69
The Global Integrated Monetary and Fiscal Model (GIMF) Technical Appendix Michael Kumhof, International Monetary Fund Douglas Laxton, International Monetary Fund March 30, 2009 1

The Global Integrated Monetary and Fiscal Model (GIMF ......This cascading of nominal rigidities from upstream to downstream sectors has important consequences for the behavior of

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • The Global Integrated Monetary and Fiscal Model

    (GIMF)

    Technical Appendix

    Michael Kumhof, International Monetary Fund

    Douglas Laxton, International Monetary Fund

    March 30, 2009

    1

  • 1 MODEL OVERVIEW

    The world consists of Ñ countries. The domestic economy is indexed by 1 and foreign economies

    by j = 2, ..., Ñ . In our exposition we will ignore country indices except when interactions between

    multiple countries are concerned. It is understood that all parameters except population growth n and

    technology growth g can differ across countries. Figure 1 illustrates the flow of goods and factors for

    the two country case.

    Countries are populated by two types of households, both of which consume final retailed output

    and supply labor to unions. First, there are overlapping generations households with finite planning

    horizons as in Blanchard (1985). Each of these agents faces a constant probability of death (1−θ(j))in each period, which implies an average planning horizon of 1/ (1− θ(j)).1 In each period,N(j)nt(1−ψ(j))

    (1− θ(j)

    n

    )of such individuals are born, where N(j) indexes absolute population

    sizes in period 0 and ψ(j) is the share of liquidity constrained agents. Second, there are liquidity

    constrained households who do not have access to financial markets, and who consequently are forced

    to consume their after tax income in every period. The number of such agents born in each period is

    N(j)ntψ(j)(

    1− θ(j)n)

    . Aggregation over different cohorts of agents implies that the total numbers

    of agents in country j is N(j)nt. For computational reasons we do not normalize world population

    to one, especially when we analyze a small open economy. In that case we assume N(1) = 1, and

    set N(j) such that N(1)/ΣÑj=2N(j) equals the share of country 1 agents in the world population. In

    addition to the probability of death households also experience labor productivity that declines at a

    constant rate over their lifetimes. This simplified treatment of lifecycle income profiles is justified

    by the absence of explicit demographics in our model, and adds another powerful channel through

    which fiscal policies can have non-Ricardian effects. Households of both types are subject to uniform

    labor income, consumption and lump-sum taxes. We will denote variables pertaining to these two

    groups of households by OLG and LIQ.

    1 In general we allow for the possibility that agents may be more myopic than what would

    be suggested by a planning horizon based on a biological probability of death.

    2

  • Firms are managed in accordance with the preferences of their owners, myopic OLG households,

    and they therefore also have finite planning horizons. Each country’s primary production is carried

    out by manufacturers producing tradable and nontradable goods. Manufacturers buy capital services

    from capital goods producers (in GIMF without Financial Accelerator) or from entrepreneurs (in

    GIMF with Financial Accelerator), labor from monopolistically competitive unions, and oil from the

    world oil market. They are subject to nominal rigidities in price setting as well as real rigidities in

    labor hiring and in the use of oil. Capital goods producers are subject to investment adjustment costs.

    Entrepreneurs finance their capital holdings using a combination of external and internal financing.

    A capital income tax is levied on capital goods producers (in GIMF without Financial Accelerator)

    or on entrepreneurs (in GIMF with Financial Accelerator). Unions are subject to nominal wage

    rigidities and buy labor from households. Manufacturers’ domestic sales go to domestic distributors.

    Their foreign sales go to import agents that are domestically owned but located in each export

    destination country. Import agents in turn sell their output to foreign distributors. When the

    pricing-to-market assumption is made these import agents are subject to nominal rigidities in foreign

    currency. Distributors first assemble nontradable goods and domestic and foreign tradable goods,

    where changes in the volume of imported inputs are subject to an adjustment cost. This private sector

    output is then combined with a publicly provided capital stock (infrastructure) as an essential further

    input. This capital stock is maintained through government investment expenditure that is financed

    by tax revenue. The combined final domestic output is then sold to consumption goods producers,

    investment goods producers, and import agents located abroad. Consumption and investment goods

    producers in turn combine domestic and foreign output to produce final consumption and investment

    goods. Foreign output is purchased through a second set of import agents that can price to the

    domestic market, and again changes in the volume of imported goods are subject to an adjustment

    cost. This second layer of trade at the level of final output is critical for allowing the model to produce

    the high trade to GDP ratios typically observed in small, highly open economies. Consumption goods

    output is sold to retailers and the government, while investment goods output is sold domestic capital

    goods producers and the government. Consumption and investment goods producers are subject

    to another layer of nominal rigidities in price setting. This cascading of nominal rigidities from

    upstream to downstream sectors has important consequences for the behavior of aggregate inflation.

    3

  • Retailers, who are also monopolistically competitive, face real instead of nominal rigidities. While

    their output prices are flexible they find it costly to rapidly adjust their sales volume. This feature

    contributes to generating inertial consumption dynamics.2

    The world economy experiences a constant positive trend technology growth rate g = Tt/Tt−1,

    where Tt is the level of labor augmenting world technology, and a constant positive population growth

    rate n. When the model’s real variables, say xt, are rescaled, we divide by the level of technology

    Tt and by population, but for the latter we divide by nt only, meaning real figures are not in per

    capita terms but rather in absolute terms adjusted for technology and population growth. We use the

    notation x̌t = xt/(Ttnt), with the steady state of x̌t denoted by x̄. An exception to this is quantities

    of labor, which are only rescaled by nt.

    Asset markets are incomplete. There is complete home bias in government debt, which takes

    the form of nominally non-contingent one-period bonds denominated in domestic currency. The

    only assets traded internationally are nominally non-contingent one-period bonds denominated in

    the currency of Ñ . There is also complete home bias in ownership of domestic firms. In addition

    equity is not traded in domestic financial markets, instead households receive lump-sum dividend

    payments. This assumption is required to support our assumption that firm and not just household

    preferences feature myopia.

    2 The alternative of using habit persistence to generate consumption inertia is not availablein our setup. This is because we face two constraints in our choice of household preferences. The first is that

    preferences must be consistent with balanced growth. The second is the necessity of beingable to aggregate across generations of households. We are left with preferences that, while commonly used,

    do not allow for a powerful role of habit persistence.

    4

  • OLG HH(HO) OLG HH(RW)LIQHH(HO) LIQHH(RW)

    lOLG lLIQ

    L=U

    Unions (HO)

    cOLG cLIQ

    Inv. Producers (HO)

    ZD

    NTG(HO)

    Manufacturers

    YN ZT

    YTF

    YT

    IN IT

    KTKNUN UT

    G

    Gov’t (HO)

    Import Adj. Costs

    Sticky Prices Sticky Prices

    Sticky

    Wages

    Unions (RW)

    L*=U*

    l*OLGc*OLGl*LIQc*LIQ

    C*

    Z*D

    U*N

    Tradables (RW)Manufacturers

    Nontradables (RW)ManufacturersI

    *NI*T

    K*T K*N

    Z*T Y*N

    Y*TF

    Y*TSticky Prices Sticky Prices

    Retailers (HO)

    Sticky Quantities

    KG

    YTH Y*TH

    Gov’t (RW)

    G*

    K*GYA

    YIH YIF

    Sticky Prices ImportAgents(HO)

    ImportAgents(RW) Y

    *A

    Y*IF Y*IH

    Sticky Prices

    ZN Z*N

    ImportAgents

    (HO)

    Import

    Agents(HO)YCH

    Cons. Producers (HO)

    YCF

    CretSticky Prices

    ImportAgents

    (RW)

    ImportAgents(RW)

    Inv. Producers (RW)

    Y*CF

    Sticky Prices

    Y*CH

    Cons. Producers(RW)

    Distributors

    (HO)

    Distributors

    (RW)

    Import Adj. Costs

    GIMF

    TG(HO)

    Manufacturers

    EPs EPs EPsEPs U*T

    Oil (HO)

    XN XT

    WorldOil Market

    X*T

    Oil (RW)

    Inv.Adj.Costs Inv.Adj.Costs

    X*N

    Sticky Wages

    XC

    C Retailers (RW)

    XC* Cret*

    Figure 1

    5

  • 2 Overlapping Generations Households

    We first describe the optimization problem of OLG households. A representative member of this

    group and of age a derives utility at time t from consumption cOLGa,t , leisure (SLt − �OLGa,t ) (where SLt

    is the stochastic time endowment, which has a mean of one but which can itself be a function of the

    business cycle, see below), and real balances (Ma,t/PRt ) (where P

    Rt is the retail price index). The

    lifetime expected utility of a representative household of age a at time t has the form

    Et

    ∞∑

    s=0

    (βtθ)s

    [1

    1− γ((cOLGa+s,t+s

    )ηOLG (SLt − �OLGa+s,t+s

    )1−ηOLG)1−γ+

    um

    1− γ

    (Ma+s,t+sPRt+s

    )1−γ]

    ,

    (1)

    where Et is the expectations operator, θ < 1 is the degree of myopia, γ > 0 is the coefficient of

    relative risk aversion, 0 < ηOLG < 13, um > 0, and βt is the (stochastic) discount factor. As

    for money demand, in the following analysis we will only consider the case of the cashless limit

    advocated by Woodford (2003), where um −→ 0. As a result the optimality conditions for moneywill be ignored throughout our analysis. Note that this does not involve a great loss of generality in

    our case, and in fact it has one major advantage. The reason is that the combination of separable

    money in the utility function and monetary policy specified as an interest rate rule implies that

    the money demand equation becomes redundant and that inflation is not directly distortionary for

    the consumption-leisure decision. But money also has a fiscal role through the government budget

    constraint, and any reduction in inflation tax revenue must be accompanied by an offsetting increase

    in other forms of distortionary taxation.4 Because of this indirect distortionary effect, an increase in

    inflation in this model would actually reduce overall distortions unless we consider the case of the

    cashless limit, in which case inflation causes no distortions in either direction.

    3 For flexible model calibration we allow for the possibility that OLG households attacha different weight ηOLG to consumption than liquidity constrained households. This allows us to model bothgroups as working during an equal share of their time endowment in steady state, while OLGhouseholds have much higher consumption due to their accumulated wealth.4 Except for the special case of lump-sum taxation.

    6

  • Consumption cOLGa,t is given by a CES aggregate over retailed consumption goods varieties

    cOLGa,t (i), with elasticity of substitution σR:

    cOLGa,t =

    (∫ 1

    0

    (cOLGa,t (i)

    )σR−1σR di

    ) σRσR−1

    . (2)

    This gives rise to a demand for individual varieties

    cOLGa,t (i) =

    (PRt (i)

    PRt

    )−σRcOLGa,t , (3)

    where PRt (i) is the retail price of variety i, and the aggregate retail price level PRt is given by

    PRt =

    (∫ 1

    0

    (PRt (i)

    )1−σRdi

    ) 11−σR

    . (4)

    A household can hold two types of bonds. The first bond type is domestic bonds denominated

    in domestic currency. Such bonds are issued either by the domestic government Ba,t or, in the case

    of GIMF with a Financial Accelerator, by banks lending to the nontradables or tradables sector,

    BNa,t +BTa,t. The second bond type is foreign bonds denominated in the currency of country Ñ , Fa,t.

    The nominal exchange rate vis-a-vis Ñ is denoted by Et, and EtFa,t are nominal net foreign assetholdings in terms of domestic currency. In each case the time subscript t denotes financial claims

    held from period t to period t + 1. Gross nominal interest rates on domestic and foreign currency

    denominated assets held from t to t + 1 are it/(1 + ξbt) and it(Ñ)(1 + ξ

    ft ). For domestic bonds,

    it is the nominal interest rate paid by the domestic government and ξbt is a domestic risk premium,

    with ξbt < 0 characterizing a situation where the private sector faces a larger marginal funding rate

    than the public sector. For foreign bonds, it(Ñ) is the nominal interest rate determined in Ñ , and ξft

    is a foreign exchange risk premium. For country Ñ , it = it(Ñ) and ξft = 0. Both risk premia are

    external to the household’s asset accumulation decision, and are payable to a financial intermediary

    that redistributes the proceeds in a lump-sum fashion either to foreigners or to domestic households.

    The functional form of the foreign exchange risk premium is given by

    ξft = y1 +y2(

    cagdpfiltt − y4)y3 + S

    fxt , (5)

    cagdpfiltt = Et

    (Σkcahk=kcal

    100cat+jgdpt+j

    )/ (kcah − kcal + 1) , (6)

    7

  • where Sfxt is a mean zero risk premium shock, y1 − y4 are parameters, y1 is constrained to generatea zero premium at a zero current account by the condition y1 = −y2/ (−y4)y3 , and cagdpfiltt is amoving average of past and future current account to GDP ratios, with kcah the maximum lead and

    kcal the maximum lag. We have found this functional form to be more suitable for applied work than

    conventional linear specifications because it is asymmetric, allowing for a steeply increasing risk

    premium at large current account deficits.

    The functional form of the domestic risk premium can similarly be made to depend on the

    government debt to GDP ratio when it is intended to highlight the effect of government borrowing

    levels on domestic interest rates. But it can also be treated as an exogenous stochastic process when

    the emphasis is on shocks to the interest rate margin between the policy rate and the rate at which the

    private sector can access the domestic capital market. For example, recent financial markets events

    may be partly characterized by a persistent negative shock to ξbt .

    Participation by households in financial markets requires that they enter into an insurance contract

    with companies that pay a premium of(1−θ)θ on a household’s financial wealth for each period in

    which that household is alive, and that encash the household’s entire financial wealth in the event of

    his death.5

    Apart from returns on financial assets, households also receive labor and dividend income.

    Households sell their labor to “unions” that are competitive in their input market and monopolistically

    competitive in their output market, vis-à-vis manufacturing firms. The productivity of a household’s

    labor declines throughout his lifetime, with productivity Φa,t = Φa of age group a given by

    Φa = κχa , (7)

    where χ < 1. The overall population’s average productivity is assumed without loss of generality to

    be equal to one. Household pre-tax nominal labor income is therefore WtΦa,t�OLGa,t . Dividends

    are received in a lump-sum fashion from all firms in the nontradables (N) and tradables (T )

    manufacturing sectors, from the distribution (D), consumption goods distribution (C) and investment

    goods distribution (I) sectors, from the retail (R) sector and the import agent (M) sector, from

    all unions (U ) in the labor market, from domestic (X) and foreign (F ) raw materials producers,

    5 The turnover in the population is assumed to be large enough that the income receipts

    of the insurance companies exactly equal their payouts.

    8

  • from capital goods producers (K), and from entrepreneurs (EP ) (only in GIMF with Financial

    Accelerator), with after-tax nominal dividends received from firm/union i denoted by Dja,t(i),

    j = N,T,D,C, I, R, U,M,X,F,K,EP . OLG households are liable to pay lump-sum transfers

    τOLGTa,t to the government, which in turn redistributes them to the relatively less well off LIQ agents.

    Household labor income is taxed at the rate τL,t, and consumption is taxed at the rate τ c,t. In addition

    there are lump-sum taxes τ lsa,t and transfers Υa,t paid to/from the government.6 It is assumed that

    retailers face costs of rapidly adjusting their sales volume. To limit these costs they therefore offer

    incentives (or disincentives) that are incorporated into the effective retail purchase price PRt . The

    consumption tax τ c,t is however assumed to be payable on the pre-incentive price PCt .

    7 PCt is

    the marginal cost of retailers, who combine the output of consumption goods producers, with price

    level Pt, with raw materials used directly by consumers, with price level PXt . We choose Pt as our

    numeraire, and denote the real wage bywt = Wt/Pt, the relative price of any good x by pxt = P

    xt /Pt,

    gross inflation for any good x by πxt = Pxt /P

    xt−1, and gross nominal exchange rate depreciation by

    εt = Et/Et−1.8

    The household’s budget constraint in nominal terms is

    PRt cOLGa,t + P

    Ct cOLGa,t τ c,t + Ptτ

    lsa,t + Ba,t + B

    Na,t + B

    Ta,t + EtFa,t (8)

    =1

    θ

    [it−1

    (1 + ξbt−1)

    (Ba−1,t−1 + B

    Na−1,t−1 + B

    Ta−1,t−1

    )+ it−1(Ñ)EtFa−1,t−1(1 + ξft−1)

    ]

    +WtΦa,t�OLGa,t (1− τL,t) +

    j=N,T,D,C,I,R,U,M,X,F,K,EP

    1∫

    0

    Dja,t(i)di− τOLGTa,t + PtΥa,t .

    The OLG household maximizes (1) subject to (2), (7) and (8). The derivation of the first-

    order conditions for each generation, and aggregation across generations, is discussed in detail in

    Appendices A and B. Aggregation takes account of the size of each age cohort at the time of birth, and

    of the remaining size of each generation. Using the example of overlapping generations households’

    6 It is sometimes convenient to keep these two items separate when trying to account for

    a country’s overall fiscal structure, and when allowing for targeted transfers to LIQ agents.7 Without this assumption consumption tax revenue could become too volatile in the short run.8 We adopt the convention throughout the paper that all nominal price level variables are

    written in upper case letters, and that all relative price variables are written in lower case letters.

    9

  • consumption, we have

    cOLGt = Nnt(1− ψ)

    (1− θ

    n

    )Σ∞a=0

    n

    )acOLGa,t . (9)

    This also has implications for the intercept parameter κ of the age-specific productivity distribution.

    Under the assumption of an average productivity of one, and for given parameters χ and θ, we

    obtain κ = (n − θχ)/(n − θ). Several of the optimality conditions that need to be aggregatedare, or are derived from, nonlinear Euler equations. In such conditions, aggregation requires

    nonlinear transformations that are only valid under certainty equivalence. Tractable aggregate

    consumption optimality conditions therefore only exist for the cases of perfect foresight and of first-

    order approximations. For our purposes this is not problematic as all applications of GIMF will use

    at most log-linear approximations. However, for the purpose of exposition we find it preferable to

    present optimality conditions in nonlinear form. We therefore adopt the notation Ẽt to denote an

    expectations operator that is understood in this fashion.

    The first-order conditions for the goods varieties and for the consumption/leisure choice are given

    by

    čOLGt (i) =

    (PRt (i)

    PRt

    )−σRčOLGt , (10)

    čOLGtN(1− ψ)SLt − �̌OLGt

    =ηOLG

    1− ηOLG w̌t(1− τL,t)

    (pRt + pCt τ c,t)

    . (11)

    The arbitrage condition for foreign currency bonds (the uncovered interest parity relation) is given

    by

    it = it(Ñ)(1 + ξft )(1 + ξ

    bt)Ẽtεt+1 . (12)

    The consumption Euler equation on the other hand cannot be directly aggregated across generations.

    For each generation we have

    Etca+1,t+1 = Etjtca,t , (13)

    jt =

    řt+1

    ) 1γ

    (pRt + p

    Ct τ c,t

    pRt+1 + pCt+1τ c,t+1

    ) 1γ

    (

    χgw̌t+1(1− τL,t+1)(pRt + pCt τ c,t)w̌t(1− τL,t)(pRt+1 + pCt+1τ c,t+1)

    )(1−ηOLG)(1− 1γ)

    .

    (14)

    10

  • Here we have used the notation

    řt =it−1

    πt(1 + ξbt−1

    ) =rt(

    1 + ξbt−1) . (15)

    We introduce some additional notation. The production based real exchange rate vis-a-vis Ñ is

    et = (EtPt(Ñ))/Pt, where Pt(Ñ) is the price of final output in Ñ . We adopt the convention thateach nominal asset is deflated by the final output price index of the currency of its denomination, so

    that real domestic bonds are bt = Bt/Pt and real foreign bonds are ft = Ft/Pt(Ñ). The real interest

    rate in terms of final output payable by the government is rt = it/πt+1, while the real interest

    rate payable by the private sector is řt = (it/πt+1) /(1 + ξbt

    ). The subjective and market nominal

    discount factors are given by

    R̃t,s = Πsl=1

    θ(1 + ξbt+l−1

    )

    it+l−1for s > 0 ( = 1 for s = 0) , (16)

    Rt,s = Πsl=1

    (1 + ξbt+l−1

    )

    it+l−1for s > 0 ( = 1 for s = 0) , (17)

    and the subjective and market real discount factors by

    r̃t,s = Πsl=1

    θ

    řt+l−1for s > 0 ( = 1 for s = 0) , (18)

    rt,s = Πsl=1

    1

    řt+l−1for s > 0 ( = 1 for s = 0) . (19)

    In each case the subjective discount factor incorporates an agent’s probability of economic death,

    which ceteris paribus makes him value near term receipts more highly than receipts in the distant

    future.

    We now discuss a key condition of GIMF, the optimal aggregate consumption rule of OLG

    households. The derivation of this condition is algebraically complex and is therefore presented

    in Appendix C. The final result expresses current aggregate consumption of OLG households as

    a function of their real aggregate financial wealth fwt and human wealth hwt, with the marginal

    propensity to consume of out of wealth given by 1/Θt. Human wealth is in turn composed of hwLt ,

    the expected present discounted value of households’ time endowments evaluated at the after-tax

    real wage, and hwKt , the expected present discounted value of capital or dividend income net of

    lump-sum transfer payments to the government. After rescaling by technology we have

    11

  • čOLGt Θt = f̌wt + ȟwt , (20)

    where

    f̌wt =1

    πtgn

    [it−1(

    1 + ξbt−1) b̌t−1 + it−1(Ñ)(1 + ξ

    ft−1)εtf̌t−1et−1

    ]

    , (21)

    ȟwt = ȟwLt + ȟw

    Kt , (22)

    ȟwLt =(N(1− ψ)(w̌t(1− τL,t)SLt )

    )+ Ẽt

    θχg

    řt+1ȟwLt+1 , (23)

    ȟwKt =(

    Σj=N,T,D,C,I,R,U,M,X,F,K,EP ďjt − τ̌OLGT,t + Υ̌OLGt − τ̌ ls,OLGt

    )+ Ẽt

    θg

    řt+1ȟwKt+1 , (24)

    Θt =pRt + p

    Ct τ c,t

    ηOLG+ Ẽt

    θjtřt+1

    Θt+1 . (25)

    The intuition of (20) is key to GIMF. Financial wealth (21) is equal to the domestic government’s and

    foreign households’ current financial liabilities. For the government debt portion, the government

    services these liabilities through different forms of taxation, and these future taxes are reflected in the

    different components of human wealth (22) as well as in the marginal propensity to consume (25).

    But unlike the government, which is infinitely lived, an individual household factors in that he might

    not be around by the time higher future tax payments fall due. Hence a household discounts future

    tax liabilities by a rate of at least řt/θ, which is higher than the market rate řt, as reflected in the

    discount factors in (23), (24) and (25). The discount rate for the labor income component of human

    wealth is even higher at řt/θχ, due to the decline of labor incomes over individuals’ lifetimes.

    A fiscal consolidation through higher taxes represents a tilting of the tax payment profile from the

    more distant future to the near future, so as to effect a reduction in the debt stock. The government

    has to respect its intertemporal budget constraint in effecting this tilting, and this means that the

    expected present discounted value of its future primary surpluses has to remain equal to the current

    debt it−1bt−1/πt when future surpluses are discounted at the market interest rate rt. But when

    individual households discount future taxes at a higher rate than the government, the same tilting

    12

  • of the tax profile represents a decrease in human wealth because it increases the expected value of

    future taxes for which the household expects to be responsible. This is true both for the direct effect

    of labor income taxes on labor income receipts, and for the indirect effect of corporate taxes on

    dividend receipts. For a given marginal propensity to consume, these reductions in human wealth

    lead to a reduction in consumption. Note that with ξbt < 0 this effect is not only due to myopia but

    also to the borrowing spread between the public and private sectors.

    The marginal propensity to consume 1/Θt is, in the simplest case of logarithmic utility and

    exogenous labor supply, equal to (1 − βθ). For the case of endogenous labor supply, householdwealth can be used to either enjoy leisure or to generate purchasing power to buy goods. The main

    determinant of the split between consumption and leisure is the consumption share parameter ηOLG,

    which explains its presence in the marginal propensity to consume (25). While other forms of taxation

    affect the different components of wealth, the time profile of consumption taxes affects the marginal

    propensity to consume, reducing it with a balanced-budget shift of such taxes from the future to the

    present. The intertemporal elasticity of substitution 1/γ is another key parameter for the marginal

    propensity to consume. For the conventional assumption of γ > 1 the income effect of an increase

    in the real interest rate r is stronger than the substitution effect and tends to increase the marginal

    propensity to consume, thereby partly offsetting the contractionary effects of a higher r on human

    wealth ȟwt. Larger γ therefore tends to give rise to larger interest rate changes in response to fiscal

    shocks.

    Finally, we allow for a variable utility value of a household’s time endowment. What we have

    in mind is that as households increase their consumption relative to the balanced growth path, this

    increases their sense of well-being not only directly, but also indirectly by making them value their

    time endowment more highly. Consequently they are willing to work more and still derive an

    increased utility value from the remaining leisure. This effect is however temporary in that the rate

    of increase in the value of their time endowment increases in the rate of increase in (normalized)

    consumption relative to a moving average of past (normalized) consumption, so that a permanent

    increase in consumption does not ultimately lead to a permanent increase in the time endowment.

    13

  • Furthermore, the strength of this effect can be calibrated by choosing the parameter toil. We have

    SLt − 1 = toil ∗(čOLGt

    čfiltt− 1)

    , (26)

    čfiltt =(

    Σkc

    j=1ωcj čOLGt−j

    )/kc , (27)

    where Σkc

    j=1ωcj = 1. We introduce this effect because it addresses a common problem with household

    preferences in calibrated DSGE models. Namely, as can be seen by inspecting (11), the model would

    ordinarily suggest that an increase in consumption demand is accompanied by an increase in the

    demand for leisure, and therefore by lower labor supply, a lower marginal productivity of capital,

    and therefore lower investment. To interpret the fact that in the data consumption, investment and

    employment show a positive comovement, the model would have to assign a major role to supply

    shocks that do generate such comovement. This is unsatisfactory because intuition suggests that

    standard demand shocks also generate a positive comovement. The specification (26), depending on

    the parameter toil, generates such comovement for all shocks by generating a positive comovement

    between consumption and labor supply.

    3 Liquidity Constrained Households

    The objective function of liquidity constrained (LIQ) households is assumed to be nearly

    identical to that of OLG households:9

    Et

    ∞∑

    s=0

    (βθ)s[

    1

    1− γ

    ((cLIQa+s,t+s

    )ηLIQ (SLt − �LIQa+s,t+s

    )1−ηLIQ)1−γ]

    , (28)

    cLIQa,t =

    (∫ 1

    0

    (cLIQa,t (i)

    )σR−1σR di

    ) σRσR−1

    . (29)

    These agents can consume at most their current income, which consists of their after tax wage income

    plus government transfers τLIQTa,t . Their budget constraint is

    PRt cLIQa,t + P

    Ct cLIQa,t τ c,t �WtΦa,t�

    LIQa,t (1− τL,t) + τ

    LIQTa,t

    + ΥLIQa,t − τls,LIQa,t . (30)

    9 The distinction of generations could be dropped as all agents must act identically.

    14

  • The aggregated first-order conditions for this problem, after rescaling by technology, are

    čLIQt (i) =

    (PRt (i)

    PRt

    )−σRčLIQt , (31)

    čLIQt (pRt + p

    Ct τ c,t) = w̌t�

    LIQt (1− τL,t) + τ̌

    LIQT,t + Υ̌

    LIQt − τ̌

    ls,LIQt , (32)

    čLIQt

    NψSLt − �̌LIQt=

    ηLIQ

    1− ηLIQ w̌t(1− τL,t)

    (pRt + pCt τ c,t)

    . (33)

    GIMF also allows for an alternative version where equation (33) is dropped and is replaced with an

    exogenous labor supply, the so-called “rule of thumb consumer”.

    4 Aggregate Household Sector

    To obtain aggregate consumption demand and labor supply we simply add the respective

    optimality quantities of the different consumers in the economy. For GIMF without a Financial

    Accelerator these are OLG and LIQ households:

    Čt = čOLGt + č

    LIQt , (34)

    Ľt = �̌OLGt + �̌

    LIQt . (35)

    15

  • 5 Manufacturers

    There is a continuum of manufacturing firms indexed by i ∈ [0, 1] in two separate manufacturingsectors indexed by J ∈ {N,T}, whereN represents nontradables and T tradables. For prices in thesetwo sectors we introduce a slightly different index J̃ ∈ {N,TH}, because the index T for pricesis reserved for a different goods aggregate produced by distributors (see below). Manufacturers

    buy labor inputs from unions and capital inputs from capital goods producers. Sector N and T

    manufacturers sell to domestic distributors, and sector T manufacturers also sell to import agents in

    foreign countries, who in turn sell to distributors in those countries.10 Manufacturers are perfectly

    competitive in their input markets and monopolistically competitive in the market for their output.

    Their price setting is subject to nominal rigidities. We first analyze the demands for their output, then

    turn to their technology, and finally describe their optimization problem.

    Demands for manufacturers’ output varieties are given by

    Y Jt (z) =

    1∫

    0

    Y Jt (z, i)σJ−1

    σJ di

    σJσJ−1

    , Y TXt (1, j, z) =

    1∫

    0

    Y TXt (1, j, z, i)σJ−1

    σJ di

    σJσJ−1

    ,

    (36)

    where Y Jt (z, i) and YJt (z) are variety i and total demands from domestic distributor z in sector J ,

    and Y TXt (1, j, z, i) and YTXt (1, j, z) are variety i and total demands for exports from country 1 to

    import agent z in country j. Cost minimization by distributors and import agents generates demands

    for varieties

    Y Jt (z, i) =

    (P J̃t (i)

    P J̃t

    )−σJY Jt (z) , Y

    TXt (1, j, z, i) =

    (PTHt (i)

    PTHt

    )−σJY TXt (1, j, z) , (37)

    with price indices defined as

    P J̃t =

    1∫

    0

    P J̃t (i)1−σJdi

    1

    1−σJ

    . (38)

    10 There are also some small sales of aggregate manufacturing output back to manufacturing

    firms, related to manufacturers’ need for resources to pay for adjustment costs.

    16

  • The aggregate demand for variety i produced by sector J can be derived by simply integrating over

    all distributors, import agents and all other sources of manufacturing output demand. We obtain

    ZJt (i) =

    (P J̃t (i)

    P J̃t

    )−σJZJt , (39)

    where ZJt (i) and ZJt remain to be specified by way of market clearing conditions for manufacturing

    goods.

    The technology of each manufacturing firm differs depending on whether the raw materials sector

    is included. If it is included, the technology is given by a CES production function in capital KJt−1(i),

    union labor UJt (i) and raw materials XJt (i), with elasticities of substitution ξZJ between capital and

    labor, and ξXJ between raw materials and capital/labor. An adjustment cost GJX,t(i) makes fast

    changes in raw materials inputs costly. Labor augmenting productivity is TtAJt , where A

    Jt is a

    country specific technology shock:11,12

    ZJt (i) = F (KJt−1(i), U

    Jt (i), X

    Jt (i)) (40)

    = T

    ((1− αXJt

    ) 1ξXJ

    (MJt (i)

    ) ξXJ−1ξXJ +

    (αXJt) 1ξXJ

    (XJt (i)

    (1−GJX,t(i)

    )) ξXJ−1ξXJ

    ) ξXJξXJ−1

    ,

    MJt (i) =

    ((1− αUJ

    ) 1ξZJ

    (KJt−1(i)

    ) ξZJ−1ξZJ +

    (αUJ) 1ξZJ

    (TtA

    Jt UJt (i)

    ) ξZJ−1ξZJ

    ) ξZJξZJ−1

    .

    If the raw materials sector is not included, the technology is given by a CES production function in

    capital KJt (i) and union labor UJt (i), with elasticity of substitution ξZJ between capital and labor:

    ZJt (i) = F (KJt−1(i), U

    Jt (i)) (41)

    = T

    ((1− αUJ

    ) 1ξZJ

    (KJt−1(i)

    ) ξZJ−1ξZJ +

    (αUJ) 1ξZJ

    (TtA

    Jt UJt (i)

    ) ξZJ−1ξZJ

    ) ξZJξZJ−1

    .

    We will from now on mostly ignore the version without raw materials sector, for which the optimality

    conditions can be derived in the same fashion as below.

    11 Note that, for the sake of clarity, we make a notational distinction between two types of

    elasticities of substitution. Elasticities between continua of goods varieties, which give riseto market and pricing power, are denoted by a σ subscripted by the respective sectorial indicator.Elasticities between factors of production, both in manufacturing and in final goods distribution, are denotedby a ξ subscripted by the respective sectorial indicator.12 The factor T is a constant that can be set different from one to obtain different levelsof GDP per capita across countries.

    17

  • Manufacturing firms are subject to three types of adjustment costs. First, quadratic inflation

    adjustment costs GJP,t(i) are real resource costs that represent a demand for the output of sector J .

    Following Ireland (2001) and Laxton and Pesenti (2003), they are quadratic in changes in the rate of

    inflation rather than in price levels, which is essential in order to generate realistic inflation dynamics.

    Compared to versions of the Calvo (1983) price setting assumption such adjustment costs have the

    advantage of greater analytical tractability. We have:

    GJP,t(i) =φP J

    2ZJt

    P J̃t (i)

    P J̃t−1(i)

    P J̃t−1

    P J̃t−2

    − 1

    2

    . (42)

    To allow a flexible choice of inflation adjustment costs we also allow for a version of Rotemberg

    (1982) sticky prices, whereby deviations of the actual inflation rate from the inflation target π̄t are

    costly. These may sometimes be preferable when working with a fixed exchange rates model, where

    sticky inflation can give rise to strong cycles. These costs are given by13

    GJP,t(i) =φP J

    2ZJt

    (P J̃t (i)

    P J̃t−1(i)− π̄t

    )2. (43)

    Second, adjustment costs on raw materials inputs are given by14

    GJX,t(i) =φJX2

    ((XJt (i)/ (gn))−XJt−1

    XJt−1

    )2, (44)

    the term gn enters to ensure that adjustment costs are zero along the balanced growth path.

    Third, adjustment costs on labor hiring are given by

    GJU,t(i) =φU2UJt

    ((UJt (i)/n)− UJt−1(i)

    UJt−1(i)

    )2. (45)

    These costs are somewhat less common in the business cycle literature, and are only included as an

    option that can be switched off by setting φU = 0.

    It is assumed that each firm pays out each period’s after tax nominal net cash flow as dividends

    DJt (i). It maximizes the expected present discounted value of dividends. The discount rate it applies

    in this maximization includes the parameter θ so as to equate the discount factor of firms θ/řt with

    the pricing kernel for nonfinancial income streams of their owners, myopic households, which equals

    13 In all other instances of nominal rigidities that follow, GIMF offers this as one option.It will however not be mentioned again in this document.14 Note that, unlike other adjustment costs, this expression treats lagged inputs as external.

    This has proved more useful than the alternatives in our applied work.

    18

  • βθEt (λa+1,t+1/λa,t). This equality follows directly from OLG households’ first order condition for

    government debt holdings λa,t = βEt

    (λa+1,t+1

    itπt+1(1+ξbt)

    ).

    Pre-tax net cash flow equals nominal revenue P J̃t (i)ZJt (i) minus nominal cash outflows. The

    latter include the wage bill VtUJt (i), where Vt is the aggregate wage rate charged by unions,

    spending on raw materials PXt XJt (i), where P

    Xt is the price of raw materials, and the cost of

    capital RJk,tKJt−1(i), where R

    KJ

    t is the nominal rental cost of capital in sector J , with the real

    cost denoted rJk,t. Other components of pre-tax cash flow are price adjustment costs PJ̃t GJP,t(i)

    that represent a demand for sectorial manufacturing output ZJt , labor adjustment costs VtGU,t(i)

    that represent a demand for labor Lt, and a fixed cost PJ̃t Ttω

    J . The fixed resource cost arises as

    long as the firm chooses to produce positive output. Net output in sector J is therefore equal to

    max(0, ZJt (i) − TtωJ). The fixed cost is calibrated to make the steady state shares of economicprofits, labor and capital in GDP consistent with the data. This becomes necessary because the

    model counterpart of the aggregate income share of capital equals not only the return to capital

    but also the profits of monopolistically competitive firms. With several layers of such firms the

    profits share becomes significant, and the capital share parameter in the production function has to

    be reduced accordingly, unless fixed costs are assumed. More importantly, the introduction of an

    additional parameter determining fixed costs allows us to simultaneously calibrate not only capital

    income shares and depreciation rates but also the investment to GDP ratio. This would otherwise be

    impossible. We calibrate fixed costs by first noting that, in normalized form, steady state monopoly

    profits equal ŽJt /σJ . We denote by sπ the share of these profits that remain after fixed costs have been

    paid, and we will calibrate this parameter to obtain the desired investment to GDP ratio. We assume

    that sπ is identical across the industries where fixed costs arise. Then fixed costs in manufacturing

    are given by

    ωJ =Z̄J

    σJ(1− sπ) . (46)

    The total after tax net cash flow or dividend of the firm is

    DJt (i) = PJ̃t (i)Z

    Jt (i)− VtUJt (i)−PXt XJt (i)−RJk,tKJt−1(i)−P J̃t TtωJ −P J̃t GJP,t(i)− VtGJU,t(i) .

    (47)

    19

  • The optimization problem of each manufacturing firm is

    Max{P J̃t+s(i),UJt+s(i),KJt+s−1(i),XJt+s(i)}∞s=0

    EtΣ∞s=0R̃t,sD

    Jt+s(i) , (48)

    subject to the definition of dividends (47), demands (39), production functions (40), and adjustment

    costs (42)-(45). The first-order conditions for this problem are derived in some detail in Appendix D.

    A key step is to recognize that all firms behave identically in equilibrium, so that P J̃t (i) = PJ̃t and

    ZJt (i) = ZJt . Let λ

    Jt denote the real marginal cost of producing an additional unit of manufacturing

    output. Also, rescale the optimality conditions by technology and population as discussed above.

    Then the condition for P J̃t (i) under sticky inflation is[σJ

    σJ − 1λJt

    pJ̃t− 1]

    =φP J

    σJ − 1

    (πJ̃t

    πJ̃t−1

    )(πJ̃t

    πJ̃t−1− 1)

    (49)

    −Etθgn

    řt+1

    φPJ

    σJ − 1pJ̃t+1

    pJ̃t

    ŽJt+1ŽJt

    (πJ̃t+1

    πJ̃t

    )(πJ̃t+1

    πJ̃t− 1)

    ,

    while under sticky prices we have[

    σJσJ − 1

    λJt

    pJ̃t− 1]

    =φPJ

    σJ − 1πJ̃t

    (πJ̃t − π̄t

    )(50)

    −Etθgn

    řt+1

    φPJ

    σJ − 1pJ̃t+1

    pJ̃t

    ŽJt+1ŽJt

    πJ̃t+1

    (πJ̃t+1 − π̄t

    ).

    The first order condition for labor demand UJt (i) is(λJtv̌tF̌ JU,t − 1

    )= φU

    (Ǔt

    Ǔt−1

    )(Ǔt − Ǔt−1Ǔt−1

    )− θgnřt+1

    φUv̌t+1v̌t

    (Ǔt+1

    Ǔt

    )2(Ǔt+1 − Ǔt

    Ǔt

    ), (51)

    where F̌ JU,t is the marginal product of labor

    F̌ JU,t = T((

    1− αXJt)ŽJt

    T M̌Jt

    ) 1ξXJ

    AJt

    (αUJ M̌

    Jt

    AJt ǓJt

    ) 1ξZJ

    . (52)

    The first order condition for raw materials demand XJt (i) is

    pXt = λJt F̌JX,t , (53)

    where F̌ JX,t is the marginal product of raw materials

    F̌ JX,t = T

    αXJtŽJt

    T X̌Jt(

    1−GJX,t)

    1

    ξXJ(

    1−GJX,t − φJXX̌JtX̌Jt−1

    (X̌Jt − X̌Jt−1

    X̌Jt−1

    ))

    . (54)

    20

  • The first-order condition for capital demand is

    rJk,t = λJt F̌JK,t , (55)

    where F̌ JK,t is the marginal product of capital

    F̌ JK,t = T((

    1− αXJt)ŽJt

    T M̌Jt

    ) 1ξXJ

    ((1− αUJ

    )M̌Jt(

    ǨJt−1/ (gn))

    ) 1ξZJ

    . (56)

    For the sake of completeness we add here the marginal products of labor and capital for the version

    of GIMF without raw materials. They are

    F̌ JU,t = T AJt(αUJ Ž

    Jt

    AJt ǓJt

    ) 1ξZJ

    , (57)

    F̌ JK,t = T( (

    1− αUJ)ŽJt(

    ǨJt−1/ (gn))

    ) 1ξZJ

    . (58)

    Rescaled aggregate dividends of firms in each sector are

    ďJt =[pJ̃t Ž

    Jt − v̌tǓJt − pXt X̌Jt − rJk,t

    (ǨJt−1/ (gn)

    )− v̌tǦJU,t − pJ̃t ǦJP,t − pJ̃t ωJ

    ]. (59)

    We define aggregate capital and investment as

    Ǐt = ǏNt + Ǐ

    Tt , (60)

    Ǩt = ǨNt + Ǩ

    Tt . (61)

    Finally, we turn to the market clearing conditions for nontradables and tradables. They equate

    the output of each sector to the demands of distributors, of manufacturers themselves for fixed and

    adjustment costs, and in the case of tradables to the demands of foreign import agents. We have15

    ŽNt = Y̌Nt + ω

    N + ǦNP,t + rcuNt + rbr

    Nt + Š

    N,nwyshkt , (62)

    ŽTt (1) = Y̌THt (1) + ω

    T (1) + ǦTP,t(1) + rcuTt + rbr

    Tt + Š

    T,nwyshkt + p̃

    expt Σ

    Ñj=2Y̌

    TXt (1, j) , (63)

    15 The tradables market clearing condition is reported for the example of country 1.

    21

  • where rcuJt is the resource cost associated with variable capital utilization, rbrJt is the resource

    cost due to bankruptcies (in GIMF with Financial Accelerator), and ŠJ,nwyshkt is the net effect of

    entrepreneurs’ output destroying net worth shocks (in GIMF with Financial Accelerator). The term

    p̃expt in the second market clearing condition refers to unit root shocks to the relative price of exported

    goods. Specifically, tradables output is converted to exports Y̌ TXt using a technology that multiplies

    tradables output by T expt = 1/p̃expt , where p̃

    expt is a unit root shock with zero trend growth.

    6 Capital Goods Producers

    6.1 GIMF with Financial Accelerator

    These agents produce the capital stock used by entrepreneurs in the nontradables and tradables

    sectors, indexed as before by J ∈ {N,T}. They are competitive price takers. Capital goodsproducers are owned by households, who receive their dividends as lump-sum transfers. They

    purchase previously installed capital K̃Jt−1 from entrepreneurs and investment goods IJt from

    investment goods producers to produce new installed capital K̃Jt according to

    K̃Jt = K̃Jt−1 + S

    invt I

    Jt , (64)

    where Sinvt is an investment demand shock. They are subject to investment adjustment costs

    GJI,t =φI2IJt

    ((IJt /(gn))− IJt−1

    IJt−1

    )2. (65)

    The nominal price level of previously installed capital is denoted by QJt . Since the marginal rate of

    transformation from previously installed to newly installed capital is one, the price of new capital

    is also QJt . The optimization problem is to maximize the present discounted value of dividends by

    choosing the level of new investment IJt :16

    Max{IJt+s}∞s=0

    EtΣ∞s=0R̃t,sD

    KJ

    t+s , (66)

    DKJ

    t = QJt

    (K̃Jt−1 + S

    invt I

    Jt

    )−QJt K̃Jt−1 − P It

    (IJt + G

    JI,t

    ). (67)

    16 Any value of capital if profit maximizing.

    22

  • The solution to this problem is

    qJt Sinvt = p

    It + φIp

    It

    (ǏJtǏJt−1

    )(ǏJt − ǏJt−1ǏJt−1

    )

    −Etθgn

    řt+1φIp

    It+1

    (ǏJt+1ǏJt

    )2(ǏJt+1 − ǏJt

    ǏJt

    )

    . (68)

    The stock of physical capital evolves as

    K̄Jt =(1− δJKt

    )K̄Jt−1 + S

    invt I

    Jt . (69)

    We allow for shocks to the deprecation rate of capital, which in the context of the Financial

    Accelerator we will refer to as capital destroying net worth shocks:

    δJKt = δ̄JK + S

    nwkshkt . (70)

    Physical capital K̄Jt is different from the capital rented by manufacturers KJt because the stock of

    physical capital is subject to variable capital utilization uJt . The normalized relationship between

    physical capital K̄J and capital used in manufacturing KJ is therefore given by

    ǨJt−1 = uJt ǨJ

    t−1 . (71)

    The real value of dividends is given by

    ďKJ

    t = qJt Sinvt Ǐ

    Jt − pIt

    (ǏJt + Ǧ

    JI,t

    ). (72)

    We let ďKt = ďKN

    t + ďKT

    t , and also Ǐt = ǏNt + Ǐ

    Tt , K̄t = K̄

    Nt + K̄

    Tt .

    6.2 GIMF without Financial Accelerator

    Capital goods producers produce the physical capital stock K̄Jt . They rent out lagged capital

    K̄Jt−1 to manufacturers in the nontradables and tradables sectors J ∈ {N,T}, after deciding on therate of capital utilization uJt . They are competitive price takers and are subject to a capital income

    tax. Capital goods producers are owned by households, who receive their dividends as lump-sum

    transfers. The accumulation of the physical capital stock is given by

    K̄Jt =(1− δJKt

    )K̄Jt−1 + S

    invt I

    Jt . (73)

    As before, we allow for shocks to the deprecation rate of capital as in (70). Investment goods IJt are

    purchased from investment goods producers, where Sinvt is an investment demand shock. Investment

    is subject to investment adjustment costs

    GJI,t =φI2IJt

    ((IJt /(gn))− IJt−1

    IJt−1

    )2. (74)

    23

  • After observing the time t aggregate shocks the entrepreneur decides on the time t level of capital

    utilization uJt , and then rents out capital services KJt−1(j) = u

    Jt K̄Jt−1(j). High capital utilization

    gives rise to high costs in terms of sector J goods, according to the convex function a(uJt )K̄Jt−1(j),

    where we specify the adjustment cost function as17

    a(uJt ) =1

    2φJaσ

    Ja

    (uJt)2

    + φJa(1− σJa

    )uJt + φ

    Ja

    (σJa2− 1)

    . (75)

    The optimization problem is to maximize the present discounted value of dividends by choosing

    the level of new investment IJt , the level of the physical capital stock K̄Jt , and the rate of capital

    utilization uJt :

    Max{IJt+s,K̄Jt+s,uJt+s}∞s=0

    EtΣ∞s=0R̃t,sD

    KJ

    t+s , (76)

    DKJ

    t =((1− τk,t)

    (RJk,tu

    Jt − Pta(uJt )

    )+ τk,tδ

    JKtQ

    Jt

    )K̄Jt−1 − P It

    (IJt + G

    JI,t

    )(77)

    +QJt((

    1− δJKt)K̄Jt−1 + S

    invt I

    Jt − K̄Jt

    ).

    The first order conditions for investment demand IJt (i) and capital K̄Jt (i) are

    qJt Sinvt = p

    It + φIp

    It

    (ǏJtǏJt−1

    )(ǏJt − ǏJt−1ǏJt−1

    )

    −Etθgn

    řt+1φIp

    It+1

    (ǏJt+1ǏJt

    )2(ǏJt+1 − ǏJt

    ǏJt

    )

    , (78)

    qJt =θ

    řt+1Et[qJt+1(1− δJK) + (1− τk,t+1)

    (uJt+1r

    Jk,t+1 − a(uJt+1)

    )+ τk,t+1δ

    JKqJt+1

    ]. (79)

    The first order condition for capital utilization is

    rJk,t = φJaσJauJt + φ

    Ja

    (1− σJa

    ), (80)

    and the resource cost associated with variable capital utilization is

    rcuJt = a(uJt )

    (ǨJ

    t−1/ (gn)

    )/pJ̃t . (81)

    The real value of dividends is given by

    ďKJ

    t =((1− τk,t)

    (rJk,tu

    Jt − a(uJt )

    )+ τk,tδ

    JKtqJt

    )K̄Jt−1 − pIt

    (IJt + G

    JI,t

    ). (82)

    We let ďKt = ďKN

    t + ďKT

    t , and also Ǐt = ǏNt + Ǐ

    Tt , K̄t = K̄

    Nt + K̄

    Tt .

    17 This follows Christiano, Motto and Rostagno (2007), “Financial Factors in Business Cycles”.Papers where the model is linearized prior to solving it only require the elasticity σa of thefunction a(ut). Because GIMF is solved in nonlinear form we require a full functional form.

    24

  • 7 Entrepreneurs and Banks

    Entrepreneurs in sectors J ∈ {N,T} purchase a capital stock from capital goods producers andrent it to manufacturers. Each entrepreneur j finances his time t capital holdings (at current market

    prices) QJt K̄Jt (j) with a combination of his net worth N

    Jt (j) and a bank loan B

    Jt (j). His balance

    sheet constraint is therefore given by

    QJt K̄Jt (j) = N

    Jt (j) + B

    Jt (j) , (83)

    or in real normalized terms byqJt Ǩ

    J

    t (j) = ňJt (j) + b̌

    Jt (j) . (84)

    After the capital purchase each entrepreneur draws an idiosyncratic shock which changes K̄Jt (j) to

    ωJt+1K̄Jt (j) at the beginning of period t + 1, where ω

    Jt+1 is a unit mean lognormal random variable

    distributed independently over time and across entrepreneurs. The standard deviation of ln(ωJt+1),

    σJt+1, is itself a stochastic process. While the realization of ωJt+1 is not known at the time the

    entrepreneur makes his capital decision, the value of σJt+1 is known. The cumulative distribution

    function of ωJt+1 is given by Pr(ωJt+1 ≤ x) = F Jt+1(x).

    After observing the time t aggregate shocks the entrepreneur decides on the time t level of capital

    utilization uJt , and then rents out capital services KJt−1(j) = u

    Jt K̄Jt−1(j). High capital utilization

    gives rise to high costs in terms of sector J goods, according to the convex function a(uJt )ωJt K̄Jt−1(j),

    where we specify the adjustment cost function as

    a(uJt ) =1

    2φJaσ

    Ja

    (uJt)2

    + φJa(1− σJa

    )uJt + φ

    Ja

    (σJa2− 1)

    . (85)

    The entrepreneur chooses uJt to solve

    MaxuJt

    [uJt r

    Jk,t − a(uJt )

    ](1− τk,t)ωJt K̄Jt−1(j) , (86)

    which has the solutionrJk,t = φ

    JaσJauJt + φ

    Ja

    (1− σJa

    ). (87)

    The resource cost associated with variable capital utilization is given by

    rcuJt = a(uJt )

    (ǨJ

    t−1/ (gn)

    )/pJ̃t , (88)

    The entrepreneur’s real ex-post, after tax return to utilized capital is given by

    retJk,t =

    (uJt r

    Jk,t − a(uJt ) +

    (1− δJKt

    )qJt

    )− τk,t

    (uJt r

    Jk,t − a(uJt )− δJKtqJt

    )

    qJt−1. (89)

    25

  • We assume that the entrepreneur receives a standard debt contract from the bank. This specifies a

    loan amount BJt and a gross rate of interest iJB,t+1 to be paid if ω

    Jt+1 is high enough. Entrepreneurs

    who draw ωJt+1 below a cutoff level ω̄Jt+1 cannot pay this interest rate and go bankrupt. They must

    hand over everything they have to the bank, but the bank can only recover a time-varying fraction

    (1− µJt+1) of the value of such firms. The cutoff ω̄Jt+1 is defined as follows:

    ω̄Jt+1retJk,t+1Q

    Jt K̄Jt (j) = i

    JB,t+1B

    Jt (j) , (90)

    where retJk,t+1 is the nominal ex-post after tax return to utilized capital. The bank finances its loans

    to entrepreneurs by borrowing from households. We assume that the bank pays households a nominal

    rate of return ǐt = it/(1 + ξbt

    )that is not contingent on the realization of time t + 1 shocks. The

    parameters of the entrepreneur’s debt contract are chosen to maximize entrepreneurial utility, subject

    to zero profits in each state of nature for the bank and to the requirement that ǐt be non-contingent

    on time t + 1 shocks. This implies that iJB,t+1 and ω̄Jt+1 are both functions of time t + 1 aggregate

    shocks.

    The bank’s zero profit or participation constraint is given by:18

    (1− F (ω̄Jt+1)

    )iJB,t+1B

    Jt (j) +

    (1− µJt+1

    ) ∫ ω̄Jt+1

    0QJt K̄

    Jt (j)ret

    Jk,t+1ωf(ω)dω = ǐtB

    Jt (j) . (91)

    This states that the stochastic payoff to lending on the l.h.s. must equal the non-stochastic payment

    to depositors on the r.h.s. in each state of nature. The first term on the l.h.s. is the nominal interest

    income on loans for borrowers whose idiosyncratic shock exceeds the cutoff level, ωJt+1 ≥ ω̄Jt+1.The second term is the amount collected by the bank in case of the borrower’s bankruptcy, where

    ωJt+1 < ω̄Jt+1. This cash flow is based on the return ret

    Jk,t+1ω on capital investment Q

    Jt K̄Jt (j), but

    multiplied by the factor(1− µJt+1

    )to reflect a proportional bankruptcy cost µJt+1. Next we rewrite

    (91) by using (90) and (83):

    [(1− F (ω̄Jt+1)

    )ω̄Jt+1 +

    (1− µJt+1

    ) ∫ ω̄Jt+1

    0ωf(ω)dω

    ]

    retJk,t+1QJt K̄Jt (j) (92)

    = ǐtQJt K̄Jt (j)− ǐtNJt (j) .

    18 Note the absence of expectations operators because this equation has to hold in each state

    of nature. Likewise for subsequent equations.

    26

  • We adopt a number of definitions that simplify the following derivations. First, note that capital

    earnings are given by retJk,t+1QJt K̄Jt (j). The lender’s gross share in capital earnings is then defined

    as

    Γ(ω̄Jt+1) ≡∫ ω̄Jt+1

    0ωJt+1f(ω

    Jt+1)dω

    Jt+1 + ω̄

    Jt+1

    ∫ ∞

    ω̄Jt+1

    f(ωJt+1)dωJt+1 , (93)

    while his monitoring costs share in capital earnings is given by µJt+1G(ω̄Jt+1), where

    G(ω̄Jt+1) =

    ∫ ω̄Jt+1

    0ωJt+1f(ω

    Jt+1)dω

    Jt+1 . (94)

    The lender’s net share in capital earnings is therefore Γ(ω̄Jt+1) − µJt+1G(ω̄Jt+1). The entrepreneur’sshare in capital earnings on the other hand is given by

    1− Γ(ω̄Jt+1) =∫ ∞

    ω̄Jt+1

    (ωJt+1 − ω̄Jt+1

    )f(ωJt+1)dω

    Jt+1 . (95)

    Using this notation and denoting the multiplier of the participation constraint by λt, the

    entrepreneur’s optimization problem can be written as

    MaxK̄Jt (j),ω̄

    Jt+1

    (1− Γ(ω̄Jt+1)

    )retJk,t+1Q

    Jt K̄Jt (j) (96)

    +λt{(

    Γ(ω̄Jt+1)− µJt+1G(ω̄Jt+1))retJk,t+1Q

    Jt K̄Jt (j)− ǐtQJt K̄Jt (j) + ǐtNJt (j)

    }.

    Before deriving the optimality conditions we rewrite this expression by dividing through by ǐtNJt (j),

    rewriting the resulting expression in terms of normalized variables, and finally replacing nominal

    returns by real returns:

    MaxǨ

    J

    t (j),ω̄Jt+1

    (1− Γ(ω̄Jt+1)

    ) rětJk,t+1řt+1

    qJt ǨJ

    t (j)

    ňJt (j)(97)

    +λt

    (Γ(ω̄Jt+1)− µJt+1G(ω̄Jt+1)

    ) rětJk,t+1řt+1

    qJt ǨJ

    t (j)

    ňJt (j)− q

    Jt ǨJ

    t (j)

    ňJt (j)+ 1

    .

    We let ΓJt+1 = Γ(ω̄Jt+1), G

    Jt+1 = G(ω̄

    Jt+1), Γ

    ′J,t+1 = ∂Γ

    Jt+1/∂ω̄

    Jt+1 and G

    ′J,t+1 = ∂G

    Jt+1/∂ω̄

    Jt+1.

    We obtain the following first-order condition with respect to ω̄Jt+1:

    −Γ′J,t+1rětJk,t+1řt+1

    qJt ǨJ

    t (j)

    ňJt (j)+ λt

    (Γ′J,t+1 − µJt+1G′J,t+1

    ) rětJk,t+1řt+1

    qJt ǨJ

    t (j)

    ňJt (j)

    = 0 , (98)

    which implies

    27

  • λt =Γ′J,t+1

    Γ′J,t+1 − µJt+1G′J,t+1. (99)

    The condition for the optimal loan contract, that is the first-order condition with respect to ǨJ

    t (j),

    can be written using (99) as19

    (1− ΓJt

    ) rětJk,třt

    +Γ′J,t

    Γ′J,t − µJt G′J,t

    {rětJk,třt

    (ΓJt − µJt GJt

    )− 1}

    = 0 , (100)

    where we have replaced time t+1 subscripts with time t subscripts everywhere because this condition

    has to hold for each state of nature, that is it has to hold exactly ex-post. The normalized lender’s

    zero profit condition is

    qJt ǨJ

    t

    ňJt

    rětJk,t+1řt+1

    (ΓJt+1 − µJt+1GJt+1)

    )− q

    Jt ǨJ

    t

    ňJt+ 1 = 0 . (101)

    Notice that we have omitted entrepreneur specific indices j for capital and net worth and replaced

    them with the corresponding aggregate variables. This is because each entrepreneur faces the same

    returns rětJk,t+1 and řt+1, and the same risk environment characterizing the functions Γ and G.

    Aggregation of the model over entrepreneurs is then trivial because both borrowing and capital

    purchases are proportional to the entrepreneur’s level of net worth.

    A key problem for coding the Financial Accelerator version of GIMF in a standard software such

    as TROLL and DYNARE consists of finding a closed form representation for the terms ΓJt , GJt and

    their derivatives. In TROLL we can use the hard-wired (like e.g. LOG) PNORM function, which

    is the c.d.f. of the standard normal distribution. In Appendix E we therefore derive the relevant

    expressions in terms of PNORM, for which we use the notation Φ(.). We obtain the following set of

    equations, starting with an auxiliary variable z̄Jt :

    z̄Jt =ln(ω̄Jt ) +

    12

    (σJt)2

    σJt, (102)

    f(ω̄Jt)

    =1√

    2πω̄Jt σJt

    exp

    {−1

    2

    (z̄Jt)2}

    , (103)

    ΓJt = Φ(z̄Jt − σJt

    )+ ω̄Jt

    (1−Φ

    (z̄Jt))

    , (104)

    19 Note that this condition has to hold for each state of nature and at all times. When coding

    GIMF it has to be coded for time t rather than time t + 1.

    28

  • GJt = Φ(z̄Jt − σJt

    ), (105)

    Γ′J,t = 1−Φ(z̄Jt), (106)

    G′J,t = ω̄Jt f(ω̄Jt). (107)

    As for the evolution of entrepreneurial net worth, we first note that banks make zero profits at all

    times. The difference between the aggregate returns to capital net of bankruptcy costs and the sum of

    deposit interest paid by banks to households therefore goes entirely to entrepreneurs and accumulates.

    To rule out a situation where over time so much net worth accumulates that entrepreneurs no longer

    need any loans, we assume that they regularly pay out to households dividends which, in terms

    of sector J output, are given by divJt . Net worth is also subject to output destroying shocks

    SJ,nwyshkt . We assume that for an individual entrepreneur both dividends and output destroying

    shocks are proportional to his net worth, which given our above result concerning the proportionality

    of borrowing and capital purchases to net worth implies that the evolution of aggregate net worth is

    a straightforward aggregation of the evolution of entrepreneur specific net worth. Nominal aggregate

    net worth therefore evolves as

    NJt = retJk,tQ

    Jt−1Ǩ

    J

    t−1

    (1− µJt GJt

    )− ǐt−1BJt−1 − P J̃t

    (divJt + S

    J,nwyshkt

    ). (108)

    This can be combined with the aggregate version of the balance sheet constraint (83) and normalized

    to yield

    ňJt =řtgn

    ňJt−1 + qJt−1Ǩ

    J

    t−1

    (rětJk,tgn

    (1− µJt GJt

    )− řtgn

    )

    − pJ̃t(ďivJt + Š

    J,nwyshkt

    ). (109)

    Dividends in turn are given by the following expressions:

    ďivJt = iňcJt + θ

    Jnw

    (ňJt − ňJ,filtt

    )(110)

    pJ̃t iňcJt = Et

    SJ,nwdt(kincJh − kincJl + 1

    )ΣkincJh

    k=kincJl

    [ňJt+j + p

    J̃t+j

    (dǐvJt+j + Š

    J,nwyshkt+j

    )], (111)

    ňJ,filtt = EtΣknwhk=knwl

    (ňJt+j

    )/ (knwh − knwl + 1) . (112)

    Regular dividends, given by expression (111), are a fraction SJ,nwdt (with S̄J,nwd typically in a range

    between 0 and 0.05) of smoothed (moving average) gross returns on net worth invested in the previous

    29

  • period, as per equation (109), with kincJh /kincJl the maximum lead/lag of the moving average. The

    dividend related net worth shock SJ,nwdt can cause temporary losses or gains of net worth that are

    a pure redistribution between households and entrepreneurs, without direct resource implications.

    The second determinant of dividends in (110) consists of a dividend response to deviations of net

    worth from its long-run value, the latter proxied by a moving average of past and future values of

    net worth. This allows us to model dividend policy as a tool to rebuild net worth more quickly

    following a negative shock. The parameter θJnw (typically in a range between 0 and 0.05) measures

    the increase/decrease in dividends if net worth rises/falls below its long-run value. The relative price

    pJt enters because dividends are in units of sector J output while net worth is in units of final output.

    We define

    ďEPt = pNt ďiv

    Nt + p

    THt ďiv

    Tt . (113)

    Output and capital destroying net worth shocks are easier to calibrate if they are expressed as

    fractions of steady state net worth.20 We therefore adopt the definitions

    ŠJ,nwyt =pJ̃t Š

    J,nwyshkt

    n̄J, (114)

    ŠJ,nwkt =

    ŠJ,nwkshkt qJt

    ((ǨJ

    t−1

    )/ (gn)

    )

    n̄J, (115)

    and express the shock processes as autocorrelated shocks to ŠJ,nwyt and ŠJ,nwkt .

    Finally, we define the sector J bankruptcy cost, which has to be paid out of the output of sector

    J , as

    rbrJt =

    ǨJ

    t−1

    gn

    (rětJk,tq

    Jt−1µ

    Jt GJt

    )

    pJt. (116)

    8 Raw Materials Producers

    In each period each country receives an endowment flow of raw materials X̌supt that, in the

    absence of exogenous shocks, is constant in normalized terms (i.e. it grows at the rate g). This

    endowment is sold to manufacturers worldwide, with total demand for each country given by X̌demt .

    20 Dividend related shocks are easier to calibrate as they are already in terms of a share of

    gross returns on net worth.

    30

  • The value of a country’s normalized raw materials exports is therefore given by

    X̌xt = pXt (X̌

    supt − X̌demt ). (117)

    The world market for raw materials is perfectly competitive, with flexible prices that are arbitraged

    worldwide. A constant share sxd of steady state (after normalization) raw materials revenue is paid

    out to domestic factors of production as dividends d̄X . The rest is divided in fixed shares (1 − sxf )and sxf = Σ

    Ñj=2s

    xf (1, j) between payments to the government ǧ

    Xt , for the case of publicly owned

    producers, and dividends to foreign owners in all other countries f̌Xt . This means that all benefits

    of favorable raw materials price shocks accrue exclusively to the government and foreigners, and

    vice versa for unfavorable shocks. This corresponds more closely to the situation of many countries’

    raw materials sectors than the polar opposite assumption of assuming equal shares between the three

    recipients at all times. We have

    d̄X = sxd p̄XX̄sup , (118)

    f̌Xt (1, j) = sxf (1, j)

    (pXt X̌

    supt − d̄X

    ), (119)

    f̌Xt = f̌Xt (1) = Σ

    Ñj=2f̌

    Xt (1, j) , (120)

    ǧXt = pXt X̌

    supt − d̄X − f̌Xt , (121)

    where by international arbitrage we have

    pXt = pXt (Ñ)et . (122)

    The dividends received by country 1 households from ownership of country j raw materials producers

    are then given by

    ďFt (1, j) = f̌Xt (j, 1)

    et(1)

    et(j), (123)

    and aggregate dividends are

    ďFt = ďFt (1) = Σ

    Ñj=2ď

    Ft (1, j) . (124)

    The raw materials sector is subject to shocks to domestic supply X̌supt and to foreign demand, the

    latter via the raw materials share parameter in the manufacturing (αXJt) and retail (αXCt

    ) sectors. Total

    31

  • demand for each country is given by

    X̌demt = X̌Tt + X̌

    Nt + X̌

    Ct , (125)

    where X̌Ct is demand from the retail sector, that is directly from household consumption. The market

    clearing condition for the raw materials sector is worldwide, and given by

    ΣÑj=1

    (X̌sup(j)t − X̌

    dem(j)t

    )= 0 . (126)

    9 Unions

    There is a continuum of unions indexed by i ∈ [0, 1]. Unions buy labor from households and selllabor to manufacturers. They are perfectly competitive in their input market and monopolistically

    competitive in their output market. Their wage setting is subject to nominal rigidities. We first

    analyze the demands for union output and then describe their optimization problem.

    Demand for unions’ labor output varieties comes from manufacturing firms z ∈ [0, 1] in sectorsJ ∈ {N,T}. The demand for union labor by firm z in sector J is given by a CES production functionwith time-varying elasticity of substitution σUt ,

    UJt (z) =

    (∫ 1

    0

    (UJt (z, i)

    )σUt−1σUt di

    ) σUtσUt

    −1

    , (127)

    where UJt (z, i) is the demand by firm z for the labor variety supplied by union i. Given imperfect

    substitutability between the labor supplied by different unions, they have market power vis-à-vis

    manufacturing firms. Their demand functions are given by

    UJt (z, i) =

    (Vt(i)

    Vt

    )−σUtUJt (z) , (128)

    where Vt(i) is the wage charged to employers by union i and Vt is the aggregate wage paid by

    employers, given by

    Vt =

    (∫ 1

    0Vt(i)

    1−σUtdi

    ) 11−σUt

    . (129)

    The demand (128) can be aggregated over firms z and sectors J to obtain

    Ut(i) =

    (Vt(i)

    Vt

    )−σUtUt , (130)

    32

  • where Ut is aggregate labor demand by all manufacturing firms.

    GIMF allows for three types of wage rigidities. The first two are the conventional cases of nominal

    wage rigidities. Sticky wage inflation takes the form familiar from (42):

    GUP,t(i) =φPU

    2UtTt

    Vt(i)Vt−1(i)

    Vt−1Vt−2

    − 1

    2

    . (131)

    Note that these adjustment costs are zero in steady state even though real wages grow at the rate

    of world technological progress. Also, the level of world technology enters as a scaling factor in

    (131), as otherwise these costs would become insignificant over time. The second type of wage

    rigidities is real wage rigidities, whereby unions resist rapid changes in the real wage Vt/Pct . We

    define πrwt (i) = πvt (i)/

    (gπCt

    ). Then these adjustment costs are given by

    GUP,t(i) =φPU

    2UtTt (π

    rwt (i)− 1)2 =

    φPU

    2UtTt

    Vt(i)Vt−1(i)

    gπCt− 1

    2

    . (132)

    The stochastic wage markup of union wages over household wages is given by µUt = σUt/(σUt −1).The optimization problem of a union consists of maximizing the expected present discounted

    value of nominal wages paid by firms Vt(i)Ut(i) minus nominal wages paid out to workers WtUt(i),

    minus nominal wage inflation adjustment costs PtGUP,t(i). Unlike manufacturers, this sector does not

    face fixed costs of operation. It is assumed that each union pays out each period’s nominal net cash

    flow as dividends DUt (i). The objective function of unions is

    Max{Vt+s(i)}

    s=0

    EtΣ∞s=0R̃t,s

    [(Vt+s(i)−Wt+s)Ut+s(i)− Vt+sGUP,t+s(i)

    ], (133)

    subject to labor demands (130) and adjustment costs (131) or (132). We obtain the first order

    condition for this problem. As all unions face an identical problem, their solutions are identical

    and the index i can be dropped in all first-order conditions of the problem, with Vt(i) = Vt and

    Ut(i) = Ut. We let πVt = Vt/Vt−1, the gross rate of wage inflation, and we rescale by technology.

    For nominal wage rigidities we obtain the condition[µUt

    w̌tv̌t− 1]

    = φPU(µUt − 1

    )(

    πVtπVt−1

    )(πVtπVt−1

    − 1)

    (134)

    −Etθgn

    řt+1φPU

    (µUt − 1

    ) v̌t+1v̌t

    Ǔt+1

    Ǔt

    (πVt+1πVt

    )(πVt+1πVt

    − 1)

    .

    33

  • For real wage rigidities we have[µUt

    w̌tv̌t− 1]

    = φPU(µUt − 1

    )πrwt (π

    rwt − 1) (135)

    −Etθgn

    řt+1φPU

    (µUt − 1

    ) v̌t+1v̌t

    Ǔt+1

    Ǔtπrwt+1

    (πrwt+1 − 1

    ).

    Real “dividends” from union organization, denominated in terms of final output, are distributed

    lump-sum to households in proportion to their share in aggregate labor supply. After rescaling they

    take the form

    ďUt = (v̌t − w̌t)Ǔt − v̌tǦUP,t . (136)We also have v̌t/v̌t−1 = (Vt/PtTt)/(Vt−1/Pt−1Tt−1), so that

    v̌tv̌t−1

    =πVtπtg

    . (137)

    Finally, the labor market clearing condition equates the combined labor supply of OLG and LIQ

    households to the labor demands coming from nontradables and tradables manufacturers, including

    their respective labor adjustment costs if applicable, and from unions for wage adjustment costs. We

    have:

    Ľt = ǓNt + Ǔ

    Tt + Ǧ

    NU,t + Ǧ

    TU,t + Ǧ

    UP,t . (138)

    10 Import Agents

    Each country, in each of its export destination markets, owns two continua of import agents, one

    for manufactured intermediate tradable goods (T ) and another for final goods (D), each indexed

    by i ∈ [0, 1] and by J ∈ {T,D}. Import agents buy intermediate goods (or final goods)from manufacturers (or distributors) in their owners’ country and sell these goods to distributors

    (intermediate goods) or consumption/investment goods producers (final goods) in the destination

    country. They are perfectly competitive in their input market and monopolistically competitive in

    their output market. Their price setting is subject to nominal rigidities. We first analyze the demands

    for their output and then describe their optimization problem.

    34

  • Demand for the output varieties supplied by import agents comes from distributors (sector T ) or

    consumption/investment goods producers (sectors D), in each case indexed by z ∈ [0, 1]. Recall thatthe domestic economy is indexed by 1 and foreign economies by j = 2, ..., Ñ . Domestic distributors

    z require a separate CES imports aggregate Y JMt (1, j, z) from the import agents of each country

    j. That aggregate consists of varieties supplied by different import agents i, Y JMt (1, j, z, i), with

    respective prices P JMt (1, j, i), and is given by

    Y JMt (1, j, z) =

    (∫ 1

    0

    (Y JMt (1, j, z, i)

    )σJM−1σJM di

    ) σJMσJM−1

    . (139)

    This gives rise to demands for varieties of

    Y JMt (1, j, z, i) =

    (P JMt (1, j, i)

    P JMt (1, j)

    )−σJMY JMt (1, j, z) , (140)

    P JMt (1, j) =

    (∫ 1

    0P JMt (1, j, i)

    1−σJMdi

    ) 11−σJM

    , (141)

    and these demands can be aggregated over z to yield

    Y JMt (1, j, i) =

    (P JMt (1, j, i)

    P JMt (1, j)

    )−σJMY JMt (1, j) . (142)

    Nominal rigidities in this sector take the form familiar from (42),

    GJMP,t (1, j, i) =φPJM

    2Y JMt (1, j)

    P JMt (1,j,i)P JMt−1 (1,j,i)

    P JMt−1 (1,j)

    P JMt−2 (1,j)

    − 1

    2

    , (143)

    and represent a claim on the underlying exports. Import agents’ cost minimizing solution for

    inputs of manufactured intermediate tradable goods (or final goods) varieties therefore follows

    equations (36) - (38) above (or similar conditions for demands of consumption/investment goods

    producers). We denote the price of inputs imported from country j at the border of country 1 by

    P JM,cift (1, j), the cif (cost, insurance, freight) import price. By purchasing power parity this satisfies

    P JM,cift (1, j) = p̃expt P

    JHt (j)Et(1)/Et(j), where p̃expt is an exogenous price shock that equals the

    inverse of a shock to the technology that converts foreign exports into domestic imports. In real

    terms we have

    pJM,cift (1, j) = pJHt (j)p̃

    expt (j)

    et(1)

    et(j). (144)

    35

  • The optimization problem of import agents consists of maximizing the expected present

    discounted value of nominal revenue P JMt (1, j, i)YJMt (1, j, i) minus nominal costs of inputs

    P JM,cift (1, j)YJMt (1, j, i), minus nominal inflation adjustment costs PtG

    JMP,t (1, j, i). The latter

    represent a demand for final output. This sector does not face fixed costs of operation. It is assumed

    that each import agent pays out each period’s nominal net cash flow as dividends DJMt (1, j, i). The

    objective function of import agents is

    Max{PJMt+s (1,j,i)}∞s=0

    EtΣ∞s=0R̃t,s

    [(P JMt+s (1, j, i)− P JM,cift+s (1, j)

    )Y JMt+s (1, j, i)− P JMt+s GJMP,t+s(1, j, i)

    ],

    (145)

    subject to demands (142) and adjustment costs (143). The first order condition for this problem, after

    dropping firm specific subscripts and rescaling by technology, has the form:

    [σJM

    σJM − 1pJM,cift (1, j)

    pJMt (1, j)− 1]

    =φPJM

    σJM − 1

    (πJMt (1, j)

    πJMt−1(1, j)

    )(πJMt (1, j)

    πJMt−1(1, j)− 1)

    (146)

    −Etθgn

    řt+1

    φP JM

    σJM − 1pJMt+1(1, j)

    pJMt (1, j)

    Y̌ JMt+1 (1, j)

    Y̌ JMt (1, j)

    (πJMt+1(1, j)

    πJMt (1, j)

    )(πJMt+1(1, j)

    πJMt (1, j)− 1)

    .

    The rescaled real dividends of country j’s import agent in the domestic economy, which are paid out

    to OLG households in country j, are

    ďJMt (1, j) = (pJMt (1, j)− pJM,cift (1, j))Y̌ JMt (1, j)− pJMt (1, j)ǦJMP,t (1, j) . (147)

    The total dividends received by OLG households in country 1, expressed in terms of country 1

    output, are

    ďJMt = ďJMt (1) = Σ

    Ñj=2ď

    JMt (j, 1)

    et(1)

    et(j), (148)

    ďMt = ďTMt + ď

    DMt . (149)

    Finally, the market clearing conditions for import agents equate the export volume received from

    abroad to the import volume used domestically plus adjustment costs:

    Y̌ JXt (j, 1) = Y̌JMt (1, j) + Ǧ

    JMP,t (1, j) . (150)

    36

  • 11 Distributors

    Distributors produce domestic final output. They buy domestic tradables and nontradables from

    domestic manufacturers, and foreign tradables from import agents. They also use the stock of public

    infrastructure free of a user charge. Distributors sell their final output composite to consumption

    goods producers, investment goods producers and final goods import agents in foreign countries.

    They are perfectly competitive in both their output and input markets.

    We divide our description of the technology of distributors into a number of stages. In the first

    stage a foreign input composite is produced from intermediate manufactured inputs originating in all

    foreign economies and sold to distributors by import agents. In the second stage a tradables composite

    is produced by combining these foreign tradables with domestic tradables, subject to an adjustment

    cost that makes rapid changes in the share of foreign tradables costly. In the third stage a tradables-

    nontradables composite is produced. In the fourth stage the tradables-nontradables composite is

    combined with a publicly provided stock of infrastructure.

    Foreign input composites Y JFt (1), J ∈ {T,D}, are produced by combining imports Y JMt (1, j)originating in different foreign economies j and purchased through import agents. A foreign input

    choice problem therefore only arises when there are more than 2 countries. Also, distributors use

    only the composite indexed by T , while the composite indexed by D is used by consumption and

    investment goods manufacturers. We present the problem here in its general form and then reapply

    the results when describing these other agents. The CES production function for Y JFt (1) has an

    elasticity of substitution ξJM and share parameters ζJ(1, j) that are identical across firms and that

    add up to one, ΣÑj=2ζJ(1, j) = 1. We also allow for an additional effect of technology shocks on

    the intermediates import share parameters. Specifically, we posit that an improvement in technology

    in a foreign country not only leads to a lower cost in that country, but also to a higher demand for

    the respective good in all foreign countries, reflecting quality improvements due to better technology.

    The import share parameter between countries 1 and j is therefore given by

    ζ̃T

    (1, j) =

    (ζT (1, j)ATt (j)

    κ(1)

    ζ̃T

    (1)

    )

    , (151)

    ζ̃T

    (1) = ΣÑj=2ζT (1, j)ATt (j)

    κ(1) , (152)

    37

  • where κ = 0 corresponds to the standard case while κ > 0 introduces positive foreign demand

    effects of technological progress. This makes it more likely that technological progress in the

    tradables sector will lead to a real appreciation. By contrast, for investment and consumption goods

    producers we assume ζ̃D

    (1, j) = ζD(1, j). The local currency prices P JMt (1, j) of imports in

    country 1 are determined by import agents, and the overall cost of the bundle Y JFt (1) is PJFt (1).

    In the calibration of the model the share parameters ζJ(1, j) will be parameterized using a multi-

    region trade matrix. We have the following sub-production function:

    Y JFt (1) =

    (ΣNj=2ζ̃

    J(1, j)

    1

    ξJM

    (Y JMt (1, j)

    ) ξJM−1ξJM

    ) ξJMξJM−1

    , (153)

    with demands

    Y JMt (1, j) = ζ̃J(1, j)Y JFt (1)

    (P JMt (1, j)

    P JFt (1)

    )−ξJM(154)

    and an import price index, written in terms of relative prices, of

    pJFt (1) =(

    ΣNj=2ζ̃J(1, j)

    (pJMt (1, j)

    )1−ξJM) 1

    1−ξJM . (155)

    Equations (153) and (154) are rescaled by technology and population to generate aggregate

    foreign input demand of country 1, Y̌ JFt (1) and aggregate demands for individual country imports

    Y̌ JMt (1, j). Note that for final goods Y̌DFt there is a market clearing condition because the imported

    bundle is sold to both consumption and investment goods producers:

    Y̌ DFt = Y̌CFt + Y̌

    IFt . (156)

    In the two country case equations (153)-(155) simplify, after aggregation, to Y̌ JFt (1) = Y̌JMt (1, 2)

    and pJFt = pJMt . In our notation we will now revert to the two-country case and drop the index 1 for

    Home.

    The tradables composite Y Tt is produced by combining foreign produced tradables YTFt with

    domestically produced tradables Y THt , in a CES technology with elasticity of substitution ξT . A key

    concern in open economy DSGE models is the potential for an excessive short-term responsiveness of

    international trade to real exchange rate movements. This model avoids that problem by introducing

    adjustment costs GTF,t that make it costly to vary the share of Foreign produced tradables in total

    tradables production Y TFt /YTt relative to the value of that share in the aggregate distribution sector

    38

  • in the previous period Y TFt−1/YTt−1. At the previous level we allowed for the possibility κ > 0,

    meaning foreign technology shocks affect relative demands for goods from different countries. We

    allow for an identical effect, dependent on the same parameter, to affect relative demands for domestic

    and foreign tradable goods. Specifically, an improvement in average world technology increases the

    relative demand for foreign produced tradables. The domestic and foreign tradables share parameters

    are therefore given by

    α̃THt =αTHt

    (ATt)κ

    ᾰTHt, (157)

    α̃TFt =

    (1− αTHt

    ) (ARWt

    ᾰTHt, (158)

    ᾰTH = αTHt

    (ATt)κ

    +(1− αTHt

    ) (ARWt

    )κ, (159)

    ARWt = ΣÑj=2A

    Tt (j)

    gdpss(j)

    ΣÑk=2

    gdpss(k) . (160)

    The sub-production function for tradables then has the following form:21,22

    Y Tt =

    ((α̃THt

    ) 1ξT

    (Y THt

    ) ξT−1ξT+(α̃TFt) 1ξT

    (Y TFt (1−GTF,t)

    ) ξT−1ξT) ξT

    ξT−1

    , (161)

    GTF,t =φFT

    2

    (RTt − 1

    )2

    1 +(RTt − 1

    )2 , (162)

    RTt =Y TFtY TtY TFt−1Y Tt−1

    . (163)

    After expressing prices in terms of the numeraire, and after rescaling by technology and population,

    we obtain the aggregate tradables sub-production function from (161) - (163). We also obtain the

    following first-order conditions for optimal input choice:

    Y̌ THt = α̃THt Y̌

    Tt

    (pTHtpTt

    )−ξT, (164)

    21 Home bias in tradables use depends on the parameter αTH and on a similar parameterαDH at the level of final goods imports.22 For the ratioRTt we assume as usual that the distributor takes the lagged denominator term as given in hisoptimization.

    39

  • Y̌ TFt[1−GTF,t

    ]= α̃TFtY̌

    Tt

    (pTFtpTt

    )−ξT (ÕTt

    )ξT, (165)

    ÕTt = 1−GTF,t − φFTRTt(RTt − 1

    )

    [1 +

    (RTt − 1

    )2]2. (166)

    The tradables-nontradables composite Y At is produced with another CES production function

    with elasticity of substitution ξA. We again allow for a relative demand effect, this time of

    nontradables productivity shocks, with input share parameters given by

    α̃Tt =(1− αN)ᾰNt

    , (167)

    α̃Nt =αN(ANt)κ̃

    ᾰNt, (168)

    ᾰNt = αN(ANt)κ̃

    + (1− αN) . (169)The sub-production function for the tradables-nontradables composite then has the following form:

    Y At =

    (

    (α̃Tt)1

    ξA

    (Y Tt) ξA−1ξA

    + (α̃Nt)1

    ξA

    (Y Nt) ξA−1ξA

    ) ξAξA−1

    . (170)

    The real marginal cost of producing Y At is, with obvious notation for sectorial price levels,

    pAt =[α̃Tt(pTt)1−ξA + α̃Nt

    (pNt)1−ξA

    ] 11−ξA . (171)

    After expressing prices in terms of the numeraire, and after rescaling by technology, we obtain the

    aggregate tradables-nontradables sub-production function from (170), and the following first-order

    conditions for optimal input choice:

    Y̌ Nt = α̃Nt Y̌At

    (pNtpAt

    )−ξA, (172)

    Y̌ Tt = α̃Tt Y̌At

    (pTtpAt

    )−ξA. (173)

    For the case where the nontradables sector is excluded from GIMF, we simply have Y̌ At = Y̌Tt and

    pAt = pTt .

    40

  • The private-public composite ZDt , which we will refer to as domestic final output, is produced

    with the following production function:

    ZDt = YAt

    (KG1t

    )αG1 (KG2t

    )αG2 S . (174)

    The inputs are the tradables-nontradables composite Y At and the stocks of public capital KG1t and

    KG2t , which are identical for all firms and provided free of charge to the end user (but not of course

    to the taxpayer). Note that this production function exhibits constant returns to scale in private inputs

    while the public capital stocks enter externally, in an analogous manner to exogenous technology.

    The term S is a technology scale factor that can be used to normalize steady state technology to one,(K̄G1

    )αG1 (K̄G2)αG2 S = 1.

    The real marginal cost of ZDt is denoted as pDHt , while the real marginal cost of Y

    At is p

    At . After

    expressing prices in terms of the numeraire, and after rescaling by technology and population, we

    obtain the normalized production function from (174), and the follow