37
Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth Working Paper No. 2005-24 Using Bilateral Advance Pricing Agreements to Resolve Tax Transfer Pricing Disputes ANJA DE WAEGENAERE Tilburg University, Center for Economic Research (CentER) RICHARD C. SANSING Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth J. WIELHOUWER Tilburg University, CentER July 21, 2005 This paper can be downloaded from the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://ssrn.com/abstract=766044

Using Bilateral Advance Pricing Agreements to Resolve Tax Transfer Pricing Disputes

  • Upload
    vu-nl

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth

Working Paper No. 2005-24

Using Bilateral Advance Pricing Agreements to Resolve Tax Transfer Pricing

Disputes

ANJA DE WAEGENAERE Tilburg University, Center for Economic Research (CentER)

RICHARD C. SANSING

Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth

J. WIELHOUWER Tilburg University, CentER

July 21, 2005

This paper can be downloaded from the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:

http://ssrn.com/abstract=766044

Using Bilateral Advance Pricing Agreements to Resolve Tax Transfer Pricing Disputes

ABSTRACT: We investigate the use of bilateral advance pricing agreements (BAPAs)

to resolve transfer pricing disputes between a taxpayer and two tax authorities. BAPAs

are designed to protect firms from double taxation while reducing expected compliance

costs (audits costs plus BAPA implementation costs). We identify settings in which we

expect BAPAs to arise and investigate the effect of the program on compliance costs. We

show that a reduction in expected compliance costs is a necessary but not sufficient

condition for an agreement to be reached. Agreements are more likely to arise when the

amount of income potentially subject to double taxation is low and the difference in tax

rates between the two countries is high. We also show that the existence of the BAPA

program can increase tax compliance costs in settings in which the absence of a BAPA

conveys information to the tax authorities, inducing them to audit a taxpayer without a

BAPA more intensively than they would have had the BAPA program not existed.

Although this outcome is socially inefficient, it increases the expected net payoff (taxes

collected less tax compliance costs) of the country with the higher tax rate.

Keywords: Bilateral advance pricing agreements, transfer pricing, tax compliance, game theor

1

I. INTRODUCTION

Income earned by a multinational enterprise can be subject to double taxation if

multiple tax authorities assert the right to tax the income. In particular, double taxation

arises to the extent that governments use different transfer pricing rules to allocate

income between countries. In the 1997, 1999, and 2001 Ernst & Young LLP Transfer

Pricing Global Surveys, over 80% of multinationals identified “double tax relief” as an

important international tax issue because transfer pricing adjustments typically result in

double taxation (Ackerman and Hobster 2001).

Governments also have severe difficulties with transfer pricing disputes. Transfer

pricing cases are factual intensive investigations featuring both legal and economic

analysis and involving both domestic and foreign entities. Billions of dollars of tax

revenue are at stake; for example, the multinational pharmaceutical firm

GlaxoSmithKline is fighting a $2.7 billion U.S. tax deficiency notice arising from

transfer pricing disputes involving its 1989-1996 tax years (Sullivan 2004). The rapidly

growing volume of international transactions between related entities has put the

traditional system of international tax compliance under considerable strain.

In response to this mutually unsatisfactory situation, the U.S. has developed and

many countries have implemented a new model of tax compliance: the bilateral advance

pricing agreement (BAPA). In a BAPA, the taxpayer approaches the governments prior

to engaging in a transaction with a foreign related party to negotiate a mutually

acceptable transfer pricing method. In a BAPA, the taxpayer provides detailed

information regarding the proposed transaction to the governments. In return, the

2

governments commit to a transfer pricing method that ensures that the taxpayer will not

be subject to double taxation.

Williams (1996) describes the APA program, the procedures involved, and the

costs and benefits of the program. Ring (2000) also describes the program and evaluates

it in terms of legal theories of administrative law. Ackerman (2001) examines how the

program has evolved into a more standardized format over time.

In this paper, we investigate the use of BAPAs using a game-theoretic approach to

tax compliance. We examine two research questions. First, under what circumstances do

we expect firms and governments to enter into a BAPA, and under what circumstances do

we expect firms to follow the traditional approach involving auditing and litigation?

Second, what are the effects of the BAPA program on aggregate tax compliance costs,

which we define to be the sum of expected audit costs and the cost of negotiating and

implementing the BAPA?

With respect to our first research question, we first find that a reduction in

aggregate tax compliance costs is a necessary but not sufficient condition for a BAPA to

occur. The fact that by definition a BAPA requires the parties to agree upon a single

transfer price makes an agreement infeasible even though aggregate tax compliance costs

would be lower with an agreement. Second, we find that a BAPA is more likely to be

used when the amount of income subject to double taxation because of asymmetric

transfer pricing rules is low. Although the rationale for the BAPA program is to provide a

mechanism by which the firm can avoid double taxation, the ability of the firm and the

countries to find a mutually acceptable transfer price decreases as the amount of income

potentially subject to double taxation increases. Third, we find that BAPAs occur less

3

frequently when the tax rates of the two countries are similar. Expected audit costs are

lower when the tax rates are similar because the country with the higher tax rate does not

have to audit as frequently to deter the taxpayer from shifting its taxable income toward

the lower tax rate country via its choice of transfer price. When expected audit costs are

lower, there is less to gain from a BAPA and so it is used less frequently.

With respect to our second research question, we find that the effect of the BAPA

program on compliance costs depends on whether the absence of a BAPA reveals

information about the taxpayer that influences the governments’ audit decisions. Even

though the tax auditors are not able to use disclosures made by the taxpayer in the BAPA

process in other tax compliance proceedings the absence of a BAPA may reveal taxpayer

information.1 If the absence of a BAPA reveals no taxpayer information, the BAPA

program reduces aggregate audit costs; otherwise, the parties would not have an incentive

to enter into the BAPA in the first place. However, if the absence of a BAPA does reveal

taxpayer information, the existence of the program can increase aggregate tax compliance

costs by inducing the countries to increase the frequency with which they audit the

taxpayer, compared to what they would have done if the BAPA program had not existed.

Despite the increase in expected compliance costs, the BAPA program increases the

expected payoff (taxes collected minus compliance costs) of the country with the higher

tax rate. Therefore, we expect that high tax countries will most aggressively promote the

use of BAPAs.

In section 2 we review the literature that relates to our paper. Section 3

characterizes the equilibrium behavior of the taxpayer and the two tax authorities when a

BAPA does not occur. Section 4 characterizes the equilibrium behavior of the taxpayer

4

and the two tax authorities when the parties have an opportunity to enter a BAPA. In

section 5 we discuss the empirical implications of our results. We also examine the

effects of the BAPA program on tax compliance costs. Section 6 concludes.

II. RELATED LITERATURE

Tomohara (2004) is the only other paper to formally investigate the economic

effects of BAPAs. The focus of that paper is on the firm’s production decisions in the

presence of a BAPA, whereas our paper focuses on whether the taxpayer and

governments will enter into a BAPA and how the presence of the BAPA program affects

their reporting and auditing decisions.

Our paper relates to several topics that have been thoroughly explored in the tax

literature. Many papers have modeled the interaction between the taxpayer and the tax

authority as a game between a wealth-maximizing taxpayer and a tax authority trying to

maximize government revenues net of audit costs (Graetz, Reinganum and Wilde 1986;

Reinganum and Wilde 1986; Beck and Jung 1989; Sansing 1993; Rhoades 1997;

Rhoades 1999; Mills and Sansing 2000; Feltham and Paquette 2002.) De Waegenaere,

Sansing, and Wielhouwer (2005) extend the standard tax compliance model to a

multinational setting in which the taxpayer interacts with two tax authorities enforcing

the transfer pricing rules of countries with different tax rates. We use a similar approach

to determine the equilibrium behaviors of the taxpayer and the tax authorities in case a

BAPA is not entered into.

Our study of the BAPA process relates to research on alternatives to litigation as a

means of resolving legal disputes. Samuelson (1991) investigates the use of final-offer

arbitration under asymmetric information. Sansing (1997) applies a variation of

5

Samuelson’s model to a tax litigation setting. He finds settings in which the taxpayer and

the tax authority will only agree to arbitration for certain realizations of their private

information. Our results are similar in that whether the parties enter into a BAPA depends

on the taxpayer’s private information.

As BAPAs are used to resolve tax transfer pricing disputes, our paper relates to

that literature as well. In particular, the fact that the two countries have asymmetric tax

transfer pricing rules that would result in double taxation in absence of a BAPA gives the

taxpayer the incentive to enter into a BAPA. It also provides the conditions under which

the BAPA process will break down. Other papers that have investigated the

distributional and efficiency effects of countries employing asymmetric tax transfer

pricing rules include Halperin and Srinidhi (1987) and Elitzur and Mintz (1996). There is

a much larger literature on distributional and efficiency effects of tax transfer pricing

rules when both countries use the same transfer pricing rule; Baldenius, Melumad, and

Reichelstein (2004) review this literature in their paper.

III. THE REPORTING GAME

A firm F earns income generated in a transaction between related parties

operating in two different countries, H and L. We normalize the amount of income to one,

without loss of generality. The two countries impose tax rates of tH and tL, respectively,

LHtt ! . The tax laws in the two countries are different with respect to the measurement

of taxable income associated with the transaction. Under H’s law, the income taxed by H

is yH, 10 !! Hy , and the income taxed by L is 1−yH. Under L’s law, the income taxed by

L is yL, 10 !! Ly and the income taxed by H is 1−yL. We assume that each country

measures income in a manner that is favorable to itself, so 1!+ LH yy . We assume that

6

yH and yL are realizations from a probability distribution f(yH , yL). We let x represent the

amount of income which would be subject to double taxation if each country were to

apply its own law, so 1!+= LH yyx . We assume that x has strictly positive probability

density on the interval [0,1]. We let µ=][xE .

The firm privately observes the realization (yH , yL) and files a pair of internally

consistent tax reports (r,1−r), where r is the amount of income from the related party

transaction reported to H and 1−r is the amount of income reported to L. We let

!

r ="yH + (1#" )(1# yL ), where α is the weight that F puts on country H’s law and

!

1"#

is the weight placed on L’s law. We do not constrain α to be between zero and one,

although in equilibrium α is never less than zero nor greater than one. We illustrate the

firm’s reporting problem in Figure 1.

[INSERT FIGURE 1 HERE]

Each country has the option to audit the taxpayer’s report. The cost of an audit

is

!

K > 0 . We assume that HtK µ< , which ensures that auditing is not so costly as to deter

H from auditing even if F reports in accordance with L’s law. The audit detects the

difference between the reported income and the income measured under that country’s

tax law. Country H (L) conducts an audit of the taxpayer’s related party transaction with

probability δH (δL). We assume that r and 1−r are contained in a much more extensive

report that aggregates the taxable income from all of the firm’s transactions. The variance

of the aggregated report is sufficiently large that the report contains essentially no

information regarding the realization of (yH , yL). Therefore, the decision to audit the

taxpayer’s related party transaction does not depend on the report. All aspects of the

model are common knowledge except for the realization (yH , yL).

7

The payoff to country H given a particular realization (yH , yL) and report r is:

])([ KrytrtP HHHHH !!+= " (1)

The payoff to country L given a particular realization (yH , yL) and report 1−r is:

]))1(([)1( KrytrtP lLLLL !!!+!= " (2)

The payoff to the firm given a particular realization (yH , yL) and reports (r,1−r) is:

)]}1([)1{()]([ ryrtryrtP LLLHHHF !!+!!!+!= "" (3)

As an alternative to dealing with the conflict in the countries’ tax laws via the

audit and litigation process, the firm can deal with the conflict in the countries’ tax laws

cooperatively via a bilateral advance pricing agreement (BAPA).

We first characterize the behavior of the players in case they do not enter into a

BAPA. We define a Nash equilibrium for this reporting game as a reporting strategy

),( LH yyr that maximizes the firm’s expected payoff given the equilibrium audit

strategies of H and L; an audit strategy H

! for country H that maximizes its expected

payoff given the firm’s reporting strategy; and an audit strategy L

! for country L that

maximizes its expected payoff given the firm’s reporting strategy.

Proposition 1 establishes the optimal strategies of the players in the reporting

game. Because the reporting game only occurs if the players have not entered into a

BAPA, the countries may be able to infer information regarding the value of the amount

of income potentially subject to double taxation, x, from the fact that the firm is filing a

tax return without a BAPA. We let µ̂ denote the conditional expectation of x, given that

a BAPA is not entered into. We assume in the following proposition that µµ !ˆ ; we will

8

show in the proof of Proposition 2 that this assumption indeed holds in this game because

in equilibrium µ̂ is always weakly greater than

!

µ.

There are two equilibria depending on K, tax rates, and µ̂ . If the cost of auditing

(K) is sufficiently low compared to the tax rates and the expected amount of income that

is subject to double taxation ( µ̂ ), both H and L audit all reports and F reports part of its

income according to L’s rules and part according to H’s rules. We refer to this as the

heavy audit equilibrium. If the cost of auditing is sufficiently high, country L never audits

and country H uses a mixed audit strategy that makes F indifferent regarding its report.

The firm reports part of its income according to L’s rules and part according to H’s rules

so as to make H indifferent between auditing and not auditing the report. We refer to this

as the light audit equilibrium.

Proposition 1 Assume that .ˆ µµ !

(a) If LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ , then the following strategies constitute a Nash equilibrium:

(i) F reports r to country H and 1−r to country L, where !"

#$%

& '(

H

H

Lt

Kt

t

K

µ

µ

µ)

ˆ

ˆ,

ˆ.

(ii) H always audits, i.e. 1=H

! .

(iii) L always audits, i.e. 1=L

! .

(b) If LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ , then the following strategies constitute a Nash equilibrium:

(i) F reports r to country H and 1−r to country L, where H

H

t

Kt

µ

µ!

ˆ

ˆ "= .

(ii) H audits with probability H

LH

H

t

tt !=" .

(iii) L never audits, i.e. 0=L

! .

9

In the heavy audit equilibrium, the cost of auditing is so low relative to the

countries’ tax rates and the expected amount of income subject to double taxation that

one of the countries will have an optimal strategy of always auditing. To deter the firm

from reporting all of its income according to the rules of that country, the other country

should also audit all reports. Given that both countries will audit the report, the only

equilibrium reporting strategy for the firm is to report its income in a way that provides

both countries with an incentive to audit.

In the light audit equilibrium, the cost of auditing is sufficiently high that country

L has an optimal strategy of never auditing. Country H audits just enough to deter the

firm from reporting its income according to country L’s law. This audit frequency is

decreasing in the tax rate ratio H

L

t

t . The firm in turn reports just enough of its income in

accordance with country H’s law to deter it from auditing all reports. The fraction of the

income reported in accordance with country H’s law is increasing in tH and µ̂ and

decreasing in the audit cost K.

IV. BILATERAL ADVANCE PRICING AGREEMENTS

In this section, we characterize the actions of the players when they have the

opportunity to enter a BAPA. In a BAPA, the firm approaches countries H and L

regarding the possibility of agreeing to an allocation of the income in which z is allocated

to H and 1−z is allocated to L. This allocation ensures that double taxation does not occur.

The firm reveals the realization (yH , yL) to H and L for those realizations of (yH , yL) for

which there exists an allocation z for which all parties would be willing to enter into a

BAPA. The cost to all parties of negotiating and implementing a BAPA is C≥ 0.

10

We define a feasible BAPA to be one in which the allocation of income (z,1−z)

and a division of the total costs C are such that each player receives a (weakly) higher

payoff under the BAPA than without the BAPA. We allow any nonnegative allocation of

the cost among the three players. The players’ payoffs before the allocation of C are:

LHFtzztA )1( !!!= , (4)

HHztA = , (5)

LLtzA )1( != . (6)

Feasibility of a BAPA requires three conditions to be satisfied for a BAPA to be

feasible: AF≥ PF, AH≥ PH, and AL≥ PL. Furthermore, we require AF+AH+AL-C≥

PF+PH+PL; we refer to a BAPA as desirable if this latter condition is satisfied. Because

tax payments are zero-sum wealth transfers between the three players, this condition is

satisfied if the BAPA cost C is less than the expected of 2K under the heavy audit

equilibrium and H

LH

t

ttK )( ! under the light audit equilibrium.

The interaction among the players when the BAPA program exists proceeds as

follows. First, the firm observes (yH , yL). We assume that the players will agree to a

BAPA when one is both feasible and desirable. F then files its tax returns in a manner

consistent with the BAPA, and H and L accept the returns as filed. If a BAPA is either

infeasible or undesirable, the firm files its tax returns without a BAPA, then the players

play the reporting game described in section 2.2

The feasibility of a BAPA will sometimes depend on x, the level of income

potentially subject to double taxation. The desirability of a BAPA depends on the costs of

implementing a BAPA (C) and on whether both governments would audit the report in

11

absence of a BAPA (the heavy audit equilibrium) or whether H would audit with some

probability and L would never audit (the light audit equilibrium). That decision in turn

depends on whether LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ or

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ , as shown in Proposition 1. We let

!

"( x) be an indicator variable that equals one if a feasible and desirable BAPA exists and

zero otherwise.

Three types of outcomes are possible. If the cost of the BAPA exceeds the

countries’ expected aggregate audit costs, then a BAPA would not be desirable, so that

0)x( =! for all x, and the players would not enter a BAPA for any value of x. When

BAPAs never occur, the tax authorities cannot infer any information about x from the

absence of a BAPA. In that case, the reporting game is played as described in Proposition

1 with µµ =ˆ .

Second, if the players would choose their heavy audit strategies in the reporting

game (i.e., when LH

LH

tt

ttˆK

+!µ ) and the cost of a BAPA is less than the aggregate audit

costs (C<2K), a BAPA is desirable. However, if the amount of income that is potentially

subject to double taxation ( )1!+= LH yyx is too high, there does not exist a transfer

price leading to an income allocation (z, 1−z) that makes both H and L better off under a

BAPA than they would be under the heavy audit equilibrium, even if F were to bear all of

the cost of the BAPA. The largest value of x for which a BAPA is feasible, which we

denote x*, is LH

LH

tt

ttKx

)(* += . If *

xx ! , F realizes that a BAPA is both feasible and

desirable, so it proposes a BAPA. If *xx ! , F realizes that a BAPA is infeasible and so

the players will choose their heavy audit strategies in the reporting game. Therefore,

12

!

"( x) = 1 if *xx ! and

!

"( x) = 0 if

!

x " x*. It is in this situation that the governments

update their beliefs regarding x given the absence of a BAPA. Because LH

LH

tt

ttKx

)(* +=

and

!

ˆ µ = E[ x | x " x*] ,

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂

is equivalent to LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! .

Third, if the players would choose their light audit strategies in the reporting game

(i.e., when LH

LH

tt

ttˆK

+!µ ) and the cost of a BAPA is less than H’s expected audit costs

!

C " K#H

=K(t

H$ t

L)

tH

%

& '

(

) * , a BAPA is desirable and feasible for all values of x, so that

!

"( x) = 1 for all x; therefore, the players will negotiate a BAPA for all realizations of x.

The reporting game is never played in this case. This equilibrium is supported by the off-

equilibrium path beliefs of the tax authorities of H and L that .1]0)x(|x[Eˆ === !µ

Proposition 2 characterizes the indicator functions )x(! that are consistent with

the decision rule of the parties to enter a BAPA if and only if one is both feasible and

desirable. For the parameter values LH

LH

LH

LH

tt

ttK

tt

tt

+!!

+

µ and KCt

ttK

H

LH 2)(

!!" ,

two different functions )(x! are both consistent with that decision rule. This occurs

because whether a BAPA is feasible and desirable (i.e. whether 1)( =x! or 0)( =x! )

depends on whether the parties would choose their heavy audit or light audit strategies in

the reporting game, which in turn depends on µ̂ . However, µ̂ itself depends on whether

BAPAs are feasible and desirable (i.e. the function )(x! ).

13

Proposition 2

(a) If KC 2! , then

!

"( x) = 0 for all x.

(b) If LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! and KC 2! , then

!

"( x) = 1 if *xx ! and

!

"( x) = 0 if

!

x " x*.

(c) If

!

K "µt

HtL

tH

+ tL

and KCt

ttK

H

LH 2)(

!!" , then

!

"( x) = 0 for all x.

(d) If LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! and

H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" , then

!

"( x) = 1 for all x.

Propositions 3-5 characterize the Nash equilibria that arise when the players have

the opportunity to enter into a BAPA instead of playing the reporting game. Proposition 3

characterizes behavior when C is sufficiently high. When K2C ! , the cost of a BAPA is

so high that a BAPA is not desirable, even if the players would choose their heavy audit

strategies in the reporting game. Since BAPAs are never desirable, the tax authorities

cannot infer any information about x from the absence of a BAPA. The equilibrium then

depends on K, as described in Proposition 1 with µµ =ˆ .

Proposition 3 If

!

C " 2K , then the Nash equilibria are:

(a) if

!

K "µt

HtL

tH

+ tL

, then

!

"( x) = 0 for all x and the players choose their heavy audit

strategies in the reporting game.

(b) if ,

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ then

!

"( x) = 0 for all x and the players choose their light audit

strategies in the reporting game.

14

Proposition 4 characterizes the equilibria in which C takes on intermediate values

!

K(tH " tL )

tH# C # 2K

$

% &

'

( ) . For these values of C, a BAPA is undesirable when the players

would choose their light audit strategies but is desirable when the players would choose

their heavy audit strategies. However, in the latter case, a BAPA is only feasible for

values of *xx ! . If the players enter a BAPA for *

xx ! , then heavy auditing is the

optimal response in the absence of a BAPA.

Proposition 4 If

!

K(tH " tL )

tH# C # 2K , then the Nash equilibria are:

(a) if

!

K "tHtL

tH

+ tL

, then

!

"( x) = 1 if *xx ! and

!

"( x) = 0 if

!

x " x*, and the players

choose their heavy audit strategies in the reporting game;.

(b) if

!

K "µt

HtL

tH

+ tL

, then

!

"( x) = 0 for all x and the players choose their light audit

strategies in the reporting game.

An important implication of Proposition 4 is that either type of equilibrium can

arise when

!

µtHtL

tH

+ tL

" K "tHtL

tH

+ tL

and

!

K(tH " tL )

tH# C # 2K . If the firm anticipates that

the countries will choose their heavy audit strategies, then it should seek a BAPA when

*xx ! , in which case heavy audit strategies are appropriate. On the other hand, if the

firm anticipates that the countries will choose their light audit strategies, it should never

seek a BAPA, in which case light audit strategies are appropriate. While we offer no

prediction regarding which equilibrium will be played, aggregate payoffs are higher in

the “no BAPA/light audit” equilibrium while country H’s payoff is greater in the “some

15

BAPA/heavy audit” equilibrium. This occurs because country H has an expected payoff

equal to

!

tH yH "K in either the heavy or light audit equilibrium and has a minimum

payoff of

!

tH yH "K in a BAPA. We predict that high-tax countries will aggressively

encourage the use of BAPAs to resolve tax transfer pricing disputes.

Proposition 5 characterizes the Nash equilibria when C is low (H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" ).

A BAPA is always desirable in that case. When

!

K "tHtL

tH

+ tL

, a BAPA is only feasible if

*xx ! , in which case the players would choose their heavy audit strategies in the absence

of a BAPA. When

!

K "tHtL

tH

+ tL

, a BAPA is feasible for all x.

Proposition 5 If H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" , then the Nash equilibria are:

(a) if

!

K "tHtL

tH

+ tL

, then

!

"( x) = 1 if *xx ! and

!

"( x) = 0 if

!

x " x*, and the players

choose their heavy audit strategies in the reporting game;

(b) if

!

K "tHtL

tH

+ tL

, then

!

"( x) = 1 for all x and the off-equilibrium path beliefs are that

!

ˆ µ = 1.

Figure 2 illustrates the equilibrium outcomes for

!

tH

= 40%, tL

= 20% , and

5.0=µ .

[INSERT FIGURE 2 HERE]

16

V. DISCUSSION AND ANALYSIS

Empirical implications

We first consider the empirical implications of our analysis. We identify three

implications of our results. First, a reduction in expected tax compliance costs is a

necessary but not sufficient condition for a BAPA to occur. This occurs because the

desirability of a BAPA depends on the difference between the cost of a BAPA and the

aggregate expected audit costs of the countries, whereas the feasibility of a BAPA

sometimes requires that the amount of income potentially subject to double taxation be

low. All feasible BAPAs are desirable, but the converse does not hold.

Second, a BAPA is more likely to be entered into when the amount of income

subject to double taxation because of asymmetric transfer pricing rules is low, i.e. *xx ! .

Although the rationale for the BAPA program is to provide a mechanism by which the

firm can avoid double taxation, the fact that by definition a BAPA requires the parties to

agree upon a single transfer price makes the procedure infeasible when the countries’ tax

laws imply large differences in their respective transfer prices.

Third, when cost of auditing is sufficiently high, BAPAs occur less frequently

when the tax rates of the two countries are similar. When K is high and the tax rates are

similar, the low-tax country does not audit (because of the high audit cost) and the high-

tax country audits infrequently (because little auditing is required to deter the firm from

reporting using the low-tax country’s transfer price.) Therefore, a BAPA is only desirable

when the cost C of negotiating and implementing the BAPA is very low. Therefore

BAPAs are more likely to be desirable when the firm has a stronger incentive to shift

17

income to the lower-tax country due to large differences in tax rates, and less likely to be

desirable when the two countries have similar tax rates.

Efficiency implications of the BAPA program

We complete our analysis by comparing the cost of tax compliance (tax auditing

plus BAPA implementation costs) when the BAPA program exists to what the cost would

have been in absence of the program. We consider two cases. First, when either K is very

low !!"

#$$%

&

+'

LH

LH

tt

ttK

µ , very high !!"

#$$%

&

+'

LH

LH

tt

ttK , or BAPA costs are very high (

!

C " 2K ),

the reporting game is unaffected by the BAPA program. When BAPAs are entered into,

all the players’ payoffs weakly improve, because all feasible BAPAs are desirable.

However, for intermediate values of K !!"

#$$%

&

+''

+LH

LH

LH

LH

tt

ttK

tt

ttµ and

!

C " 2K , the

very existence of the BAPA program can change the audit strategies that occur in the

reporting game. When

!

K(tH " tL )

tH# C # 2K

$

% &

'

( ) , Proposition 4(a) shows that an equilibrium

exists in which the players choose their heavy audit strategies when a BAPA does not

occur but would have chosen their light audit strategies if the BAPA program did not

exist. This occurs because the tax audit authorities of countries L and H infer that the

potential level of double taxation is high from the absence of a BAPA. They infer

important taxpayer information from the absence of a BAPA even though they learn

nothing directly about the taxpayer from the BAPA process itself.

As Proposition 4(b) shows, this inefficiency need not arise, because it is still an

equilibrium for the firm to not seek a BAPA and for the players to choose their light audit

18

strategies in the reporting game. Because the “no BAPA and light audit” equilibrium

features lower aggregate compliance costs than the “some BAPA and heavy audit”

equilibrium, at least one player will prefer the equilibrium without BAPAs. However,

country H’s payoffs are higher in the equilibrium in which a BAPA arises for sufficiently

low x. We expect high tax rate countries to be the most aggressive in promoting BAPAs

for this reason; whether the BAPA program creates an inefficiency depends on whether

the high-tax country succeeds in getting the players to play its preferred equilibrium.

When BAPA costs are very low !!"

#$$%

& '(

H

LH

t

ttKC

)( , the efficiency implications of

the BAPA program are mixed. When the potential for double taxation is low ( )*xx ! , the

players enter into a BAPA, which is the efficient outcome. When the potential for double

taxation is high, however, a BAPA is not feasible and players choose their heavy audit

strategies, but would have chosen their light audit strategies if the BAPA program did not

exist. Therefore, total tax compliance costs increase.

Proposition 6 summarizes the implications of the existence of a BAPA program

on total tax compliance costs.

Proposition 6 The existence of a BAPA program

(a) decreases compliance costs for *xx ! if

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ and KC 2! ;

(b) decreases compliance costs ifLH

LH

tt

ttK

+! and

H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" ;

(c) increases compliance costs if LH

LH

LH

LH

tt

ttK

tt

tt

+!!

+

µ and

!

K(tH " tL )

tH# C # 2K

when the players choose the equilibrium strategies described in Proposition 4(a)

19

and has no effect on compliance costs when the players choose the equilibrium

strategies described in Proposition 4(b);.

(d) decreases compliance costs for *xx ! and increases compliance costs for *

xx !

if LH

LH

LH

LH

tt

ttK

tt

tt

+!!

+

µ and H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" .

For combinations of parameter values not mentioned in Proposition 6, the BAPA

program has no effect on tax compliance costs. We illustrate the possibilities described in

Proposition 6 in Figure 3.

[INSERT FIGURE 3 ABOUT HERE]

VI. CONCLUSIONS

We have modeled the resolution of tax transfer pricing disputes as a strategic game

between the firm and two governments. BAPAs have emerged as an alternative means of

resolving these disputes. BAPAs are designed to protect firms from double taxation and

reduce tax compliance costs.

Our analysis yields three insights into when such agreements will arise. First, a

reduction in expected tax compliance costs is a necessary but not sufficient condition for

a BAPA to occur. Second, BAPAs are less likely to occur when the amount of income

potentially subject to double taxation because of asymmetric transfer pricing rules is high.

Third, BAPAs occur less frequently when the tax rates of the two countries are similar.

We also use investigate the effect of the BAPA program on tax compliance costs.

We find that the program can increase tax compliance costs. This occurs when the

absence of a BAPA conveys information to the tax authorities, inducing them to increase

the level of auditing over what is would have been in the absence of a BAPA program.

20

Although this is a socially inefficient outcome, it increases the expected payoff of the

high-tax country. Therefore, we expect that countries with the highest tax rates will most

aggressively promote the use of BAPAs.

21

REFERENCES

Ackerman, R. 2001. Will U.S. standardization erode key flexibility in APAs? Journal of

International Taxation 12 (February): 12

Ackerman, R. and J. Hobster. 2001. Transfer pricing practices, perspectives, and trends in

22 countries. Tax Notes International 24 (December 17): 1151-1158.

Baldenius, T., N. Melumad, and S. Reichelstein. 2004. Integrating managerial and tax

objectives in transfer pricing. The Accounting Review 79 (July): 591-615.

Beck, P., and W. Jung. 1989. Taxpayers’ reporting decisions and auditing under

information asymmetry. The Accounting Review 64 (July): 468-487.

De Waegenaere, A., R. Sansing, and J. Wielhouwer. 2005. Who benefits from

inconsistent multinational tax transfer pricing rules? Contemporary

Accounting Research (forthcoming).

Elitzur, R. and J. Mintz. Transfer pricing rules and corporate tax competition. Journal of

Public Economics 60 (June): 401-422.

Feltham, G. and S. Paquette. 2002. The interrelationship between estimated tax payments

and taxpayer compliance. Journal of the American Taxation Association 24

(Supplement): 27-45.

Graetz, M., J. Reinganum, and L. Wilde. 1986. The tax compliance game: Toward an

interactive theory of law enforcement. Journal of Law, Economics, and

Organization 2 (Spring): 1-32.

Halperin, R., and B. Srinidhi. 1987. The effects of U.S. income tax regulations’ transfer

pricing rules on allocative efficiency. The Accounting Review 62 (October):

686-706.

22

Mills, L., and R. Sansing. 2000. Strategic tax and financial reporting decisions: Theory

and evidence. Contemporary Accounting Research 17 (Spring): 85-106.

Reinganum, J., and L. Wilde. 1986. Equilibrium verification and reporting policies in a

model of tax compliance. International Economic Review 27 (October): 739-

760.

Rhoades, S. 1997. Costly false detection errors and taxpayer rights legislation:

Implications for tax compliance, audit policy, and revenue collections.

Journal of the American Taxation Association 64 (Supplement): 27-47.

Rhoades, S. 1999. The impact of multiple component reporting on tax compliance and

audit strategies. The Accounting Review 74 (January): 63-85.

Ring, D. 2000. On the frontier of procedural innovation: Advance pricing agreements and

the struggle to allocate income for cross border taxation. Michigan Journal of

International Law 21 (Winter): 143-234.

Samuelson, W. 1991. Final-offer arbitration under incomplete information. Management

Science 37 (October): 1234-1247.

Sansing, R. 1993. Information acquisition in a tax compliance game. The Accounting

Review 68 (October): 874-884.

Sansing, R. 1997. Voluntary binding arbitration as an alternative to Tax Court litigation.

National Tax Journal 50 (June): 279-296.

Sullivan, M. 2004. With billions at stake, Glaxo puts U.S. APA program on trial. Tax

Notes International 34 (May 3): 456-463.

23

Tomohara, A. 2004. Inefficiencies of bilateral advanced pricing agreements (BAPA) in

taxing multinational companies. National Tax Journal 57 (December): 863-

873.

Williams, E. 1996. Basics of the U.S. advance pricing agreement program. Tax Notes

International 13 (August 26): 723-731.

24

The firm’s reporting problem

Figure 1

Note: The bold line is the range of reports )r1,r( ! for which ].1,0[!"

25

Nash equilibrium outcomes for

!

tH

= 40%, tL

= 20%, µ = 0.5.

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.350

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12

0.14

0.16

0.18

0.2

Always BAPA Never BAPA, light audit

BAPA if x<x*,

heavy audit Never BAPA, heavy audit

BAPA if x<x*, heavy audit

OR

Never BAPA, light audit

C

K

Figure 2

26

Effects of BAPA program on tax compliance for

!

tH

= 40%, tL

= 20%, µ = 0.5.

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3

0

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12

0.14

0.16

0.18

0.2

D

I

U

U

D if x<x*

I if x>x*

I or U

D if x<x*

U if x>x*

U

C

K

Figure 3

Note: D indicates that compliance costs are decreasing; I indicates that compliance costs are increasing; and U indicates that compliance costs are unaffected.

27

APPENDIX

Proof of Proposition 1

(a)LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂

(i) Given the audit strategies 1=

H! and 1=

L! , the firm is indifferent over all

possible values of α. Substituting )1)(1( LH yyr !!+= "" into equation (3) yields:

xtytytP HLLLHF !!!!= )1(

which does not depend on α.

(ii) Given the firm’s equilibrium reporting strategy !!"

#$$%

& '(

H

H

Lt

Kt

t

K

µ

µ

µ)

ˆ

ˆ,

ˆ,

it is optimal for H to always audit because the expected incremental payoff from

auditing is:

KyytEKrytE LHHHH !!!!=!! ))]1()(1([])([ "

KxtEH

!!= ])1([ "

which is positive because .ˆ

ˆ

H

H

t

Kt

µ

µ!

"#

(iii) Given the firm’s equilibrium reporting strategy !"

#$%

& '(

H

H

Lt

Kt

t

K

µ

µ

µ)

ˆ

ˆ,

ˆ, it is

optimal for L to always audit because the expected incremental payoff from

auditing is:

KyytEKrytE HLLLL !!!=!!! ))]1(([]))1(([ "

KxtEL

!= ][ "

28

which is positive because Lt

K

µ!

ˆ" . The assumption that

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ ensures that

an α exists in the interval ].1,0[ˆ

ˆ,

ˆ!"

#

$%&

' ()

H

H

Lt

Kt

t

K

µ

µ

µ*

(b)LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ :

(i) H is indifferent between auditing and not auditing the report. H′s incremental

payoff from auditing is:

0))]1()(1([])([ =!!!!=!! KyytEKrytE LHHHH "

because H

H

t

Kt

µ

µ!

ˆ

ˆ "= . The assumptions that

HtK µ! and µµ !ˆ ensures that

.10 !!"

(ii) L never audits because its incremental payoff from auditing is:

KyytEKrytE HLLLL !!!=!!! ))]1(([]))1(([ "

KxtEL

!= ][ "

which is negative because H

H

t

Kt

µ

µ!

ˆ

ˆ "= and

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ .

(iii) Given H

LH

H

t

tt !=" and 0=

L! , F is indifferent among its reports, because

substituting )1)(1( LH yyr !!+= "" into equation (3) yields:

)1( HLHHF ytytP !!!=

which is independent of α. QED

29

Proof of Proposition 2:

(a) When ,2KC ! a BAPA is never desirable because the BAPA costs will be greater

than audit costs and thus 0)x( =! for all x.

(b) When LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ , the players will choose the heavy auditing strategies in the

reporting game and incur audit costs of K2 . Because KC 2! , a BAPA is desirable.

A BAPA is feasible if for the realization (yH, yL) if there is a z that weakly improves the

payoffs of H, L, and F, i.e.:

Kytzt HHH !" (A1)

Kytzt LLL !"! )1( (A2)

LLHHLH ytytztzt +!"+ )1( . (A3)

A z exists that satisfies equations (A1)−(A3) if and only if:

L

L

H

Ht

Ky

t

Ky +!"! 1

and

LH

LLHH

H

Htt

ytyt

t

Ky

!

!!"!

)1( .

These two conditions are satisfied if and only if .)(

1 *

LH

LH

LHtt

ttKxyyx

+=!"+=

Therefore,

!

"( x) = 1 if *xx ! and

!

"( x) = 0 if

!

x " x*. This implies that

!

ˆ µ = E[ x | x " x*] . Because 1ˆ

*!! µx , there exists a )1,0[!p such that

)1(]|[ˆ **ppxxxxE !+="=µ . Substituting this expression for µ̂ into the

30

condition LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ and using the fact that

LH

LH

tt

ttKx

)(* += implies that

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ is equivalent to

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! . Therefore,

!

"( x) = 1 if *xx ! and

!

"( x) = 0

if

!

x " x* if

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! .

(c) WhenLH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ , the players would choose the light audit strategies in the

reporting game. Because H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" , a BAPA is undesirable. If 0)x( =! for all

x, µ̂ µ= , so that LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ is equivalent to

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ . So 0)x( =! for all x if

!

K "µt

HtL

tH

+ tL

and H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" .

(d) When LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ , the players would choose the light audit strategies in the

reporting game and incur audit costs of H

LH

H

t

ttKK

)( !=" . Because

H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" ,

a BAPA is desirable. A BAPA is feasible if for the realization (yH, yL) there is a z that

weakly improves the expected payoffs of H, L, and F. The payoffs of H, L, and F in

the light audit equilibrium are:

))1(())1(( Kxtxyt HHHH !!+!! "#"

!"

#$%

&+'

H

HLt

Kxyt

µ̂1 , where [ ] 10)x(|xEˆ === !µ given the off-

equilibrium path beliefs of H and L.

31

).1( HLHH ytyt !!!

Therefore, the conditions under which a feasible BAPA exists are:

)1(ˆ

H

L

H

L

HHHt

tK

t

tKxytzt !!!"

µ (A4)

!"

#$%

&+'('

H

HLLt

Kxytzt

µ̂1)1( (A5)

)1()1( HLHHLH ytytztzt !+"!+ . (A6)

A z exists that satisfies equations (A4)−(A6) if and only if:

H

H

H

L

HH

L

H

Ht

Kxy

t

t

t

K

t

t

t

Kxy

µµ ˆ)1(

ˆ!"!!! ,

which is true for all x because 1ˆ =µ and 1!x . Therefore, a BAPA is feasible for all x

and thus 1)x( =! for all x.

The off-equilibrium path belief that 1ˆ =µ is the only belief that is consistent with

the conjectured equilibrium. For any other belief, a BAPA would not be feasible for

realizations of µ̂x ! and so F would choose 0)x( =! when µ̂x ! . However, the

only solution to µµ ˆ]ˆ|[ =!xxE is 1ˆ =µ . This implies that the condition LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂

is equivalent to LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! . Therefore, 1)x( =! for all x if

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! and

H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" . QED

32

Proof of Proposition 3

(a) Because KC 2! , Proposition 2(a) shows that 0)x( =! for all x, which implies

µµ =ˆ . Proposition 1(a) implies that the players choose their heavy audit strategies in

the reporting game because

!

K "µt

HtL

tH

+ tL

.

(b) Because KC 2! , Proposition 2(a) shows that 0)x( =! for all x, which implies

µµ =ˆ . Proposition 1(b) implies that the players choose their light audit strategies

in the reporting game because

!

K "µt

HtL

tH

+ tL

. QED

Proof of Proposition 4

(a) Because LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! and KC 2! , we know from Proposition 2(b) that

!

"( x) = 1

if *xx ! and

!

"( x) = 0 if

!

x " x*, and that

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ is equivalent to

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! . Proposition 1(a) therefore implies that the players will choose their

heavy audit strategies in the reporting game.

(b) Because

!

K "µt

HtL

tH

+ tL

and

!

K(tH " tL )

tH# C # 2K , we know from Proposition 2(c)

that 0)x( =! for all x, which implies that

!

ˆ µ = µ. if, and that LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ is

equivalent to LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! . Proposition 1(b) implies that the players will choose

their light audit strategies in the reporting game. QED

33

Proof of Proposition 5

(a) Because

!

K "tHtL

tH

+ tL

and

!

C "K(t

H# t

L)

tH

, Proposition 2(b) shows that

!

"( x) = 1 if

*xx ! and

!

"( x) = 0 if

!

x " x*, and that

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ̂ is equivalent to

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! .

Proposition 1(a) implies that the players will choose their heavy audit strategies in

the reporting game.

(b) Because

!

K "tHtL

tH

+ tL

and

!

C "K(t

H# t

L)

tH

, Proposition 2(d) shows that

!

"( x) = 1

for all x and that

!

ˆ µ = 1. QED

Proof of Proposition 6 In the absence of a BAPA program, aggregate audit costs would

be 2K if LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ and

H

LH

t

ttK )( ! if LH

LH

tt

ttK

+!µ (Proposition 1 with µµ =ˆ .) BAPA

costs are always C.

(a) From Proposition 4(a), it follows that a BAPA will occur when *

xx ! and the

players will choose their heavy audit strategies when .*xx ! In the absence of the

BAPA program, the players would choose their heavy audit strategies for all x because

!

K "µt

HtL

tH

+ tL

. Because KC 2! , the existence of the BAPA program decreases

compliance costs when *xx ! and has no effect on compliance costs when .

*xx !

(b) From Proposition 5(b), it follows that a BAPA will occur for all x. In the absence

of the BAPA program, the players would choose their light audit strategies for all x.

34

Because H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" , the existence of the BAPA program decreases compliance

costs for all x.

(c) From Proposition 4(a), it is an equilibrium for a BAPA to occur when *

xx ! and

for the players will choose their heavy audit strategies when .*xx ! In the absence of

the BAPA program, the players would choose their light audit strategies for all x

because

!

K "µt

HtL

tH

+ tL

. Because H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" , the existence of the BAPA program

increases compliance costs for all x when that equilibrium occurs. However, from

Proposition 4(b) it is also an equilibrium for the players to not enter into a BAPA and

choose their light audit strategies. In that case, compliance costs would not change.

(d) From Proposition 5(a), it follows that a BAPA will occur when *

xx ! and the

players will choose their heavy audit strategies when

!

x " x* because

LH

LH

tt

ttK

+! . In

the absence of the BAPA program, the players would choose their light audit strategies

for all x because

!

K "µt

HtL

tH

+ tL

. Because H

LH

t

ttKC

)( !" , the existence of the BAPA

program decreases compliance costs when *xx ! and increases compliance costs

!

K "µt

HtL

tH

+ tL

when .*xx ! QED

35

ENDNOTES

1 An important practical issue in this process is whether the governments have the option

of acting in bad faith by engaging in BAPA negotiations solely to obtain information

about the taxpayer, which it then uses in an adversarial audit process. Taxpayers of

course would not be willing to negotiations under such circumstances. To guard against

this outcome, Sections 9.03 and 9.04 of Rev. Proc. 91-22 [1991 C.B. 526] bars the

Internal Revenue Service from using taxpayer disclosures in any proceeding not covered

by an advance pricing agreement.

2 Given that firms and the governments behave in this manner in general, deviating in any

particular instance (e.g., by having the firm not propose a BAPA that is both feasible and

desirable) would decrease the deviating player’s payoff . However, other sets of

behaviors also have this property. For example, if firms could collectively boycott the

BAPA process for certain parameter values, doing so could alter the governments’

optimal audit strategies in the reporting game.