27
University-Industry Collaboration : a firm perspective Prof. Dr. R. Veugelers KULeuven, EC-BEPA and CEPR

University-Industry Collaboration : a firm perspective

  • Upload
    tilden

  • View
    38

  • Download
    6

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

University-Industry Collaboration : a firm perspective. Prof. Dr. R. Veugelers KULeuven, EC-BEPA and CEPR. EU-25 Innovation Gap with US : improving Source: EIS 2006. EIS uses a composite indicator to assess Innovation (input&output). Decomposing the EU- US Innovation Gap - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Citation preview

Page 1: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

University-Industry Collaboration :

a firm perspective

Prof. Dr. R. VeugelersKULeuven, EC-BEPA and CEPR

Page 2: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

EU-25 Innovation Gap with US : improvingSource: EIS 2006

EIS uses a composite indicator to assess Innovation (input&output)

Page 3: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Decomposing the EU- US Innovation GapSource: EIS 2006

Page 4: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

…no significant change in business R&D expenditures

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

EU-27 f inanced by business enterprise US financed by business enterprise EU-27 f inanced by government US financed by government

Page 5: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Europe’s performance in R&D and innovation continues to be a disappointing story

Capabilities failure (supply) R&D investments (public, esp private)

Incentives/rewards – framework conditions failure Fragmented product markets, capital markets,

labour markets IPR, standards&regulations, competition, lead markets, public

procurement, …

Systems failure Client/supplier networks Public Private networks

Industry Science Links

Page 6: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Industry Science Links

Importance of Indicators and Analysis

Currently no ISL indicators used in EU policy monitoring (EIS, Structural Indicators)No robust research findings on effects of ISL on performance (do they matter?)Which policy levers to use? (business sector, science sector, intermediaries)

Page 7: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

GROWING SCIENCE-INDUSTRY CONNECTIONS

University-industry collaboration (Darby and Zucker; 2001; Zucker et al, 2001; 2002);

Start-ups and university spin-offs and licensing (Jensen and Thursby, 2001; Thursby and Thursby, 2002);

Science parks (Siegel 2003) Increased linkage to science in patents (Narin et al (1997);

Branstetter and Ogura, 2005):

“Open Innovation” literature reflects an increasing attention to the phenomenon of industry science links

But are industry science links indeed important for (innovative) performance?

Page 8: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

FrequencyInnovation Strategy

% Sales fromNew Products

NoMake&Buy 16 (6%) 14.9%

MakeOnly 59 (22%) 13.5%

BuyOnly 16 (6%) 9.7%

Make&Buy 178 (66%) 20.5%

TOTAL 269 (100%) 18.0%

Internal and External Activities performed by the same firm

…improve innovation performance!

Source: Cassiman and Veugelers (Management Science, 2006)

Page 9: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

IMPORTANCE OF SCIENCE FOR TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS

At the macro level: Positive impact of public research on industrial innovation and economic

growth; and implied geographical effects (Jaffe (1989) and Adams,1990; Acs, et al (1992) ). Rates of return to publicly funded research estimated between 20% and 60%.

At the micro level: Mansfield (1998): 15% of new products, 11% of new processes representing

about 5% of total sales in a sample of major firms in US could not have been developed in the absence of academic research.

Yale Survey (1983) and Carnegie Mellon Survey (1994) confirm relevance of university research for innovation for R&D active firms.

But In Eurostat Community Innovation Survey (1999-2000) only 4.5% of all

innovation active firms rate universities as an important source of information. 68% indicate universities as not important at all.

European Paradox? Science but no Link to Industry

Page 10: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Measuring Firm Level Links to Science While at the industry level ISL is correlated with R&D intensity of the

industry, a lot of variation at the firm level exists, i.e. there is not that much overlap between different types of ISL at the firm level

Source: Cassiman, Veugelers and Zuniga (2006)

Having a link to science is correlated with the innovation performance of firms, in particular products new to market, but no one indicator seems to dominate this effect.

Firms with scientific NPR

Use of public sources of informationCooperation public

institutions74

60

7

2

40

55

Firms “without”

Science Link

649

Firms with Science Link 193

Page 11: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Co-authorship with university employees increases R&D productivity by

pharmaceutical firms as measured by international patents (Henderson and

Cockburn,1998).

Star scientists associated to firm entry, new product development in biotech

and nanotech (Zucker et al. 1998, Zucker et al., 2005, Stephan et al 2006)

Recruitment of university scientists increases research productivity (Kim et

al., 2005)

Cooperation with Universities results in a higher percent of innovations new

to the market (Monjon & Waelbroeck 2003)

SCIENCE MATTERS FOR INNOVATION AT FIRM LEVEL?

Page 12: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

WHY WOULD SCIENCE MATTER FOR INNOVATION at the firm level?

– By providing a map for research and codified forms of problem solving science helps firms• Increase the productivity of applied research (Nelson; 1959;

Evenson and Kislev, 1976)• Avoid wasteful experimentation when working with highly

coupled (complex) technologies (Fleming and Sorenson (2004)• Better identification, absorption and integration of external

knowledge, e.g. what is cutting edge; identifing most promising technological opportunities (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989; Gambardella, 1995; Henderson and Cockburn, 1998).

• Internal Spillovers; cross-projects fertilization of basic knowledge (Cockburn and Henderson, 1994)

Page 13: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Research Questions when studying cooperative agreements with science (CPscience) from industry perspective

Which firms choose CPscience? What do firms do within CPscience ? What are the effect of CPscience on (innovative)

performance of these firms? What are the effects of CPscience on social (innovative

performance)?

Taking into account: CPscience within Industry – Science link portfolio CPscience within Innovation strategy

Page 14: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Literature

Why do firms cooperate? Transaction Cost Economics: balancing access to new knowledge and

exposure to opportunism (Pisano, 1990; Oxley, 1997) Industrial Organization:

Appropriation conditions can increase the incentive to internalize the positive externality (d’Aspremont and Jacquemin, 1988; De Bondt, 1997).

Appropriation conditions can increase the incentive to free ride on the cooperative agreement; Kesteloot and Veugelers, 1995; Greenlee and Cassiman, 1999).

Management: Complementarity with own R&D activities (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989;

Kamien and Zang, 2000) Complementarity with internal and external innovation activities (Arora and

Gambardella, 1990; Cassiman and Veugelers, 2003)

Page 15: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Literature

Why do firms cooperate with science? Empirical Studies: firm size, own R&D, organization, government

support, uncertainty, spillovers, scientific status of industry,... Hall, Link and Scott, 2001; Capron and Cincera, 2002; Tether 2002, Mohnen

and Hoareau, 2006; Miotti and Sachwald, 2003)

Performance effects of CPscience Innovative performance (sales of new products, especially more

radically new products) (CIS-data) Crusciola & Haskel (2003), Janz et al (2003), van Leeuwen

(2002), Tether (2002) Monjon & Waelbroeck (2003) Productivity growth

Belderbos et al (2006) No evidence of positive performance effects of single use of CPscience Complementarity with CPcustomers for small firms and with CPsuppliers for

large firms Subadditivitiy between CPscience and CPcompetitors

Page 16: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Our research questions when studying cooperative agreements with science (CPscience) from industry perspective:

Which firms choose CPscience?

Taking into account

Size, Organization, Technology Characteristics Appropriation (Spillovers) Complementary innovation activities

Veugelers & Cassiman, 2005, IJIO,R&D cooperation between firms and universities: some empirical evidence from Belgium,

Page 17: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Hypotheses Cooperation with Universities

Appropriation conditions might increase the likelihood of R&D cooperation (internalization), decrease the likelihood of R&D cooperation (free riding) or be irrelevant given the early stage of the innovation process.

R&D Cooperation with Universities increases the firm’s basic R&D capability. Increases in the basic R&D capability of the firm increases the marginal benefit of engaging in other (applied) R&D activities: Complementarity with other innovation activities.

Basic R&DCapability

UniversityR&D Cooperation

Own (Applied) R&D

Public Information

Vertical Cooperation

Page 18: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Hypotheses Cooperation with Universities

Larger firms have the necessary in-house capabilities to interact with universities, but small firms might be more agile.

Facing a more competitive environment increases innovation, but this might pressure towards more short-term applied innovations.

At multinationals, research linking with universities is done at headquarters.

At early stage technology development of the type developed in university-industry R&D cooperation, financial barriers might be high.

The high uncertainty involved in university-industry cooperation might lead to risk sharing. At the same time, it leads to higher transaction costs, making contracting on output more difficult.

Page 19: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Data

DATA: CIS I (1990 - 1992) for Belgium• 1335 questionnaires sent

• 748 usable questionnaires returned (53%)

• 439 innovators between 1990 and 1992 (59%)

SAMPLE: Innovation Active Firms in 1992• 325 observations• 89 cooperate with universities• quantitative and qualitative information

Page 20: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Empirical Model

Dependent Variable: Cooperation with Universities (0/1)

Appropriation Legal: effectiveness of patents at industry level Strategic: effectiveness of complexity, secrecy, or, lead time

Complementary Innovation Activities Own R&D: absorption, integration and application (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989) Cooperation with customers and suppliers (Arora and Gambardella, 1990) Publicly available information (Cassiman and Veugelers, 2002)

Control Variables Size (number of employees) Foreign ownership (foreign headquarter) Costs (importance of innovation costs as barrier to innovation) Risk (importance of risk as barrier to innovation) Industry Cooperation

Page 21: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Empirical Model:Instrumental variables estimation We regress the complementary strategies on a set of specific assumed exogenous variables and instruments

in a first step. In the second step, we use the predicted values of the complementary strategy variables as independent variables in the probit estimation of the cooperation with universities decision

Instruments for INTSourcing = {OBSTEXTERNAL, OBSTRESOURCE, IndINTsourcing, X}

Instruments for PUBSourcing= {BASICRD, IndPUBsourcing, X}

Instruments for CPvert= {TECH, IndCPvert,X}

With the set of exogeneous variables X X= {SIZE, FOR, COST, RISK, PROTstrat, IndPROTleg, IndCPuniv}

Heckman correction for innovation {SIZE, EXP, FOR, COST, OBSTEXTERNAL, OBSTRESOURCE ,

OBSTMARKET, OBSTTECHNOLOGY, Industry dummies}

Page 22: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Mean if CPuniv = 0 Mean if CPuniv = 1

SIZE*** 4.81 (1.48

6.19 (1.43)

EXP*** 0.54 (0.25)

0.63 (0.35)

FOR*** 0.32 (0.47)

0.51 (0.50)

COST** 0.47 (0.20)

0.51 (0.19)

RISK 0.48 (0.29)

0.46 (0.25)

PROTstrat*** 3.21 (1.00)

3.57 (0.62)

IndPROTleg*** 1.85 (0.30)

2.04 (0.33)

INTsourcing*** 3.79 (0.97)

4.16 (0.71)

PUBsourcing*** 2.76 (0.73)

3.16 (0.63)

CPvert*** 0.20 (0.40)

0.64 (0.48)

Page 23: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Table 2: Pairwise Correlations between Innovation Activities

Cpuniv CPvert INTsourcing PUBsourcing

CPuniv 1

CPvert 0.42*** 1

INTsourcing 0.18*** 0.11** 1

PUBsourcing 0.25*** 0.24*** 0.24*** 1

***correlations significant at 1%; **correlations significant at 5%

Page 24: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective
Page 25: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Summary findings on who cooperates with universities?

Cooperation is more likely in chemical and pharmaceutical industries

Larger firms are more likely to cooperate Sharing costs seems an important driver of cooperation.

Cooperation happens when risk is not an important obstacle to innovation

Appropriation is not an important factor in cooperation with universities (but for cooperation with customers and suppliers it is)

Cooperation with universities complementary to other forms of cooperation and innovation activities

Source: Veugelers and Cassiman (IJIO,2005)

Page 26: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

What happens inside the Firm?

Of the 50+ projects examined, about 40% include cooperation and/or contracting with universities.

Cooperation with universities is more likely in more basic projects that develop new knowledge.

In strategically important projects, cooperation with other firms is less likely, but cooperation with universities in initial activities is more likely.

There are distinct measures of success of a project: Efficiency (on-time, within budget,...) Learning over time of new applications, new capabilities... As well

as knowledge for future projects, but this is difficult to measure and account for, i.e. SPILLOVERS

Source: Cassiman, Di Guardo y Valentini (2006)

Page 27: University-Industry Collaboration :  a firm perspective

Conclusions

Still far from helping policy design for improving ISL

Nevertheless, helpful insights: Large firms are more likely involved in Industry – Science links,

but subsidiaries of multinationals less likely to cooperate with local universities

An important characteristic to Industry – Science links is the fact that firms engaged in cooperating with universities are at the same time involved in many complementary innovation activities

Cooperation with universities is characterized by an open, non-exclusive exchange between researchers