102
ASIAN FINANCIAL REFORM AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE – DUALITY OF DEVELOPMENT 1 World Bank-Japan East Asia Prospects Project International Steering Committee Meeting Shanghai 28 June 2002 I. Introduction My thesis is very simple: the historical dual-track mercantilist model of Asian development, a globally efficient export sector with highly protected domestic agricultural and service sectors, while successful in the past, is no longer sustainable in the New Economy. The Asian models of corporate governance and financial sector strategy have to change accordingly. In the World Bank, I coined the five key factors or “P”s of financial markets. A financial market is all about People, trading financial Products across a process/Platform, under a set of Policy and Prudential 1 I am grateful to Ms Lim Yam Poh for research assistance in preparing this paper, to Dr Geng Xiao and Ms Tan Gaik Looi for valuable comments and Ms Rosetta Chiu for secretarial assistance. The views expressed here are entirely the personal views of the author and not attributable to the Securities and Futures Commission, Hong Kong. 799 87

Chapter 87 - 90

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Chapter 87 - 90

ASIAN FINANCIAL REFORM AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE – DUALITY OF DEVELOPMENT1

World Bank-Japan East Asia Prospects ProjectInternational Steering Committee MeetingShanghai 28 June 2002

I. Introduction

My thesis is very simple: the historical dual-track mercantilist model of Asian development, a globally efficient export sector with highly protected domestic agricultural and service sectors, while successful in the past, is no longer sustainable in the New Economy. The Asian models of corporate governance and financial sector strategy have to change accordingly.

In the World Bank, I coined the five key factors or “P”s of financial markets. A financial market is all about People, trading financial Products across a process/Platform, under a set of Policy and Prudential framework. Now that I have had more experience in the securities markets and dealing with corporate behaviour, I like to analyze Asian financial reform issues in the four key functions of financial markets: -

1 I am grateful to Ms Lim Yam Poh for research assistance in preparing this paper, to Dr Geng Xiao and Ms Tan Gaik Looi for valuable comments and Ms Rosetta Chiu for secretarial assistance. The views expressed here are entirely the personal views of the author and not attributable to the Securities and Futures Commission, Hong Kong.

799

87

Page 2: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

price discovery resource allocation risk management corporate governance

The financial markets can also be broken down into seven key “I”s factors:

1. information2. incentives3. issuers4. intermediaries5. infrastructure6. investors; and finally,7. I – the regulator.

II. Asian Policy in Financial Sector Reform

Asian policies in financial sector fundamentally and historically stemmed from its mercantilist approach to development. Given scarce resources and management skills, Asian policy makers took calculated but large bets in industrial policy, supplemented by mild financial repression to generate resources for development through an export-led growth policy, as the World Bank study on Asian Miracle demonstrated.

Because Asian enterprises were initially weak, the export-led strategy selected key firms (either state-owned or politically connected families) to spearhead development in leading industries, such as iron and steel, shipbuilding and in recent years, electronic chips. These industries were fostered through a combination of direct grants, tariff protection and also cheap financing. Hence, the banking and securities sector were tightly controlled or “guided” towards backing the “winners” or priority sectors.

800

Page 3: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

In North Asia, this gave rise to large industrial groups, such as Japanese keiretsus, Korean Chaebols and Chinese State-owned Enterprises (SOEs). In Southeast Asian economies, where industrial policy was not so obvious given their high natural resource base, state backing was generally for government-led companies (Singapore GLCs) or politically connected family led companies, such as Indonesia congloms.

The state-enterprise nexus took different forms in different Asian economies, but by and large and to different degrees, a dual economy emerged. The export-led sectors, closest to global competitive forces, were the most efficient, with corporate governance standards to match. The more protected natural resources and services sectors were political franchises to give to favoured firms, backed by protective barriers to foreign entry. These vested interests explain largely why few of these inward-looking firms or banks adopted international standards of corporate governance and many are still resistant to change. This basic dual nature of Asian policy thinking had huge implications on the shape of the Asian financial sector and the evolution of its corporate governance. As long as the duality exists, it will retard Asia’s migration into the New Economy.

Resource Allocation

Because of the export-led industrialization strategy, Asian dragons and tigers basically protected their banking systems, kept lending and deposit rates low to fund industrialization and infrastructure, without overly distorted resource allocation during the export-led phase. The result was a bank-dominated financial system. For example, Japanese households have 53% of their financial assets with the banks, compared

801

Page 4: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

with 11.4% for US households. Asian banking systems account for 80-140% of GDP in asset size, compared with only 60% of GDP for the US banking system.

In other words, too many resources were concentrated in the banking system, and if it allocated resources inefficiently (through non-performing loans), then the high level of Asian domestic savings was actually wasted. This was exactly what happened during the Asian asset bubble. The Asian crisis economies spent as much as 50% of their GDP to resolve NPLs. In some economies, this inefficiency has neither been fully recognized nor written off.

By and large, Asian policy makers did not like to encourage their domestic savers to invest abroad because this would reduce their source of cheap funds. This derived from the mercantilist policy, which can be called a “fish-trap” mentality. We like money to come in, but we do not like capital to flow out. As can be seen later, this mentality, which may not have been wrong during the early stages of development, had huge consequences for efficient resource allocation, price discovery, risk management and corporate governance.

Price Discovery

The dual nature of the Asian economy meant that domestic prices did not always reflect internationally competitive supply and demand conditions. While this was feasible in early stages of international trade, when transactions cost of goods, services and information were high, this cannot be sustained in a WTO and Internet world, where such transaction costs are coming down rapidly. Arbitrage in the New

802

Page 5: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

Economy is happening very fast, as domestic consumers have global choice of suppliers of goods and services.

This is particularly clear in the financial system, as can be demonstrated from two sets of Asian prices, interest rates and securities prices.

Because of the “fish trap” mentality, excessively high domestic savings on top of the inflow of foreign funds when securities markets were opened up, led to domestic asset bubbles, particularly where there was rigidity in local planning and land use laws. Excessive liquidity did not lead to high inflation in consumer prices, because most of the food and consumer durables were at internationally competitive price levels.

Asian policy makers, who were basically financially and fiscally quite prudent, understood that in order to keep the domestic labour force happy, you needed to keep key consumer supply prices stable, and this was achieved not through subsidies, but supply side efficiencies. However, in many service sectors, there was protection, but such inefficiencies did not show up in the CPI, but rather through NPLs.

As I have said elsewhere, Asian bank restructuring policies are currently doomed to failure if the credit risks are not priced correctly. Currently, Asian banking spreads [lending rate minus deposit rate and administrative costs before bad debt provision] are between 1.5% to 2%, but Asian non-performing loans (NPLs) are between 10% to 50% of the banks’ books. Clearly, many Asian banks cannot clean their NPLs through their own cash flow.

803

Page 6: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

If the cost of funds is excessively low, it is likely that the borrowers will waste their usage. Property developers found that they could borrow very long-term funds at cheap rates, leading to a self-fulfilling asset bubble. The more the banks were willing to lend for property, the larger the bubble.

Similarly, in the stock market, Asian PE ratios [with the exception of Hong Kong and Singapore] have tended to be high. There are structural and policy reasons why the PE ratio in Asia tends to be high. First, the float in public hands tends to be low, either because it is held by families, or by institutions that are within industry groups. In Japan, institutions, such as affiliated companies, insurance companies and pension funds, hold the bulk of equity so that these cross-holdings ensure that control is kept within the same “keiretsu” or conglomerate.

Secondly, high PE ratios would insulate the Asian corporations from being raided by foreign multinationals cheaply. Asian companies tend to be much higher leveraged than their US or European competitors. The high leverage means that with a smaller equity base, the majority shareholders retain their control without seceding power to minority shareholders.

Risk Management

Financial systems are supposed to distribute risks of the real sector. However, with a dominant banking system, too many risks are absorbed in the banks. Moreover, since the banks have low capital adequacy ratio, the ultimate risks in Asia are absorbed by the implicit or explicit deposit insurance schemes. In essence, Asian banking system suffers from inherent moral hazard.

804

Page 7: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

Moreover, fish-trap mentality was bad risk management. By keeping savings in domestic markets, Asian policy makers were concentrating risks, rather than diversifying them. The principle of risk diversification is to distribute the portfolio in assets that are negatively correlated with each other. Thus, the best way to diversify out of a domestic economy is to invest in foreign investments. The late de-regulation of exchange control and rules allowing Asian investors to invest abroad meant that retail investors were not able to diversify their risks in the event the domestic market declined.

Corporate Governance

The price and resource allocation distortions described above are a manifestation of the failure of Asian financial markets to evolve as an important check and balance on domestic corporate governance. Indeed, transparency and accounting practices worked against improving corporate governance. Trade protection and non-tariff barriers against investments by foreign strategic investors prevented weak companies from being taken over and restructured. Asians have tended to resolve problems by “internalizing losses” through mergers of failing institutions. For example, banking problems were solved initially through mergers and consolidation into larger banks. But the management problems that gave rise to financial failures were not addressed.

Poor accounting standards also hid the scale of losses. Asian banks also did not apply generally accepted Basle loan classification standards in accounting for non-performing loans. The result was

805

Page 8: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

that the true extent of Asian NPLs has always been debated between market analysts and the authorities.

The historical legacy of dominance by SOEs or closely-knit bank-corporate relationships, meant that generally there was insufficient protection of minority rights for investors in Asia. This is beginning to change. Currently, institutional investors are either domestic, which have close relationship with the companies, or foreign fund managers, who are less interested to put pressure on companies they invest in to improve corporate governance. Consequently, the internal and external pressures for change at the management level have not that been strong. Many succeeded by seniority or family/political connections and not necessarily by merit. Although the export business was kept vibrant and highly productive by their exposure to international competition, the bulk of the non-trade business – primarily agriculture, business services, construction and real estate – were highly inefficient with poor corporate governance and transparency.

These inefficiencies do not necessarily show up as bankruptcies, but as NPLs in the banking system.

III. The Three Disciplines

Good corporate governance is like a three-legged stool of key disciplines. First of all, we rely on the management or controlling shareholders to exercise self-discipline. This works when the controlling shareholders or management are highly ethical and treat minority shareholders fairly.

But if the morality and ethics are lacking, and when the internal checks and balances, such as independent board committees, internal and external

806

Page 9: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

audits, and the transparency of disclosure do not function well, then you need outside forms of discipline.

This is where regulatory discipline comes in. Regulatory discipline requires not only clear rules and regulations, but also good enforcement.

But self-discipline and regulatory discipline are not enough, without market discipline. Companies, when protected from competition, may develop cartels or monopolistic tendencies that do not treat consumers or investors fairly. These may deter foreign or minority investors from entering the market when they perceive that they are not treated equally.

Market discipline comes from two inter-related forces, market competition and global standards -

(1) To compete globally, the market demands professionalism and more effective management models. Previously protected industries will have to meet challenges from international competition and have to meet global standards of quality, code of conduct and accounting and disclosure rules.

(2) Greater transparency to global standards will force the enterprises and their management to greater accountability. In well-functioning markets, the market’s assessment of corporate performance is reflected in the prices of equities and bonds. Corporations that fail the test could find difficulty in raising new capital, and eventually be competed out of the market.

807

Page 10: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

Good corporate governance requires all three disciplines to keep the checks and balances for healthy companies.

Let me now dissect Asian financial sector and corporate governance issues into the seven “I” factors.

The first “I” is information. Accurate, timely and accessible information is a market fundamental. To have good information, you need to have international accounting standards (IAS) and good auditing standards. Enron, which is currently the largest corporate failure in history, has demonstrated clearly that without good information and good checks and balances, large companies can fail even in the best of regulated markets.

But Asia was slow to adopt rapidly international accounting and auditing standards, and even after the Asian crisis, implementation or adoption of such standards, including the loan classification standards, has been relatively slow.

Without good information, banks have not been able to exercise good credit culture and discipline. Management cannot exercise good risk management and decision-making and investors cannot exercise market discipline on the companies they invest in.

The second “I” is incentives. Currently, Asian incentives are skewed because of the inherent moral hazard of dual economy policies to protect depositors, protect domestic industries and reluctance to pay for the job. For example, civil service salaries and salaries of many state-owned or even family-dominated companies are not yet commensurate with the risk-reward structure of markets. For markets to

808

Page 11: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

function well, the incentive structure must be evenly matched. If the risks and rewards are imbalanced, the markets will be distorted by greed without the fear of the risks of failure. Underpaid bureaucracies do not have the incentive to enforce laws that protect property rights. Underpaid bankers engender NPLs. Egalitarian pay policies do not encourage innovation and competition, resulting in talent leaving for foreign companies. Addressing the incentive structure is one of the most challenging of tasks in the Asian reform process.

The third “I” is the Investor. The investor benefits most from globalization because of global choice. Currently, retail investors in Asia are not well educated. They have not been discriminating and have not exercised more discipline on the corporate governance of the issuers. Ignorant and uneducated investors can easily be cheated or be persuaded to invest in risky or bad assets by poor quality intermediaries or bad issuers. Investor education is clearly very high priority for promoting investor protection.

The fourth “I” is intermediaries. The trend in international finance is that the wholesale and retail business will be more and more dominated by 10-20 large complex financial service providers, covering the whole range of insurance, banking, fund management and risk management. Asian financial markets generally face the following problems –

Financial markets are too bank-dominated. Lack of strong credit culture leading to

inefficient capital allocation. Stock markets tend to be speculative and have

not been very successful in providing funding for small and medium enterprises (SMEs).

809

Page 12: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

Too few incentives to compete in a protected environment leading to an inability to properly handle risks.

As Asian financial sectors open up, competition from foreign intermediaries will result in some domestic intermediary failure or the “crystallization” of their inefficiencies through large NPLs or losses. On the positive side, qualitative changes will arise from the emergence of a greater pool of foreign trained investment bankers, fund managers, lawyers, accountants and other service providers operating more and more to international standards. The higher the quality of intermediaries, the more the financial regulators can rely on the market to exercise discipline on the market participants.

The fifth “I” is issuer. The quality of a market is determined by the quality of the companies that raise capital from the public. At the end of the day, they have to provide an appropriate risk-adjusted rate of return to investors. The first and foremost persons responsible for the quality of a company are its management and controlling shareholders. They set the standards of ethics and performance that the company is judged by.

Currently, Asian family-led companies and SOEs are having problems re-organizing their management structures to compete effectively against non-Asian competitors. US management in particular have evolved matrix management styles with the use of technology to facilitate flexible and rapid response to market needs. As Asian enterprises compete globally, they will be able to have global reach and also tap global capital. But to do so, they have to learn to play by global rules of conduct, including standards of transparency and corporate governance.

810

Page 13: Chapter 87 - 90

Asian Financial Reform and Corporate Governance - Duality of Development

In practice, the benefits of opening up more to globalization would be limited in Asia if there is continuing local protectionism, fiscal favouritism, and barriers to entry, complex ownership structures and insufficient disincentives against the expropriation of minority shareholders. Unless there is a change in mindset, the potential for Asian economies to benefit fully from global standards and processes would be constrained.

The sixth “I” is infrastructure. The financial infrastructure comprises the platform and processes to ensure that markets function in an orderly and robust manner. It must also have a legal framework and efficient and fair judiciary that protects property rights of market participants. Asian financial infrastructure currently reflects the protective nature of the dual economy. This results in fragmented systems, without critical mass in technology and which are still subject to large operational inefficiencies and risks.

The quality of the infrastructure determines the size of the operational risks. It can also determine the quality and efficiency of financial services, since important checks and balances are normally built into a world-class trading, payment and settlement systems. September 11 has shown so dramatically the importance of good back-up systems and contingency planning.

Last but not least, the quality of markets must depend on the quality of I, the regulator, and the regulatory framework. Because of the need to protect domestic intermediaries, Asian regulators have been accused of “over-regulating and under-

811

Page 14: Chapter 87 - 90

enforcing1”. Dealing with very inefficient domestic intermediaries in the face of rapid external competition, with major pressures to bring domestic regulatory standards to global levels, is extremely demanding.

IV. Where do we go from here?

It is necessary to consider the question of financial reform and corporate governance in Asia in the context of the New Economy. Part of this process entails an analysis of how technology is changing markets and society, and how the financial sector in Asia needs to adapt to protect investor rights through more efficient financial markets and better corporate governance.

What is the New Economy2 all about?

Financial markets can be likened to networks. The global network is a patchwork of local networks that have not been designed to operate on global capital flows. The combination of technology and entrepreneurship has re-written the old order, eroding old franchises and elites and creating new structures where the rules are as yet unclear.

Technology is changing markets and society so fast that no one can claim any defining insights into the future. The overall effect of

1 “Corporate Governance Development in The Greater China: A Taiwan Perspective”, by Lawrence Liu, November 2-3, International Conference at Hong Kong University Law School. PRNews Asia at http://prnewsasia.com/china2 J Bradford Delong and Lawrence H Summers, “The New Economy: Background, Historical Perspective, Questions, and Speculations,” Federal Reserve Bank, Kansas City, 2001 Jackson Hole Conference material.

812

Page 15: Chapter 87 - 90

technological advance on investor rights is also unclear.

Information, and hence knowledge, is a fundamental market requirement. Information is costly to produce, but through technology, it can be replicated and disseminated at very low marginal costs. New entrepreneurial and market institutions are using technology to flatten structures to replace old hierarchical structures. This is achieved through empowerment of the consumer, worker, investor or manager and the institution of global standards.

The social costs of downsizing obsolete and

inefficient “Old Economy” institutions and labour force will be large. Policy makers will have to manage this in a socially stable manner, without provoking excessive protectionist measures and not killing innovation and ability to compete in the New Economy.

Network economies of scope and size3 means that those first to achieve global name recognition [branding] obtain “winner takes all” dominance. Liquidity begets liquidity, marginalizing the smaller players. There will therefore be greater pressure for protectionism.

There will be shorter industry life cycles.

Technology changes so fast that a monopoly in an industry can be shortlived, particularly as the industry becomes obsolete when rival technology emerges. Enterprises will therefore have to reorganize their own management

3 Hal R Varian, “High-Technology Industries and Market Structure”, 2001, Jackson Hole Conference op cit.

813

Page 16: Chapter 87 - 90

structures to meet challenges for global competition.

These trends and issues should lead to profound

changes in how policymakers should act to provide for property rights, institutional frameworks and the rules of the game that underpin a market economy. Globalization of capital markets is already a reality, but laws and regulatory frameworks are still national in scope and mindset. The design of national incentive structures and risk management will have to fit the New Economy model.

Since change is so rapid and complex, social or

system stability will therefore depend upon the ethics or knowledge foundations of the individual. In other words, investor, consumer or mass education will ultimately be the key to market or social stability and sustainability.

In particular, technological advancement can make more information available, and faster, and in greater quantity, and to more people. Much depends on the quality of information and the ability of investors to digest this information4.

Issuers and intermediaries may have incentives to distort the quality of information in order to raise stock prices. Intermediaries in turn may rely on companies for information. Some of them may also have incentives to suppress or distort information for their own interests.

4 Gene D’Avolio, Efi Gildor, and Andrei Shleifer, “Technology, Information Production and Market Efficiency”, , in particular, page 132, 2001, Jackson Hole Conference, op cit.

814

Page 17: Chapter 87 - 90

The marginal investor being less experienced and less sophisticated, will be less able to derive fundamental security values from raw information.

Inevitably, the New Economy forces a major re-think of policies to grapple with issues of corporate governance and competitiveness within Asia -

How laws and regulations can properly prevent corporate insiders – whether managers or owners – from expropriating minority investors and from distorting information. Thus, the regulatory and institutional structure – essentially the incentive structure – must be designed in such a way that trust is rewarded and fraudulent acts are punished.

The role of education at all levels for investors, managers, intermediaries, regulators and policy makers to enable them to function and compete in the New Economy.

For the regulatory framework to be trusted, there must be a level playing field, and that the rules of game are by and large global rules according to global standards of conduct. Of course, not all standards are as yet global by consensus or by legislation. As Nobel Laureate Joe Stiglitz pointed out, the greatest value added comes from re-engineering global information and standards for local use. Those who succeed will benefit. Those who refuse to do so are likely to be competed out of business.

Addressing obsolete policies and institutional structures, where vested interests resist new entrepreneurial and market institutions and opening up to competition, or which are

815

Page 18: Chapter 87 - 90

involved in the capture of the decision-making process.

Revisiting the historical dual-track mercantilist model of Asian development. This is no longer sustainable in the New Economy. Economies and entrepreneurs not geared to join the New Economy are less and less able to access either private or official capital without large spreads or additional conditionality.

In short, the current Asian models of corporate governance and financial sector strategy have to change.

Andrew Sheng28 June 2002

816

Page 19: Chapter 87 - 90

THE FUTURE OF CAPITAL MARKETDEVELOPMENT IN EAST AND SOUTH EAST ASIA

10th SEC Thailand Anniversary Seminar:“How Can NBFIs Play a Greater Role in a Bank-based Economy”Bangkok, Thailand6 September 2002

First of all, allow me to say my warm congratulations and thanks to Dr Prasarn and all members and staff of the Thai SEC on the occasion of their 10th

anniversary. There is an old Asian saying that it takes ten years to grow a tree, but a hundred to grow man. Of course, in today’s language we do not use the word man, we use the word “person” as man or woman. And secondly I think obviously by man we mean institution. Ten years actually is very young in the life of an institution but ten years is a very important landmark.

On behalf of the Hong Kong Securities and Futures Commission, I would like to say how much we have admired the growth and maturity of the Thai SEC under the able leadership of Secretary-General Prasarn. His standing and the Thai SEC’s standing in IOSCO is exemplified by their Chair of the IOSCO Emerging Markets Committee, even though for a short time.

The depth of the ability, professionalism and tact of the Thai SEC was very well-demonstrated at the May 2002 IOSCO Annual Meeting in Istanbul when Dr

817

88

Page 20: Chapter 87 - 90

The Future of Capital Market Developmentin East and South East Asia

Prasarn unfortunately could not be present at the final Plenary Session. I could still remember how Ms Tipsuda very ably stood in front of this huge audience and delivered the message wonderfully and clearly on behalf of Dr Prasarn, showing how much has the work of the Emerging Markets Committee been carried forward under the leadership of the Thai SEC.

I would also like to thank my good friend Michael Pomerleano and World Bank for co-sponsoring this excellent conference. This is the 10th Anniversary not only of the Thai SEC but ten years since I have known Mike, and in fact nearly 10 years since I left the World Bank. I think it is a good occasion to celebrate both the Thai SEC’s perspective of capital markets as well as the World Bank’s.

I am also really grateful for Dr Prasarn’s invitation for me to be here to be amongst old friends like Chairman Herwidayatmo (Indonesia Bapenas), Lilia Bautista (Philippines SEC), Alan Cameron and also the highly-respected Khun Chavalit, former Governor of Bank of Thailand, who was my model central banker in the 1980s, when I was then a young central banker.

The theme of this Conference is very important because it talks essentially about a bank-based system. What I really want to do this morning is to give an overview of where capital markets in Asia are today. But I want to make this important caveat. You should never listen to securities regulators talk about the future. Securities regulators always understand you can never talk about the market because everything they say is market sensitive. The views that I express here are totally personal with no connection whatever to any organisation that I am

818

Page 21: Chapter 87 - 90

The Future of Capital Market Developmentin East and South East Asia

associated with. I want to express my views as an institutional economist, rather than as a securities regulator.

Asian Capital Markets Today

Where are our capital markets today? Specifically, how has Asian growth strategy shaped our financial systems? How have our financial markets performed their four key functions of resource allocation, price discovery, risk management and corporate governance? How has the global environment changed our Asian financial markets? And finally the important question: What conditions are required for regional integration?

You cannot look at the future without looking at the past and the present. The really interesting feature is that, given the fact that Asia accounts for more than half of mankind, more than one quarter of global exports, one third of global GDP, how is it that we only account for 16% of global equity market capitalisation? In fact, if we exclude Japan, the whole of Asia is only 7% of global market capitalisation. This is amazing.

If we really look at the MSCI weighting of market capitalisation (Table 1), calculated on a free float basis, the share of Asia in the MSCI weighting is in fact only 13% not 16%. Our share in global market capitalisation is shrinking, compared with US MSCI share of 55%, EU 17% and others 14%.

Asia has one of the highest savings rates in the world. We have a current account surplus and more than US$1 trillion in foreign exchange reserves. Yet we are the biggest importer of capital, including foreign direct investments (FDI) in the world. According to

819

Page 22: Chapter 87 - 90

The Future of Capital Market Developmentin East and South East Asia

BIS statistics, we account for one quarter of daily global FX trading. Given our economic strengths, we are still dependent upon Europe and America as engines of growth. There are no strong signs that we have been able to develop our internal growth engines.

Table 2 demonstrates that the Asian financial system is still bank-dominated. Every banking system in Asia amounted to more than 100% of GDP in asset size, including India. With the exception of Hong Kong and Singapore markets, which are basically financial centres, the rest of Asia has equity markets that are significantly smaller and bond markets that are relatively small with the exception of Japan.

820

Table

Page 23: Chapter 87 - 90

The Future of Capital Market Developmentin East and South East Asia

What has shaped East Asia’s financial structure? Finance is a derivative of the real sector. Financial strategy is a subset of overall economic strategy, and Asian economic strategy, if you have read the 1993 World Bank book on the Asian Miracle1, was essentially a mercantilist growth strategy. Essentially the strategy adopted up to the 1980s shows growth pursued through pushing exports. This was financed by a mild financial repression of the financial sector in order to mobilise resources to support the selective export manufacturing drive, and protecting the domestic natural resources, services and financial sectors.

In doing so, and because of this financial repression, the banking system was protected in order to mobilise the bulk of savings, with certain guided lending to priority sectors at subsidised or lower than market interest rates. Of course, since the 1950s and 1960s, this old model has been changing, and changing very fast. But by and large the strategy and 1 World Bank (1993), The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. (New York: Oxford University Press)

821

Table 2:

Page 24: Chapter 87 - 90

The Future of Capital Market Developmentin East and South East Asia

the mindset have not changed. In Asia, we have what I call a “fish-trap” mentality in fund flows. We love money coming in but we don’t like money going out. This is quite natural. We like to buy and we never like to sell. But this means that if there is too much money flowing into a domestic economy without compensating outflows, you end up with an asset bubble.

For example, if we really look at our stock markets, it is very short-term speculative and we almost have no foreign listings in our domestic market. Asian stock markets are essentially national stock markets. Even in Tokyo today, the largest of the Asian equity markets, there are much less foreign listings than at the height ten years ago. Moreover, because the corporate sector is state-or family-dominated, corporate governance behaviour basically reflected that ownership structure.

I always like to go back to basics and ask – what is a capital market for? Allow me to compare Asian capital markets against the four major functions of financial markets – Resource Allocation, Price Discovery, Risk Management and Corporate Governance. The first is to make sure that the savings are channelled efficiently to the users of savings, i.e. the borrowers and direct investors. As we can see, we have too much savings locked in the banking system. Because too much funds are locked up in the banking system, as the Asian crisis has shown, the result was a lack of credit culture, too much collateral-based lending, and too much excess liquidity that, coupled with a “fish-trap” mentality, created the classic asset bubble. Many of us are currently still paying the price of that asset bubble.

822

Page 25: Chapter 87 - 90

The Future of Capital Market Developmentin East and South East Asia

What do non-performing loans (NPLs) represent? The Asian crisis cost the crisis economies as much as 50% of GDP in rescuing the problem banks. This means that scarce domestic savings have been unfortunately wasted in inefficient investment. Post-Asian crisis, everybody agrees that we must develop deep and liquid bond markets, deepen equity markets, create derivative markets, diversify risks from the banking system, and impose greater market discipline on the intermediation of savings.

Why hasn’t this happened faster than we all would like to see? Part of the answer lies in the problem of price discovery. Because of capital controls and supply distortions, domestic fund prices get somewhat distorted from efficient market clearing. The interesting point is that this “fish-trap” mindset does not result in inflation because Asian economies are very open to trade. Asia is very efficient at the trade in consumer goods side that give rise to stable consumer prices at global prices. But the lending guidelines to priority sectors, listing guidelines and exchange controls of one form or other, meant that interest rates have been much lower relative to the credit risks and even the stock market PE ratios have tended to be speculative and high rather than reflective of the underlying overall earnings trend.

If the Asian crisis showed that we had up to 50% non-performing loans in some economies, how come the interest spreads – loan rate minus deposit rate minus the administrative costs – do not reflect that credit risk? And after the bank restructuring, why do they still not reflect the credit risk? This is a very important question we need to answer.

823

Page 26: Chapter 87 - 90

The Future of Capital Market Developmentin East and South East Asia

The listed corporate earnings yield is equal to 1/PE ratio. If the earnings yield is excessively low relative to a risk-free asset like a government bond, something is wrong. There is a price distortion somewhere. Why is there no risk premium or equity premium over and above a risk-free government bond? This distortion is partly due to the restricted free float of shares as major shareholders (state or families) liked to have high leverage and therefore control the shares tightly in order to prevent takeovers by other parties, including foreigners or competitors. Add to this bank herding into property with cheap loans fuelled the property asset bubble.

Secondly, as you are aware, the bond spreads in Asia before the crisis never reflected the bond credit risks. During the Asian crisis there was an overshoot of bond spreads when bond spreads rose as high as 800 basis points over equivalent US Treasuries. But today the bond spreads are even lower than pre-crisis even though we know there remain many structural and risk issues in Asia. For example, PE ratios remained around 80 in Japan, as the Nikkei 225 plunged from a peak 38,000 to around 10,000 today. China PE ratios peaked around 60, declining to 30+ today. The point that I really want to make is that such price levels are due to the quantitative distortions. Such mispricing means that if we are not careful the large domestic savings could be wasted in channelling towards inefficient investments.

The third point is all about risk management. Ten years ago I wrote a paper with Prof Yoon Je Cho at the World Bank comparing Ghana’s growth with Malaysia’s growth2. The paper pointed out that in the

2 Andrew Sheng and Yoon Je Cho (1993), Risk Management and Stable Financial Structure, World Bank Financial Policy and Systems

824

Page 27: Chapter 87 - 90

globalised economy today, developing economies, including large economies, need to have national balance sheets and an overall national risk management strategy. You cannot have the left hand taking risks that the right hand does not know about. Given global volatility in terms of trade or financial shocks, you have to have a strategy to manage national risks. It goes back to the old development economies debate in the 1960s of balanced growth versus unbalanced growth3. If you adopt a mercantilist approach, you are going for unbalanced growth. You are taking calculated risks in pushing growth in one direction. If you are not careful and you don’t manage these risks well, you pay for it. Bank-dominated systems with high NPLs and low capital base carried high moral hazard risks because of implicit and explicit deposit insurance.

If we realise that we need to develop all these derivative markets to spread the risks, why did we not spread these risks? The answer is, if you have a “fish-trap” mindset, it runs counter to the Modigliani-Miller Theorem that tells you to diversify your risks into an asset that is negatively correlated with your domestic assets. These are clearly foreign exchange assets.

If you put all your eggs into a domestic basket, if anything happens to the domestic economy, your people suffer from it. In the 1960s and 1970s, Malaysia diversified its assets into foreign assets, and diversified its production from just natural resources to manufacturing, petroleum, palm oil etc. Malaysia diversified and was therefore much better able to cushion global trade shocks than Ghana. You will

Working Paper WPS1109, March.3 See Gerald M Meier, “Leading Issues in Development Economics,” Oxford University Press, 1964, - “Growth-Balanced or Unbalanced?” pp250-266

825

Page 28: Chapter 87 - 90

remember that in the 1960s, Ghana with gold and cocoa was one of the richest economies in Africa. Malaysia at that time was totally dependent on rubber and tin exports. Both economies were subject to highly concentrated terms of trade shocks.

A risk diversification strategy would allow an economy to cushion global trade and financial shocks. The world is still suffering from such shocks today. Shocks from one part of the world are being transmitted to another part of the world through trade and financial links.

Consequently, we should have a national risk management strategy, not just at a sectoral level but at the national level, and of course larger net foreign exchange reserves. Allowing domestic residents to invest abroad spreads the risks. This comes back to Professor Mukul Asher’s point about insurance funds or pension funds also being allowed to invest abroad in order to spread their risks. This is because if you crowd all your pension investments in your domestic economy and if your domestic economy is yielding only 0.5% to 2% per annum, when real growth in a foreign currency asset is earning 4-5% per annum, then actually you are taxing your pension-holders by the opportunity cost of higher yields and lower risks in holding high quality foreign assets. As the Cho-Sheng paper indicated, diversified economies grow faster and more stably than highly concentrated economies. If you have a domestic financial crisis then the pension fund (by implication, retiring investor or next generation) also suffers together with everybody else.

So having a choice of financial instruments and markets and the participation of different types of specialist market intermediaries are extremely

826

Page 29: Chapter 87 - 90

important in the national strategy to improve asset allocation and in hedging market risks.

The fourth issue is all about corporate governance. We all know that financial markets, because they transmit information to investors, should allow investors to price the quality of corporate governance as well as the quality of assets in the company. Financial markets should reinforce corporate governance. If a company is doing badly, its share prices fall indicating investors are not satisfied with corporate performance. Why is it that Asian capital markets do not appear to reinforce corporate governance?

It is clear that post-Asian crisis we need to improve accounting, we need to begin to privatise SOEs, and we need to disentangle corporate-bank relationship which has traditionally marginalised minority shareholder interests. Moreover, domestic pension funds and Asian institutional investors have close links with corporations, while entry barriers to foreign strategic investments protected companies from takeovers/restructuring. Furthermore, Asians prefer the strategy of merger of failing institutions rather than liquidation or opening up to foreign participation. These factors limited the ability of investors to impose corporate discipline. All these mean that Asian corporate governance is not as strong as it should be.

What is corporate governance? Corporate governance is actually three key disciplines – self-discipline, regulatory discipline and market discipline.

Asia has traditionally focused very largely on self-discipline and regulatory discipline. But if you protect against competition by various ways and

827

Page 30: Chapter 87 - 90

means, you don’t allow the market discipline to ensure that the prices reflect the risks and that the resource allocation is efficient. So it is extremely important that you allow all three disciplines to work. Each country must tailor their own corporate governance framework because corporate governance cannot be divorced from the domestic cultural, historical, legal and institutional background. But you have to understand that the existence of self-discipline, regulatory discipline and market discipline is universal. It is a question of what combination of discipline is used to improve corporate governance.

So what does globalisation now mean for the Asian economy in this post-mercantilist environment? What does globalisation truly mean? Globalisation really means that domestic financial markets which are networks are being linked with every other national network to form a global financial network. The Asian crisis demonstrated very clearly that the global network is only as safe, as risky, as the weakest link in that network, which sometimes happens to be a domestic network. When one part of that network blows a fuse, the whole network malfunctions.

What we are now seeing globally is that the network effects are growing. Liquidity begets liquidity because liquidity will move from smaller markets to bigger markets as bigger markets offer deep liquidity, higher efficiency, greater economies of scale, lower transactions cost and perhaps better rules that protect the minority shareholders. So if we are not careful, there is a real danger that globalisation is being imposed on us whether we like it or not. First, it is being imposed by technology because telecommunications are getting better. Secondly, under WTO and IMF rules, there is continual peer

828

Page 31: Chapter 87 - 90

pressure on financial opening and adherence to global standards. So it’s only a matter of time that a domestic economy must begin to open up to foreign trade and finance. Globalisation marks domestic prices to global prices. If domestic prices are higher than world prices, this shows up in the national balance sheet as a “loss”. This loss is an economic loss, not always recognised in accounting terms.

At the corporate level, these networks are linking together. What is a bancassurance company? It is the banking network linking with the insurance network and the asset management fund network to form a very large supermarket network for financial services. Globalisation means that consolidation is happening in the financial sector, mergers are happening, and liquidity is being improved4.

At the exchange level, exactly as Alan Cameron, Jeffrey Carmichael and Michael Pomerleano had discussed in an earlier session in this Conference, there have been vertical and horizontal consolidations in order to extract greater efficiency, better safety, better infrastructure and greater competitiveness. Accenture has estimated that if they are able to integrate the EU securities market, back-office savings alone is US$1 billion annually. Back-office cost by the rule of thumb is sometimes four times the front-end trading cost for securities trading. Consequently, there are huge efficiency gains for exchanges to merge or consolidate.

If this is happening in Europe, as it has already begun to happen in America, what is happening in Asia? Essentially, we are now working in a global three

4 Andrew Sheng (2001), Securing the Third Zone of the Global Markets. Speech at the ASAF 2001 Conference (Hong Kong, 3 December)

829

Page 32: Chapter 87 - 90

time zone market. New York accounts for 50% of global market trading, with US$12.8 trillion market capitalisation. Some Latin American shares are migrating to New York for trading, where liquidity is greater than in their home markets. I am told some Australian shares have also begun to migrate to New York. In Europe, they are consolidating because of the EU and Euro, and some South African shares have begun to migrate to London for better liquidity.

Asia has tremendous savings but totally fragmented financial markets. Our capital markets are very retail driven. Our institutional markets are highly concentrated and generally conservative, requiring the institutional funds to invest mainly in domestic government bonds and some domestic equity. Under this policy, you essentially lock away large amount of funds with very little trading. It is clear that the network effects of “liquidity begets liquidity” do benefit the issuer, the investor and intermediaries. However, our liquidity is flowing to the major markets and coming back as FDI and as foreign portfolio investment. Aren’t we back to the old 1950s colonial debate which argued how all the colonial monies used to go to the imperial centre and came back in the form of colonial investments? If you look at this as a financial historian, you wonder how much has changed in the flow of global funds.

One point that most people tend to forget is that the Asian miracle is demographically driven. I am extremely grateful to Jeffrey Williamson, for his paper on Demographic Shocks and Global Factor Flows5, to point this out to me. In fact the biggest lesson to me from what is happening in Asian markets today,

5 Jeffrey Williamson (2001), Demographic Shocks and Global Factor Flows, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Series, No. 46 (Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, June)

830

Page 33: Chapter 87 - 90

including the Japanese economy, is that if we do not pay attention to this demographic factor, we are going to have a lot of financial problems on our hands.

In the early period, Asia has grown faster because we have a young working population (Figure 1), with high savings, high productivity and very export competitive. Our leaders had great foresight to open up to international trade. We entered in the post-crisis period into an era of peace, of lowering tariffs, of greater competition, and we benefited from it. But what has happened to all our savings? The Asian crisis has shown that some of us have had to use half of our savings to bail out inefficient enterprises. What people have not noticed is that if we are not careful, if we stuffed all our retirement funds with inefficient bonds and equity, bought at historically high prices, our future generation will pay for the deficits in the pension funds that have insufficient assets to meet the growing social burden as the population ages.

831

Figure 1:

Page 34: Chapter 87 - 90

In fact, the point that Professor Mukul made yesterday which I thought was very good is that if the return to capital on the retirement fund is below the global benchmark average, that lower return is a tax on retirees. In the long run they will not benefit from the opportunity cost in investing in diversified global assets with global yields. So essentially as Asia begins to age, and in North Asia the population is aging very fast already, we require more and more retirement funds. But having these retirement funds without a deep bond market, derivatives market, good equity market to absorb those savings, you may be digging yourself deeper and deeper into trouble in future generations.

In essence, if we keep on pumping our scarce resources into the existing systems which do not appear to be able to absorb these savings efficiently, you are going to miss a great window of opportunity when you have that growth period. This situation is like a young person when we are growing up. We are very happy to spend on whatever we like. But when we begin to reach middle age, you really begin to think whether you have enough savings for your retirement. If you have spent all that savings and invested wrongly, then you have to save even more when you are beginning to retire, which is now increasingly the case in North Asia. As North Asia begins to age, its economic growth is slowing and it will require more retirement funding. South-east Asia is still young, but must avoid North Asian retirement funding mistakes. There is an urgent need to develop deep and well-diversified retirement institutional funds in Asia. It is extremely important that we avoid the mistake of some policy makers who use pension funds to avoid historical

832

Page 35: Chapter 87 - 90

policy errors, by postponing the cost to the future. This is exactly what I mean by the importance of market discipline in the financial sector.

What is the relationship between the Asian Third Time Zone and the OECD? The Third World and the OECD are in two demographic cycles. The older OECD countries are aging much faster than the Third World. The Third World has labour surplus and capital shortage, the OECD has scarce labour and capital surplus. But Asia in fact has both labour surplus and capital excess because it is still running current account surpluses. Essentially we are funding the OECD capital markets which rechannel these funds back to Asia.

This brings me to the next question: How can Asia institutionalise our savings within Asia for better resource allocation?

What then are the lessons from the above analysis? Historical problems and barriers have hindered our ability to intermediate our own savings more efficiently. The North Asian markets are large, but relatively domestic oriented. There has been too much volatility in prices, and markets are still inward looking. The South-east Asian markets are relatively small. We have the Australia and New Zealand markets that have very sophisticated systems but they are not well integrated with the rest of Asia. If we have no integration, how do we compete with the large markets that are integrating very fast?

What therefore are the conditions for regional integration or cooperation? In my personal view, these are clearly the following. First of all, bank reforms must go on, as NPLs remain a drag on the domestic economy and really must be cleaned up.

833

Page 36: Chapter 87 - 90

But bank reforms cannot succeed unless corporate governance standards are raised to improve corporate efficiency. So we must have a higher standard of transparency and disclosure with a move to international accounting standards, international auditing standards and shortly international disclosure standards.

There are the 5 ‘Ps’ in the financial sector I think we really need to think about. First, we really need to develop people skills. We still have not moved fast enough in this area. We need investment banking skills, assets management skills and risk management skills. You cannot build these skills domestically overnight. With global competition, one may have to hire such skills from the global market. It is exactly like football. If you can’t compete, you hire somebody with the necessary skills, like Korea hired a Dutch coach. Why? Because you cannot get that skill overnight to be able to compete in the World Cup. The same is true in respect of capacity building to strengthen corporate governance and make investors more discerning and demanding.

Second, the pricing of the spreads has to reflect the risk. Third, we have to develop the right products for better risk management. Fourth, we have to develop common platforms. Our technology is so disintegrated as everybody is trying to protect their own domestic markets, and the result is that they cannot connect except at a very high cost. This is what Europe is currently experiencing. This is why Europe is moving towards integration at the platform level. And fifthly and finally, it is political will. Do you want to have cooperation or not? If you don’t want it, there is very little any one of us can do to make it happen.

834

Page 37: Chapter 87 - 90

In my personal view, improving market liquidity is clearly a priority. The segmented market fragments liquidity and the negative feedback effects of declining liquidity are bad for capital markets. To improve liquidity, we need to develop common products, common rules and common markets. This is very clear from what Chairman Dato’ Ali Kadir from the Malaysian Securities Commission said yesterday at this Conference. The questions I want to ask concern, “Can we afford marginalisation? Are we ready to adopt international accounting standards and codes? We do have competitive threats, but do we have common goals?” I don’t have the answers. I am just posing the questions.

If we want to be part of the global market, one has to play by global rules and standards. This is the biggest lesson from Africa and Latin America. If you follow the wrong theory that you should be inward-looking and import-substituting, history has shown that this is the wrong strategy. Asia did the right strategy but did not move to a full global strategy. It went totally global in export and manufacturing but did not go global in the protected dualist sectors, such as services. Actually what the Asian crisis is all about is that we have marked all these dualistic sectors to market. In very crude terms, when we marked to market the losses and inefficiencies, they emerged as NPLs in the national balance sheet.

If we are to have successful integration, we need equivalent standards. Currently, the US and EU are setting these standards and Asia is at the moment a free rider on these standards. We are lucky that they are doing all the hard work in developing these standards. But we have no say in shaping these standards because even though we are big in population, big in production, we are very small in

835

Page 38: Chapter 87 - 90

capital markets so our ability to influence these standards is very limited. Isn’t that sad? Global markets must have global representation. That is what markets are all about. If you have market power, you have a greater say in those standards. And if you don’t, you don’t have a say.

What we clearly need is common Asian standards. I’m not saying that Asian standards must be unique to Asia. I’m saying that these standards need to be inter-operable with European and American standards because that is where the current global standards are. And because we currently have no common voice to influence these standards, we need to build critical mass to get that communication and influence through.

I must confess that at the moment in Asia I do not see a common platform where this voice can be developed. My personal view, and I want to stress that this is only in the financial area, ASEAN + 3 is not representative of the Asian financial markets as long as the major players like Australia and Hong Kong are not part of this round table for discussion of Asian common financial interests.

In practical terms, everybody understands that domestic considerations out-weigh regional interests. At the moment, it is not surprising that regional cooperation has been a low priority because everybody is busy focusing on their domestic issues and domestic reforms.

But if we do not standardise, at least we should talk. We should not talk in political terms but we should talk at the level of technical terms. We need to standardise for liquidity and differentiate for value added. What do I mean? There is a very important

836

Page 39: Chapter 87 - 90

article which was written by a British think tank on why products migrate globally and why some products stay domestically. The answer is information intensity. Low intensity financial products such as bonds and foreign currency are very easily traded in other markets. High intensity products like equity generally do not tend to migrate.

For example, Hong Kong has got more than 30 – 40 shares that are traded both in New York and Hong Kong. And New York is obviously a deeper and larger market. However, the liquidity of these shares traded in Hong Kong is actually three to four times higher than in New York, because Hong Kong people and international traders understand that liquidity and knowledge in these shares is concentrated in Hong Kong. New York is superior in information intensity in US shares. On the other hand, Asian bonds and currencies, which are relatively straightforward products with the information intensity, are traded significantly in London, New York and elsewhere. So clearly we need to standardise for liquidity but differentiate for value added.

Can we have a phased approach to regional integration? Gordon de Brouwer6 from the Australian National University has written a very good paper, providing an excellent overview of issues on regional integration. I am grateful for his comments on this paper. He basically suggested that some of the slightly more developed markets like Australia, Hong Kong, Japan and Singapore work at free trade in services in the financial area first and then talk about integration with others. My personal opinion is that I’m not sure if this phased approach will work in practice. If we have a phased approach, we can

6 Gordon de Brouwer (2002), Financial Markets, Institutions and Integration in East Asia, Mimeo, Australian National University, May.

837

Page 40: Chapter 87 - 90

cause greater market differences and tensions. I think my point today is very simple. We need a common forum for technical discussions first. Work out the technical issues before you think about the political issues.

As I said, the previous proposals such as the Asian BIS and the Asian Monetary Fund were too politically charged. With such different regional perspectives, you cannot get agreement. What I am proposing here, tentatively, is that we should establish an Asian Financial Institute. There will be no physical headquarters. There are chapters in every market who are interested, so that we don’t have to fight over where to establish the headquarters. We are all friends. We are all masters of our own destiny. We can sit down and talk technically what are the issues, whether we agree or not, the debate on issues, standards, goals and processes. This is the lesson from Europe in the 1950s and 1960s where they began this kind of common platforms for common discussion, before they even think about working together technically. Europe’s experience is that cooperation is not possible unless there are not only common goals, but also common channels of discussion at the operational level.

So what are the conditions for increasing the liquidity? Clearly we should work on common products, we should work on inter-operability, we should lower transaction costs, we should work on inter-connectivity. I don’t have the solutions. I am just posing these questions so that we can put them forward for better debate. Clearly any talk about Asian financial cooperation and even integration is, I believe, a long journey. But it is clear to me that the right approach is clearly a “win-win” situation and not a “win-lose” situation.

838

Page 41: Chapter 87 - 90

What we need is actually an independent and non-profit making research institute that studies these areas from an Asian perspective. The conduct of research on issues with strategic significance for Asia would deepen our understanding of the implications of global developments and provide a basis for an objective debate on win-win solutions for us all. And we can attract the best and brightest from around the world to work on this. Knowledge is no longer domestically exclusive and the whole idea of discussions of the Asian Financial Institute is to strengthen our capacity building.

To conclude, basic to what I am saying today is that the Asian growth model which was based on a dualist model of development must be re-written in order to have a globally efficient and regionally “fitting” model, where markets perform their functions much more efficiently, and the inherent risks from imbalanced growth need to be addressed. When we were younger economies, we could afford large bets and more risks. As we mature, we need to move towards more balanced growth and better national risk management. So one priority is to improve corporate governance, where trust is rewarded, and fraudulent behaviour is punished.

The quality of all our markets and players must be enhanced to improve the quality of our markets. In my personal opinion, non-integration is not an option, but we have to play by global rules and standards. We should cooperate to set our own standards, have a say in these global standards, and work together to improve the liquidity of our markets. Either we do this or we continue with our individual agenda and see continued marginalisation of our individual markets. To me that would not be the optimal future

839

Page 42: Chapter 87 - 90

for Asia. Personally, I do believe that the future of Asian financial markets is very very bright indeed.

Thank you very much.

840

Page 43: Chapter 87 - 90

POST-ENRON IMPACT ON REGULATION OF FINANCIAL MARKETS

Vocational Training Council 20th Anniversary Distinguished Lecture Series“Post-Enron impact on regulation of financial markets”23 September 2002

Professor Lee Ngok,Professor David Lim,Distinguished Guests,Ladies and Gentlemen,

I am extremely honoured to be invited to deliver the third of the Vocational Training Council’s 20th

Anniversary Distinguished Lecture Series. Following a distinguished scientist and new Chancellor of HKU, as well as the Chief Executive Officer of the Hong Kong Science and Technology Parks, is no easy feat.

I want to start this lecture with the usual caveat as a securities regulator. The views expressed in this lecture are totally personal. I have consulted some of my colleagues in the preparation of this lecture, but I want to stress that these views are not necessarily those of the Commission7, including non-executive directors. I want to put these views out for airing, since I believe that we have reached an important crossroad in our objective of promoting investor protection in Hong Kong.

7 I am grateful to Ashley Alder and other colleagues in the Commission for valuable comments and to Rosetta Chiu for secretarial assistance. All opinions, errors and omissions are those of the author.

841

89

Page 44: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

As you are all aware, post-Enron and WorldCom, corporate failure and the failure of corporate governance has become a household topic. In the last year, the total market cap loss for Enron and WorldCom was US$80 billion (HK$624 billion), roughly equivalent to the drop in the whole Hong Kong market capitalization during the same period.

I propose to divide this lecture into three parts: -

An overview of what went wrong and what the major markets are doing to fix it;

The current structure of regulation of listed companies in Hong Kong; and

The role of the SFC in tackling corporate misconduct.

Post-Enron change in regulations

The importance of good corporate governance came sharply into focus after the Asian crisis, and attention to this became universal after the tech bubble of 2000, when both US and European regulators realized that the bubble may have been partly fuelled by bad accounting and corporate misconduct. In other words, after the party (or when the tide goes out), the hangovers (or rocks) begin to appear.

The stories of Enron, WorldCom and others are still unwinding. Reasons for their failure are still being debated, but it would appear to be, as one senior US regulator told me, the “perfect storm” of corporate governance failure in the United States. Corporate governance has failed because the various checks and balances within the system have been weakened by the conflicts of interest that exist at different levels. Because the United States is the largest and deepest

842

Page 45: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

of securities markets, with the most sophisticated regulatory structure, it is worth spending some time to explain the differences between the US system and the Hong Kong system (which is broadly based on the UK and Australian common law framework).

Corporate governance is steeped in each jurisdiction’s financial, legal and market history. The US securities framework stems from the 1929 Wall Street crash, which led to the 1933 and 1934 securities legislation that founded the SEC. It is premised on statutory disclosure, with companies seeking public funding being required to file statutory information with the SEC, now under the famous EDGAR8 system. This rules-based system is based on “caveat emptor”, or buyer beware, with a set of rules that specify the disclosure that issuers must make to investors and the public, and which is presumptively material.

In the US, there are in fact four important lines of defence against corporate misconduct. The first line of defence against corporate misconduct is clearly the management or Board of Directors itself, including the independent non-executive directors, who should represent the public interest. The US Senate report on the role of the Board of Directors in Enron’s Collapse9 clearly stated that there was fiduciary failure –

“The Enron Board of Directors failed to safeguard Enron shareholders and contributed to the collapse of the seventh largest public company in the United States, by allowing

8 Electronic Data Gathering, Analysis, and Retrieval system.9 Committee on Governmental Affairs, US Senate “The Role of the Board of Directors in Enron’s Collapse”, Report 107-70, 8 July 2002

843

Page 46: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

Enron to engage in high risk accounting, inappropriate conflict of interest transactions, extensive undisclosed off-the-books activities, and excessive executive compensation”.

The question whether underpaid non-executive directors can stop important corporate misconduct is still being debated in many jurisdictions.

The second line of defence lies with the corporate advisers, such as auditors, lawyers, professional valuers, sponsors, investment bankers, bankers and rating agencies who should provide independent and professional advice on corporate performance, including compliance with the relevant codes of conduct, rules and laws. As the recent cases show, when these professional advisers draw substantial fees from their clients, the question of independence of opinion has sometimes been called into question. This is where the regulatory oversight of such professionals comes in. For example, in the US and some parts of Europe, the auditing profession comes under public oversight, whereas in UK, other parts of Europe and Hong Kong, the profession is by and large still self-regulatory.

The third line of defence is the regulatory framework for listed companies. In the United States, the exchanges such as NYSE and NASDAQ assess eligibility according to their rules and quantitative criteria, but all the issuers must file statutory information with the SEC. The US has a huge range of sanctions, ranging from fines to jail sentences, on the provision of false or misleading information. Generally, willful violation of securities regulations is a criminal offence. In addition, the US exchanges closely monitor companies listed on their exchanges and frequently delist companies that do not perform.

844

Page 47: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

For example, NASDAQ delisted 770 companies last year, of which 390 were delisted for non-compliance with listing requirements, nearly 2.7 times more than the 145 companies that were newly listed. In addition, the US state and federal prosecutors’ offices can take severe action against corporate stealing, cheating or fraud.

Finally, the three lines of defence are buttressed by the class action-contingency fee system, whereby shareholders can jointly undertake direct legal action against management or majority shareholders where they feel that they have been disadvantaged. Such a powerful weapon in the hands of minority shareholders ensures that directors, controlling shareholders and their advisers are more careful to act without provoking costly class action suits.

I want to point out that such class action-contingency fee system is not available in the UK, Australian and Hong Kong legal systems, because of a different legal tradition and the view that it would encourage a litigious society.

Nevertheless, even under such powerful checks and balances the cases of Enron and WorldCom have slipped through. To be fair, the US authorities have quickly enacted the Sarbanes-Oxley Act on 30 July, 2002, which seeks to strengthen corporate governance and auditing oversight by: -

Creating an independent Public Company Accounting Oversight Board to enforce professional standards, ethics and competence for the accounting profession;

Strengthening the independence of firms that audit public companies by having the SEC prohibit the provision of consulting

845

Page 48: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

services to audit clients, when these services create conflicts of interest;

Requiring CEOs and CFOs to personally vouch for the veracity of their financial statements and providing much stiffer penalties for fraud;

Strengthening disclosure requirements for public companies, notably in the areas of off-balance sheet transactions and insider trading;

Protecting the independence and objectivity of securities analysts by directing the SEC to review rules ensuring their independence;

Directing the SEC to undertake comprehensive reviews of corporate governance, the separation of audit and non-audit work, and the role of rating agencies; and

Increasing the resources available to the SEC.

I have spent some time on the US system because market analysts who are familiar with the US system often wonder why we cannot adopt US-type legislation and rules into the Hong Kong system. This is founded on a popular misconception. As I hope to show later, each system is very different, and we need to understand how best to protect shareholder rights within our own legal and regulatory framework.

In Europe, the European Commission has issued a series of major reform directives aimed at harmonizing and strengthening the securities markets in Europe. These include the development of the Prospectus Directive, the Transparency Obligations Directive, the Investment Services

846

Page 49: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

Directive, the Market Abuse Directive and the amendment of the Admissions to Listing Directive.

The United Kingdom has also been upgrading its company law and securities regulatory framework: -

In May 2000, the function of the Competent Authority for Listing was transferred from the London Stock Exchange (which had held this role since 1984) to the Financial Services Authority (FSA). The Competent Authority for Listing is responsible for making the Listing Rules, which lay down the requirements that issuers of securities to the UK primary markets need to meet, and for policing compliance with these Rules. It is also responsible for admitting securities to the UK’s Official List;

On 16 July 2002, following the final report of the Steering Group of the Company Law Review, the UK Government issued a White Paper indicating that the companies law would be simplified and modernized for all companies; and

On 30 July 2002, the FSA issued a consultation paper on the review of the listing regime10.

In Australia, the Corporate Law Economic Reform Program Act was passed in October 1999 and came into force on 13 March 2000. Amongst the major reforms were: -

The introduction of a statutory derivative action against corporate wrongdoing,

10 Financial Services Authority, “Review of the Listing Regime”, Discussion Paper 14, July 2002

847

Page 50: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

which modified the common law action and circumstances under which shareholders can enforce their rights;

The clarification of directors’ duties of care and diligence; and

The establishment of new institutional arrangements for the Australian accounting standard setting process.

In the Mainland, the China Securities Regulatory Commission has also made impressive strides in corporate governance measures for listed companies, such as: -

Rules requiring the appointment of independent non-executive directors;

Quarterly reporting; Delisting of poorly performing companies;

and Strengthening enforcement by closer

cooperation with the police.

All these go to show that major markets, including the Mainland market, are actively reforming their corporate governance and their securities market regulatory structure.

Corporate Governance & Protection of Investor Rights in Hong Kong

Hong Kong has not been idle in pushing for reforms in corporate governance. As the Financial Secretary said in the 2001-02 Budget Speech, our primary objective is “to establish Hong Kong as a paragon of corporate governance, ensuring that those investing in Hong Kong are afforded the best protection and

848

Page 51: Chapter 87 - 90

that our listed companies are managed with excellence11”.

The major initiatives include the following: -

A major consultation paper by HKEx on changes to the Listing Rules relating to corporate governance, which covers protection of shareholders’ rights, directors and board practices, and corporate reporting and disclosure of information. The consultation was completed in May, and the results of that consultation are awaited;

A comprehensive review of corporate governance by the Standing Committee on Company Law Reform (SCCLR) began in 2000. A Consultation paper on specific proposals relating to directors’ duties, shareholders rights and corporate reporting enhancements was issued in July 2001. The SCCLR has received widespread support from the community on many subjects, which are very close to measures being adopted in the major markets. The Administration is looking at how best to take forward these recommendations;

SCCLR is now forging ahead with the second phase of the review to examine the role and functions of Audit Committees, developing financial reporting standards for different companies, and the efficiency of our present corporate reporting regime.

11 Much of the material in this section is taken from the report by the Financial Services Bureau to the Legco Panel on Financial Affairs, “Continuous Efforts to Strengthen Corporate Governance: Review of Listing Rules and Other Initiatives”, February, 2002

849

Page 52: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

This work is expected to be completed by the end of 2002;

The Securities and Futures Ordinance (SFO) was passed in March and is expected to be in force in early 2003. It will enhance the transparency of listed companies, establish a Market Misconduct Tribunal, and augment the SFC’s investigatory power, as well as providing investors with a private cause of action for false or misleading public communications;

The consultation paper on May 6, 2002 on subsidiary legislation to be made under amendments to the regulations under the SFO was issued to empower the SFC under the SFO to become the statutory regulator of listed company disclosure. This moves Hong Kong closer to the US SEC model, where the exchange (e.g. NASDAQ or NYSE) handles the listing, but the statutory regulator can enforce if listed companies disclose information that is false or misleading; and

On the international front, the SFC has co-chaired with the Italian securities regulator, CONSOB, a Task Force on Transparency and Disclosure to develop a set of International Ongoing Disclosure Standards. If these are adopted by IOSCO, we could readily apply them for Hong Kong.

While these initiatives are being pushed forward, Hong Kong has also begun to witness its fair share of corporate incidents. Recently, there has been a spate of minority shareholder activism, which called for regulators to intervene in corporate transactions. Minority shareholder activism in Hong Kong is a very

850

Page 53: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

healthy sign, and there is a very good reason why there are currently more investor complaints. Suspicious transactions are less obvious during a bull market, because all investors hope that asset prices would rise. However, during a bear market, minority investors are concerned that majority shareholders may enter into transactions that may dilute their interests or that are prejudicial to their rights.

There is a need to regulate listed companies because entities that raise funds from the public have a duty to the public to be honest and fair in their dealings. Hence, listed companies are normally regulated through entry requirements [under the Listing Rules], their conduct in transactions [under the Takeovers & Mergers Code and Listing Rules] and the enforcement of applicable legislation, such as the Companies Ordinance and the SFO.

As you can see from Figure 1, the rules covering corporate behaviour comprise both codes and rules, such as the non-statutory Listing Rules for listed companies, as well as legislation, such as the Companies Ordinance. There is, for example, a Code of Conduct governing the behaviour of corporate finance advisers. The main difference between codes and legislation is that sanctions for breach of the former do not have statutory backing, whereas the latter can include statutory sanctions, ranging from civil damages to jail sentences.

Under the current regulatory regime in Hong Kong, we have one regulator in charge of the entry requirements for listed companies [Stock Exchange], and many more with oversight over the conduct of their business [such as the Stock Exchange under Listing Rules, the SFC under the Takeovers Code, and in insider dealing and market manipulation, ICAC in

851

Page 54: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

corruption and CCB in fraud and theft]. The Financial Secretary can appoint special inspectors under Section 143 of the Companies Ordinance. The exit of companies from the Exchange depends upon the Listing Rules and also on the liquidation process.

Since corporate misconduct cuts across many areas and the jurisdiction of several regulators, the core issue is whether there should be a single lead corporate regulator or co-ordinating body that ensures a consistent, coherent and firm response to corporate misconduct in Hong Kong.

Corporate misconduct can be divided into different levels of seriousness, ranging from incompetence, and unfair transactions to outright stealing. I would like to make three relevant points: -

First, most listed companies in Hong Kong obey the law. Indeed, as the recent Standard & Poor’s review of Hong Kong Corporate Governance12 says, “compared with other Asian countries, Hong Kong is a leader in the corporate governance domain.” We do have some of the best run companies in Asia;

Second, the fundamental principle of full and fair disclosure is that the listed entity should provide all information that would be material or relevant to an investor’s investment decision as to its financial condition and future prospects. This is where enforcement against false and misleading information comes in;

Third, the regulators’ involvement in transactions of companies after they are

12 Standard & Poor’s, “Corporate Governance in Hong Kong”, 15 February, 2002, available on http://www.standardpoor.com

852

Page 55: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

listed come in two areas – a “middle ground” of transactions where the regulators are often involved in ensuring that their own rules are complied with before the transaction happens. Then there are the “after-the-transaction” enforcement actions, which require investigation and prosecution of wrongdoing. These involve our Enforcement Division, the Police and sometimes the ICAC.

I shall concentrate in this section on the “middle ground” of corporate transactions, which are largely the preserve of the Exchange and the SFC. In the next section, I shall elaborate on our enforcement functions.

Under the 1991 Memorandum of Understanding between the SFC and Stock Exchange of Hong Kong, the Stock Exchange (now part of HKEx) is the frontline regulator of listed companies. This is because the Stock Exchange administers the Listing Rules, which governs the entry of listed companies, a large part of the conduct of listed companies and their exit or delisting.

The Stock Exchange basically operated a merit-based regulatory system in vetting the entry of listed companies for the Main Board. A disclosure-based regulatory system was adopted for the Growth Enterprise Market (GEM) when it was established in 1999. After demutualization and listing of the exchange in 2000, the perception of the nature of its regulatory role began to change.

Firstly, a for-profit exchange could not be given statutory enforcement powers. Its

853

Page 56: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

relationship with other listed companies is contractual in nature.

Secondly, the market perceives, rightly or wrongly, that a for-profit exchange has a commercial incentive to encourage listings, but tackling corporate misconduct involves cost and risk, and often no commercial gain. Tough enforcement cases can lead to lawsuits that hurt corporate value.

Third, there is a widely held view that a listed company should not regulate other listed companies.

As I explained earlier in describing the US regulatory system, the first and second lines of defence against corporate misgovernance lie in the integrity and conduct of the management of the company, the Board committees, and their auditors, legal advisers, sponsors and investment bankers. The bulk of these corporate governance attributes, therefore, fall to be regulated within the purview of the Listing Rules, which carry no statutory sanctions, unlike in the US or UK where the SEC or FSA can impose civil fines. Others are regulated by self-regulatory organisations.

Thus, in the middle ground of day-to-day corporate transactions, the third line of defence depends on the role of the regulators in overseeing such transactions. This middle ground is currently covered by two sets of codes, the Listing Rules, administered by the Exchange, and the Takeovers Code, administered by the SFC. Listed companies in Hong Kong engage in thousands of commercial transactions every day. The bulk of these transactions do not involve regulators because,

854

Page 57: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

as I said, Hong Kong has overall a good corporate governance framework.

There are, however, transactions that can be disputed by shareholders, creditors and other corporate stakeholders that should fall under the purview of the courts, which is the fourth line of defence. Under our common law system, it is only the courts that are, quite properly, entrusted with deciding whether a transaction is legitimate. However, litigation is expensive in Hong Kong, and there is no class action/contingency fee system, so it is not surprising that shareholders call for the regulators to intervene in disputed transactions.

When these transactions fall under the Listing Rules or the Takeovers Code, the responsible regulator does the due diligence on compliance, which would involve considering whether the applicant or their advisers had done their work properly, whether there is full and fair disclosure, and in specific cases, requiring voting by independent shareholders. Such due diligence may include requirements for greater disclosure, requests for clarification and independent valuations.

At the controversial end of the spectrum of transactions are those that appear unfair but comply with the non-statutory rules. These should lead to rule changes, which would then go through the appropriate market consultation and due process.

The issue really boils down to whether corporate behaviour can be effectively regulated through non-statutory rules or codes, where private/public reprimands or censures are seen at best as slaps on the wrist. Codes of conduct can work where breaches can be disciplined as conditions of exit, such as the

855

Page 58: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

threat of withdrawal of licences, or where those who do not comply can effectively be excluded from the market, as in the Takeovers Code. But in the case of listed companies, delisting has so far not been used as a disciplinary tool.

The Commission has identified this gap in the enforcement of corporate disclosure, particularly with respect to the disclosure-based regulatory framework for the GEM. In order to strengthen the sanctions on disclosure, we consulted the market in May on “dual filing”, which would make the Commission the statutory regulator of listed company disclosure.

We are pleased that the results of the consultation exercise supported the suggested rule changes, and the Government has approved this move. Consequently, under the SFO subsidiary legislation, which should be effective at the beginning of next year, all information to be filed with HKEx will be required to be dual filed with the SFC too.

For example, if disclosure is materially false or misleading, the SFC can exercise its Section 182-3 SFO investigatory powers to investigate. It also has a range of enforcement options, such as: -

Suspending trading in listed securities; Applying for court orders to remedy

oppression, inadequate disclosure, unfair prejudice or crime or misconduct in a listed company;

Injunctions to restrain breaches of the SFO;

Recommending to the FS civil actions before the Market Misconduct Tribunal for disclosing false or misleading information about securities;

856

Page 59: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

Criminal prosecution for disclosing false or misleading information about securities;

Winding up applications; and Disciplinary action (including fines up to

$10 million, reprimands, revocation and suspension of licences) against a listed company's SFC licensed corporate finance advisers.

The problem is that, despite reforms like these, we currently have a middle ground that has a front-line regulator looking after entry and exit, the corporate governance structure and transactions under the Listing Rules. The SFC is directly responsible for the Takeovers Code and is also tasked to monitor and supervise that front-line regulator.

This is where the current dual or split regulator roles lack clarity and add complexity and costs to the whole process. The need to coordinate regulatory roles leads to delays in regulatory response, because no one regulator has the total picture of what the perpetrator is up to.

Indeed, as some recent cases have shown, regulatory arbitrage can occur since if one transaction fails the regulatory test under one set of regulations, such as the Takeovers Code, the company may try a modified transaction with a similar motive under the Listing Rules, much to the frustration of minority shareholders. In sum, the present Hong Kong model is very different from the “US model” of regulation and minority protection, where the US legal system enables aggrieved shareholders to sue on bad disclosure and other grounds through class action/contingency fee arrangements. There are also

857

Page 60: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

many other differences, in SEC powers and remit, institutional investor pressure, and quick delisting action by the Exchanges.

The UK is closer to Hong Kong so far as minority shareholder suits are concerned. Legal action is also costly to pursue there. But there the Listing Rules are administered by the FSA as statutory regulator and it has the ability to impose fines for breach of the rules. Stern administrative sanctions enforced by a strong independent agency covering the full range of core listed company regulation is a credible deterrent – it is quick, efficient, generates public confidence and is checked by administrative appeals and the possibility of judicial review.

It is vital in Hong Kong that this “middle ground” of regulation, currently administered by the Exchange and the Commission, is able to function at its full potential. It is the main bulwark against corporate misconduct when, in practice, legal remedies are hard to pursue. If the middle-ground regulators are weakened, there are no other compensating mechanisms and the result is that the whole area of investor protection cannot operate at its full potential.

In other words, two major policy issues need to be addressed. First, whether we should move to a statutory regime to improve corporate governance to protect shareholders’ rights; and second, whether the present “middle ground” regulatory structure and processes should be simplified so as to avoid duplication and delays in regulatory response to corporate misconduct.

These are important questions that only wide public consultation and the government and legislature can answer. All I can do is to point out that there is

858

Page 61: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

ample international experience and debate on these issues that we can draw upon.

My colleagues and I do understand that there are complexities involved in making such policy choices, nor do we underestimate the resources and expertise that are needed to undertake this task. I personally, therefore, welcome the announcement by the Financial Secretary that the Government is considering appointing an expert group to look at these complex issues.

The Role of SFC in combating corporate misconduct

Finally, allow me now to describe how the SFC is combating corporate misconduct in the enforcement area. As explained earlier, there is no single corporate regulator in Hong Kong. The Stock Exchange is the front-line regulator of listed companies, and administers the Listing Rules. It is the gatekeeper in allowing companies to be listed. The SFC shares the regulation of conduct of the listed company sector in the policing of insider dealing, statutory disclosure of interests in securities (SDIO), and inspecting the books and records of listed companies if impropriety is suspected. The SFC also administers the Code on Takeovers and Mergers. In areas such as corruption, fraud and theft, and cases outside the jurisdiction of Hong Kong, the SFC cooperates with other regulators, such as the Stock Exchange, the CCB and ICAC, as well as overseas regulators to investigate and pursue enquiries.

As a statutory regulator safeguarding the rule of law in the securities field, the SFC must also act within its powers under the law. It is important to understand that we cannot normally intervene in commercial

859

Page 62: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

transactions. This is for the Board of Directors, the legal and financial advisers, accountants, and professional valuers and in specific cases, for voting by shareholders, to determine.

Three significant factors unique to the Hong Kong market govern our approach to combating corporate misconduct: -

Nearly three quarters of the companies listed in Hong Kong are incorporated outside Hong Kong;

Many of the listed companies in Hong Kong also have operations outside Hong Kong; and

We therefore must cooperate closely with Hong Kong and overseas regulators to investigate companies listed in Hong Kong.

Some of you may wonder why we have stayed silent on a number of high profile cases. The reason is that section 59 of the SFC Ordinance imposes an obligation of secrecy on SFC personnel in conducting investigations.

There are good reasons for this. First, any announcement of investigation can lead to a sharp drop in the share price of the company being investigated, causing potential losses to the shareholders. Second, any information leakage may tip off those under investigation, leading to the destruction of evidence or abscondment. Third, such leaks may prejudice subsequent criminal trials.

The same restrictions apply under section 378 of the new SFO. Whilst we cannot comment on live cases or investigations, I can say categorically that we are

860

Page 63: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

currently investigating a number of cases that have received high media profile in recent months.

Mr. Alan Linning, our Executive Director of Enforcement, has already in his press briefing on 24 June stated that the top priority in 2002-2003 will be corporate governance investigations. A few simple statistics should suffice: -

We have already initiated 4 section 29A investigations and 3 section 33 investigations into listed companies since March this year alone;

We have 19 active cases that we are discussing with the CCB, including 7 cases that involve listed companies;

We have one of the best records in insider dealing prosecutions outside the United States. Last year, we had 3 major successes, disgorging $22.8 million in profits and $23.2 million in penalties (involving shares in Tysan Holdings, Indesen Industries and China Apollo). 4 more cases are under investigation and 8 are awaiting referral to the Insider Dealing Tribunal;

In the area of market manipulation activities, we had 4 people convicted in 3 cases last year (Good Fellow Group, Perfectech International and The Hong Kong Parkview Group). The courts are getting tougher - 2 jailed, 1 given suspended a sentence and community service, 1 fined;

In the first quarter of 2002, 4 persons were convicted in 2 cases (Grand Field Group and Gay Giano International Group), with full cooperation with the CCB. The CCB

861

Page 64: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

has charged 2 more persons in the Gay Giano case;

In the disclosure of interests prosecutions, which require increased transparency regarding insiders’ share dealings, 14 persons and 8 companies were successfully prosecuted and fined in the year to March 2002, with 72 warning letters issued. In the first quarter of this year, 4 persons and 2 companies have been prosecuted under SDIO, and 16 warning letters were issued; and

In the last 12 months, we imposed 2 “cold shoulders” under the Takeovers Code, with 4 active investigations involving serious breaches of the Code, including 4 section 33 investigations.

In the matter of derivative actions, I wish to state that the Government has taken the advice of the SCCLR and asked the Commission to look into the possibility of developing a statutory derivative action. As the SCCLR Consultation document pointed out, the common law derivative actions for shareholders are complicated, but the Commission is actively studying the matter.

As you are all aware, the Commission successfully undertook the first legal suit under section 37A SFCO in the case of Mandarin Resources for unfair prejudice, in which we withdrew our section 45 SFCO winding up application only after the defendant agreed to buy out the minorities at fair value. This investigation and case took 6 years, but we persevered to successful settlement. I would like to warn all those who engage in corporate misconduct that we will not hesitate to use our powers under the

862

Page 65: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

SFO to pursue them to court. My Enforcement colleagues are already actively looking.

The Commission is currently beefing up its enforcement and corporate finance resources to tackle these areas as a matter of priority. It will add 15 staff to this area by the end of the year.

In addition, the Commission has strengthened its cooperation with both the CCB and the CSRC in the investigation of corporate misconduct in Hong Kong and also the activities of Hong Kong listed companies in the Mainland. We will increase our vigilance and we will strive to complete our investigations as fast as we can work together with our regulatory counterparts.

In short, those who break the securities law are now warned. We will pursue them without fear or favour. They will be investigated and prosecuted in accordance with the law.

Ladies and Gentlemen,

The lessons of Enron and WorldCom are quite clear. Those who seek capital from the public have a fiduciary duty to the public – to be truthful, honest and fair. If Hong Kong is to maintain its role as an international financial centre and the leading overseas fund raising centre for Mainland and other regional companies, then we must press ahead with our reforms in the regulatory and infrastructure areas. The opportunities are huge, but so are the pains of adjustment.

In exercising regulatory functions, I am always reminded of the line that Dr Goh Keng Swee, former Deputy Prime Minister of Singapore used in

863

Page 66: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

paraphrasing an old Chinese saying, “regulation [governance] is like frying small fish – it must not be overdone.” If we over-regulate, we can stifle the entrepreneurship of the majority of listed companies that are law abiding and seek to raise funds from the public as efficiently and with as low costs as possible. Hong Kong has always prided itself as the freest of markets. On the other hand, if we under-regulate, a small minority that exploit loopholes or deliberately skirt the law can do huge damage to the integrity of our markets. Enron and WorldCom have already demonstrated what can happen in the largest and best regulated of markets.

The regulation of financial markets needs to walk that delicate tightrope between rewarding trust and efficiency, and punishing those who break the law. Each market must find its own right balance. There is no easy solution.

Under the new SFO, which has finally come into being after more than a decade in the making and which has strengthened our ability to do our job, the Commission is committed to defending the integrity of our markets. There are clearly structural issues in the Hong Kong regulatory framework that need to be addressed. Irrespective of these factors, the Commission will work closely with the Stock Exchange and all the other regulators in Hong Kong and abroad to tackle corporate misconduct as a matter of top priority. We all share the same objective to protect the integrity of our markets and the rights of shareholders.

I want to thank the Vocational Training Council once again for giving the opportunity to present these personal views.

864

Page 67: Chapter 87 - 90

Post-Enron Impact on Regulation of Financial Markets

Thank you very much.

Securities and Futures Commission23 September 2002

865

Page 68: Chapter 87 - 90

Figure 1Corporate Governance: Entry, Conduct & Exit

ENTRY CONDUCT & TRANSACTIONS EXIT

Code,Rules and Law

Listing Rules

Listing Rules- Corpo

rate disclosure

- Director & board practices

- Protection of shareholders’ rights

Takeovers & Mergers Code- Regulation

of acquisitions & mergers

Securities and Futures Ordinance- Investi

gation- Inside

r dealing- Marke

t manipulation

- Protection of shareholders’ rights

Companies Law- Special investigation- Prospectus law

Criminal Law- Stealing- Fraud

Anti-Corruption Laws-

Corruption

Delisting - Listing Rules- Insolvency

Legal Status

Non-statutory

Non-statutory Non-statutory Statutory Statutory Statutory

Statutory LR – Non-statutoryCompanies Ordinance - statutory

Post-E

nro

n im

pact o

n re

gu

latio

n o

f fi

nan

cial m

ark

ets

Page 69: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

Regulator HKEx HKEx SFC SFC FSRegistrar of Companies

CCB, Police

ICAC HKExOfficial Receiver

867

Page 70: Chapter 87 - 90

安 然 事 件 對 金 融 市 場 監 管 的 影 響

職業訓練局二十周年傑出學者/企業家講座2002年 9月 23日

李鍔教授、林麟書教授、各位傑出學者、各位嘉賓:

大家好!我很榮幸獲邀在職業訓練局二十周年的第三場傑出學者/企業家講座上發表演說。不過,緊隨國際知名的傑出科學家兼香港大學新任校長以及香港科技園行政總裁之後發表演講並不輕鬆。

我想在演說的開首作出證券監管者一般會作出的聲明:今次演說的內容純屬個人意見。雖然我在預備講稿時曾徵詢若干同事的意見,但我想強調,以下意見不一定代表證監會(包括證監會非執行董事)的立場13。我希望發表這些意見,是因為我相信在完善香港投資者的權益保障這個目標的進程上,我們正處於一個重要的轉折點。

眾所周知,自美國發生 Enron(安然) 及WorldCom(世界通訊)事件後,企業倒閉和企業管治失當事件已成為熱門的話題。去年,安然及世界通訊事件所涉及的市值損失總額達 800億美元(6,240億港元),約相等於香港同期股市市值的總跌幅。

我打算將這次演講分成三部分:13 我很感謝歐達禮先生與其他證監會同事就這篇講稿向我提供寶貴的意見,亦多謝趙雅賢女士在秘書事務上為我提供協助。本講辭內一切觀點、錯誤及遺漏完全屬於作者本身的責任。

868

90

Page 71: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

首先,我會概述企業管治問題的癥結和各主要市場正採取的補救行動;

目前監管香港上市公司的架構;及 證監會在處理企業失當行為方面所擔當的角色。

安然事件發生後的規例修訂

亞洲金融危機爆發後,良好的企業管治的重要性立即備受注目。2000年科技股泡沫的破裂,使歐美的市場監管機構理解到,科技股泡沫在某程度上可能是因差劣的會計帳目和企業失當行為所導致的,而這亦使到企業管治成為全球關注的課題,換言之,歡呼聲過後(或潮水退後),問題(或礁石)便開始顯露和呈現。

安然、世界通訊及其他有關公司事件的始末正逐步揭露。人們仍在爭論這些公司的倒閉原因,但情況似乎是,正如一名美國監管機構高層人員向我表示,美國出現了有史以來最嚴重的企業管治失當事件。企業管治之所以失當,是由於有關制度的若干制衡機制被不同層面的利益衝突削弱所致。由於美國擁有規模最大、最具深度的證券市場,並且設有最嚴密的監管架構,因此值得我花點時間解釋美國與香港的制度(香港的制度大致上建基於英國和澳洲的普通法制度)之間的分別。

企業管治攙合於每個司法管轄區的金融、法律和市場歷史之中。美國於 1929 年發生的華 爾 街股災,促 使當局在1933及 1934年訂立有關的證券法規及成立美國證券交易委員會(SEC),形成了美國現行的證券監管制度。該制度是以法定的信息披露為基礎,規定任何打算向公眾集資的公司都必須透過著名的電子數據收集、分析及檢索系統(EDGAR)14,向美

14 EDGAR的英文全稱是 Electronic Data Gathering, Analysis and Retrieval System。

869

Page 72: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

國證券交易委員會呈交法定資料存檔備案。這個以規則為本的制度是以 “買方自負”原則 (caveat emptor)為基礎,設有一套規則以指明發行人必須向投資者和公眾披露按推定理應是重要的的信息。

事實上,美國設有四道遏止企業失當行為的重要防線。

很明顯,第一道阻止企業失當行為的防線是企業的管理層或董事局本身,包括應該代表公眾利益的獨立非執行董事。美國參議院在《董事局在安然倒閉事件中所擔當的角色報告書》15中,清楚指明安然事件涉及有關方面未有履行受信責任:

“安然的董事局未有保障公司股東的權益,並因允許安然進行高風險的會計帳目活動、進行存在利益衝突的不恰當交易、大量未經披露的帳外活動以及向行政人員支付過高薪酬,導致這美國第七大上市公司倒閉。”

很多司法管轄區仍在討論薪酬偏低的非執行董事是否可以阻止嚴重的企業失當行為的發生。

第二道防線為企業顧問,例如審計師、律師、專業估值師、保薦人、投資銀行、銀行家和信貸評級機構等,他們應就企業的表現(包括其遵守相關操守準則、規則及法例的情況)提供獨立專業意見。近期的個案顯示,由於上述專業顧問向其客戶收取巨額費用,因此人們便會質疑他們所提供的意見的獨立性。這就是為何上述專業人士本身亦須受到規管。例如,在美國和若干歐洲國家,審計師受到公眾監督。然而,在英國、歐洲其他國家和香港,審計行業仍普遍實行自我監管。

15 美國參議院政府事務委員會,《董事局在安然倒閉事件中所擔當的角色報告書》,頁 107-70,2002年 7月 8日。

870

Page 73: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

第三道防線是上市公司的監管制度。美國的交易所(例如紐約證券交易所和納斯達克)按照其相關規則和數量準則來評審公司的上市資格,而所有發行人必須向美國證券交易委員會呈交有關的法定資料以作存檔備案。美國的制度設有由罰款以至判監等不同形式的制裁,從而懲處提供虛假或具誤導成分信息的人士。一般而言,蓄意違反證券法規屬刑事罪行。此外,美國的交易所會密切監察在其上市的公司,並經常將表現欠佳的公司除牌。例如,去年有 770家公司在納斯達克被除牌,其中有 390家因未有遵從上市規定遭除牌,數目接近新上市公司總數(145家)的 2.7倍。另外,美國各州及聯邦檢察部門亦可採取嚴厲的行動來打擊企業盜竊、行騙或欺詐罪行。

最後,上述三道防線以集體訴訟及勝訴收費制度作後盾。任何股東若認為利益受損,均可聯手對有關公司的管理層或大股東直接採取法律行動。小股東掌握這項強力武器後,便可確保公司的董事、控權股東及其顧問加倍謹慎行事,以避免引發費用高昂的集體訴訟行動。

我想指出英國、澳洲及香港的法制並不設有上述集體訴訟及勝訴收費制度,原因是這三個司法管轄區採用另一套法律制度,並認為此舉會促使社會上形成動輒興訟的風氣。

然而,縱使設有上述強大的制衡機制,仍然難以避免安然和世界通訊事件的發生。為秉持公平行事的原則,美國當局迅速在 2002年 7月 30日制定《塞巴尼斯-奧克斯雷法案》(Sarbanes-Oxley Act),透過以下措施加強企業管治及審計監管:

成立獨立的上市公司會計審察委員會以強制執行會計業的專業標準、操守準則和專業能力;

871

Page 74: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

美國證券交易委員會禁止有關方面向審計客戶提供涉及利益衝突的顧問服務,從而加強上市公司帳目審核的獨立性;

規定公司的行政總裁和財務總監須親自認證公司的財務報表的真確性,以及就欺詐行為訂立更嚴厲的罰則;

加強上市公司的信息披露要求,尤其是涉及帳外交易和內幕交易等範疇的規定;

指示美國證券交易委員會檢討確保證券分析員的獨立性的規則,以保障其獨立性和客觀性;

指示美國證券交易委員會全面檢討企業管治、審計與非審計工作的分隔,以及信貸評級機構的角色;及

增加美國證券交易委員會可動用的資源。

以上我花了點時間講解美國的制度,是因為熟悉美國制度的市場分析員往往會質疑,為何我們不能將美國模式的法規納入香港的制度。他們有此想法是因為他們普遍存有某種誤解。我將於稍後解釋這兩個制度其實截然不同,而我們亦需要了解在我們本身的法律和監管制度之下保障股東權益的最佳方法。

在歐洲,歐洲委員會發表了連串重大的改革指令,旨在協調和鞏固歐洲各證券市場,當中包括制定《招股章程指令》、《透明度責任指令》、《投資服務指令》、《打擊市場舞弊指令》以及對《上市准入指令》的修訂。

英國亦正完善其公司法和證券監管制度:

在 2000年 5月,英國上市主管當局的職能由倫敦證券交易所(該所自 1984年起擔當這項職責)轉移至英國金融事務管理局(FSA)。上市主管當局負責制訂英國《上市規則》,即證券發行人及英國一級市

872

Page 75: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

場需符合的規定,並監督該規則的遵從情況。上市主管當局亦負責批准證券納入作為英國的正式上市證券;

在 2002年 7月 16日,繼公司法檢討督導委員會發表總結報告後,英國政府發表了白皮書,指出公司法將予以精簡和現代化,以便適用於所有公司;

在 2002年 7月 30日,英國金融事務管理局就上市機制的檢討發表諮詢文件16。

澳洲於 1999年 10月通過《企業法經濟改革計劃法案》,並於 2000年 3月 13日生效,當中提出以下的主要改革:

引入遏止企業失當行為的法定衍生訴訟制度,以修訂在普通法下實施的訴訟制度和規定股東可強制行使其權利的情況;

釐清董事應謹慎行事及勤勉盡責的責任;及 為澳洲的會計準則釐定過程設立全新的制度性安排。

在內地,中國證券監督管理委員會(“中國證監會”)為上市公司訂立企業管治措施的工作亦有顯著的進展,例如:

引入規定上市公司必須聘請獨立非執行董事的規則; 推出提交季度報告的規定; 規定表現差劣的公司須退市;及 中國證監會與公安部門更緊密合作,加強執法行動。

由此可見,各主要市場,包括內地市場,都正就本身的企業管治和證券市場監管架構積極進行改革。

香港的企業管治和保障投資者權益的情況

16 英國金融事務管理局,《上市機制的檢討》,第 14號討論文件,2002年 7月。

873

Page 76: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

香港一直對企業管治的改革進程未有怠慢。正如財政司司長在 2001-02年度的財政預算案中表示,我們的首要目標是 “希望香港在企業管治方面成為典範,遠超區內的競爭對手。我們要為投資香港業務的人士提供亞洲區內最佳的保障,讓本港上市公司的企業管治水平……符合最高標準” 17。

香港就此所採取的主要措施包括以下各項:

香港交易及結算所有限公司(“香港交易所”)發表重要的諮詢文件,提出有關企業管治事宜的《上市規則》修訂建議,當中涉及股東權益保障、董事及董事局常規及企業匯報及資料披露。諮詢工作於 5月結束,市場正等待有關的諮詢結果;

公司法改革常務委員會(“常委會”)於 2000年開始全面檢討企業管治事宜,並於 2001年 7月發出諮詢文件,載述有關董事責任、股東權益及加強企業匯報的具體建議。常委會在多個範疇所提出的建議都獲得社會人士的廣泛支持,而有關建議亦與各主要市場的措施十分接近。政府當局正研究如何盡量採納該等建議;

常委會正穩步邁向第二階段的檢討,以研究審計委員會的角色與職能、制定各類公司的財務匯報準則,以及研究現行企業匯報制度的效用。上述工作預期於 2002年底完成;

《證券及期貨條例》(“該條例”)於 2002年 3月獲得通過,並預期將於 2003年初生效。該條例將可提高上市公司的透明度,而市場失當行為審裁處亦將根據該條例成立。此外,該條例可增強證監會的調

17 本段內容大部分摘錄自由財經事務局於2002年2月向立法會財經事務委員會提交的題為《致力加強企業管治:〈上市規則〉的檢討及其他措施》的報告。

874

Page 77: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

查權力,並賦予投資者就向公眾作出的虛假或具誤導成分的信息披露提起私人訴訟的訴因;

在 2002年 5月 6日發表諮詢文件,建議根據對該條例的有關規例作出的修訂訂立附屬法例,以賦權證監會根據該條例成為上市公司的信息披露事宜的法定監管機構。此舉使香港更接近美國證券交易委員會的運作模式,即由交易所(例如納斯達克或紐約證券交易所)處理上市事宜,但若上市公司披露虛假或具誤導成分的信息,則法定監管機構可以採取執法行動;及

至於國際方面,證監會與意大利的證券監管機構,即意大利全國證券交易所監察委員會(CONSOB)共同主持透明度與信息披露專責小組,負責制定一套國際持續披露準則。若國際證監會組織採納該套準則,我們日後將可以直接因應香港的情況而採用該套準則。

在推行上述措施期間,香港亦開始經歷若干企業事件。最近,香港的小股東採取了連串主動爭取權益的行動,要求監管機構干預有關企業的交易。在香港,小股東採取行動以爭取權益是良好的徵兆,而近日投資者的投訴日漸增多亦不無原因。市況暢旺時,鑑於所有投資者都期望資產價格上升,因此可疑的交易會較難察覺。然而,在跌市期間,小投資者會關注到大股東或會進行某些交易,使小股東的權益被攤薄或使其權利受到損害。

鑑於凡向公眾籌集資金者,都向公眾負有以竭誠公正的態度行事的責任,因此我們有必要對上市公司進行監管。上市公司通常透過以下途徑受到規管:它們必須首先符合《上市規則》所規定的上市準則才可獲准上市、其進行交易的手法須符

875

Page 78: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

合《公司收購及合併守則》及《上市規則》的規定,並且需符合例如《公司條例》及《證券及期貨條例》等適用法例的規定。

正如圖 1所示,涵蓋企業行為的規則,包括守則及規則(如規管上市公司、非法定的《上市規則》)及法例(如《公司條例》)。此外,舉例而言,有關規則亦包括管限企業融資顧問行為的《企業融資顧問操守準則》。守則與法例的主要分別,在於守則所施加的制裁並無法定權力,而法例則可施加由民事賠償以至監禁的法定制裁。

在香港的現行監管制度之下,除了由一家監管機構[聯合交易所(“聯交所”)]負責執行上市公司需符合的上市要求之外,另外亦有多家機構同時負責規管上市公司經營業務的手法[例如聯交所依據《上市規則》進行監管、證監會根據《收購守則》實施規管和監察有否內幕交易及市場操縱活動、廉政公署負責處理貪污個案,而商業罪案調查科則處理欺詐及盜竊個案]。財政司司長可以根據《公司條例》第143條委任特別審查員進行調查。至於上市公司是否需要退出香港交易所營辦的市場,則取決於《上市規則》的規定以及有關公司的清盤程序。

鑑於企業失當行為跨越多個範疇及不同監管機構的司法管轄權,因此當中涉及的核心課題,在於香港應否設立單一的主要企業監管機構或統籌部門,確保有關當局對在香港發生的企業失當行為採取貫徹一致及堅定不移的回應措施。

企業失當行為可按不同的嚴重程度加以劃分,當中包括缺乏管治能力及不公平的交易以至明顯的盜竊行為。現就此提出以下三大要點:-

876

Page 79: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

首先,大部分的香港上市公司都遵守法紀。正如近期標準普爾就香港的企業管治作出的檢討18所指出:“與其他亞洲國家比較,香港在企業管治方面表現卓著。”我們的確有若干上市公司躋身亞洲區內運作得最良好的公司的行列;

其次,所謂充分及公平的信息披露的基本原則,是指如果有任何信息對於投資者就有關公司的財政狀況及未來業務展望作出的投資決定屬關鍵或相關的資料,那麼該上市公司便應該提供所有這些信息。這便是執行遏止提供虛假及具誤導成分的資料的法規的作用;

第三,在公司成功上市後,監管者在這些上市公司進行的交易方面的參與涉及兩個範疇 – 交易的“監管地帶”,即監管者往往為著確保本身執行的有關規則在有關交易進行之前已獲得遵從而介入該等交易。此外,另一些執法行動屬於在“交易完成後”才採取的,當中需要監管者就有關失當行為進行調查及檢控,並會牽涉證監會的法規執行部、警方及在有些情況中,廉政公署。

我將在本節集中講述企業交易中的“監管地帶”的情況,即屬於香港交易所及證監會專責管轄的範圍。在下一節,我將會詳述我們的執法職能。

根據證監會與聯交所在1991年簽署的《諒解備忘錄》,聯交所(目前附屬於香港交易所)是上市公司的前線監管機構。這是因為聯交所負責執行規管上市公司的上市、大部分有關上市公司行為操守的事宜及退市或除牌規定的《上市規則》。

18 標準普爾,“香港的企業管治”,2002年 2月 15日,載於 http://www.standardpoor.com。

877

Page 80: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

聯交所基本上是採用以素質審核為本的監管制度來審批主板的上市申請,而於 1999年設立的創業板則採用以信息披露為本的監管制度。香港交易所於 2000年進行股份化改革及上市後,市場對其監管角色的性質的看法開始有所改變。

首先,一家以盈利為目標的交易所不能獲賦予法定執法權力,而其與其他上市公司之間存在屬合約性質的關係。

第二,市場認為(不論是對或錯),基於商業上的誘因,以盈利為目標的交易所會積極鼓勵更多公司上市,但打擊企業失當行為涉及成本和風險,而且通常不會帶來任何商業利益。一些棘手的個案可能會引致訴訟行動,繼而損害公司價值。

第三,各界普遍認為不應讓一家上市公司監管其他上市公司。

正如我剛才在講述美國的監管制度時所解釋,遏止企業失當行為的第一及第二道防線分別是公司管理層、董事局委員會,以及其審計師、法律顧問、保薦人及投資銀行的廉潔穩健和持正操守。在香港,監管上述各方的企業管治的規範,主要屬於缺乏法定制裁的《上市規則》的範疇,而與美國或英國比較,前者的證券交易委員會及後者的金融事務管理局則可以施加民事罰款。不屬上述範疇的其他界別則由自我監管組織加以監察。

因此,在日常企業交易的“監管地帶”中,第三道防線取決於監督這些交易的監管者的角色。目前,上述監管地帶由兩套準則所規範,分別是香港交易所執行的《上市規則》及由證監會執行的《收購守則》。

878

Page 81: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

香港的上市公司每日進行數以千計的商業交易。正如我所說,由於香港整體上具備良好的企業管治架構,所以這些交易大多無需監管者介入。

然而,某些可能會被股東、債權人及企業的其他關涉各方提出爭議的交易,應該受到法院的管轄。這就是第四道防線。根據我們的普通法制度,只有法院才獲賦最適當的權力決定一宗交易是否合法。可是,在香港,訴訟費用十分高昂,而且缺乏集體訴訟/勝訴收費制度,所以不難想像會有股東要求監管者介入有關的爭議性交易。

若這些交易屬於《上市規則》或《收購守則》的監管範圍,負責的監管機構便會進行盡職審查,以確定有關法規有否獲得遵守。當中涉及查證有關申請人或其顧問是否已妥當地完成本身的工作,以及有否作出全面而公平的披露,而在特殊情況下,更需要由獨立股東作出表決。上述盡職審查工作可能包括要求有關方面披露額外資料、作出澄清及進行獨立估值。

最可能會引起爭論的,就是那些看來不公平但卻符合有關的非法定規則的交易。這方面應透過適當地進行市場諮詢及其他必要的程序,從而在規則上作出修訂。

其實,問題的關鍵在於非法定的規則或準則能否有效地監管企業行為。在這些準則之下,私下/公開譴責或嚴厲譴責被認為充其量只屬於輕微的處罰。若能夠對違規行為處以被驅逐離場的懲罰,例如撤銷牌照,或訂明違規者實際上會被勒令退市(如《收購守則》的規定),操守準則才能發揮作用。然而,退市機制迄今尚未被用作為制裁上市公司的紀律處分手段。

證監會已發現這個問題構成執行企業信息披露規定的漏洞,尤其是對於採用以信息披露為本的監管制度的創業板,有

879

Page 82: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

關問題更為嚴重。為了加強信息披露的制裁措施,我們在 5月就“雙重呈報規定”諮詢市場意見,建議訂立證監會作為上市公司信息披露的法定監管者。

我們很高興看到諮詢結果支持建議中的規則修訂,而政府亦已經給予有關批准。所以,根據應該會在明年初生效的該條例的附屬法例,所有呈報香港交易所的資料,都必須同時呈交予證監會。

舉例來說,如果有關方面所披露的資料存在嚴重的虛假或誤導成分,證監會可行使該條例第 182-3條所賦予的權力展開調查,並從一系列的執法途徑中選擇採取適當的行動,當中包括:

暫停上市證券的交易; 申請法庭頒令,以便就上市公司出現的壓迫小股東

情況、不充分披露、不公平地損害股東的利益的行為、形事罪行或失當行為作出補救;

發出禁制令以制止違反該條例的行為; 建議財政司司長就披露涉及證券的虛假或誤導性資

料的個案,在市場失當行審裁處進行民事訴訟; 就披露涉及證券的虛假或誤導性資料的行為作出刑

事檢控; 申請將有關公司清盤;及 對上市公司的證監會持牌企業融資顧問採取紀律處分行

動(包括處以最高為 1,000萬元的罰款,作出譴責及暫時吊銷或撤銷牌照)。

現行制度的問題在於縱使進行了這些改革,我們的監管地帶目前仍是由一家前線監管機構根據《上市規則》來監察上市及除牌事宜、企業管治架構及各類交易,而證監會則直接負責執行《收購守則》的事宜,並監察和監督該前線監管機構。

880

Page 83: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

這就是目前由兩家監管機構進行監管的制度或割裂的監管制度有欠清晰之處,也使到整個監管過程更形複雜並增加額外成本。由於沒有單一的監管機構能夠全面瞭解犯案者的最終意圖,因此需要協調監管角色,結果導致監管工作受到阻延。

事實上,近期的一些個案亦顯示出,監管套戥的情況是有可能發生的。這是因為如果某宗交易未能符合其中一套規則(例如《收購守則》)的規定,有關公司可對交易加以修改,然後嘗試根據《上市規則》進行另一宗動機類同的交易,因而令致小股東感到相當失望。

總而言之,就監管及保障小股東權益而言,香港的現行模式與“美式制度”有很大差別。在美國的法制下,受屈的股東可以透過集體訴訟/勝訴收費的訴訟安排,就差劣的信息披露或以其他理由提起訴訟。除此之外,兩者之間還有很多其他差異,包括美國證券交易委員會的權力及職權範圍、機構投資者對企業施加的壓力,以及美國的交易所可迅速地將上市公司除牌等。

在小股東進行訴訟方面,英國與香港的情況較為相近。在英國,法律訴訟費用亦甚為高昂,但英國的金融事務管理局則以法定監管機構身分負責執行《上市規則》,更有權就違反該規則的行為施加罰款。由強而有力的獨立組織執行全面涵蓋上市公司監管重點的嚴厲行政制裁,可起到最有效的阻嚇作用 - 其優點是迅速、有效率、可增加公眾的信心,並以行政上訴作為制衡機制及提供司法覆核的機會。

在香港,這個目前由香港交易所及證監會管理的“監管地帶”必需能夠充分發揮其應有的作用。這是因為當有關方面實際上難以借助法律上的補救措施時,這個“監管地帶”便構

881

Page 84: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

成我們對付企業失當行為的主要防線。假如“監管地帶”的監管者的權力受到削弱,那麼在沒有其他補償機制的情況下,整個投資者保障制度也無法全面發揮其應有的作用。

換言之,我們必需首先處理兩項主要的政策事宜。第一,我們應否改變現行的法定監管制度,以完善企業管治及保障股東的權益;第二,現行的涉及“監管地帶”的監管架構及程序應否簡化,以免在就企業失當行為作出監管回應時出現工作重疊及延誤的情況。

這些問題事關重大,只有透過廣泛的諮詢才可由政府當局及立法機構加以解答。我可以在此提出的,就是國際上已就這些事宜提供充足的經驗及進行充分的討論,值得我們參考借鑑。

我在證監會的同事和我本人當然明白,有關政策決定涉及極其繁複的考慮因素,再者,我們也沒有低估承擔有關工作所需的資源和專業知識。因此,我個人歡迎財政司司長最近公布政府正在考慮委任專家小組,以研究這個複雜的課題。

證監會在打擊企業失當行為方面的角色

最後,讓我說明證監會如何透過執法行動打擊企業失當行為。正如我剛才所解釋,香港並沒有單一的企業監管機構。聯交所除擔任上市公司的前線監管者,負責執行《上市規則》之外,亦是批准公司上市的審批機關。證監會亦分擔監管上市公司操守的責任,所涉及的範疇包括打擊內幕交易、監管證券權益的法定披露(《證券(披露權益)條例》),以及在懷疑有不當情況時審查上市公司的簿冊和紀錄。此外,證監會亦負責執行《公司收購及合併守則》。至於涉及貪污、詐騙及盜竊的案件,以及超越香港司法管轄權的個案,證監會會與其他監管機構合

882

Page 85: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

作進行調查及跟進查訊,當中包括聯交所、商業罪案調查科、廉政公署及海外監管機構。

作為保障證券業的法治情況的法定監管機構,證監會亦必須在法律所賦予的權力範圍內行事。大家必須明白,我們一般不能干預商業上的交易,而該等交易的事宜有賴公司的董事局、有關法律及財務顧問、會計師及專業估值師作出判斷,而在個別情況下,亦需要由股東來作出表決。

香港市場獨有的三個重要因素,決定我們打擊企業失當行為的方法:

在香港上市的公司,有接近四分之三是在香港境外註冊成立的;

香港大部分上市公司都同時在香港境外經營業務;及

我們因此必需與香港或其他海外監管機構緊密合作,以進行涉及香港上市公司的調查。

有人可能會對我們在多宗矚目個案中保持沉默感到疑惑。背後的原因,是由於《證券及期貨事務監察委員會條例》(“《證監會條例》”)第59條對進行調查的證監會人員施加的一項保密責任。

這項保密責任背後的理據是非常充分的。首先,若將調查公開,可能會導致受調查公司的股價急跌,使股東可能蒙受嚴重損失。第二,泄露調查的資料會使受調查人預早知悉有關的調查行動,引致相關證據可能會被銷毀或這些人畏罪潛逃。第三,泄露調查資料可能會影響其後進行的刑事審訊。

新訂立的《證券及期貨條例》第378條亦訂有相同限制。然而,雖然我們不能評論當前的個案或調查,但我可以明確地

883

Page 86: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

告訴大家,最近數月被傳媒廣泛報道的多宗個案,我們現正進行調查。

我們的法規執行部執行董事李顯能先生已在6月24日的記者招待會上表明,對企業管治案件的調查將會是證監會2002-2003年度的首要工作。以下一些簡單數據應是最佳的說明: -

自今年3月開始,我們根據《證監會條例》第29A條對上市公司展開的調查個案已達4宗,而根據《證監會條例》第33條展開調查的個案亦有3宗;

我們與警方商業罪案調查科共同商討並在調查中的個案達19宗,其中7宗涉及上市公司;

我們是在美國以外在內幕交易檢控工作方面最成功的地區之一。去年,我們的主要成功檢控個案有3宗(涉及泰昇集團、永德信實業及中國太陽神的股份),當中導致有關方面被勒令交回利潤2,280萬元及繳付罰款2,320萬元;另外有4宗調查仍在進行中,另有8宗正等待轉交內幕交易審裁處審理;

至於操縱市場活動,我們的調查去年導致4人在3宗個案(金威集團控股、威發國際集團及僑福企業)中被定罪,而法院對有關犯案者的懲處亦日漸嚴厲 – 當中有2人被判監禁、1人獲判緩刑並需進行社會服務,另一人則被判罰款;

在2002年度首季,在商業罪案調查科全力合作之下,4人在2宗證監會的調查個案(涉及鈞濠集團及Gay Giano International Group)中被定罪,而該科亦在Gay Giano的案件中對另外2人提出檢控;

884

Page 87: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

至於涉及披露權益的檢控個案,即旨在要求掌握內幕消息者增加其股份交易的透明度的案件,我們在截至2002年3月為止的一年內,除成功檢控14人及8家公司(當中有些被判罰款)之外,亦發出72封警告信。在本年首季內,我們根據《證券(披露權益)條例》檢控 4人及2家公司,並發出16封警告信;及

在過去12個月以來,我們根據《收購守則》施加2項“冷淡對待令”,而目前正調查4宗涉及嚴重違反該份守則規定的個案,當中包括4宗根據《證監會條例》第33條展開調查的個案。

關於衍生訴訟的建議,我謹指出,政府當局已接納常委會的建議,要求證監會研究能否訂立一套法定的衍生訴訟制度。正如常委會的諮詢文件所述,在普通法下的股東衍生訴訟行動是頗為複雜的。儘管如此,證監會目前正積極研究該項事宜。

相信在座各位都知道,證監會在德智發展有限公司的個案中,成功根據《證監會條例》第 37A條以不公平損害股東利益為理由提起首宗法律訴訟。在有關個案中,證監會使辯方同意按公平價值購入小股東的全部股份,然後才撤回本會先前根據《證監會條例》第 45條就該公司向法院提出的清盤呈請。該宗調查及個案歷時 6年之久。由於我們努力不懈,最終能夠與有關人士達成和解協議。我謹此警告所有從事企業失當行為的違規者,我們將會毫不猶疑地運用《證券及期貨條例》賦予我們的權力,將其繩之於法。我在證監會法規執行部的同事已經積極注視有關活動。

為配合上述的目標,證監會現正加強法規執行及企業融資部門的資源,以便重點對付這類個案。本會將在今年年底前為這些部門增添15名職員。

885

Page 88: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

此外,我們亦與商業罪案調查科及中國證監會加強合作,以便調查在香港發生的企業行為失當個案,以及調查香港上市公司在內地的活動。我們將會提高警覺,致力取得我們監管同行的合作,盡快完成有關的調查。

簡單來說,我們現已向所有違反證券法規者發出警告。我們將會不徇私、不畏懼地向其採取行動。違規者必定會依法受到調查和加以檢控。

各位,安然和世界通訊事件所帶來的教訓清楚不過:任何人如要從公眾取得資金,便要對公眾負上受信責任 – 即其本身必須真誠、信實及行事公正。假如香港要維持其作為國際金融中心及內地和其他地區企業首要海外集資中心的角色,我們便必須繼續推動在監管和基礎設施方面的改革。我們面對的機遇很多,但調整所帶來的痛楚亦是不可小覷的。

在履行監管職能時,我時刻都謹記新加坡副總理吳慶瑞博士引用中國古籍所說的一句話,就是“治大國 [機構]若烹小鮮 – 不能過火。”假如我們監管過度,便會扼殺大部分上市公司的企業家精神,而這些上市公司都是奉公守法的,以及尋求以最有效和最低成本的方法從公眾集資。香港經常以作為全球最自由的市場自豪。另一方面,假如我們監管不足,小部分利用制度的漏洞或規避法規的人可以對本港市場的廉潔穩健構成重大的損害。安然和世界通訊事件已顯示出這些人對全球最大和監管最嚴格的市場所帶來的傷害。

金融市場的監管工作需要在既獎勵信實和效率又懲處違法份子這個困難而微妙的取向上謀取平衡。每個市場必須找出本身適當的平衡點。在這方面並沒有任何簡單的解決方法。

886

Page 89: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

經過逾10年的制訂工作後,新的《證券及期貨條例》終於快將生效。該條例加強了證監會的能力,以便我們可以更有效地工作。在該條例之下,證監會矢志捍衞香港市場的廉潔穩健。香港的監管架構明顯存在一些必需處理的結構性問題。然而,不論這些因素存在與否,證監會都會與聯交所及香港和境外的所有其他監管者並肩合作,重點對付企業失當行為個案。我們全都有一個共同目標,就是保護市場的廉潔穩健和保障股東的權益。

我謹此再次多謝職業訓練局給予我這次機會發表上述個人意見。

多謝各位。

證券及期貨事務監察委員會2002年 9月 23日

887

Page 90: Chapter 87 - 90

圖 1 - 企業管治 :

上市準則、行為操守及退市機制

上市準則 行為操守及交易事宜 退市機制

守則、規則及法例

《上市規則》

《上市規則》- 企業的信息披露- 董事及董事局常規- 股東權益保障

《公司收購及合併守則》- 規管涉及上市公司的收購及合併

《證券及期貨條例》- 調查- 內幕交易- 操縱市場- 保障股東權益

公司法- 特別調查- 招股章程法例

刑事法例- 偷竊- 欺詐

反貪污法例- 貪污個案

除牌規則- 《上市規則》- 無力償債

法律地位

非法定 非法定 非法定 法定 法定 法定 法定 《上市規則》- 非法定《公司條例》- 法定

監管者 香港交易所

香港交易所 證監會 證監會 財政司司長公司註冊處處長

商業罪案調查科警方

廉政公署 香港交易所破產管理署署長

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

Page 91: Chapter 87 - 90

安然事件對金融市場監管的影響

889