39
1 Joint EPUNet-2003 and BHPS-2003 Conferences 3-5 July 2003, Colchester Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans Anita Koo Sociology Department Oxford University Email: [email protected]

Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

1

Joint EPUNet-2003 and BHPS-2003 Conferences

3-5 July 2003, Colchester

Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans

Anita Koo

Sociology Department

Oxford University

Email: [email protected]

Page 2: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

2

Abstract:

Intergenerational correlations on individuals' educational attainment and economic

success later in their lives constitute one of the classic research questions in

sociology. Educational choice is made when people were young, but has long term

determining effects on one's educational attainment and occupational status. This

paper presents the regularities of differentiated patterns of educational plans across

sections of the populations. It also shows that there are inheritance features in the

pattern of students' educational aspiration (their school plans are partly influenced by

their parental educational qualifications and occupational status). My analysis

suggests that economic factors, which measured in household income and household

size, do not have significant effect on youth's school plans. However, parents'

educational attainment and occupational status, which always be treated as sources of

class-based culture and values, are shown to have some impacts on students'

educational plans. In this paper, I have explored some intervening variables that may

contribute to the intergenerational inherence of educational aspiration. They are (1)

students' perceptions of probability of success in school that measured by their

satisfaction levels of schoolwork, (2) students' educational values measured by how

they evaluate the valuation of doing well in school. Significant associations are found

between these variables to students' educational aspirations. Also, some associations

between these variables and youth's family structure and class backgrounds are shown

in my results.

Page 3: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

3

I. Introduction:

Educational choices are made when people are young, but have long-term

determining effects on one’s educational attainment and socio-economic status.

Higher education is associated with access to more desirable jobs and higher incomes.

It is the key to economic success in modern society, which has substantial impact on

occupational outcomes and mobility chances. Simple human capital theory claims

that students are motivated to advance to higher educational qualifications or stay in

school longer by the foreseeable increase in their future income after graduation

(Becker, 1996). The decision of investment in education, like other form of economic

investment, is guided by a rational cost-benefit calculus. In economics, students’

decision-making mechanism is a description of individualistic rational calculation

process, in which individuals will choose to stay in school only if the expected future

income returns exceed the expected costs of further education (Manski & Wise,

1983). However, the regularities of the differentiated pattern of choice across

sections of populations suggest that there may be other forces at work within the

decision making process. Sociological research has put a lot of effort examining how

individual background characteristics, such as gender, family structure and class

origin, have an effect on one’s educational choice and attainment (Halsey et al, 1980).

The most important implication of this empirical research is that we should not

overlook the group differences in educational decisions.

Another main concern is the relationship between educational outcome and social

inequality. The correlations of educational attainment between parents and children

constitute one of the classic research questions in social science. A considerable

amount of research has been done to describe and explain the nature of regular

patterns of inequality and to obtain more insight into the impact of family background

on individuals’ educational attainment (Shavit & Blossfeld, 1993; Becker & Tomes,

1986; Bowles & Gintis, 2000). A great deal of effort has gone into explaining and

understanding the consistently significant impact of class origin on individuals’

educational attainment (Boudon, 1974; Halsey, Heath and Ridge, 1980; Erikson &

Jonsson, 1996; Breen & Goldthorpe, 1997; Goldthorpe, 1996). The differences

between social classes in economic resources, academic performance and educational

Page 4: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

4

aspirations are commonly recognized as three major sets of influential factors that

lead to educational inequality. However, given the introduction of free or subsidized

educational programs in most developed countries, the accounts of inequality that are

merely based on economic deprivation among working class students are no longer

satisfactory. Besides, performance differences among students from different class

backgrounds are not large enough to explain existing levels of inequality in

educational attainment (Erikson & Jonsson, 1996). Some studies reveal that even

when educational performance are controlled, children from different class origins are

continue to differ in their tendency to stay longer in full-time education. (Gambetta,

1987; Manski & Wise, 1983). Other scholars suggest that more attention should be

placed on the selection effect on educational inequality by taking class differences in

educational aspirations and demand of schooling more seriously (Murphy, 1981;

Willis & Rosen, 1979). They perceive the social differentials in education as a result

of self-selection that emphasized the intentional processes.

In fact, there are increasing number of studies that explain the stability of class

inequality in educational attainment by adopting the ‘rational choice model’ in recent

decades (Erikson & Jonsson, 1996; Breen & Goldthorpe, 1997). The new approach

seeks to understand educational inequality with respect to educational decisions made

by students, that is to examine how individual choices lead to aggregate differences of

educational attainment between groups. They address the issue of social class

differences with regards to students’ valuations and expectations of future educational

choices, which vary considerably according to students’ position in the social

structure.

The aim of my research is to understand educational inequality with respect to

educational decisions made by students. My argument is that the apparently

‘structured’ behaviour patterns are accumulations of individually understandable

purposeful actions. I try to explain the stability of the class-differentiated patterns of

educational choice based on the question why some people choose to stay in school

after their compulsory school years, while others do not. The main concern of this

paper is to examine the roles of both structural and intentional variables that act in the

mechanism of individuals’ formation of aspiration and choice-making process. As

Page 5: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

5

students make their choices voluntarily according to their ability with different values,

expectations and preferences, I aim at investigating the source of educational

preferences and aspirations, expectations and perceptions on their probability of

success, in relation to their school plans.

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. In section II, I will discuss

different theoretical approaches to relations between social inequality and differential

educational choice by means of a literature review. Sociologists and economists have

examined the existence of cultural and economic constraints from class backgrounds

shaping individuals’ educational aspirations and limiting the range of potential

choices. Section III identifies the potential determinants of students’ school plans.

They include students’ demographic characteristics and variables related to their class

background. Section IV describes the data and explores the relations between

student’s school plan and their family characteristics by presenting the results of

statistical analysis. I will also use other intentional data to illustrate the possible

mechanisms about how different school plans are patterned by students’ socio-

economical background. Section V is the conclusion.

II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice

The causes of inequality in educational choices have been the subject of much debate

among social scientists. The sociological and economical theories suggest different

economic, social and cultural constraints that shape the conditions under which

different individuals make their decisions. They also use different perspectives to

investigate how class origin effects have an influence in one’s decision-making

process. Sociological theories put much emphasis on the relations among structural

variables (in terms of parents’ socio-economic status), academic performance, and

differential educational aspirations. In economics, educational choices are made

mainly under the calculations of the differences in costs and expected returns for

individuals. But one’s ability and class differences in the availability of economic

resources also have an impact on their expectation and evaluation of this human

capital investment. In short, academic performance, economic resources and

educational aspiration are commonly recognized as the key determinants of

Page 6: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

6

differential educational choice. Boudon (1974) referred them to two mechanisms of

class effects on class differences in educational choice. The primary mechanism

states the effects of class-origin on students’ average ability. The secondary

mechanism formulates the effects of class differences in resources that influence

people’s aspirations and decisions. Through primary effect, students’ ability and their

school performance is affected by genetic and cultural inheritance. Apart from the

primary effects, class origin still has a secondary or indirect effect on students’ choice

over available options. That is, even controlling students’ cognitive ability or school

performance, the levels of ambition and aspiration associated with every educational

option are different according to students’ class origins. Also, this secondary effect

can be explained by the variations in availability of economic resources among

different classes.

In this paper, I use the rational choice framework to posit that a student’s educational

decision is a function of fulfilling goals or aspirations and making sensible calculation

with available information on the costs and probability of success. Different theories

approach the relations between social inequality and differential educational choice in

different ways. In the following, I try to capture these different approaches on this

issue explored with respect to academic ability, economic resources and educational

aspirations.

Among economists, human capital theory has been widely used to investigate the

decision to process schooling (Betts, 1994; Manski, 1993; Doministz & Manski,

1994; Modesto, 2003). Individuals are assumed to choose from further investment in

additional education or stop formal schooling and join the labour market. Children’s

education is an important human capital investment, and their expected potential

earnings determine their length of stay in school. Some economists suggest that class

differences may cause students to either react differently to similar information about

the job market or have access to different information on which to base their

enrollment decisions (Manski & Wise, 1983; Manski, 1993). The economic model of

choice is characterized by motivation or market incentives to maximize income

return. Students’ basic concern, or the guiding principles of their educational

Page 7: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

7

decisions is the costs and benefits of further schooling. They will choose to stay in

the educational system only if the expected benefits exceed the expected costs.

Other than the labour market’s information on expected income returns, both the

academic ability and the economic resources are relevant to individuals’ or families’

investment decisions on education. Ability is regarded as a complement of human

capital (Becker & Tomes, 1986; Becker, 1989). A high-ability child will earn more

from an additional unit of investment than a low-ability child, therefore, greater

amount of human capital will be invested in the high-ability child. The differences in

parental income are another determinant factor on educational choice. In free market,

individuals will choose an optimal mix between consumption and investment in

human capital resources to maximize value or utility. Poor families may borrow for

investment and leave negative financial bequests to later generations. In reality, with

borrowing constraints, families cannot borrow freely in the market. Those lower

income families will invest less in human capital and children from poorer families

will stay shorter in schools. The high-ability children in poor families suffer most. In

other words, the income effect overrides the ability effect which explains the low

participation rate in higher education among students from low income families.

Investment models with different budget sets under different market settings that

formulate the income effects of class on educational choice provide a good account of

how limited resources influence families’ or students’ educational choice (Mulligan,

1997). However, they have limitations in explaining the stability and persistence of

educational inequality in modern societies. In recent years, the direct costs of

education, in terms of fees and maintenance, have been reduced through growing

public provision of fee or subsidized education at all levels. Different credit and loan

systems also allow families with less income to borrow for children’s education.

Poorer families that previously faced financial constraints could benefit from the cost

cut and the relaxation of borrowing constraints. As long as the class differences in

educational choice and the participation rate in education beyond the compulsory

period remain, the income effect of parental choice fail to fully explain the class

differences in educational choice.

Page 8: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

8

On the contrary, cultural theorists and value theorists use a very different approach in

explaining how and why social origins bear upon the divergence of educational

outcome and schooling choice. They argue that cultural inheritance and class-based

values are the key determining factors which influence children’s educational choice.

Both of them have direct impact on academic performance and educational aspiration.

First, cultural theorists argue that class bias within the school system (Willis, 1977),

and differing cultural resources acquired from the family (Bourideu & Passeron,

1977) leads to class differences in students’ academic performance. And the

performance in school is expected to influence students’ educational aspirations as it

determines their evaluation of the probability of success when they choose to stay in

school. Second, they claim that the divergence of school choice and future

educational attainment is a result of different class-based value and culture which

affect one’s job preferences (Bouridue, 1973; Karlsen, 2001). The class differences in

job preferences influence students’ value attachment on educational outcome, which

result in different educational aspirations. This directly leads the children from

working class families to have lower aspirations for further education.

The class-divided pattern of aspiration has been understood in a different way from

the rational choice perspective by Breen and Goldthorpe (1997). The rational action

theory posits that class background is influential in students’ educational choice in

terms of their aspirations that are affected by their average ability and resources. The

mechanism of risk aversion, which is crucial to the theory, suggests that educational

choice is made to avoid downward mobility or to minimize the risk of ending up in a

lower social class than one’s parents. The model of risk aversion explains the class

effects on students’ aspiration formation referring to their intention of avoiding social

demotion. Students from advantaged families are more likely to stay longer in school

because their parents are under constant pressure to make greater investments in their

children’s education as a form of ‘defensive expenditure’, in order to maintain their

position at a level as good as the current generation. Given the high aspirations, even

if the investment is a rather high-risk one (when their children’s ability levels for

successful outcome is relatively low), the family will continue to input human capital

until a certain level to prevent their children from social demotion.

Page 9: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

9

The rational action theory of educational differentials accounts for the diversity of

choice by an inclusive decision-making mechanism. It considers not only the class

origin effect on students’ aspiration level but also the role of economic resources in

the decision making process. Breen and Goldthorpe suggest that the cost of taking a

risk to continue education has greater influence in stopping working class students

from continuing their education. The cost of paying tuition fees plus spending

additional years in school without getting a pass is higher for students from working-

class families. Therefore, even if they share the same occupational preferences as

middle-class students such as preferring a service class job and are ambitious to

obtain a higher educational qualification, the risk of failing in school may stop them

from having high aspirations to choose to stay longer in school. Through these

mechanisms of choice – aspiration formation and economic constraints – the rational

action theory clearly states that levels of educational aspirations and school decisions

are not determined by class specific culture and value, but are structured by students’

relative positions in the social hierarchy.

III. Determinants of school plan or educational aspiration:

The consequences of educational choices are big. At the individual level, they have a

long-term determining effect on one’s earning and occupational status. At the societal

level, the regularities of differentiated patterns of educational choices across sections

of the population (i.e. gender groups, family income groups, parents’ occupational

groups, parents’ educational attainments) might explain the phenomenon of different

levels of educational attainment and occupational status across groups of populations.

If the aspirations, school performance and expectations are really varied by class,

their choices will follow suit and the pattern of social mobility between generations

will remain undisturbed. In order to understand the pattern and causes of differential

educational choice across groups, it is useful to start with the factors that are known to

influence educational plans.

Gender

Page 10: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

10

Men traditionally achieved more years of education than women. However, from

1970s the gap between gender differences in educational attainment has declined

sharply (Shavit & Blossfeld, 1993; Erikson & Jonsson, 1996). In some countries,

results even show that there are more female students than boys in college after they

leave high school. However, at the same time, evidence shows that boys are

continuously more optimistic than girls about their future income (Bett, 1994).

Actually, women are still clustered in lower-ranking jobs with lower pay in the labour

market. Also, boys are shown to be more confident of their academic ability as they

are more likely to overestimate their school grades than girls (Sullivan, 2001).

Obviously, the relations between the trends in gender equity in schooling and the

gender differential perceptions of ability and income returns are still far from clear.

We are quite sure that gender has played a central role in the formulation of

educational and occupational aspirations.

Family structure

Family structure has important impact on students’ educational plans and decisions,

by its influences on one’s school performance. Evidence shows that the presence and

marital status of parents have an effect on children’s educational attainment (Pierret,

2001). Children in intact families with two biological parents are shown to have

better grades. Also, they are more likely to finish high school and attend college than

children in other types of families.

Family size

Family size also has an effect on the chances for further education among youth. It is

not difficult to understand as the family income and resources for each child’s

investment will decrease when the total number of children increases. Family income

is expected to play an important role in the decisions to go to college. By the same

token, family size, as measured by the number of siblings, is also often included as an

explanatory variable in models of college attendance. Besides, researchers also found

a negative relationship between family size and a student’s school achievement (Heer,

1985), which may be understood by the fact that parental attention for each child also

Page 11: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

11

decreases in large families. This means, interpersonal and economic resources will be

diluted in families with many children, leading to lower average school achievements

and years of education for such children (Downey, 1995; Heer, 1985). Children

within a family are assumed to compete for scare resources and parents are assumed

to allocate time and other resources to maximize their objective function. The larger

the number of siblings in the family, the lesser the resources are allocated for each

child.

Parental educational qualification

Parental education has long been noted as a powerful predictor of post-compulsory

education. Research results indicate strongly evidence of the intergenerational

transmission of educational achievement. These points to educational segregation

among families, a situation in which parents with high levels of educational

achievement encourage their children to stay longer in schools (Sewell et al., 1969 &

1970). Also, more highly educated parents are more likely to invest in their child’s

education as a consequence of their own educational experience and to avoid social

demotion. On the other hand, parents with low levels of educational achievement

have a greater tendency to encourage their children to enter the labour market.

Parental occupational status

Parents’ occupation is another important determinant of students’ educational

aspiration. It might capture part of the effects of family’s economic resources, but it

still has an independent effect on student’s job preferences and aspiration formation.

Household income

Family income is expected to play an important role in the decisions to go to college.

As mentioned above, children from lower-income families tend to leave school earlier

and have higher drop-out rates. Families with higher-income are expected to have

more resources available to support their children’s education. Also, they are more

willing to take the risk of investing longer years of school years in their children,

Page 12: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

12

while lower-income families have economic constraints even if their children have

high educational aspirations.

Self-assessment on schoolwork, general value towards education and occupational

aspirations are three variables that are included in my analysis. All of these variables

have influential impact on children’s school plans and educational choices. However,

at the same time, the effects could probably be explained away by variables of

students’ class background, as ability, values and occupational aspirations which are

greatly influenced by one’s social origin. These variables therefore can be treated as

intervening variables that mediate students’ class origin effects on their school plan.

IV. Data and Analysis

The analyses in this paper are based on the British Youth Panel of British Household

Panel Study, i.e. a regular survey of children in sample households who are in the age

band of 11 and 15. The British Youth Panel surveys have been conducted annually

since 1994 (the fourth wave of BHPS). To assess whether school plans are varied to

students’ individual and contextual characteristics, I will use data from the Youth

Panel for the years 1994 to 2001 which contains a sample of 1,476 youth who

participated in the survey at the age of 15. This group of young people at age 15 is

particularly suitable for my purposes as they are still in compulsory education and

will have to make their decisions of whether to stay or leave school when they turn

16. Of the responses received, 766 were male and 710 female.

This paper is based on an investigation of differential education choice across sections

of population in the UK. The British Youth Panel assess children’s school plans by

asking, “Do you want to leave school when you are 16, or do you plan to go on to

sixth form?” The data is explored in relation to children’s educational aspirations

which are classified into three groups: (1) ‘stay group’ for those who say that they

will go on to sixth form or college after 16; (2) ‘leave group’ for those who answer

that they will leave school after compulsory level; and (3) ‘unsure group’ for those

answer “don’t know”. Variables are considered at more than bivariate level. The

data is used to measure students’ plans for post-compulsory education, as well as the

Page 13: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

13

influence of their socio-economic backgrounds on their educational decision-making

processes. The survey collects data on: youth’s school plans; their self-assessment on

schoolwork; attitudes towards education and their occupational aspirations. With

information in the main panel, wide ranges of information about the children’s family

backgrounds and parental socio-economic status are ready for investigation.

The vector of covariates can be grouped into:

(1) Students’ demographic background: gender, family structure and number of

siblings: Family structure captures the number of parents in the household,

but not the relationship of the parents to the responding youth, taken from the

data source I am using. Dichotomous measures contrast two parent

households (either biological/ adoptive parent household or reconstituted

families, i.e. one biological or adoptive parent and one step-parent), with

one-parent families. Here, family size is measured as the number of children

in respondents’ household, including own, step- and adoptive children, by

directly asking the adults in household.

(2) Socio-economic characteristics: parent’s highest educational level, parents’

occupational status and household income: Parents’ educational levels equal

the highest qualification they obtained before the interview. Given some of

the youth are came from single parent families, the use of either only

‘father’s educational level’ or mother’s educational level’ as a measure of

parent’s educational qualification is problematic. Therefore, the highest level

of parent’s educational attainment will be used. When father’s educational

level is higher than the mother’s, father’s will be used, and vice versa. This

also applies to the measure of parents’ occupational status. Father’s or

mother’s information will be used depending on whose occupational status is

higher. As the occupational status is measured by fathers’ or mothers’ most

recent job, the data of this variable cannot capture their employment status in

the survey years. They may be unemployed when they were interviewed.

This information might be indirectly reflected by data on household income.

Household income equals total family income received a month before

interview. For this analysis, I use 1994 as the base year. Income data,

Page 14: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

14

collected in different years of the survey, are adjusted for inflation and keep

all measures in units of 1994’s pounds. I have grouped the data of monthly

household income into five income groups: less than 1000 pounds, 1001 to

2000 pounds, 2001 to 3000 pounds, 3001 to 4000 pounds, and more than

4001 pounds.

(3) The British Youth Panel also includes survey questions that ask about

students’ satisfaction level with their schoolwork, the meaning of doing well

in school, the job they plan to do in future. The three survey questions are

directly asked of youth respondents. As the third questions were asked only

from wave 4 to wave 8, the sample size decreased to 677. I have recoded

their chosen occupations into Goldthorpe’s seven-class scheme.

The first phase of the analysis examines relative influence of personal and family

characteristics on school plans. I use the demographical and socio-economical data to

explore associations between youth’s aspirations and factors such as gender, number

of siblings, family structure, household income, parental educational qualifications

and occupational status. Group differences are first explored by using chi-square tests

and oneway anova. Then, I use multivariate regression to examine the diversity

across aspirational groups in terms of all the available demographical and socio-

economic variables. The method of multinomial regression is employed, because I

intend to model the extensive set of choices. The model does not only allow me to

assess the effectiveness of a range of variables in terms of how well they perform in

predicting outcomes, rather, it seeks to identify those explanatory variables that are

effective in terms of classifying youth into the outcome categorical groups (i.e.

whether students plan to proceed to post-16 education, plan to leave school after 16 or

have not decided yet). It may be informative to investigate the extent to which factors

such as personal characteristics and family backgrounds have differential effect across

these three responses on school plans.

In the second phase of analysis, I consider the associations between the intervening

factors, including students’ satisfaction with their schoolwork, their evaluation on the

valuation of education and occupational aspirations. I will also examine how one’s

Page 15: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

15

personal characteristics and family background have an impact on these intervening

variables. At the end, I explore the effect of these variables on school plans with

reference to factors such as gender, number of siblings and parents’ socio-economic

status in the multinomial regressions models. My aim is to check if these factors have

direct and independent effects on students’ planning.

A. Do you want to leave school when you are 16, or do you plan to go on to sixth

form?

Figure 1: Students' School Plan

10.64 14.02

75.34

01020304050607080

don't know leave school at 16 go to sixth form orcollege

Leave school when you are 16?

Per

cent

age

Among the 1486 observations, 75.34% belong to the ‘stay group’ – plan to go on to

sixth form or college after age 16, 14.02% belong to the ‘leave group’ – plan to leave

school after age 16, and 10.64% belong to the ‘unsure group’ – responded that they do

not know whether they will stay or leave school after age 16.

Gender

The results indicate a significant association between gender and youth’s aspirations

with regard to post-16 education (X2=32.851; df=2; p<.001). A higher percentage of

females would like to stay in post-16 education. They are less likely to say that they

‘plan to leave school after 16’ or say they ‘don’t know’, while males are more likely

to give these two answers.

Page 16: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

16

Figure 2: Students' Gender in terms of SchoolPlan

0

20

40

60

80

100

don't know leave school at16

go to s ixth form orcollege

Leave school when you are 16?

Perc

enta

ge

m ale

female

Parental setup

The results indicate that there is some association between family structure and

educational aspirations (X2=7.754; df=2; p<.05). Among students who are living with

two parents, more students than expected plan to stay in post-16 education. In single-

parent families, however, fewer students choose this option. They are more likely to

plan to leave school after 16.

Figure 3: Family Structure in terms of School Plan

0

20

40

60

80

100

don't know leave school at16

go to sixthform or college

Leave school when you are 16?

Per

cent

age

2-parentssingle parents

Page 17: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

17

Family size

Associations between household size and school plans are also explored here since

students living with different number of siblings do not always fall into discrete

family structures. Although students from big families (with more than 3 children in

household) are less likely to belong to the ‘stay group’ than those from smaller

families, statistics does not show any strong association between the variables

(X2=10.596; df=6; p=.102).

Figure 4: Family Size (number of children) in terms of School Plan

0

20

40

60

80

100

don't know leave school at16

go to sixth formor college

Leave school when you are 16?

Perc

enta

ge 1

2

3m ore than 3

Parents’ highest educational level

Strong association between parents’ highest educational level and students’

educational plans is evident from the analyses (X2=66.398; df=10; p<.001). Students

with parents who have a degree are most likely to plan to stay in post-16 education.

For those parents who have A-Level qualifications or have teaching, nursing and

other higher qualifications, their children are also likely to plan to stay in post-16

education. While children whose parents have O-Level or commercial qualifications

are also likely to answer they will stay, children from the remaining groups, whose

parents have no qualifications at all, are more likely to answer they ‘plan to leave

school’ or ‘don’t know’.

Page 18: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

18

Figure 5: Parent's Highest Educational Attainmentin terms of School Plan

0

20

40

60

80

100

don't know leave school at16

go to sixth formor college

Leave school when you are 16?

Per

cent

age degree

higher QFA-LevelO-LevelCSE gradno QF

Parents’ occupational status

There is a significant association between parental socio-economic status and

students’ educational aspirations. Children who have parents working in class I and

class II occupations are more likely to plan to stay in post-16 education. On the other

hand, while students from class V and class VII families are more likely to answer

they ‘plan to leave school’, those from class VI families are more likely to answer

‘don’t know’. Statistics show a strong association between the variables (X2=75.413;

df=12; p<.001).

Figure 6: Parent's Highest Occupational Status interms of School Plan

0

20

40

60

80

100

don't know leave school at16

go to s ixth formor college

Leave school when you are 16?

Perc

enta

ge

Class IClass IIClass IIIClass IV

Class V

Class VIClass VII

Page 19: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

19

Household income

The results indicate a strong association between household income and students’

school plans (F=5.33; df=4; p<.001). Students from families in the higher-income

groups are more likely to plan to stay in post-16 education than those from families in

the lower-income groups. They are unlikely to answer they ‘plan to leave school’ or

‘don’t know’. On the other hand, students from families in the two lowest income

groups are more likely to plan to leave school than other groups.

Figure 7: Household income in terms of School Plan

0

20

40

60

80

100

don't know leave school at16

go to sixth formor college

Leave school when you are 16?

Per

cent

age

0-1001001-20002001-30003001-40004001 or more

I explore the diversity across the aspirational groups in terms of all the discussed

demographical and socio-economical variables by using multivariate analysis. Table

1 shows the results of two multinomial logistic regressions comparing the personal

characteristics and class background of the groups between (1) ‘stay group’ and

‘unsure group’, and (2) ‘stay group’ and ‘leave group’, in relation to the predictor

variables.

Page 20: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

20

Table 1: Multinominal Logit Model of Youth's School Plan (Constrast against youth who plan to stay in school after 16)

Unsure LeaveIndependent Variables Coefficient S.E. Coefficient S.E.

Constant -2.341 *** 0.468 -2.199 *** 0.463

Female -0.582 *** 0.180 -0.978 *** 0.171

Single parent family 0.112 0.244 -0.069 0.218

Number of Children in Household 2 -0.249 0.209 -0.113 0.186 3 -0.173 0.266 -0.327 0.252 4 or more 0.534 0.322 -0.056 0.329

Parent's Highest Educational Level Teaching, Nursing or other higher QF 0.097 0.322 0.659 0.377 GCE A Level -0.304 0.427 0.288 0.468 GCE O Level or Equiv 0.117 0.365 1.045 ** 0.403 Commercial, CSE Grade, Apprenticeship or other QF 0.464 0.409 1.270 ** 0.445 No qualification 0.277 0.393 1.388 *** 0.418

Parent's Highest Occupational Status (Goldthorpe's Class Scheme) II 0.458 0.331 -0.411 0.351 III 0.586 0.344 0.388 0.314 IV 0.837 0.428 0.684 0.379 V 0.914 * 0.463 1.073 ** 0.388 VI 1.096 * 0.445 0.302 0.446 VII 0.849 * 0.395 0.760 * 0.352

Household Income (Monthly) 1001-2000 -0.028 0.266 -0.157 0.230 2001-3000 0.325 0.305 -0.068 0.278 3001-4000 -0.159 0.411 -0.796 0.429 4001 -0.936 0.599 -0.109 0.411

Log likelihood -954.966Number of Observations 1422

Note: * p<0.05 (Wald statistic), ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001

It is evident from the multinomial logistic regressions that variables such as family

structure, sibling size and household income do not contribute significantly to

predicating students’ answers on school plans after controlling other explaining

variables. On the other hand, variables of gender and parents’ educational

qualifications and occupational status contributed significantly to the model. When

other variables are being controlled, girls are more unlikely to respond ‘don’t know’

or ‘plan to leave school’ than boys. Besides, when we compare the parameter

estimates of regression estimated among samples with different answers, parents’

Page 21: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

21

occupational status also has great influence on students’ school plans. After

controlling variables of household income and parents’ educational qualifications,

children in class V, VI or VII families are less likely to plan to stay in school after 16

but tend to response ‘don’t know’ about their school plan. Compared with children

from class I, they have greater probability for not having concrete school plans at age

15. On the other hand, students having parents who are foremen or technicians (class

V) are more likely to plan to leave school after compulsory education. This result is

significant at 1% level and the coefficient is high. That means, compared to the base

group whose parents are professional or managerial workers, children with parents

who have class V occupations are the group who have greatest intention to leave

school after 16.

Parents’ educational qualifications are another powerful predictor of post-compulsory

school plan when we compare the ‘stay group’ and ‘leave group’ in the regression

model. The coefficients of the regressions provide strong evidence that the

probability of planning to leave school after compulsory level increases as the

educational qualifications of parents decreases. Compared to the base group whose

highest qualifications is ‘have a degree’, students who have parents have O-level

qualifications have higher probability to plan to leave school after 16. Students who

have parents with CSE Grade qualifications have even higher probability, while

whose parents with no qualifications have the greatest probability to plan to leave

school after 16.

At the same time, we should not overlook the role of different variables in parameter

estimates of two multinomial logistic regressions in comparing samples with different

answers. First, variables of parent’s occupational status play an important

explanatory role in both regressions (i.e. the comparison between the ‘stay group’ and

the ‘unsure group’, and the comparison between the ‘stay group’ and the ‘leave

group’), while the variables of parent’s educational level have an effect only when we

compare the ‘stay group’ and the ‘leave group’. These findings suggest that the

availability of concrete plans or purposively preferences is conditioned by

individuals’ class positions in terms of parents’ occupational status. It also shows that

the level of parent’s education have a greater influence on the direction of choice/

Page 22: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

22

preferences of stay or leave, rather than having an effect on the eagerness of planning

at age 15 (i.e. have a concrete educational plan or not).

Another important finding is the insignificance of the effects contributed by

household income to the variation of educational aspirations when we control parent’s

educational levels and occupational status. As the effect of sibling size is

insignificant as well, the aspiration differences because of the family resources are not

as great as we expected. On the other hand, the class effect in terms of parents’

educational levels and occupational status take a more significant role in influencing

student’s school plans.

This preliminary finding describes the effects of structural factors, but reveals little

about the underlying processes that actually lead to diverse educational aspirations.

Results presented in table 1 show the ‘full’ effect of family background, without

making distinction between its direct effect of preferences or educational aspirations,

and the effect coming through school performance or assessment. For example,

students with parents having low educational qualifications or students from class V

families have a higher probability of planning to leave school after 16 may be due to

one or both of the ability effect and other class effect on aspiration. As mentioned

above, the class origin effect on educational choice may be associated with the

availability of cultural capital and other parental inputs that facilitate or hinder one’s

school performance. Students from specific class backgrounds may inherit more

cultural capital which helps them to be more adaptable to school environments and

enjoy their studies more than those from other class backgrounds. Besides, the effect

of class origin can have a direct impact on educational choice whereby students from

specific classes have higher educational aspirations. Parents will encourage their

children to stay on in school irrespective of their performance and probability of

success. Sociologists have referred to these direct and indirect impacts as the

‘secondary’ and ‘primary’ effects of class inequality in educational choice. In the

following sections, I will explore the associations between children’s school plans and

the variables that related to either primary or secondary effects of class origin. The

variables include student’s self-assessment, educational and occupational aspirations.

Page 23: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

23

B. How do you feel about your schoolwork?

School experience and educational achievement are two important determinants on

students’ future participation in higher education. They facilitate progression to the

next educational level, and serve as an indicator to evaluate the probability of success

in continuing education. Experience in school and studying experience also

contribute to the ways in which education is perceived by students. Good experiences

may build students’ confidence and encourage them to continue or process in

education, while bad experiences could discourage their participation in post-

compulsory education. In this paper, students’ experience and schoolwork will be

measured in terms of their satisfaction with their schoolwork. This survey question

may provide a piece of important information about students’ educational

achievement, which is reflected in their self-perception of their ability and

performance in school.

The British Youth Panel includes relatively limited questions on youth’s school

performance and their self-perception of academic ability. Neither the data about

students’ self-assessment nor data on their school records is available. But the

question on how youth feel about their schoolwork may provide some insights into

the relationship between the sample’s experiences and their school plans. In the

interview the youth respondents were asked to classify how they feel about their

schoolwork into seven-scale measure, from ‘completely happy’ to ‘completely

unhappy’ in seven-scale. This survey question is not identical to students’

educational achievement. It provides on the other hand more information about

student’s self-perception on their ability and performance in school. As I argue that

individuals will rationally assess the possibility of success and the constraints

involved while making educational decisions, it is important to examine how they

make decisions based on their perceptions of their schoolwork. Here, I am going to

examine the relations between positive school experiences and the chance to have

purposive school plans. After having a general idea on relations between youth’s

educational choice and their degree of happiness about schoolwork, I use an ordinal

Page 24: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

24

regression to further investigate the distribution of demographic and socio-economic

characteristics of youth who have different self-assessment about their schoolwork.

Figure 8: Student's Degre e of Happiness andSchool Plan

05

10152025303540

comple

te ly hap

py 2 3ne

ither 5 6

comple

te ly un

happy

De g re e o f Hap p in e s s a bo u t s ch o o l w o rk

Perc

enta

ge

don't know

leave schoolat 16

go to s ix thform orcollege

First of all, results from an analysis of variance indicate a significant association

between students’ school plans and the satisfaction level of their schoolwork (F=6.89;

df=6; p<.001). As expected, the ‘stay group’ is the happiest, and the ‘leave group’ is

least happy. In figure 8, we can see from the distributions that more than 35% of the

youth in ‘stay group’ feel very happy (degree 2) with their schoolwork and 30% of

them feel happy (degree 3). On the other hand, the degree of happiness among youth

in the ‘leave group’ is more evenly distributed among different levels of happiness

(degree 2 and 3) and ‘neither happy nor unhappy’ (degree 4). However, we have to

bear in mind that there is only a small percentage of youth who feel unhappy about

schoolwork among all three aspirational groups. Only 9% of the children from the

‘stay group’ feel unhappy about their schoolwork (from degree 5 to 7), and 13.4%

from the ‘unsure group’. Even among the ‘leave group’, only slightly more then one

fifth of the children feel unhappy about their schoolwork.

Page 25: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

25

The positive association between students’ degree of happiness and purpose to stay in

school after 16 might suggest that students make choice according to their perception

on probability of success. If self-assessment about schoolwork is one of the concerns

in making educational decision, it is interesting to know the characteristics of youth

who are more likely to feel happy about schoolwork. In the following, I use an

ordinal logistic regression to further investigate the distribution of demographic and

socio-economic characteristics of youth who have different self-assessment about

their schoolwork.

In table 2, the dependent variable of the ordinal regression model is the different

degree of happiness about schoolwork and the independent variables including

gender, sibling size, family structure, household income, parents’ occupational status

and educational attainment. Comparing groups of youth with different degrees of

happiness, the family structure has a very significant effect on their level of self-

assessment on schoolwork. Children from single-parent families are more likely to

choose ‘completely unhappy’ than those in families with two parents. Another

variables of students’ family structure also have some effect on their satisfaction

levels of schoolwork. Youth in households that have 2 children are less likely to feel

completely unhappy compared to those in families with only one child.

Page 26: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

26

Table 2: Ordinal logit Regression: Youth's degree of happiness about their school work

Independent Variables Coeff icient S.E.

1 Completely happy -1.500 0.2462 0.392 0.2393 1.775 0.2444 Neither happy/ unhappy 2.864 0.2535 3.680 0.2686 4.476 0.296

Female 0.020 0.096

Single Parent Family 0.456 *** 0.138

Number of Children in Household 2 -0.272 * 0.109 3 -0.260 0.144 4 or more -0.029 0.212

Parent's Highest Educational Level Teaching, Nursing or other higher QF 0.213 0.158 GCE A Level 0.202 0.208 GCE O Level or Equiv 0.115 0.189 Commercial, CSE Grade, Apprenticeship or other QF 0.373 0.230 No qualification 0.424 * 0.212

Parent's Highest Occupational Status (Goldthorpe's Class Scheme) II 0.099 0.156 III 0.213 0.169 IV 0.250 0.226 V 0.427 0.244 VI 0.597 * 0.255 VII 0.254 0.209

Household Income (Monthly) 1001-2000 0.492 *** 0.152 2001-3000 0.443 * 0.175 3001-4000 0.273 0.212 4001 0.271 0.241

Log Likelihood -2251.48Number of observations 1422

Note: * p<0.05 (Wald statistic), ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001

There are also some class origin effects on students’ satisfaction level in terms of

parental educational qualification, parental occupational status and household income.

The parameter estimates of the ordinal logistic regressions show that compared to

children who have parents with a degree or higher qualification, students whose

parents without any qualification are more likely to feel completely unhappy about

Page 27: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

27

schoolwork. At the same time, compared to children of professionals and managers,

students from class VI families are more likely to choose ‘completely unhappy’ about

their satisfaction level. After controlling both the income effect and parent’s

educational attainment, the positive coefficient of class VI remains high. Besides,

students from families in income groups with monthly income £1001-£2000 and

£2001-£3000 have a higher probability to feel completely unhappy than those from

the lowest income group. In the regression, however, the effect of gender is small and

insignificant, which means there is no gender difference between students’

satisfaction level with schoolwork.

C. How much does it mean to you to do well in school?

Value placed on education is another determinant on students’ school performance

and purposes for continuation in education after compulsory level. Students’ school

plans and their school grades are expected to be closely linked to how they evaluate

the value of doing well in school. Presenting the pattern of educational values among

students could be a way for us to understand the reason of certain choices. And if the

educational values are products of structural variables, examining youth’s values

placed on their schoolwork is a way for us to examine the intervening variables

between class background of family and educational decisions. This allows a more

systemic discussion on the sub-cultural values or other social psychological variables

that significant others such as parents, who are supposed to contribute to the

formation and adjustment of the youth’s aspirations. Therefore, I am going to

examine students’ evaluation on the importance of education in order to clarify the

relations between class origins and educational plans of youths.

The question of ‘how much does it mean to you to do well in school?’ is asked in the

British Youth Panel from 1995. From wave 5 to wave 11, we have 1277 responses to

this question. The respondents were asked to choose among four answers to describe

how much it means to do well in school from ‘a great deal’, ‘quite a lot’, ‘a little but

not very much’ to ‘very little’. As only a small number of children choose the last

two options, I combined them into one.

Page 28: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

28

Figu re 9: S tu de nt s' Atti tud e and S ch o ol Plan

0

1 0

2 0

3 0

4 0

5 0

6 0

7 0

8 0

a g r ea t dea l qu ite a lo t lit tle

Ho w m u ch m e an s t o d o w e ll a t s ch o o l?

Perc

enta

ged o n't kn o w

le a ve s ch o ola t 1 6

g o to s ix thfo r m o rco ll e g e

Not surprisingly, results from an analysis of variance indicate a strongly significant

association between students’ school plans and their educational attitudes (F=35.83;

df=2; p<.001). Youth in the ‘stay group’ place highest value on education. Nearly

70% of them think that doing well in school means a great deal to them. Around 30%

of them think that education means quite a lot to them, and only 3% say that it means

little. Among the ‘unsure group’, around 40% think that education means a great deal

to them, nearly 50% answer ‘quite a lot’, and only 10% think that it means little to

them. On the other hand, a relatively high percentage of students from the ‘leave

group’ (around 30%) answer that doing well in school means only a little or very little

to them.

To further investigate the distribution of demographic and socio-economic

characteristics of youth who have placed different values on education, I use an

ordinal logistic regression. In the model, gender, sibling size, family structure,

household income, parents’ occupational status and educational attainment are the

dependent variables. I am interested in the characteristics of youth who are more

likely to place higher value on education. This examination helps to check if

students’ demographic backgrounds or scoio-economic backgrounds do have cultural

or direct effect on educational aspirations through their educational values.

Page 29: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

29

T able 3: Ordina l Logi t R egres sion: Youth's Value on Education

Inde pende nt Variables C oeff ic ien t S .E.

A gre at dea l 0.68 7 0.287Quite a lo t 2.81 9 0.302

Fema le -0.40 3 *** 0.116

Single Pare nt Fam ily 0.30 5 0.161

Num ber of Children in Ho use hold 2 -0.05 2 0.131 3 -0.16 9 0.176 4 or more -0.28 4 0.243

Paren t's High est Ed uca tion al L eve l Tea ch ing, Nursing or other h ighe r QF -0.19 1 0.193 GCE A Le vel 0.05 0 0.253 GCE O Level o r Equiv 0.06 6 0.228 Co mm ercial, CSE Gra de, Appren ticeship or othe r QF 0.48 0 0.267 No qualificatio n 0.63 4 * 0.250

Paren t's High est Occupa tion al S tatu s (Goldthorpe 's Class Sche me) II 0.00 1 0.196 III 0.08 6 0.205 IV 0.45 6 0.273 V 0.45 4 0.294 V I 0.69 6 * 0.300 V II 0.09 5 0.250

Househo ld Inco me (M onth ly) 10 01-200 0 0.27 0 0.178 20 01-300 0 0.43 7 * 0.206 30 01-400 0 -0.00 4 0.263 40 01 0.11 7 0.290

Log Likelihoo d -1069 .24Numb er of Observatio ns 1 277

Note: * p<0.05 (W ald stat ist ic), ** p<0.01, *** p< 0.001

The result show in table 3 indicates gender effects and some class effects on students’

educational value. Comparing groups of youth who place different values on

education, gender has a strong and significant effect. Girls are more likely to think

that doing well in school means a great or a lot to them, while boys tend to think that

it means only little to them. This may explain why girls’ participation rate in post-

compulsory level has increased a lot and remained high in these years. Parents’

educational qualification, occupational status and household income also have some

Page 30: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

30

effects on children’s educational value. Compared to children whose parents have a

degree, children have parents with no qualifications are more likely to place low value

on education. Compared to children in class I families, children who have parents

have class VI occupations also place low value on education. Among the income

groups, children in families with monthly income from £2001 to £3000 are more

likely to place lowest value on education when compared to the lowest income group.

In the above analyses, I have evaluated (1) the effects of satisfaction level of

schoolwork and educational value on youth’s school plans, and (2) the effects of

children’s demographic backgrounds and class origins on their educational value and

self-assessment. The results show that there are significant associations between

students’ school plans and the two intervening variables (i.e. students’ educational

value and self-assessment of school performances). At the same time, some of these

associations may be explained away by students’ class origin effects. To determine

the collective impact of these characteristics, some multinomial logistic regressions

analyses have been performed. In table 4, I compare the results of two nominal

regression models of students’ school plans. The results of Model I have already been

presented in table 1. The model is designed to show the ‘full effect’ of students’

personal characteristics and family backgrounds on their educational aspiration. I add

another model (Model II), which contains variables of students’ degree of happiness

about schoolwork and their values placed on education, in table 4. The variables of

youths’ demographic and socio-economic characteristics are also considered in the

model. Together with students’ educational values and their satisfactory level of

schoolwork related indices, all these variables are explored in order to describe the

probable associations between students’ school plans and their family background.

My proposition is if the class effect is working through the two introduced intervening

variables, there should be considerable reductions in many of the socio-economic

backgrounds coefficients in Model II.

Page 31: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

31

Table 4: Two Multinominal Logit Models of Youth's School Plan (Constrast against youth who plan to stay in school after 16)

Unsure LeaveIndependent Variables Model I Model II Model I Model II

Constant -2.341 *** -2.679 *** -2.199 *** -2.635 ***(0.468) (0.578) (0.463) (0.569)

Female -0.582 *** -0.511 ** -0.978 *** -0.865 ***(0.180) (0.197) (0.171) (0.191)

Single parent family 0.112 -0.011 -0.069 -0.302(0.244) (0.266) (0.218) (0.244)

Number of Children in Household 2 -0.249 -0.159 -0.113 -0.145

(0.209) (0.230) (.0186) (0.211) 3 -0.173 0.129 -0.327 -0.133

(0.266) (0.288) (0.252) (0.281) 4 or more 0.534 0.646 -0.056 0.030

(0.322) (0.348) (0.329) (0.358)Parent's Highest Educational Level Teaching, Nursing or other higher QF 0.097 0.198 0.659 0.706

(0.322) (0.347) (0.377) (0.408) GCE A Level -0.304 -0.167 0.288 0.353

(0.427) (0.452) (0.468) (0.499) GCE O Level or Equiv 0.117 0.307 1.045 ** 1.164 **

(0.365) (0.395) (0.403) (0.438) Commercial, CSE Grade, Apprenticeship or other QF 0.464 0.573 1.270 ** 1.253 **

(0.409) (0.442) (0.445) (0.484) No qualification 0.277 0.070 1.388 *** 1.090 *

(0.393) (0.433) (0.418) (0.456)Parent's Highest Occupational Status (Goldthorpe's Class Scheme) II 0.458 0.294 -0.411 -0.375

(0.331) (0.356) (0.351) (0.391) III 0.586 0.433 0.388 0.335

(0.344) (0.367) (0.314) (0.353) IV 0.837 0.912 * 0.684 0.595

(0.428) (0.460) (0.379) (0.434) V 0.914 * 0.828 1.073 ** 1.190 **

(0.463) (0.500) (0.388) (0.438) VI 1.096 * 0.939 * 0.302 0.104

(0.445) (0.479) (0.446) (0.503) VII 0.849 * 0.825 0.760 * 0.846 *

(0.395) (0.422) (0.352) (0.396)Household Income (Monthly) 1001-2000 -0.028 -0.179 -0.157 -0.379

(0.266) (0.288) (0.230) (0.257) 2001-3000 0.325 0.336 -0.068 -0.306

(0.305) (0.329) (0.278) (0.313) 3001-4000 -0.159 -0.144 -0.796 -0.682

(0.411) (0.451) (0.429) (0.455) 4001 -0.936 -0.880 -0.109 -0.373

(0.599) (0.612) (0.411) (0.454)Degree of Happiness about Schoolwork 2 -0.612 -0.186

(0.374) (0.348) 3 0.187 -0.009

(0.351) (0.348) Neither happy nor unhappy 0.197 0.164

(0.384) (0.372) 5 -0.089 0.107

(0.508) (0.473) 6 0.178 0.434

(0.669) (0.603) Completely unhappy 0.918 1.406 *

(0.667) (0.581)Importance of Schoolwork Quite a lot 0.760 *** 0.874 ***

(0.212) (0.207) Little 1.170 *** 2.350 ***

(0.382) (0.310)Note: Number in parentheses are standard error of the estimation, * p<0.05 (Wald statistic), ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001 Log likelood = -954.966 (Model I) and -790.071 (Model II)

Page 32: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

32

Surprisingly, the parameter estimates in Model II do not have big differences between

those in Model I. For the effects of variables concerning students’ socio-economical

background on educational aspiration, there is not much change in their coefficients.

The findings show that variables of students’ class background do not have much

interaction with variables of students’ satisfaction level of their schooling and their

values placed on education in the multinomial regression models. This means both of

the variables do not significantly mediate students’ class origin effects and their

school plans. There are net effects of students’ family background on students’

school plans, or other mechanisms are working. We may need to explore another

mediating variables to explain the class effects on educational aspirations.

Also, we should not overlook the results that students’ educational values have very

significant and strong effect on students’ school plans. The effects remain strong

even after controlling the variables of students’ personal characteristics and family

backgrounds. However, students’ satisfaction levels of schoolwork have only limited

effects on students’ different educational plan. There is only some effect on students’

choice between stay and leave. Compared to youth who feel completely happy in

school, students’ who feel completely unhappy are more likely to plan to leave school

after 16.

D. What job would you like to do when you have left school?

Data on students’ occupational aspirations is another important information that is

expected to bear significant relevance to the outcome of this study. As educational

attainment is one of the main determinants of occupational attainment, participation in

post-compulsory education is essential if youth aim to succeed in the labour market.

In the British Youth Panel, the question of ‘What job would you like to do after leave

school?’ is asked of the respondents from wave 4 to wave 8. There are 677

observations in the dataset. I have recoded their chosen occupations into

Goldthorpe’s seven-class scheme.

Page 33: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

33

Figure 10: School plan in terms of occupationalaspiration

0

20

40

60

80

100

don't know leave school at16

go to sixth formor college

Leave school when you are 16?

Perc

enta

ge Class I

Class IIClass III

Class IVClass V

Class VIClass VII

In figure 10, a simple distribution of school plans among different occupation

aspirational groups is presented. As expected, a high percentage of youth with higher

occupational aspirations (class I, II and III) plan to stay in school after 16. More than

90% of children who aspire to be professionals or managers plan to stay in school.

For those who like to have class II and III occupations, around 80% show purposive

preference to stay as well. These groups are least likely to plan to leave school after

16. Surprisingly, a high percentage of youth who plan to have a Class VI occupation

also plan to continue their education as well.

Risk aversion theory predicts that each individual set their aspirations and preferences

with reference to the status of their parents. It argues that every family or every

student aims to avoid downward mobility compared to their previous generation.

Therefore, understanding students’ occupational plans and aspiration is a way to set

the theoretical scene to explain differential educational choice. However, with limited

sample size, I have problems in associating youth’s occupational aspiration with their

class backgrounds, and other familial variables. Further analysis, with additional

relevant data, is needed and important. I am sure exploring relations between one’s

occupational aspirations with one’s class origin could shed light in our understanding

of students’ educational demand and choice. For example, empirical evidence shows

that gender acts as an important determinant of educational decision-making.

Although women have actually surpassed men in rates of high school completion and

Page 34: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

34

college enrolment in the past few decades, women are still disproportionately

concentrated in sectors of higher education that yield smaller income returns.

Different patterns of employment by gender, occupational sex segregation therefore

could be reflected in the occupational aspirations.

Discussion and Conclusion:

To summarize the above results, there are inherent features in the pattern of students’

school plans (their probability of stay is partly influenced by their socio-economic

background and educational value). My findings corroborate the results of previous

studies, which find that family background factors, particularly parental education,

strongly influence the post-high school choice of youths. Although the income effects

(measured in household income and household size) have no significant effect on

youth’s educational plans, it does have some influences on students’ self-assessment

of their schoolwork and their values placed on education. Moreover, parents’

educational qualifications and occupational status, which are always treated as

sources of class-based culture and values, are shown to have effects on educational

plans. They also have some impact upon students’ satisfaction level and values on

education. Children whose parents have no educational qualifications are more likely

to feel completely unhappy about their schoolwork and think doing well in school

means a little to them. At the same time, compared to children whose parents are

professionals or managers, children who have parents have class VI jobs are more

likely to feel completely unhappy about schoolwork and place low values on

education.

The results obtained in this paper indicate that post-compulsory education is

influenced to a considerable extent by an individual’s values and aspirations.

Characteristics such as educational values, and family backgrounds play an important

role in determining the school plan after compulsory level. On the other hand, self-

assessment does not play a strong influential role in students’ school plan. Except

those feel completely unhappy about schoolwork are more likely to plan to leave,

other students with various levels of satisfaction have similar possibility to have each

of different answers. Students’ self-perception on ability does not a key concern for

Page 35: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

35

them to plan to stay or leave school. In other words, whether having a higher

probability to success in later educational levels is not a main consideration in their

deciding making process.

The limited class effects which work within only certain socio-economic status

groups in the analyses also suggests that class-specific values or preferences could

only be effective to a limited extent, depending on which social class we focus on.

There are possibilities that different mechanisms are working among students with

different classes and social backgrounds that enhance responsiveness to their choice.

For example, it is found that parents’ educational attainment has an effect which

prevent students from being ambiguous about their plans. Having a clear purposively

forward looking plan in early year may encourage students to stay in school. On the

other hand, effects of parental occupational status on educational aspiration are not

direct. Compare to the base group whose parents are professionals or managers,

students from class V and class VII families tend to plan to leave school after 16,

while students from class IV and class VI families are more unlikely to have concrete

plan at age 15. Given the patterned educational preferences or plans, there are always

alternative intervening factors for different classes that mediate in between to make

sense of the result I have.

Besides, a more universal and individualistic concept on occupational aspiration may

be another possible explanation of the differences in levels of aspiration among social

classes. If each individual set their aspirations and preferences with reference to the

status of their parents, understanding students’ occupational plans and aspirations is a

way to set the theoretical scene for the explanation of differential educational choice.

Future research in this area should empirically test. In this paper, I have not

attempted to address the complexity of the process of formulating occupational

aspirations and their impact on diverse school plans and educational choice in

relations to students’ class backgrounds. The likelihood of school planning is no

doubt influenced by other potential pathways to adulthood on expectations of working

for pay. The task of assessing and modelling the complexity of youth’s choices

among different occupational aspirations is a fruitful direction for future research into

youth’s school plans and educational decisions.

Page 36: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

36

One concern not directly addressed by this paper is whether students’ school plans at

15 are highly correlated to their educational decisions at 16. That is whether

aspirations are important as determinants of future outcomes, although the general

issue has been discussed at some length by others (Manski, 1990; Dominitz and

Manski, 1997, 1999). More extensive analyses of the educational paths of the youth

in the British Panel Survey may be able to adjudicate between the intentional

variables (school plans) and actual/ observable choice (their educational attainment).

We can even further check up who or which groups of youth success or fail to live up

to their educational goals of a college education years later.

Acknowledgment:

The data from the British Household Panel Survey used in this paper were made

available through the UK Data Archive. The data were originally collected by the

ESRC Research Centre on Macro Social Change at the University of Essex. Neither

the UK Archive and nor the original collectors bear any responsibility for the further

analyses or interpretations presented here.

Page 37: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

37

References:

Becker, G. (1989) ‘On the Economics of the Family: Reply to a Skeptic’, The American Economic Review, 79(3): 514-518. Becker, G. (1996) Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education (3rd ed.). Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press. Becker, G., and Tomes, N. (1979) ‘An equilibrium theory of the distribution of income and intergenerational mobility’, Journal of Political Economy, 87(6): 1153-80. Becker, G., and Tomes, N. (1986) ‘Human capital and the rise and fall of families’, Journal of Labour Economic, 4(3): S1-39. Betts, J.R. (1994) ‘What do student know about wages?’, Journal of Human Resources, 31(1): 27-56. Bowles, S. & Gintis, H. (2000) ‘The Inheritance of Economic Status: Education, Class and Genetics’ Boudon, R. (1974) Education, Opportunity, and Social Inequality: Changing Prospects in Western Society. New York and London: John Wiley & Sons. Bourdieu, P. (1973) ‘Cultural Reproduction and Social Reproduction’, in R.K. Brown (eds.) Knowledge, Education and Cultural Change. London: Tavistock. Bourdieu, P. & Passeron, J.C. (1977) Reproduction In Education, in Society and Culture. Sage. Beverly Hills, Calif. Breen, R., and Goldthorpe, J. (1997) ‘Explaining Educational Differentials: Towards a Formal Rational Action Theory’, Rationality and Society, 9 Breen, R. (2001) ‘A Rational Choice Model of Educational Inequality’, Estudio/ Working Paper 2001/166. Doministz, J., and Manski, C.F. (1994) ‘Eliciting Student Expectations of the Returns to Schooling’, Journal of Human Resources, 31(1): 1-26. Downey, D.B. (1995) ‘When Bigger Is Not Better: Family Size, Parental Resources, and Children’s Educational Performance’, American Sociological Review 60: 746-61. Erikson, R. and Jonsson, J.O. (1996) ‘Explaining Class Inequality in Education: The Swedish Test Case’, in Can Education Be Equalized?. Boulder: Westview Press. Erikson, R., and Goldthorpe, J. (2002) ‘Intergenerational Inequality: A Sociological Perspective’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(3): 31-44.

Page 38: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

38

Gambetta, D. (1987) Were they pushed or did they jump? Cambridge University Press. Goldthorpe, J. (1996) ‘Class Analysis and the Reorientation of Class Theory: The Case of Persisting Differentials in Educational Attainment’, British Journal of Sociology, 47(3): 481-505. Halsey, A.H., Heath, A.F., and Ridge, J.M. (1980) Origins and Destinations: family, class, and education in modern Britain. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Heer, D.H. (1985) ‘The Effects of Sibling Number on Child Outcomes’, Annual Review of Sociology, 11: 27-47 Hyman, H. (1954) ‘The Value Systems of Different Classes’, in R. Bendix and S. M. Lipset (eds.), Class, Status and Power. Glencoe, Lu: Free Press. Jonsson, J. (1999) ‘Explaining Sex Differences in Educational Choice’, in European Sociological Review, 15(4): 391-404. Karlsen, U.D. (2001) ‘Some Things Never Change: Youth and Occupational Preferences’, Acta Sociologica, 44: 243-255. Manski, C.F. (1993) ‘Adolescent Econometricians: How Do Youth Infer the Returns to Schooling?’ in Clotfelter, C (ed.) Studies of Supply and Demand in Higher Education. The University of Chicago Press. Manski, C., and Wise, (1983) College Choice in America, Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press. Modesto, L. (2003) ‘Should I stay or should I go? Educational choices and earnings: An empirical study for Portugal’, Journal of Population Economics, 16:307-322 Mulligan, C. (1997) Parental Priorities and Economic Inequality, Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press. Murphy, J. (1981) ‘Class inequality in education: two justifications, one evaluation but no hard evidence’, British Journal of Sociology, 41(1): 29-54. Pierret, C. (2001) ‘The Effect of Family Structure on Youth Outcomes in the NLSY97’ in Social Awakening: Adolescent Behaviour as Adulthood Approaches by Robert T. Michael (ed.). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Piketty, T. (1998) ‘Self-fulfilling beliefs about social status’, Journal of Public Economics, 70: 115-132. Sewell, W.H., Haller, A.O., and Porters, A. (1969) ‘The educational and early occupational attainment process’, American Sociological Review, 34: 82-92.

Page 39: Social Inequality and Differential Educational Plans · 2008-06-10 · II. Social Inequality and differential educational choice The causes of inequality in educational choices have

39

Sewell, W.H., Haller, A.O., and Ohlendorf, G. (1970) ‘The education and early occupational status attain process: replication and revision’, American Journal of Sociology, 35(6): 1014-39. Sewell, W.H., Hauser, R.M. (1980) ‘The Wisconsin Longitudinal Study of Social and Psychological Factors in Aspirations and Achievements’, Rsearch in Sociology of Education and Socialization, 1: 59-99. Shavit, Y., and Blossfeld, H.P. (1993) (eds.), Persistent Inequality: Changing Educational Attainment in Thirteen Countries. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press. Sullivan, A. (2001) ‘Students as Rational Decision-Makers: The Question of Beliefs and Desires’, Working Paper Number 2001-02, Department of Sociology, University of Oxford. Willis, P. (1977) Learning to Labour, Farnborough: Saxon House. Willis, R., and Rosen, Sherwin (1979) ‘Education and Self-Selection’, Journal of Political Economy, 87(5): S7-S36.