57
Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh National Chengchi University, Taiwan and Ming-Hua Hsieh National Chengchi University, Taiwan Seminar on Department of Financial and Computational Mathematics Providence University 8 November, 2011 1

Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

  • Upload
    vutuyen

  • View
    218

  • Download
    2

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swapsby

Hidetoshi Nakagawa

Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo

and

Meng-Lan Yueh

National Chengchi University, Taiwan

and

Ming-Hua Hsieh

National Chengchi University, Taiwan

Seminar on Department of Financial and Computational Mathematics

Providence University

8 November, 2011

1

Page 2: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Agenda

• Introduction of CDS/CMCDS

• Pricing of Credit Default Swaps (CDS)

• Pricing of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps (CMCDS)

• Determination of Participation Rate

• Examples

• Conclusions

2

Page 3: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Introduction of CDS

• Constant maturity credit default swaps (CMCDS) are a new kind of credit

derivative that provides a natural extension to vanilla credit default swaps

(CDS).

• A vanilla credit default swap (CDS) is a contract that provides insurance

against the default risk of an underlying entity. A CDS contract has a fixed

premium leg and a contingent default leg.

– The fixed premium leg corresponds to the periodic payments made by the

protection buyer to the seller until the maturity of the CDS or until the

occurrence of a credit event.

– The default leg corresponds to the net payment made by the protection

seller to the buyer in case of default.

• The fair spread for CDS is determined by equating the discounted cash flows

of these two legs.

3

Page 4: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

ProtectionBuyer ProtectionSeller

ReferenceAsset

Periodic Fees

Payment

Contingent on

Default

Synthetic exposure

-

6 3

4

Page 5: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Introduction of CMCDS

• The premium leg of a CDS has fixed premium payments, however, the

premium leg of a CMCDS is floating and reset periodically.

• The premium payment is linked to a pre-specified benchmark of a fixed

maturity (called”constant maturity”) CDS rate, e.g. the current 5-year CDS of

a particular reference entity.

• CMCDS can be seen as floating premium CDS contracts.

5

Page 6: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Premium Legs of CDS

6

Page 7: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Premium Legs of CMCDS

7

Page 8: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

CMCDS v.s CMS (Constant Maturity Interest Rate

Swaps)

• CMCDS is an extension of CMS in the area of credit market.

• In the fixed-income markets, constant maturity swap (CMS) was originally

used by insurance companies and pension funds to hedge their constant

maturity liabilities.

• Rates with constant maturity features generally facilitate the trading of pure

interest rate instruments for a selected maturity, without reducing time to

maturity associated with physical bonds.

• CMS allow investors to take positions on the forward interest rates between

two nominated CMS rates.

8

Page 9: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Strategy Involving CMCDS

• CMCDS transactions are receiving increasing attentions because they allow

investors to take a view on future credit spreads.

• The strategy of combining a CMCDS with an opposite position in a vanilla

CDS provides a means to separate spread risk from default risk.

• The resulting net position is a floating-fixed premium swap, which enables

investors to take exposure to only credit spread risk. In this way, a CMCDS

becomes a pure synthetic contract used for expressing a view on spread

widening or narrowing.

• Curve steepening benefits CMCDS protection sellers.

• Curve flattening benefits CMCDS protection buyers.

9

Page 10: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Nomura Fixed Income Research

(5)

Illustration of Fixed vs. Floating Premium

0 15

432

The "Fixed Leg" (Regular CDS)

The "Contingent Leg"

Year

Credit Event!

0 15

432

The "Floating Leg" (CMCDS)

The "Contingent Leg"

Year

Credit Event!

0 15

432

The "Fixed Leg" (Regular CDS)

The "Contingent Leg"

Year

Credit Event!

0 15

432

The "Floating Leg" (CMCDS)

The "Contingent Leg"

Year

Credit Event!

Source: Nomura

The market value of a CDS fluctuates as the default risk of the reference entity changes. The current level of default risk for a reference entity is reflected in the market spread. Accordingly, the value of an outstanding fixed-spread CDS changes with the market spread of the same maturity. For instance, if the market spread widens, the protection seller of the outstanding fixed-spread CDS contract suffers a mark-to-market loss, because the spread payment he receives is no longer enough to compensate for the amount of default risk implied in the market spread. On the other hand, if the spread tightens, the protection seller would benefit, because he continues to receive the fixed premium which is now greater than the market level. In contrast, movements in general spread levels little affect the value of a CMCDS, since the spread is periodically reset in sync with the market level.

Unlike an ordinary CDS, however, a CMCDS is sensitive to the shape of the spread curve. As discussed above, the gearing factor of a CMCDS is determined based on the expected levels of future spreads of the reference CDS, as reflected in the forward spreads. An upward-sloping spread curve implies that the reference CDS spread is likely to widen in the future. If that happens, the CMCDS spread will also increase. Therefore, the gearing factor, g, for the CMCDS is low when the spread curve is upward sloping and steep. If the spread curve gets steeper after the gearing factor is set, it will benefit the protection seller of a CMCDS (i.e., investor), because the breakeven level of g declines. The opposite is true when the spread curve gets flatter.

We can gain an exposure to just spread risk, but not default risk, by combining a fixed-spread CDS and a CMCDS. The combined position is sometimes called a “credit spread swap.” This in a sense is closer to the original definition of a “swap,” where two parties exchange series of floating payments and fixed payments.

A. Risk Profile

As mentioned above, the value of a CMCDS is much less sensitive to spread movements than an ordinary CDS. For example, the value of a CMCDS is virtually unchanged when the overall spread level widens by 1 basis point, while a 5-year fixed-spread CDS would see its value drop by nearly 5 bps. Graph 1 compares the value changes of a CMCDS and a regular CDS as we shift the spread curve in a parallel manner, assuming a notional value of $10 million and a flat spread curve of 100 bps initially. As we can see in Graph 1, the value of a regular CDS declines as the spread increases. In contrast, the value of a CMCDS is not very sensitive to changes in overall spread levels.

Page 11: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Price Quotes of CMCDS

• Since a vanilla CDS and a CMCDS provide the same protection against the

credit event of a same reference entity, no arbitrage principle thus implies that

the present value of the floating premium leg of a CMCDS must equal to the

present value of the CDS fixed premium leg.

• The equivalence is achieved by expressing the floating premium in a CMCDS

as a percentage of the reference fixed maturity CDS spread.

• The percentage is called the “participation rate”. The participation rate is the

multiplication factor that equates the expected discounted cash flow of

premium leg on a CMCDS with that of an equivalent CDS.

• CMCDS prices are quoted in terms of the participation rate.

10

Page 12: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

16 March 2004 CMCDS: The Path to Floating Credit Spread Products Deutsche Bank@

Global Markets Research 5

Exhibit 3: Comparative Spreads for Traditional versus Constant Maturity

CDS structures (indicative levels as of 14 March 2004)

Single Name CMCDS

Reference Credit 5-Yr CDS

Mid Spread (bp)

5Yx5Y CMCDS Bid

Participation Rate (%)

Deutsche Telekom AG 60 65 France Telecom S.A. 60 64 Telecom Italia SpA 73 66 GMAC 185 78 Ford Motor Co. 219 77 Peugeot S.A. 49 71 Renault S.A. 50 74

CMCDO tranches

5Yx5Y CMCDO

Participation Rate (%) Reference Credit

5-Yr CDO

Tranche

Spread (bp)

Expected

S&P Rating Uncapped

Capped At 2x

Current Spread

Triton4 6 (6%x1%) 90 AAA 120 Triton 6 (4.75%x1%) 190 AA 250 Triton 6 (4.4%x1%) 235 A 275 Triton 6 (3.4%x1%) 400 BBB 370 Strauss (6%x1%) 105 AAA 115 130 Strauss (5.5%x1%) 155 AA 165 195 Strauss (4.4%x1%) 265 A 270 320 Strauss (3.4%x1%) 430 BBB 370 430

Source: DB Global Markets

In Exhibit 3, we show spreads and participation rates for selected single-name CMCDS and tranches of CMCDO deals. We also show participation rates for the Strauss capped and uncapped CMCDO tranches. Capped tranches (tranches where the portfolio spread is capped) offer higher participation rates. For each tranche, we also show expected S&P ratings, tranche subordination and thickness. Standard CMCDOs and capped structures are discussed in more detailed in the last section of this document.

4 Triton 6 is a static 100, predominantly US investment grade portfolio while the Strauss portfolio consists largely of European names.

Page 13: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Introdocution

What is CMS?

plain vanilla swap: floating rate = 6M LIBOR (+α)

CMS: floating rate = the swap rate for a swap for a certain period (e.g. 5-year swaprate)

Convexity adjustments are often used for simple and easy evaluation of future 6MLIBOR.

Floating -ratepayer

Fixed -rate payer

Periodic fixed payments

-Periodic floating paymentsfloating rate = the swap ratefor a swap for a certain period(e.g. 5-year SWAP rate)

Figure: The typical structure of CMS.

Nakagawa, Yueh and Hsieh (HU & NCU ) Valuation of CMCDS Nov. 24, 2010 4 / 36

Page 14: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

注意事項:本文件係參照發行公司產品內容,委託人須詳細閱讀,自行判斷是否投資,並自行承擔風險,實際損益計算方式以交易日之英文版商品說明書(term sheet)所載條款為準。

UU SS DD 33 00 yy 及及 11 00 yy CC MM SS 利利 差差 走走 勢勢 圖圖

發發 行行 機機 構構 簡簡 介介 商商 品品 條條 件件

投投 資資 熱熱 線線

產產 品品 特特 色色

保保障障配配息息:: 首年固定配息 88..55%%(p.a.),之後配息利率以 44%%(p.a.)加碼計算,皆優於定存。

倍倍數數給給息息:: 緊盯長短天期利差,利差越大,配息越高。

到到期期保保本本:: 發行機構到期 100%返還本金。

合合法法節節稅稅:: 自然人海外投資免稅,保障高資產客戶節稅需求。

計計 息息 方方 式式

第一年:無須任何條件,年息 8.5%

第二年至第十二年:配息利率 x n/N(計息基礎:30/360)

配息利率:4% + Max【0, 6 x(30y CMS Coupon Fixing – 10y CMS Coupon Fixing)】

30y CMS Coupon Fixing:每季債息起息日之前二個美國政府債券營業日的美元 30 年期 CMS

10y CMS Coupon Fixing:每季債息起息日之前二個美國政府債券營業日的美元 10 年期 CMS

n:於每季計息期間,符合計息條件之日曆天數。 N:360 天

計息條件:(美元 30 年期 CMS – 美元 10 年期 CMS)大於或等於 0。

募集時間:12/27/2004-01/07/2005 或額滿為止 最低申購金額:10,000 美元,以 10,000 美元累加。 發行日:2005.01.17 到期日:2017.01.17 或依發行機構提前買回條件 提前買回條件:發行機構有權自 2005/07/17 起(含),每季

以票面金額 100%向委託人買回本債券。 配息日:每季配息一次 信託手續費:申購金額之 1.5%,一次計收。 信託管理費:第一年不收取。自第二年起,依客戶實際持

有天數,按年費率 0.2%,於到期時或客戶提前贖回時收取。贖回規定:自發行半年後,委託人可於每月 7 日、17 日申

請。提前贖回以 10 萬美元為最低贖回單位,並以其倍數增加。(提前贖回,可能會有本金折價的風險)

Commonwealth Bank of Australia(澳大利亞聯邦銀行)成立於 1912 年,為澳洲第一大零售、信用卡

發行以及基金管理銀行,全球銀行排名第 78,主要業務包括銀行貸款、 保險及中小企業融資業務。

信用評等:AA- by S&P;Aa3 by Moody’s

其他商品條件及投資風險請詳商品說明書

過去 10 年(1994 至 2004 年)期間,僅有 130 天利差小於 0

Page 15: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

2

Page 16: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Notations

• (Ω,F , Q) : a complete probability space, where Q is supposed to be a

risk-neutral measure for the market model.

• τ : the default time of an issuer, which is a random time defined on

(Ω,F , Q).

• (Ft) : the filtration including the market information except for τ . In short, τ

cannot be a stopping time w.r.t. (Ft).

• (Ht) : the filtration generated by only τ . Namely, Ht := στ ∧ s|s ≤ t.

• (Gt) : the smallest filtration generated by (Ft) and (Ht). Namely,

Gt := Ft ∧Ht.

• F (t) := Q (τ ≤ t|Ft).

• S (t) : the (Ft)-survival process of τ ;

S (t) := 1− F (t) = Q (τ > t|Ft) = EQ[

Iτ>t|Ft

]

.

• Assume that S (t) > 0 for any t ≥ 0 and S (t) is continuous in t.

11

Page 17: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

• Γt := − log (S (t)) : the (Ft)-hazard process of τ underQ; equivalently,

S (t) = e−Γt .

• rt : the risk-free short rate process that is (Ft)-adapted process.

• D (t, s) (t ≤ s) : the discount factor from s to t:

D (t, s) := exp(

−∫ s

trudu

)

.

• Tj : the time of the jth premium payment to take place, j = 1, 2, · · · .

• T : maturity of the CDS/CMCDS; T = Tn.

• j−1,j : time increment between payment at the (j − 1)th

and jth time

point in units of years.

• δ : a constant time increment we assume; that is, j−1,j = δ for all j.

• N : notional amount.

• R : recovery rate for the underlying obligor (supposed to be constant;

0 ≤ R < 1).

12

Page 18: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

• I• : indicator function.

• s (t;Tj, Tk) (t ≤ Tj < Tk) : Gt-measurable variable; the spread that

makes the CDS contract, which has first payment at time Tj+1 and last

payment at time Tk, fair at the valuation time t; i.e. the spread for protection

in (Tj , Tk] at initial time t. In particular, s (t;Tj , Tk) ≡ 0 if τ ≤ t.

• M : constant maturity defined in the floating premium leg of a CMCDS;

M = mδ.

• η(t) the participation rate in the floating premium leg of a CMCDS.

13

Page 19: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

CDS Pricing - Premium Leg

• Define PV premt

(

CDS(T0,Tn])

to be the present value at time t of the fixed

premium leg of a CDS for the period (T0, Tn], then

PV premt

(

CDS(T0,Tn])

(1)

= EQ

n∑

j=1

s (t;T0, Tn)×N × δ ×D(t, Tj)× Iτ>Tj

∣Gt

= N × δ × s (t;T0, Tn)×

n∑

j=1

EQ[

D(t, Tj)× Iτ>Tj

∣Gt

]

= N × δ × s (t;T0, Tn)× Iτ>t ×n∑

j=1

EQ[

D(t, Tj)× eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

= N × δ × s (t;T0, Tn)×n∑

j=1

EQ[

D(t, Tj)× eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

.

14

Page 20: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

• The second last equality follows Lemma 1.

• The last equality follows from s (t;T0, Tn)× Iτ>t = s (t;T0, Tn), for

s (t;T0, Tn) = 0 when τ ≤ t by assumption.

15

Page 21: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Lemma 1

• Lemma 1 (Corollary 5.1.1 of Bielecki-Rutkowski) LetX be a Fs-measurable

and Q-integrable random variable. Then for any t ≤ s, we have

EQ[

Iτ>sX |Gt

]

= Iτ>tEQ[

XeΓt−Γs |Ft

]

.

16

Page 22: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

CDS Pricing - Default Leg

• Define PV deft

(

CDS(T0,Tn])

to be the present value at time t of the default leg of the CDS,

then

PV deft

(

CDS(T0,Tn])

= EQ[

(1− R)×N ×D(t, τ)× IT0<τ≤Tn

∣Gt

]

= (1− R)×N × EQ[

D(t, τ)× IT0≤τ≤Tn|Gt

]

= (1− R)×N × Iτ>t × EQ

[∫ Tn

T0

D(t, u)eΓt−ΓudΓu

∣Ft

]

.

• The last equality is justified due to Lemma 2.

17

Page 23: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Lemma 2

EQ[

D(t, τ)× IT0≤τ≤Tn|Gt

]

= Iτ>t×EQ

[

∫ Tn

T0

D(t, u)eΓt−ΓudΓu

∣Ft

]

.

• (Proof)

18

Page 24: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

EQ[

D(t, τ)× IT0≤τ≤Tn|Gt

]

= EQ[

D(t, T0)EQ[

D(T0, τ)× IT0≤τ≤Tn|GT0

]

∣Gt

]

(2)

= EQ

[

D(t, T0)Iτ>T0EQ

[

∫ Tn

T0

D(T0, u)eΓT0−ΓudΓu

∣FT0

]

∣Gt

]

= Iτ>tEQ

[

D(t, T0)eΓt−ΓT0EQ

[

∫ Tn

T0

D(T0, u)eΓT0−ΓudΓu

∣FT0

]

∣Ft

]

= Iτ>tEQ

[

EQ

[

∫ Tn

T0

D(t, u)eΓt−ΓudΓu

∣FT0

]

∣Ft

]

= Iτ>tEQ

[

∫ Tn

T0

D(t, u)eΓt−ΓudΓu

∣Ft

]

.

19

Page 25: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

• The first and the last equality follow from the iterated conditioning property of

conditional expectation.

• The second equality and the third one respectively follow from (5.21) in

Cor.5.1.3 and (5.13) in Cor. 5.1.1 of Bielecki and Rutkowski (2002).

20

Page 26: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Pricing CDS - CDS Spread

• By equating the present values of both legs, we have the fair spread

s (t;T0, Tn) as

s (t;T0, Tn) = Iτ>t ×(1− R)× EQ

[

∫ Tn

T0D(t, u)eΓt−ΓudΓu

∣Ft

]

δ ×∑n

j=1EQ

[

D(t, Tj)× eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

=: Iτ>t × s (t;T0, Tn) .

• Remark that s (t;T0, Tn) is Ft-measurable.

21

Page 27: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

CMCDS Pricing

• In a CMCDS with first payment in T1 and with final maturity Tn, protection on

a reference credit against default in [T0, Tn] is given from protection seller to

a protection buyer. In exchange for this protection, a “constant maturity” CDS

spread is paid.

• A contract that protects in [T0, Tn] can be decomposed into a stream of

contracts, each single contract protecting in [Tj−1, Tj ] , for j = 1, · · · , n,

with default payment postponed to Tj if default occurs in [Tj−1, Tj ] .

• In each single period [Tj−1, Tj], the rate s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M) paid

at time Tj makes the exchange fair, so that a contract offering protection on a

reference credit in [T0, Tn] in exchange for payment of spread

s (T0;T0, T0 +M) , · · · , s (Tn−1;Tn−1, Tn−1 +M) at time

T1, · · · , Tn, is fair, i.e. has zero initial value at time t.

22

Page 28: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

CMCDS Pricing - Premium Leg

• Define PVpremt

(

CMCDS(T0,Tn])

to be the present value of a premium leg of the CMCDS at

time t as

PVpremt

(

CMCDS(T0,Tn])

= EQ

n∑

j=1

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×N × δ ×D(t, Tj)× Iτ>Tj

∣Gt

= N × δ ×n∑

j=1

EQ[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)× Iτ>Tj−1×D(t, Tj)× Iτ>Tj

∣Gt

]

= N × δ ×n∑

j=1

EQ[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×D(t, Tj)× Iτ>Tj

∣Gt

]

= N × δ × Iτ>t ×n∑

j=1

EQ[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×D(t, Tj)× eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

.

The last equality follows from Lemma 1.

23

Page 29: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

CMCDS Pricing - Premium Leg

• Since the default leg of a CMCDS is identical to the default leg of a plain

vanilla CDS written on the same reference entity, it follows that the premium

legs of CDS and CMCDS should be identical too.

PV premt

(

CDS(T0,Tn])

= PV premt

(

CMCDS(T0,Tn])

× η (t)

• The question of pricing a CMCDS reduces to finding the value of participation

rate η (t)

η (t) =s (t;T0, Tn)×

∑n

j=1EQ[

D(t, Tj)× eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

∑n

j=1EQ

[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×D(t, Tj)× eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

] .

• The numerator in the above equation can be directly obtained under

assumptions for stochastic processes of rt and λt.

The denominator seems still complicated.

24

Page 30: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

CMCDS Pricing - Participation Rate

• The determination of participation rate is reduced to the calculation of

EQ[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×D(t, Tj)× eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

(j = 1, · · · , n).

where

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)

=(1−R)× EQ

[

∫ Tj−1+M

Tj−1D(t, u)eΓt−ΓudΓu

∣Ft

]

δ ×∑j+m−1

k=j EQ[

P (t, Tk)eΓt−ΓTk |Ft

]

25

Page 31: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Determination of

EQ[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×D(t, Tj)× eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

EQ

[

s(

Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)

× D(t, Tj) × eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

= EQ

(1 − R) × EQ

[

∫Tj−1+M

Tj−1D(Tj−1, u)e

ΓTj−1−Γu

dΓu

∣FTj−1

]

δ ×∑j+m−1k=j

EQ

[

D(Tj−1, Tk)eΓTj−1

−ΓTk |FTj−1

] × D(t, Tj) × eΓt−ΓTj

Ft

=

(1 − R) × EQ[

∫Tj−1+M

Tj−1D(t, u)eΓt−ΓudΓu

∣Ft

]

δ ×∑j+m−1k=j

EQ[

D(t, Tk)eΓt−ΓTk |Ft

] ×

∑j+m−1k=j

EQ[

D(t, Tk)eΓt−ΓTk |Ft

]

EQ[

∫Tj−1+M

Tj−1D(t, u)eΓt−ΓudΓu

∣Ft

]

× EQ

EQ

[

∫Tj−1+M

Tj−1D(Tj−1, u)e

ΓTj−1−Γu

dΓu

∣FTj−1

]

∑j+m−1k=j

EQ

[

D(Tj−1, Tk)eΓTj−1

−ΓTk |FTj−1

] × D(t, Tj) × eΓt−ΓTj

Ft

= s(

t;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)

×

∑j+m−1k=j

EQ[

D(t, Tk)eΓt−ΓTk |Ft

]

EQ[

∫Tj−1+M

Tj−1D(t, u)eΓt−ΓudΓu

∣Ft

]

× EQ

EQ

[

∫Tj−1+M

Tj−1D(Tj−1, u)e

ΓTj−1−Γu

dΓu

∣FTj−1

]

∑j+m−1k=j

EQ

[

D(Tj−1, Tk)eΓTj−1

−ΓTk |FTj−1

] ×D(t, Tj) × eΓt−ΓTj

Ft

.

26

Page 32: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Assumptions and Definitions

• Assume that the risk-free short rate process rt follows a stochastic process.

• Assume that the hazard process Γt is absolutely continuous, that is, there

exists a nonnegative (Ft)-progressively measurable process λt, which is

called the (Ft)-hazard rate process of τ underQ, such that for t ≤ s

Γt =

∫ t

0

λudu.

• Define

ϕ(t, s; rt, λt) := EQ

[

D(t, s)eΓt−Γs |Ft

]

= EQ

[

exp

(

s

t(ru + λu) du

)

|Ft

]

ψ(t, s; rt, λt) := EQ

[

λsD(t, s)eΓt−Γs |Ft

]

= EQ

[

λs exp

(

s

t(ru + λu) du

)

|Ft

]

.

Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rt, λt) :=

j+m−1∑

k=j

ϕ(t, Tk; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rt, λt) :=

Tj−1+M

Tj−1

ψ(t, u; rt, λt)du

27

Page 33: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Determination of EQ[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M) ·D(t, Tj) · eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

EQ[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×D(t, Tj)× eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

= s (t;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×

∑j+m−1k=j ϕ(t, Tk; rt, λt)

∫ Tj−1+M

Tj−1ψ(t, u; rt, λt)du

× EQ

∫ Tj−1+M

Tj−1ψ(Tj−1, u; rTj−1 , λTj−1)du

∑j+m−1k=j ϕ(Tj−1, Tk; rTj−1 , λTj−1)

×D(t, Tj)×Γt−ΓTj

Ft

.

• Define a new probability measure Qj equivalent to Q by

dQj

dQ:=

D(0, Tj)e−ΓTj

EQ

[

D(0, Tj)e−ΓTj

] .

• From the Bayes’ rule(see Lemma 5.3 of Karatzas and Shreve(1991)), it

28

Page 34: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

follows

EQ

[

s(

Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)

× D(t, Tj) × eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

= s(

t;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)

×Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rt, λt)

×1

e−ΓtD(0, t)EQ

e−ΓTj D(0, Tj) ×

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Ft

= s(

t;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)

×Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rt, λt)

×1

e−ΓtD(0, t)EQ

[

e−ΓTj D(0, Tj)|Ft

]

× EQj

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Ft

= s(

t;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)

×Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rt, λt)

× ϕ(t, Tj ; rt, λt) × EQj

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Ft

= s(

t;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)

×Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; rt, λt)× ϕ(t, Tj ; rt, λt)

×

R2

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; r, λ)

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M; r, λ)Qj (rTj−1

∈ dr, λTj−1∈ dλ|Ft).

29

Page 35: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

• That is,

EQ[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×D(t, Tj)× eΓt−ΓTj |Ft

]

= s (t;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rt, λt)× ϕ(t, Tj ; rt, λt)

×

R2

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; r, λ)

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; r, λ)Qj(rTj−1 ∈ dr, λTj−1 ∈ dλ|Ft).

30

Page 36: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Theorem

• Under all the assumptions given above, the value of participation rate η (t) of

CMCDS is given as

η (t) =s (t;T0, Tn)× Φ(t, T0, Tn; rt, λt)

∑n

j=1 s (t;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)× ϕ(t, Tj ; rt, λt)×Θ(t, Tj−1)

where

Θ(t, Tj−1) :=Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rt, λt)

×

R2

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; r, λ)

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; r, λ)Qj(rTj−1 ∈ dr, λTj−1 ∈ dλ|Ft).

31

Page 37: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Convexity Adjustments

• In some institutional reports on CMCDS, the pricing of CMCDS is discussed

in terms of “convexity adjustment” methodology.

• The conditional expectation of a forward CDS spread is specified as the

product of the conditional forward survival probability and the current CDS

spread with the same maturity as the forward CDS plus some additional term

containing the volatility of the default intensity process.

EQt

[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)× Iτ>Tj−1

]

= s (t;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×Q (τ > Tj−1|Ft) + convexity adjustment

32

Page 38: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

• Given Gt, what is the conditional expectation of a forward CDS spread

EQ [s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M) |Gt]?

EQ [s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M) |Gt]

= EQ[

Iτ>Tj−1 × s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M) |Gt

]

= Iτ>t × EQ[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)× eΓt−ΓTj−1 |Ft

]

.

33

Page 39: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

And

EQ[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)× eΓt−ΓTj−1 |Ft

]

= s (t;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rt, λt)

×EQ

[

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rTj−1 , λTj−1)

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rTj−1 , λTj−1)× eΓt−ΓTj

Ft

]

34

Page 40: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

• Define a new probability measure Qj−1 equivalent to Q by

dQj−1

dQ:=

e−ΓTj−1

EQ

[

e−ΓTj−1

] .

• Then the Bayes’ rule implies

EQ[

s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)× eΓt−ΓTj−1 |Ft

]

= s (t;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M)×Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rt, λt)

× EQ[

eΓt−ΓTj−1 |Ft

]

× EQj−1

[

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rTj−1 , λTj−1)

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 +M ; rTj−1 , λTj−1)

Ft

]

.

35

Page 41: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

• Finally we have

EQ [s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 + M) |Gt]

= Iτ>t · eΓt · s (t;Tj−1, Tj−1 + M) ·Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rt, λt)

· EQ[

e−ΓTj−1 |Ft

]

· EQj−1

[

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Ft

]

= Iτ>t · s (t;Tj−1, Tj−1 + M) ·EQ

[

e−ΓTj−1 |Ft

]

e−Γt·Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rt, λt)

· EQj−1

[

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Ft

]

= s (t;Tj−1, Tj−1 + M) · Q (τ > Tj−1|Ft, τ > t)

·Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rt, λt)· EQj−1

[

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Ft

]

.

36

Page 42: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

• The forward spread EQ [s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 +M) |Gt] is as

follows:

EQ

[s (Tj−1;Tj−1, Tj−1 + M) |Gt]

= s (t;Tj−1, Tj−1 + M) × Q (τ > Tj−1|Ft, τ > t)

×Φ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rt, λt)

Ψ(t, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rt, λt)× E

Qj−1

[

Ψ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Φ(Tj−1, Tj−1, Tj−1 + M ; rTj−1, λTj−1

)

Ft

]

.

37

Page 43: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Example - Vasicek Mean-Reverting Processes of rt

and λt

• Assume that both the default-free instantaneous spot rate rt and the

instantaneous hazard rate λt follow so-called Vasicek model as follows:

drt = κ(θ − rt)dt+ σdWt,

dλt = κ(θ − λt)dt+ σdWt.

• Suppose all the parameters are positive. Also, let Wt and Wt are

(Ft)-Brownian motions under the measureQ with dWtdWt = ρdt.

38

Page 44: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Example - Vasicek Mean-Reverting Processes of rt

and λt

For t ≤ s and dummy variables a, b, c(> 0), let

Z(t, s; a) :=1

a

(

1− e−a(s−t))

,

Y (t, s; a, b, c) := −

(

b

a−

c2

2a2

)

(s− t)

+

(

b

a−

c2

2a2

)

Z(t, s; a)−c2

4aZ(t, s; a)2.

Then we have

Proof: See Proposition 7.2 of Schonbucher (2003).

39

Page 45: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Example - Vasicek Mean-Reverting Processes of rt

and λt

• Denote by Lt the Radon-Nikodym density process

Lt : = EQ

[

dQj

dQ

∣Ft

]

=1

EQ

[

exp(

−∫ T

0ru + λudu

)] (3)

×EQ

[

exp

(

∫ T

0

ru + λudu

)

Ft

]

. (4)

• Since the instantaneous correlation betweenWt and Wt is given by ρ, we

can use anotherQ-standard Brownian motion Wt independent of Wt to

regardWt as

Wt = ρWt +√

1− ρ2Wt. (5)

40

Page 46: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

• Then we also have

dLt = Lt

(

−Z(t, T ;κ)σdWt − Z(t, T ; κ)σdWt

)

(6)

= Lt

(

−ρσZ(t, T ;κ) + σZ(t, T ; κ)dWt − σ√

1− ρ2Z(t, T ; κ)dWt

)

.

(7)

41

Page 47: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

41-1

Page 48: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Example - Vasicek Mean-Reverting Processes of rt

and λt

• From Girsanov theorem, it follows that the followings are independent

standard Brownian motions on the period [0, Tj ] with respect to “Tj -forward”

measure Qj .

Wjt := Wt +

∫ t

0

ρσZ(u, T ;κ) + σZ(u, T ; κ) du,

Wjt := Wt +

∫ t

0

σ√

1− ρ2Z(u, T ;κ)du.

• In addition, set Wjt := ρW

jt +

1− ρ2Wjt , which is also a standard

Brownian motion with respect to Qj and dWjt dW

jt = ρdt.

42

Page 49: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Dynamics of rt and λt under Measure Qj

• The dynamics of rt and λt under the “Tj -forward” measure Qj are given by

drt =

κθ − ρσσZ(t, T ; κ)− σ2Z(t, T ;κ)− κrt

dt+ σdWjt ,

dλt =

κθ − ρσσZ(t, T ; κ)− σ2Z(t, T ; κ)− κλt

dt+ σdWjt .

• Namely, we have

rT = rte−κ(T−t) +

∫ T

t

e−κ(T−s)

κθ − ρσσZ(s, T ; κ)− σ2Z(s, T ; κ)

ds

+

∫ T

t

e−κ(T−s)σdW js ,

λT = λte−κ(T−t) +

∫ T

t

e−κ(T−s)

κθ − ρσσZ(s, T ;κ)− σ2Z(s, T ; κ)

ds

+

∫ T

t

e−κ(T−s)σdW js .

• Anyway, Qj(rTj−1∈ dr, λTj−1

∈ dλ|rt, λt) can be seen as two-dimensional normal

distribution.

43

Page 50: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Numerical Results - Parameters Setting• Default intensity λt :

dλt = κ(θ − λt)dt+ σdWt

where κ = 0.2; θ = 0.03; σ = 0.7;λ0 = 0.03

• Short rate rt :

drt = κ(θ − rt)dt+ σdWt

whereκ = 0.5; θ = 0.06;σ = 0.03; r0 = 0.06 . . .Ait-Sahalia (2002, Econometrica)

or κ = 0.261; θ = 0.07; σ = 0.022; r0 = 0.07 . . .Cheng and Chen (2009,Journal of

Econometrics)

• ρ : Correlation between rt and λt : ρ = 0.2, 0.4, 0.6, 0.8,−0.2,−0.4,−0.6,−0.8

• Tn = 5 or 7 or 10

• M = 5 (constant maturity)

44

Page 51: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Numerical Result - Base Case

Parameter Values - Base Case

t = 0 current time

T0 = t CMCDS starting date

Tn = T = 5 CMCDS maturity date

δ = 0.25 quarterly payemt

M = 5 constant maturity

ρ = 0.2 correlation between rt and λt

s (t;T0, Ti) = 150 bp = 1.5%, for all i flat initial spread curve

κ = 0.2; θ = 0.03; σ = 0.03;λ0 = 0.03 dλt = κ(θ − λt)dt+ σdWt

κ = 0.5; θ = 0.06;σ = 0.03; r0 = 0.06 drt = κ(θ − rt)dt+ σdWt

45

Page 52: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

The Effect of Hazard Rate Volatility

Value of σ

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05

η 0.8195 0.8149 0.8064 0.7929 0.7728

Θ(0, 1) 1.0291 1.0387 1.0563 1.0820 1.1203

Θ(0, 2) 1.1083 1.1228 1.1492 1.1921 1.2730

Θ(0, 3) 1.2420 1.2543 1.2797 1.3244 1.4098

Θ(0, 4) 1.4366 1.4398 1.4454 1.4487 1.4787

Θ(0, 5) 1.7047 1.6855 1.6499 1.5829 1.3754

46

Page 53: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

The Effect of Short Rate Volatility

Value of σ

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05

η 0.8077 0.8068 0.8066 0.8063 0.8055

Θ(0, 1) 1.0535 1.0540 1.0556 1.0570 1.0592

Θ(0, 2) 1.1449 1.1478 1.1482 1.1492 1.1526

Θ(0, 3) 1.2766 1.2772 1.2791 1.2794 1.2819

Θ(0, 4) 1.4482 1.4450 1.4469 1.4459 1.4415

Θ(0, 5) 1.6540 1.6558 1.6494 1.6446 1.6430

47

Page 54: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

The Effect of Correlation between Hazard Rate and

Short Rate

Value of ρ

0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8

η 0.8039 0.8052 0.8056 0.8066 0.8076 0.8084 0.8094 0.8104 0.8115

Θ(0, 1) 1.0675 1.0632 1.0588 1.0556 1.0519 1.0483 1.0448 1.0417 1.0373

Θ(0, 2) 1.1658 1.1589 1.1538 1.1485 1.1444 1.1390 1.1335 1.1307 1.1248

Θ(0, 3) 1.2887 1.2845 1.2820 1.2777 1.2754 1.2714 1.2694 1.2666 1.2633

Θ(0, 4) 1.4394 1.4381 1.4424 1.4436 1.4445 1.4475 1.4487 1.4504 1.4549

Θ(0, 5) 1.6090 1.6166 1.6348 1.6447 1.6610 1.6704 1.6819 1.6870 1.6979

48

Page 55: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

The Effect of Initial Credit Spread Curve

Initial Credit Spread Curve s (t;T0, Ti)

flat curve upward-sloping curve downward-sloping curve

η 0.8063 0.5346 0.9713

Θ(0, 1) 1.0562 1.0562 1.0556

Θ(0, 2) 1.1492 1.1480 1.1483

Θ(0, 3) 1.2796 1.2785 1.2780

Θ(0, 4) 1.4446 1.4438 1.4439

Θ(0, 5) 1.6442 1.6479 1.6505

49

Page 56: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

The Effect of Contract Maturity

Contract Maturity Tn

Tn = 5 Tn = 7 Tn = 10

η 0.8148 0.7083 0.5977

Θ(0, 1) 1.0387 1.0390 1.0388

Θ(0, 2) 1.1227 1.1228 1.1219

Θ(0, 3) 1.2544 1.2540 1.2543

Θ(0, 4) 1.4405 1.4395 1.4393

Θ(0, 5) 1.6882 1.6870 1.6850

50

Page 57: Valuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default · PDF fileValuation of Constant Maturity Credit Default Swaps by Hidetoshi Nakagawa Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo and Meng-Lan Yueh

Conclusion

• A broad class of exotic interest rate derivatives can be valued simply by

adjusting the forward interest rate. This adjustment is known in the market as

“convexity correction”. Various ad hoc rules are used to calculate the

convexity correction for different products.

• In this research, we examines the mechanism of a CMCDS contract and

develop a method of valuing the credit derivatives with constant maturity

features.

• We put convexity correction on a rigorous mathematical basis by showing that

it can be interpreted as the side-effect of a change of probability measure.

• The analysis here provides us with a theoretically consistent framework to

calculate convexity corrections.

51