -0.288*** -0.290*** -0.304*** -0.346***

(0.089) (0.089) (0.092) (0.096)

Metal products -0.176* -0.173* -0.151 -0.178*

(0.094) (0.094) (0.097) (0.10)

Food stuffs -0.00170 -0.00206 0.00567 -0.0185

(0.087) (0.087) (0.088) (0.096)

Transport -0.422*** -0.440*** -0.457*** -0.486***

(0.089) (0.087) (0.090) (0.089)

Arequipa -0.199*** -0.219*** -0.186*** -0.155**

(0.067) (0.067) (0.070) (0.075)

Trujillo -0.148 -0.178* -0.141 -0.242**

(0.10) (0.10) (0.11) (0.11)

Huancayo -0.0909 -0.108 -0.0514 -0.0627

(0.086) (0.087) (0.087) (0.093)

Cusco -0.0567 -0.0800 -0.00219 -0.0119

(0.091) (0.093) (0.092) (0.099)

Log distance to SUNAT office -0.0416 -0.0454 -0.0603 -0.0372

(0.041) (0.041) (0.041) (0.044)

Log distance to Municipal office -0.0987*** -0.0946*** -0.105*** -0.0913***

(0.032) (0.032) (0.032) (0.035)

Log distance to city center 0.0110 0.00622 0.0313 -0.00709

(0.040) (0.040) (0.041) (0.044)

In business to care for family -0.0714* -0.0536 -0.0495

(0.042) (0.044) (0.048)

In business for flexibility 0.115** 0.128** 0.157***

(0.050) (0.052) (0.057)

In business because can't find wage job -0.000140 0.0123 -0.00333

(0.044) (0.046) (0.048)

In business for prospect of growth 0.0131 -0.0241 -0.0460

(0.076) (0.076) (0.081)

6 to 10 workers 0.181*** 0.105**

(0.040) (0.050)

11 to 50 workers 0.325*** 0.254***

(0.036) (0.054)

Log November Sales 0.0682***

(0.019)

Observations 801 801 801 694

Note: omitted dummies are Restaurants, Lima, <5 workers, Male, and Less than Secondary Education.

Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Page 65: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

65

2.45 Results are mixed regarding the role that inspection rates may play in

determining whether a business gets a license or a RUC number. Taking the

regressions results at face value would suggest that enforcement, as captured by the

inspection rate by city/industry, does not play a role in the decision of businesses to

obtain a license or a RUC number. However, it is possible that other variables for which

we are controlling may be capturing some information regarding enforcement. As noted

above, the city dummies themselves may well be capturing part of the enforcement

information. More importantly, the distance of a business to the municipality and to the

SUNAT are robust determinants of the likelihood that a business obtains a license and a

RUC number (the further you are the less likely you are to obtain the license and a RUC).

In part, this negative correlation between formality and distance to the offices can be

explained by the costs involved in dealing with the authority. However, as we have

already seen regarding the case of the SUNAT, those businesses that are closer to the

SUNAT offices are in fact more likely to be inspected (see Annex B), possibly affecting

the results on the inspection rate variable.

2.46 Business characteristics such as age and size also help explain the probability

that a business provides workers with health insurance. The econometric exercise

conducted above was repeated to examine the determinants of the probability of a

business having (any) workers with medical health coverage (see Annex C).

Significantly, larger businesses are more likely to have some workers with health

insurance but also to have a lower share of their workers covered. This result is fully

consistent with the view that informality in labor relations does not decrease as

businesses grow. Other results regarding the determinants of having workers with health

coverage include the positive correlation with the owner of the business having a

university education, being married, and also businesses in retail sales.

2.47 Labor inspections play a role in explaining the probability that a business

provides workers with health insurance. In contrast with the mixed conclusions about

the role of enforcement in the case of tax or business licensing, there is stronger evidence

that the labor inspections rate by city/industry positively affect the probability that a

business would have workers with health insurance (see Annex C).

Page 66: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

66

D. Dynamics out of informality

In addition to the survey and focus groups, three case studies were commissioned to

provide further insights on the question of what the key steps are in the trajectories that

businesses follow along the informality-formality continuum. This section introduces

these case studies and also provides a summary of the evidence gathered regarding this

question of the dynamics out of informality.

Box 7: Case studies – formality is also a ‘refuge’

These case studies tracked the evolution of three agri-businesses that were selected to capture

businesses which, while successful, were at different stages of growth and expansion.

Following a summary table with their key characteristics, this box briefly reviews their

experience with the formalization process.

Overall, three main insights may be drawn from the business cases studied.

First, many entrepreneurs have several businesses at any given point in time and, since those

business have different age profiles and operate in different sectors, their informality

characteristics are also likely to be different. A business person that has a highly formal

business and decides to start a new business is likely to do so as informal. This conclusion

underscores the importance the cost-benefit calculations that MSEs make regarding the

decision to formalize or not. It also suggests that simply providing information to micro and

small entrepreneurs is unlikely to have much of an impact since even those that know how to

formalize typically choose not to when setting up a new venture.

Second, the trajectory toward formality is not necessarily one-way and can certainly be bumpy.

In two of the cases studied, the businessperson decided at some point in time to revert back to

work as a natural person, effectively closing down the legal business. Dealings with the tax

authorities account for a fair share of the bumpiness, mostly as a result of limited knowledge

by the entrepreneur on how to file taxes; trying to exploit the system of duty drawbacks for

exporters; as well as labor disputes with former employees.

Third, formality – and in particular business incorporation can be a refuge. Typically one

thinks of informality as the refuge where the non-payment of taxes gives the entrepreneur a

fighting chance. In contrast to this view, these businesspeople found that formality provided

them with a refuge to preserve their personal property and a conduit to transmit wealth; a way

to protect themselves from labor lawsuits; and an immediate boost in their credit standing.

Business Since Annual

sales

Activity Key steps in

formalization

Key drivers

Ecological

Amazon

Food SAC

(PERSA)

1992 USD 0.3

million

Snacks,

jams,

yoghurts

It reverted back to

operating as a natural

person from 2000 to

2005 to take

advantage of certain

incentives.

The initial drive to register

in 1993 was enforcement

by the local authorities.

In 2005 the return to

operating as a legal entity

was due to tax issues.

Malakasí 1987 USD 0.6 Mango

producer

In 2005 incorporated To obtain duty drawback

Page 67: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

67

SAC million and

exporter

the business;

Repeated attempts to

formalize as previous

businesses had to

close

from exports;

Self-confidence in

capacity to grow the

business

Frutas y

Frutas

SAC

1993 USD 0.7

million

Avocado

producer

and

exporter

In 2006 incorporated

the business, this has

allowed him to obtain

credit previously

unavailable due to his

advanced age.

The link with larger

exporters ‘forced’ him to

formalize;

To reduce the risk of labor

lawsuits against him

Ecological Amazon Food SAC (PERSA)

Rocío Torres set up this small jam manufacturer in Iquitos in 1992 in a completely informal

manner, trying to make a living after she had been fired by her employer when she got

pregnant. Within one year Rocío Torres and her husband had incorporated a business (PERSA

SRL), obtained their RUC number and, in 1994, obtained the municipal license and sanitary

certification for their products. In 1997 she was able to register the brand PERSA with the

relevant authorities (Instituto Nacional de Defensa del Consumidor y la Propiedad Intelectual,

INDECOPI) as well as receive some financing through the Financial Corporation for

Development (Corporación Financiera de Desarrollo, COFIDE). The business continued

growing, diversifying into new products like snacks, and in 2000 they decided to close down

PERSA SRL to continue working as a natural person. The intention was to benefit from the tax

concessions granted through the law of regional development of the Amazonas. However, this

caused problems with SUNAT. After some financial difficulties in 2005, which prevented them

from having access to credit, the company was once again incorporated (as Ecological Amazon

Food SAC) and has continued to expand in the Iquitos market.

Agroindustrias Malakasí SAC

Armando Echevarría started to trade agricultural products in 1987. Since then he has started

five different business ventures. He has operated businesses both formally, with different

business partners, and informally, especially in fishing. The formal activities, however, were

the ones that brought problems with the authorities, in particular related to duty drawbacks.

Despite these problems with the authorities, Armando Echevarría’s business activities

generated enough capital for him to be able to invest in a mango packing plant in Piura, as well

as in land to grow mangos in 2003. Throughout this process, access to credit has been blocked

to him and he has had to rely on retained earnings for every business he has undertaken.

Following his decision to enter into this business, at the same time keeping his fishing

business, Armando Echevarría decided to incorporate Malakasí in 2005 in order to be eligible

for claiming the duty drawback from his exports as the rules require a certain amount of capital

before being eligible for any payment back.

Frutas y Frutas SAC

Armando Bermúdez has been in business since 1968, working on auto parts and diesel engines.

By the 1990s, however, competitive pressures from used spare parts and informal repair

workshops made him consider a change of activity. In this case the accountant not only

prepared the books but also offered him a business deal: a plot of land in Casma that he could

purchase in installments. Thus, in 1993 Armando Bermúdez became an avocado producer and

Page 68: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

68

soon-to-be exporter. Despite being a seasoned entrepreneur, Armando Bermúdez started off his

new business venture as a natural person. Funding for the investments into the new activity was

from the earnings of his previous businesses. But by 2000 that source of funds had dried up and

Armando Bermúdez unsuccessfully looked around for financing. It took until 2003 before he

obtained some funding, at high rates and mortgaging the land, from the Caja Rural.

Apparently, a cause of concern from lenders was his advanced age (he is now 73). In 2002 the

land finally started producing as expected and he channeled his sales through some local

wholesalers and in 2004 he started to sell to an import-export trader directly. After 13 years of

having to run the business as a natural person, the business was incorporated in 2006. The main

reasons for doing so was to put an end to some problems that were building up with SUNAT

and the MTPE as he had worked as a natural person under the agrarian regime but with

continuous contracts for his laborers. In addition, as a separate legal entity he is now protected

from lawsuits by former hired-hands. Finally, Armando Bermúdez noted that he is now able to

draw credit from financial institutions as a legal person since his age is no longer the key

consideration but rather the soundness of his business.

2.48 Based on the three data gathering efforts undertaken for this report: the survey,

the case studies, and the focus groups and interview, a synthesis of the steps toward

formality is presented in Table 2.12.

Table 2.12: Summary of steps towards formalization

Step Timing Key factors

1. Obtain RUC number, start

paying taxes

­ Shortly after starting

operations, typically within a

year

­ Business needs to issue

receipts (boletas) to expand

customer base

2. Obtain municipal license

(if business visible from

the street)

­ Shortly after getting RUC

number or simultaneously

­ Avoid fines and having to

pay-off inspectors

3. Maintain workers as

service providers

­ As the business expands, can

take several years

­ To avoid paying high social

benefits and eventual firing

costs

­ Need for flexibility

4. Incorporate business as a

separate legal entity

­ As the business expands

several years before it happens

(if at all)

­ To expand customer base to

larger firms and the state

­ To gain better access to credit

5. Include workers on payroll ­ Businesses only do so when

they reach a much bigger size,

not as MSEs

­ Enforcement of labor

regulations

Source: World Bank staff elaboration.

Page 69: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

69

2.49 The survey data also provide further evidence to support this stylized

summary of businesses’ trajectories toward formality. We can corroborate these

findings with our survey data in two ways. First, we can exploit the questions in the

survey that ask about the process of formalization itself; we know that around 50 percent

of businesses surveyed state that they have had a RUC number and a municipal license

since they started the business (see further details in Table E.1 in Annex E). Second, even

though the survey provides only a snapshot of a cross-section of businesses, we can

examine the formality characteristics of businesses of different ages (Figure 2.9). This

evidence suggests that while formalization with regard to the RUC number and the

municipal license not only starts from a high level but also continues an upward trend

over time, it also confirms that informality along the labor relations dimension does not

actually take place; and only a few micro and small entrepreneurs choose to incorporate

their businesses as separate legal entities. However, caution must be exercised when

interpreting this evidence since we might expect more productive firms to be more likely

to be formal and therefore also to survive. This would create an upward bias for older

businesses when looking at the cross-section of the formality-age relationship. Given this

possible bias, it is all the more remarkable how few businesses have workers with a

contract or are incorporated as separate legal entities.

Figure 2.9: Formality characteristics among surveyed businesses, by age of business Proportion among surveyed businesses, percent

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19

Age of business in years

With RUC

number

With

municipal

license

Incorporated

With some

workers

under

contract0

20

40

60

80

100

1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19

Age of business in years

With RUC

number

With

municipal

license

Incorporated

With some

workers

under

contract

Page 70: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

70

3. The impact of informality

Establishing empirically the effect of a variable like informality is not a simple task. The

potential for estimation biases arising from the self-selection of businesses into different

categories (formal/informal) is large. To minimize these potential biases this chapter

makes use of three different methods, discussed in detail in Annex D and follows the

methodology used in World Bank (2008a): (i) the OLS estimates as a first approximation;

(ii) a treatment effects regression that tries to take account of the potential endogeneity of

formality; and (iii) an estimate using propensity score matching.

A. Is informality a cause of low profitability?

3.1 Any analysis of the impact of informality on business performance must be

interpreted with great caution as there are many possible links that are not easy to

capture. The methodology used in this report does not attempt to capture the negative

effects that informality may have on the performance of formal firms, or the effects that

informality may have in undermining social trust and the overall business environment.

In addition, we must also bear in mind that to the extent that informality is a second-best

reaction, forcing firms to become formal may actually hurt growth, under the assumption

that there is no increase in the benefits of formality. Therefore, as a general starting point

for the discussion on the impact of informality on business performance we must

acknowledge the difficulty of establishing causal links. What is usually accepted is that

the factors that drive informality (high regulation, excessive payroll-financed

employment protection legislation) negatively affect business performance and reduce

economic growth.

3.2 A naïve comparison would appear to suggest that businesses with a

municipal license are more profitable than informal ones. A naïve comparison of the

profitability of businesses with and without a municipal license shows an apparent

‘premium’ for formality, as businesses in our sample that have a municipal license are

around 55 percent more profitable than those without a license. However, these

correlations are o not accurately indicated the true effect of a municipal license on the

profitability of a business. The survey data allows us to dig much deeper into this issue

and to go beyond these naïve comparisons.

3.3 But controlling for exogenous characteristics of the business and its owner

indicates that there is no robust impact of having a municipal license on

profitability. The survey provides us with a large number of characteristics of the owner

and the business which we can take into account when estimating the profitability

premium of formal businesses. The results of this analysis applied to the profitability

‘premium’ of having a municipal license, after controlling for different sets of variables

are shown in Figure 3.1. The figure starts with the naïve comparison, not controlling for

any observable characteristic, and then reports a number of OLS regressions controlling

by an increasing number of variables. We first account for differences in owner

characteristics (gender, marital status, level of education attained, and whether a parent of

the owner had a business), age of the business, and city and industry dummy variables.

Page 71: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

71

Controlling for this first set of variables brings down the profitability ‘premium’ of

having a municipal license to around 41 percent (as shown in the second bar from the left

in Figure 3.1). The third bar in Figure 3.1 shows the estimated profitability ‘premium’

controlling for an even larger number of variables, now including the reasons as to why

the owner went into business as well as a measure of self-efficacy. This is to control for

the possibility that the causality chain would run from more able entrepreneurs to more

profitable businesses to greater likelihood of having a license. When we then control for

the number of workers in the business, – the fourth bar in the figure, we no longer obtain

a statistically significant profitability ‘premium.’ The last two bars on the right of Figure

3.1 represent estimates of the ‘premium’ using different techniques. In the ‘matching’

methodology the premium is estimated by comparing those businesses that most closely

resemble each other on all observable characteristics, other than having a municipal

license. However, this technique does not account for the possibility that businesses may

differ in characteristics other than those that can be observed by the variables in our

dataset. This is a serious shortcoming since factors such as entrepreneurial or sales skills

are typically difficult to fully capture. The final bar on the right in Figure 3.1 shows the

results from a technique that allows for the underlying observations to be heterogeneous

on unobservable characteristics. Overall, the last three bars on the right of Figure 3.1

represent alternative ways of having controlled for as many variables as possible. The

results indicate that having a municipal license does not have a robust impact on the

profitability of a business.

Figure 3.1: Difference in profitability between the business with a municipal license and

those without Percent

Source: World Bank staff calculations. See Table 3.1 below and Table D.1 and Table D.2 in Annex D.

3.4 Similarly, there is no robust impact of having a RUC number on the

profitability of a business. As in the case of the municipal license, a naïve comparison

suggests that businesses in our sample that have a RUC number have a profitability that

is around 103 percent higher than the profitability of those businesses without a RUC

-40

-20

0

20

40

60

80

no additional

variable (OLS)

owner

characteristics, age

of firm, industry

and city (OLS)

+ reasons for being

in business and

owner ability (OLS)

+ number of

workers (OLS)

Matching on all

observable

characteristics

Controlling for

unobservable

characteristics

(2SLS)

Statistically

not significant

Statistically

not significant

Page 72: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

72

number. However, as in the case of the municipal license, this correlation is not robust to

a different estimation technique, especially when we allow for the possibility that the

underlying observations in our sample differ also on characteristics that are not captured

by the variables in our dataset (Figure 3.2).

Figure 3.2: Difference in profitability between businesses with a RUC number and those

without Percent

Source: World Bank staff calculations. See Table 3.1 below and Table D.1 and Table D.2 in Annex D.

3.5 Overall, the econometric analysis provides no evidence that as a consequence

of having a municipal license or a RUC number businesses are more profitable

(Table 3.1). Evidence from the propensity score matching would appear to suggest a

positive impact on profits of having a license or a RUC number, however, the result is not

robust in the treatment effects regression (2SLS), suggesting that a self-selection of

businesses on the basis of unobservable variables may be the driving force behind the

OLS and the matching results (for additional results see Table D.1 and Table D.2 in

Annex D).

-160

-120

-80

-40

0

40

80

120

no additional

variable (OLS)

owner

characteristics,

age of firm,

industry and

city (OLS)

+ reasons for

being in

business and

owner ability

(OLS)

+ number of

workers (OLS)

+ capital stock

(OLS)

Matching on all

observable

characteristics

Controlling for

unobservable

characteristics

(2SLS)

Statistically

not significant

Page 73: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

73

Table 3.1: Impact of different formality characteristics on firm profits

OLS First-stage F-Stat 2SLS Matching

Municipal license

All businesses 0.351*** 3.70 -0.124 0.435***

(0.13) (1.95) (0.134)

1 to 5 workers 0.138 8.55 0.240 0.237*

(0.15) (0.66) (0.137)

6 to 10 workers -0.222 0.36 n.a. 0.003

(0.29) (0.218)

11 to 50 workers 0.536 0.19 n.a. 0.350

(0.39) (0.444)

RUC

All businesses 0.845*** 2.14 -1.635 0.886***

(0.13) (3.30) (0.144)

1 to 5 workers 0.490*** 1.73 -0.523 0.550***

(0.15) (2.09) (0.135)

6 to 10 workers 0.396 3.33 2.068 0.374

(0.36) (2.30) (0.314)

11 to 50 workers 0.459 0.02 n.a. -0.131

(0.47) (0.706)

Note: Dependent variable is log profits. Robust Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

These regressions weigh observations differentially to account for the differential reporting of profits of businesses

depending on distance to the SUNAT office.

N.a.: the intended instrument (distance to municipal office / SUNAT) was not feasible in some cases due to missing

data (reporting of profits by businesses closer to the offices was poor).

Source: World Bank staff estimates.

Page 74: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

74

B. What is the impact of informality on access to credit?

This section examines the current context of how Peruvian informal businesses access

sources of finance. It briefly reviews conceptual and measurement issues, and presents

evidence based on the firm-level survey built for this study on the extent to which credit

access is an obstacle to informal firms and entrepreneurs. In the background, as a

motivation for our concern with this issue, lies the cross-country evidence that returns to

capital are high for micro enterprises (World Bank, 2007c) suggesting that, to the extent

that informality may be found to curb access to credit for micro and small businesses,

this would provide an incentive to formalize.

3.6 While financial depth, as captured by the ratio of bank credit to the private

sector, remains low, the growth of the performing loan portfolio has been high in

recent years. The Peruvian financial system remains shallow relative to the region

(Figure 3.3), but has experienced a rapid expansion of bank credit in recent years. The

policy objectives in the context of rapid credit growth should be to consolidate the gains

from improved financial depth by implementing policies that will limit the vulnerability

of the real and financial sectors while at the same time prioritizing financial widening, or

access to finance for all. The GOP has taken several steps to mitigate risks and continue

promoting sustainable credit expansion.18

Widening access to the system is also a key

policy priority and encompasses a broad range of issues pertaining to the overall business

environment.

Figure 3.3: Financial depth

Private sector credit in Peru and selected

neighboring countries

Percent of GDP, 2006

Total credit to the private sector in Peru

In USD million

0

20

40

60

80

100

Chile Brazil Colombia LAC

average

Mexico Peru

-

10,000

20,000

30,000

40,000

50,000

60,000

Ene

99

May

99

Sep

99

Ene

00

May

00

Sep

00

Ene

01

May

01

Sep

01

Ene

02

May

02

Sep

02

Ene

03

May

03

Sep

03

Ene

04

May

04

Sep

04

Ene

05

May

05

Sep

05

Ene

06

May

06

Sep

06

Ene

07

May

07

Sep

07

Month Year

US

$ M

M

Source: WDI. Source: BCRP.

3.7 Access to credit is conceptually distinct from the actual use of credit.

Financial depth, as measured by domestic credit to the private sector or by the ratio of

quasi-money to GDP, is a commonly used macro indicator of credit access. The

efficiency of the formal financial system in resource mobilization is usually summarized

18

See World Bank (2008b) for specific details on policies implemented.

Page 75: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

75

by a variable such as the share of deposits in GDP and summary indicators of the cost of

credit. These measures have the advantage that they are readily available, and easy to

update and compare across countries. However, they tend to capture actual use as

opposed to improvements in the opportunity to access finance by all segments of the

population.19

Measuring access to credit involves a qualitative assessment of the costs of

and opportunities to potential users of obtaining finance. A good measure of credit access

should therefore reflect the ability of the financial system to be accessible by all segments

of the population. It should therefore capture the extent to which the system facilitates

information flows and risk diversification; lowers transactions costs; and eases

intermediation. It should also reflect the quality of the institutional environment. For

example, a financially-developed system is associated with a regulatory and legal

framework that supports credit expansion and protects both debtor and creditor rights.20

It

encourages the creation of infrastructure that can allow technology to bring down

transaction costs.

3.8 Obstacles to financial widening at the user-end include the need to provide

proof of income, guarantees and/or collateral. It is harder to keep track of income and

assets in the informal sector, especially at the small and micro end, which leads to

financial institutions typically requiring both loan guarantees and collateral from

borrowers. Giving every individual a national identification number and creating credit

registries where lenders share information about their clients' repayment records can be

very valuable in this context. All borrowers would then have an asset: their future access

to credit, that they implicitly offer as collateral when they obtain a loan. Reducing the

costs of registering or repossessing collateral, as well as the elimination of usury laws is

another feature of accessible financial systems. Authorities should seek to strengthen

creditors’ rights and facilitate access to secured credit through the full implementation of

the new movable guarantees registry from the National System for Public Registry

(Sistema Nacional de Registros Públicos, SUNARP). Movable collateral is a widely-held

asset and using it as guarantee to obtain credit should enable an important sector of the

population to become part of the financial sector. A new Movable Collateral Law has

been enacted and SUNARP has taken the necessary steps to set up the infrastructure for

implementing the law.

3.9 The high cost of credit is an additional constraint on widening access to

credit. The per dollar transaction costs associated with small and micro loans is higher

than those of large loans. Micro firms comprise 53 percent of the survey sample and over

90 percent of the population of informal firms in Peru, suggesting that the average size of

financial transactions is likely to be small. The result is a high cost of credit to small,

informal borrowers. Many medium- and long-term policies that enhance the overall

effectiveness of the system will lower the cost of financial services for both large and

small borrowers, for example: judicial reforms to strengthen creditor and debtor rights;

improvements in information exchange;21

or the provision of credit registries; liens; and

property ownership security.

19

World Bank (2008a) provides a database of micro measures of credit penetration. 20

See Demirguc-Kunt and Levine (2008), World Bank (2008d), and de la Torre et al. (2007) for a more

detailed treatment of issues pertaining to credit access and market-friendly intervention. 21

Djankov, McLiesh, and Shleifer (2007); Haselmann and Wachtel (2006).

Page 76: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

76

3.10 Policy reforms aimed at improving credit access should focus on both the

supply and demand-side. There is strong cross-country evidence that security of

contracts and private property rights significantly influence financial development.22

In

addition to increasing incentives to engage with formal financial institutions, these

reforms reduce firms’ incentives to “circle around” the domestic system.23

Reducing

transactions costs will also require the adoption of supply-side innovations that improve

flexibility in use, such as mobile banks and electronic technology, along with demand-

side measures such as strengthening consumer protection laws and services. There is also

evidence that competition-enhancing policies are effective in stimulating the

development of financial products targeted at poorer households, with the appropriate

prudential precautions.24

As private sector banks find traditional businesses facing

competition, they will seek out non-traditional business. Given the right environment, the

private sector has the ability, the incentives, and the resources to develop innovative

services that can strengthen access to finance for informal firms and entrepreneurs.

3.11 The data supports the hypothesis that firm size and geographic location

matters for access to credit (Annex D). The access characteristics examined were firm

participation in the formal financial system; terms of credit; availability of finance for

start-up capital; and whether or not the proprietor of the firm holds the title to their own

home. Data stratification was by sector, location (in Lima or outside Lima), firm size, and

whether firms had acquired a RUC number from the very outset. The last factor turned

out to be of significance only in the context of holding an account at a financial

institution and borrowing for start-up capital, and was therefore dropped in subsequent

tabulations. Significant differences emerged however across firms by size and location.

3.12 Less than half the firms surveyed had an account with a financial institution. Only 43 percent of the respondent firms had an account with any kind of financial

institution, and only 15 percent of total firms had a bank account (Table D.4 in Annex D).

Of firms with less than 6 workers, 70 percent had no account at all, while the

corresponding figure for larger firms (with 11 to 50 workers) was about one-third

suggesting significant differences based on firm-size. Firms outside Lima were more

likely to have an account. The highest proportion of firms without accounts was in

foodstuffs and shoe leather. Having had a RUC number from the outset had some impact

in this context, especially for larger firms, but the differences are not significant.

Moreover, most firms operate on a cash-only basis. 70 percent of the respondent firms

accepted neither checks nor credit cards from their customers. While the proportion of

cash-only transactions was highest for food stuffs and shoe leather, this trend holds across

all sectors.

3.13 In order to start the business, 48 percent of businesses used only personal

savings, which accounted for 64 percent of all capital needed at the outset. More than

90 percent of surveyed businesses reported having used personal savings as a source of

finance while 12 percent of businesses reported having drawn from family and friends (as

a business can use several sources of finance these percentages add up to more than 100

22

Acemoglu and Johnson (2005). 23

De la Torre and Schmukler (2004) and Qian and Strahan (2007) point to many such mechanisms, such

as dollar contracts, short maturities with rollover clauses, and contracting under foreign jurisdiction. 24

Caprio and Honohan (2004).

Page 77: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

77

percent). External finance accounts for less than a fourth of total borrowing for starting a

business. Transport and textile clothing show the highest extent of borrowing from banks

at close to 14 percent of start-up capital, however, inter-sectoral differences are minor

(Table D.7 in Annex D). Small and mid-sized firms outside Lima were more likely to use

formal financing sources: Banks, Cajas Municipales, Edpymes, and Microfinance

institutions, with the opposite holding true for larger firms. Personal savings and support

from family and friends provide the dominant share of start-up financing in Lima and

outside Lima, and across all firm sizes and sectors. Formal finance was more likely to be

used by firms that had always had a RUC number, this may be used as an indicator of

“tending towards formality.” However the impact is small, suggesting that the general

credit environment, including the full range of laws relating to creditor and debtor

protection; comprehensiveness of credit registries; and collateral-related regulation, may

be more important than informality per se in improving access to the formal financial

system.

3.14 The picture is quite different when one examines whether firms have

currently taken out a loan for any purpose at all. Overall, nearly half the firms in the

sample took out a loan in either 2006 or 2007, and of these more than 93 percent relied

on formal sources (Table D.9 in Annex D). These figures are relatively high. Using data

from 71 investment climate surveys, an average of just over 20 percent of firms with 1 to

20 employees use external finance for new investment (World Bank 2008d:45). The

loans were taken primarily for equipment and machinery and also to finance working

capital, as out of the 392 businesses that took out a loan 235 reported it being at least

partly used for financing machinery and equipment.

3.15 Slightly more than half of all loans are granted with the interest rate on a

monthly basis. Around 53 percent of those businesses declaring having taken a loan are

quoted monthly interest rates, although in the case of banks the share of loans with annual

interest rates is around 55 percent (banks are the finance provider for which loans with

annual interest rates are more common than those with monthly interest rates (Table D.10

in Annex D). Among loans from banks the most common interest rate is 30 percent per

year (for loans with annual interest rates) and 4 per cent per month (for loans with

monthly interest rates). Among loans from moneylenders the most common interest rate

is 10 percent per month.

3.16 The maturity of loans is around 14 months. The maturity of loans does not vary

much by location or firm size, hovering around 14 to 15 months in all cases (Table D.11

in Annex D). The results of the survey have to be interpreted cautiously, as limited

financial literacy may affect the quality of survey responses. In this regard, it should be

noted that 56 percent of total respondents outside Lima claimed to have taken a loan

recently, compared to only 41 percent in Lima. This may have been due to some

confusion between “commercial” borrowing and interest-free loans from friends and

family.

3.17 Nearly two-thirds of the respondent firms had to provide loan guarantees. The proportion of firms providing guarantees was lower in Lima than in other regions.

Larger firms were less likely to be asked for a guarantee than small or mid-sized firms.

Overall, the proportion of firms that had to guarantee loans was 62.2 percent. This data

Page 78: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

78

points to the potentially significant impact of implementing the new Movable Collateral

Law and recent reforms aimed at improving coverage of credit registries.

3.18 There is no econometric evidence that having a municipal license or a RUC

enhances the likelihood of obtaining a loan. The same econometric techniques applied

to the impact on profits were also used to estimate the impact that having a municipal

license or a RUC number has in terms of the probability of getting a loan. The evidence

indicates that having a license or RUC number does not increase the probability of

getting a loan (Table D.14 in Annex D)

Page 79: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

79

List of references

Acemoglu, D. and S. Johnson (2005), ‘Unbundling Institutions,’ Journal of Political Economy

(113)5 (doi: 10.1086/432166).

Caprio, G. and P. Honohan (2004), ‘Can the unsophisticated market provide discipline?’ World

Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3364.

Chong, A., Galdo, and J. Saavedra (2007), ‘Informality and Productivity in the Labor Market:

Peru 1986–2001,’ IDB Research Department Working Paper No. 609

De La Roca, J. and M. Hernández (2004), ‘Evasión Tributaria e Informalidad en el Perú: Una

aproximación a partir del Enfoque de Discrepancias en el Consumo,’ Lima: Consorcio de

Investigación Económica y Social.

De la Torre, A., J. C. Gozzi, and S. L. Schmukler (2007), ‘Financial Development: Maturing and

Emerging Policy Issues,’ The World Bank Research Observer Advance Access published

on May 4, 2007.

De Mel, S., D. McKenzie, and C. Woodruff (2007), ‘Returns to Capital in Microenterprises:

Evidence from a Field Experiment,’ World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No.

4230, May.

Demirguc-Kunt, A. and R. Levine (2008), ‘Finance and Economic Opportunity,’ World Bank

Policy Research Working Paper No. 4468.

Djankov, S., C. McLiesh, and A. Shleifer (2007), ‘Private credit in 129 countries,’ Journal of

Financial Economics (84)2:299-329(doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2006.03.004).

Gasparini L. and L. Tornarolli (2006), ‘Labor Informality in Latin America and the Caribbean:

Patterns and Trends from Household Survey Microdata,’ background paper for World

Bank (2007), Informality. Exit and Exclusion, Flagship report of the Latin American and

Caribbean Vice-Presidency.

González, D. (2006), ‘Regímenes especiales de tributación para pequeños contribuyentes en

América Latina,’ Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo, Departamento de Integración y

Programas Regionales.

Haselmann, R.F. and P. Wachtel (2006), ‘Bank risk and bank management in transition,’ Policy

Conference, Tokyo, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development.

IFC (2008), Municipal Scorecard 2008. Midiendo las Barreras Burocráticas a Nivel Municipal.

Reporte Perú. Washington, D.C.: World Bank - IFC.

ILO (1991), Dilemma of the informal sector. Report of the Director-General presented at the 78th

International Labour Conference, International Labour Office, Geneva.

ILO (2006), Strategies and practice for labour inspection, Report of the Committee on

Employment and Social Policy to the Governing Body of the International Labor

Organization (GB.297/ESP/3), November.

Jaramillo, M. (2004), ‘La Regulación del Mercado Laboral en el Perú,’ Lima: GRADE.

Kristensen, N. and W. Cunningham (2006), ‘Do Minimum Wages in Latin America and the

Caribbean Matter? Evidence from 19 Countries,’ World Bank Policy Research Working

Paper No. 3870, March.

Page 80: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

80

Loayza, N. and J. Rigolini (2006), ‘Informality Trends and Cycles,’ World Bank Policy Research

Working Paper No. 4078, December.

Maloney, W. and J. Núñez (2001), ‘Measuring the Impact of Minimum Wages: Evidence from

Latin America,’ World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No.2597, April.

Qian, J. and P.E. Strahan (2007), ‘How laws and institutions shape financial contracts: the case of

bank loans,’ Journal of Finance (62)6:2803-2834 (doi:10.1111/j.1540-

6261.2007.01293.x)

World Bank (2007a), Peru: Casting Light on the Shadow Economy (Report No. 40220-PE).

World Bank (2007b), Informality. Exit and Exclusion, Flagship report of the Latin American and

Caribbean Vice-Presidency.

World Bank (2007c), Doing Business 2008. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

World Bank (2008a), Republic of Bolivia: Policies for Increasing Firms’ Formality and

Productivity (Report No. 40057-BO). Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

World Bank (2008b), Second Fiscal Management and Competitiveness Policy Development Loan

– Project Appraisal Document. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

World Bank (2008c), Database associated with is the database associated with A. Demirguc-

Kunt, A. and R. Levine, ‘Finance and Economic Opportunity,’ World Bank Policy

Research Working Paper No. 4468.

World Bank (2008d), Finance for All? Policies and Pitfalls in Expanding Access, A World Bank

Policy Research Report.

Yamada, G. and J. Chacaltana (2007), ‘Generación de Empleo en el Perú: Seis Casos Recientes

de Éxito,’ Documento de Discusión, DD/07/03. Universidad del Pacifico, Lima, Perú.

Page 81: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

81

Annex A. Measures of informality based on the ENAHO using different

definitions

Figure A.1: Calculating the productive definition of informality based on the ENAHO

p507ocu500 niv_ed / pub_o_priv tamano

2. Desocupado abierto

3. Desocupado oculto

4. No pea

7. Domestic workers

6. Family worker and others

5. Trabajador

familiar no

remunerado

6. Trabajador

del hogar

7. Otro

Yes

Yes

Trabajador

4. Self employed non

professional

1. Self employed

professional

1. Self employed

professional

3. Salaried public - formal

5. Salaried private -

informal

2. Salaried private - formal

3. Salaried public - formal

5. Salaried private -

informal

1. Más de 10

0. Hasta 10

0. Hasta 10

6. Educaci ón superior

completa

1. Primaria incompleta

2. Primaria completa

3. Secundaria

incompleta

4. Secundaria completa

5. Superior incompleta

Público

Privado

6. Educaci ón superior

completa

Público

Privado

2. Trabajador

independiente

3. Empleado

4. Obrero

2. Salaried private - formal

6. Family worker and others

1. Más de 10

Yes

1. Primaria incompleta

2. Primaria completa

3. Secundaria

incompleta

4. Secundaria completa

5. Superior incompleta

Yes4. Self employed non

professional

1. Ocupado

1. Empleador o

patrono

Information by respondent from ENAHO Calssification

Yes

Yes

Yes

Included in

informality

as per

productive

definition?

p507ocu500 niv_ed / pub_o_priv tamano

2. Desocupado abierto

3. Desocupado oculto

4. No pea

7. Domestic workers

6. Family worker and others

5. Trabajador

familiar no

remunerado

6. Trabajador

del hogar

7. Otro

Yes

Yes

Trabajador

4. Self employed non

professional

1. Self employed

professional

1. Self employed

professional

3. Salaried public - formal

5. Salaried private -

informal

2. Salaried private - formal

3. Salaried public - formal

5. Salaried private -

informal

1. Más de 10

0. Hasta 10

0. Hasta 10

6. Educaci ón superior

completa

1. Primaria incompleta

2. Primaria completa

3. Secundaria

incompleta

4. Secundaria completa

5. Superior incompleta

Público

Privado

6. Educaci ón superior

completa

Público

Privado

2. Trabajador

independiente

3. Empleado

4. Obrero

2. Salaried private - formal

6. Family worker and others

1. Más de 10

Yes

1. Primaria incompleta

2. Primaria completa

3. Secundaria

incompleta

4. Secundaria completa

5. Superior incompleta

Yes4. Self employed non

professional

1. Ocupado

1. Empleador o

patrono

Information by respondent from ENAHO Classification

Yes

Yes

Yes

Included in

informality

as per

productive

definition?

p507ocu500 niv_ed / pub_o_priv tamano

2. Desocupado abierto

3. Desocupado oculto

4. No pea

7. Domestic workers

6. Family worker and others

5. Trabajador

familiar no

remunerado

6. Trabajador

del hogar

7. Otro

Yes

Yes

Trabajador

4. Self employed non

professional

1. Self employed

professional

1. Self employed

professional

3. Salaried public - formal

5. Salaried private -

informal

2. Salaried private - formal

3. Salaried public - formal

5. Salaried private -

informal

1. Más de 10

0. Hasta 10

0. Hasta 10

6. Educaci ón superior

completa

1. Primaria incompleta

2. Primaria completa

3. Secundaria

incompleta

4. Secundaria completa

5. Superior incompleta

Público

Privado

6. Educaci ón superior

completa

Público

Privado

2. Trabajador

independiente

3. Empleado

4. Obrero

p507ocu500 niv_ed / pub_o_priv tamano

2. Desocupado abierto

3. Desocupado oculto

4. No pea

7. Domestic workers

6. Family worker and others

5. Trabajador

familiar no

remunerado

6. Trabajador

del hogar

7. Otro

Yes

Yes

Trabajador

4. Self employed non

professional

1. Self employed

professional

1. Self employed

professional

3. Salaried public - formal

5. Salaried private -

informal

2. Salaried private - formal

3. Salaried public - formal

5. Salaried private -

informal

1. Más de 10

0. Hasta 10

0. Hasta 10

6. Educaci ón superior

completa

1. Primaria incompleta

2. Primaria completa

3. Secundaria

incompleta

4. Secundaria completa

5. Superior incompleta

Público

Privado

6. Educaci ón superior

completa

Público

Privado

2. Trabajador

independiente

3. Empleado

4. Obrero

2. Salaried private - formal

6. Family worker and others

1. Más de 10

Yes

1. Primaria incompleta

2. Primaria completa

3. Secundaria

incompleta

4. Secundaria completa

5. Superior incompleta

Yes4. Self employed non

professional

1. Ocupado

1. Empleador o

patrono

Information by respondent from ENAHO Calssification

Yes

Yes

Yes

Included in

informality

as per

productive

definition?

p507ocu500 niv_ed / pub_o_priv tamano

2. Desocupado abierto

3. Desocupado oculto

4. No pea

7. Domestic workers

6. Family worker and others

5. Trabajador

familiar no

remunerado

6. Trabajador

del hogar

7. Otro

Yes

Yes

Trabajador

4. Self employed non

professional

1. Self employed

professional

1. Self employed

professional

3. Salaried public - formal

5. Salaried private -

informal

2. Salaried private -

2. Salaried private - formal

6. Family worker and others

1. Más de 10

Yes

1. Primaria incompleta

2. Primaria completa

3. Secundaria

incompleta

4. Secundaria completa

5. Superior incompleta

Yes4. Self employed non

professional

1. Ocupado

1. Empleador o

patrono

Information by respondent from ENAHO Calssification

Yes

Yes

Yes

Included in

informality

as per

productive

definition?

p507ocu500 niv_ed / pub_o_priv tamano

2. Desocupado abierto

3. Desocupado oculto

4. No pea

7. Domestic workers

6. Family worker and others

5. Trabajador

familiar no

remunerado

6. Trabajador

del hogar

7. Otro

Yes

Yes

Trabajador

4. Self employed non

professional

1. Self employed

professional

1. Self employed

professional

3. Salaried public - formal

5. Salaried private -

informal

2. Salaried private - formal

3. Salaried public - formal

5. Salaried private -

informal

1. Más de 10

0. Hasta 10

0. Hasta 10

6. Educaci ón superior

completa

1. Primaria incompleta

2. Primaria completa

3. Secundaria

incompleta

4. Secundaria completa

5. Superior incompleta

Público

Privado

6. Educaci ón superior

completa

Público

Privado

2. Trabajador

independiente

3. Empleado

4. Obrero

2. Salaried private - formal

6. Family worker and others

1. Más de 10

Yes

1. Primaria incompleta

2. Primaria completa

3. Secundaria

incompleta

4. Secundaria completa

5. Superior incompleta

Yes4. Self employed non

professional

1. Ocupado

1. Empleador o

patrono

Information by respondent from ENAHO Classification

Yes

Yes

Yes

Included in

informality

as per

productive

definition?

Page 82: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

82

Figure A.2: Map of prevalence of informality by region Percent of workers without a contract (2006)

76.8

84.5

76.4

74.7

81.0

58.3

63.7

68.9

64.2

62.6

85.4

84.890.6

89.0

76.4

77.2

89.7

86.3

78.2

86.2

89.5

78.5

75.4

88.2

55.4

Five less informal departments

Second five less informal departments

Third five less informal departments

Second five more informal departments

Five more informal departments

Legend

Five less informal departments

Second five less informal departments

Third five less informal departments

Second five more informal departments

Five more informal departments

Legend

Note: Informality rates are shown at the departmental level since this is the most disaggregated geographical unit for which the annual ENAHO survey provides a representative sample of the population.

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO.

Page 83: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

83

Figure A.3: Map of prevalence of informality by region Percent of workers working in businesses without legal personality (2006)

92.6

88.8

87.2

82.7

89.5

65.7

70.6

79.2

78.0

81.9

95.9

94.096.2

98.0

91.6

89.3

97.0

90.3

90.4

97.7

97.5

89.0

89.7

96.3

62.0

Five less informal departments

Second five less informal departments

Third five less informal departments

Second five more informal departments

Five more informal departments

Legend

Five less informal departments

Second five less informal departments

Third five less informal departments

Second five more informal departments

Five more informal departments

Legend

Note: Informality rates are shown at the departmental level since this is the most disaggregated geographical unit for which the annual ENAHO survey provides a representative sample of the population.

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO.

Page 84: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

84

Figure A.4: Map of prevalence of informality by region Percent of workers working in businesses that do not keep accounting books (2006)

88.5

86.5

75.7

78.8

82.1

60.9

66.9

74.9

78.0

75.1

92.3

88.494.9

93.7

84.9

84.9

94.3

90.2

88.2

90.9

95.2

77.0

87.8

95.1

58.5

Five less informal departments

Second five less informal departments

Third five less informal departments

Second five more informal departments

Five more informal departments

Legend

Five less informal departments

Second five less informal departments

Third five less informal departments

Second five more informal departments

Five more informal departments

Legend

Note: Informality rates are shown at the departmental level since this is the most disaggregated geographical unit for which the

annual ENAHO survey provides a representative sample of the population.

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO.

Page 85: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

85

Figure A.5: Prevalence of informality by region and income per capita Informality as measured by the ratio of workers without a contract (2006)

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO and INEI.

Amazonas

Ancash

Apurímac

Arequipa

Ayacucho Cajamarca

Callao

Cusco

HuancavelicaHuánuco

Ica

Junín

La LibertadLambayeque

Lima

Loreto

Madre de Dios

Moquegua

Pasco

Piura

PunoSan Martín

Tacna

Tumbes

Ucayali

.5.6

.7.8

.9In

form

alit

yp

reva

lence

4500 5000 5500 6000 6500 7000 7500 8000 8500 9000 9500 1000010500110001150012000

Average annual income, Nuevos soles

Amazonas

Ancash

Apurímac

Arequipa

Ayacucho Cajamarca

Callao

Cusco

HuancavelicaHuánuco

Ica

Junín

La LibertadLambayeque

Lima

Loreto

Madre de Dios

Moquegua

Pasco

Piura

PunoSan Martín

Tacna

Tumbes

Ucayali

.5.6

.7.8

.9In

form

alit

yp

reva

lence

4500 5000 5500 6000 6500 7000 7500 8000 8500 9000 9500 1000010500110001150012000

Average annual income, Nuevos soles

Page 86: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

86

Figure A.6: Prevalence of informality by region and income per capita Informality as measured by the ratio of workers working in a firm without legal personality (2006)

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO and INEI.

Amazonas

Ancash

Apurímac

Arequipa

Ayacucho

Cajamarca

Callao

Cusco

Huancavelica

Huánuco

Ica

Junín

La Libertad

Lambayeque

Lima

LoretoMadre de Dios

Moquegua

Pasco

Piura

Puno

San Martín

Tacna

Tumbes

Ucayali

.6.7

.8.9

1In

form

alit

yp

reva

lence

4500 5000 5500 6000 6500 7000 7500 8000 8500 9000 9500 1000010500110001150012000

Average annual income, Nuevos soles

Amazonas

Ancash

Apurímac

Arequipa

Ayacucho

Cajamarca

Callao

Cusco

Huancavelica

Huánuco

Ica

Junín

La Libertad

Lambayeque

Lima

LoretoMadre de Dios

Moquegua

Pasco

Piura

Puno

San Martín

Tacna

Tumbes

Ucayali

.6.7

.8.9

1In

form

alit

yp

reva

lence

4500 5000 5500 6000 6500 7000 7500 8000 8500 9000 9500 1000010500110001150012000

Average annual income, Nuevos soles

Page 87: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

87

Figure A.7: Prevalence of informality by region and income per capita Informality as measured by the ratio of workers working in a firm without accounting books (2006)

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO and INEI.

Figure A.8: Informality rate and economic growth, 2003 to 2006 Informality as measured by the percent of workers without a contract

Informality rate for sectors selected for the

survey and for all economic activities

Informality rate (all economic activities)

and economic growth

70

75

80

85

90

95

2003 2004 2005 2006

Info

rmal

ity r

ate

All economySelected sectors

70

75

80

85

90

95

3.5% 4.5% 5.5% 6.5% 7.5% 8.5%

Real GDP growth

Info

rmal

ity r

ate

200520042006

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO and INEI.

Amazonas

Ancash

Apurímac

Arequipa

Ayacucho

Cajamarca

Callao

Cusco

HuancavelicaHuánuco

Ica

Junín

La Libertad

Lambayeque

Lima

Loreto Madre de Dios

Moquegua

Pasco

Piura

Puno

San Martín

Tacna

Tumbes

Ucayali

.6.7

.8.9

1In

form

alit

yp

reva

lence

4500 5000 5500 6000 6500 7000 7500 8000 8500 9000 9500 1000010500110001150012000

Average annual income, Nuevos soles

Amazonas

Ancash

Apurímac

Arequipa

Ayacucho

Cajamarca

Callao

Cusco

HuancavelicaHuánuco

Ica

Junín

La Libertad

Lambayeque

Lima

Loreto Madre de Dios

Moquegua

Pasco

Piura

Puno

San Martín

Tacna

Tumbes

Ucayali

.6.7

.8.9

1In

form

alit

yp

reva

lence

4500 5000 5500 6000 6500 7000 7500 8000 8500 9000 9500 1000010500110001150012000

Average annual income, Nuevos soles

Page 88: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

88

Figure A.9: Informality rate and economic growth, 2003 to 2006 Informality as measured by the percent of workers working in businesses without legal personality

Informality rate for sectors selected for the

survey and for all economic activities

Informality rate (all economic activities)

and economic growth

70

75

80

85

90

95

2003 2004 2005 2006

Info

rmal

ity

rat

e

All economySelected sectors

70

75

80

85

90

95

3.5% 4.5% 5.5% 6.5% 7.5% 8.5%

Real GDP growth

Info

rmal

ity

rat

e

200520032004

2006

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO and INEI.

Figure A.10: Informality rate and economic growth, 2003 to 2006 Informality as measured by the percent of workers working in businesses without accounting books

Informality rate for sectors selected for the

survey and for all economic activities

Informality rate (all economic activities)

and economic growth

70

75

80

85

90

95

2003 2004 2005 2006

Info

rmal

ity r

ate

All economySelected sectors

70

75

80

85

90

95

3.5% 4.5% 5.5% 6.5% 7.5% 8.5%

Real GDP growth

Info

rmal

ity r

ate

20052003 2004 2006

Source: World Bank staff calculations based on ENAHO and INEI.

Page 89: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

89

Table A.1: Special fiscal regimens for small taxpayers in Latin America

Component Countries

Have special tax regimes for small contributors. Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Colombia, Costa Rica, Chile, Ecuador,

México, Nicaragua, Honduras, Paraguay, Peru, Dominican

Republic and Uruguay.

Do not have special tax regimes for small

contributors

El Salvador, Panama y Venezuela.

Applies more than one special regime. Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, México, Peru y Uruguay.

Only includes individual persons. Argentina, Bolivia, Colombia, Chile, Ecuador, México Nicaragua,

Honduras, Paraguay, Peru (RUS), Dominican Republic and

Uruguay.

Includes juridical persons. Brazil, Costa Rica, Chile, Mexico, Peru (RER) and Uruguay.

Considers only gross income to determine

included contributors.

Brazil, Chile, México, Paraguay, and Dominican Republic.

Considers assets, physical parameters or other

indicator to determine included contributors.

Argentina, Bolivia, Colombia, Costa Rica, Chile, Ecuador,

Mexico, Nicaragua, Honduras, Paraguay, Peru and Uruguay.

Applies fixed tariff technique. Argentina, Bolivia, Chile, México, Nicaragua, Peru (RUS)and

Uruguay.

Applies a percentage over gross income. Brazil, Chile and Peru (RER).

Applies a regime that substitutes taxes only. Bolivia, Brazil, Colombia, Costa Rica, Chile, Ecuador, Mexico,

Nicaragua, Honduras, Paraguay, Peru, Dominican Republic and

Uruguay.

Applies a regime that substitutes taxes and social

security.

Argentina, Brazil and Uruguay

Applies a regime that substitutes only one tax. Brazil, Colombia, Costa Rica, Chile, Ecuador, Honduras,

Paraguay, Peru (RER) and Dominican Republic

Applies a regime that substitutes VAT and the

income tax

Argentina, Bolivia, Mexico, Nicaragua, Paraguay, Peru (RUS)

and Uruguay.

Source: Gonzalez (2006)

Table A.2: Regulatory labor burden in comparative perspective

Difficulty of

Hiring Index

Rigidity of

Hours Index

Difficulty of

Firing Index

Rigidity of

Employment Index

Nonwage labor cost

(% of salary)

Firing costs (weeks

of wages)

Peru 44 60 60 55 10 52

Argentina 44 60 20 41 26 139

Bolivia 78 60 100 79 14 n.a.

Brazil 78 60 0 46 37 37

Chile 33 20 20 24 3 52

Colombia 22 40 20 27 29 59

Ecuador 44 60 50 51 12 135

Mexico 33 40 70 48 21 52

Paraguay 56 60 60 59 17 113

Uruguay 33 60 0 31 6 31

Venezuela 78 60 100 79 16 n.a.

Latin America & Caribbean 36.9 35.5 24.5 32.3 12.7 56.1

Source: Doing Business 2008.

Page 90: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

90

Descriptive statistics from the dedicated survey

Table A.3: Main informality characteristics among surveyed businesses, by city

Percent of surveyed businesses

Arequipa Cusco Huancayo Lima Trujillo

Firm has municipal license 60 72 80 71 43

Firm has permanent license 52 53 46 58 30

Firm paid taxes in November 2007 50 75 67 71 73

Percent of sales reported for tax purposes 62 58 44 52 51

Firm has RUC number 68 79 82 81 77

Firm files under RUS 21 40 37 24 32

Firm files under Special Regime (RER) 14 12 11 7 17

Firm files under General Regime 32 26 32 49 26

Firm never gives facturas or boletas 19 22 17 19 19

Firm has no workers with a labor contract 86 78 82 81 94

Firm has no workers with health insurance 71 78 72 66 79

Firm has no workers with pension coverage 86 87 81 79 88

Firm has limited liability (SA, SRL, SAC) 15 12 19 23 6

Sample size 111 108 93 368 122

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Table A.4: Main informality characteristics among surveyed businesses, by sector

Percent of surveyed businesses

Shoes

and

leather

Textiles

& apparel

Wood

products

Metal

products

Retail

food-

stuffs

Trans-

port

Restau-

rants

Firm has municipal license 56 51 60 69 81 68 83

Firm has permanent license 43 37 44 51 63 47 70

Firm paid taxes in November 2007 64 54 68 78 85 55 75

Percent of sales reported for tax purposes 54 50 56 46 53 59 53

Firm has RUC number 74 71 80 87 90 54 88

Firm files under RUS 38 23 19 25 49 5 39

Firm files under Special Regime (RER) 16 10 14 10 6 11 7

Firm files under General Regime 21 38 46 52 36 35 37

Firm never gives facturas or boletas 21 21 12 7 13 52 15

Firm has no workers with a labor contract 90 89 80 82 88 80 74

Firm has no workers with health insurance 85 82 69 69 67 69 57

Firm has no workers with pension coverage 90 87 80 82 84 84 75

Firm has limited liability (SA, SRL, SAC) 9 15 16 25 11 29 17

Sample size 117 119 126 118 105 95 122

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 91: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

91

Table A.5: Most important problem affecting micro and small business owners

Percent of respondents

Most important problem affecting the business

1 to 5 workers 6 to 10 workers 11 to 50 workers Total

Economic situation 18 15 18 17

Taxes 11 21 16 14

Lack of capital, financing 12 15 14 13

Inflation 16 9 7 12

Competition 10 15 10 11

Lack of support from the authorities 5 4 7 5

Crime 5 4 5 5

Bureaucracy 4 1 5 4

Other social problems 3 1 5 3

Imports 3 1 3 3

Difficulties getting inputs 3 4 1 3

Unemployment 2 4 0 2

Corruption 2 1 3 2

Low purchasing power 2 1 2 2

Difficulties getting right employees 1 2 1 1

Informality 1 1 2 1

Lack of investment 1 0 1 1

Lack of information and advice 1 0 0 1

High cost of rents 1 1 0 1

Lack of infrastructure (transport, etc) 0 1 1 1

Not being located in a commercial area 0 0 1 0

Sample size 378 171 153 702

Second most important problem affecting the business

1 to 5 workers 6 to 10 workers 11 to 50 workers Total

Inflation 17 17 10 16

Taxes 14 9 16 14

Unemployment 1 1 2 1

Crime 6 9 3 6

Lack of capital, financing 11 10 8 10

Economic situation 11 11 8 10

Competition 12 10 12 11

Bureaucracy 1 4 4 2

Informality 1 1 0 1

Lack of support from the authorities 5 4 6 5

Corruption 3 6 3 4

Imports 2 2 2 2

Difficulties getting right employees 2 4 11 5

Difficulties getting inputs 3 1 2 2

High cost of rents 0 0 0 0

Lack of infrastructure (transport, etc) 2 3 0 2

Low purchasing power 4 2 5 4

Not being located in a commercial area 1 0 0 1

Other social problems 3 2 5 3

Lack of information and advice 1 1 2 1

Sample size 306 139 128 573

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 92: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

92

Table A.6: Obstacles for micro and small businesses - detailed questionnaire

Percent of respondents. Issues ordered top-to-bottom, left-to-right according to share of respondents that

consider an issue to be a serious obstacle.

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersTotal

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersTotal

Crime The limited size of the market

No obstacle 4 4 3 4 No obstacle 10 21 23 16

Minor obstacle 9 10 10 9 Minor obstacle 17 17 19 17

Moderate obstacle 19 19 17 18 Moderate obstacle 32 37 36 34

Serious obstacle 68 68 69 68 Serious obstacle 41 25 22 33

Corruption Lack of qualified labor

No obstacle 7 7 7 7 No obstacle 34 24 29 30

Minor obstacle 9 8 10 9 Minor obstacle 20 20 21 20

Moderate obstacle 17 17 15 17 Moderate obstacle 27 31 29 29

Serious obstacle 67 68 68 68 Serious obstacle 19 24 22 21

Economic instability Access to inputs

No obstacle 4 5 5 4 No obstacle 31 33 38 33

Minor obstacle 9 13 13 11 Minor obstacle 19 22 19 20

Moderate obstacle 26 26 21 25 Moderate obstacle 29 27 22 27

Serious obstacle 61 58 62 60 Serious obstacle 21 19 20 20

Political instability Customs regulations

No obstacle 7 7 8 7 No obstacle 45 40 40 43

Minor obstacle 15 15 15 15 Minor obstacle 16 15 17 16

Moderate obstacle 26 26 26 26 Moderate obstacle 22 20 24 22

Serious obstacle 52 52 51 52 Serious obstacle 18 25 19 20

Taxes Quality of transport infrastructure

No obstacle 14 11 11 13 No obstacle 35 27 37 34

Minor obstacle 15 12 12 13 Minor obstacle 24 24 15 22

Moderate obstacle 24 25 23 24 Moderate obstacle 20 32 26 24

Serious obstacle 47 53 55 50 Serious obstacle 21 16 22 20

Cost of credit Enforcing contracts

No obstacle 13 15 19 15 No obstacle 33 36 36 34

Minor obstacle 14 9 20 14 Minor obstacle 25 25 22 24

Moderate obstacle 27 24 25 26 Moderate obstacle 22 25 20 22

Serious obstacle 46 52 36 45 Serious obstacle 20 14 22 19

Unfair competition Labor regulations

No obstacle 11 6 9 9 No obstacle 34 27 31 32

Minor obstacle 17 16 15 16 Minor obstacle 24 21 24 23

Moderate obstacle 31 27 29 29 Moderate obstacle 29 37 24 30

Serious obstacle 41 51 47 45 Serious obstacle 13 14 21 15

Requirements to obtain a loan

No obstacle 16 23 31 21

Minor obstacle 16 12 19 16

Moderate obstacle 23 26 23 24

Serious obstacle 45 39 27 39

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 93: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

93

Table A.7: Sales of micro and small businesses surveyed, by customer type and business size

Percent of total sales

1 to 5 workers 6 to 10 workers 11 to 50 workers Total

General public 90 78 73 83

Small businesses (less than 20 workers) 3 7 9 5

To intermediaries in Peru 3 6 5 4

Medium and large businesses (> 20 workers) 1 2 4 2

Exports directly 0 1 3 1

To intermediaries that export 0 2 2 1

State 0 1 2 1

Multinationals 0 1 0 0

Others 2 3 3 3

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Table A.8: Elements of formality

Percent of businesses displaying different elements of formality

All businesses

Business belongs

to an association

(gremio )?

Business has a key

supplier providing

more than 25 percent

of inputs?

Business has a key

client that buys more

than 25 percent of its

output?

Business is linked to a

bigger firm through

sub-contracting

arrangement?

Total1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersNo Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes

Nothing 15 24 7 2 16 7 20 9 15 13 15 8

Municipal license only 6 11 2 1 6 7 9 2 7 2 6 11

RUC only 16 15 23 11 17 13 13 20 14 24 16 22

Municipal license and RUC 39 40 47 31 41 28 38 41 43 29 40 32

RUC, municipal license, and limited

liability10 4 9 26 8 22 8 12 9 14 10 12

RUC, municipal license, and all

workers with contract6 4 6 11 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 5

RUC, municipal license, all workers

with contract, and limited liability5 1 5 15 4 11 5 5 4 8 5 5

Other combinations of formality 3 2 4 4 2 5 2 4 3 4 3 6

Sample size 802 688 114 438 364 615 187 737 65

o/w businesses with 1 to 5 workers 421 421 - - 381 40 265 156 348 73 394 27

…businesses with 6 to 10 workers 201 - 201 - 172 29 94 107 145 56 177 24

…businesses with 11 to 50 workers 180 - - 180 135 45 79 101 122 58 166 14

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 94: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

94

Table A.9: Factors affecting the choice of tax regime

Percent of businesses

Reasons for choosing the General Regime Reasons for choosing the RUS or RER regimes

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersTotal

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersTotal

To issue receipts (facturas ) You pay less taxes

Not important 1 4 2 2 Not important 4 8 5 6

Somewhat important 10 6 5 7 Somewhat important 14 13 11 14

Fairly important 27 27 26 27 Fairly important 37 30 32 34

Very important 62 62 67 64 Very important 44 48 52 47

Sample size 101 77 126 304 Sample size 166 99 44 309

To avoid fines I have always been in a special regime

Not important 5 11 4 6 Not important 14 6 17 12

Somewhat important 10 7 8 8 Somewhat important 23 9 7 16

Fairly important 23 26 29 26 Fairly important 33 39 41 36

Very important 62 57 59 60 Very important 30 46 34 36

Sample size 101 76 125 302 Sample size 153 93 41 287

I have always been in the general regime My sales are low

Not important 5 9 10 8 Not important 8 12 11 10

Somewhat important 19 13 14 15 Somewhat important 26 27 23 26

Fairly important 31 24 25 27 Fairly important 29 29 30 29

Very important 44 53 51 50 Very important 37 32 36 35

Sample size 99 75 125 299 Sample size 167 97 44 308

All businesses in my area are in this regime All businesses in my area are in the special regimes

Not important 10 14 11 11 Not important 16 7 5 12

Somewhat important 22 28 22 23 Somewhat important 24 21 21 23

Fairly important 26 23 25 25 Fairly important 29 42 44 35

Very important 43 35 43 41 Very important 31 30 31 31

Sample size 94 69 114 277 Sample size 147 81 39 267

My sales are too high for a special regime I do not need to issue receipts (facturas) to my clients

Not important 24 18 14 19 Not important 15 12 18 15

Somewhat important 33 38 20 29 Somewhat important 28 24 16 25

Fairly important 20 20 26 23 Fairly important 28 29 39 30

Very important 22 24 39 30 Very important 29 35 27 31

Sample size 90 71 125 286 Sample size 166 100 44 310

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 95: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

95

Table A.10: Participation in state-supported programs

Percent of businesses unless otherwise indicated

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersTotal

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersTotal

Do you know about? Do you take part or ever took part?

Credit lines by COFIDE

Yes 28 31 44 33 1 1 2 1

No 72 69 56 67 99 99 98 99

Preferences to micro businesses in state purchases (PROMPYME program)

Yes 24 30 39 29 2 5 4 3

No 76 70 61 71 98 95 96 97

Market information by MTPE or PRODUCE ministries

Yes 10 15 24 15 1 2 4 2

No 90 85 76 85 99 98 96 98

BONOPYME

Yes 8 14 17 12 2 4 3 2

No 92 86 83 88 98 96 97 98

Support for exporting by PROMPEX

Yes 14 20 30 19 2 3 3 2

No 86 80 70 81 98 97 97 98

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersTotal

Number of businesses participating in…

At least one program 20 19 18 57

Any two programs 13 11 10 34

Credit lines by COFIDE 6 2 4 12

Preferences to micro businesses in state purchases (PROMPYME program) 9 10 7 26

Market information by MTPE or PRODUCE ministries 4 4 7 15

BONOPYME 7 8 5 20

Support for exporting by PROMPEX 7 6 5 18

Memo item: survey sample 421 201 180 802

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 96: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

96

Rationale for decision-making regarding business licensing

Table A.11: Key factors behind the decision to not have a license, by business size

Percent of businesses without a license that answered yes when asked if a particular factor had played a

role or not in their decision not to have a license

Factor1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersTotal

The process is too time consuming 71 65 65 69

The costs of running a business with a license are too high 67 56 61 63

My business is too small to have a license 64 47 35 57

The process is too expensive 59 53 48 56

I see no benefits in getting it 56 55 45 54

The forms are too complicated 50 39 42 46

There is no obligation to get it 47 44 45 46

No business like mine has a license 43 45 29 42

I do not know how to obtain it 39 36 52 40

No point obtaining it since fines are rare 36 36 45 37

Number of respondents 250 135 149 534

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Table A.12: Knowledge of where to formalize

Percent of businesses

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersAll

Do you know where is the office to get the municipal license?

Yes 91 97 93 93

Do you know where is the office to get the RUC number?

Yes 87 94 91 90

Do you know where is the office of SUNAT?

Yes 87 94 94 90

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 97: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

97

Rationale for decision-making regarding labor relations

Table A.13: Share of workers earning less than minimum wage, by business size

Percent of workers. Mean of responses to the question: In your area of activity, what percentage of workers

do you estimate earn less than the minimum wage?

1 to 5 workers 6 to 10 workers 11 to 50 workers Total

All 62 52 45 56

Shoe and leather manufacturing 61 41 43 52

Textile and apparel manufacturing 63 54 53 58

Manufacturing of wood products and furniture 60 53 46 55

Manufacturing of metallic products 58 53 37 52

Retail of foodstuffs 73 67 57 68

Transport by land 43 36 40 41

Restaurants and hotels 72 63 42 62

Arequipa 64 49 48 57

cusco 64 57 35 59

Huancayo 75 70 63 72

Lima 54 49 43 50

Trujillo 64 47 46 56

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Table A.14: Reasons for not paying the minimum wage, by business size

Percent of businesses that answered yes when asked if a factor explains why workers are paid less than the

minimum wage

1 to 5 workers 6 to 10 workers 11 to 50 workers Total

There are many people willing to work for less than the

minimum wage81 80 81 81

The business is not productive enough to allow paying the

minimum wage71 66 51 65

It is not compulsory to pay the minimum wage to workers

that are not on the payroll53 46 54 51

No firm in my sector pays the minimum wage to its

workers55 42 41 49

You do not have to pay family members to work in the

family business40 38 36 39

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 98: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

98

Table A.15: Percent of workers not on the payroll, by business size

Percent of workers. Mean of responses to the question: In your area of activity, what percentage of workers

do you estimate that are not on the payroll?

1 to 5 workers 6 to 10 workers 11 to 50 workers Total

All 75 68 61 70

Shoe and leather manufacturing 76 76 80 77

Textile and apparel manufacturing 74 64 63 69

Manufacturing of wood products and furniture 72 70 59 69

Manufacturing of metallic products 67 70 51 64

Retail of foodstuffs 79 71 63 74

Transport by land 79 61 62 71

Restaurants and hotels 77 61 52 67

Arequipa 75 70 65 72

cusco 76 73 44 72

Huancayo 76 73 63 73

Lima 73 67 60 68

Trujillo 76 59 68 69

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Table A.16: Reasons for not having workers on payroll, by business size

Percent of businesses that answered yes when asked if a factor explains why workers are not on the payroll

1 to 5 workers 6 to 10 workers 11 to 50 workers Total

There are many people willing to work without

being on the payroll88 90 89 89

One would have to pay the worker holidays and

other benefits if they were on the payroll89 84 81 86

It would be very expensive to fire a worker that is

on the payroll 77 72 64 73

It would be very complicated to fire a worker that is

on the payroll 76 69 59 70

You have to pay them a higher salary 77 67 55 70

Having an employee on the payroll creates more

paperwork71 64 60 67

No busineses in my sector has its employees on the

payroll58 53 46 54

You do not need to include family members on the

payroll50 39 37 44

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 99: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

99

Annex B. Econometric results on the choice of tax regime and

determinants of tax inspections Table B.1: Choice of tax regime - probit regression

Marginal effects from probits looking at choice of

1. RER vs RUS

2. RER vs Regimen General

In both cases RER is coded as 1. There are only 86 firms with RER.

(1) (2)

Female owner 0.00889 0.0629

(0.056) (0.053)

Owner's Age 0.000767 0.000842

(0.0025) (0.0022)

Owner is Married 0.0698 0.0180

(0.053) (0.046)

Owner has Tecnico education 0.0479 -0.0299

(0.098) (0.075)

Owner has University education 0.0253 -0.105*

(0.083) (0.059)

Owner has complete secondary education 0.132* 0.0124

(0.071) (0.061)

Parent owned a business 0.0424 0.00680

(0.053) (0.044)

Age of firm 0.000199 0.00313

(0.0028) (0.0022)

SUNAT inspection rate in city*industry -0.210 -0.342

(0.22) (0.21)

Shoe/Leather 0.0870 0.239*

(0.097) (0.12)

Textiles/Clothing 0.108 0.0459

(0.11) (0.095)

Wood products 0.309*** 0.0504

(0.12) (0.088)

Metal products 0.164 0.00268

(0.11) (0.084)

Food stuffs -0.0470 0.00991

(0.088) (0.094)

Transport 0.272** 0.0647

(0.14) (0.100)

Arequipa 0.279** 0.196**

(0.11) (0.090)

Trujillo 0.221* 0.163

(0.13) (0.13)

Huancayo 0.0150 0.290**

(0.100) (0.13)

Cusco 0.0863 0.344***

(0.11) (0.13)

6 to 10 workers 0.228*** 0.0688

(0.061) (0.055)

11 to 50 workers 0.233** -0.0526

(0.099) (0.054)

Log distance to the SUNAT Office -0.00218 0.0611

(0.049) (0.043)

Log distance to City Center -0.0232 -0.0577

(0.045) (0.040)

Firm has limited liability 0.318** -0.111**

(0.13) (0.045)

Observations 345 389

Note: omitted dummies are Restaurants, Lima, <5 workers, Male, and Less than Secondary Education

Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Page 100: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

100

Table B.2: Choice of tax regime - multinomial logit (general regime)

Multinomial Logit

Marginal effects of being under the Regimen General.

variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X

---------+ ----------- --------------- ------ ------- ---------- ---------- ---------

female*| -0.045 0.053 -0.850 0.396 -0.150 0.059 0.299

ownerage | -0.002 0.002 -0.740 0.461 -0.007 0.003 41.664

married*| 0.027 0.051 0.530 0.595 -0.073 0.127 0.472

ed_tec~o*| 0.008 0.088 0.100 0.923 -0.164 0.181 0.131

ed_uni~y*| 0.098 0.074 1.310 0.190 -0.048 0.243 0.307

ed_sec~e*| 0.033 0.069 0.470 0.635 -0.102 0.168 0.384

parent~s*| 0.055 0.049 1.120 0.264 -0.041 0.150 0.407

firmage | -0.004 0.003 -1.430 0.153 -0.009 0.001 12.116

inspec.. | 0.211 0.241 0.870 0.382 -0.262 0.683 0.206

shoele~r*| -0.187 0.087 -2.150 0.032 -0.358 -0.016 0.140

textil~g*| 0.115 0.088 1.300 0.193 -0.058 0.287 0.133

woodpr~s*| 0.134 0.085 1.580 0.113 -0.032 0.300 0.160

metalp~s*| 0.161 0.082 1.950 0.051 -0.001 0.322 0.164

foodst~s*| -0.039 0.089 -0.440 0.661 -0.215 0.136 0.153

transp~t*| 0.093 0.098 0.950 0.342 -0.099 0.285 0.091

arequipa*| -0.082 0.080 -1.020 0.308 -0.240 0.076 0.116

trujullo*| -0.042 0.116 -0.360 0.718 -0.270 0.186 0.150

huancayo*| -0.255 0.082 -3.100 0.002 -0.416 -0.094 0.117

cusco*| -0.262 0.087 -3.000 0.003 -0.433 -0.091 0.144

mediana1*| 0.061 0.055 1.120 0.264 -0.046 0.169 0.279

grande1*| 0.301 0.055 5.510 0.000 0.194 0.408 0.262

ldista~T | -0.110 0.044 -2.500 0.013 -0.196 -0.024 1.391

ldista~y | 0.100 0.045 2.220 0.027 0.012 0.189 1.312

limite~y*| 0.378 0.050 7.500 0.000 0.279 0.477 0.202

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

Page 101: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

101

Table B.3: Choice of tax regime - multinomial logit (RUS)

Multinomial Logit

Marginal effects for being under the RUS

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X

---------+ ----------- --------------- ------ ------- ---------- ---------- ---------

female*| 0.029 0.050 0.590 0.558 -0.069 0.128 0.299

ownerage | 0.001 0.002 0.530 0.595 -0.003 0.006 41.664

married*| -0.048 0.048 -1.000 0.318 -0.142 0.046 0.472

ed_tec~o*| -0.017 0.080 -0.210 0.831 -0.174 0.140 0.131

ed_uni~y*| -0.059 0.067 -0.880 0.381 -0.191 0.073 0.307

ed_sec~e*| -0.079 0.060 -1.300 0.193 -0.197 0.040 0.384

parent~s*| -0.060 0.045 -1.310 0.189 -0.149 0.029 0.407

firmage | 0.002 0.003 0.870 0.382 -0.003 0.007 12.116

inspec.. | -0.012 0.218 -0.060 0.956 -0.440 0.416 0.206

shoele~r*| 0.081 0.087 0.930 0.354 -0.090 0.251 0.140

textil~g*| -0.148 0.068 -2.180 0.029 -0.281 -0.015 0.133

woodpr~s*| -0.224 0.056 -3.990 0.000 -0.334 -0.114 0.160

metalp~s*| -0.196 0.060 -3.270 0.001 -0.314 -0.078 0.164

foodst~s*| 0.059 0.083 0.710 0.476 -0.104 0.222 0.153

transp~t*| -0.183 0.067 -2.720 0.007 -0.314 -0.051 0.091

arequipa*| -0.091 0.071 -1.290 0.198 -0.229 0.048 0.116

trujullo*| -0.113 0.088 -1.290 0.196 -0.285 0.058 0.150

huancayo*| 0.169 0.097 1.740 0.082 -0.022 0.360 0.117

cusco*| 0.119 0.097 1.230 0.219 -0.071 0.308 0.144

mediana1*| -0.164 0.044 -3.770 0.000 -0.250 -0.079 0.279

grande1*| -0.324 0.042 -7.620 0.000 -0.407 -0.240 0.262

ldista~T | 0.092 0.041 2.270 0.023 0.012 0.172 1.391

ldista~y | -0.076 0.041 -1.830 0.067 -0.157 0.005 1.312

limite~y*| -0.366 0.041 -8.970 0.000 -0.446 -0.286 0.202

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

Page 102: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

102

Table B.4: Choice of tax regime - multinomial logit (RER)

Multinomial Logit

Marginal effects for being under the RER

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X

---------+ ----------- --------------- ------ ------- ---------- ---------- ---------

female*| 0.016 0.034 0.470 0.639 -0.051 0.082 0.299

ownerage | 0.001 0.001 0.390 0.698 -0.002 0.003 41.664

married*| 0.021 0.031 0.660 0.508 -0.040 0.082 0.472

ed_tec~o*| 0.009 0.058 0.150 0.883 -0.106 0.123 0.131

ed_uni~y*| -0.039 0.043 -0.900 0.366 -0.122 0.045 0.307

ed_sec~e*| 0.046 0.043 1.060 0.287 -0.039 0.131 0.384

parent~s*| 0.005 0.030 0.170 0.864 -0.054 0.065 0.407

firmage | 0.002 0.002 1.010 0.314 -0.001 0.004 12.116

inspec.. | -0.198 0.137 -1.450 0.147 -0.467 0.070 0.206

shoele~r*| 0.107 0.080 1.340 0.180 -0.049 0.262 0.140

textil~g*| 0.033 0.067 0.500 0.620 -0.099 0.165 0.133

woodpr~s*| 0.090 0.074 1.220 0.222 -0.054 0.234 0.160

metalp~s*| 0.035 0.066 0.530 0.596 -0.095 0.165 0.164

foodst~s*| -0.020 0.061 -0.330 0.742 -0.139 0.099 0.153

transp~t*| 0.090 0.084 1.060 0.288 -0.076 0.255 0.091

arequipa*| 0.173 0.077 2.240 0.025 0.021 0.324 0.116

trujullo*| 0.155 0.104 1.490 0.135 -0.049 0.359 0.150

huancayo*| 0.085 0.084 1.020 0.309 -0.079 0.250 0.117

cusco*| 0.143 0.093 1.540 0.123 -0.039 0.325 0.144

mediana1*| 0.103 0.041 2.490 0.013 0.022 0.184 0.279

grande1*| 0.023 0.042 0.550 0.581 -0.059 0.105 0.262

ldista~T | 0.018 0.029 0.600 0.551 -0.040 0.075 1.391

ldista~y | -0.024 0.028 -0.890 0.374 -0.078 0.029 1.312

limite~y*| -0.013 0.037 -0.340 0.737 -0.086 0.061 0.202

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

Page 103: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

103

Table B.5: Probit regression on the determinants of tax inspections Who does SUNAT inspect?

Marginal effects from probit estimation of probability of receiving an inspection

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Log distance to SUNAT office -0.0337*** -0.0289** -0.0390** -0.0121

(0.012) (0.012) (0.017) (0.026)

Has a RUC 0.169*** 0.161*** 0.140***

(0.027) (0.026) (0.028)

6-10 workers 0.0613* 0.0552 0.0496

(0.037) (0.036) (0.037)

11-50 workers 0.0901** 0.124*** 0.0838**

(0.040) (0.042) (0.042)

Arequipa 0.113** 0.0975*

(0.055) (0.057)

Trujillo 0.295*** 0.246***

(0.058) (0.089)

Huancayo 0.0402 0.0437

(0.061) (0.063)

Cusco 0.232*** 0.225***

(0.064) (0.072)

Female owner -0.0430

(0.029)

Owner's Age -0.000396

(0.0014)

Owner is Married -0.0455

(0.029)

Owner has Tecnico education 0.132*

(0.070)

Owner has University education 0.144***

(0.055)

Owner has complete secondary education 0.0674

(0.044)

Parent owned a business 0.0268

(0.029)

Age of firm 0.00215

(0.0015)

In business to care for family -0.0103

(0.031)

In business for flexibility 0.0304

(0.032)

In business because can't find wage job -0.0507

(0.033)

In business for prospect of growth 0.00293

(0.056)

Shoe/Leather -0.0305

(0.045)

Textiles/Clothing -0.0763*

(0.039)

Wood products -0.00140

(0.049)

Metal products -0.0404

(0.044)

Food stuffs 0.136**

(0.063)

Transport 0.00379

(0.055)

Log distance to the city center -0.0245

(0.026)

Observations 801 801 801 801

Note: omitted dummies are Restaurants, Lima, <5 workers, Male, and Less than Secondary Education

Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Page 104: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

104

Annex C. Econometric results on the determinants of informality

Determinants of Public Medical Coverage of Workers

Columns 1-4: marginal effects from probit of any worker being covered

Column 5: results dropping family enterprises

Column 5: OLS regression of share of workers covered

Column 6: OLS regression of share of workers covered conditional on having any worker covered

Column 7: Fractional logit model of share of workers covered, to account for proportion

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Female owner 0.0114 0.0151 0.0221 0.0422 0.0417 0.0298 -0.0107 0.331

(0.039) (0.039) (0.039) (0.043) (0.055) (0.027) (0.061) (0.25)

Owner's Age -0.00244 -0.00262 -0.00116 -0.00131 -0.00228 -0.000559 -0.00169 -0.00606

(0.0017) (0.0017) (0.0017) (0.0018) (0.0023) (0.0011) (0.0024) (0.013)

Owner is Married 0.108*** 0.108*** 0.109*** 0.111*** 0.142*** 0.0682*** 0.0321 0.635***

(0.036) (0.036) (0.036) (0.038) (0.047) (0.025) (0.055) (0.24)

Owner has Tecnico education 0.0923 0.0950 0.0837 0.114 0.116 0.0896** 0.303*** 1.126***

(0.073) (0.073) (0.074) (0.081) (0.10) (0.044) (0.10) (0.40)

Owner has University education 0.258*** 0.258*** 0.201*** 0.167** 0.223*** 0.106*** 0.256*** 1.211***

(0.062) (0.064) (0.066) (0.070) (0.080) (0.038) (0.092) (0.37)

Owner has complete secondary education 0.0517 0.0461 0.0548 0.0317 0.0328 0.0538 0.371*** 0.838**

(0.052) (0.052) (0.053) (0.055) (0.071) (0.033) (0.094) (0.34)

Parent owned a business -0.0182 -0.0183 -0.0232 -0.0292 0.0289 -0.00720 -0.00438 -0.0954

(0.035) (0.035) (0.035) (0.036) (0.047) (0.024) (0.058) (0.22)

Age of firm 0.00764*** 0.00758*** 0.00607*** 0.00564*** 0.00771*** 0.00281** 0.000110 0.0268**

(0.0018) (0.0018) (0.0018) (0.0020) (0.0025) (0.0013) (0.0026) (0.011)

Labor inspection rate in city*industry 0.829** 0.860** 0.823** 0.729** 0.651 0.443* -0.123 4.073*

(0.33) (0.33) (0.33) (0.35) (0.44) (0.23) (0.52) (2.37)

Shoe/Leather -0.183*** -0.177*** -0.185*** -0.181*** -0.199*** -0.0749 0.130 -0.932**

(0.042) (0.044) (0.040) (0.039) (0.059) (0.048) (0.12) (0.41)

Textiles/Clothing -0.142*** -0.135*** -0.132*** -0.0828 -0.141** -0.0286 0.0844 -0.264

(0.050) (0.051) (0.050) (0.058) (0.071) (0.051) (0.12) (0.46)

Wood products -0.0528 -0.0449 -0.0473 -0.0535 -0.0767 0.00253 0.0843 0.0487

(0.059) (0.060) (0.058) (0.058) (0.078) (0.047) (0.094) (0.37)

Metal products -0.0926* -0.0908* -0.0757 -0.0847 -0.0620 -0.0470 0.0101 -0.461

(0.053) (0.053) (0.055) (0.053) (0.078) (0.047) (0.095) (0.39)

Food stuffs -0.0377 -0.0252 -0.0116 -0.0371 0.000893 -0.0305 -0.0260 -0.365

(0.061) (0.063) (0.065) (0.063) (0.095) (0.049) (0.10) (0.43)

Transport -0.0859 -0.0867 -0.0701 -0.0660 -0.113 -0.0135 0.106 -0.0605

(0.056) (0.056) (0.057) (0.058) (0.072) (0.050) (0.11) (0.38)

Arequipa -0.131*** -0.133*** -0.0913** -0.0264 -0.131** -0.0536 -0.176* -0.602*

(0.040) (0.040) (0.044) (0.054) (0.057) (0.040) (0.093) (0.32)

Trujillo -0.145** -0.147*** -0.102 -0.0783 -0.109 -0.0267 -0.00731 -0.430

(0.057) (0.057) (0.063) (0.068) (0.086) (0.053) (0.14) (0.56)

Huancayo -0.182*** -0.177*** -0.134*** -0.0943* -0.103 -0.0934* -0.197* -0.900**

(0.038) (0.039) (0.046) (0.055) (0.077) (0.050) (0.12) (0.45)

Cusco -0.221*** -0.228*** -0.185*** -0.152*** -0.170*** -0.0804* 0.127 -0.897*

(0.032) (0.031) (0.037) (0.043) (0.063) (0.045) (0.12) (0.53)

Log distance to the SUNAT Office -0.0309 -0.0305 -0.0465 -0.0296 -0.0387 -0.0226 -0.00683 -0.132

(0.032) (0.032) (0.032) (0.033) (0.043) (0.023) (0.053) (0.19)

Log distance to City Center -0.0386 -0.0429 -0.0253 -0.00961 -0.00907 -0.00674 0.00942 -0.0912

(0.033) (0.033) (0.033) (0.034) (0.045) (0.022) (0.052) (0.22)

In business to care for family -0.0634 -0.0468 -0.0561 -0.0549 -0.0274 0.0966 -0.231

(0.040) (0.040) (0.042) (0.052) (0.026) (0.063) (0.21)

In business for flexibility 0.0113 0.0144 0.0259 0.0111 -0.0261 -0.115* -0.0785

(0.041) (0.041) (0.042) (0.055) (0.029) (0.064) (0.25)

In business because can't find wage job 0.00885 0.0366 0.0224 0.0339 -0.000835 -0.0867 0.0372

(0.038) (0.037) (0.038) (0.050) (0.026) (0.062) (0.25)

In business for prospect of growth -0.0932 -0.145* -0.162* -0.128 -0.0611 -0.0876 -0.560

(0.076) (0.082) (0.091) (0.10) (0.047) (0.11) (0.39)

6 to 10 workers 0.158*** 0.0331 0.184*** -0.0442 -0.279*** -0.224

(0.047) (0.048) (0.062) (0.030) (0.074) (0.29)

11 to 50 workers 0.386*** 0.177*** 0.434*** 0.0633* -0.196** 0.323

(0.052) (0.064) (0.060) (0.037) (0.079) (0.32)

Log November Sales 0.0766*** 0.0523*** 0.0181 0.442***

(0.015) (0.010) (0.022) (0.11)

Observations 713 713 713 626 504 609 159 609

Note: omitted dummies are Restaurants, Lima, <5 workers, Male, and Less than Secondary Education

Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Any worker covered Share covered

Page 105: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

105

Annex D. The impact of informality – methodology and impact on profits

and on access to credit

Impact on profitability - methodology

We consider three approaches for measuring the impact of formality on profitability. Our

methods include: (i) an ordinary least squares regression (OLS); (ii) a Treatment Effects

regression that tries to take account of the potential endogeneity of formality; and (iii) an estimate

using propensity score matching.

Methodology for the OLS regression. The ordinary least squares regression is based on the

following equation:

(1) iiiiii

FormalLocationIndustrysticsCharacteriOwnerssticsCharacteriFirmsPROFITS ''ln

The outcome of interest here is θ, which measures the average increase in log profits associated

with being formal, conditional on the other variables included in the regression. Assigning a

causal interpretation to formality based on this estimation requires assuming selection on the

observable variables included in this equation, as well as assuming that the linear functional form

adequately captures profits.

A key concern with OLS estimation of equation (1) is that the error term ε is correlated with

formality. There are several possible reasons for this concern. First, if we exclude firm size from

equation (1), we would expect a positive bias, due to larger firms earning higher profits and also

being more likely to be formal. In the OLS results we should therefore expect the estimate of θ to

become less positive as we include firm size. Second, a concern is that ε may include unmeasured

ability of the firm, with higher ability leading to more profits and also affecting the decision to

become formal. If ability is a complement to formality, we should again expect this to lead to an

upward bias in θ.

Methodology for the Treatment Effects regression. A second approach to estimation is to take

account of the potential endogeneity of formality by instrumenting for formality status when

estimating equation (1). Since formality is a binary variable, we use STATA’s treatreg command

to fit a maximum-likelihood Treatment Effects model. The instrument we rely on is the distance

from the firm to the location of the office where the firm would have to register.

The exclusion restriction we rely on here is that, conditional on the distance of a firm to the city

center, and the average tax enforcement in a firm’s city and industry pair, distance to the SUNAT

office has no direct impact on profitability. One possible reason this assumption could be violated

would be if firms choose where to operate with the location of the SUNAT office in mind.

However, within a large city it seems that the location of the tax office is not a main concern

when deciding where to locate.

Methodology for the propensity score matching. Finally, to complement the OLS and

Treatment Effects regressions, we also provide estimates of the impact of being formal on profits

using propensity score matching. Propensity score matching assumes that all selection occurs on

observables, but does not require assuming a linear function form. We use the same variables as

in the OLS regressions, along with higher-order interaction terms in carrying out the match.

Page 106: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

106

Table D.1: "Impact" of having a RUC on log profits Columns 1-7 OLS regression, Columns 8-9 2SLS

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)

OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS W-OLS W-2SLS

RUC 1.030*** 0.960*** 0.840*** 0.532*** 0.299** 0.371* 0.380* -1.181 0.166 0.531*** -0.129

(0.11) (0.11) (0.12) (0.11) (0.12) (0.21) (0.21) (3.40) (2.12) (0.13) (1.99)

Female owner -0.334*** -0.327** -0.286** -0.266** -0.222 -0.220 -0.402** -0.293** -0.310** -0.316**

(0.13) (0.14) (0.13) (0.13) (0.19) (0.19) (0.20) (0.13) (0.13) (0.13)

Owner's Age -0.0250*** -0.0234*** -0.0156*** -0.0110** -0.0172* -0.0170* -0.0266*** -0.0154*** -0.0141** -0.0134**

(0.0049) (0.0054) (0.0053) (0.0051) (0.0095) (0.0098) (0.0085) (0.0056) (0.0055) (0.0060)

Owner is Married 0.204* 0.176 0.126 0.114 0.175 0.191 0.219 0.130 0.149 0.150

(0.11) (0.12) (0.11) (0.11) (0.17) (0.17) (0.16) (0.11) (0.11) (0.11)

Owner has Tecnico education 0.0699 -0.197 -0.147 -0.145 0.394 0.457 0.0296 -0.111 -0.0339 0.0366

(0.21) (0.24) (0.22) (0.22) (0.32) (0.32) (0.45) (0.29) (0.23) (0.30)

Owner has University education 0.450** 0.271 0.114 0.0738 -0.0806 -0.0653 0.754 0.179 0.144 0.267

(0.18) (0.19) (0.18) (0.18) (0.30) (0.30) (0.84) (0.41) (0.20) (0.41)

Owner has complete secondary education 0.199 -0.0647 -0.0354 0.00969 0.259 0.253 0.0955 -0.00934 0.0156 0.0634

(0.15) (0.16) (0.15) (0.15) (0.26) (0.26) (0.33) (0.21) (0.17) (0.22)

Parent owned a business 0.163 0.201* 0.192* 0.151 -0.113 -0.117 0.124 0.178 0.158 0.134

(0.11) (0.12) (0.11) (0.11) (0.20) (0.19) (0.19) (0.13) (0.11) (0.14)

Age of firm 0.0104* 0.0152** 0.00927 0.00834 0.00333 0.00473 0.0290 0.0112 0.00981 0.0129

(0.0059) (0.0064) (0.0061) (0.0058) (0.0099) (0.010) (0.024) (0.013) (0.0066) (0.011)

SUNAT inspection rate in city*industry 0.320 0.219 0.464 0.235 -0.0830 0.0649 0.0277 0.448 0.799 0.749

(0.52) (0.61) (0.57) (0.54) (0.91) (0.87) (0.72) (0.53) (0.67) (0.66)

Shoe/Leather -0.244 -0.242 -0.297* -0.235 -0.526* -0.509* -0.422 -0.335 -0.282* -0.344

(0.18) (0.19) (0.17) (0.17) (0.30) (0.30) (0.39) (0.29) (0.17) (0.26)

Textiles/Clothing -0.0542 -0.0939 -0.155 -0.175 -0.139 -0.135 -0.422 -0.220 -0.0952 -0.197

(0.18) (0.18) (0.17) (0.17) (0.28) (0.28) (0.60) (0.42) (0.17) (0.35)

Wood products 0.0379 0.107 0.0730 0.0386 -0.108 -0.0816 -0.0736 0.0401 0.0657 0.0180

(0.17) (0.17) (0.16) (0.17) (0.30) (0.30) (0.39) (0.27) (0.16) (0.22)

Metal products -0.206 -0.261 -0.210 -0.210 -0.736** -0.727** -0.229 -0.201 -0.189 -0.169

(0.18) (0.19) (0.18) (0.18) (0.30) (0.30) (0.24) (0.19) (0.19) (0.20)

Food stuffs -0.374 -0.316 -0.337 -0.222 -0.573 -0.570 -0.219 -0.324 -0.519* -0.493

(0.25) (0.29) (0.26) (0.25) (0.42) (0.43) (0.31) (0.23) (0.31) (0.31)

Transport 0.330 0.392 0.232 0.194 -0.0861 0.0395 0.0174 0.154 0.187 0.0350

(0.22) (0.26) (0.25) (0.24) (0.39) (0.37) (0.69) (0.50) (0.24) (0.49)

Arequipa -0.351** -0.489*** -0.370** -0.340** 0.0331 0.0855 -0.708* -0.402 -0.366** -0.423*

(0.16) (0.16) (0.15) (0.15) (0.23) (0.23) (0.42) (0.25) (0.15) (0.23)

Trujillo -0.529*** -0.647*** -0.549*** -0.574*** -0.215 -0.220 -0.729*** -0.556*** -0.581*** -0.593***

(0.19) (0.21) (0.19) (0.19) (0.26) (0.26) (0.28) (0.20) (0.20) (0.20)

Huancayo -0.555*** -0.696*** -0.439** -0.458** -0.0400 0.0241 -0.819** -0.443** -0.438** -0.443**

(0.19) (0.20) (0.20) (0.19) (0.28) (0.28) (0.33) (0.20) (0.20) (0.20)

Cusco -0.726*** -0.770*** -0.495** -0.489** -0.213 -0.217 -0.877** -0.492** -0.609** -0.593**

(0.21) (0.25) (0.24) (0.23) (0.41) (0.41) (0.35) (0.24) (0.27) (0.27)

Log distance to City Center 0.0592 0.0803 0.113* 0.100 0.125 0.137 0.0508 0.110 0.121* 0.113

(0.067) (0.070) (0.068) (0.067) (0.10) (0.11) (0.099) (0.071) (0.070) (0.074)

In business to care for family -0.219* -0.149 -0.118 -0.199 -0.204 -0.382 -0.170 -0.120 -0.167

(0.13) (0.13) (0.13) (0.22) (0.23) (0.31) (0.17) (0.14) (0.19)

In business for flexibility -0.224 -0.237 -0.159 -0.268 -0.304 -0.202 -0.231* -0.250 -0.235

(0.17) (0.16) (0.15) (0.31) (0.32) (0.17) (0.14) (0.17) (0.17)

In business because can't find wage job -0.0528 -0.0507 0.0216 0.174 0.211 -0.0519 -0.0535 -0.0134 -0.0179

(0.12) (0.12) (0.11) (0.19) (0.19) (0.15) (0.12) (0.12) (0.12)

In business for prospect of growth 0.391 0.301 0.279 0.353 0.376 0.532 0.324 0.451 0.485

(0.30) (0.29) (0.28) (0.43) (0.42) (0.39) (0.28) (0.35) (0.34)

Entrepreneurial Self-efficacy 0.106*** 0.0763*** 0.0581** 0.0662* 0.0641 0.146** 0.0800** 0.0669*** 0.0739**

(0.027) (0.025) (0.025) (0.040) (0.039) (0.073) (0.032) (0.025) (0.034)

6 to 10 workers 0.562*** 0.643 0.603*** 0.743*

(0.12) (0.49) (0.13) (0.43)

11 to 50 workers 1.201*** 1.293** 1.219*** 1.377***

(0.17) (0.55) (0.17) (0.53)

Log capital stock 0.0758

(0.061)

Dummies for each worker category no no no no yes yes yes no no no no

First stage F-statistic 1.19 2.11 3.54

Observations 615 614 520 520 520 205 205 520 520 520 520

R-squared 0.09 0.22 0.26 0.35 0.42 0.50 0.49 0.35

Note: omitted dummies are Restaurants, Lima, <5 workers, Male, and Less than Secondary Education

Robust Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Page 107: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

107

Table D.2: "Impact" of having a municipal license on log profits

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS W-OLS W-2SLS

Municipal Licence 0.546*** 0.409*** 0.324** 0.157 0.107 -0.756 -0.147 0.180 0.238

(0.11) (0.12) (0.13) (0.11) (0.11) (1.85) (1.49) (0.12) (1.46)

Female owner -0.375*** -0.374*** -0.308** -0.279** -0.351** -0.299** -0.328** -0.330**

(0.13) (0.14) (0.13) (0.13) (0.14) (0.13) (0.14) (0.14)

Owner's Age -0.0266*** -0.0237*** -0.0148*** -0.0103** -0.0258*** -0.0150*** -0.0127** -0.0126**

(0.0051) (0.0057) (0.0054) (0.0051) (0.0071) (0.0056) (0.0056) (0.0060)

Owner is Married 0.240** 0.190 0.133 0.116 0.219 0.139 0.148 0.147

(0.11) (0.12) (0.11) (0.11) (0.14) (0.12) (0.11) (0.12)

Owner has Tecnico education 0.132 -0.114 -0.101 -0.118 -0.0170 -0.0727 0.0131 0.00768

(0.21) (0.24) (0.22) (0.22) (0.28) (0.24) (0.23) (0.26)

Owner has University education 0.602*** 0.412** 0.186 0.105 0.601 0.230 0.229 0.221

(0.18) (0.19) (0.18) (0.18) (0.38) (0.28) (0.20) (0.27)

Owner has complete secondary education 0.253* -0.00335 0.00306 0.0342 0.0123 0.00855 0.0651 0.0649

(0.15) (0.17) (0.15) (0.15) (0.17) (0.15) (0.17) (0.16)

Parent owned a business 0.111 0.164 0.175 0.136 0.221 0.191 0.142 0.139

(0.11) (0.12) (0.11) (0.11) (0.16) (0.13) (0.11) (0.14)

Age of firm 0.0144** 0.0184*** 0.0110* 0.00922 0.0241** 0.0123 0.0113* 0.0111

(0.0060) (0.0064) (0.0062) (0.0057) (0.012) (0.0085) (0.0067) (0.0087)

Municipal inspection rate in city*industry 0.0817 0.943 0.899 0.466 1.400 1.018 0.936 0.918

(0.73) (0.79) (0.72) (0.67) (1.15) (0.94) (0.72) (0.85)

Shoe/Leather -0.290 -0.0232 -0.124 -0.135 -0.0936 -0.149 -0.123 -0.118

(0.26) (0.27) (0.23) (0.22) (0.33) (0.30) (0.24) (0.25)

Textiles/Clothing -0.0747 0.195 0.0686 -0.0472 -0.0779 -0.0122 0.129 0.144

(0.31) (0.32) (0.29) (0.28) (0.59) (0.50) (0.30) (0.47)

Wood products 0.0443 0.253 0.195 0.100 0.134 0.159 0.189 0.195

(0.21) (0.23) (0.20) (0.20) (0.33) (0.29) (0.21) (0.25)

Metal products -0.165 -0.0608 -0.0502 -0.126 -0.0910 -0.0590 -0.0385 -0.0368

(0.22) (0.22) (0.22) (0.21) (0.26) (0.23) (0.22) (0.22)

Food stuffs -0.289 -0.179 -0.180 -0.130 -0.169 -0.177 -0.316 -0.316

(0.24) (0.26) (0.23) (0.24) (0.23) (0.20) (0.27) (0.27)

Transport 0.0574 0.466 0.339 0.251 0.549 0.356 0.279 0.278

(0.29) (0.35) (0.32) (0.30) (0.35) (0.29) (0.31) (0.30)

Arequipa -0.381** -0.558*** -0.411*** -0.347** -0.784* -0.466 -0.379** -0.369

(0.17) (0.17) (0.15) (0.16) (0.43) (0.32) (0.15) (0.30)

Trujillo -0.325* -0.547*** -0.431** -0.503*** -0.939 -0.534 -0.389** -0.369

(0.18) (0.19) (0.18) (0.17) (0.70) (0.53) (0.18) (0.53)

Huancayo -0.546*** -0.718*** -0.423** -0.431** -0.818*** -0.437** -0.405** -0.403**

(0.19) (0.20) (0.19) (0.19) (0.29) (0.22) (0.19) (0.20)

Cusco -0.687*** -0.844*** -0.470** -0.475** -0.976*** -0.490** -0.498** -0.496**

(0.19) (0.22) (0.20) (0.20) (0.33) (0.24) (0.21) (0.21)

Log distance to City Center 0.0673 0.0850 0.113 0.102 0.0201 0.0961 0.118 0.121

(0.071) (0.075) (0.071) (0.069) (0.14) (0.11) (0.072) (0.11)

In business to care for family -0.252* -0.159 -0.123 -0.353 -0.183 -0.126 -0.121

(0.13) (0.13) (0.13) (0.22) (0.17) (0.15) (0.18)

In business for flexibility -0.276 -0.261 -0.176 -0.106 -0.214 -0.282 -0.292

(0.18) (0.16) (0.15) (0.33) (0.27) (0.17) (0.30)

In business because can't find wage job -0.0662 -0.0629 0.0162 -0.0451 -0.0561 -0.0260 -0.0275

(0.12) (0.12) (0.11) (0.14) (0.13) (0.12) (0.13)

In business for prospect of growth 0.442 0.343 0.293 0.468 0.345 0.499 0.499

(0.30) (0.29) (0.27) (0.29) (0.25) (0.35) (0.34)

Entrepreneurial Self-efficacy 0.118*** 0.0816*** 0.0582** 0.139*** 0.0861*** 0.0730*** 0.0720**

(0.027) (0.025) (0.025) (0.046) (0.033) (0.025) (0.036)

6 to 10 workers 0.681*** 0.699*** 0.713*** 0.709***

(0.12) (0.16) (0.13) (0.15)

11 to 50 workers 1.293*** 1.347*** 1.296*** 1.286***

(0.17) (0.30) (0.17) (0.31)

Observations 615 614 520 520 520 520 520 520 520

R-squared 0.03 0.16 0.22 0.34 0.42 0.34

Note: omitted dummies are Restaurants, Lima, <5 workers, Male, and Less than Secondary Education

Robust Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Page 108: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

108

Table D.3: OLS Regression of log profits on both municipal license and RUC number

Dependent variable: Log profits (1) (2) (3)

RUC 0.975*** 0.850*** 0.532***

(0.12) (0.13) (0.13)

Municipal Licence 0.202 0.129 0.0524

(0.13) (0.13) (0.12)

Female owner -0.375*** -0.325**

(0.14) (0.14)

Owner's Age -0.0212*** -0.0131**

(0.0058) (0.0056)

Owner is Married 0.212* 0.158

(0.12) (0.11)

Owner has Tecnico education -0.0235 0.0318

(0.25) (0.23)

Owner has University education 0.325 0.157

(0.21) (0.20)

Owner has complete secondary education 0.0357 0.0566

(0.18) (0.16)

Parent owned a business 0.161 0.161

(0.12) (0.11)

Age of firm 0.0130* 0.00828

(0.0071) (0.0067)

Municipal inspection rate in city*industry 0.671 0.473

(0.93) (0.86)

SUNAT inspection rate in city*industry 0.478 0.741

(0.82) (0.77)

In business to care for family -0.153 -0.0942

(0.15) (0.14)

In business for flexibility -0.261 -0.259

(0.18) (0.17)

In business because can't find wage job -0.00247 -0.000332

(0.13) (0.12)

In business for prospect of growth 0.569 0.440

(0.37) (0.35)

Shoe/Leather -0.00553 -0.131

(0.28) (0.25)

Textiles/Clothing 0.261 0.0923

(0.34) (0.31)

Wood products 0.285 0.186

(0.24) (0.21)

Metal products -0.0628 -0.0703

(0.23) (0.23)

Food stuffs -0.429 -0.488

(0.39) (0.36)

Transport 0.514 0.290

(0.37) (0.34)

Arequipa -0.460*** -0.361**

(0.17) (0.16)

Trujillo -0.551** -0.505**

(0.23) (0.22)

Huancayo -0.589*** -0.365*

(0.20) (0.20)

Cusco -0.903*** -0.611**

(0.29) (0.27)

Log distance to city center 0.0834 0.114

(0.074) (0.071)

6 to 10 workers 0.652***

(0.13)

11 to 50 workers 1.264***

(0.17)

Constant 6.560*** 6.872*** 6.538***

(0.10) (0.63) (0.59)

Observations 520 520 520

R-squared 0.09 0.24 0.35

Robust standard errors in parentheses

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Page 109: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

109

Access to credit Table D.4: Businesses with and without bank accounts

Percent of businesses

No account With bank With savings association With microfinance institution

All businesses 57 35 6 2

By sector

Shoe leather 62 27 8 3

Textile clothing 46 46 5 3

Metal works 52 43 3 2

Wood products 53 38 8 1

Foodstuffs 76 20 2 2

Restaurant 53 39 7 3

Transport 60 33 7 0

No. of workers Lima Other regions

1 – 5 26 32

6 – 10 45 55

11 – 50 65 68

Overall

29

51

66 Source: World Bank survey of micro and small enterprises.

Table D.5: Sources of finance among businesses that have borrowed in 2007 or 2006

Percent of businesses Personal

Savings

From

family and

friends

Banks Caja

Municipal

Edpyme Micro-

finance

Money

lender

Client

advance

Supplier

credit

Other

All businesses 77 14 11 3 1 1 1 2 2 5

By sector

Shoe & leather 67 14 7 3 1 1 0 1 4 8

Textile clothing 62 12 14 3 1 0 1 2 1 5

Metal manuf. 84 13 9 3 0 0 2 3 1 3

Wood products 87 12 12 4 1 0 0 4 1 1

Foodstuffs 66 17 14 3 1 1 1 1 4 6

Restaurant 95 15 11 3 0 2 0 0 1 5

Transport 73 13 14 2 0 1 2 1 1 6 Source: World Bank survey of micro and small enterprises.

Page 110: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

110

Table D.6: Use of credit to purchase inputs

Percent of businesses

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersTotal

Did you buy inputs on credit?

Yes 28 40 57 37

No 72 60 43 63

Total 100 100 100 100

Only businesses from manufacturing sectors

Yes 22 43 59 35

No 78 58 41 65

Total 100 100 100 100

Percent that bought on credit by business size and sector

Shoe and leather manufacturing 16 48 48 32

Textile and apparel manufacturing 30 33 72 39

Manufacturing of wood products and furniture 24 43 57 36

Manufacturing of metallic products 18 46 62 34

Retail of foodstuffs 64 78 68 69

Transport by land 29 25 42 31

Restaurants and hotels 16 10 52 24

Percent that bought on credit by business size and city

Arequipa 22 47 39 32

Cusco 28 43 45 34

Huancayo 38 29 69 40

Lima 27 39 64 41

Trujillo 24 42 38 32

If purchasing on credit, what percentage of purchases was bought on credit?

All 44 46 45 45

Shoe and leather manufacturing 47 47 48 47

Textile and apparel manufacturing 49 51 52 51

Manufacturing of wood products and furniture 39 38 41 39

Manufacturing of metallic products 45 50 52 49

Retail of foodstuffs 39 45 50 43

Transport by land 64 49 41 54

Restaurants and hotels 31 40 30 31

Arequipa 53 40 50 47

Cusco 41 48 19 41

Huancayo 50 34 43 45

Lima 40 51 49 46

Trujillo 49 46 29 43

If purchasing on credit, how many days to pay were you given?

All 67 50 51 57

Shoe and leather manufacturing 23 33 34 31

Textile and apparel manufacturing 120 95 75 97

Manufacturing of wood products and furniture 86 66 61 71

Manufacturing of metallic products 105 58 36 63

Retail of foodstuffs 20 20 24 20

Transport by land 127 86 163 127

Restaurants and hotels 18 37 21 22

Arequipa 88 49 44 64

Cusco 72 53 163 78

Huancayo 39 30 52 40

Lima 75 51 49 58

Trujillo 54 59 16 46

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 111: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

111

Table D.7: Sources of start-up capital

Percent of businesses

1 to 5 workers 6 to 10 workers 11 to 50 workers

All cities

Personal savings 76 66 90

From family and friends 13 16 12

Formal finance* 14 18 15

Other** 8 11 10

Lima

Personal savings 85 63 89

From family and friends 12 20 14

Formal finance* 9 15 16

Other** 6 14 7

Other cities

Personal savings 69 69 92

From family and friends 14 13 10

Formal finance* 18 21 14

Other** 9 9 16

* Banks, Caja Municipal, Edpyme, Micro finance institutions; ** Money lender, client advance, supplier credit, and others.

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small enterprises.

Table D.8: Borrowing by sector

Percent of businesses

Businesses who took loan in

2006 or 2007

Among those businesses that took a loan, share

that borrowed from formal sources

All businesses 49 93

By sector

Shoe & leather 60 91

Textile clothing 60 96

Metal manuf. 47 96

Wood products 51 94

Foodstuffs 53 91

Restaurant 37 87

Transport 41 90

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 112: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

112

Table D.9: Sources of finance for most recent loan

Percent of businesses, relative to businesses that took a loan

1 to 5 workers 6 to 10 workers 11 to 50 workers

All cities

Banks 51 66 80

Caja Municipal 32 18 4

Micro finance 5 5 3

Edpyme 5 7 4

Money lender 3 3 8

Other 3 2 1

Memo item: share of businesses that borrowed in 2007 or 2006 43 59 52

Lima

Banks 82 88 89

Caja Municipal 7 0 0

Micro finance 2 0 0

Edpyme 0 5 2

Money lender 6 5 9

Other 4 2 0

Memo item: share of businesses that borrowed in 2007 or 2006 32 49 48

Other cities

Banks 38 54 68

Caja Municipal 43 27 10

Micro finance 7 8 8

Edpyme 7 8 8

Money lender 2 3 5

Other 3 1 3

Memo item: share of businesses that borrowed in 2007 or 2006 50 67 59

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Table D.10: Terms of loan (annual or monthly rates) by source of finance Number of businesses receiving loans under annual and monthly rates of interest

BankCaja

municipal

Micro-

financeEdpyme

Money

lenderOther Total

Number of businesses that have taken a

loan with annual interest rate126 30 6 9 1 2 174

Number of businesses that have taken a

loan with monthly interest rate103 52 12 12 16 5 200

Sum of the above 229 82 18 21 17 7 374

Total number of businesses that have

taken a loan245 82 18 21 17 9 392

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses

Note: the sum and the total number of businesses having taken a loan does not necessarily match since there are businesses which report having

taken a loan but do not answer the question on whether the interest rate they received was on an annual or monthly basis

Page 113: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

113

Table D.11: Average length of loan in months

No. of workers Overall Lima Other

1 - 5 14.3 14.6 14.2

6 - 10 15.1 16.5 14.4

11 - 50 14.0 11.5 17.4

Overall 14.5 14.0 14.8

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses

Table D.12: Home ownership - percent of entrepreneur owning their home

Sector Overall Lima Other Regions

Overall 53 48 57

Restaurant 57 39 67

Foodstuffs 59 56 63

Wood products 56 52 60

Shoe leather 56 51 60

Metal products 54 56 53

Textile clothing 43 41 45

Transport 40 36 43

No. of workers Overall Lima Other regions

1 – 5 48 42 52

6 – 10 52 41 60

11 – 50 63 62 66

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small enterprises.

Table D.13: Business taking credit cards and checks, percent

 Sector Both Only Checks Only Credit Cards None

Overall 6 19 5 69

Foodstuffs 2 7 3 89

Transport 4 15 0 79

Restaurant 8 2 15 75

Shoe leather 4 14 8 74

Textile clothing 4 30 2 64

Wood products 10 26 5 60

Metal works 9 37 4 49

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small enterprises.

Page 114: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

114

Table D.14: Impact on getting a loan of having a license and RUC number

OLS First-stage 2SLS Matching OLS First-stage 2SLS Matching

F-stat F-stat

All firms -0.0381 8.12 -0.245 -0.037 0.0862* 5.65 -0.680 0.117**

(0.045) (0.42) (0.047) (0.052) (0.71) (0.055)

5 or fewer workers -0.0136 11.28 0.137 -0.008 0.00444 4.48 -0.532 -0.025

(0.060) (0.34) (0.060) (0.066) (0.58) (0.064)

6 to 10 workers -0.150* 0.69 . -0.185** 0.172 1.02 -0.973 0.231*

(0.090) (0.086) (0.13) (1.68) (0.130)

11 - 50 workers 0.0534 0.02 0.015 0.297 0 0.498**

(0.15) (0.151) (0.18) (0.210)

RUCMunicipal license

Page 115: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

115

Annex E. Trajectories towards formality

Table E.1: Time lapsed from opening business to getting RUC number and municipal license

Percent of businesses

Timeline for getting a RUC number

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersTotal

Since starting the business 48 55 56 52Less than a year after starting the business 15 17 14 151 to 2 years after starting the business 15 12 10 133 - 4 years after starting the business 5 8 8 75 or more years after starting the business 16 8 12 13Sample size 273 181 173 627

Timeline for getting a municipal license

1 to 5

workers

6 to 10

workers

11 to 50

workersTotal

Since starting the business 53 53 57 54Less than a year after starting the business 19 22 14 191 to 2 years after starting the business 14 11 8 123 - 4 years after starting the business 4 8 7 65 or more years after starting the business 9 6 13 9Sample size 249 135 149 533

Source: World Bank survey of micro and small businesses.

Page 116: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

116

Annex F. Database of sector-specific labor regulations - methodology

To prepare a dataset of labor regulations affecting specific sectors, a listing available in the Labor

Ministry's website <http://www.mintra.gob.pe/leyes.php> containing 833 legal instruments was

used as a basis. In addition, to ensure that no legal instruments were overlooked, other sources

were consulted. In this sense, other listings - available in the Labor Ministry's website - were

used. That is the case of <http://www.mintra.gob.pe/normas_sst.php> - which provided 81 legal

instruments - <http://www.mintra.gob.pe/prodlab_legislacion.php> - which provided 101 legal

instruments - and <http://www.mintra.gob.pe/sst_prot_insp_segur_legislacion.php> - which

provided 76 legal instruments to the counting. Combining all these sources the total number of

legal instruments issued by the Ministry of Labor totaled 865. However, this total number

contained very broad legal instruments since it included all regulations issued by the Labor

Ministry and other legal instruments that were not really labor-specific. For example,

appointments of officers in several positions in the Ministry and procurement decisions were

included. This total number of legal instruments had to be filtered to create a long list of legal

instruments that were truly affecting labor regulations. This long list of legal instruments

affecting labor regulations had 284 legal instruments as 581 laws were excluded on the basis that

they did not cover labor regulations. The excluded laws dealt largely with administration of the

Labor Ministry (279), pensions (118), administrative sanctions for rehiring in the public sector

(28), holidays (15), survey approvals (15), income taxation (11), and a group of other diverse

legal instruments (115).

Once non-labor regulations were removed from the listing, a second selection process involved

identifying those labor regulations that applied to specific sectors. Out of the long list of 284 legal

labor instruments, 162 legal instruments were removed because they were not specific to any

determined sector. Out of the remaining 122 legal instruments affecting only specific sectors, 2

were excluded because they were specific not to sectors but to professions that cut across

different sectors of activity,25

and 37 were excluded because they were specific to public sector

activities. A final list of 83 legal instruments was identified as referring to labor regulation,

including those that were identified as specific to private sector activities and were mapped to

those areas of activity.

25

This is the case of the “law for the work of the biologist”, and the “law for the work of the

psychologist”, which although are specific to certain professionals, is not specific to any activity.

Page 117: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

117

Annex G. The Marginal Effective Tax Rate Methodology

Conceptual Explanation of the METR

There are two main "stakeholders" that hold an interest in firms: debt holders and equity holders

(owners or "shareholders"). In order to satisfy these stakeholders, an investment must earn a rate

of return after the payment of all business taxes which is greater than or equal to the (weighted

average) "hurdle" rate of return required by these stakeholders. The hurdle rate is the minimum

rate of return acceptable to the stakeholders.

For example, say the (weighted average) hurdle rate of return is 10%. This means that all capital

projects that earn a rate of return greater than 10%, after the payment of all business taxes, will be

undertaken. So, if a firm invests in all projects with a rate of return greater than the hurdle rate,

and it invests in projects with the highest rate of return first and then moves down the “menu” of

capital projects available to it, the last (marginal) project undertaken will earn an after-tax rate of

return of 10% exactly.

The derivation of the METR formula can be quite complicated, but the idea can be conveyed in a

simple example. As above, say the hurdle rate of return is 10% - i.e., the minimum (weighted

average) rate of return required by the stakeholders in the project after the payment of all business

taxes is 10%. Say the business tax system is such that in order to earn a rate of return of 10% after

business taxes, an investment must earn a rate of return of 15% before business taxes. The METR

is then 33.33% (determined as (.15-.10)/.15). The METR therefore measures the share of the

investment’s pre-tax required rate of return needed to cover the tax costs associated with the

investment.

Note that the 33 1/3% METR could differ substantially from the statutory CIT rate because of the

existence of other taxes, deductions, credits, allowances, etc. The METR will equal the statutory

tax rate in the case of no debt financing, no investment incentives, no turnover or other implicit or

explicit capital taxes, and if the tax depreciation rate is equal to the economic rate of

depreciation.26

In general, the METR is higher (the tax distortion greater),

the higher is the statutory CIT rate and other tax rates on capital - capital taxes, business

taxes, property taxes, turnover taxes;

the lower is the tax depreciation rate on capital relative to the "economic" depreciation rate;

the lower are various tax incentives - investment tax credits, investment allowances, etc,

the lower the proportion of investment financed by tax deductible debt

Several things should be kept in mind when interpreting the METRs calculated for this study.

First, the METR should not be confused with the average effective tax rate (AETR). The AETR

measures total taxes as a share of total income while the METR measures taxes paid by a

marginal investment as a share of the required before-tax rate of return on that investment. The

METR is thus a forward-looking measure which measures the impact of taxes on the incentive to

invest at the margin. The AETR is a backward looking measure which reflects previous

investment decisions and taxes levied on the income generated by those past investments. METRs

and AETRs can differ significantly. In particular, it is quite possible for the AETR to be quite

high and the METR quite low, or vise-versa. Both measures are useful for tax policy analysis, but

serve quite different purposes. The METR provides a measure of the incentive effects of the tax

system on investment. The AETR provides a measure of the burden of the business tax system

26

This also presumes no personal taxes or, a small open economy with internationally mobile capital. See

below.

Page 118: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

118

and is a useful indicator of the distribution of the business tax burden across companies or

sectors.

Second, it is important to understand that the METR measures the impact of taxation on the

incentive to invest in capital inputs. Taxes that corporations pay on other inputs that do not

impinge on the rate of return to capital, in particular various taxes imposed on labor such as

payroll taxes, are not reflected in the METR on capital.

Third, it is important to emphasize that METR analysis is only one of several tools that should be

employed in an analysis of the tax system. The calculations are based upon a hypothetical

marginal capital investment subject to a rough caricature of the tax system. While several

important aspects of the tax system can be incorporated into the calculations: the corporate

income tax rate; tax depreciation allowances; investment allowances; tax credits; property and

capital taxes; tax holidays; implicit sales taxes on inputs; the treatment of inventories; etc., several

simplifying assumptions must be made, and important nuances of the tax code cannot be captured

in METR calculations.27

The methodology thus captures only the “big picture” aspects of the tax

code and should be interpreted in this light.

Finally, it is important to note that the METR calculations reflect the statutory provisions of the

tax system. As a rule, METR calculations do not reflect various administrative and compliance

issues that are extremely important for determining how a tax system works “on the ground.”28

Taxes on capital can lead to several types of distortions in an economy. First, a high overall

METR on capital is indicative of a tax system that discourages investment, generating what might

be called an inter-temporal distortion. Second, differences in METRs across assets suggest a tax

system that distorts the allocation of investment across different types of capital: inter-asset

distortions. Third, differences in METRs across sectors is indicative of a tax system that

introduces distortions in the allocation of investment across industries, leading to inter-sectoral

distortions.

All of these types of distortions: inter-temporal, inter-asset and inter-sectoral, can lead to an

inefficient allocation of resources in the economy, and therefore to an economy that does not

produce to its capacity; does not generate jobs to its capacity; and therefore does not grow to its

capacity.

More Formal Explanation of the METR

Neoclassical investment theory tells us that a firm will invest in capital up to the point where, at

the margin, the present value of the after-tax cash flow from the last dollar invested equals one

dollar. Therefore the marginal unit of capital just breaks even in the sense that the present value

of the cash flows after the payment of taxes just equals the one dollar cost. Thus, for a simple

corporate tax system:

(1) 1 = ∫ C(1-u)e-(r

f-π-δ)t

dt – t + uZ(1+t)

where C is the asset’s pre-tax rental rate, u is the corporate income tax rate, rf is the firm’s after-

tax nominal discount rate (defined in more detail below), π is the inflation rate, δ is the economic

depreciation rate, Z is the present value of the tax depreciation deductions on $1 of capital

27

An example is loss carryforward provisions. While it is possible to incorporate loss carryforwards, this

requires detailed information on the anticipated future profile of income and taxes, which is typically not

available in reliable form. 28

An attempt to illustrate the importance of these issues in the METR framework is undertaken below.

Page 119: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

119

(explained in more detail below), and t is the implicit tax rate on $1 of capital (for example a sales

tax imposed on capital, an asset transfer tax, a turnover tax, etc.). The left hand side of the

equation is the cost of $1 in capital while the right hand side is the present value of the after-tax

returns to that marginal unit of capital. The first term on the right hand side is the present value of

the after-tax cash flows (net of depreciation) generated by the marginal unit of capital; the second

term is the sales taxes paid on that unit of capital; the third term is the value of the tax

depreciation allowances.

The term Z, which is the present value of the tax depreciation deductions on a $1 capital

expenditure, depends upon the form of the tax depreciation allowances (i.e., straight line or

declining balance), whether or not tax depreciation allowances are indexed for inflation, and can

incorporate tax incentives such as tax allowances and investment tax credits. For example, under

a declining balance approach to tax depreciation with no allowance for inflation, Z is equal to:

Z = α/(rf+α)

where α is the tax depreciation rate (i.e., 20%, in which case α=.2). If inflation indexing of tax

depreciation allowances is allowed the nominal discount rate rf is replaced with the real discount

rate rf-π.

Under straight-line depreciation, where an asset is written off over T years, and again assuming

no inflation adjustment,

Z = ∑t=1 to T (1/T)/(1+rf)t

An investment allowance granted at rate θ, for example in the presence of a declining balance

approach, can be incorporated as follows:

Z = θ + (1-fθ)α/(rf+α)

Where f=1 if the investment allowance reduces the subsequent depreciation allowances and f=0 if

it does not. An investment tax credit granted at rate φ can be incorporated by replacing θ with

φ/(1-u).

Integrating equation (1) to determine C, and subtracting the economic depreciation rate δ, gives

the before-tax, after depreciation, rate of return required to cover the firm’s opportunity cost of

funds and the taxes associated with a marginal investment, commonly referred to as the user cost

of capital:

(2) rg ≡ C - δ = (1+t)(rf-π+δ)(1-uZ)/(1-u) - δ

This is akin to the before-tax hurdle rate of return discussed above.

The user cost of capital, as written above, clearly reflects the corporate income tax and any sales

taxes imposed on capital, which are levied on the demand side of the capital market. Personal

taxes levied on the supply side of the capital market can enter the user cost of capital expression

through the firm’s discount rate rf.

The precise expression for rf (and the impact of personal taxes on the user cost of capital) depends

upon several assumptions concerning the marginal source of funds to the firm and the extent to

which capital is internationally mobile. The extent to which capital is mobile internationally, and

therefore whether the domestic capital market should be thought of as closed or open, or some

combination of the two, is a complicated question. It turns out that the assumption that one makes

Page 120: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

120

in this regard has a big impact on the expression for rf and important implications for the effect of

the domestic tax system on investment.

To deal with this issue, we present several sets of calculations. First, we assume that large

corporations operate in a small open economy with internationally mobile capital. This is a

common assumption that is made in many METR studies. For small corporations, we take a

slightly different approach. First, in order to compare the calculations directly with those of large

corporations, we present a set of METRs under the small open capital market assumption.

Second, we present another set of METRs for small businesses under the closed capital market

assumption. The idea here is that small businesses do not have access to international financial

markets, and may therefore be thought of as operating in a segmented, closed market for capital.

One might think of the METRs for the closed economy case as the METRs on “entrepreneurial”

firms.

As will be shown below, an important difference between the open and closed capital markets

scenarios is that in the open economy, domestic personal taxes levied on the return to saving have

no impact on the level of domestic investment. In the closed economy case, on the other hand,

domestic taxes levied on the return to savings at the personal level can affect domestic investment

undertaken by small firms.

In order to understand the distinction more easily, it is useful to start with the closed economy

model and utilize a simple diagram. Diagram 1 (below) depicts the market for a homogeneous

investment good in a closed economy. The investment demand schedule, I(rg), gives the level of

investment as a function of the before-all-taxes (gross-of tax) rate of return. The savings supply

schedule, S(rn) gives the level of savings as a function of the required after-all-taxes (net-of-tax)

rate of return. All taxes mean both corporate and personal taxes. In terms of the conceptual

framework laid out above, rg is the before-all-taxes hurdle rate of return and rn is the after-all-

taxes hurdle rate of return.

Diagram 1: Closed Capital Market Diagram 2: Open Capital Market with

Internationally Mobile Capital

Of course in a closed economy the level of saving must equal the level of investment. This means

that there is an equivalence between taxes imposed on savings (the supply side) and taxes

imposed on investment (the demand side); taxes imposed on both sides of the market impact upon

both investment and savings. In equilibrium, given the taxes imposed on both sides of the market,

the level of investment and savings in the diagram is Ie=Se, the gross-of-tax rate of return is rg and

the net-of-all-taxes rate of return is rn.

S(rn)

I(rg)

rg

ri

rn

Ie Se

S(rn)

I(rg)

rg

rn

Ie=Se

Page 121: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

121

In the closed economy case the nominal cost of debt to the firms is the return to debt required to

yield rn after personal taxes, given by:

(3) rd = (rn+π)/(1-Ti)

where Ti is the domestic PIT rate on interest.

Similarly, the nominal cost of equity is given by:

(4) re = (rn+π)/(1-Te)

where Te is the domestic PIT rate on equity, which is a weighted average of the tax rate on

dividends and the accrual equivalent tax rate on capital gains.29

The discount rate facing the firm, rf, is then a weighted average of the cost of debt and equity,

given by:

(5) rf = βrd(1-u) + (1-β)re

where β is the debt/asset ratio. This reflects the fact that debt interest costs are deductible for CIT

purposes, while the cost of equity is not.

The marginal effective tax rate on capital is the share of the before-tax-rate of return (rg) required

to pay the taxes on the investment (rg-rn):

(6) METR = (rg – rn)/rg

The METR therefore determines the share of the investment’s pre-tax required rate of return

needed to cover the tax cost.

In the closed economy model it is important to note that there is an equivalence between supply

side taxes on savings and demand side taxes on investment: both lead to a decrease in investment

(and savings). If capital is perfectly mobile internationally and the domestic capital market is

small in the sense that savings and investment decisions in the country have no impact on the

“world” interest rate, the link between domestic savings and domestic investment is broken. This

means that the equivalence between taxes levied on investment and taxes levied on savings no

longer holds. An important implication of this is that domestic personal taxes imposed on savings

may then have very little impact on domestic investment, though these taxes can still affect

domestic savings.

This is most easily seen with reference to Diagram 2 (above). In an open economy the after-

corporate-tax but before-personal-tax rate of return is fixed by world financial markets. Denote

this fixed rate of return in real terms by ri. Demand side domestic taxes imposed on corporate

capital increase the before-corporate-tax rate of return required to generate this after-corporate-

tax rate of return to rg. Domestic investment in this case is Ie and the METR on capital in an open

economy is given by the tax wedge (rg-ri) divided by the gross-of-tax rate of return rg. Supply side

taxes imposed on domestic savings decrease the after-personal-tax rate of return to rn, yielding

29

More precisely, the tax rate on equity is Te=γTd+(1-γ)Tc, where Td is the tax rate on dividends and Tc is

the accrual equivalent tax rate on capital gains. The accrual equivalent tax rate on capital gains reflects

the fact that capital gains are taxed on realization and not on accrual. Te thus takes the deferral of capital

gains taxes until realization into account. If one presumes a ten year holding period for shares, this

typically means that the accrual equivalent tax rate on capital gains is approximately half of the realized,

statutory rate.

Page 122: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

122

domestic savings of Se. In the case depicted, the excess of domestic investment over domestic

savings (Ie-Se) is provided by foreign investment inflows. Importantly, while taxes on domestic

savings affect savings and the share of domestic investment financed by foreigners, they have no

impact on domestic investment itself (unlike in the closed economy model).

In terms of the user cost of capital framework laid out above, the internationally determined cost

of funds determines the firm’s discount rate, rf in the user cost of capital expression given in

equation (2). An important consideration here is the identity of the marginal international

investor. We assume that the marginal investor is an “average” of investors from G7 countries. If

rd is the nominal cost of debt facing the firm, fixed by international markets, then the nominal cost

of equity is given by the arbitrage condition that the after-tax return to debt equals the after-tax

return to equity, rd(1-Td*)= re(1-Te

*) where Td

* is the tax rate on debt for the marginal international

investor and Te* is the tax rate on equity. Then, in equilibrium the nominal cost of equity facing

the firm fixed by international financial markets is:

(7) re = rd(1-Td*)/(1-Te

*)

and the weighted average nominal discount rate facing the firm is:

(8) rf = βrd(1-u) + (1-β)re

The after-corporate-tax, before-personal-tax, real rate of return fixed by international financial

markets is then:

(9) ri = βrd + (1-β)re - π

and the marginal effective tax rate on capital in a small open economy is then:

(10) METR = (rg – ri)/rg

All of the above formulae were developed for physical capital, in particular for depreciable

capital like equipment and buildings. Non-depreciable capital, such as land, is easily

accommodated by setting economic depreciation (δ) and the present value of tax depreciation

allowances (Z) to zero in the expression for the user cost of capital, rg (equation (2)), giving:

(11) rg = (1+t)(rf-π)/(1-u)

For inventory capital the expression for the cost of capital can be shown to be:

(12) rg = (1+t)(rf-π+uπf)/(1-u)

where the parameter f is equal to 0 if LIFO inventory valuation is used for tax purposes and equal

to 1 if FIFO is used. Thus, the use of FIFO inventory accounting is seen to increase the cost of

holding inventory capital by virtue of the taxation of the inflationary increase in the cost of

inventories.

Issues Illuminated by METR Analysis

The primary applications of METR analysis are twofold. First, the results of a METR analysis

show the net effect of all components of the tax system on the level of the taxation of capital

income generated by the marginal investment analyzed. Thus, a METR provides a measure of the

actual tax burden on a prospective investment attributable to the existing (or proposed) tax

system. Moreover, an appropriately weighted average of the METRs on specific types of

Page 123: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

123

investments can be constructed to provide a measure of the overall level of taxation of capital

income in the economy, showing how the tax system distorts investment decisions (and, if

individual level taxes are considered, saving decisions as well) and thus introduces inefficiencies

or “excess burdens” into the economy.30

Second, by considering a wide variety of investments that differ by asset, method of finance,

investor or economic circumstances, METR analysis provides an indicator of the tax differentials

that arise across different types of investments, that is, it shows how taxes affect the composition

of investment. In particular, a METR analysis shows how the tax system results in a variety of

distortions of investment decisions, thus creating additional efficiency losses, beyond those

associated with simply taxing capital income at a uniform effective tax rate. The most commonly

cited distortion is across types of assets, as differential taxation of different types of assets

induces businesses to invest too heavily in tax-advantaged assets and too little in tax-

disadvantaged assets. This of course translates into distortions across business sectors, as the tax

system favors sectors with production processes that use tax-favored assets intensively and

penalizes businesses that use relatively heavily taxed assets intensively.

METRs provide an indication of the overall level of taxation of various forms of capital income

and thus indicate how the tax system affects investment and saving decisions. Because they

consider many aspects of the tax system, METR analyses often give very different results

regarding the effects of the tax system on investment decisions than would a simple examination

of statutory tax rates (or special preferences) in isolation. Effective tax rates that are far above or

below the statutory rate indicate potential areas for reform, as relatively high positive rates act as

a deterrent to investment, while negative METRs suggest that the tax system stimulates

investments that are socially undesirable because they earn a return lower than the opportunity

cost of funds.

METRs are also very useful in identifying the extent to which the tax system distorts investment

allocation decisions by asset and by business sector (given the benchmark level of taxation of

capital income in the tax system). Apart from the arguments for differential taxation noted above,

most public finance economists would argue that competitive markets are generally efficient in

allocating resources. The implication of this view is that tax differentials are generally

undesirable because the associated distortions of investment allocation decisions result in reduced

productivity of investment; that is, a disproportionate amount of capital is allocated to those

sectors and assets in which tax treatment is relatively favorable rather than to those sectors and

assets where investment would be most productive in the sense of generating output valued by

30

"Distortions" of investment decisions must be measured relative to a benchmark. In general, a tax

system would not distort investment decisions if the METR were zero on all types of investment;

this would occur, for example, under an ideal consumption-based tax (Zodrow and McLure, 1991).

In this case, METR differentials – and the associated distortions of investment decisions – would be

measured relative to a benchmark tax rate of zero. However, under an income-based tax, the

benchmark level of taxation of capital income is typically the statutory income tax rate. In this case,

the distortion of saving/investment decisions implied by the taxation of capital income at the

statutory rate is in a sense taken as given, and the distortions attributable to tax differentials are

measured relative to the statutory income tax rate. In addition, note that this discussion assumes that

efficiency requires a tax system that is neutral across assets. This need not be true. For example, tax

differentials may be desirable to correct for negative production externalities (e.g., pollution) or to

offset other inefficiencies in the economy (e.g., inefficiencies in the taxation of labor income). These

complications are ignored in the analysis, as they are best addressed with specific tax policies as

needed (e.g., taxes on effluents or reform of the system of labor income taxation) rather than through

the ordinary income tax system applied to capital income; for further discussion, see Gugl and

Zodrow (2004).

Page 124: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

124

consumers. In other words, the tax system should generally be characterized by "economic

neutrality" with respect to investment allocation decisions, or METRs that do not vary according

to the type of asset or business sector.

Limitations of the METR analysis

The METR analysis of capital, while being a very useful parameter for measuring the burden on

investment across capital assets and sectors, has its limitations. First, it only measures the burden

on capital investment. It does not measure the burden of other taxes such as payroll taxes, custom

duties, etc. that do not affect the calculation of the METR on capital.

Second, it is an analysis of the tax code as it exists in the statute books and does not incorporate

the actual implementation of the tax code which might vary widely due to compliance reasons

and the way the tax administration operates.

Third, the METR analysis does not incorporate government revenue considerations. While a

lower METR is good for encouraging investment, this is only a one sided view, as lower taxes

also imply lost revenue for the government. The economics literature suggests that the optimal

tax on capital is zero; but this holds only when economic efficiency is the sole consideration.

When equity is also a consideration a zero METR need not be the optimal choice. Also, the

METR analysis does not incorporate issues of incidence. It is assumed that the burden on capital

is borne by capital, though in reality, part of this could be passed on to labor. Likewise taxes,

other than those imposed on capital such as payroll taxes can also be passed on to capital. For the

purpose of this study incidence issues are not taken into consideration.

Fourth, it must be noted that, in order for the METR analysis to be used to provide broad

information of the tax burden faced by different sectors of the economy, it limits the input

parameters to those mentioned above. Hence highly nuanced tax benefits faced by a small

number of taxpayers are generally not incorporated into the METR analysis, though it can be

done in these individual cases.

It must be noted that the METR is highly sensitive to non-tax parameters such as the interest rate.

The METR is most useful when used as a tool to compare the burden imposed by the tax system

across different capital assets or across different sectors of the economy. When comparing across

countries, several simplifying assumptions are made in order to make a comparison of only the

tax systems. As a result, non-tax parameters are kept constant as far as possible. For example, the

interest rates might vary across countries due to various reasons, but only the tax aspects that

cause this difference are incorporated into the METR. When a comparison of the METRs is

made, the interest rate in the local country is taken to be inflation plus the international real

interest rate, when the country operates as a small open economy. This is a valid assumption

because any interest rate that is different from this can be arbitraged away in the financial market

through the open economy. When the country is considered a closed economy, the interest rate in

the local country less the tax imposed on it, when reduced by inflation is assumed to be equal to

the international interest rate. As a result, in the closed economy model, the tax system imposes a

wedge between the international interest rate and, the local interest rate less inflation. As this

translates to a higher interest rate in the local country, the METRs calculated using the closed

economy model take into consideration the differential interest rates across countries that are

explained by the taxation of interest income. All other non-tax factors that impose a wedge

between the after-tax interest rate and inflation plus international real interest rate are not a part of

the calculation. As a result local credit constraints, country risk premia, etc. that might result in a

high cost of doing business in a country are not included in the analysis.

Page 125: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

125

The two input parameters in the model: the debt equity ratio and the sector-wise composition of

assets are very important for determining the METRs. For the purpose of the calculation, these

ratios are taken as exogenous. In reality, these parameters are also a function of the tax and

economic parameters. Hence there is need to fix this at an arbitrary but reasonable value. The

debt-equity ratio, for example, is a function of the extent of risk that an investor faces and his

expected returns from the investment, both of which depend on the tax system. The same applies

to the sector-wise composition of capital assets. While the capital asset composition depends on

the nature of the business, the differential effective tax rates on asset types distorts the investment

in different assets. (This only affects the total METR which is a weighted average of the separate

asset-wise METRs). When the sector-wise ratio of debt to equity and the capital asset ratios for

the country being studied are available, it is not unreasonable to use this ratio as an input into the

model when one is analyzing the METR across sectors within an economy. But, when comparing

across countries these ratios are kept fixed and the tax system is analyzed from that stand point.31

Based on actual surveys of the asset ratios it has been found that the asset ratios in general follow

the composition used, though the actual numbers are not exactly the same. Manufacturing in

general has high proportion of equipment while Tourism is much more building-intensive.

Despite these limitations, the Marginal Effective Tax Rate analysis is one of the very few tools

that allows us to quantitatively summarize the impact of the complicated tax system on

investment. It allows us to isolate the tax impact from all the other factors that affect investments.

As a result, it is used on a regular basis to analyze tax systems all over the world and is very

useful for comparing tax systems. The approach used in this report uses the analysis developed by

Hall & Jorgenson (1967), King and Fullerton (1984) and Mintz (1995).32

31

FIAS has used the asset ratios based on a survey in Canada for all its country analysis. This keeps

this fixed and allows us to show the only effect the Tax factors. 32

Mintz, Jack M. (1995). “Tax Holidays and Investment,” in Anwar Shah (ed.), FiscalIncentives for

Investment and Innovation. Oxford: Oxford University Press, for the World Bank. King, Mervyn and

Don Fullerton (1984). The Taxation of Income From Capital. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Page 126: PERU Trajectories towards Formality

126

Annex H. Data for calculating the marginal effective tax rate

Domestic Corporate Income Tax rate 30% of income before dividends

Capital Gains Tax

Of a natural person If the net income is up to 27 UIT: 15%. For the excess over the 27 UIT: 21%. For

the excess over the 54 UIT: 30%.

Of a legal person 30%

Tax on Interest Currently 0%. However, it has already been decided that a 6.25% tax rate will start

to be effective in 2009. Corporates will be able to include interests as part of their

net income paying the regular corporate tax rate.

Tax on Dividend 4.1% of net income after taxes are paid

Sector specific tax

(Agri/Manufact/tourism/Mining)

Agr. 15% of income [compared with the 30% of income for non agriculture activities]

Domestic inflation rate 3.90%

Tax depreciation rate equipment 20%, except when the machine is leased, in which case the machine is depreciated

with an special rate

Tax depreciation rate building 3%, except when leased, in which case it is depreciated with an special rate

Customs Duty on machinery-equipment 0%

Land transfer tax/Stamp Duty

Property registration 3/1000 of the real estate property's value for "registration rights" plus a fee of

1.94% of UIT for "qualification rights"

Transfer registration 1.5/1000 of the transfer value when the value does not exceed S/ 35 000 or 3/1000

of the transfer value when the value exceeds that amount plas a fee of 0.8% of UIT

for "qualification rights"

Capital tax

Net Assets Temporal Tax Currently 0% for net assets worth of up to 1 million Nuevos Soles and a 0.5% tax

rate for the excess over the 1 million Nuevos Soles threshold. However, it has

already been ruled that starting 2009, the tax rate for the excess over the 1 million

Nuevos Soles threshold will be lowered to 0.4%. Rebatable.

Mining royalty For annual sales of up to 60 US$ millions: 1%. For annual sales between 60 y 120

US$ millions: 2%. For annual sales of more than 120 US$ millions: 3%

Selective Consumption Tax For fuels: an specific tax currently averaging 2.11 Soles per galon. For the purchase

of vehicles: 10% for new vehicles, 30% for used vehicles and 10 % for pick up

trucks. For sodas: 17%. For alcoholic beverages: wines, whisky, rum, gin are taxed

at 20%, Pisco at 1.50 soles per liter, and beer at 27.8% of the import price or the

recommended retail price. For tobacco: common cigarettes are taxed at 50%,

cigarettes of black and blond tobacco at 30%. For rice: 4% of the price of the first

sale in national territory.

VAT Refund (Delay in years) Legally 45 working days

Tax holiday (years): H No

Investment Tax credits No

Small Business Tax regime / Micro

Business Tax Regime (RUS and RER)

 As described in Table 2.5 in the main text

VAT 19%, of which 2 percentage points correspond to the Municipal Promotion Tax,

which is transferred to local governments