42
The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the Optimal Rate of Inflation Henning Weber Kiel Institute for the World Economy Seminar at the Economic Institute of the National Bank of Poland November 20, 2012

The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    5

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growthfor the Optimal Rate of Inflation

Henning Weber

Kiel Institute for the World Economy

Seminar at the Economic Institute of the National Bank of Poland

November 20, 2012

Page 2: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Motivation

Central banks all over the world pursue inflation targets.

A core concern of central banks is to understand how the levels of their inflation targetaffect the economy.

Existing work studies the role of, e.g., transaction frictions, downwardly rigid wages,sticky prices, and the ZLB for the optimal inflation target, i.e., long-run inflation rate.

This paper studies the role of “firm-level productivity growth” and sticky prices for theoptimal choice of the long-run inflation rate.

2/42

Page 3: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Motivation

Empirical work shows that productivity growth rates of new firms and incumbent firmssystematically differ from one another.

Learning By Doing:

I New firms with little experience see their productivity grow faster than incumbentfirms with a lot of experience (e.g., Bahk Gort 1993, Cooper Johri 2005).

Embodied Productivity Growth:

I Best-practice technology is embodied in new firms and improves at a faster ratethan technology installed in incumbents (e.g., Jensen, McGuckin, Stiroh 2001).

3/42

Page 4: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Plan of talk

Analysis:

Examine New Keynesian model with firm-level productivity growth & sticky prices.

Quantify optimal long-run inflation rate using a calibration based on firm-level data.

Result:

The optimal long-run inflation rate is positive and between 0.5% and 1.5% per year,despite sticky prices.

CB faces a tradeoff absent in other models, namely to minimize the distortions ineither new or incumbent firms.

CB resolves this tradeoff depending on the relative importance of each set of firms.

4/42

Page 5: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Main mechanism

In basic NK model without FLPG, a positive (long-run) inflation rate distorts real pricesof all firms and, thus, depresses output.

With FLPG, a positive inflation rate still distorts real prices of incumbent firms.

At the same time, however, it reduces distortions in real prices of new firms.

Productivity of new firms grows fast relative to productivity of incumbent firms.

Thus, new firms see their marginal costs decline, and want to reduce their price.

A positive inflation rate erodes real prices provided nominal prices are sticky.

Price erosion helps new firms to align their real price with marginal costs.

5/42

Page 6: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Related work

Related work assumes that firms have common productivity (Kahn et al. 2003, KimRuge-Murcia 2009, Schmitt-Grohe Uribe 2010, Billi 2011, Coibion et al. 2012).

In the data, however, firms (products, plants) differ substantially in their productivity.

Assuming firm-level productivity shocks greatly helps to reconcile macro models withkey facts about prices (e.g., Nakamura Steinsson (2008)).

In these macro models, a productivity increase or decrease is equally likely.

On average, thus, a firm maintains its rank in the productivity distribution.

6/42

Page 7: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Related work

In the data, however, firms tend to systematically change their rank in the productivitydistribution over their lifetime as a result of:

I Learning by doing (e.g., Bahk Gort 1993, Cooper Johri 2005).

I Embodied productivity growth. (e.g., Jensen, McGuckin, Stiroh 2001).

I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006).

I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors (e.g., Wolman 2011).

I explore the role of these factors for the optimal long-run inflation rate.

7/42

Page 8: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Model overview

∗ New Keynesian model with nominally sticky prices.

∗ A firm’s productivity grows deterministically and exogenously.

∗ Firms (products, plants) enter and exit the market at exogenous rate δ.

∗ Exiting firms are randomly selected.

∗ A new firm sets its price optimally.

∗ Incumbent firms set prices with probability (1− α) in each period.

∗ There are no firm-level productivity shocks.

8/42

Page 9: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Technology of firm j

yjt = qt−sjt

(at gsjt

1 + λλsjt

)`jt

∗ sjt = 0, 1, 2, . . . is firm’s age.

∗ q is embodied productivity growth.

∗ g is incumbent productivity growth.

∗ λ ≥ 0 and 0 ≤ λ < 1 are scope and speed of learning by doing (LBD).

∗ a is common productivity growth.

Rewrite technology as:

yjt =

(at gsjt

1 + λλsjt

)`jt , with a = aq, g = g/q.

9/42

Page 10: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 450.7

0.75

0.8

0.85

0.9

0.95

1A. Firm-level productivity: λ = 0.81, λ = 0.42, g/q = −0.6%

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 901

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

quarters

B. Embodied productivity growth: q = 1.3%

Firm AFirm BFirm C...

10/42

Page 11: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Firm j ’s pricing decision

Optimal price of firm j ∈ [0, 1] maximizes expected discounted profits (κ = α(1− δ)):

maxPjt

∑i=0

κi Ωt,t+i

[Pjt yjt+i −Wt+i yjt+i

(1 + λλsjt+i

at+i gsjt+i

)]

s.t. yjt+i =

(Pjt

Pt+i

)−θ

yt+i

When the firm sets its price, it anticipates evolution of its productivity.

Optimizing firms differ in their productivity and, thus, set various optimal prices.

11/42

Page 12: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Firm j ’s optimal price

In the steady state, the pricing equation of a new firm is:

0 =∞

∑s=0

(κβπθ)s[

P?jt

P t+s− θ

θ − 1

(1 + λλs

at+sgs

)W t+s

P t+s

].

New firm anticipates the decline in its future marginal costs.

Therefore, it sets a lower optimal price, P?jt , than without declining marginal costs.

12/42

Page 13: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 450.9

0.95

1

1.05

1.1

1.15

1.2

1.25

1.3

Lifetime s

θ

θ−1

(1+λλs

at+sgs

)W t+s

P t+s

P∗jt

P t+s

13/42

Page 14: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Representative household

maxBt ,`t ,cjt∞

t=0

E0

∑t=0

βt [u(ct )− h(`t )] s.t. ct = (∫ 1

0c1−1/θ

jt dj)θ

θ−1

Bt +∫ 1

0Pjt cjt dj ≤(1 + it−1)Bt−1 + (1− τL)Wt `t + Tt + Dt .

Price level Pt =∫ 1

0 (cjt /ct )Pjt dj , and πt = Pt /Pt−1 denotes the inflation rate.

14/42

Page 15: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Steady state price level

Firm-level growth and staggered pricing yield 2-dimensional firm heterogeneity.

Thus, denote price of firm j as Pjt = P?t−(n+k),t−k with n, k = 0, 1, 2, . . .

Weighted average price of the cohort with age s ≥ 0 is:

Λt (s) =

(1− α)∑s−1

k=0 αk (P?t−s,t−k )

1−θ + αs(P?t−s,t−s)

1−θ if s ≥ 1 ,

(P?t,t )

1−θ if s = 0 .

Unit mass of operating firms is composed of many entry cohorts:

1 = δ∞

∑s=0

(1− δ)s .

15/42

Page 16: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Steady state price level

Akin to Dotsey, King, Wolman 1999, aggregate price level is:

P1−θt = δ

∑s=0

(1− δ)sΛt (s) ,

Pricing equation implies that optimal prices of firms with different levels of productivitymap into one another (N is a function of parameters):

P?t−k ,t−k = gn

(1 + λN

1 + λnλN

)P?

t−(n+k),t−k .

E.g., with k = 0, optimal price of a new firm ∝ optimal prices of incumbent firms.

16/42

Page 17: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Steady state price level

Combining these equations yields, using p? = P?t,t /P t :

1 =

δ + (1− α)m

(p?)1−θ + κπθ−1

m = δ∞

∑n=0

(1− δ)n+1g(n+1)(θ−1)

(1 + λN

1 + λn+1λN

)θ−1

.

m contains marginal costs of incumbent firms that reset prices at date t , relative tomarginal costs of new firm.

17/42

Page 18: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Steady state aggregate technology

Aggregate output y t grows at rate a = aq along the balanced growth path.

Denote steady state output as y = y t /at , and combine firms’ technology to:

y = `/∆

∆ =∫ 1

0

(1 + λλsjt

gsjt

)(P jt

P t

)−θ

dj .

Firm-level growth alters level of aggregate productivity, 1/∆, and thus output y .

Price dispersion makes household substitute expensive for cheap products. Unevendistribution of output across firms reduces output y .

18/42

Page 19: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Aggregate steady state

In aggregate steady state, decentralized economy can be summarized as

h`(`)uc(y)

(µ(π)

1− τL

)=

1∆e

, y = R(π)`

∆e.

1/∆e is efficient amount of output dispersion in the planned economy.

R(π) = ∆e/∆ is effect of relative price dispersion on output.

µ(π) = 1/(w∆e) is average markup.

R(π) and µ(π)/(1− τL) represent all distortions in the decentralized economy.

19/42

Page 20: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Calibration for US economy

A time period t corresponds to one quarter.

Preferences are log-utility of consumption and h(`) = ηL`1+ν/(1 + ν).

Parameter Value Descriptiona 2% p.a. Aggregate growth a = aq (BFK 2006)a 0.7% p.a. Common growth (derived)g 0.7% p.a. Incumbent growth (JMS 2001)q 1.3% p.a. Embodied growth (JMS 2001)λ 0.42 Scope for learningλ 0.81 Speed of learningδ 8% p.a. 12 years expected lifetime (JMS 2001)

(1− α(1− δ))−1 2 qrts Median price duration (BK 2004)θ 4.33 30% steady-state markupν 0.25 Labor supply elasticityβ 0.995 4% p.a. real interest rateτL −0.30 labor income tax offseting θ/(θ − 1)

20/42

Page 21: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Calibration for US economy

λ and λ determined jointly by relative size of new firms and speed of learning:

I Set relative size (hours worked per firm) to 60% (JMS 2001).

I Assume it takes 2 years for firms to close 75% of learning gap, 1− 1/(1 + λ)

(Hornstein Krusell 1996 use 1 year, Yorukoglu 1998 uses 3 years).

Calibration implies:

I Productivity of firms with age ≤ 5 years relative to average productivity is 99%.

I Price of new firms with age ≤ 5 years relative to average price level is 101%.

21/42

Page 22: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

The optimal inflation rate in the model without LBD

Case without LBD, λ = 0 and λ = 1, allows to derive analytical results.

Interpret as economy with only incumbent firms with no further increments in learning.

Proposition 1:

Without LBD and using g = g/q, the optimal long-run inflation rate that maximizessteady state welfare is:

π? = g/q

= − 0.63% per year.

22/42

Page 23: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

The optimal inflation rate in the model without LBD

A new firm sets its price according to (using w = w t /(aq)t and p? = P?t,t /Pt )

0 =∞

∑s=0

(κβπθ)s[

p?

πs −θ

θ − 1w

(g/q)s

].

I g > 1 indicates positive productivity growth of incumbent firms.

I Relative to newest firms, however, incumbents become obsolete at rate g/q < 1.

I Thus, real marginal costs of incumbent firms increase.

I Thus, firm’s desired real price (markup over real marginal costs) also increases.

I π < 1 maps sticky nominal prices, which cannot increase, into increasing real prices.

23/42

Page 24: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

0.98 0.99 1 1.01 1.020.9999

1

1

1.0001

1.0001

1.0002

1.0002

1.0003

1.0003

π

A. Markup µ

0.98 0.99 1 1.01 1.020.9996

0.9996

0.9997

0.9997

0.9998

0.9998

0.9999

0.9999

1

1

π

B. Relative price distortion R

h`(`)uc(y)

(µ(π)

1− τL

)=

1∆e

y = R(π)`

∆e

24/42

Page 25: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

The optimal inflation rate in the model with LBD is +1.04% per year

0.98 0.99 1 1.01 1.020.9998

1

1.0002

1.0004

1.0006

1.0008

1.001

1.0012

π

A. Markup µ

0.98 0.99 1 1.01 1.020.9991

0.9992

0.9993

0.9994

0.9995

0.9996

0.9997

0.9998

0.9999

1

π

B. Relative price distortion R

25/42

Page 26: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

The optimal inflation rate in the model with LBD

With LBD, CB faces a tradeoff and, thus, no longer achieves efficient allocation.

With LBD, a new firm sets its price as

0 =∞

∑s=0

(κβπθ)s[

p?

πs −θ

θ − 1

(1 + λλs

(g/q)s

)w

].

The inflation rate that is optimal for the new firm moves 1:1 with firm’s productivity:

π?t ∝

((g/q)t

1 + λλt

).

But this rate is suboptimal for old firms, say, which prefer π? = g/q.

Thus, CB can minimize distortion in either new or incumbent firms, but not both.

26/42

Page 27: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

The role of the inflation rate in the model with LBD

0 10 20 30 400.9

0.95

1

1.05

1.1

1.15

1.2

1.25

1.3

Lifetime s

B. Zero long−run inflation rate

θ

θ−1

(1+λλs

(g/q)s

)w

p∗(s)/πn

0 10 20 30 400.9

0.95

1

1.05

1.1

1.15

1.2

1.25

1.3

Lifetime s

A. Positive long−run inflation rate

27/42

Page 28: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Robustness of the optimal inflation rate to various calibrations

−1.5 −1 −0.5 00

0.5

1

1.5

2

π* per

yea

r

g

(a)

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.80

0.5

1

1.5

2

λ

(b)

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.80

0.5

1

1.5

2

π* per

yea

r

α

(e)

0.015 0.02 0.025 0.030

0.5

1

1.5

2

δ

(d)

3 4 5 60

0.5

1

1.5

2

θ

(f)

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.80

0.5

1

1.5

2

π* per

yea

r

Relative size

(c)

28/42

Page 29: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

How should CB trade off distortions in new versus incumbent firms?

CB weighs new firms heavily, if their market share is large & LBD is important, i.e.:

I If it is difficult to substitute away from relatively expensive goods (θ small).

I If the number of new firms in each period is large (δ large).

I If the scope for learning is reasonably large (λ large).

I If the speed of learning is reasonably slow (λ large).

Price stickiness is not important (as long as it exists), because it affects new andincumbent firms similarly.

29/42

Page 30: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Role of sectoral asymmetries

Magnitude and composition of productivity growth differs across economic sectors:

I While Goods grow at 2%, Services grow at only 1% per year.

I While embodied growth accounts for 66% of total growth in Goods, it accountsfor 100% in Services (Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006).

Also, prices in Services change less frequently than prices in Goods.

How do sectoral asymmetries in magnitude and composition of productivity growthand price stickiness affect the optimal inflation rate?

30/42

Page 31: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Model extension with sectoral asymmetries

I Two sectors, Services and Goods, denoted by z = 1, 2.

I Aggregate output: yt = yψ1t y

1−ψ2t .

I Asymmetry in magnitude and composition of prod. growth: az , az , qz , gz .

I Asymmetry in frequency of price changes, αz , and survival probability, δz .

I (Asymmetry in LBD, λz , λz .)

31/42

Page 32: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Steady state of two-sector model

In aggregate steady state, decentralized two-sector economy can be summarized as

h`(`)uc(y)

(µ(π)

1− τL

)=

1∆e

, y = R(π)`

∆e,

with

µ(π) = µψ1 µ

1−ψ2

R(π) =

(µ2

µ1

)1−ψ

ρ−11 + (1− ψ)

(µ1

µ2

ρ−12

]−1

.

µz(π) is average markup in sector z.

ρz(π) is effect of RPD on output in sector z relative to planned economy.

32/42

Page 33: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Calibration for US economy

Sector 1 represents Services, Sector 2 represents Goods.

Parameter Value Descriptiona1 1.08% p.a. Sectoral growth a1 = a1q1 (FHK 2006)a1 0% p.a. Common growth (derived)g1 0% p.a. Incumbent growth (FHK 2006)q1 1.08% p.a. Embodied growth (FHK 2006)δ1 11% p.a. 9 years expected lifetime

(1− α1(1− δ1))−1 3 qrts Median price duration (BK 2004)a2 2% p.a. Aggregate growth a = aq (BFK 2006)a2 0.7% p.a. Common growth (derived)g2 0.7% p.a. Incumbent growth (JMS 2001)q2 1.3% p.a. Embodied growth (JMS 2001)δ2 8% p.a. 12 years expected lifetime (JMS 2001)

(1− α2(1− δ2))−1 2 qrts Median price duration (BK 2004)ψ 0.6 Relative size of Services (W 2011)λ 0.42 Scope for learningλ 0.81 Speed of learning

33/42

Page 34: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

The optimal inflation rate in the two-sector model without LBD

Akin to Proposition 1, the special case without LBD yields analytical results.

Proposition 2:

In the limit β→ 1, the optimal aggregate long-run inflation rate π solves

0 = ω(π?)

(π? − (g1/η1)

(g1/η1)

)+ (1−ω(π?))

(π? − (g2/η2)

(g2/η2)

),

with η1 = (a2/a1)(1−ψ) and η2 = (a1/a2)ψ.

I.e., CB faces the tradeoff π? = g1/η1 versus π? = g2/η2, and resolves it using ω.

Calibrated model yields π? = −1.19% per year.

34/42

Page 35: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Weight ω(π?) implies that π? weighs sector with stickier prices more heavily

α1

α2

0.01

0.1

0.3

0.5

0.7

0.9

0.99

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

35/42

Page 36: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

−1 0 10.9999

1

1.0001

1.0002

1.0003

1.0004

1.0005

1.0006

1.0007

1.0008

π

µ(π)

µµ

1

µ2

−1 0 10.9988

0.999

0.9992

0.9994

0.9996

0.9998

1

π

R(π)

1

ρ2

36/42

Page 37: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Special case: No sectoral productivity growth differential

With a1 = a2, optimal aggregate inflation rate solves:

0 = ω(π?)

(π? − g1

g1

)+ (1−ω(π?))

(π? − g2

g2

).

I Recall that π? = g in one-sector model without LBD.

I With two sectors, gz represents the inflation rate that is optimal in sector z.

I However, with g2 > g1, no π is optimal in both sectors at the same time.

I Weight ω makes CB pull π? toward the Services sector with more sticky prices.

Calibrated model yields g1 = −1.07%, g2 = −0.64%, and π? = −0.99% per year.

37/42

Page 38: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Special case: No firm-level productivity growth (Wolman 2011)

With gz = 1, optimal aggregate inflation rate solves:

0 = ω(π?) (η1π? − 1) + (1−ω(π?)) (η2π? − 1) .

I Since ηz π = πz , CB strives for zero sectoral inflation rates, π?z = 1.

I Since a1 6= a2, relative price, P1t /P2t , is trending, so that π1/π2 = a2/a1.

I Therefore, using ω, CB trades off π?1 = 1 against π?

2 = 1.

Calibrated model yields π? = −0.20% per year, with π?1 = .17% and π?

2 = −.74%.

Calibration implies, survival growth (gz ) matters more than sectoral growth (az ) for π?.

38/42

Page 39: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Related work

ω(π) incorporates ”stickiness principle”, i.e., optimal monetary policy weighs sector,or country, with the stickier prices more heavily (Goodfriend King 1997).

Aioki 2001, Mankiw Reis 2003, Benigno 2004: Stickiness principle applies totemporary changes in relative price across sectors.

Proposition 2, Wolman 2011: Stickiness principle also applies to optimal long-runinflation rate.

39/42

Page 40: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

The optimal inflation rate with two sectors and LBD is +0.82% per year

−1 0 11

1.0005

1.001

1.0015

1.002

1.0025

π

µ(π)

µµ

1

µ2

−1 0 10.998

0.9985

0.999

0.9995

1

1.0005

π

R(π)

1

ρ2

40/42

Page 41: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

The optimal inflation rate with two sectors and LBD

With two sectors and LBD, policy tradeoff btw sectors coexists with policy tradeoff btwnew and incumbent firms within a sector.

The optimal price of a new firm in sector z, p?z = P?z,t,t /(η

tz Pt ), fulfills:

0 =∞

∑i=0

(κz πθz β)i

[p?z

(ηz π)i −θ

θ − 1

(1 + λz λi

z

g iz

)w

].

I Learning-by-doing dynamics, λz , and λz ,

I survival and vintage growth, gz = gz /qz , and

I sectoral productivity growth, az (via ηz ),

interact with price stickiness, αz , and relative sector size, ψ, to determine the optimalinflation rate.

41/42

Page 42: The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the …I Incumbent productivity growth (e.g., Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan 2006). I Various productivity growth rates in economic sectors

Summary

Incorporating firm-level productivity growth into a NK model tends to increase theoptimal long-run inflation rate from zero to between 0.5 and 1.5% per year:

One-sector model with vintage & survival growth, and no LBD: π? = −0.63%.

One-sector model with vintage & survival growth, and LBD: π? = 1.04%.

Two-sector model with vintage & survival growth, and LBD: π? = 0.82%.

Optimizing central bank trades off the distortions in new versus incumbent firms.

The more important are new firms and LBD, the higher is the optimal inflation rate.

42/42