38
Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Unit III- Market Structure

Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Page 2: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Theory of FirmTheory of FirmThe theory of the firm consists of a number of economic theories which describe the nature of the firm, company, or corporation, including its existence, its behaviour, and its relationship with the market.

In simplified terms, the theory of firm aims to answer these questions:1.Existence - why do firms emerge, why are not all transactions in the economy mediated over the market? 2.Boundaries - why the boundary between firms and the market is located exactly there? Which transactions are performed internally and which are negotiated on the market? 3.Organization - why are firms structured in such specific way? What is the interplay of formal and informal relationships?

These questions are not answered by the established economic theory, which usually views firms as given, and treats them as black boxes without any internal structure.

Page 3: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Nature of a Market• To determine structure of any particular market, we begin by

asking – How many buyers and sellers are there in the market?– Is each seller offering a standardized product, more or less

indistinguishable from that offered by other sellers• Or are there significant differences between the

products of different firms?– Are there any barriers to entry or exit, or can outsiders

easily enter and leave this market?• Answers to these questions help us to classify a market into

one of four basic types– Perfect competition– Monopoly– Monopolistic– Oligopoly

Page 4: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Perfect Competition: The Three Requirements

• Large numbers of buyers and sellers, and – Each buys or sells only a tiny fraction of the total quantity in the

market– Sellers offer a standardized product– Sellers can easily enter into or exit from market

Page 5: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

A Large Number of Buyers and Sellers

• In perfect competition, there must be many buyers and sellers– How many?

• Number must be so large that no individual decision maker can significantly affect price of the product by changing quantity it buys or sells

Page 6: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

A Standardized Product Offered by Sellers

• Buyers do not perceive significant differences between products of one seller and another– For instance, buyers of wheat do not prefer one farmer’s wheat

over another

Page 7: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Easy Entry into and Exit from the Market

• Entry into a market is rarely free—a new seller must always incur some costs to set up shop, begin production, and establish contacts with customers– But perfectly competitive market has no significant barriers to

discourage new entrants• Any firm wishing to enter can do business on the same

terms as firms that are already there• In many markets there are significant barriers to entry

– Legal barriers– Existing sellers have an important advantage that new entrants

can not duplicate• Brand loyalty enjoyed by existing producers would require a

new entrant to wrest customers away from existing firms– Significant economies of scale may give existing firms a cost

advantage over new entrants

Page 8: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Easy Entry into and Exit from the Market

• Perfect competition is also characterized by easy exit– A firm suffering a long-run loss must be able to sell off its plant

and equipment and leave the industry for good, without obstacles

• Significant barriers to entry and exit can completely change the environment in which trading takes place

Page 9: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Is Perfect Competition Realistic? Assumptions market must satisfy to be perfectly competitive are

rather restrictive In vast majority of markets, one or more of assumptions of perfect

competition will, in a strict sense, be violated Yet when economists look at real-world markets, they use

perfect competition more often than any other market structure

Why is this? Model of perfect competition is powerful Many markets—while not strictly perfectly competitive—come

reasonably close We can even—with some caution—use model to analyze markets

that violate all three assumptions

Page 10: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Figure 1: The Competitive Industry and Firm

Ounces of Gold per Day

Price per Ounce

D

$400

S

Market

Demand Curve Facing

the Firm

$400

Firm

1. The intersection of the market supply and the market demand curve…

3. The typical firm can sell all it wants at the market price…

Ounces of Gold per Day

Price per Ounce

2. determine the equilibrium market price

4. so it faces a horizontal demand curve

Page 11: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Goals and Constraints of the Competitive Firm

• Perfectly competitive firm faces a cost constraint like any other firm

• Cost of producing any given level of output depends on – Firm’s production technology – Prices it must pay for its inputs

Page 12: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

The Demand Curve Facing a Perfectly Competitive Firm

• Panel (b) of Figure 1 shows demand curve facing Firm– Notice special shape of this curve

• It’s horizontal, or infinitely price elastic• Why should this be?

– In perfect competition output is standardized– No matter how much a firm decides to produce, it cannot

make a noticeable difference in market quantity supplied • So cannot affect market price

Page 13: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

The Demand Curve Facing a Perfectly Competitive Firm

• Means firm has no control over the price of its output– Simply accepts market price as given

• In perfect competition, firm is a price taker– Treats the price of its output as given and beyond

its control• Since a competitive firm takes the market price as given

– Its only decision is how much output to produce and sell

Page 14: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Cost and Revenue Data for a Competitive Firm

• For a competitive firm, marginal revenue at each quantity is the same as the market price

• For this reason, marginal revenue curve and demand curve facing firm are the same– A horizontal line at the market price

Page 15: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Figure 2(a): Profit Maximization in Perfect Competition

TR

550

$2,800

2,100

TC

Slope = 400

Ounces of Gold per Day

Dollars

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Maximum Profit per Day = $700

Page 16: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Figure 2(b): Profit Maximization in Perfect Competition

MC

$400 D = MR

Ounces of Gold per Day

Dollars

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Page 17: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

The Total Revenue and Total Cost Approach

• Most direct way of viewing firm’s search for the profit-maximizing output level

• At each output level, subtract total cost from total revenue to get total profit at that output level– Total Profit = TR - TC

Page 18: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

The Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost Approach

• Firm should continue to increase output as long as marginal revenue > marginal cost

• Remember that profit-maximizing output is found where MC curve crosses MR curve from below

• Finding the profit-maximizing output level for a competitive firm requires no new concepts or techniques

Page 19: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Measuring Total Profit Start with firm’s profit per unit

Revenue it gets on each unit minus cost per unit Revenue per unit is the price (P) of the firm’s output, and cost

per unit is our familiar ATC, so we can write Profit per unit = P – ATC

Firm earns a profit whenever P > ATC Its total profit at the best output level equals area of a rectangle

with height equal to distance between P and ATC, and width equal to level of output

A firm suffers a loss whenever P < ATC at the best level of output Its total loss equals area of a rectangle

Height equals distance between P and ATC Width equals level of output

Page 20: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Figure 3(a): Measuring Profit or Loss

$400300

Profit per Ounce ($100)

d = MR

MC

ATC

Economic Profit

Ounces of Gold per Day

Dollars

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Page 21: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Figure 3(a): Measuring Profit or Loss

MC

ATC

d = MR$300

200

Loss per Ounce ($100)

Economic Loss

Ounces of Gold per Day

Dollars

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Page 22: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

The Firm’s Short-Run Supply Curve A competitive firm is a price taker

Takes market price as given and then decides how much output it will produce at that price

Profit-maximizing output level is always found by traveling from the price, across to the firm’s MC curve, and then down to the horizontal axis, or As price of output changes, firm will slide along its MC

curve in deciding how much to produce

Page 23: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Figure 4: Short-Run Supply Under Perfect Competition

0.50

1,0002,000

4,0005,000

7,000

1.00

2.00

$3.50

2.50

MCATC

d1=MR1

AVC

(a)

Firm's Supply Curve

0.50

2,0004,000

5,000

7,000

1.00

2.00

$3.50

2.50

(b)

d2=MR2

d3=MR3

d4=MR4

d5=MR5

Bushels per Year

Dollars Price per Bushel

Bushels per Year

Page 24: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

The Shutdown Price• Price at which a firm is indifferent between producing and shutting

down• Can summarize all of this information in a single curve—firm’s

supply curve– Tells us how much output the firm will produce at any price

• Supply curve has two parts– For all prices above minimum point on its AVC curve, supply

curve coincides with MC curve– For all prices below minimum point on AVC curve, firm will

shut down• So its supply curve is a vertical line segment at zero units of

output• For all prices below $1—the shutdown price—output is zero and

the supply curve coincides with vertical axis

Page 25: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Short-Run Equilibrium

• How does a perfectly competitive market achieve equilibrium?– In perfect competition, market sums buying and selling

preferences of all the individual consumers and producers, and determines market price

– Each buyer and seller then takes market price as given– Each is able to buy or sell desired quantity

• Competitive firms can earn an economic profit or suffer an economic loss

Page 26: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Figure 6 Perfect Competition

Quantity Demanded at

Different Prices

Quantity Supplied at

Different Prices

Quantity Supplied by Each Firm

Quantity Demanded by

Each Consumer

Individual Demand

Curve

Individual Supply Curve

Quantity Demanded by All Consumers at

Different Prices

Quantity Supplied by All Firms at Different

Prices

Market Demand

Curve

Market Supply Curve

P S

D

Q

Market Equilibrium

Added together Added together

Page 27: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Figure 7: Short-Run Equilibrium in Perfect Competition

400,000 700,000

2.00

$3.50

S

D1

D2

MC

d1

d2

ATC

7,0004,000

2.00

$3.50

3. If the demand curve shifts to D2 and the market equilibrium moves here . . .

4. the typical firm operates here and suffers a short-run loss.

2. the typical firm operates here, earning economic profit in the short run.

1. When the demand curve is D1 and market equilibrium is here . . .

Profit per Bushel at p = $3.50

Price per Bushel

Market

Bushels per Year

DollarsFirm

Bushels per Year

Loss per Bushel at p = $2

Page 28: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Profit and Loss and the Long Run In a competitive market, economic profit and loss are the forces

driving long-run change Expectation of continued economic profit (losses) causes

outsiders (insiders) to enter (exit) the market In real world entry and exit occur literally every day

In some cases, we see entry occur through formation of an entirely new firm

Entry can also occur when an existing firm adds a new product to its line

Exit can occur in different ways Firm may go out of business entirely, selling off its assets and

freeing itself once and for all from all costs Firm switches out of a particular product line, even as it

continues to produce other things

Page 29: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

From Short-Run Profit to Long-Run Equilibrium

• As we enter long-run, much will change– Economic profit will attract new entrants

• Increasing number of firms in market– As number of firms increases, market supply curve

will shift rightward causing several things to happen

» Market price begins to fall» As market price falls, demand caurve facing

each firm shifts downward» Each firm—striving as always to maximize

profit—will slide down its marginal cost curve, decreasing output

Page 30: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

From Short-Run Profit to Long-Run Equilibrium

• This process of adjustment—in the market and the firm—continues until…well, until when?– When the reason for entry—positive profit—no longer

exits– Requires market supply curve to shift rightward enough,

and the price to fall enough• So that each existing firm is earning zero economic

profit• In a competitive market, positive economic profit continues

to attract new entrants until economic profit is reduced to zero

Page 31: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Figure 8(a/b): From Short-Run Profit To Long-Run Equilibrium

S1

d1ATC

MC

$4.50

With initial supply curve S1, market price is $4.50…

$4.50

900,000 9,000

So each firm earns an economic profit.

AA

Price per Bushel

Market

Bushels per Year

Dollars

Firm

Bushels per Year

D

Page 32: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Figure 8(c/d): From Short-Run Profit To Long-Run Equilibrium

S1

d1ATC

MC

$4.50

Profit attracts entry, shifting the supply curve rightward…

$4.50

900,000 9,0005,000

until market price falls to $2.50 and each firm earns zero economic profit.

S2

d1

AA

2.502.50EE

Market Firm

Price per Bushel

Bushels per Year

Dollars

Bushels per Year

D

1,200,000

Page 33: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

From Short-Run Loss to Long-Run Equilibrium

• What if we begin from a position of loss?– Same type of adjustments will occur, only in the opposite

direction• In a competitive market, economic losses continue to cause

exit until losses are reduced to zero• When there are no significant barriers to exit

– Economic loss will eventually drive firms from the industry• Raising market price until typical firm breaks even

again

Page 34: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Distinguishing Short-Run from Long-Run Outcomes

• In short-run equilibrium, competitive firms can earn profits or suffer losses– In long-run equilibrium, after entry or exit has occurred,

economic profit is always zero• When economists look at a market, they automatically think of

short-run versus long-run– Choose the period more appropriate for the question at

hand• Basic Principle #7: Short-Run versus Long-Run Outcomes

– Markets behave differently in the short-run and the long run– In solving a problem, we must always know which of these

time horizons we are analyzing

Page 35: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

The Notion of Zero Profit in Perfect Competition

• We have not yet discussed plant size of competitive firm• The same forces—entry and exit—that cause all firms to earn

zero economic profit also ensure– In long-run equilibrium, every competitive firm will select

its plant size and output level so that it operates at minimum point of its LRATC curve

Page 36: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Perfect Competition and Plant Size Figure 9(a) illustrates a firm in a perfectly competitive market

But panel (a) does not show a true long-run equilibrium How do we know this?

In long-run typical firm will want to expand Why?

Because by increasing its plant size, it could slide down its LRATC curve and produce more output at a lower cost per unit

By expanding firm could potentially earn an economic profit Same opportunity to earn positive economic profit will attract new

entrants that will establish larger plants from the outset Entry and expansion must continue in this market until the price falls to

P* Because only then will each firm—doing the best that it can do—earn

zero economic profit

Page 37: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

Figure 9: Perfect Competition and Plant Size

P1

q1

d1 = MR1

LRATCMC1 ATC1

E

d2 = MR2

LRATC

MC2 ATC2

P*

q*4. and all firms earn zero economic profit and produce at minimum LRATC.

.

Dollars Dollars

Output per Period

Output per Period

3. As all firms increase plant size and output, market price falls to its lowest possible level . . .

1. With its current plant and ATC curve, this firm earns zero economic profit.

2. The firm could earn positive profit with a larger plant, producing here.

Page 38: Unit III- Market Structure Dr. R. Jayaraj, M.A., Ph.D., UPES

A Summary of the Competitive Firm in the Long-Run

• Can put it all together with a very simple statement– At each competitive firm in long-run equilibrium

• P = MC = minimum ATC = minimum LRATC• In figure 9(b), this equality is satisfied when the typical firm

produces at point E– Where its demand, marginal cost, ATC, and LRATC curves

all intersect• In perfect competition, consumers are getting the best deal

they could possibly get