Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    1/27

    BROADENING THE FISCAL DESIGN

    OF LOCAL AUTONOMY:PATCHING THE LOOPHOLES OF DEVOLUTION AND MAKING IT WORK

    AN ACT CREATING THE SPECIAL HEALTH FUND

    AND AMENDING SECTIONS 235, 236, 237, 273, 285, 287

    OF THE LOCAL GOVERNMENT CODE OF 1991

    Aonuevo, LesterCruz, Judy

    Faller, Beatrice AstridKadatuan, Arif

    Moran, Ralph EdwardRabanes, Eleazar

    1A

    San Beda College of Law

    Mendiola, Manila

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    2/27

    INTRODUCTION

    Local government units assumed a greater responsibility in local service delivery and in

    the provision of health services since 1991. The decentralization of national government

    function to local government units is an institutional reform that is expected to lead more

    efficient and equitable delivery of public services. The expected gains from the devolution arebased from the assumptions that LGUs have better information about the preferences of their

    constituencies, and also better incentives to act on their superior information because of their

    direct accountability to the service clients.

    As the declaration of principles and state policies expressly mention, Section 15 of

    Article II expresses this states duty: The state shall protect and promote the right to health of

    the people and instill health consciousness among them. In the fulfillment of this duty,

    Sections 11 and 12 of Article XIII, specify what the state has to do, viz:

    SEC 11. The State shall adopt an integrated and comprehensive approach tohealth development which shall endeavor to make essential goods, health and other social

    services available to all the people at affordable cost. There shall be priority for the needs

    of the underprivileged sick, elderly, disabled, women, and children. The state shall

    endeavor to provide free medical care to paupers.

    SEC 12. The State shall establish and maintain an effective food and drug

    regulatory system and undertake appropriate health manpower development and

    research, responsive to the countrys health needs and problems.

    Public health services in the Philippines are delivered to communities by local

    government units, with the Department of Health, through Centers for Health Development,providing technical assistance. Overall, access remains the fundamental objective of the delivery

    of public health services. However, problems persist with quality and effectiveness of these

    services.

    The devolution of health services ended the concept of integrated care at the district

    level. Public health and hospital services are now administered independently. The provincial

    governments took over the management of secondary hospitals, while municipal governments

    were put in charge of the delivery of primary level health care services and the corresponding

    facilities such as the Rural Health Units and Barangay Health Centers. The national

    government, meanwhile, has retained the management of tertiary level facilities. Fragmentation

    is compounded by the management of the three levels of health care that is vested in three

    different government levels.

    While the post-devolution health care delivery system achieved gains, it is evident that it

    weakened due to lack of resources and local capacity to manage devolved health facilities, the

    unwillingness or inability of local authorities to maintain pre-devolution spending for health,

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    3/27

    and low morale and lack of opportunities for continuing education among devolved health

    providers.

    Background and Significance

    The Local Government Code of 1991 clearly specified the tasks that should be devolvedto the local government units. As expressed in the following table, the following indicates the

    distribution of tasks between LGUs.

    UNIT FUNCTIONS

    Barangay Section 17 (b) (1) (ii)

    Health and Social Services which includes maintenance

    of barangay health center and day care center

    Municipality Section 17 (b) (2) (iii)

    Subject to the Provisions of Title Five, Book I of the Local

    Government Code, Health services which include theimplementation of programs and projects on primary

    health care, maternal and child care, and communicable

    and non-communicable disease control services, access to

    secondary and tertiary health services, purchase of

    medicines, medical supplies, and equipment to carry out

    the services herein enumerated.

    Province Section 17 (b) (3) (iv)

    Subject to the Provisions of Title Five, Book I of the Local

    Government Code, Health services which include the

    hospitals and other tertiary health services

    City Section 17 (b) (4)

    All the services and facilities of the municipalities and

    province

    TABLE 1

    Functions of Local Government Units in RA 7160

    According to Pimentel (Philippine Congress Deliberations on LGS of 1991), access to

    secondary health services means access to doctors for the treatment of disease and provisionof medicine for indigent patients. He further elaborated that tertiary health services means

    access to hospitals. Provincial and district hospitals are funded out of the provincial

    governments budget while municipal/city hospitals are financed by municipal/city budgets.

    Management and financial parameters are determined primarily by the local chief executive

    and, in varying level of influence and technical leadership.

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    4/27

    The DOHs Steering Role

    Paralleling in the general decentralization trend in the past decades, health sector

    decentralization policies have been implemented on a broad scale throughout developing

    countries. In combination with health finance reform, decentralization has been touted as a key

    means of improving health sector performance and promoting social and economicdevelopment (Brillantes, 1998).

    The Local Government Code completely changed the terrain of the delivery of health

    services as it gave local government units responsibility for and financial management of their

    own health activities with the Department of Health providing guidance and advice through a

    network of DOH representatives and Centers for Health Development.

    With the devolution, the role of the Department of Health changed from the sole

    provider of health services to provider of specific health services and technical assistance for

    health for LGUs. It is designated as the national technical authority on health and is mandatedto define and formulate programs and strategies that will ensure the highest achievable

    standards of quality health care, health promotion, and health protection, on which LGUs,

    NGOs, other private organizations, and individual members of civil society will anchor their

    own health programs and strategies.

    The Department of Health was made servicer of servicers by developing health

    policies, enhancing partners capacity through technical assistance, leveraging performance for

    priority health programs among partners, developing and enforcing regulatory policies and

    standards, providing specific programs that affect large segments of the population, and

    providing specialized and tertiary health care. These functions brought radical changes in the

    structure of the health service delivery system in the country.

    The Department of Health is also mandated to maintain national health facilities and

    hospitals with modern and advanced capabilities to support local services. The health facilities

    and special hospitals should provide technical support to all rural health centers.

    Interestingly enough, a unique feature of the Philippine health care system is the

    existence of a non-devolved autonomous health care system in the Autonomous Region of

    Muslim Mindanao which is provided mainly through a public sector health system managed by

    a regional authority. This has retained the centralized character of the health system under

    DOH-ARMM, which directly runs the provincial hospitals and municipal health centers underits jurisdiction instead of the component provinces and towns of ARMM.

    The succeeding table provides the different facilities that are left to local government

    units upon enactment of the Local Government Code.

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    5/27

    FUNCTIONS MUNICIPALITIES PROVINCES CITIES

    Basic Primary

    Health Care

    2,299 Rural Health Units

    10,683 Barangay Health

    Stations

    210 Peuriculture Centers

    Municipal Maternity ClinicsMunicipal and Barangay Staff

    Hospital Services 596 Provincial,

    District and

    Municipals and

    Infirmaries

    District and

    Provincial Hospital

    Staff

    Administrative

    Services

    70 Integrated

    Provincial Health

    Offices

    District Health

    Officers

    IPHO and DHO

    Staff

    60 City Health

    Officers

    Assistant City

    Health

    Officers

    TABLE 2

    Delineation of Functions in RA 7160

    The LGUs, on the other hand, serve as stewards of the local health system and therefore

    they are required to formulate and enforce local policies and ordinances related to health,nutrition, sanitation and other health-related matters in accordance with national policies and

    standards. They are also in charge of creating an environment conducive for establishing

    partnerships with all sectors at the local level.

    Complementing the new functionality of the LGUs are the local health boards (LHBs).

    These are special bodies that exist in all levels of LGUs expect in the barangays. An LHB is

    composed of the local chief executive (i.e. governor for the provincial health board, city mayor

    for the city, and municipal mayor for the municipality) as chair, local health officer (i.e.

    provincial / city / municipal health officer) as vice-chairperson, the committee chair on health of

    every local legislative body (sangguniang panlalawigan, sangguniang panlunsod, and

    sangguniang bayan), a representative from private sector or nongovernment organizations

    involved in health services, and DOH representative (provincial / city / municipality). The main

    function of the LHB is to formulate policies on budget allocations and act as advisory committee

    for the sanggunian.

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    6/27

    FIGURE 1Philippine Organizational Structure and Accountability in the Health Care System

    (Romualdez et al, Asia Pacific Observatory on Health Systems and Policies, 2011)

    The LGUs political and administrative terrain

    Geography, politics, administrative and legal factors condition in a complex way the

    emergence of consolidated local health systems in the Philippines being archipelago of around

    7,100 islands, divided into 17 administrative regions. Each region, except for the National

    Capital Region (NCR), is subdivided into provinces, and each province into municipalities and

    cities, and each of which into barangays. In 2009, there were already more than 1600 provinces,cities and municipalities, and around 40,000 barangays.

    The constraints to cooperation that the geographical barriers pose are supposed to be

    offset by the political and administrative structures of local governments in the Philippines.

    Each province in governed by a governor, each municipality or city by a mayor, and each

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    7/27

    barangay by a barangay captan. A local chief executive is elected every three years, for a

    maximum of three consecutive terms, directly by his or her constituents.

    Administratively, each barangay captain is under the municipal or city mayor, and each

    mayor in turn is under the provincial governor. The provincial governor is administratively

    under the national government. This administrative setup within each province provides a dejure venue for consolidating the local government programs and projects. Region-wide

    consistency of provincial plans is attained during the regular meetings of the regional

    development councils comprising the local chief executives and key officials from the local

    branches of national government agencies.

    Some LGUs however are outside the usual administrative setup. In the National Capital

    Region (NCR), the 17 component cities and municipalities are each independent of one another

    and there is no provincial government to supervise them. In some provinces, there are

    independent cities that are outside the administrative control of the provincial government.

    The constituents of these cities do not vote for the provincial governors, unlike the

    residents of component cities in some provinces. In the Autonomous Region of Muslim

    Mindanao (ARMM), a regional government is established and run by an elected regional

    governor that supervises directly the component provinces.

    However, all these LGUs NCR cities and municipalities, independent cities, and

    ARMM regional government are administratively within the ambit of the national

    government.

    The question of whether devolution or decentralization is the better alternative to

    achieve the desired health outcome cannot be answered directly since the experience in health is

    not a perfect predictor since services lead to different outputs or impacts, which are both

    important but not directly comparable contributions to human development indicators.

    However, Capuno (2009) points, that in principle, broad trends in terms of welfare

    impact can be established from data sets. Contributions to individual or household welfare or

    well-being can be estimated and compared with the right data. While special surveys on users

    access to and satisfaction with local public services or their awareness of decentralization were

    conducted in the past, this provides limited sample socioeconomic information for firm

    statistical evaluation.

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    8/27

    Review of Related Literature

    Framing Decentralization

    North (1990) provides that institutions are the rules of the game in a society or, more

    formally, are the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction. It may be askedthat when the government or public agency decentralizes, what sort of constraints or incentives

    are changed that will align the objectives of government officials with that of the public that

    they serve.

    In a hierarchical organization such as a system of government in the Philippines, in light

    of fiscal federalism, decentralization relaxes information constraints. Lower-level officials

    interact more with service clients and because of their frequent contact, those who are informed

    more would know more than superiors about the needs of the target beneficiaries and the local

    social climate.

    However, the information advantage is not sufficient to justify decentralization as

    Bardhan (2002) suggested for it can be commissioned through surveys, client interviews and

    focus group discussions. Thus, Bardhan posits that it is also necessary that the authorized

    lower-level official should have the incentive to act upon superior information and proximity to

    service clients.

    A greater focus on accountability can be discerned from the recent literature on fiscal

    decentralization (Bardhan and Mookherjee, 2006). In principle, decentralization could improve

    accountability since:

    At the local level, citizens can more easily learn of the activities and programs that their

    local leaders have promoted and supported, discern how much effort they have devoted to

    improving public services, and confirm whether they have delivered on campaign

    promises. In other words, the information that citizens need to make judgments is more

    readily accessible under decentralization. (Campos and Hellman 2005)

    Under decentralization, the citizens can directly their feedback about their preferences to

    local officials or service providers, instead of transmitting the same to policymakers. However,

    they can still provide other information to policy makers to hold the local officials or civil

    servants accountable for their performance.

    In addition to incentives and accountability, three other aspects are important in the

    design of decentralization policies. One important aspect is the determination the functions to

    assign to each level in the organization or government. The guiding principle often used is that

    a function should be assigned to that level whose jurisdiction covers all those who would be

    affected by the discharge of that function. The idea is that the level should internalize all the

    benefits and costs arising from the performance of its assigned function.

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    9/27

    Another important aspect is building the capacity of each level so that it can perform its

    assigned responsibilities. The required capacity would include the powers or authority to

    determine, raise and use the inputs and the processes needed to deliver the public service. The

    inputs would include funds, human resources and organizational capital.

    Where the lower-level official or unit unable to mobilize these inputs, then the higher-level official or unit should transfer the financial resources, provide the training and other

    technical assistance. Finally, a system of monitoring activities and performance, and supervising

    tasks and personnel should be in place. The responsibility to monitoring and supervise lower-

    level units or personnel should be assigned to higher-level units or officials to avoid conflict of

    interest.

    Forms of Decentralization

    Capuno (2009) provides three general forms of decentralization in government. The first

    is devolution wherein the LGUs are given full autonomy and control over their assigned publicservices, subject only to oversight by the national government. In 1991, for example, most health

    functions were devolved to LGUs in the country. In this case, the devolved health personnel

    answer directly to local elected officials, who are responsible to their constituents.

    The second form is deconcentration wherein the lower-level offices are bestowed

    additional functions, powers or responsibility previously held by the higher-level offices within

    the same government department or agency. Beginning in 2001, for example, more

    responsibilities were delegated to sub-national education officials in the country. In this case,

    the lower-level officials are still accountable to their superiors in the department.

    Lastly, the third form of decentralization is the delegation of government functions to

    parastatal units, private sector groups or non-government organizations who now act as agents

    of the national government. The private sector group or NGO may be involved in service

    production, delivery or financing, or in the monitoring and regulation of public services.

    When the DOH, for example, commissions a medical association to train or certify local

    health personnel or screen facilities for licensing, then it delegates some of its functions to a

    private organization. The accountability of the private organization in this case is to the

    contracting government agency.

    Emerging Inter-LGU arrangements

    One strand in the literature argues that in some circumstances smaller jurisdictions in

    terms of geographic size and functional responsibilities can provide local officials with better

    information about their citizens preferences and can thus make them more responsive and

    directly accountable to the needs of their service clients. The larger number of competing local

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    10/27

    governments will give individuals more choices in publicly- provided services, and thereby will

    better accommodate differences in preferences for these services.

    Another strand favors larger jurisdictions that yield benefits from economies of scale

    while promoting consistency in service quality. They are also in a better position to internalize

    the costs and benefits of externalities generated by publicly-provided services. Moreover, theinformational advantages associated with smaller arrangements can also be achieved in a

    consolidated set-up a national government agency, for example can assign some functions of

    the central office to the local offices, which have direct and frequent contact with service clients

    (Bardhan 2002).

    Both factors - the economies of scale and customized local provision seem to underlie

    the current arrangement of local health systems in the Philippines. The emergence of the inter-

    LGU health arrangements is better appreciated within the context of the countrys nearly

    twenty years of decentralization experience. Relative to the expected efficiency gains from a

    devolved health setup, the realized gains are found modest, partly because of the weaknesses inthe design and implementation of the Local Government Code of 1991 (Lieberman, Capuno and

    Van Minh, 2005).

    One purported gain is the increasing share LGUs in total health expenditures, which

    contributed to the rise in the share of health expenditures to GDP 2.9 percent in 1992 to about

    3.3 percent in 2005 (Capuno and Kraft 2009). Per capita health spending has increased from PhP

    334 in 1992 to about PhP 507 in 2005, representing a real 48 percent growth from 1992 levels.

    Further evidence from a study by Racelis et al. (2005) on the Philippine National Health

    Accounts suggest that total health expenditures exhibit an increasing trend in both real and per

    capita terms after devolution, although minor setbacks were encountered in 1998, 2001 and

    2002.

    Under devolution, LGUs have also exhibited a capacity for innovation, particularly in

    terms of establishing partnerships with the local communities, private sector, and non-

    government organizations or in integrating health objectives into other programs of the local

    government. Under the current setup, LGUs were also able to leverage existing systems (e.g.

    health insurance) to solve health problems specific in their areas.

    Some LGUs were able to hire more doctors and acquire more supplies that enabled them

    to improve health outcomes. Infant mortality rate also continued to decline since 1991, implyingthat some desired trends in health were sustained despite the weaknesses in the Local

    Government Code. Notwithstanding the proliferation of innovations in local public services, the

    impact of devolution on health outcomes and outputs remains ambiguous at best.

    The financing constraints, political realities, differences in organizational capacity, and

    other institutional factors have led to insufficient services and deterioration in both the levels

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    11/27

    and quality of devolved health services. Differences in human resource capacities, as evidenced

    by the inability of some LGUs to hire doctors, nurses and other critical health personnel, and,

    more starkly, the unequal distribution of executive talents have led to widening variations in

    performance across LGUs. Some LGUs are lucky to have innovative local chief executives.

    Ostensibly, the devolution of the different levels of health functions followed theadministrative hierarchy of levels of governments in the country. On the one hand, the

    Department of Health retained responsibility over the regional and specialty hospitals and

    public health programs. On the other hand, the provincial governments took charge of the

    devolved curative care services and most secondary and tertiary-level hospitals, while

    municipal and city governments handle primary care and the operation of smaller facilities

    such as the rural health units and barangay health stations.

    Proposed Amendments

    The landmark legislation, Republic Act No. 7160, otherwise known as the Local

    Government Code of 1991 (LGC), introduced sweeping challenges in the Philippines political

    process. The LGC dramatically shifted power from central government to local governments. Its

    end goal is to unleash the potentials at the local level. It redirected the countrys strategies to be

    locally driven as it transferred the responsibilities for the delivery of basic services to the LGUs,

    including appropriate personnel, assets, equipment, programs and projects. The LGC altered

    the mode, configuration and level of services that local government provides.

    As Balisacan et al (2006) puts it, the code enlarges local bureaucracy, expressly grants

    local governments the authority to implement organizational reforms in order to perform

    effectively in a decentralized set-up, increases the financial capacity of LGUs, allows local

    governments to seek alternative forms of service delivery, provides for popular participation in

    decision-making and program implementation, and localizes accountability.

    In the Philippines, one promise of decentralization is better local service delivery for an

    improved quality of life (Magno, 2001; Manasan, 2007). However, for decentralization to realize

    this, certain prerequisites which are mainly about policy, institutions, and finance - must be

    met.

    First, the design of decentralization needs to be based on rightsizing and proper phasing

    of intergovernmental transfer of powers, functions, and responsibilities. The abrupt transfer ofpowers, functions, and responsibilities, especially on the decentralization of certain sectors such

    as health, social services, and agriculture, has created a mismatch between LGUs powers and

    their responsibilities and their institutional and financial capacities.

    This has impacted on the delivery of services and public goods. In health for example,

    the cost of devolution (PS and MOOE), has made the LGUs, particularly the provinces,

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    12/27

    incapable of delivering public goods and services; hence, the clamor to return health service

    responsibilities to the national government.

    Second, the institutional actors both local and national should be capacitated and be

    imbued with a sense of urgency to own up the local service delivery agenda as a way to make

    decentralization work for the people through their innovative ideas, capabilities, and politicalwill. With many LCEs not having the required capabilities and political will to own up the local

    service delivery agenda, people suffer from poor quality of education and poor health and

    sanitation.

    Third, the functions, functionaries, and funds demand no less than commensurate

    transfer and burden-sharing of the required capacity-building, institutional development, and

    financial sustainability. The resultant resource constraints and institutional deficits experienced

    by LGUs, mostly by 5th and 6th class municipalities and their barangays, as well as the low-

    income provinces, greatly impact on the quality and quantity of services delivered.

    Saddling these resource-starved LGUs with costly devolved functions in health,

    education, and water for example, compounds their inability as institutional functionaries in

    meeting the supply-side of governance and the basic needs of their people. The problems of

    devolution described are very much apparent in the health sector particularly in the quality of

    maternal and child health care services.

    Capuno (2009) observes an overall decline in the means of both Infant Mortality Rate

    and Maternal Mortality Ratio in the years 2000 to 2008, the standard deviation has been

    increasing among provinces.In spite of the downward trend, the Philippines still has a high

    MMR when compared with other countries. Some 230 women die in the Philippines for every

    100,000 live births, compared with 110 in Thailand, 62 in Malaysia and 14 in Singapore.

    To address this problem, the DOH and UNICEF now assiduously promote facility-based

    delivery, in lieu of home-based delivery unless attended by skilled health professionals. This

    strategy is adopted given the observation that countries with modest per capita incomes but

    high proportions of facility-based deliveries have achieved relatively low mortality ratios.

    Furthermore, the poor performance of the Philippines when it comes maternal and child

    mortality rates can be partly attributed to the low percentage of facility-based deliveries. The

    World Health Organization estimates that about 72 percent of deliveries in the Philippines

    occur outside of health facilities, frequently without the assistance of a skilled birth attendant,

    and many deliveries do not meet the minimal conditions for early essential newborn care.

    Arguably, a greater reduction in IMR and MMR can be achieved with the concentrated

    health interventions of local governments, namely the provinces and municipalities. There are

    both administrative and political reasons why these local governments will consolidate their

    devolved health services. Majority of the reasons expressed by the local government units is the

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    13/27

    narrow fund dedicated for health, especially investing on health facilities and program

    interventions.

    Creating the Special Health Fund

    The proposed special fund shall be managed by the Local Health Board. Thus thefollowing provision in the Local Government Code shall be:

    SECTION 235. Additional levy on real property for the Special Education Fund

    and Special Health Fund Province or city, or a municipality may levy and

    collect an annual tax of TWO PERCENT (2%) on the assessed value of real

    property which shall be in addition to the basic real property tax. The proceeds

    thereof shall exclusively accrue to Special Education Fund and Special Health

    Fund, each amounting to the equivalent one percent (1%) of the aforecited real

    property tax allocation and application of proceeds shall include the following:

    a) The proceeds of the additional one percent real property tax accruingto special health fund shall be automatically released to the local

    health boards

    b) In case of provinces, the proceeds shall be divided equally betweenthe provincial and municipal health boards

    c) Said proceeds shall be allocated as determined and approved by thelocal health boards concerned for the following purposes:

    1. Operation and maintenance of public hospitals, rural healthcenters;

    2. Construction and Repair of Health Centers, Health Facilitiesand Equipment;

    3. Medical and Health Research;4. Purchase of Medicines, if warranted; and5. Training of Local Public Health Officers

    Congruent to the increase of another percent (1%) in the additional levy on real

    property, is the empowerment of the local health board in decision-making. The lack of

    preparation of introducing the decentralization process resulted not only resulted to

    decreased hospital occupancy and health center utilization rates, untimely or decreased

    procurement of medicines and supplies, decreased but also the lack of capacity to

    handle devolved health services.

    Phased decentralization and good governance

    The Philippine experience on decentralization is contrary to the Rwandan experience

    which provides a more conclusive phased decentralization. According to the Ministry of Local

    Government, Good Governance, Community Development and Social Affairs, the

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    14/27

    decentralization process is being implemented in three successive phases. The first phase (2000-

    2005) established democratic and community development structures. To facilitate the

    functioning of these structures, a number of legal, institutional and policy reforms were

    undertaken. This prompted the creation of a matured local set-up to implement the devolved

    health services.

    The second phase was characterized by banking on progress and enhanced effectiveness

    in service delivery to communities. This was achieved by increasing capacities at levels of

    administration (Villages, Cells and Sectors) close to communities, promotion of integrated local

    economic development and fostering community participation at Village level, in the planning

    and management of local affairs.

    The third phase of implementation (2011-2015) will improve and sustain the

    achievements of the first two phases. The number of administrative entities will be further

    reduced to diminish the distance between upper and lower levels of administration and make

    the Government more effective, efficient and responsive to peoples needs and preferences. Inthis phase, multi-sectoral decentralization at local level will be reinforced and mechanisms for

    partnerships between public sector and non-state organizations will be operational.

    On 31 December 2005, Law No 29/2005 determining the administrative entities of the

    Republic of Rwanda was published and represented the legal basis of the Local Administration

    Reform Policy, adopted in 2005 with the following specific objectives: to promote and enhance

    effectiveness in service delivery by making the Sector a truly service; delivery focal point with

    adequate human, material and financial capacity, and to improve collection of data and

    information at this level; to streamline and strengthen the coordination of public services and

    local economic development at District Level by availing more technically competent personnel

    as well as financial resources to the District to ensure sustainable decentralized fiscal regimes;

    to strengthen the coordination of development activities; to establish and strengthen coherent

    monitoring and evaluation systems as well as institutionalize accountability tools and systems .

    The administrative organization of Rwanda is guided by the principle of subsidiarity.

    The Central Government agencies roles and responsibilities are mainly in policy formulation,

    regulation and support to Local Governments through capacity building, financing and

    monitoring and evaluation throughout a steady pace.

    Local Governments with the administrative entities are mainly in charge of

    implementation of government policies and service delivery, and provide an avenue for citizenvoice and accountability. In this type of set-up, the decentralization implementation process

    has been successful in reinforcing institutional capacity building in participatory (bottom-up)

    planning, budgeting and monitoring and evaluation.

    The first phase of the decentralization process widely promoted the creation of effective

    partnerships between communities, local governments, central government, private sector, non-

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    15/27

    governmental organizations and international development partners, to engage in projects and

    programs for improving local development and delivery of services through a joint fund. This

    was evidenced by recent studies and surveys, which showed high rates of satisfaction among

    citizens with the level of participation in decentralized governance and development program

    through transparency and solidarity.

    Citizens effectively participated in local governance and resources are managed in a

    transparent and accountable manner. The phased decentralization policy has been specifically

    designed to empower local governance structures with appropriate autonomy to bring public

    administration closer to the people, and to make local governance accountable to the electorate.

    Accountability embraces political, administrative and fiscal dimensions that need to be

    reinforced along with mechanisms to improve transparency in public affairs of local

    governments.

    Imposing Mandatory Ad Valorem Tax for Idle Lands

    Mixed Feedback on Quality

    While the Department of Health has achieved a certain degree of devolution with

    respect to functions, the quality of healthcare delivery after devolving the major tasks to LGUs

    remains to be mixed. However, the challenges seem to be consistent. Experts expressed concern

    over the deterioration of technical quality, while most of the people expressed more positive

    views (de Mello et al, 2000). In the area of technical performance, there was no significant

    change in the volume of in-patients treated or outpatient consultations in spite of quality of care

    which deteriorated in terms of supplies, equipment and infrastructure because of decreased

    funds for maintenance and other operating expenses (MOOE) and almost non-existent funds for

    capital outlay.

    The major setback of devolution is that it resulted in the significant deterioration of

    employment conditions of devolved personnel, causing demoralization. In the health sector,

    salaries of devolved workers decreased relative to central government employees (by one-fifth

    to one-third on average), and civil-servant vertical career mobility was interrupted by the

    fragmentation of the public health system (Miller 1998). Strong objections from healthcare

    workers brought about the passing of the Magna Carta of Health Workers which resulted in

    further disarray.

    Some LGU officials became demoralized because some health workers received highersalaries than LGU executives. These gave local chief executives a reason to pressure the national

    government to fund the implementation of the Magna Carta of Health Workers and provide for

    the compensation of health personnel.

    In People of the Philippines versus Florendo (2004), the Magna Carta Benefits were paid

    100% by the National Government to the Municipal Health Workers of V. Sagun, Zamboanga

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    16/27

    del Sur. Salary increase as per Local Budget Circular No. 54 could not be implemented since the

    salaries of organic personnel have not equaled after the necessary adjustment to that of the

    devolved health workers of the municipality. For 1995, the Magna Carta Benefits were not

    implemented due to insufficiency of funds. Instead devolved health workers were given

    Productivity Incentive Benefits.

    In 1996, only 50% of the Magna Carta Benefits were implemented again due to

    insufficiency of funds and instead were provided Productivity Incentive Benefits. Under

    Republic Act 7305, public health workers are entitled to a host of benefits. Mandating hospitals,

    whether devolved or not, to provide Magna Carta Benefits without giving offices the

    appropriate budget and restricting the implementation despite the enactment is an outcry.

    Apparently, the budgets available to most of LGUs could not match all the requirements

    concerning human resources.

    Furthermore, the affected or devolved personnel have little or no chance of availing

    themselves of any training or scholarships, both local and foreign, because national employeesare being prioritized. If ever there is a chance, the LGUs usually will not have the counterpart

    funds required.

    As far as technical quality is concerned, despite the extensive devolution that took place

    in the health sector, there is a noticeable trend of re-nationalizing some hospitals. The DOH

    continues to retain 48 hospitals, 35 of which are classified as tertiary: hospitals that are fully

    departmentalized and equipped to treat most ailments. The number might have risen to 54

    because the DOH regularly brings back to the fold other hospitals that have been re-

    nationalized by Congress. The re-nationalization of these hospitals resulted in the DOH putting

    52% of its budget into the maintenance of these hospitals. This explains the continuous increase

    in the budget of the DOH, despite the devolution of almost 70 percent of its personnel.

    As a consequence of the national subsidy for these hospitals which are usually in the

    urban centers, a spatial bias has formed against rural and municipal health centersthe very

    ones which should have received bigger budgets, since these are where the more numerous but

    economically deprived members of society access health services.

    Local government units were forced to stretch all possible ways to make the demand of

    local service delivery and financial requirements meet (Solon, et al, 2009). The formal

    administrative mechanisms for integrating the operations of the devolved health services is

    expressed in the Local Government Code, it further stipulates that LGUs can form specialcooperative arrangements among themselves:

    Section 33. Cooperative Undertakings Among Local Government Units. - Local

    government units may, through appropriate ordinances, group themselves, consolidate,

    or coordinate their efforts, services, and resources for purposes commonly beneficial to

    them. In support of such undertakings, the local government units involved may, upon

    approval by the Sanggunian concerned after a public hearing conducted for the purpose,

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    17/27

    contribute funds, real estate, equipment, and other kinds of property and appoint or

    assign personnel under such terms and conditions as may be agreed upon by the

    participating local units through Memoranda of Agreement.

    Consistent with this provision, some LGUs have banded togther, presumably because oftheir common problems, shared goals or political alliances. For example, some LGUs have

    formed collaborative arrangements to tackle more specific development concerns in industry

    (e.g.Metro Iloilo-Guimaras Development Council), resource management (e.g. Northern Iloilo

    Alliance for Coastal Development), urbanization (e.g. Metro Cebu Development Council) and

    health (Inter-Local Health Zones).

    These configurations ranges from simple coordination in the planning and delivery of

    public services, to formal cooperation involving the joint use and financing of health services, to

    consolidation of devolved health services under the administration or supervision of the

    province or a single authority created for the purpose.

    Apart from these voluntary arrangements, LGUs in many provinces have also

    participated in the Province-wide Investment Plan for Health (PIPH), a strategy of the

    Department of Health to forge LGU partnerships to coordinate local health plans, secure

    resource commitments, and ensure the achievement of health goals in the province. Intended to

    be an integral part of the LGU development process, the PIPH deviates from the usual LGU

    planning practice wherein city or municipal development plans which include local health

    plans are reviewed and put together perfunctorily into one provincial development plan, with

    minimal regard for possible inconsistencies, duplications and potentials for possible economies

    of scale or externalities.

    To ensure LGU commitment, the plans under the PIPH are supposedly developed in a

    participatory manner, implemented with support from the DOH and donor institutions, and

    monitored and evaluated based on results.

    Thus, as a means of support the little room of public expenditure, it is further

    proposed to amend the following in the Local Government Code:

    SECTION 236. Additional Ad Valorem Tax on Idle Lands. A city or a

    municipality shall levy an annual ad valorem tax on idle lands at the rate of 20%

    of the assessed value of the property tax which shall be in addition to the basic

    real property tax.

    SECTION 237. Idle lands, Coverage. For purposes of real property taxation, idle

    lands shall include the following:

    a. Agricultural lands, more than one hectare in area, suitable forcultivation, farming, dairying, inland, fishery, poultry and other

    agricultural uses, one-half of which remain uncultivated or

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    18/27

    unimproved by the owner of the property or person having legal

    interest therein. Agricultural lands planted with permanent trees of at

    least fifty trees to a hectare, or a proportion thereof if less than one

    hectare, shall not be considered idle lands. Lands actually used for

    grazing purposes shall likewise not be considered idle lands.

    b. Lands, other than agricultural, located in a city or municipality, morethan 1,000 square meters in area one-half of which remain unutilized

    or unimproved by the owner of the property or person having legal

    interest therein. The planting of permanent crops or trees of at least 50

    trees to a hectare, or a proportion thereof if less than one hectare, shall

    not be considered idle lands.

    c. Regardless of land area, this section shall likewise apply to:i. Residential lots in subdivisions duly approved by proper

    authorities, the ownership of which has been transferred to the

    buyer-owners, who shall be liable for the additional tax:

    Provided that individual lots, the ownership of which has notbeen transferred to the buyer shall be considered as part of the

    subdivision, and shall be subject to the additional tax payable

    by subdivision owner or developer; and

    ii. Vacant lots intended for commercial, industrial, or residentialor condominium projects duly approved by proper authorities

    shall be subject to the additional tax until full completion of

    the construction or project as certified by engineer/building

    officials of the local government concerned.

    SECTION 273. Proceeds of Tax on Idle Lands. The proceeds of the additional ad

    valorem real property tax on idle lands shall accrue to the special health fund.

    The imposition of the idle tax under the present provisions of RA 7160 is optional

    on the part of the local government units concerned. The proposed amendments is to

    make it mandatory and increased from 5% to 20% of the assessed value of the real

    property, in addition to the basic real property tax due.

    The proliferation of idle and unproductive private lands should bear economic,

    environmental and social functions. It addresses two-fold challenges for the government

    as it would raise additional funds to address basic service delivery to the less-privileged

    members of society.

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    19/27

    Expanding the basis of Internal Revenue Shares

    Local Government Functions and Financing

    Hospitals serve as the locus of health care delivery in the Philippines. Survey data shows

    that most households go directly to hospitals for treatment of illnesses. With the breakdown ofreferral networks due to devolution, tertiary level hospitals which are designed to cater to more

    serious diseases are also accommodating cases that can be handled to attend all its patients. In

    the Philippines, a total of 1,578 hospitals were registered with the Department of Health in 2007.

    Public hospitals account only for 39% of the total number of hospitals and are usually bigger

    than private hospitals and relatively have higher number of beds as shown in the following

    graph.

    FIGURE 2

    Number of Hospital Beds, Public and Private

    (Philippine National Health Accounts, National Statistical Coordination Board)

    Among the factors that affect the utilization of health facilities are geographical barriers,

    cost of medical care and demography. Based on rough estimates on the 2003 National

    Demographic and Health Survey, it shows that among those who utilized any health care

    facility, 52% came from urban and 48% came from rural areas.

    The type of health facility utilized also depends on the wealth level of households. The

    poorest of the poor quintiles tend to utilize public facilities while the richer quintiles utilize

    private clinics and hospitals.

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    20/27

    TABLE 3Utilization of Health Facilities by Wealth Quintile, 2003

    (Lavados calculation based on 2003 National Demographic Household Survey, 2009)

    With the breakdown of referral networks, tertiary hospitals which are designed to cater

    to more serious diseases are also accommodating cases that can be handled by lower-level

    facilities. This leads to tertiary hospitals requiring more financial resources to be able to attend

    to all its patients. Aside from being expensive, the current arrangement leads to overcrowding

    of tertiary facilities. The mismatch in the capability of tertiary facilities and the severity of cases

    to cater to make costs of seeking health care higher not only for facilities but for patients as well.

    The LGC provides for inter-governmental fiscal relations between National Government

    and LGUs also known as vertical fiscal relation and between and among LGUs or horizontal

    fiscal relations.

    Vertical fiscal relation between NG and LGUs are in the areas of: (i) Shares in internal

    revenue taxes (Sec. 284); (ii) Shares (40% other than the 40% internal revenue allotment) of

    LGUs of the gross collection in the exploitation of national wealth within their respective areas

    preceding the fiscal year (Sec. 290); (iii) Shares from the proceeds of government agencies or

    government-owned or controlled corporations in utilizing and developing national wealth (Sec.

    291); (iv) borrowings of LGUs either from private or public sources (Sec 297); and (v) local

    budgets submission and review.

    Section 284 provides for the forty percent (40%) shares in the national internal revenue

    taxes of local government units. A differentiated allotment scheme is followed: (i) Provinces

    Twenty-percent (23%); (ii) Cities - Twenty-percent (23%); (iii) Municipalities Thirty-four

    percent (34%); and (iv) Barangays Twenty percent (20%). This revenue-sharing is based on an

    FACILITY POOREST POORER MIDDLE RICHER RICHEST

    Any health facility 18.4 21.1 20.6 20.2 19.7

    Barangay Health

    Station

    28.2 27.6 21.4 14.9 7.9

    Rural HealthUnit/Barangay

    Health Center

    20 24.4 23 21 11.7

    Municipal Hospital 19.2 26.4 19.8 22.4 12.2

    District Hospital 21.3 23.4 22.5 18.3 14.4

    Provincial Hospital 16 26 20.7 21.5 15.8

    Regional Hospital 19.8 20.5 20.6 30 19.1

    Private Clinic 7.5 13 18.2 27.1 34.1

    Private Hospital 4.5 8.9 16.6 24.7 45.3

    Others 22.9 19.8 19.8 21.3 16.3

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    21/27

    allotment formula: (i) Population Fifty percent (50%), (ii) Land Area Twenty-five percent

    (25%), and (iii) Equal Sharing Twentyfive percent (25%).

    Each barangay shall receive a minimum of eighty thousand pesos per annum (P80,000)

    depending on its population to be charged against the twenty percent (20%) share of the

    barangay from IRA. Also, LGC grants LGUs credit financing powers to create indebtednessand to enter into credit and other financial transactions (Sec. 295) for human development and

    other purposes.

    These may be in the form of loans and credits with any government or domestic private

    bank and other lending institutions (Sec. 297); issuance of bonds and other long-term securities

    subject to the rules and regulations of the Central Bank and the Securities and Exchange

    Commission (Sec. 299); inter-LGU loans, grants, and subsidies (Sec. 300); loans from foreign

    sources through national government (Sec. 301); and contracts with the private sector (Sec. 302).

    In Book II of 1991 LGC, LGUs are granted taxing and revenue-raising powers. Section129 states that Each local government unit shall exercise its power to create its own sources of

    revenue and levy taxes, fees, and charges subject to the provisions herein, consistent with the

    basic policy of local autonomy. Examples of local revenue generating sources are: (a) Province:

    Real property tax, Tax on transfer of real property ownership, Tax on business of printing and

    publication, Franchise tax, Sand and gravel tax, Professional tax, Amusement tax on admission,

    and Annual fixed tax per delivery truck or van of manufacturers or producers of or dealers in

    certain products; (b) Municipalities: Tax on business, Fees and charges, Fishery rental or fees

    and charges, Fees for sealing and licensing of weights and measures, and Community tax; (c)

    Cities: The cities either highly-urbanized or independent component cities - may levy and

    collect among others any of the taxes, fees and other impositions which the province or

    municipality may impose; and (d) Barangays: Taxes and fees, Service charges, and

    Contributions.

    However, there are still constraints that the IRA allocation formula leaves provinces and

    municipalities at the losing end. Both levels of LGUs combined received 57% of the transfers but

    shoulder 92.5% of the cost of devolved functions, including health, while cities and barangays

    bear only 5.7% if the cost of devolution but receives 43% of IRA. Thus, provinces and

    municipalities complain that budgets is inadequate to fulfill health and responsibility devolved

    to them (Atienza, 2003).

    There are LGUs, particularly municipalities, that are simply too poor to assume all itshealth responsibilities even if they wanted to. Second, even if an LGU has sufficient budget,

    local chief executives and officials may not prioritize health. Finally, there may be a large

    allocation for health but people in the locality may be too many for the budget to be adequate.

    For example, a poor rural municipality like Irosin, Surigao noted for its successful

    participatory health programs only spent roughly P90.31 per constituent based on its 2000

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    22/27

    health budget and population. Meanwhile, a high-income, heavily-populated municipality such

    as Baliuag, with Sentrong Sigla-certified health facilities, roughly spent P83.93 per constituent

    based on its 2000 budget and population (Atienza 2003).

    As an offshoot of the financing, Diokno (2003) posits that rapid conversion from 72

    municipalities to cities during the last 20 years, made a lot of sense since the IRA of cities couldincrease several times over by simply converting from municipalities to cities. This

    phenomenon imposes no additional financial burden on the national government. Its a zero-

    sum game. But there are losers and winners among LGUs: the big winners are the newly

    converted cities; the big losers are the old cities that have to settle for a lower IRA.

    Diokno continues to opine that the IRA allocation has created perverse results: the

    higher, predictable, formula-based, and mandatory grant system has resulted in heavier

    dependence of by local government units on the IRA. LGUs never had it so good. Instead of

    being stimulative, the IRA has become a substitute for raising own taxes for most local

    governments.

    To put it frankly, local authorities have become lazy collecting own taxes. This is true for

    most local communities, with the exception of some urban communities. The reliance on the

    IRA is more pronounced for municipalities and provinces rather than cities. In 2010, IRA as

    share of total revenues were 79 percent, 75%, and 50% for municipalities, provinces and cities,

    respectively.

    Cities happen to have broader tax bases than both municipalities and provinces. Local

    health services, social welfare and local public infrastructure did not get top priority spending.

    More were spent for general public services, that is salaries and wages for officials and

    employees, and in running the office of the local chief executive and local councils.

    However, Dioknos opinion is rebutted by a careful study of Hiroko Uchimura and

    Yurika Suzuki in 2009 on fiscal decentralization of the 1991 Local Government Code, which

    found that the heavy dependence of local governments is evident on intergovernmental fiscal

    transfers and that the gap of total revenues by provincial governments in 2000 is wider than

    that in 1990.

    According to the study, the expenditure discretion of local governments is exceptionally

    high in the country. However, qualitatively, the degree of local expenditure discretion lessens.

    Along with the fiscal decentralization in the country, the local expenditure responsibilityincreased while the fiscal capacity was not strengthened.

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    23/27

    Lorenz Curve of Total Revenue Lorenz Curve of Tax Revenue including IRA

    FIGURE 3

    Fiscal Revenue Gap between Provinces in 1990 and 2000

    (Measuring Fiscal Decentralization in the Philippines, 2009)

    Figure 3 shows that the Lorenz curve of tax revenues excluding IRAs in 2000 is located

    outside that in 1990. The Lorenz curve of tax revenues excluding IRAs in 2000 is located outside

    that in 1990 which means that the gap of tax revenues including IRAs in 2000 also becomes

    wider that that in 1990, although the width is less than for tax revenues excluding IRAs. This is

    an indication, according to Uchimura, that IRAs become more important for alleviating the

    disparity of local tax revenues between provinces in 2000 as it has expanded greatly after thedecentralization.

    IRAs contribute to alleviating tax revenue gaps between provincial governments,

    nonetheless, the local tax revenue gaps between provincial governments expanded greatly after

    decentralization.

    Prior to the LGC, the share of IRA to the different levels of LGUs was 27% to provinces,

    22.5% to cities, 40.5% to municipalities and 10% to barangays. According to Manasan (2007),

    barangays have been the biggest gainers in the reallocation of IRAs in the decentralization,

    while provinces and municipalities are at the losing end. Thus, the aforementioned restrictionsmay be solved by increasing the weight given to equal sharing to equalize IRA in the following

    amendment:

    SECTION 285. Allocation to local government units, the share of the local

    government units in the internal revenue allotment shall be allocated starting in

    2004, after deducting therefrom the cost of devolved functions and capital

    outlays, increased at the rate of 10% per annum shall be distributed and directly

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    24/27

    remitted to the local government units concerned and the net or balance of the

    internal revenue allotment shall be allocated in the following manner:

    a) Provinces Twenty three percent (23%)b) Cities Twenty three percent (23%)c) Municipalities Twenty percent (20%)d) Municipalities Thirty percent (34%)

    Provided, however, that the share of each province, city, and municipality shall

    be determined on the basis on the following formula:

    a) Population Fifty percent (23%)b) Land Area Twenty five percent (25%)c) Equal Sharing Twenty percent (25%)

    Provided further that the share of each barangay with a population of not lessthan one hundred inhabitants (100) inhabitants shall not be less than Eighty

    thousand (P80,000.00) per annum chargeable against the twenty percent (20%)

    share of the barangay from the internal revenue allotment, and the balance to be

    allocated on the basis of the following formula:

    (a) On the first year of the effectivity of this Code:

    (1) Population - Forty percent (40%); and

    (2) Equal sharing - Sixty percent (60%)

    (b) On the second year:

    (1) Population - Fifty percent (50%); and

    (2) Equal sharing - Fifty percent (50%)

    (c) On the third year and thereafter:

    (1) Population - Sixty percent (60%); and

    (2) Equal sharing - Forty percent (40%).

    Provided, finally, that the financial requirements of barangays created by local

    government units after the effectivity of this Code shall be the responsibility of

    the local government unit concerned.

    Fixing at least 5% in the Local Development Projects for Health

    The demonstrated lack of operational costs and a sufficient revenue base limits

    the capacity of frontline managers and public health workers

    SECTION 287. Local Development Projects Each local government unit shall

    appropriate in its annual budget no less than twenty percent (20%) of its annual

    internal revenue allotment for development projects, fixing 5% for health and

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    25/27

    health related programs and activities. Copies of the development plans of local

    governments shall be furnished to the Department of Interior and Local

    Government.

    With the aforementioned premises, a strategic retreat from devolution is not only legally

    problematic but also politically unpalatable. Devolution has even come to be associated withdemocratization as the transition from a centralized regime to one characterized by meaningful

    local autonomy is never easy. While the negative effects of devolution on health care systems in

    developing countries have been well documented, the innovative and effective programs LGUs

    have implemented in their respective communities show that devolution can actually work.

    Conclusion

    A primary aim of decentralization is to increase the resource base for primary

    care, by shifting as many resources as possible from central to peripheral locations. The

    experience in the Philippines is that LGUs often lacked the financial commitment andcapacity to fund post-devolution services.

    Secondly, the decentralization expanded the decision-making space of middle

    and lower level managers, in order to increase the responsiveness of sub-national

    authorities to local health needs and situations. Comparing to Asian neighbors, the

    Philippines style of administrative decentralization is the most extensive.

    Lastly, decentralization is there to enhance the efficiency and effectiveness of

    health services management through prompt and appropriate middle level management

    decision-making. The introduction of devolution has been associated with the

    complication efforts to construct logical hierarchies of health services, mainly due to

    existence of gray areas of responsibility between systems and the lack of preparation of

    local managers to take on new roles.

    The critical resolution of the decentralization challenge in the Philippines is to

    widen the revenue base of local government units. With the proposed amendments of

    creating a special health fund, imposing ad valorem tax for idle lands, increasing the

    revenue base, and fixing at least 5% for health in the local development plans, the

    primordial dilemma can be solved, mitigated the least.

    Local service delivery, being triangulated by policy, institutions, and finance,and more specifically, by good policy environment and effectiveness, can be achieved by

    inter-governmental fiscal and financial system, and accountable institutional actors. To

    assume, generally, that devolution failed in the Philippines is to constrict

    democratization.

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    26/27

    References

    Atienza, Maria Ela L. (2003). The Politics of Health Devolution in the Philippines with

    Emphasis on Experiences of Municipalities in a Devolved Set-up. Unpublished

    dissertation submitted to the Graduate School of International Cooperation

    Studies, Kobe University, Japan, June 20.

    Balisacan, M. Arsenio and Hal Hill, Regional Development Dynamics and

    Decentralization in the Philippines: Ten Lessons from a Starter, Australian

    National University, Economic RSPAS, Department Working Papers, 2006.

    Bardhan, P. (2002), Decentralization of Government and Development, Journal of

    Economic Perspectives 16(4):185-205.

    Bardhan, P. and D. Mookherjee, eds. (2006). Decentralization and Local Governance in

    Developing Countries, A Comparative Perspective. Cambridge, MA: The MITPress.

    Brillantes, Alex, Jr. B. (1998). Decentralized Democratic Government Under the Local

    Government Code: A Governmental Perspective. Philippine Journal of Public

    Administration 42 (1 and 2): 38-57.

    Capuno, J.J. and A.D. Kraft. (2009). Equity in Delivery of Health and Education Services

    in the Philippines: Background Country Report. Report Submitted to the Asian

    Development Bank.

    Campos, J.E. and J.S. Hellman (2005) Governance and Local: Does Decentralization

    improve accountability? in R. White and P. Smoke (eds.) East Asia Decentralizes:

    Making Local Government Work. Washington, DC: The World Bank. pp. 237-252

    de Mello, J.R., R. Luiz. Fiscal Decentralizarion and Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations:

    A Cross-Country Analysis, World Development, Vol. 28, No. 2, 2000. pp. 365-380.

    Department of Health (2007). Field Health Service Information System Annual Reports.

    Manila: Department of Health.

    Diokno, B. E. (2003). Decentralization in the Philippines after 10 years: What have welearned? What have I learned? UPSE Discussion Paper No. 0308. University of

    the Philippines School of Economics. Diliman, Quezon City

    Lavado, R. F. et al (2010). How are government hospitals performing? A study of

    resource management in Government-Retained Hospitals. PIDS Discussion Paper

    Series 2010-02

  • 7/28/2019 Broadening the Fiscal Design of Local Autonomy.pdf

    27/27

    Lieberman, S.S., J.J. Capuno, and H. Van Minh (2005), Health Decentralization: Some

    Lessons from Indonesia, Philippines and Vietnam, pp.155-78 in R. White and P.

    Smoke (eds), East Asia Decentralizes: Making Local Government Work,

    Washington DC: World Bank.

    Ministry of Local Government, Good Governance, Community Development and Social

    Affairs,, R. G. (2007). Local Public Finance in the Philippines: Lessons in

    Autonomy and Accountability. Philippine Journal of Development, 60 (1): 31-102.

    Magno, C. (2001). Devolution: An Unhealthy Mix of Politics. Paper delivered at the

    Local Governance Policy Forum, Manila. November.

    Ministry of Local Government, Good Governance, Community Development and Social

    Affairs, Rwanda Decentralization Strategic Framework. 2007. Rwanda.

    National Statistical Coordination Board (2007). 2007 Philippine Statistical Yearbook.

    Manila: National Statistical Coordination Board.

    National Statistical Coordination Board (1010). 2007 Philippine National Health Account.

    http://www.nscb.gov.ph/stats/pnha/2007/shareexpdt.asp

    North D. C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge,

    UK: Cambridge University Press.

    People of the Philippines versus Florendo et al. Criminal Case No. 25028. 2004.

    Racelis, R., F. Dy-Liaco, R. Sabenano, M. Beltran, and T. Manaoag. (2005). The National

    Health Accounts of the Philippines: Continuing Development and New

    Findings. Philippine Journal of Development, 62 (1&2): 179-210/

    Romualdez et. al. (2011). The Philippine Health System Review. Asia Pacific

    Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. Health Systems in Transition Vol.1,

    No. 2.

    Solon, O., R. V. Fabella and J. J. Capuno (2009). Is local development Good Politics?

    Local Development expenditures and the re-election of governors in thePhilippines in the 1990s.Asian Journal of Political Science 17 (3): 264-284.

    Uchimura, H. and Y. Suzuki, (2009). Measuring Fiscal Decentralization in the

    Philippines. ID E Discussion Paper. 209. 2009.

    http://www.nscb.gov.ph/stats/pnha/2007/shareexpdt.asphttp://www.nscb.gov.ph/stats/pnha/2007/shareexpdt.asphttp://www.nscb.gov.ph/stats/pnha/2007/shareexpdt.asp