14
SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF NAIROBI COURSE NAME: ADVANCED MICROECONIMICS THEORY 11 COURSE CODE: XET 502 LECTURER: PROF MWABU. G PRESENTED BY: MAJUNE KRAIDO SOCRATES REGISTRATION NUMBER: X50/68921/2013 CONCEPT PAPER TOPIC: THE RETURNS TO SCHOOLING IN KENYA DATE OF SUBMISSION: 9 th JUNE, 2014

The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF NAIROBI

COURSE NAME: ADVANCED MICROECONIMICS THEORY 11

COURSE CODE: XET 502

LECTURER: PROF MWABU. G

PRESENTED BY: MAJUNE KRAIDO SOCRATES

REGISTRATION NUMBER: X50/68921/2013

CONCEPT PAPER TOPIC: THE RETURNS TO SCHOOLING IN KENYA

DATE OF SUBMISSION: 9th JUNE, 2014

Page 2: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

ii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

TABLE OF CONTENTS ................................................................................................................ ii

1. INTRODUCTION ............................................................................................................... 1

1.1 Background ...................................................................................................................... 1

1.1.1. External Expenditure .................................................................................................... 1

1.1.2 Domestic Expenditure (Kenya) ................................................................................. 1

1.1.3 Household Expenditure ............................................................................................. 2

1.2 Problem Statement and Objectives .................................................................................. 2

2 LITERATURE REVIEW ........................................................................................................ 3

2.1 Theoretical Literature Review .......................................................................................... 3

2.2 Empirical Literature Review ............................................................................................ 3

3 MODEL ................................................................................................................................... 4

3.1 Conceptual Framework .................................................................................................... 4

3.2 Data .................................................................................................................................. 5

3.3 Estimation shortcomings .................................................................................................. 5

4 DATA ANALYSIS ................................................................................................................. 7

4.1 Regression results and heteroscedasticity test .................................................................. 7

4.2 Discussion of results......................................................................................................... 7

5 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION ........................................................................................ 9

5.1 Areas of further research .................................................................................................. 9

REFRENCES ................................................................................................................................ 10

APPENDIX: Summary Statistics .................................................................................................. 12

Page 3: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

1

1. INTRODUCTION

1.1 Background

Education is one of the major pillars of development often poised as a means of achieving both

social and economic benefits at individual and country level. Education is also a human right and

a foundation for development as declared by the United Nations, the reason for the push for the

adoption of Education For All (EFA) yardsticks (UNESO, 2014; Youseff, 2005). Therefore the

benefits of education can be generalized as follows; improvement of equity, acceleration of

technological change, promotion of human rights, enhancing social cohesion and reducing

poverty especially in developing countries (Fasih et al., 2012; Orodho et al., 2013). These

benefits have compelled several stakeholders at household, country and international levels to

prioritize education as shown by their expenditure levels. This study is interested in determining

the returns to these expenditures.

The next sections of this background indicate different levels of expenditures at the aforesaid

levels with an inclination to Kenya.

1.1.1. External Expenditure

Donor funding highly promotes resource allocation in education mostly in developing countries

(UNESCO, 2014)1. UNESCO (1998) shows that the World Bank alone financed about a third of

all external lending for education between 1989 and 1996. The World Bank has also been critical

in setting of international education policy agendas. However, donor funding has declined in

recent times and this trend is likely to persist over time (UNESCO, 2014). For instance, overall

education aid has decreased from $10.7 billion in 2004 to $8.3 billion in 2005 coupled with a 1%

decline from 2010 to 2011 and a further 4% decline in the 2011/2012 period (UNESCO, 2014).

1.1.2 Domestic Expenditure (Kenya)

Kenya like many developing countries has increased her commitment towards enhancing

education thereby leading to increased enrolment and government expenditure on education. The

government introduced Free Primary Education in 2003 and Free Day Secondary Education in

2008, which have led to increased enrolment mostly at Secondary level, i.e. 65% between 2001

and 2013 (ROK, 2013). Moreover, net primary enrolment rate increased to 95.3% in 2012, up

from 92.5% in 2008 (ROK, 2013). As a remedy to declining external funding, total education

expenditure as percentage of GDP has stabilized above 6% in recent years as per the analysis on

the following page but it is encouraging to note that it has been above the average of most Sub-

Saharan Africa countries.

1 Donor funding accounts for a quarter of education budgets in some countries (UNESCO, 2014).

Page 4: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

2

1.1.3 Household Expenditure

Besides government, households also account for a significant level of education expenditure

whose burden is larger in developing countries. For instance, households are responsible for 32%

of secondary education expenditure in Malawi (UNESCO, 2014) while it can be assumed that

households meet most of the remaining University expenditure in Kenya given the government

only covers 60% (ROK, 2012). According to (Mariara et al., 2007), the monthly cost of sending

a child to primary school is roughly Ksh 90 per child (with a high standard deviation) while

secondary school ranks at Ksh 277 per month with a high standard deviation of Ksh 1200.

1.2 Problem Statement and Objectives

With this in mind, the question raised in this study is whether there are returns to these huge

investments in education. Returns to education can be addressed from both a macroeconomic and

a microeconomic level. At the macro level, returns to education can be computed from the

amount of human capital that is released to the economy. Conversely, at the micro level, returns

to schooling are depicted through wages of individuals whose externalities spread to the whole

population. Education can also be viewed as a consumption good where by returns are in form of

utility to the consumer who in this case is the person bearing the burden of meeting the costs of

education.

This study seeks to estimate returns to schooling in Kenya as the main objective by addressing

the following specific objectives: seeking to estimate the effect of sex on the level of earnings in

6.1 6 6.2 6.3 6.25.3 4.8 5.7 4.3 3.8

28 2623.2

25 26.7

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

Percentage

Years

Education as % of GDP

External financing as % of Education Expenditure

Education as % of GOK Total Expenditure

Enrolment

Primary 5,941,600(2001)-10,182,600(2013)

Secondary 763,245(2001)-2,104,262(2013)

University 203,566(2006)-324,560(2013)

Number of Universities has escalated by 27%

between 2006 and 2013 (24-33)

Total public expenditure on education as a percentage of

GNP was 6% in 2007 above the average for Sub-Saharan

countries in 2011 i.e. 5.0% with a 6.7% share of

Education on GDP in 2011

Figure 1: Domestic and External expenditure on education Table 1: Enrolment

Source: UNESCO, 2014; ROK, 2012; KIPPRA, 2010; and authors’ calculations

Page 5: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

3

Kenya which will offer great insights in meeting Millennium Development Goals. In addition

this study will also seek to analyze the effect of experience on private remuneration in Kenya.

2 LITERATURE REVIEW

This section reviews studies in and outside Kenya alongside theories on returns to schooling.

2.1 Theoretical Literature Review

The human capital theory is based on the principle that expected future gains on earnings

determine an individual’s current investment in education. Thus, Investment in education

continues until marginal cost equals marginal return to education (Walker et al., 2001). Equally,

schools are taken as a good platform for acquiring relevant labour market skills at the expense of

foregone earnings from the time spent in schools (Wambugu, 2003). Nevertheless, a detailed

analysis of this theory will be discussed in the next chapter when the Mincer (1974) model is

reviewed.

Besides the human capital theory, signaling theory is also a vital explanation of returns to

schooling. This theory by Michael Spence views schooling level as an indication of someone’s

innate ability which employers consider in hiring labour and not necessarily skills (Frazis, 2002).

Therefore, individuals are compelled to seek education for perception that it creates.

2.2 Empirical Literature Review

Several studies have established that education positively impacts an individual’s future

earnings. For instance Krueger and Lindahl (2000) note that an additional year of schooling

increases earnings by 10% in the US with 13% in Sub-Saharan Africa (UNESCO, 2014). This is

certainly in line with the initial projections of 5% in developed countries and 29 % in developing

countries (Psacharopoulos, 1994)2. However, empirical evidence shows that not all countries

have met this standard. For instance, Oyelere (2010) found that that the average returns to

education in Nigeria was only 2.8 %. Similar Chirwa and Matita (2009) found that an additional

year of schooling increases life time earnings by 10% in Malawi, with more benefits accruing to

women than me, 11.4% and 9.7% respectively.

Studies on returns to schooling in Kenya resonate with most findings from other places. Kimenyi

et al. (2006) while analyzing private returns and human capital externalities in Kenya found that

returns were higher among females than males. This was supported by a study by Mariara and

Mwabu (2007) which concurred that girls had a high education affection ratio than boys using

household survey data. Wambugu (2003) further notes that all levels of education reduce chances

of agricultural employment while higher education levels are skewed to formal employment and

vice versa for lower education levels.

2 Primary education has highest returns in developing countries while tertiary education has high returns in

developed countries (Fasih et al., 2012)

Page 6: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

4

This study adds to this pool of knowledge by reviewing returns to schooling with a major

emphasis of sex and experience on remuneration.

3 MODEL

3.1 Conceptual Framework This study formulates the basic earning function based on Mincer (1974) which estimates a semi-

log ordinary square regression with the natural logarithm of earnings as the dependent variable.

Independent variables include years of schooling, potential years of labour market experience

and its square. This can formally be shown in the following equation:

ln 𝑊 = 𝑎 + 𝑏1𝑆 + 𝑏2𝐸 + 𝑏3𝐸2 + 𝜀 (1)

Where ln 𝑊 is the natural logarithm of earnings, S is individual’s years of schooling or different

levels of schooling, E is work experience which is age minus years of schooling, 𝐸2 is square of

work experience, 𝑎, 𝑏1, 𝑏2 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑏3 are a constant and coefficients to be estimated respectively

with 𝜀 as the error term. Work experience is squared to capture the declining effects of

experience as an individual ages (Kifle, 2007).

This model can further be modified to include control variables like area of residence, gender

and dummies as follows:

𝑙𝑛(𝑊𝑗) = 𝑎 + ∑ 𝑏𝑘 𝑆𝑗𝑘 + 𝛾𝐴𝑗+∝ 𝑍𝑗 + 𝜀𝑗 (2)

Where W is the hourly earnings for worker j (used hourly wages other than monthly earnings to

avoid labour supply effects on returns), 𝑆𝑘 is a dummy variable for being educated at least up to

level k, A is the experience variable, Z is a vector of j control variables such as gender and area

of residence, α,b, 𝛾 and ∝ are parameters to be estimated, and 𝜀 is the error term.

Using the analysis of Heckman et al. (2003), equation 2 can be derived from Mincer’s

assumption that potential earnings today (at time t i.e.𝐸𝑡) depends on investment in human

capital made yesterday. Hence, an individual invests in human capital a share 𝑘𝑡 of his/her

potential earnings with a return of 𝑟𝑡 in each period t.

𝐸𝑡+1 = 𝐸𝑡 (1 + 𝑟𝑡𝑘𝑡) which with repeated substitution yields 𝐸𝑡 = ∏ (1 + 𝑟𝑗𝑘𝑗)𝐸0𝑡−1𝑗=0 or

basically ln 𝐸𝑡 = ln 𝐸0 + ∑ ln (1 +𝑡−1𝑗=0 𝑟𝑗𝑘𝑗).

This specification postulates that schooling is based on the number of years spent in full-time

investment (𝑘𝑡=1), the return to post-schooling investment in terms of potential earnings is

constant over time, the return to formal schooling in terms of potential earnings is also constant

over time and that formal schooling takes place at the beginning of life. This study objects this

Page 7: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

5

last assumption since there is no schooling between the ages of 0 to 6 in Kenya according to the

current regulations unless it is Early Childhood Education which is ages 4-5 (ROK, 2012).

To establish a relationship between potential earnings and years of labor market experience,

Mincer (1974) approximated the Ben Porath (1967) model besides assuming a linearly declining

rate of post-school investment which in turn gives ln 𝑊(𝑠, 𝑥) ≈ 𝑙𝑛𝐸𝑥+𝑠 − 𝐾 (1 −𝑥

𝑇) where 𝑥 =

𝑡 − 𝑠 ≥ 0 is the amount of work experience as at age t. T is the length of working life and it is

assumed to be independent of years of schooling. It is from this that the model in Equation 1 is

found.

To fulfill the objective of finding returns to education, the following equation can be used as

suggested by (Amin et al., 2005);

Rate of Return to Education= 𝑒𝑥𝑝(𝜏𝑖−𝜏ℎ)

𝐷𝑖−𝐷ℎ -1 (3)

With 𝜏𝑖 being the estimated coefficient of a higher level of education; 𝜏ℎ is the estimated

coefficient of a lower level of schooling; 𝐷𝑖 is the total number of years taken to attain a

particular level of higher education while 𝐷ℎ is the total number of years spent schooling at a

lower level of the education system.

Nevertheless, it is significant to note that both years of education and schooling are expected to

contribute to high earnings given that they foster skill acquisition and there by enhance

productivity. Education squared is expected to affect incomes negatively because it is expected

that as one ages their earnings reduce.

3.2 Data

This study uses cross-sectional from the Kenya Integrated Household Budget Survey of

2005/2006 which was collected among 13,430 households (8,610 rural and 4,820 urban) for a

period of 12 months in 70 Districts in Kenya.

Heteroscedasticity (unequal variance) is tested to avoid any wrong inference on the estimated

coefficients (Gujarati, 2004)3.

3.3 Estimation shortcomings

It is important to note that due to data limitation, this study fails to account for omitted variables

and endogeneity of schooling:

i. Omitted variables; These basically include unobservable characteristics such as ability and

family background whose omission can give biased OLS estimates (Kimenyi et al., 2006).

Several studies have diversified and included additional variables in their analysis of returns

to education which has given better results. For example, Wambugu (2003) included parent’s

3 Heteroscedasticity is prevalent in cross-sectional data (Gujarati, 2004).

Page 8: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

6

education and income to depict family background and found out that the two variables had a

positive impact on wages and that returns to education decline when family background

variables are included in the earnings regressions.

ii. Endogeneity of schooling; By treating schooling as exogenous implies that investment in

schooling is independent of earnings which should be the contrary. Accounting for

endogeneity in schooling means that an individual takes into account expected earnings in

making the decision to invest in education (Kimenyi et al., 2006).Two remedies can be

suggested i.e. constructing a ‘selectivity-correction’ term from a schooling attainment

equation and then including the correction term in the earnings equation or using exogenous

variation in educational attainment (such as differences in educational attainment across

siblings) to provide instrumental variable (IV) estimates of returns to education (Kimenyi et

al, 2006).

Page 9: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

7

4 DATA ANALYSIS

This section contains regression results as per equation (2) and a test for heterogeneity.

4.1 Regression results and heteroscedasticity test4

Running a regression on equation (2) gives the following results: Where natural logarithm of

earnings is the dependent variable with years of education, working experience (age minus 6

minus years of schooling), working experience squared and, sex (where 1=female, 0=male) are

the respective independent variables.

Log wage coefficient std. error t-ratio P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Years of

education

0.0427027 0.0368713 1.16 0.247 -0.0296867 0.1150921

Experience 0.0057483 0.0054169 1.06 0.289 -0.0048868 0.0163834

Experience

squared

-0.0000434 0.0001001 -0.43 0.665 -0.00024 0.0001533

Sex -0.2940651 0.1034785 -2.84 0.005 -0.4972245 -0.0909056

Constant 4.75398 0.2253118 21.10 0.000 4.311625 5.196335

Number of observations=712 F(4,712)=2.89 R-squared=0.0160 Adj R-squared=0.0105

Breusch-Pagan test for heteroscedasticity

Null hypothesis: heteroscedasticity not present

Test statistic: LM = 13.1061,

with p-value = P(Chi-square(4) > 13.1061) = 0.0107688

Critical Chi-square value (at 1%)= 13.2767

t-critical (n=712)=1.96

F-critical (4,707,0.05)= 2.38453

4.2 Discussion of results

From the Breusch-Pagan test results in Table 2, the calculated value is lower than the critical

value which indicates that we accept our null hypothesis and conclude that homoscedasticity

exists. This means that we can credibly make inferences from the regression results.

The regression results linked to equation (2) yields the following results:

log 𝑤𝑎𝑔𝑒 = 4.75398 + 0.0427027𝑌𝑒𝑎𝑟𝑠 𝑜𝑓 𝑒𝑑 + 0.0057483 Experience −

0.0000434 Experience Squared − 0.2940651𝑆𝑒𝑥 + 𝜀 (4)

With t-statistic values ranging from 21.10, 1.16, 1.06, -0.43 and -2.84 respectively. Therefore, it

can be noted that:

Both experience and years of schooling boost earnings by 0.6% and 4.27% respectively for an

additional year of schooling and an additional year of experience. Hence, workers pursue higher

4 The Breusch- Pagan test was used to detect heteroscedasticity. It follows a Chi-Square distribution where the

calculated and critical values are compared. If the calculated value is greater than the critical value, we reject the

null hypothesis and conclude that there is heteroscedasticity. Homoscedasticity only exists where the calculated

value is less than the ctitical value (Gujarati, 2004).

Table 2: Regression results & Breusch-Pagan test results

Page 10: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

8

incomes when they have been educated and at the same time accumulate skills which results in

improved output leading to higher remuneration. However, they are both insignificant at 5%

level because there t-calculated values are below the t-critical value of 1.96. Sex is a significant

determinant of earnings with female workers earning less by about 30%. This could be attributed

to the notion that women are still perceived in a low status because studies such as (Kimenyi et

al., 2006) used a male dummy and found out a positive relationship.

The F test shows that our model is significant at 5% level because the calculated value is greater

than the critical value. There is need to include more explanatory variables in the model because

the current explanatory variables only explain 1.6% of variations in wages according to the R-

squared value.

Page 11: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

9

5 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION

From the analysis of returns to schooling depicted through earnings, this study has shown the

importance of considering sex in determining levels of earning. Even though the female

coefficient was negative, indicating declined earnings, there is still a need to promote education

of females. This will not only promote gender equality but also female empowerment. The

positive impact of years of schooling and experience indicates the importance of both in

fostering personal development.

However, it can generally be noted that perhaps better results5 would have been obtained had the

study solved the two estimation problems, omission of variables and endogeneity of schooling.

5.1 Areas for further research There is need to expound on this topic of returns to education by considering a rural set-up of a

developing country where in most cases land or cattle6 is sold to finance education. Two critical

points arise from this: (1) whether this inter-temporal investment is worthwhile because the

recipients of this education work towards buying inter alia land or cattle that was used to fund

their studies in future. (2) The first puzzle begs the question whether there is need to seek

alternative ways of financing education in a rural set-up other than merely relying on the stated

assets.

5 As seen, the R-Squared value is too low, only 1.6%. 6 Other household assets are also sold.

Page 12: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

10

REFRENCES

Amin, A.A., & Awung, J.W. (2005). Economic Analysis of Private Returns to Investment in

Education in Cameroon. African Institute for Economic Development and Planning, 1-16.

Chirwa, W.E., & Matita. M.M (2009). The Rate of Return on Education in Malawi. Department

of Economics University of Malawi, Working Paper No. 2009/01.

Frazis, H. (2002). Human Capital, Signaling, and the Pattern of Returns to Education. Oxford

Economic Papers, Vol. 54, No. 2, 298-309.

Gujarati, D.N. (2004).Basic Econometrics (4th Edition). New York, USA: The McGraw-Hill

Companies.

Kifle, T. (2007). The Private Rate of Return to Schooling: Evidence from Eritrea. Essays in

Education, Vol. 21, 83.

Kimenyi, S.M, Mwabu, G., & Manda, D.K. (2006). Human Capital Externalities and Private

Returns to Education in Kenya. Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 32, No. 3, 493-513.

Kenya Institute of Public Policy Research and Analysis. (2010). Kenya Economic Report 2010:

Enhancing Sectoral Contribution towards reducing poverty, unemployment and inequality in

Kenya. Nairobi, Kenya: KIPPRA.

Krueger, A.B., & Lindahl, M. (2001). Education for Growth: Why and For Whom? Journal of

Economic Literature, Vol. 39, No.4, 1101–1136.

Mariara, J.K., & Mwabu, D.K. (2007). Determinants of School Enrolment and Education

attainment: Empirical evidence from Kenya. South African Journal of Economics, Vol. 75, No.3,

572-593.

Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, Experience and Earnings. New York, National Bureau of

Economic Research.

Republic of Kenya. (2012). Towards a globally competitive quality education for sustainable

development. Government Printer.

Republic of Kenya. (2013). Vision 2030 Second Medium Term Plan, 2013 – 2017. Government

Printer.

Orodho, J.O., Waweru, P.N, Ndichu, M., & Nthinguri, R. (2013). Basic Education in Kenya:

Focus on Strategies Applied to Cope with School-based Challenges Inhibiting Effective

Implementation of Curriculum. International Journal of Education and Research, Vol. 1, No.11,

1-20.

Page 13: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

11

Oyelere, R. U. (2010). Africa's education enigma? The Nigerian story. Journal of Development

Economics, Vol. 91, No.1, 128-139.

Psacharopoulos, G. (1994). Returns to Investments in Education: A Global Update. World

Development, Vol. 22, No. 9, 1325–1343.

UNESCO. (2014). Teaching and Learning: Achieving quality for all (First edition). Paris,

France, United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization.

Wambugu, A. (2003). Essays on earnings and human capital in Kenya (PhD Thesis). Goteborg

University, Gothenburg, Sweden.

Youssef, C. (2005). World Bank priorities in education lending: An ever-changing

endeavor. Paterson Review, Vol. 6, 1-29.

Page 14: The Returns to Schooling in Kenya

12

APPENDIX: SUMMARY STATISTICS

Variable Mean Median Minimum Maximum

log wage 4.90451 4.60517 0.000000 10.2036

Experience 10.5270 6.00000 -21.0000 90.0000

Experience

Squared

461.464 81.0000 0.000000 8100.00

age 22.1716 17.0000 0.000000 99.0000

sex 0.493338 0.000000 0.000000 1.00000

years_ed 5.66071 5.00000 2.00000 15.0000

Variable Std. Dev. C.V. Skewness Ex. Kurtosis

Log wage 1.36929 0.279190 1.12295 2.42045

Experience 18.7257 1.77882 1.20886 1.28860

Experience

Squared

945.528 2.04898 3.65492 16.8101

age 18.5964 0.838748 1.21117 1.27432

sex 0.499959 1.01342 0.0266490 -1.99929

years_ed 1.38857 0.245299 2.48990 10.9230